You are on page 1of 80

Journal of Economic Literature

Vol. XL (March 2002), pp. 7–72

Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality,


Journal of and the
Economic Labor
Literature, Vol. XLMarket
(March 2002)

Technical Change, Inequality,


and the Labor Market
D ARON ACEMOGLU1

1. Introduction the 90th percentile of the wage distri-


bution earned 266 percent more than a
1.1 Motivation worker at the 10th percentile. By 1995
What are the implications of techni- this number had risen to 366 percent
cal change for the labor market? How (author’s calculations from March CPS
does new technology affect the distri- data). Many commentators see a direct
bution of wages and income? Is tech- causal relationship between technologi-
nology responsible for the changes in cal changes and these radical shifts in
the wage structure observed in many the distribution of wages taking place in
advanced economies since the 1970s? the U.S. economy. The title of Alan
The recent consensus is that techni- Krueger’s (1993) influential paper on
cal change favors more skilled workers, computers and inequality summarizes
replaces tasks previously performed by this view: “How Computers Have
the unskilled, and exacerbates inequal- Changed the Wage Structure.” Jeremy
ity. This view is shaped largely by the Greenwood and Mehmet Yorukoglu
experience of the past several decades, (1997, p. 87) similarly give a succinct
which witnessed both major changes in statement:
technology, including the rapid spread Setting up, and operating, new technolo-
of computers in workplaces and in our gies often involves acquiring and processing
lives, and a sharp increase in wage in- information. Skill facilitates this adoption
process. Therefore, times of rapid technologi-
equality. In the United States, for ex- cal advancement should be associated with a
ample, the college premium—the wages rise in the return to skill.
of college graduates relative to the wages
of high-school graduates—increased by They further argue that we are now
over 25 percent between 1979 and in the midst of a “Third Industrial Revo-
1995. Overall earnings inequality also lution,” fueled by advances in informa-
increased sharply. In 1971, a worker at tion technology, and that this revolu-
tion is responsible for the increase in
1 Massachusetts Institute of Technology. I thank
inequality (as does Francesco Caselli
Alexis Leon for excellent research assistance and
Joshua Angrist, David Autor, Olivier Blanchard, 1999, in a paper entitled “Technological
Lawrence Katz, Omer Moav, John McMillan, Revolutions”).
Lawrence Mishel, Donald Morrison, Lee Ohanian, The view that technological develop-
Steve Pischke, Thomas Lemieux, Gianluca Vio-
lante, Bas ter Weel, and two anonymous referees ments favor skilled workers also receives
for comments. support from accounts of earlier
7
8 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

episodes. For example, there were already the idea that technological advances fa-
signs of significant technology-skill vor more skilled workers is a twentieth-
complementarity in the 1910s. Claudia century phenomenon. In nineteenth-
Goldin and Lawrence Katz (1998) argue century Britain, skilled artisans
that the spread of batch and continuous- destroyed weaving, spinning, and
process methods of production in- threshing machines during the Luddite
creased the demand for skills. They and Captain Swing riots, in the belief
add, “. . . the switch to electricity from that the new machines would make
steam and water-power energy sources their skills redundant. They were right:
was reinforcing because it reduced the the artisan shop was replaced by the
demand for unskilled manual workers factory and later by interchangeable
in many hauling, conveying, and assem- parts and the assembly line (e.g., John
bly tasks” (p. 695). Over this period, James and Jonathan Skinner 1985;
capital-intensive industries increased Goldin and Katz 1998). Products pre-
the demand for skills considerably (see viously manufactured by skilled artisans
Goldin and Katz 1998, table 3), and the started to be produced in factories by
scope of these industries expanded with workers with relatively few skills, and
the sharp fall in the price of electricity many previously complex tasks were
(see, for example, Arthur Woolf 1984, simplified, reducing the demand for
p. 178). The rapid increase in the im- skilled workers. 2 Joel Mokyr (1990, p.
portance of white-collar and clerical oc- 137) describes this process vividly:
cupations gave another boost to the de- First in firearms, then in clocks, pumps,
mand for skills. Generalizing from the locks, mechanical reapers, typewriters, sew-
experience of the 1920s, Harry Jerome ing machines, and eventually in engines and
(1934, p. 402) argued that “. . . in the bicycles, interchangeable parts technology
future . . . there is considerable reason proved superior and replaced the skilled
artisans working with chisel and file.
to believe that the effect of further
[mechanization] will be to raise the 2 In the absence of detailed econometric evi-
average skill required.” dence, it is difficult to generalize from the histori-
The early twentieth-century evidence cal examples and conclude that technical change
was so powerful that Zvi Griliches was definitely skill-replacing during the nine-
teenth century. Still, the only econometric evi-
(1969) suggested capital and skills are dence that I am aware of supports this view. Using
intrinsically complementary. Richard the 1850 Census of Manufacturers, James and
Nelson and Edmund Phelps (1967), Skinner (1985) find that there was more rapid sub-
stitution of capital for skilled workers than un-
Finis Welch (1970), Theodore Schultz skilled workers. It can also be argued that techni-
(1975), and Jan Tinbergen (1975) also cal change always increases the demand for
argued that technological developments “skills,” and the artisans who were hurt as a result
of new technology were not “skilled” since they
increase the demand for skills. Events lacked the flexibility to adapt to the required
since then support this notion. Personal changes. This argument is not totally convincing,
computers, computer-assisted produc- since the artisans earned considerably more than
other laborers (for example, James and Skinner
tion techniques, and robotics appear to 1985 report over 60 percent wage differentials for
complement skilled workers, replacing building and printing workers relative to laborers
many labor-intensive tasks. In this light, in the 1850s). So the artisans possessed skills that
were being rewarded by the market, and the stan-
it is perhaps natural to view the in- dardization of the production process destroyed
crease in inequality over the past sev- these rewards. On the other hand, it has to be
eral decades as a direct consequence of noted that many of the skill-replacing technologies
of the nineteenth century may have also increased
technical change. the demand for engineers and managers (see, e.g.,
Although the consensus is now broad, Goldin and Katz 1998).
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 9

Interchangeable parts were in fact very an acceleration in skill bias during the
much designed to be skill-replacing past few decades appears to be the main
(unskill-biased). Eli Whitney, a pioneer cause of the increase in inequality.
of interchangeable parts, described the • We can understand the behavior of
objective of this technology as: technical change by recognizing that
the development and use of technol-
. . . to substitute correct and effective op-
erations of machinery for the skill of the art-
ogy is, at least in part, a response to
ist which is acquired only by long practice profit incentives.3 When developing
and experience; a species of skill which is not skill-biased techniques is more profit-
possessed in this country to any considerable able, new technology will tend to be
extent. . . . (quoted in H. J. Habakkuk 1962, skill-biased. I suggest that the early
p. 22)
nineteenth century was characterized
The experience of the nineteenth and by skill-replacing developments be-
early twentieth centuries led Harry cause the increased supply of unskilled
Braverman (1974) and Stephen Marglin workers in the English cities (resulting
(1974) to argue that technical change from migration from rural areas and
was “deskilling”—a major purpose of from Ireland) made the introduction
technical change was to expand the divi- of these technologies profitable. In
sion of labor and simplify tasks pre- contrast, the twentieth century has
viously performed by artisans by break- been characterized by skill-biased
ing them into smaller, less skill-requiring technical change because the rapid in-
pieces. Braverman (1974, p. 113), for ex- crease in the supply of skilled workers
ample, suggested that the first principle has induced the development of skill-
of management and production tech- complementary technologies. The re-
niques of the period was “dissociation of cent acceleration in skill-biased tech-
the labor process from skills of the work- nical change is in turn likely to have
ers. The labor process is to be rendered been a response to the rapid increase
independent of craft, tradition, and the in the supply of skills during the past
workers’ knowledge.” several decades. However, I also argue
A longer view therefore suggests that that despite the acceleration in skill
technological advances may not have bias, we are most likely not in the
always increased the demand for skills. midst of a “technological revolution”;
In fact, most early nineteenth-century what has changed is not necessarily
innovations appear to have replaced the overall rate of progress, but the
skilled workers and expanded tasks per- types of technologies that are being
formed by the unskilled. But then, why developed.
have technological advances been skill-
biased in the twentieth century? And, 3 Precedents of this approach include Jacob

are technological changes the major cause Schmookler (1966), who emphasized demand pull
and the extent of the market as key determinants
of the recent increase in inequality? of innovations; the endogenous growth theory,
This essay attempts to answer these e.g., Paul Romer (1990), Gene Grossman and El-
questions. It has two main theses: hanan Helpman (1991), and Philippe Aghion and
Peter Howitt (1992); the induced innovation the-
ory, including Syed Ahmad (1965), Charles Ken-
• The behavior of wages and returns to nedy (1964), Paul Samuelson (1970), Yujiro
schooling indicates that technical Hayami and Vernon Ruttan (1970), and Paul
change has been skill-biased during the David (1975); and recent work including my own,
Acemoglu (1998, 1999b, 2000), Acemoglu and
past sixty years and probably for most Fabrizio Zilibotti (1999), and Michael Kiley
of the twentieth century. Furthermore, (1999).
10 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Finally, I conjecture that recent tech- creases in within-group (residual) in-


nological developments are likely to have equality—i.e., increases in inequality
affected the organization of the labor among observationally equivalent
market—including the way firms are workers—account for much of this
organized, labor market policies, and rise.
the form of labor market “institutions”— 4. Average wages have stagnated and
and may have had a large effect on the wages of low-skill workers have fallen
structure of wages through this channel. in real terms since 1970.
In the process of developing this ar-
gument, this essay sets out a simple I argue that technical change over the
theoretical framework in which inequal- past sixty years, or even over the past
ity and returns to skills are determined century, has been skill-biased. This con-
by supply and demand forces (technol- clusion follows from fact 1 above: in the
ogy). 4 Using this framework as a unify- absence of substantial skill bias in tech-
ing device, I critically survey many of nology, the large increase in the supply
the theories that explain the recent in- of skilled workers would have depressed
crease in inequality by technological the skill premium. In 1970, Welch (1970,
factors and discuss how various pieces p. 36) reached the same conclusion, and
of evidence can be interpreted within argued:
this framework. With the phenomenal rise in average edu-
cation, why have rates of return failed to
1.2 Summary of the Argument decline? . . .
It is obvious that changes have occurred to
I begin with a roadmap of the argu- prevent the decline in returns to acquiring
ment. Since the effect of new technol- education that would normally accompany a
rise in average educational level. Presumably,
ogy on the distribution of wages in the these changes have resulted in growth in de-
recent past is central to the focus here, mand for . . . education . . . sufficient to ab-
I organize this essay around a number sorb the increased supply with constant or
of salient facts from the post-war U.S. rising returns.
economy. 5 Briefly, these facts are:
The thirty years after Welch wrote these
1. The past sixty years have seen a large words witnessed a much more rapid in-
increase in the supply of more educated crease in the supply of education and a
workers, while returns to education sharp increase in the returns to more
have risen. skilled workers, suggesting that skill-
2. Returns to education fell during the biased changes in technology continued
1970s, when there was a very sharp throughout the postwar period.
increase in the supply of educated And yet, if technical change has been
workers. Returns to education then skill-biased throughout the recent past,
began a steep rise during the 1980s. why did inequality increase during the
3. Overall wage inequality rose sharply past thirty years, but not before? There
beginning in the early 1970s. In- are at least two possible answers to this
question. The first, which I call the
4 Precedents of the supply and demand ap-
steady-demand hypothesis, maintains that
proach include, among others, Gary Becker
(1964), Finis Welch (1970), and Jan Tinbergen demand for skills increases at a constant
(1975). pace, so changes in inequality must be
5 I limit the discussion of the major trends to
explained by the pace of the increase in
the U.S. economy because of space constraints and
also because there is notably more research to the supply of skills. According to this
build upon. hypothesis, inequality (returns to skills)
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 11

was relatively stable before the 1970s, ior of entrepreneurs driven by a variety
because the rate of skill accumulation of nonprofit motives. Demand for skills
in the U.S. economy was as rapid increased faster during the past thirty
as the constant pace of skill-biased years, this approach would maintain,
technical change (e.g., Katz and Kevin because of a technological revolution led
Murphy 1992; Murphy, Craig Riddell, by the microchip, personal computers,
and Paul Romer 1998; David Card and and the internet. 6 New technologies of
Thomas Lemieux 2000). The recent in- the early nineteenth century were skill-
crease in inequality is then explained, replacing (unskill-biased) because the
not by a major technological change, technological frontier then only en-
but by a decline in the growth rate of abled the invention of skill-replacing
the supply of skills. The second possible techniques.
answer comes from the acceleration hy- Nevertheless, there are several prob-
pothesis, which maintains that there has lems with this approach. First, although
been an acceleration in skill bias begin- a number of papers, including Green-
ning in the 1970s or the 1980s. Accord- wood and Yorukoglu (1997), Andres
ing to this hypothesis, there is a dis- Hornstein and Krusell (1997), and Ga-
continuity in the growth rate of the lor and Moav (2000), show that rapid
demand for skills. The most popular technical change may lead to slower to-
version of this hypothesis claims that tal factor productivity (TFP) growth,
there has been a notable acceleration in the slow rates of TFP and output
the skill bias of technology, driven by growth of the past several decades are
advances in information technology, or difficult to reconcile with a technologi-
perhaps a “Third Industrial Revolution.” cal revolution during this time period.
So was there an acceleration in skill Second, demand for skills appears to
bias? This question is difficult to an- have accelerated starting in the late
swer, as we lack direct measures of the 1970s, precisely when the supply of
degree of skill bias. To tackle this ques- skills increased very rapidly. Exogenous
tion, one therefore needs to look at a technology theories do not explain the
variety of evidence often pointing in timing of this acceleration. 7
different directions. I conclude below 6 See, among others, Krueger (1993), Eli Ber-
that skill-biased technical change is man, John Bound, and Griliches (1994), and David
likely to have accelerated over the past Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) for evidence that
several decades. This conclusion is the rapid spread of computers has increased the
demand for skills. See Per Krusell, Lee Ohanian,
based on the sharp increase in overall Victor Rios-Rull, and Giovanni Violante (2000),
inequality starting in the 1970s and on Oded Galor and Daniel Tsiddon (1997), Green-
the fact that returns to schooling rose wood and Yorukoglu (1997), Aghion and Howitt
(1998, ch. 9), Caselli (1999), Galor and Omer
over the past thirty years despite the Moav (2000), Violante (2000), Yonna Rubinstein
unusually rapid increase in the supply and Tsiddon (1999), Aghion, Howitt, and Violante
of educated workers. (2000), and Eric Gould, Moav, and Bruce Wein-
berg (2000) for models in which rapid technical
Why did the demand for skills accel- change increases the demand for skills and causes
erate over this period? And why has a rise in inequality.
7 Naturally, supply and demand may have
new technology favored more skilled
moved together because supply responded to de-
workers throughout the twentieth cen- mand. I argue below that the large increase in the
tury, but not during the nineteenth cen- supply of educated workers was not in anticipation
tury? One approach would view tech- of, or in response to, high returns, but driven by a
variety of other factors. More generally, I often
nology as exogenous, stemming from focus on the effect of the supply of skills on tech-
advances in science or from the behav- nology not because I view supply as exogenous,
12 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

An alternative theory maintains in- acceleration in skill bias could cause a


stead that new technologies are endoge- TFP slowdown because it creates an
nous and respond to incentives. It was imbalance in the composition of R&D.
the large increase in the supply of This approach also provides a possi-
skilled workers, this approach claims, ble explanation for the skill-replacing
that induced the acceleration in the de- technical change of the early nine-
mand for skills. When skill-biased tech- teenth century. The emergence of the
niques are more profitable, firms will most skill-replacing technologies of the
have greater incentives to develop and past two hundred years, the factory sys-
adopt such techniques. A key determi- tem, coincided with a large change in
nant of the profitability of new tech- relative supplies. This time, there was a
nologies is their market size; machines large migration of unskilled workers
that can be sold in greater numbers will from villages and Ireland to English cit-
be more profitable. Jacob Schmookler ies (see, for example, Habakkuk 1962;
(1966), in his pioneering study, Inven- Paul Bairoch 1988; or Jeffrey William-
tion and Economic Growth, placed son 1990). This increase in the “reserve
great emphasis on market size. He ar- army of unskilled workers,” slightly
gued that (p. 206) “invention is largely paraphrasing Karl Marx, created profit
an economic activity which, like other opportunities for firms to exploit by in-
economic activities, is pursued for gain; troducing technologies that could be
. . . expected gain varies with expected used with unskilled workers. In fact,
sales of goods embodying the inven- contemporary historians considered the
tion.” This reasoning implies that ma- incentive to replace skilled artisans by
chines complementary to skilled work- unskilled laborers to be a major objec-
ers will be more profitable to develop tive of technological improvements of
when there are more skilled workers the period. Ure, a historian in the
to use them. New technologies have first half of the nineteenth century,
become more skill-biased throughout describes these incentives as follows:
most of the twentieth century because It is, in fact, the constant aim and tendency
the supply of skilled workers has grown of every improvement in machinery to super-
steadily. This perspective also suggests sede human labor altogether, or to diminish
that a faster increase in the supply of its costs, by substituting the industry of
skills can lead to an acceleration in the women and children for that of men; of that
of ordinary labourers, for trained artisans.
demand for skills (Acemoglu 1998). So (quoted in Habakkuk 1962, p. 154)
the timing of the increases in supply
and demand is not a coincidence— These incentives for skill-replacing tech-
instead, it reflects technology respond- nologies, I argue, were shaped by the
ing to the supply of skills. Furthermore, large increase in the supply of unskilled
rapid skill-biased technical change is workers. So, it may be precisely the dif-
not necessarily associated with rapid ferential changes in the relative supply
overall technical progress. In fact, an of skilled and unskilled workers that ex-
plain both the presence of skill-replacing
technical change in the nineteenth cen-
but simply because the effect of supply on tech-
nology is more important in understanding the tury and skill-biased technical change
questions posed above. I discuss below how supply during the twentieth century.
may respond to changes in skill premia, and how A major shortcoming of the “pure
this response may account for the joint behavior of
the supply of, and demand for, skills over the past technological” approaches—of both ex-
century. ogenous and endogenous varieties—is
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 13

that they do not provide a natural expla- zational change, labor-market institu-
nation for the fall in the wages of tions, and international trade have in-
low-skill workers. Although a number of teracted with technical change in a fun-
papers, including Caselli (1999), Green- damental way, amplifying the direct
wood and Yorukoglu (1997), and Galor effect of technical change on inequality,
and Moav (2000), show that technologi- and likely causing the decline in the
cal revolutions may be associated with a wages of less-skilled workers.
fall in the wages of low-skill workers, it Therefore, the overall picture that
is difficult to see how sustained techno- emerges is not necessarily one in which
logical change can be associated with technology is the only factor affecting
an extended period of falling wages of the distribution of income. On the con-
low-skill workers and stagnant average trary, the underlying thesis of this essay
wages. This leads to the next question is that technology itself is no more than
for this essay. an endogenous actor. To explain the
Why did the real wages of low-skill changes in the distribution of income,
workers fall over the past several de- and to forecast what other changes may
cades? There are a number of possible happen in the future, we need to under-
answers. First, labor-market institu- stand the forces that shape technologi-
tions, for example labor unions, under- cal progress, and how technology inter-
went important changes over the past acts with the overall organization of the
thirty years, and these changes may labor market.
have reduced the wages of many manu- There is considerable uncertainty on
facturing workers, causing an increase many issues, and both more theoretical
in inequality and a decline in the real and more empirical work are needed.
wages of low-skill workers (e.g., Rich- Two areas deserve special attention.
ard Freeman 1991; John DiNardo, Ni- The first is the differential behavior of
cole Fortin, and Lemieux 1995; David residual inequality and returns to
Lee 1999). Second, international trade schooling during the 1970s. Most
between skill-scarce less-developed coun- economists view changes in residual in-
tries and skill-abundant rich economies equality as related to changes in labor-
increased over this period, and this may market prices. It is therefore puzzling
have put downward pressure on the that during the 1970s, while returns to
wages of low-skill workers in the United schooling fell, residual and overall in-
States (e.g., Adrian Wood 1994; Edward equality increased. I argue below that
Leamer 1995). Third, there has been a models based on a single skill index
transformation of the way in which (one type of skill or many types of skills
firms are organized, or perhaps in the that are perfect substitutes) are unable
way that firms and workers match (see, to explain this pattern. Instead, we need
for example, Acemoglu 1999a; Michael models with multidimensional skills.
Kremer and Eric Maskin 1999; Timothy Moreover, for this type of model to ex-
Bresnahan 1997; Bresnahan, Erik Bryn- plain the behavior of residual inequality
jolfsson, and Lorin Hitt 1999; and during the 1970s and the 1980s, techno-
Autor, Frank Levy, and Richard Mur- logical progress needs to have changed
nane 2000). Although each of these fac- the demand for different types of skills
tors could have been the cause of the differentially. The endogenous technol-
recent changes in the wage structure, I ogy models discussed above provide a
argue that their direct effect has been possible explanation for why different
limited. Instead, I suggest that organi- dimensions of skills may have been
14 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

affected differentially by technical rizes many of the salient trends I want


change. Nevertheless, the reasons for this to emphasize. In particular,
type of behavior require much more re- 1. There has been a remarkable in-
search. More generally, we know rela- crease in the supply of skills in the U.S.
tively little about the determinants of economy over the past sixty years. In
residual inequality, and this topic is a 1939, just over 6 percent of American
major research area for the future. The workers were college graduates. By
second area is cross-country differences 1996 this number had increased to over
in the behavior of wage inequality. 28 percent. In 1939, almost 68 percent
While inequality increased sharply in of all workers did not have a high
the United States, the United Kingdom, school degree. In 1996, this number
and Canada, it increased much less had fallen to less than 10 percent (see,
in Germany and many Scandinavian for example, Autor, Katz, and Krueger
economies. Although there are a num- 1998, table 1). The relative supply of
ber of recent papers addressing these skills plotted in figure 1 provides a
questions, much uncertainty still re- summary of these changes.
mains. I conjecture that cross-country 2. There has been no tendency for
differences in wage inequality may the returns to college to fall in the face
reflect, in part, technological choices of this large increase in supply—on the
made by these countries in response contrary, there is an increase in the col-
to the different incentives created by lege premium over this time period. An
their labor-market institutions, but important issue is whether changes in
much more research on this topic is the returns to college (or more gener-
required. ally other measures of wage inequality)
correspond to true changes in the re-
2. Empirical Trends turns to skills. As is well-known in the
labor literature, observed schooling pre-
The objective of this section is to il-
mia may reflect returns to ability. This
lustrate a number of major inequality
raises the possibility that changes in the
trends from the past several decades.
returns to schooling may be driven by
My aim is not to offer a comprehensive
composition effects (changes in the
survey of the empirical literature, but
composition of ability across schooling
simply to highlight the most salient
groups). In the appendix, I elaborate
trends to anchor the theoretical discus-
how changes in the distribution of un-
sion (see, e.g., Peter Gottschalk 1997;
observed skills across groups can create
George Johnson 1997; Katz and Autor
composition effects, and show that
2000, for recent surveys).
these composition effects cannot be re-
Figure 1 plots a measure of the sup-
sponsible for the changes in the wage
ply of college skills between 1949 and
structure. Therefore, here I interpret
1995, constructed along the lines of
these changes in the observed returns
Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998), as the
to schooling as changes in the true
ratio of college equivalents (those with
price of skills.
at least college + 0.5 × those with some
3. Following an acceleration in the
college) to noncollege equivalents
supply of skills, returns to college fell
(those with high school or less + 0.5 ×
sharply during the 1970s, leading
those with some college). 8 It also plots
Richard Freeman to conclude that
returns to college. This picture summa-
“Americans are over-educated” (Free-
8 See the appendix for data details. man 1976). Returns to college then rose
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 15

College wage premium Rel. supply of college skills

.8
.6

.6

Rel. supply of college skills


College wage premium

.5

.4

.4
.2

.3 0

39 49 59 69 79 89 96
year
Relative Supply of College Skills and College Premium
Figure 1. The Behavior of the (log) College Premium and Relative Supply of College Skills (weeks worked by
college equivalents divided by weeks worked of noncollege equivalents) between 1939 and 1996. Data from
March CPSs and 1940, 1950, and 1960 censuses.

very sharply during the 1980s. This in- illustrates two more important patterns:
crease in the returns to schooling has 1. Overall wage inequality started to
been one of the major motivating facts increase sharply in the early 1970s after
for the empirical inequality literature a period of relative stability—prior to
(e.g., Bound and Johnson 1992; Katz the 1970s, the 90th, 50th, and 10th per-
and Murphy 1992). centiles of the wage distribution fol-
There have also been important lowed each other closely, but came
changes in the overall distribution of apart sharply in the 1970s.
wages. Figure 2 plots the 90th, 50th 2. Median wages stagnated from 1975
and 10th percentiles of the overall onwards, while workers at the 10th
wage (weekly earnings) distribution percentile of the wage distribution (i.e.,
for white male workers between 1963
and 1997 (with the 1963 values for this would likely contribute to the composition ef-
all series indexed to 100). 9 This figure fects. Moreover, male-female wage difference nar-
rowed substantially over the same time period as
9 Sample constructed as described in the appen- well. School quality for black men also under-
dix. I focus here on wage inequality for white men went significant transformation (e.g., Welch 1973;
since labor market participation of women in- Card and Krueger 1992), and this could create
creased substantially over the sample period, and significant composition effects.
16 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

index 10th pctile wages index 50th pctile wages


index 90th pctile wages

150

140

130

120

110

100

90
65 70 75 80 85 90 95
year
Indexed Wages for White Males 1963–97
Figure 2. Changes in the Indexed Value of the 90th, 50th, and 10th Percentiles of the Wage Distribution for
White Males (1963 values normalized to 100). Data from March CPSs.

“low-skill workers”) saw their earnings Figure 3 turns to another measure: re-
fall in real terms to levels even below sidual (within-group) inequality, which
those in 1963. 10 shows inequality among observationally
equivalent workers. This figure displays
10 Average wages, like median wages, have stag-
nated. For example, white men aged 30–49 earned
three measures of residual inequality
409 a week in 1999 dollars in 1949, and 793 in among white male workers between
1969, which corresponds approximately to a 3.4 1963 and 1997: 50–10, 90–50 and 0.5
percent a year increase in real wages between
1949 and 1969. In contrast, the same age group
times 90–10 log wage residual differen-
earned 909 in 1989, or experienced only a 0.6 per- tials (I plot 0.5 times 90–10 wage differ-
cent a year increase between 1969 and 1989 (all entials in order to fit this on the same
numbers author’s calculation from census data).
The behavior of the median and average wage
scale as the other measures).
growth depends on the consumption deflator. I
have followed the literature in using the personal the increase in benefits, the share of labor in na-
consumption expenditure deflator. It has been ar- tional income has not fallen over this period (see,
gued that this deflator overstates inflation because e.g., Krueger 1999). So whether average wages
of difficulties in measuring quality change (e.g., have stagnated or continued to increase in line
Michael Boskin et al. 1995). Even in the presence with output growth depends on how benefits are
of such measurement problems, a large gap re- valued relative to earnings. It is also important to
mains between the rate of increase of real wages note that if these non-wage benefits are taken into
before and after the 1970s, unless there is an “ac- account, inequality appears to have increased even
celeration” in this bias exactly around the 1970s. more than the numbers here indicate (Brooks
Part of this gap is due to the increased importance Pierce 2000). This is because high-wage workers
of nonwage income and benefits. In fact, thanks to are the primary recipients of such benefits.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 17

90– 50 residual differences 50 –10 residual differences


0.5 times 90–10 residual diffs

.65

.6

.55

.5

.45

.4
65 70 75 80 85 90 95
year
Residual Inequality Measures for White Males 1963– 97
Figure 3. 90– 50, 50–10 and 0.5 × 90–10 Differentials from Log Weekly Wage Regressions for White Males
Aged 18–65.

To calculate these measures, I look at much in tandem with overall inequality—


the residuals from a standard Mincerian it shows a sharp increase starting in the
wage regression of the form early 1970s.11 Remarkably, all three mea-
ln w it = X′itβt + vit, (1) sures of residual inequality behave very
similarly, suggesting that forces affecting
where w it is weekly earnings for individ- the top of the male wage distribution
ual i observed in year t, and Xit is a set of (90–50) are also affecting the bottom of
controls which include nine education the wage distribution (50–10). Finally, note
dummies, a quartic in experience, and an important contrast between figure 1
region controls (constructed from the and figures 2 and 3. While returns to
March CPSs; see the appendix for details schooling fell during the 1970s, overall
of the sample). The fact that βt is in-
dexed by t indicates that returns to these 11 DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux (1995) provide
observed characteristics are allowed to evidence from the May Current Population Survey
vary from year to year. The measures of (CPS) data that residual and overall wage inequal-
residual inequality are calculated as the ity started to increase in the 1980s. Katz and Autor
(2000), on the other hand, find that residual wage
difference between the 90th and the inequality started to increase in the 1970s from
10th (or the 50th and the 10th, etc.) March and May CPS data, and from census data.
percentile values of the residual distri- See the appendix. Recent work by Thomas Piketty
and Emanuel Saez (2001) also finds an increase in
bution from this regression, vit. Residual inequality during the 1970s using data from the
inequality appears to have increased very Internal Revenue Service tax returns.
18 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

and residual inequality increased. I the returns to skills will also lead to an
return to this issue later in the essay. increase in within-group inequality.
Suppose that there are L(t) unskilled
3. Introduction to the Theory (low-education) workers and H(t) skilled
of Skill Premia (high-education) workers, supplying la-
bor inelastically at time t. All workers
While, undoubtedly, many factors af- are risk neutral, and maximize (the pres-
fect the distribution of wages, a natural ent value of) labor income. Also sup-
starting point for an economic analysis pose that labor markets are competitive
is that of supply and demand. In the in- (I return below to the role played by
troduction to his pioneering study of noncompetitive elements, especially in
income distribution, Tinbergen (1975, the European context).
p. 15) wrote The production function for the ag-
. . . what matters is the difference between gregate economy takes the constant
qualities available and qualities required by elasticity of substitution (CES) form
the demand side, that is by the organization
of production. (italics in original) Y(t) = [(Al(t)L(t))ρ + (Ah(t)H(t))ρ]1 ⁄ ρ, (2)

This is where I begin as well. I intro- where ρ ≤ 1, and Al(t) and Ah(t) are factor-
duce a simple framework that links augmenting technology terms. Although
wages to supply of skills and to demand all the results of interest hold for a general
generated by the technology possibili- constant returns to scale F(.) function, I
ties frontier of the economy. There are focus on the CES production function to
two types of workers, skilled and un- simplify the discussion. I drop the time
skilled (high and low-education work- argument when this causes no confusion.
ers), who are imperfect substitutes. Im- The elasticity of substitution between
perfect substitution between the two skilled and unskilled workers in this
types of workers is important in under- production function is σ ≡ 1 ⁄ (1 − ρ). I
standing how changes in relative sup- refer to skilled and unskilled workers as
plies affect skill premia. For now I gross substitutes when the elasticity of
think of the unskilled workers as those substitution σ > 1 (or ρ > 0), and gross
with a high school diploma, and the complements when σ < 1 (or ρ < 0).
skilled workers as those with a college Three noteworthy special cases are: (i)
degree. 12 So the focus in this section is σ → 0 (or ρ → −∞) when skilled and un-
on returns to schooling (or between- skilled workers will be Leontieff, and
group inequality), and I use the terms output can be produced only by using
“skill” and education interchangeably. skilled and unskilled workers in fixed
In practice, education and skills are proportions; (ii) σ → ∞ when skilled and
only imperfectly correlated, so it is use- unskilled workers are perfect substi-
ful to bear in mind that since there are tutes, and (iii) σ → 1, when the pro-
skilled and unskilled workers within the duction function tends to the Cobb
same education group, an increase in Douglas case. The value of the elasticity
of substitution will play a crucial role in
12 This classification of workers into skilled and
the interpretation of the results that fol-
unskilled groups is obviously appropriate only for
the twentieth-century United States. In many low. In particular, in this framework,
other countries or periods, high school graduates technologies either increase the pro-
could be considered to be “skilled” workers. More ductivity of skilled or unskilled workers,
generally, the two-skill model is a convenient
simplification, less realistic than a world with a that is, there are no explicitly skill-
continuum of imperfectly substitutable skills. replacing or unskilled-labor-replacing
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 19

technologies. 13 But, as we will see be- This equation implies ∂w L ⁄ ∂H ⁄ L > 0: as


low, depending on the value of the elas- the fraction of skilled workers in the
ticity of substitution, an increase in Ah labor force increases, the unskilled wage
can act either to complement or to should increase. Similarly, the skilled
“replace” skilled workers. wage is
The production function (2) admits ∂Y ρ ρ ρ
three different interpretations: wH = = Ah [Al (H ⁄ L) − ρ + Ah ](1 − ρ) ⁄ ρ,
∂H
1. There is only one good, and
skilled and unskilled workers are imper- which yields ∂w H ⁄ ∂H ⁄ L < 0; everything
fect substitutes in the production of this else equal, as skilled workers become
good. more abundant, their wages should fall.
2. The production function (2) is also Combining these two equations, the skill
equivalent to an economy where con- premium—the wage of skilled work-
sumers have utility function [Yρl + Yρh]1 ⁄ ρ ers divided by the wage of unskilled
defined over two goods. Good Yh is pro- workers—is14
duced using only skilled workers, and Yl ρ −(1 − ρ)
wH  Ah   H 
is produced using only unskilled work- ω= =
ers, with production functions Yh = AhH, w L  Al   L  (4)
and Yl = AlL. In this interpretation, it is (σ − 1) ⁄ σ −1 ⁄ σ
important that the economy is closed.  Ah  H
=  L .
We will see in section 6.3 that different  Al   
results obtain when international trade Equation (4) can be rewritten in a more
in these two goods is allowed. convenient form by taking logs,
3. A mixture of the above two
whereby different sectors produce σ − 1  Ah  1 H
goods that are imperfect substitutes, ln ω = ln   − ln   . (5)
σ A
 l σ L
and high- and low-education workers are
employed in both sectors. Naturally, the skill premium in-
Although the third interpretation is creases when skilled workers become
more realistic, I generally use one of the more scarce, i.e.,
first two, as they are easier to discuss. ∂ ln ω 1
Since labor markets are competitive, = − < 0. (6)
∂ ln H ⁄ L σ
the unskilled wage is
This is the usual substitution effect, and
∂Y ρ ρ ρ
wL = = Al [Al + Ah (H ⁄ L)ρ](1 − ρ) ⁄ ρ. (3) shows that for given skill bias of technol-
∂L ogy, as captured by Ah ⁄ Al, the relative
demand curve for skill is downward slop-
13 A more general formulation would replace ing with elasticity 1 ⁄ σ = (1 − ρ). Intui-
equation (2) with the production function tively, an increase in H/L creates two
different types of substitution. First, if
Y(t) = [(1 − bt)(A l(t)L(t) + B l(t))ρ
+ bt(A h (t)H(t) + B h (t))ρ ]1 ⁄ ρ , 14 For some parameter values, skilled workers
may have lower wages than the unskilled, i.e.,
where B l and B h would be directly unskilled-labor- ω ≤ 1. One may want to impose
replacing and skill-replacing technologies, and an σ−1
 Ah  H
increase in b t would correspond to some of the A  > ,
L
tasks previously performed by the unskilled being  l
taken over by the skilled (see, e.g., Johnson and to avoid this. Alternatively, one could assume that
Stafford 1999 on this). For most of the analysis skilled workers can use the technologies normally
here, there is little to be gained from this more used by the unskilled, A l, and be more (or equally)
general production function (but see section 5.3). productive at this than the unskilled.
20 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Skill premium college graduate workers (relative to


Relative supply high school graduates) that were as high
ω′′ of skills
as 40 percent quickly fell to less than 20
percent. The extent of substitution was
Relative demand
also clear. First, many college graduate
ω for skills workers could not find employment in
skilled jobs: Angrist (1995) shows a
sharp increase in the unemployment
ω′
rate of college graduates, and Ze’ev
Skill-biased tech.
change Schiff and Ehud Ya’ari (1989) report
H/L H′/L′
that only one in eight Palestinian gradu-
ates could find work in his profession,
Figure 4. The Relative Demand for Skills with the rest working as unskilled labor-
ers, mainly in the construction industry.
Second, premia for tasks usually per-
skilled and unskilled workers are produc- formed by more educated workers fell
ing the same good, but performing dif- sharply. Between 1984 and 1987, the
ferent functions, an increase in the num- premium for administrative and mana-
ber of skilled workers will necessitate a gerial jobs (relative to manual laborers)
substitution of skilled workers for tasks fell from .32 to .12, while the premium
previously performed by the unskilled. for clerical workers fell from .02 to –.08
Second, if skilled and unskilled work- (see Angrist 1995 for details).
ers are producing different goods, the As equation (6) shows, the elasticity
greater number of skilled workers will of substitution, σ, is important for the
lead to a substitution of the consumption behavior of the skill premium when
of the unskilled good by the skilled good. supply changes. The elasticity of substi-
In both cases, this substitution hurts the tution is also crucial for the response of
relative earnings of skilled workers. the skill premium to changes in tech-
Figure 4 draws the relative demand nology. Unfortunately, this parameter is
for skills, equation (5), against the rela- rather difficult to estimate, since it re-
tive supply of skills, H/L, which is taken fers to an elasticity of substitution that
to be given for the purposes of this ex- combines substitution both within and
ercise. An increase in the relative sup- across industries. Nevertheless, there
ply, from H/L to H′/L′, moves the equi- are a number of estimates using aggre-
librium point along the downward gate data that give a range of plausible
sloping relative demand curve, and values. The majority of these estimates
reduces the skill premium from ω to ω′. are between σ = 1 and 2 (see for exam-
An interesting case study of the re- ple Freeman 1986). The response of
sponse of the returns to schooling to an college premium for Palestinian labor
increase in the supply of skills is pro- reported in Angrist (1995), for example,
vided by the experience in the West implies an elasticity of substitution be-
Bank and Gaza Strip during the 1980s. tween workers with sixteen years of
As Joshua Angrist (1995) illustrates, schooling and those with less than
there was a very large increase in the twelve years of schooling of approxi-
supply of skilled Palestinian labor as mately σ = 2.
Palestinian institutions of higher educa- Given the focus of this essay, it is also
tion, totally absent before 1972, began important to know how the skill premium
to open. Angrist shows that premia to responds to technology. Differentiation
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 21

of (5) shows that the result depends on elasticity of substitution between skilled
the elasticity of substitution: and unskilled workers greater than 1.
It is also useful to compute the aver-
∂ ln ω σ−1 age wage in this economy. Without con-
= .
∂ ln (Ah ⁄ Al) σ trolling for changes in the educational
composition of the labor force, the
Therefore, if σ > 1 (i.e., ρ ∈ (0, 1]), then average wage is
improvements in the skill-complementary
technology increase the skill premium. Lw L + Hw H [(AlL)ρ + (AhH)ρ]1 ⁄ ρ (7)
w= = ,
This can be seen in figure 4 as a shift out L+H 1+ H⁄L
of the relative demand curve, moving the
skill premium from ω to ω′′. The con- which is also increasing in H/L as long as
verse is obtained when σ < 1: that is, the skill premium is positive (i.e., ω > 1
when σ < 1, an improvement in the pro- or Aρh(H ⁄ L)ρ − Aρl > 0). Intuitively, as the
ductivity of skilled workers, Ah, relative skill composition of the labor force
to the productivity of unskilled workers, improves, wages will increase.
Al, shifts the relative demand curve in Therefore, the results so far imply
and reduces the skill premium. This case that in response to an increase in H/L:
appears paradoxical at first, but is, in 1. The relative wages of skilled workers,
fact, quite intuitive. Consider, for ex- the skill premium ω = w H ⁄ w L, decreases.
ample, a Leontieff (fixed proportions) 2. Wages of unskilled workers increase.
production function. In this case, when 3. Wages of skilled workers decrease.
Ah increases and skilled workers become 4. The average wage (without control-
more productive, the demand for un- ling for education) rises.
skilled workers increases by more than
the demand for skilled workers. In some It is also useful to highlight the impli-
sense, in this case, the increase in Ah is cations of an increase in Ah on wage
creating an “excess supply” of skilled levels. First, an increase in Ah, with Al
workers given the number of unskilled constant, corresponds to an increase in
workers. This excess supply increases the Ah ⁄ Al; the implications of this change
unskilled wage relative to the skilled on the skill premium were discussed
wage. This observation raises an impor- above. Moreover if Ah increases, every-
tant caveat. It is tempting to interpret thing else being equal, we expect both
improvements in technologies used by the wages of unskilled and skilled work-
skilled workers, Ah, as “skill-biased.” ers (and therefore the average wage) to
However, when the elasticity of substitu- increase: in this framework, technological
tion is less than 1, it will be advances in improvements always increase all wages.
technologies used with unskilled work- The most central result for our pur-
ers, Al, that increase the relative produc- poses is that as H/L increases, the skill
tivity and wages of skilled workers, and premium, ω , should fall. In terms of
an increase in Ah relative to Al will be figure 4, the increase in supply cor-
“skill-replacing.” responds to a rightward shift in the ver-
Nevertheless, the conventional wis- tical line from H/L to H′ ⁄ L′, which
dom is that the skill premium increases would move the economy along the
when skilled workers become relatively downward sloping demand curve for
more—not relatively less—productive, skills. But this tendency of the skill pre-
which is consistent with σ > 1. In fact, mium to fall could be counteracted by
as noted above, most estimates show an changes in technology, as captured by
22 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
σ−1
σ
ln (Ah ⁄ Al). Therefore, this simple for- of wages and employment. Autor, Katz,
mulation encapsulates the essence of and Krueger (1998) report employment
the two forces that Tinbergen (1975) and wage-bill shares for different
emphasized: groups of workers in their appendix ta-
The two preponderant forces at work are ble A1. If we assume a specific value for
technological development, which made for σ, we can translate these numbers into
a relative increase in demand and hence in changes in Ah ⁄ Al. In particular, notice
the income ratio . . . and increased access that the relative wage bill of skilled
to schooling, which made for a relative workers is given by
decrease. (p. 35, italics in original)
(σ − 1) ⁄ σ (σ − 1) ⁄ σ
wHH  Ah  H
As discussed in the empirical trends SH = = . (8)
section, the past sixty years, and par- w LL  Al  L
 
ticularly the past thirty years, have wit- Hence, we have
nessed a rapid increase in the supply of
Ah SσH ⁄ (σ − 1)
skills, H/L, but no corresponding fall in = . (9)
the skill premium. This implies that the Al H⁄L
demand for skills must have increased— In table 1, I calculate the implied
as a result of Tinbergen’s “technological Ah ⁄ Al values for σ = 1.4 and for σ = 2
development”—to prevent the relative using workers with some college, col-
wages of skilled workers from declining. lege graduates, and college equivalents
Although in richer models there could definitions of Autor, Katz, and Krueger
be other factors leading to such a steady (1998)—see their paper for a more de-
increase in the demand for skills, the tailed analysis that controls for potential
cause highlighted by this simple frame- composition effects. In all cases, there
work, skill-biased technical change, is a is a large implied increase in Ah ⁄ Al and
natural candidate. More explicitly, the (Ah ⁄ Al)(σ − 1) ⁄ σ. For example, the num-
relative productivity of skilled workers, bers indicate that, assuming an elastic-
(Ah ⁄ Al)(σ − 1) ⁄ σ, must have increased. ity of substitution of 1.4, the relative
The increase in (Ah ⁄ Al)(σ − 1) ⁄ σ can be productivity of college graduates, Ah ⁄ Al,
interpreted in a number of different which was approximately 0.030 in 1960,
ways. In a two-good economy, such skill- increased to 0.069 in 1970, and to 0.157
biased technical change corresponds to in 1980. Between 1980 and 1990, it in-
an increase in Ah ⁄ Al and ρ > 0 (σ > 1) creased by a factor of almost three to
—i.e., skilled workers becoming more reach 0.470. As equation (5) shows,
productive. Skill-biased technical change changes in the demand index
σ−1
could also take the form of a decrease D = (Ah ⁄ Al) σ may be more informative
in Ah ⁄ Al and ρ < 0 (σ < 1). In this case than changes in Ah ⁄ Al, so table 1 also
the “physical” productivity of unskilled gives the evolution of D.
workers would increase, but their rela- The view that the post-war period is
tive wages would fall due to relative characterized by skill-biased technical
price effects. Alternatively, with the change also receives support from the
one-good interpretation, skill-biased within-industry changes in employment
technical change simply corresponds to patterns. With constant technology, an
a change in the production function increase in the relative price of a factor
that increases (Ah ⁄ Al)(σ − 1) ⁄ σ. should depress its usage in all sectors.
Some back-of-the-envelope calcula- Since the college premium increased
tions provide a sense of the rise in Ah ⁄ Al after 1979, with constant technology,
implied by the changes in the structure there should be fewer college graduates
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 23

TABLE 1
EMPLOYMENT SHARES AND SKILL-BIASED TECHNICAL CHANGE, 1940–1990

Employment Share Wage Bill Share


Some College College Some College College
college graduate equivalent college graduate equivalent
1940 6.4 6.1 9.3 8.9 12.3 16.7
1950 9.5 7.7 12.4 11.0 11.9 17.4
1960 12.5 10.1 16.4 14.1 16.4 23.4
1970 16.4 13.4 21.5 16.5 21.5 29.7
1980 23.6 19.2 31.0 22.4 28.1 39.3
1990 30.8 24.0 39.3 28.5 36.7 51.0
σ = 1.4 σ=2
Some College College Some College College
college graduate equivalent college graduate equivalent
Ah Ah Ah Ah Ah Ah
Al
D Al
D Al
D Al
D Al
D Al
D
1940 0.004 0.21 0.016 0.31 0.035 0.38 0.140 0.37 0.303 .055 0.392 0.63
1950 0.006 0.24 0.011 0.28 0.030 0.37 0.146 0.38 0.219 0.47 0.313 0.56
1960 0.013 0.29 0.030 0.37 0.080 0.48 0.189 0.43 0.343 0.59 0.476 0.69
1970 0.017 0.32 0.069 0.47 0.179 0.61 0.199 0.45 0.485 0.70 0.652 0.81
1980 0.042 0.40 0.157 0.59 0.486 0.81 0.270 0.52 0.643 0.80 0.933 0.97
1990 0.090 0.50 0.470 0.81 1.777 1.18 0.357 0.60 1.064 1.03 1.673 1.29

Note: The first panel gives the ratio of the employment of skilled relative to unskilled workers, and the wage bill of
skilled to unskilled workers for the corresponding skill categories. These data are taken from Autor, Katz, and
Krueger (1998). Some college refers to those with more than high school (hence the measure is those with more
than high school divided by those with high school or less). College graduate refers to all those with a college
degree, and college equivalent is defined, as in Autor et al., as those with a college degree + 0.5 × those with some
college (correspondingly, the unskilled are defined as those with high school and less + 0.5 × those with some
college). The bottom panel gives the implied technology shifts using equation (9) above for different values of the
σ−1
elasticity of substitution. The demand index D is defined as (A h ⁄ A l) σ .

employed in all sectors—and the sec- complementarity during the 1910s and
toral composition should adjust in order 1920s. In light of this evidence, one
to clear the market. The evidence is very might consider the bulk of the twenti-
much the opposite. Berman, Bound, eth century to have been characterized
and Griliches (1994) and Murphy and by skill-biased technical change, though
Welch (1993) show a steady increase in whether technical change during the
the share of college labor in all sectors. early twentieth century was or was not
This discussion leads to my first con- skill-biased is not central for the focus
clusion, which I highlight for future of this paper.
reference.
4. Steady-Demand and Acceleration
Conclusion 1. The past sixty years must Hypotheses
have been characterized by skill-biased
technical change. The previous section highlighted the
importance of skill-biased technical
Furthermore, Goldin and Katz (1998) change over the past several decades. A
provide evidence of technology-skill first hypothesis is that skill-biased
24 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

technical change takes place steadily— to equation (11), “technological devel-


at a constant pace—over time. Alfred Mar- opments” take place at a constant rate,
shall begins The Principles of Econom- but the supply of skilled workers could
ics by reiterating the eighteenth-century grow at different rates. Therefore,
taxonomist Carl Linneaus’ motto that changes in the returns to skills are
“Nature does not make leaps.” It is also caused by uneven growth in the sup-
natural in this context to begin with a ply of skills. When H/L grows faster
hypothesis in which skill-biased techni- than the rate of skill-biased technical
cal change does not make jumps, but change, (σ − 1)γ1, the skill premium will
progresses steadily. The alternative fall. And when the supply growth falls
would be a process that is at times more short of this rate, the skill premium will
skill-biased than others—or even unskill- increase. The story has obvious appeal
biased during some episodes. In this because the 1970s, when returns to
section, I contrast the steady-demand schooling fell sharply, were a period of
hypothesis, which maintains that skill- faster than usual increase in the supply
biased technical change has progressed of college graduate workers as figure 1
at a constant pace over the post-war pe- and table 1 show. In contrast, the 1980s
riod, against the acceleration hypothe- were a period of slow increase in the
sis, which sees a break with past trends supply of skills relative to the 1970s.
in recent decades. Katz and Murphy (1992) estimate a ver-
sion of equation (11) above using ag-
4.1 Steady-Demand Hypothesis gregate data between 1963–87.15 They
find
According to this hypothesis, there
has been no major change in the struc- H
ln ω = 0.033 ⋅ t −0.71 ⋅ ln  L 
ture of demand for skills. Versions of  
(0.01) (0.15)
this story have been suggested by Free-
man (1976), and it has been proposed This approach does fairly well in captur-
as an explanation for the changes in the ing the broad features of the changes in
wage structure during the 1970s and the college premium between 1963 and
the 1980s by Katz and Murphy (1992), 1987. The predicted values from the
and more recently by Murphy, Riddell, above equation are quite close to the ob-
and Romer (1998) and Card and served movements in the college pre-
Lemieux (2000). mium, suggesting that the U.S. labor
In a simple form, this hypothesis can market since 1963 can be characterized
be captured by writing by an elasticity of substitution between
college graduate workers and noncollege
 Ah(t) 
ln   = γ0 + γ1t, (10) workers of about σ = 1 ⁄ 0.71 ≈ 1.4, and an
 Al(t)  annual increase in the demand for skills
where t is calendar time. Substituting at the rate of about 3.3 percent (or
this equation into (5), we obtain γ1 ≈ σ σ− 1 ⋅ 0.033 ≈ 0.115). The increase
in the college premium during the 1980s
σ−1 σ−1 1 H is then explained by the slowdown in the
ln ω = γ0 + γ1t − ln   . (11)
σ σ σ L 15 They use the relative supply of college
equivalent workers. This is defined as college
It is useful to link this equation to the graduates + 0.29 × some college – 0.05 × high
school dropouts divided by high school gradu-
two forces discussed above, and empha- ates + 0.69 × some college + 0.93 × high school
sized by Tinbergen (1975). According dropouts.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 25

growth rate of the supply of college biased technical change. It is hard to


graduate workers. know whether the computer wage pre-
Nevertheless, there are a number of mium is for computer skills, or whether
reasons for preferring a cautious inter- it is even related to the widespread
pretation of this regression evidence. use of computers in the labor market.
The regression uses only 25 aggregate For example, DiNardo and Jorn-Steffen
observations, and there is significant se- Pischke (1997), Horst Enthorf and
rial correlation in the college premium Francis Kramartz (1998) and Lex Bor-
(as also noted by Katz and Murphy). If ghans and Bas Ter Weel (2000) show
the true data were generated by an ac- that the computer wage premium is
celeration in skill bias and a larger likely to be a premium for unobserved
value of the elasticity of substitution, skills. 16
this regression could estimate a smaller The second set of evidence comes
elasticity of substitution and no accel- from the cross-industry studies of,
eration in the demand for skills (see be- among others, Berman, Bound, and
low on this). For example, Katz and Griliches (1994), Autor, Katz and
Murphy show that if the true elasticity Krueger (1998), and Stephen Machin
of substitution is σ = 4, a significant ac- and John Van Reenan (1998). These pa-
celeration in the skill bias of technical pers document that almost all industries
change is required to explain the data. began employing more educated work-
Moreover, from the wage-bill share ers during the 1970s and the 1980s.
data reported above, Autor, Katz, and They also show that more computerized
Krueger (1998) conclude that even for industries experienced more rapid skill
the range of the values for the elasticity upgrading, i.e., they increased their de-
of substitution between σ = 1 and 2, mand for college-educated workers more
skill-biased technical change is likely to rapidly. For example, Autor, Katz, and
have been more rapid during the 1980s Krueger run regressions of changes in
than the 1970s. This can also be seen in the college wage-bill share in three-
table 1 above, where, for most mea- digit industries on computer use
σ−1
sures, the increase in (Ah ⁄ Al) σ appears between 1984 and 1993. They find:
much larger between 1980 and 1990 ∆Sc80 − 90 = .287 + .147 ⋅ ∆cu84 − 93
than in other decades. We therefore (.108) (.046)
need to discuss more detailed evidence
on this issue. ∆Sc90 − 96 = −.171 + .289 ⋅ ∆cu84 − 93
(.196) (.081)
4.2 Evidence on Steady-Demand versus
where ∆Sc denotes the annual change in
Acceleration
the wage-bill share of college graduates
The first piece of evidence often put in that industry (between the indicated
forth in support of an acceleration re- dates), and ∆cu84 − 93 is the increase in
lates to the role of computers in the the fraction of workers using computers
labor market. Krueger (1993) argued in that industry between 1984 and 1993.
that computers changed the structure of These regressions are informative since
wages, and showed that workers using 16 Equally, however, it would be wrong to inter-
computers are paid more, and this com- pret the findings of DiNardo and Pischke (1997)
puter wage premium has increased over and Enthorf and Kramartz (1998) as evidence
time. Although this pattern is striking, against an acceleration in skill-biased technical
change, since, as argued below, such technical
it is not particularly informative about change would increase the market prices for a
the presence or acceleration of skill- variety of skills, including unobserved skills.
26 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

the college wage-bill share is related to the demand for skills, since industries
the demand for skills as shown by equa- that are highly computerized may de-
tion (9). The results indicate that in an mand more skilled workers for other
industry where computer use increased reasons as well. 18 In fact, when Autor,
by 10 percent, the college wage-bill Katz, and Krueger (1998) run the above
share grew by about 0.15 percent a year regressions for the 1960–70 college
faster between 1980 and 1990, and 0.3 wage-bill shares, they obtain
percent faster a year between 1990 and
1996. ∆Sc60 − 70 = .085 + .071 ⋅ ∆cu84 − 93.
Although this evidence is suggestive, (.058) (.025)
it does not establish that there has been Therefore, industries investing more in
a change in the trend growth of skill- computers during the 1980s were al-
biased technology. As pointed out in ready experiencing more skill upgrading
conclusion 1 above, the only way to during the 1960s, before the spread of
make sense of the post-war trends is to computers (though perhaps slower than
incorporate skill-biased technical change after the 1980s, since the coefficient
over the whole period. Moreover, here is about half of that between 1980
Goldin, and Katz (1998) present evi- and 1990). This suggests that at least
dence suggesting that capital-skill com- part of the increase in the demand for
plementarity may have been as high skills coming from highly computerized
during the 1910s as during the recent industries may not be the direct effect of
period because of increased demand for computers, but reflect a secular long-run
skills coming from the introduction of shift toward more skilled workers. So
electricity in most manufacturing pro- faster skill upgrading by highly comput-
cesses. Similarly, even though there erized industries is not inconsistent with
were few computers in workplaces the steady-demand hypothesis.
before the 1970s, other technological The third, and probably most power-
developments may have increased the ful, piece of evidence in favor of an ac-
demand for skills as rapidly as—or more celeration in skill bias also comes from
rapidly than—computers. Therefore, the Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998). They
question is whether computers and the document that the supply of skills grew
associated information technology ad- faster between 1970 and 1995 than be-
vances increased the demand for skills tween 1940 and 1970—by 3.06 percent
more than other technologies did dur- a year during the latter period com-
ing the 1950s and the 1960s, or even pared to 2.36 percent a year during the
earlier. This question cannot be an- earlier thirty years. In contrast, the col-
swered by documenting that computer- lege premium increased between 1970
ized industries demand more skilled and 1995 by about 0.39 percent a year,
workers. 17 while it fell by about 0.11 percent a
Cross-industry studies also may not year during the earlier period. If de-
reveal the true impact of computers on mand for skills had increased at a steady
pace, the college premium should have
17 This argument is related to a point first raised
by Lawrence Mishel and Jared Bernstein (1994). 18 Mark Doms, Timothy Dunne, and Kenneth
They pointed out that much of the evidence pre- Troske (1997) show that new technologies (but
sented in favor of the impact of technology on in- not computers) are adopted by plants that have
equality shows that there has been skill-biased more skilled and more highly paid workers, and
technical change during the 1980s, not that skill- these plants do not increase their wages or de-
biased technical change has accelerated relative to mand for skills after the implementation of these
earlier periods. technologies.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 27

also fallen since 1970. 19 Moreover, more flexible time trends show an accel-
Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) docu- eration in the relative demand for skills
ment greater within-industry skill up- during the 1970s or the 1980s (the cubic
grading in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s and quartic time trends are almost iden-
than in the 1960s, which is also con- tical, hence practically indistinguishable
sistent with more rapid skill-biased in the figure).
technical change during these later A fourth piece of evidence comes
decades. from Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997)
A simple regression analysis also con- and Per Krusell et al. (2000). These
firms this point. I combined the data authors argue, based on the work of
from the March CPSs and decennial Griliches (1969), that equipment capital
censuses used in figure 1 above. Using is more complementary to skilled work-
these data, a regression similar to that ers than unskilled workers. This prem-
of Katz and Murphy for the period ise may be reasonable since advances in
1939–96 yields similar results: equipment often appear to substitute
H
machines for tasks previously per-
ln ω = 0.025 ⋅ t − 0.56 ⋅ ln L  , formed by unskilled workers. Following
 
(0.01) (0.20) the work by Robert Gordon (1990) and
Greenwood, Zvi Hercowitz, and Krusell
with an R 2 of 0.63 and an implied elastic-
(1997), these papers document that the
ity of substitution of 1.8, which is some-
post-war period has witnessed a secular
what larger than the estimate of Katz
decline in the relative price of equip-
and Murphy. However, adding higher
ment capital, and argue that the associ-
order terms in time (i.e., time squared,
ated increase in the stock of equipment
time cubed, etc.) improves the fit of the
capital led to skill-biased technical
model considerably, and these higher-
change. Moreover, they argue that this
order terms are significant. In figure 5, I
relative decline accelerated in the early
plot the implied time trends from regres-
1970s, and the associated acceleration
sions with higher-order terms as well as the
in the stock of equipment capital
linear trend (all numbers were rescaled
increased the demand for skills.
to fit in one graph). All three of these
Krusell et al. (2000) formalize their
19 The college premium fell between 1940 and approach by assuming the following
1970 in part because it is estimated to be very high production function:
in the 1940 census. There may be reasons to be
suspicious of data quality from this census, be- Y = Kαs [b1Lµ + (1 − b1)(b2Kλe
cause (i) the education variable was different, (ii)
there may have been an overstatement of years of + (1 − b2)H λ)µ ⁄ λ](1 − α) ⁄ µ
schooling, possibly by as much as a factor of 1.5 or where Ks is structures capital (such as
2 for some cohorts, and (iii) there was no self-
employment income in this census. But it is not buildings), and Ke is equipment capital
clear whether any of these measurement problems (such as machines). The parameter
will cause an upward bias in the college premium. σ1 = 1 ⁄ (1 − λ) is the elasticity of substitu-
In any case, the level of the college premium from
this census is not out of line with other historical tion between equipment and skilled
evidence (see, e.g., Goldin and Katz 2000; and workers, and σ2 = 1 ⁄ (1 − µ) is the elastic-
Piketty and Saez 2001). Moreover Autor, Katz, and ity of substitution between unskilled
Krueger show that even ignoring data from the
1940 census, there is evidence for an acceleration workers and the equipment-skilled
in the skill bias of technical change. For example, worker aggregate. If σ1 > σ2 (i.e., µ > λ),
for the range of the values for the elasticity of sub- equipment capital is more complemen-
stitution between σ = 1 and 2, skill-biased techni-
cal change appears more rapid during the 1980s tary to skilled workers than unskilled
than in the 1970s and the 1960s. workers, and an increase in Ke will
28 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

linear time trend quadratic time trend


cubic time trend quartic time trend

39 49 59 69 79 89 96
year
Alternative Time Trends for the Relative Demand for Skills
Figure 5. Estimates of Time Trends from Regressions of ln ω on ln (H/L), year, year 2, year 3 and year 4
between 1939 and 1996 (with observations in 1939, 1949, 1959 from the decennial censuses and
observations for 1963–96 from the March CPSs)

increase the wages of skilled workers equipment goods, there will be an asso-
more than the wages of unskilled work- ciated increase in the quantity of equip-
ers. More formally, the skill premium in ment capital, Ke, increasing the demand
this model is for skills steadily.
Figure 6, which plots the log of this
wH
ω= (12) relative price series, shows the faster
wL
proportional decline after the 1970s.
(1 − b2 )(1 − b1 )H λ − 1 (b2 K λe + (1 − b2 )Hλ)(µ − λ) ⁄ λ
= . The behavior of the relative price series
b1L µ − 1
then suggests that there may have been
Differentiation of (12) shows that as an acceleration in the substitution of
long as µ > λ, which corresponds to equipment capital for labor, causing
equipment capital being more comple- more rapid skill-biased technical change.
mentary to skilled workers than un- Nevertheless, because there are seri-
skilled workers, we have ∂ω ⁄ ∂Ke > 0. So ous difficulties in adjusting capital
provided that equipment capital is more prices for quality, we may want to be
complementary to skilled workers than cautious in interpreting this evidence.
unskilled workers, an increase in the Another problem comes from the fact
quantity of equipment capital will in- that, as I discuss in more detail below, a
crease the demand for skills. Since the variety of other evidence does not sup-
post-war period has been characterized port the notion of faster technological
by a decline in the relative price of progress since 1974, which is a basic
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 29

Log rel. price of equip. capital Pre-1974 trend


Post-1974 trend

–.1
Log relative price of equipment capital

–.4

–.7

–1

–1.3

1963 1968 1973 1978 1983 1988 1992


year
Figure 6. Behavior of the Log Relative Price of Equipment Capital, 1963–92

tenet of this approach. Finally, one column 1. The remainder of the table
would presume that if, in fact, the de- shows that once these terms are entered
cline in the relative price of equipment simultaneously with the time trend, the
capital is related to the increase in the time trend is significant, while there is
demand for skills, then in a regression no evidence that the relative price of
of equation (11), it should proxy for the equipment capital matters for the de-
demand for skills and perform better mand for skills. While this evidence
than a linear time trend. Table 2 re- may simply reflect the fact that the rela-
ports a series of regressions which show tive price of equipment is measured
that, on the contrary, the level or the with error, it casts some doubt on the
log of the relative price of equipment view that the relative price of equip-
capital is not significant in such regres- ment capital is directly linked to the
sions. Column 1 shows the equivalent of demand for skills and that its faster
the regression by Katz and Murphy decline since the 1970s indicates an
(1992) with only a time trend and the acceleration in skill bias.
relative supply of skills. Columns 2 and A final piece of evidence for accelera-
3 show regressions that replace the time tion comes from the behavior of overall
trend with the level and log of the rela- and residual inequality over the past
tive price of equipment capital. These several decades. The sharp rise in both
terms are significant, but the fit of the overall and residual wage inequality
regression is worse than the one in since the early 1970s, documented in
30 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

TABLE 2
THE EFFECT OF THE RELATIVE PRICE OF EQUIPMENT ON SKILLED PREMIA

Dependent variable is log college premium


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Relative supply –0.742 –0.388 –0.610 –0.691 –0.740
(0.053) (0.037) (0.068) (0.100) (0.054)
Time 0.026 0.022 0.024
(0.002) (0.007) (0.005)
Log relative price –0.323 –0.051
(0.024) (0.084)
Relative price –0.875 –0.056
(0.086) (0.167)
Adjusted R2 0.900 0.864 0.795 0.898 0.897

Note: This table reports the regression of the log college premium on a linear time trend,
the log relative supply of skilled workers and various measures of the relative price of
equipment capital. For comparability, all data taken from Krusell et al. (2000).

section 2, weighs in favor of a marked Pierce view, instead, suggests that the
change in labor market prices and de- increase in residual inequality and the
mand for skills during recent decades. bulk of the rise in overall inequality
This argument is based on the view that are related to changes in labor market
changes in residual inequality reflect prices, and therefore to the supply and
changes in labor market prices, a thesis demand for skills. Second, according to
put forth by Chinhui Juhn, Murphy, this view, the rise in residual inequality
and Brooks Pierce (1993). 20 This view is is an important piece of evidence in the
important for an interpretation for the debate on acceleration: residual in-
recent changes in wage structure for equality, which was stable during the
two reasons. First, as the evidence in 1960s, began to increase rapidly during
section 2 indicates, much of the recent the early 1970s (figures 2 and 3), indi-
increase in overall inequality is due to cating a discontinuity in labor market
the rise in residual inequality. If resid- prices and, most likely, in the rate of
ual inequality were unrelated to the de- increase of the demand for skills.
mand and supply of skills, the frame- A concrete example is useful for clari-
work here could only account for a fying why residual inequality is linked
relatively small fraction of the increase to labor market prices. Suppose that
in overall inequality. The Juhn-Murphy- two otherwise identical individuals dif-
20 Of course, an alternative—and more cynical—
fer in terms of their unobserved skills
view would be to interpret residual inequality as (for example, in terms of interpersonal
“a measure of our ignorance” (as Moses Abramo- skills, motivation, specific skills for their
vitz 1957 did for TFP). When a standard wage job, or IQ). 21 Denote the unobserved
regression such as (1) provides a good fit, the
residuals will be less disperse. Nevertheless, given
the variety of skills that we are unable to measure 21 By unobserved skills, I mean skills that are
in standard data sets, much of the residual will not observed by the econometrician. These skills
plausibly reflect rewards to some unobserved could be—and are likely to be—observed by em-
skills. ployers. These types of skills are often referred to
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 31

skill of individual 1 by a1 and that of behavior of overall and residual in-


individual 2 by a2 > a1, and assume that equality since the 1970s suggest a
wages are given by marked shift in the demand for skills
ln w it = 2θtai + γthi, (13) over the past several decades. I therefore
where γt is the price of h skills at time t, tentatively conclude: 23
while θt is the price of a skills. Since
these individuals are identical in all re- Conclusion 2. The behavior of returns
spects other than their unobserved skills, to schooling and residual inequality
a, we have the variance of log wages over the past three decades suggests an
(or of residual wages) among these two acceleration in the demand for skills
individuals as: beginning in the 1970s or 1980s.
Var(ln w) = θ2t (a2 − a1)2. 5. Acceleration in Skill Bias
Now if at a later date, t′, this variance
increases to Var(ln w)′, and we know that What explains the more rapid in-
these two individuals are still identical crease in the demand for skills over
in all other respects and that a2 − a1 has the past several decades? The first pos-
not changed, we can interpret the in- sibility is a change in labor market insti-
crease in Var(ln w) as reflecting an in- tutions. The second is the role of in-
crease in the price of unobserved skills, creased international trade. The third is
θt. The discussion in the appendix
more rapid skill-biased technical change.
shows that the bulk of the increase in I argue in section 6 that changes in
overall and residual inequality cannot labor market institutions and the in-
be explained by composition effects, creased importance of international
i.e., by changes in a2 − a1, so this in- trade cannot explain the change in labor
crease is most likely due to a rise in the market prices by themselves. Moreover,
price of and demand for unobserved the evidence discussed in section 4 is
skills during the 1970s. 22 Therefore, consistent with new technologies play-
with this interpretation, the rapid rise ing an important role in changing the
in the residual inequality during the wage structure. So here I begin with
1970s and the 1980s indicates a more changes in technologies, and in particu-
rapid increase in demand for skills lar, I discuss “pure technological” ap-
during these decades than earlier. proaches where technology is the only
Overall, there is a variety of evidence factor determining the demand for
suggesting an acceleration in skill bias skills.
over the past 25–30 years. Although not 5.1 “Technological Revolutions” and
all evidence is equally convincing, the Acceleration in Skill Bias
rise in the returns to schooling over the
past thirty years, despite the very rapid The first group of technological theo-
increase in the supply of skills, and the ries links the acceleration in skill bias to
exogenous technological developments,
and argues that a “technological revolu-
as “unobserved ability.” This does not imply that
these unobserved skills are necessarily synony- tion” led to more rapid skill-biased
mous with IQ or other single dimensional skill technical change beginning in the 1970s
indices.
22 Put differently, the absence of large composi- 23 The most important caveat is that the avail-
tion effects indicates that the rise in residual in- able data suggest relatively slow skill-biased tech-
equality likely reflects changes in the demand nical change during the second half of the 1990s
for unobserved skills rather than changes in the (see Mishel, Bernstein, and John Schmitt 1998;
“supply of unobserved skills.” and Murphy and Welch 2000).
32 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

or the 1980s. In terms of the model de- acceleration is that new technologies
veloped above, this corresponds to a are more complementary to skilled
more rapid increase in Ah ⁄ Al during this workers than to unskilled workers—for
period, translating into greater skill pre- example, there are more rapid advances
mia. Many of the proponents of this in the technologies used by skilled
view argue that the acceleration in skill workers, as captured by Ah above. Rapid
bias is, at least in part, related to infor- technological progress then corre-
mation technology and computers (for sponds to an acceleration in skill bias.
example, Krueger 1993; Berman, Bound, An alternative perspective, building on
and Griliches 1994; Autor, Katz, and an idea originally suggested by Nelson
Krueger 1998; Berman, Bound, and and Phelps (1966), also focuses on the
Machin 1998). effect of rapid technical change on in-
An interesting version of this story is equality, but puts the emphasis on the
the one developed by Krusell et al. ability of skilled workers to deal with
(2000) discussed above. They argue that the introduction of new technologies.
the demand for skills accelerated as a According to this view, demand for
result of the more rapid decline in skills will automatically increase during
the relative price of capital equipment periods of rapid technological change.
beginning in the early 1970s. 24 The Welch (1970) gave an early succinct
Krusell et al. theory is attractive since it summary of these two views. The first
provides a unified framework in which view, which we may call the accelera-
we can identify both the cause of the tion hypothesis, sees human capital as a
steady increase in the demand for skills, factor of production, and the more rapid
and the source of the more rapid skill- increase in the demand for skills results
biased technical change, though the evi- from an acceleration in technical change
dence provided in the previous section that favors this factor of production. In
casts some doubt on the link between other words:
the relative price of equipment and the
demand for skills. [T]echnical change may not be neutral
The main idea of all these theories of between skill classes. It may be that incre-
ments in technology result in increments in
the relative productivity of labor that are
24 I classify this approach as one of exogenous positively related to skill level. (Welch 1970,
technology, since the driving force, the decline in p. 38)
the relative price of equipment capital, is assumed
exogenous.
An alternative interpretation of the approach by In contrast, the second view—the
Krusell et al. (2000) is that the main determinant Nelson-Phelps hypothesis—argues that25
of the demand for skills is not technology-skill
complementarity, but capital-skill complementarity. 25 A recent paper by Samuel Bowles, Herbert
I believe that the distinction between technology- Gintis, and Melissa Osborne (2001) has a similar
skill versus capital-skill is not very useful. Capital- classification of different approaches. They call
skill complementarity could play an important role the first view Walrasian, and the second Schumpe-
only in a model as in Greenwood et al. (1997) or terian. In the first, skills that enable workers to
Krusell et al. (2000), where new capital embeds produce more are valued, while in the second, it is
superior technologies. In this sense, it is a combi- skills that enable workers to deal with changes in
nation of new capital and new technologies that is economic and social environments. They also pro-
increasing the demand for skills. Moreover, Autor, pose an alternative, Coasian, view, where “skills”
Katz, and Krueger (1998) show that demand for are workers’ capacity to work within organizations
more educated workers across industries is af- and follow authority. From the point of view of
fected by high-tech capital (e.g., computers), but the analysis here, this view is not fundamentally
not by equipment capital, suggesting further that different from the Walrasian view, since workers
it is new technologies, not simply capital intensity, are paid more for skills that increase their marginal
that matters for inequality. contribution to the profits of their employers.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 33
[T]he productivity of education would be approaches, it is useful to consider a
positively related to the rate of change in use- simple model based on Galor and Moav
ful technology (the ability to change) and to
the size of the technological gap (room for (2000). Suppose that
innovation). In this case, if the rate of utiliza-
tion of technology is accelerating, or if the Al = φl(g)a and Ah = φha (14)
technology gap is growing, the return to
education will rise relative to other inputs. where a is a measure of aggregate tech-
(p. 38) nology, and g is the growth rate of a, i.e.,
g ≡ a⋅ ⁄ a. The presumption that skilled
Studies building on the Nelson- workers are better equipped to deal with
Phelps hypothesis include Galor and technological progress can be captured
Tsiddon (1997), Greenwood and Yoru- by assuming that φ′l < 0. Galor and Moav
koglu (1997), Caselli (1999), Aghion (2000) refer to this assumption as the
and Howitt (1998, ch. 9), Galor and “erosion effect,” since it implies that
Moav (2000), Violante (2000), Rubin- technical change erodes some of the es-
stein and Tsiddon (1999), Aghion, tablished expertise of unskilled workers,
Howitt and Violante (2000), and Gould, and causes them to benefit less from
Moav and Weinberg (2000). 26 These pa- technological advances than skilled work-
pers argue that there has been a tech- ers do. Substituting from (14) into (4),
nological revolution in the U.S. econ- the skill premium is
omy starting in the 1970s and relate the (σ − 1) ⁄ σ −1 ⁄ σ
rise in inequality to the increased wH  Ah  H
ω= =
demand for skills resulting from the w L  Al  L
 
technological revolution. For example, (σ − 1) ⁄ σ −1 ⁄ σ (15)
Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997) draw  φh  H
=  L .
a parallel between the First and the
 φl(g)   
Second Industrial Revolutions and what
has been happening in the U.S. econ-
Therefore, as long as φ′l < 0, more rapid
omy since 1974. Caselli (1999) develops
technological progress, as captured by a
a similar theory where a technological
higher level of g, will increase the skill
revolution increases the demand for
premium.
workers who can switch to the sectors
Theories that explain the increase in
that benefit from the introduction of
inequality as a result of rapid tech-
new technologies. 27
nological progress have a number of
To get a basic understanding of these
attractive features. 28 First, many econo-
26 See Aghion (2001) for an approach that com- mists and commentators view the ad-
bines the Nelson-Phelps insights with the Schum- vances in computer and information
peterian notion of creative-destruction to discuss
the impact of the diffusion of computers on technology as a break with the tech-
inequality. nologies of the past, and so are open to
27 The explanation offered by Rubinstein and
Tsiddon (1999), and Aghion, Howitt, and Violante 28 These theories also predict that inequality
(2000) is somewhat different. They argue that should increase when new technologies are being
there is increased uncertainty at times of rapid introduced, but should decline when these new
technological change, and more skilled workers technologies are standardized and being used rou-
are better able to cope with uncertainty. This idea tinely by many firms (see, for example, Galor and
is also related to a thesis first put forth by Michael Tsiddon 1997, or Aghion, Howitt, and Violante
Piore and Charles Sabel (1984) that the oil price 2000). So far, there seems to be no evidence of a
shocks increased the uncertainty faced by produc- decline in inequality in the United States, but per-
ers, and induced them to change the organization haps the years to come will see a return to the
of production toward organizational forms that levels of inequality experienced during the 1960s,
require adaptable workers. vindicating this approach.
34 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

the idea that we might be in the midst It is difficult to imagine how a new
of a technological revolution. Second, a and radically more profitable technol-
variety of evidence supports the notion ogy will first lead to 25 years of substan-
that skilled workers have a comparative tially slower growth. Although, in an
advantage in coping with rapid tech- influential paper, Paul David (1990)
nical change. Ann Bartel and Frank argues that the spread of electricity to
Lichtenberg (1987) show that firms in- American manufacturing was also slow
troducing new technologies hire more and productivity gains from electrifica-
skilled workers. Bartel and Nachum tion were limited until the 1920s, the
Sicherman (1998) document that re- parallel with the recent productivity
turns to unobserved ability appear to be slowdown should not be overstated.
higher in industries with more rapid First, though productivity growth from
technical change. Andrew Foster and electrification was sluggish during the
Mark Rosenzweig (1996) provide evi- early 1900s, the U.S. economy overall
dence from developing countries that had a much higher level of output
more educated workers are better growth than the growth levels experi-
placed to take advantage of advances in enced over the past three decades. Data
agricultural technology. from table A-XVIII of John Kendrick
The main difficulty with both the (1961) imply that output growth be-
theories based on the acceleration and tween 1899 and 1909 in the U.S. econ-
the Nelson-Phelps hypotheses is that omy was 4.2 percent a year, while be-
they rely explicitly on rapid technical tween 1909 and 1919, it was 3 percent,
change in recent decades. 29 There is and between 1920 and 1929, output
little direct evidence that the decades grew by 3.6 percent a year. Second, as
between 1970 and 1995 have been a pe- noted by Stephen Oliner and Daniel
riod of rapid technical change, how- Sichel (1994), computers and other ad-
ever. First, this period has experienced vanced office equipment have only been
sluggish TFP and output growth rela- a trivial part of the aggregate capital
tive to earlier periods. Greenwood and stock of the U.S. economy until the mid-
Yorukoglu (1997) and Hornstein and 1990s. It is therefore unlikely that the
Krusell (1996) argue that the slow TFP whole of the U.S. economy has been
growth itself may be an outcome of the adapting to the changes in this rela-
more rapid technical change. According tively small part of the capital stock. Fi-
to this argument, new revolutionary nally, as shown by Ernie Brendt, Cath-
technologies first reduce productivity erine Morrison, and Larry Rosenblum
growth as firms and workers spend time (1994), more computerized sectors did
learning to use these technologies. not perform any better in terms of labor
productivity growth over this period;
this pattern is also difficult to recon-
29 Another argument that applies only against
cile with a computer-led technological
approaches based on the Nelson-Phelps hypothe-
sis is that historical evidence is not necessarily in revolution.
line with a view that demand for skills always in- It is also useful to note that although
creases during times of rapid technical change. As computers have no doubt increased our
discussed in the introduction, the major techno-
logical changes of the early nineteenth century ap- standards of living and quality of life
pear to have been largely skill-replacing (unskill- over the past thirty years, they may be
biased), even though they seem as radical as much less radical innovations than cer-
computer technology. This suggests that it is
the skill bias of technology, not merely its rapid tain previous new technologies (see
arrival, that is important for the demand for skills. Gordon 1998). To gain perspective,
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 35

consider the difference that the tele- increase in the supply of skills. There is
graph made to a world in which the no a priori reason to expect the accel-
fastest medium of communication was eration in skill bias to coincide with the
pigeons. Mokyr (1990, p. 124) describes rapid increase in the supply of skills.
this as follows: Those who want to subscribe to the
exogenous technological progress view
The telegraph had an enormous impact on
19th-century society—possibly as great as
have to explain this as a chance event. 31
that of the railroad. Its community and politi- 5.2 Endogenous Skill-Biased Technical
cal value was vast, as was its effect in coordi-
nating international financial and commodity
Change
markets. Unlike the railroad, it had no close The theories discussed so far pre-
substitutes, the closest being homing pigeons
and semaphore.
sume technical change to be skill-
biased by nature (or, at the very least,
Or consider the difference that the auto- recent technologies to have increased
mobile and air conditioning made to the the demand for skills due to exogenous
quality of life, and electricity and in- reasons). A different perspective is to link
terchangeable parts made to the manu- the types of technologies that are devel-
facturing sector. As also pointed out by oped and adopted to (profit) incentives,
Gordon (1998), compared to these improve- or to demand pull as emphasized by
ments, the switch from mainframes to Schmookler (1966). 32
PCs, or from telephone to e-mail, or from Historical evidence is consistent with
the typewriter to the word processor may the notion that profit incentives and op-
be modest. 30 portunities are important for the de-
A final problem for all of the ap- velopment and introduction of new
proaches based on exogenous techno- 31 One could argue that the supply of skilled
logical developments is the coincidence workers increased because, during the 1960s,
in the timing of this change, and the workers anticipated that there was going to be a
technological discontinuity in the decades to
rapid increase in the supply of skilled come, and responded to this by increasing their
workers. Recall that there was a very education. This story appears quite unreasonable,
large increase in the supply of college however. There is no evidence that anyone, let
alone teenagers, foresaw the technological devel-
graduate workers during the late 1960s opments of the 1970s and the 1980s as early as the
and the early 1970s (figure 1 and table 1960s. Moreover, the increase in the supply of
1 show the large increase in the em- skills can be largely explained by two factors.
First, the Vietnam era draft laws encouraged
ployment share of college workers be- young males to stay in college longer (and indi-
tween 1970 and 1980). So the accelera- rectly also influenced female enrollments). Sec-
tion in skill bias is either concurrent ond, college enrollments were on an upward trend
since the early 1950s, and much of the increase in
with, or immediately follows, this large the supply of college graduate workers is ac-
counted for by the interaction of this upward
30 Another argument is that our ability to mea- trend with the very large relative size of the baby
sure TFP growth may have deteriorated following boom cohorts.
a change in technological regime. However, as 32 This is also the approach taken by the endog-
Martin Bailey and Gordon (1988) document, pro- enous growth theory, which determines the overall
ductivity slowdown has been concurrent in many rate of technical change—but not the degree of
sectors, some of them with little problems in skill bias—from profit incentives (e.g., Romer
measuring output or output quality. It is interest- 1990; Gene Grossman and Elhanan Helpman
ing to note, however, that evidence in favor of this 1991; Aghion and Howitt 1992). An advantage of
hypothesis may yet emerge, especially since pro- the endogenous-technology perspective in this
ductivity growth has been quite rapid during the context is that it provides clear reasons for the de-
past three years (but see Gordon 1998, and more gree of skill bias to increase even without a change
recently, Dale Jorgensen and Kevin Stiroh 2000, in the overall pace of technological improvement
on this). —see below.
36 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

technologies. Fernand Braudel (1984, cotton gin on the South was nothing
p. 566) took a strong position on this: short of spectacular. In the court case
[T]he efficient application of technology over the patent rights, Judge Johnson
lags, by definition, behind the general move- wrote:
ment of the economy; it has to be called on,
sometimes several times, to meet a precise “[. . . as a result of the cotton gin] . . .
and persistent demand. individuals who were depressed with poverty,
and sunk with idleness, have suddenly risen to
An interesting example of the timing wealth and respectability. Our debts have been
of technological development respond- paid off, our capital increased; and our lands
are treble in value.” (Quoted in Constance
ing to profit incentives is given by the Green 1956, p. 92)
introduction of the electric street car in
U.S. cities during the late nineteenth Within a short time, Eli Whitney’s gin
century. In his history of electricity in turned the United States from a cotton
the United States, David Nye (1990) importer into the largest cotton exporter
describes this as follows: in the world.
Cities grew larger, better transportation Schmookler (1966) provides a famous
was needed, so the [electric] trolley was in- argument for the importance of demand
vented, called into being by the crowded late pull in the development of many tech-
nineteenth century cities . . . . By the 1870s nologies. He documents rapid innova-
large cities had ceased to be accessible by
foot, or built to the scale of pedestrians, and
tions in railroads following increased
traffic congestion was terrible. (p. 85) purchases of railroad equipments, and
more generally argues that industries
This created the profit opportunities to with greater investments experience
develop and introduce the electric trol- faster technological progress because
ley. The technological requirements had the returns to such progress are greater.
been met long before, and awaited these A natural next step is then to argue that
profit opportunities. Nye writes, “How- the degree of skill bias in technical change
ever great the need for the electric trol- is also determined by profit opportuni-
ley after 1870, it was hardly a new idea; ties and by the demand for different
it had been the object of experiment types of technologies. Here, by endoge-
during four decades” (p. 86). nous (skill bias) technology approach I
Another example of the type of inno- mean the view that the degree of skill
vation responding to profit incentives is bias in technical change is influenced
provided by the cotton gin. In the late by profit incentives. 33
eighteenth and early nineteenth centu- A key determinant of profitability is
ries, only green seed cotton, which was market size. As Schmookler (1966)
difficult to clean, could be grown in stated in the title of two of his chapters:
most of the American South, and Brit- “The amount of invention is governed by
ain imported most of its cotton from the the extent of the market.” The most suc-
West Indies, Brazil, and India. A ma- cessful businessmen have always been
chine to remove the seeds was essential aware of this. For example, Matthew
for the success of American cotton. In
33 An alternative explanation for the increase in
contrast to almost all other textile inno-
wage inequality based on endogenous technical
vations that were taking place in Eng- change is offered by Huw Lloyd-Ellis (1999). In
land and Europe, such a machine, the his model, it is the interaction between endoge-
cotton gin, was developed in the United nous technical change and the slowdown in the
growth of labor quality that leads to increased in-
States in 1793 by Eli Whitney in re- equality. Skill bias is not endogenous in Lloyd-
sponse to this need. The impact of the Ellis’ model.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 37

Boulton wrote to his business partner, his pioneering study of the supply-
James Watt, “It is not worth my while demand framework, in fact, foresaw this
to manufacture your engine for three possibility, and wrote (1975, p. 61): “. . .
countries only, but I find it very well an inequality-furthering phenomenon is
worth my while to make it for all technological development. But need it
the world” (quoted in Michael Scherer be? Increasingly we get the feeling that
1984, p. 13). Schmookler (1966) simi- technological development is not simply
larly provided many examples where something given, but that it may be
market size was crucial in determining guided, within limits.”
the directions of technical change. The At some level, the idea that there will
horseshoe is perhaps the most interest- be more technologies developed, cre-
ing one. Schmookler documented that ated and adopted for skilled workers—
there was a very high rate of innovation “within limits”—when there are more
throughout the late nineteenth and early skilled workers to use them is quite ap-
twentieth centuries in this very ancient pealing. An extreme form of this view is
technology, invented in the second cen- captured by my model in Acemoglu
tury B.C., and no tendency for inven- (1998), where forward-looking profit-
tors to run out of additional improve- maximizing firms create new technolo-
ments. On the contrary, inventions and gies anticipating the profitability of
patents increased because demand for these different investments. According
horseshoes was high. Innovations came to this view, it would be the Vietnam
to an end only when “the steam traction War draft laws and the high college en-
engine and, later, internal combustion rollment rates of the baby boom cohorts
engine began to displace the horse . . .” that induced the development of com-
(p. 93). puters. Such an interpretation is not lit-
According to this reasoning, the de- eral. A more plausible interpretation may
velopment of skill-biased technologies be that new technological platforms—
will be more profitable when they have macroinventions to use Joel Mokyr’s
a larger market size—i.e., when there term, or General Purpose Technologies
are more skilled workers. Therefore, to use Bresnahan and Trajtenberg’s term—
the equilibrium degree of skill bias stem from advances in basic science or
could be an increasing function of the from labs with little profit-maximizing
relative supply of skilled workers. An incentive. The development of the mi-
increase in the supply of skills will then crochip would be such a macroinven-
lead to skill-biased technical change. tion. But what matters for most workers
Furthermore, an acceleration in the in the labor force is how this new tech-
supply of skills can lead to an accelera- nological platform is developed, i.e.,
tion in the demand for skills. It is useful the microinventions that follow the
to link this approach to technological macroinvention. At the expense of over-
development with the above framework. simplifying, we can say that the micro-
While the above supply-demand frame- chip could have been used to develop
work explains the prices of skills by sup- advanced scanners to increase the pro-
ply and technology, the perspective of ductivity of unskilled workers, or ad-
endogenous skill bias relates technology vanced computer-assisted machines to
to the supply of skills. 34 Tinbergen, in be used by skilled workers to replace
unskilled workers. The theory of endog-
34 Naturally, it is also possible to link the supply enous skill bias requires that the extent of
of skills to skill premia. See below for a discussion. the advances in these two technologies
38 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

is affected by profit opportunities. When profit-maximizing monopolists. Creat-


there are more college graduates, com- ing a new machine costs B units of the
puters become relatively more profit- final good Y, and the marginal cost of
able to develop than scanners, and this producing these machines, once cre-
explains the acceleration in skill bias. 35 ated, is zero. The marginal willingness
The endogenous response of firms to to pay for an additional machine in the
the increase in supply will raise the de- two sectors is given by the derivatives
mand for skills. In fact, supply may not of phYh and plYl with respect to N h and
simply create its own demand, but the N l, i.e.,
response of firms could be so pro- phH and plL. (17)
nounced that demand could overshoot I assume that the creator of each new
the supply. In this theory, therefore, machine obtains this “market” marginal
the increased supply may be the cause willingness to pay (see Acemoglu 1998,
of the increase in the skill premium for a more rigorous and detailed discus-
(see Acemoglu 1998, and also Michael sion). Equation (17) therefore highlights
Kiley 1999). Here I outline a simplified two effects that encourage the creation
version of this theory based on the above of new technologies.
framework.
Suppose that consumers have a utility 1. The price effect: technologies produc-
function defined over Y = [Yρl + Yρh]1 ⁄ ρ, ing more expensive goods will be im-
and that Yh = N hH and Yl = N lL where N h proved faster. Since goods using the
and N l can be interpreted as the num- scarce factor will command a higher
ber of specialized machines used with price (see equation 16), this effect
skilled and unskilled workers, respec- implies that there will be more inno-
tively. This is equivalent to the above vation directed at the scarce factor—
setup with Ah = N h and Al = N l. An in- i.e., directed at unskilled workers
crease in N h relative to N l will corre- during the 1970s and the 1980s.
spond to skill-biased technical change 2. The market size effect: a larger clien-
as long as σ = 1 ⁄ (1 − ρ) > 1. From con- tele for a technology leads to more
sumer maximization, the relative price innovation. Since the clientele for a
of skill-intensive goods is technology is the number of workers
ρ−1 who use it, the market size effect en-
ph  N hH  courages innovation for the more
p≡ = , (16)
pl  N lL  abundant factor, and encourages
where once again ph denotes the price of more technologies for skilled and
good Yh and pl is the price of Yl . highly educated workers during the
Suppose now that these specialized 1970s and the 1980s.
machines are created and sold by The creation of new machines will
35 There is some evidence that the composition
stop when the marginal increase in
of R&D shifted toward more skill-biased tech- profits is equal to the marginal cost of
nologies during the period of the rapid increase in innovation in both sectors. This implies
the supply of college-educated workers. From the
R&D expenditure data reported by the NSF, in
that in equilibrium
1960 company funded R&D for office computing phH
was 3 percent of the total company funded R&D = 1, (18)
expenditure. This ratio had increased to 13 percent
p lL
by 1987, suggesting that during this period of i.e., the price and market size effects
rapid increase in the supply of skills, there was
significantly more R&D directed to one of the
have to be balanced in equilibrium. How
technologies most complementary to skills. can equation (18) be satisfied? Since H/L
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 39

is fixed, equation (18) can only hold if There are a number of implications
the relative price of skill-intensive goods, that follow from this approach. First, as
p = ph ⁄ pl, adjusts. From equation (16), this the relative supply of skilled workers
can only happen if N h ⁄ N l changes. There- has been growing throughout the past
fore, in this economy, the skill bias of tech- sixty years, we expect technology to en-
nology has to adjust in order to “clear the dogenously respond by becoming more
technology market.” Combining (16) and skill-biased over time. If the elasticity
(18), we obtain equilibrium skill bias as of substitution between skilled and un-
ρ ⁄ (1 − ρ) skilled workers is greater than 2, i.e.,
Nh Ah  H 
= = . (19) ρ > 1 ⁄ 2, the increase in the demand for
N l Al  L  skilled workers would be more than
This equation shows that when ρ > 0, i.e., enough to offset the increase in the
when skilled and unskilled good are gross supply of skilled workers, and the econ-
substitutes, the market size effect will omy would be moving steadily along an
dominate the price effect, and a greater upward-sloping relative demand curve
relative supply of skilled workers will lead for skills. This would explain why re-
to more skill-biased technologies—higher turns to college have been increasing
N h ⁄ N l. over the past half century.
Finally, by substituting from equation A new theory for the acceleration in
(19), the skill premium in this economy skill bias also emerges from this simple
is model. According to this theory, the
(2ρ − 1) ⁄ (1 − ρ) σ−2 rapid increase in the supply of college
phN h  H  H educated workers during the 1970s cre-
ω= =  = 
p lN l  L  L ated a more pronounced shift toward
where the final expression is obtained by skill-biased technologies, further in-
combining (16) and (19). creased the demand for skill, and raised
The most important result is that if the college premium. This story be-
ρ > 1 ⁄ 2, i.e., if the elasticity of substitu- comes more interesting once we recog-
tion σ is greater than 2, the skill pre- nize that the equilibrium skill bias of
mium will be an increasing function of technologies, N h ⁄ N l, is a sluggish vari-
the relative supply of skills. 36 This is be- able determined by the slow buildup
cause an increase in H/L encourages so and development of new technologies.
much skill-biased technical change that In this case, a rapid increase in the sup-
the demand for skills increases more than ply of skills first reduces the skill pre-
enough to offset the increase in the mium as the economy moves along a
supply of skills. As a result, the (long- constant technology (constant N h ⁄ N l)
run) relative demand for skills is an up- curve as drawn in figure 7. After a while
ward-sloping curve as drawn in figure 7, the technology starts adjusting, and the
and an increase in the supply of skilled economy moves back to the upward-
workers increases the skill premium. sloping relative demand curve, with a
very sharp increase in the college pre-
36 The result that the elasticity of substitution mium. This theory therefore gives an
needs to be greater than 2 for the long-run rela- interpretation for both the decline in
tive demand to slope upwards is a feature of the
simple model here, and does not generalize to the college premium during the 1970s
richer environments. In any case, there are a num- and its subsequent surge, and relates
ber of estimates above 2, and a somewhat upward both to the large increase in the supply
sloping relative demand curve for skills, even with
this model’s parameterization, is an empirical of skilled workers.
possibility. For the key insights of this theory,
40 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Relative Wage

Long-run Relative
Demand for Skills
Long-run Rel. Wage

Initial Rel. Wage

Short-run Response

Exogenous Shift in Relative Supply


Figure 7. The Dynamics of the Relative Wage of Skilled Workers in Response to an Increase in the Supply of
Skills with Endogenous Skill-Biased Technical Change

that increases in the relative supply of Additional exogenous skill-biased tech-


skills induce skill-biased technical nical change is then necessary for the
change, we do not need the long-run skill premium to increase above its
relative demand curve to be upward- initial level.
sloping. When ρ < 1 ⁄ 2, increases in the There are also other historical epi-
supply of skills still induce skill-biased sodes in which a large increase in the
change, but this technical change is not supply of skills appears to have affected
enough to prevent the skill premium the direction of technical change. High
from falling. Further “exogenous” skill- school enrollment and graduation rates
biased technical change is also neces- doubled in the 1910s. Goldin and Katz
sary to explain why returns to schooling (1995) argue that increased enrollments
have risen over the past sixty years. were mostly driven by supply side fac-
With a downward-sloping long-run de- tors; changes in the location and curric-
mand curve, the story for the 1970s and ula of schools and improvements in
the 1980s is also different. The large in- transportation technology. The skill
crease in the supply of skills again premium fell sharply in the 1910s. But,
moves the economy along a steeply despite the even faster increase in the
downward-sloping constant technology supply of high school skills during the
demand curve. The response of technol- 1920s, the skill premium levelled off
ogy then moves the economy to a less and started a mild increase. Goldin and
steep long-run demand curve as drawn Katz (1995) conclude that the demand
in figure 8, raising the skill premium. for high school graduates must have
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 41

Relative Wage

Initial Rel. Wage

Long-run Rel. Wage

Long-run Relative
Demand for Skills

Short-run Response

Exogenous Shift in Relative Supply


Figure 8. The Dynamics of the Relative Wage of Skilled Workers in Response to an Increase in the Supply of
Skills with Limited Endogenous Skill-Biased Technical Change

expanded sharply starting in the 1920s, creased the Israeli population by 12


presumably due to changes in office percent in the first half of the 1990s. A
technology and higher demand from theory with exogenous technology
new industries, such as electrical ma- would predict a large decline in the
chinery, transport and chemicals (see relative wages of educated workers,
also Goldin and Katz 1998). 37 very much as in the case of Palestinian
Another interesting case study comes labor discussed above. 38 In practice, the
from the response of the Israeli labor education premium did not fall (e.g.,
market to the influx of large numbers of Rachel Friedberg 1997). This seems to
highly educated immigrants from the be mainly because most industries in-
former Soviet Union. The size of this creased their employment of more
influx was enormous: migration in- skilled workers during this large influx
(Neil Gandal, Gordon Hanson, and
37 As Goldin and Katz (2000) show using data
Matthew Slaughter 2000; and Sarit
from Iowa Prairies, returns to education were
most likely higher in 1915 than in 1950. Although
this evidence suggests that the long-run relative 38 The key difference between the two episodes
demand curve for skills was downward sloping is that Palestinian labor is a relatively small frac-
over this period, it is consistent with the notion of tion of the Israeli work force, so we expect much
skill-biased technical change induced by an in- less of a technology response to changes in the
crease in the supply skilled workers. Specifically, educational composition of Palestinian labor. Fur-
during this period, demand for skills expanded thermore, Palestinian college graduates are not a
very rapidly to accommodate the very large in- close substitute for Israeli college graduates, and
crease in the supply of high school graduates (see only a limited range of occupations are open to
Goldin and Katz 1995, 2000). them.
42 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Cohen and Chang-Tai Hsieh 2000). of rural industry came to the cities.
This response suggests a change in Fourth, “there was a large influx of
the production structure toward more labor from Ireland” (p. 137). Finally,
skilled workers, consistent with the “technical changes in agriculture in-
theories outlined in this section. 39 creased the supply of labor available to
Despite this evidence showing simul- industry” (p. 137).
taneous increases in the supply of, and According to the endogenous tech-
demand for, skills in a number of episodes, nology hypothesis, this increase in the
it is difficult to distinguish exogenous supply of unskilled labor should encour-
and endogenous technical change. The age unskill-biased technical change. And
exogenous technical change theory as predicted by this approach, there
maintains that technical change is often were major skill-replacing (unskill-
skill-biased. Endogenous technical change biased) technologies introduced during
theory instead suggests that new tech- this period, most notably the factory
nologies should be skill-biased when system replacing tasks previously per-
the supply of skills increases. Since the formed by skilled artisans. Moreover, in
supply of skills has increased most of his classic study, Habakkuk argues that
the time over the past one hundred or the increase in the supply of labor was
so years, the implications of the two an important inducement to the devel-
theories are quite similar. The increase opment of factory methods. He also
in the supply of unskilled labor in the quotes an American historian, Handlin,
English cities during the early nine- to explain why the adoption of factory
teenth century provides an interesting methods in the United States was
contrasting event for the two ap- somewhat delayed. Handlin wrote:
proaches. Bairoch (1988, p. 245) de-
[N]o matter what degree of standard-
scribes this rapid expansion as follows: ization technical process of manufacturing
“. . . between 1740 and 1840 the popu- reached, the absence of a cheap labor supply
lation of England . . . went up from 6 precluded conversion to factory methods.
million to 15.7 million. . . . while the (p. 146)
agricultural labor force represented 60–
Habakkuk placed much more impor-
70% of the total work force in 1740, by
tance on the role of wages in determin-
1840 it represented only 22%.” Habak-
ing innovation decisions, a view that
kuk (pp. 136–37) also emphasizes the
later became known as the “Habakkuk
increase in the supply of unskilled labor
hypothesis.” But he also emphasized the
in English cities, and attributes it to
different availabilities of skilled labor in
five sources. First, enclosures released
Britain and the United States. He wrote:
substantial labor from agriculture. Sec-
ond, “population was increasing very [I]n both countries this provided manufac-
rapidly” (p. 136). Third, labor reserves turers with an incentive to adopt and devise
methods which replaced skilled by non-
skilled . . . [but ] . . . the English had a
39 Since Israel can be approximated by a small
stronger incentive than the Americans to
open economy, another possibility is a change in replace skilled by unskilled labor. (p. 152)
the output mix and trade patterns. Gandal, Han-
son, and Slaughter (2000) and Cohen and Hsieh
(2000) find no evidence for this, and show that With a similar reasoning to Habakkuk
demand for skills increased in all Israeli sectors. and Schmookler, the endogenous tech-
Cohen and Hsieh (2000) also argue that because nology view suggests that nineteenth-
many Russian immigrants initially worked in low-
skill occupations, the supply of skills to the Israeli century businessmen took advantage of
economy may not have increased by much. the rapid increase in the supply of labor
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 43

in the cities by developing the factory As discussed above, a major problem


system. According to this view, there is for the “technological revolution” mod-
a close link between the skill-replacing els is the slowdown in TFP. Since the
technologies of the nineteenth century endogenous technology approach places
and the change in the factor supplies the emphasis on which type of tech-
faced by employers—“the reserve army nologies are developed, it is not incon-
of unskilled labor.” Although these his- sistent with the slow growth in TFP
torical examples are informative, they during the past thirty years: an accel-
do not reveal whether endogenous tech- eration in the skill bias of new technolo-
nology choices are important in under- gies does not require faster technical
standing more recent skill-biased tech- progress. The evidence presented in
nical change. A systematic study of how Richard Newell, Adam Jaffee, and
technologies respond to large changes Robert Stavins (1999) is consistent with
in the relative supply of skills is clearly the notion that changes in the direction
a worthwhile future research project. 40 of technical change can happen without
An important aspect of the endoge- an increase in the overall rate of pro-
nous technology theory is that it makes ductivity growth. They show that inno-
relatively tight predictions regarding vation in air conditioners responded to
the future path of technical change. changes in energy prices by becoming
While, with exogenous skill bias theo- more energy-efficient, but find no in-
ries, there is no clear reason to expect a crease in the rate of productivity
further acceleration or deceleration in growth. In fact, Acemoglu (1998) and
the skill bias of new technologies, ac- Kiley (1999) show that the increased
cording to this endogenous skill bias effort of firms to develop more skill-
theory, the future path of technical biased technologies could run into de-
progress should be closely tied to the creasing returns, and hence may cause a
path of the supply of skills. If the relative slowdown in TFP growth. Intuitively,
supply of skills continues to increase, the overall productivity growth in the
we should expect further skill-biased economy is maximized with a balanced
technical change. 41 distribution of resources toward devel-
oping skill-biased and unskill-biased
40 It is also useful to note that the skill bias of technologies (due to decreasing returns
technology most likely responds not only to to each activity). During periods of
changes in the relative supply of skills, but to a rapid skill-biased technical change, all
variety of other factors. Recent work by Marcus
Mobius (2000) and David Thesmar and Mathias resources go into developing skill-
Thoenig (2000) shows how the size of the product biased machines, and cause a decline in
market, the degree of competitive pressure and advances in unskill-biased technologies.
instability facing firms may affect the way firms
choose to organize, and therefore the demand for Because of the decreasing returns to
skills. Moreover, Mobius suggests that these
changes reduced the demand for skills during the
nineteenth century as there was greater stan- the 1980s has come to an end. It also has to be
dardization of products, but increased this de- noted that the increase in the relative supply of
mand during the past several decades as the need college educated workers in the 1990s may have
for flexibility increased. How the organization of been less than the previous trend (see figure 1),
product markets and the extent of competition af- and this may have affected the technology choices
fect technology choices and the demand for skills of firms. In particular, with the increased labor force
is a very promising area for future research. participation of less skilled workers, there may
41 Although evidence from the 1990s suggests now be a sufficient number of unskilled workers
that skill-biased technical change is now slower, supplying labor at low wages to make the further
there is not yet sufficient evidence to decide development of unskilled-labor-complementary
whether the rapid skill-biased technical change of technologies quite profitable.
44 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

scale, improvements in the other sector ers. 43 In the basic framework of section
will not fully offset this decline, and 3, average wages always increase when
overall TFP growth will fall. 42 the supply of educated workers in-
Finally, it is useful to discuss briefly creases, and all wages should rise in re-
the response of skills to technology. sponse to an increase in the productiv-
The analysis so far treated the supply of ity of skilled workers, Ah. Yet, over the
skills as exogenous, and investigated the past thirty years the wages of low-skill
implications of the supply on the de- workers have fallen in real value, which
mand for skills. Naturally, the supply contrasts with their steady increase in
of skills will also respond to economic the previous thirty years.
incentives: more workers are likely to Models of faster technological prog-
acquire skills when skill premia are ress would naturally predict that un-
higher. Such supply choices can be eas- skilled workers should benefit from this
ily incorporated into this framework. faster progress. The endogenous tech-
Suppose, for example, that the relative nology approach discussed in the pre-
supply of skills, H/L, is an increasing vious subsection, on the other hand,
function of the skill premium, ω . In this predicts that there may be no improve-
case, if the long-run demand curve for ments in the technologies for unskilled
skills is upward-sloping, we can have workers for an extended period of time
an equilibrium path in which both the because skill-biased innovations are
relative supply of skills and the skill more profitable than unskill-biased in-
premium increase together over time novations. Yet in that case, their wages
(see Acemoglu 1998). This equilibrium should be stagnant or increase slowly,
configuration gives us an attractive in- but not fall.
terpretation for the joint behavior of Some of the studies mentioned above
college skills and the college pre- have suggested explanations for the fall
mium in the U.S. economy over the past in the wages of low-skill workers. For
sixty years (see figure 1): high returns example, recall that Galor and Moav
to schooling encourage education, (2000) argue that faster technological
which in turn induce more skill-biased change creates an “erosion effect,” re-
technical change, increasing returns to ducing the productivity of unskilled work-
schooling again. ers. Using equation (3) from above, in
the simplified version of their model
discussed in section 5.1, the unskilled
5.3 A Puzzle: The Decline in Wages
wage is w L = φl(g)a[1 + φρh(H ⁄ L)ρ](1 − ρ) ⁄ ρ,
of Low-Skill Workers
where the φl function captures the ero-
A common shortcoming of all the sion effect. The rate of growth of un-
pure technology approaches discussed skilled wages will be w⋅ L ⁄ w L = g(1 + εφ),
in this section is that they do not natu- where εφ is the elasticity of the φl func-
rally predict stagnant average wages tion which is negative by the assump-
and/or falling wages for unskilled work- tion that φ′l < 0. If this elasticity is less
than –1, an acceleration in economic
42 The view that too much effort toward im-
growth can reduce the wages of
proving the skill-biased technologies may be re-
lated to the TFP slowdown is consistent with the
pattern of sectoral TFP growth observed recently. 43 However, recall that if the increase in non-
As Gordon (1998) and Jorgensen and Stiroh (2000) wage benefits is taken into account, average wages
document, there has been rapid TFP growth in increased over this period. So the more robust fact
computer-producing sectors, but mediocre, or might be the fall in the real wages of low-skill
even disappointing, TFP growth in other sectors. workers.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 45

low-skill workers due to a powerful and Green show that an increase in H/L
erosion effect. can raise inequality, and depress the
Acemoglu (1999a) and Caselli (1999) wages of low-skill workers. Although
derive a fall in the wages of less-skilled this is related to the effects of the in-
workers because the capital-labor ratio crease in the relative supply of skills on
for low-education/low-skill workers falls the path of technological progress dis-
as firms respond to technological devel- cussed in the last subsection, the mech-
opments. In Caselli’s model this hap- anism in Beaudry and Green’s paper is
pens because the equilibrium rate of quite different. The increase in H/L in-
return to capital increases, and in my creases the demand for capital, and
paper, this happens because firms de- pushes the interest rate up. This in-
vote more of their resources to opening crease in the interest rate hurts un-
specialized jobs for skilled workers. skilled workers more than skilled work-
Consider the following simple exam- ers because of the assumption that
ple to illustrate this point. There is a η < α.
scarce supply of an input K, which A potential problem with both the
could be capital, entrepreneurial talent Beaudry and Green and Caselli stories
or another factor of production. Skilled is that they explicitly rely on an increase
workers work with the production in the price of capital. Although the in-
function terest rates were higher during the
Yh = Aαh K1h − αH α, (20) 1980s in the U.S. economy, this seems
mostly due to contractionary monetary
while unskilled workers work with the policy, and related only tangentially to
production function inequality. Perhaps future research will
Yl = Aαl K1l − αLα, (21) show a major role for the increase in
where Kl and Kh sum to the total supply the interest rates in causing the decline
of K, which is assumed fixed. For sim- in the wages of low-education workers,
plicity, assume that Yl and Yh are perfect but as yet, there is no strong evidence
substitutes. In equilibrium, the marginal in favor of this effect. 44
product of capital in the two sectors has Overall, a potential problem for mod-
to be equalized, hence els based on technical change is to ac-
count for the decline in the wages of
Kl K − Kl low-skill workers. 45 I argue in the next
= .
A lL AhH section that the effect of technical
Therefore, an increase in Ah relative to change on the organization of the labor
Al will reduce Kl, as this scarce factor
44 Acemoglu (1999a), which is more in the spirit
gets reallocated from unskilled to skilled
of the organizational theories discussed below, ob-
workers. The wages of unskilled workers, tains the decline in the wages of unskilled workers
w L = (1 − α)Aαl K1l − αLα − 1, will fall as a through a change in the organization of produc-
result. tion, which also entails a reallocation of capital
away from them, but no increase in the rate of
An innovative version of this story is return to capital.
developed by Paul Beaudry and David 45 Another possibility is that some of the techno-

Green (2000). Suppose that equation logical developments of the past two decades have
been “truly labor-replacing,” for example, corre-
(21) above is replaced by Yl = Aηl K1l − ηLη, sponding to an increase in B l(t) or bt in terms of
with η < α, and K is interpreted as the production function in footnote 13. Autor,
physical capital. This implies that un- Levy, and Murnane (2000), for example, suggest
that computers have replaced unskilled routine
skilled workers are more “dependent” tasks. This possibility has not been extensively
on capital than skilled workers. Beaudry researched yet.
46 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

market both amplifies the effect of cause of the increase in inequality. In-
technology on wage inequality, and stead they have become powerful actors
provides a possible explanation for this only by interacting with technical
decline. change, amplified the direct effect of
technical change on inequality, and
6. Ramifications of Technical Change contributed to the fall in the wages of
low-skill workers.
This section discusses how technical 6.1 Organizational Change and
change can affect labor market prices Inequality
by transforming the organization of the
labor market. The idea that technology A variety of evidence suggests that
affects the organization of production, important changes in the structure of
and the institutions around it, is an old firms have been taking place in the U.S.
one. Marx put it in a dramatic fashion: economy over the past 25 years. More-
“The hand-mill gives you society with over, it seems clear that a major driving
the feudal lords; the steam-mill, society force for this transformation is changes
with the industrial capitalist.” The argu- in technologies (hence the view that
ment here is not as extreme, but re- technical change is essential for the
lated: recent technological developments changes in the organization of firms).
may have led to important changes in For example, team production and
the organization of production. other high-performance production
My focus here is on three sets of methods are now widespread in the
changes that could account for the fall U.S. economy (e.g., Casey Ichniowski,
in the wages of low-skill workers: the Giovanna Prennushi, and Kathryn
transformation of the organization of Shaw 1997, or Eileen Applebaum and
firms; change in labor market “insti- Rosemary Batt 1994). Similarly, Peter
tutions,” 46 particularly the decline in Cappelli and Steffanie Wilk (1997) show
unionization; and the interaction between that there has been an increase in the
international trade and technical change. screening of production workers, espe-
Organizational change often destroys cially from establishments that use
the types of jobs that pay high wages to computer technology and pay high
low-skill workers. Deunionization re- wages.
duces the bargaining power of low-skill Murnane and Levy (1996) report case
workers. And international trade with study evidence consistent with this
less developed countries (LDCs) in- view. From their interviews with human
creases the effective supply of unskilled resource personnel at a number of com-
labor and depresses the marginal value panies, they describe the change in the
product of less skilled workers in the hiring practices of U.S. companies. A
U.S. economy. Therefore, all three manager at Ford Motor company in
changes could be responsible for the 1967 describes their hiring strategy as
changes in the U.S. wage structure and follows: “If we had a vacancy, we would
for the decline in the wages of low-skill look outside in the plant waiting room
workers. Nevertheless, I argue that these to see if there were any warm bodies
factors by themselves are not the major standing there. If someone was there
and they looked physically OK and
46 I am using the term institutions loosely here,
weren’t an obvious alcoholic, they were
to capture the rules of the game in the labor mar-
ket, patterns of bargaining, as well as government hired” (p. 19). In contrast, comparable
labor market policy. companies in the late 1980s use a very
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 47

0.38

0.375

0.37
Weight-at-the-tails

0.365

0.36

0.355

0.35
1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993
Year
Figure 9. The Evolution of the Percentage of Employment in the Top and Bottom 25 Percentile Industry-
Occupation Cells (weight-at-the-tails of the job quality distribution)

different recruitment strategy. Murnane tively high or relatively low wages. In


and Levy discuss the cases of Honda of 1983, 35 percent of employment was in
America, Diamond Star Motors, and the top and bottom 25-percent job
Northwestern Mutual Life. All three categories. By 1993, this number had
companies spend substantial resources risen to just under 38 percent. So, ap-
on recruitment and hire only a fraction proximately 2.5 percent more workers
of those who apply. Kremer and Maskin now have either higher or lower quality
(1999) provide evidence of more segre- jobs rather than medium quality jobs.
gation of workers across establishments. The actual changes in the distribution
It seems that high-wage workers are of jobs may be much larger than this,
now much more concentrated in certain since substantial changes in the types
establishments. Similarly, in Acemoglu of jobs often take place within given
(1999a) I documented a change in the occupations.
composition of jobs over the past The view that changes in the organi-
twenty years. Figure 9 here replicates a zation of firms have had a fundamental
pattern found in that paper, and plots effect on the labor market is often ex-
the total percentage of workers em- pressed in the popular press, and in the
ployed in the top 25-percent and bot- organizational literature (e.g., Shohana
tom 25-percent industry-occupation Zuboff 1988). This organizational ap-
cells (what I called weight-at-the-tails proach is formalized by Kremer and
of the job quality distribution). These Maskin (1999), Acemoglu (1999a), Mobius
are the cells (job types) that pay rela- (2000), Thesmar and Thoenig (2000),
48 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

and Gilles Duranton (2001). Kremer mulation implies that if the productivity
and Maskin consider a production func- (ability) of unskilled workers, Al, is very
tion which distinguishes between man- low relative to Ah, they pull down the
agers and workers. They show that a productivity of skilled workers. In
change in technology or an increase in contrast, when they work in separate
the dispersion of skills may encourage firms, skilled workers are unaffected by the
high-skill workers to match with other productivity of unskilled workers. More-
high-skill workers, rather than work as over, β > 1, which implies that improve-
managers in establishments employing ments in the productivity of skilled work-
low-skill workers. ers has more effect on the productivity
Here I outline a simple model, syn- of new-style organizations. The parame-
thesizing Kremer and Maskin (1999) ters Bp and Bs capture the relative effi-
and Acemoglu (1999a), that captures ciency of old and new-style production
the effect of the technical change on functions.
the organization of production, and via The labor market is competitive, so
this channel, on wage inequality. The the equilibrium organization of produc-
basic idea is simple. As the productivity tion will maximize total output, given
of skilled workers increases, it becomes by Bp[(AlL)ρ + (AhhO)ρ]1 ⁄ ρ + BsAβh(H − hO),
more profitable for them to work by where hO ∈ [0, H] is the number of
themselves in separate organizations skilled workers employed in the old-style
rather than in the same workplace as organizations. For all cases in which
the unskilled workers. This is because hO > 0, the solution to this problem will
when the skilled and the unskilled work involve
together, their productivities interact,
and unskilled workers may put downward w H = BpAρh hρO − 1[Aρl Lρ + Aρh hρO ](1 − ρ) ⁄ ρ (22)
β
pressure on the productivity of skilled = B sA h ,
workers (for example, because unskilled i.e., skilled workers need to be paid BsAβh
workers have to implement part of the to be convinced to work in the same
production process designed by skilled firms as the unskilled workers. The
workers). unskilled wage is
Specifically, suppose that firms have
access to the following production ρ ρ ρ ρ
w L = BpAl Lρ − 1[Al Lρ + Ah hO ](1 − ρ) ⁄ ρ (23)
functions
< wH.
the old-style production function: Now consider an increase in Ah. Dif-
Y = Bp[(AlL)ρ + (AhhO )ρ]1 ⁄ ρ, ferentiating (22) yields ∂hO ⁄ ∂Ah < 0, that
the new-organization production function: is, there will be fewer skilled workers
β working with the unskilled. Moreover,
Y = B sA h h N ,
differentiation also gives ∂(AhhO) ⁄ ∂Ah < 0,
where hO is the number of skilled work- so the efficiency units of skilled workers
ers employed in the old-style firms, and that the unskilled work with declines.
hN is the number of skilled workers em- From (23), this implies that dw L ⁄ dAh < 0.
ployed in new organizations separately Therefore, skill-biased technical change
from unskilled workers. The fact that encourages skilled workers to work by
when they are employed in the same themselves, and as a result, unskilled
firm these two types of workers affect wages fall. Intuitively, because, in the
each other’s productivity is captured by old-style organizations, the productiv-
the CES production function. This for- ity of skilled workers depends on the
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 49

ability of unskilled workers, when the this evidence does not yet enable an as-
skilled become even more productive, sessment of whether changes in organi-
the downward pull exerted on their pro- zational forms have been an important
ductivity by the unskilled workers be- contributor to the changes in labor
comes more costly, and they prefer to market prices, and future research is
work in separate organizations. This re- required to determine the role of
duces the ratio AhhO ⁄ L and depresses organizational change in the rise in
unskilled wages. As a result, improve- inequality.
ments in technology, which normally
6.2 Institutional Change
benefit unskilled workers as in section
3, may hurt unskilled workers because Labor market “institutions,” includ-
they transform the organization of ing minimum wage laws, the impor-
production. tance of collective bargaining in wage
An increase in Bs ⁄ Bp, which raises the determination, and perhaps social
relative profitability of the new organi- norms, undoubtedly have an important
zational form, also leads to further seg- effect on the distribution of wages. The
regation of skilled and unskilled work- Great Compression in the wage distri-
ers in different organizations. This last bution after the Second World War is
comparative static result is useful since difficult to explain without invoking
Bresnahan (1999) and Autor, Levy and changes institutions and social norms
Murnane (2000) argue that by replacing (see, e.g., Goldin and Robert Margo
workers in the performance of routine 1992). Could changes in labor market
tasks, computers enabled a radical change institutions also account for the in-
in the organization of production. 47 crease in wage inequality and the dis-
This is reminiscent of a technological continuity in that demand for skills
change that makes the new-organization during the past decades?
production function more profitable. Two major changes in labor market
These organizational stories are at- institutions over the past 25 years are
tractive since they provide a unified ex- the decline in the real value of state and
planation for the changes in the wage federal minimum wages and the reduced
structure and the apparent changes in importance of trade unions in wage de-
the organization of firms. An interesting termination. Although many economists
recent paper by Eve Caroli and Van suspect that these institutional changes
Reenan (1999) provides evidence sug- may be responsible for the changes in
gesting that changes in wages have been the structure of the U.S. labor market
accompanied by changes in organi- (see Freeman 1991; DiNardo, Fortin,
zational forms. Acemoglu (1999a) and and Lemieux 1995; Lee 1999), I will
Kremer and Maskin (1999) also provide argue that these changes are unlikely
evidence suggesting a number of orga- to be the major cause of the recent
nizational changes in the U.S. economy increase in U.S. wage inequality.
during the past 25 years. Nevertheless, The real value of the minimum wage
was eroded throughout the 1980s as the
47 A related perspective is offered by Aghion
(2001), who also argues that computers replace
nominal minimum wage remained con-
unskilled tasks. He suggests that computers are a stant for much of this period. Since the
“general-purpose technology,” so their diffusion minimum wage is likely to increase the
follows an inverted S shaped pattern. He sug- wages of low-paid workers, this decline
gests that as more and more firms adopted com-
puters over the past decades, demand for unskilled may be responsible for increased wage
workers fell rapidly. dispersion. DiNardo et al. (1995) and
50 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Lee (1999) provide evidence in support increase in wage inequality. Unions


of this hypothesis. Although the contri- often compress the structure of wages
bution of the decline in the minimum and reduce skill premia (see for example
wage to increased wage dispersion can- Lloyd Reynolds 1951; or Freeman and
not be denied, most economists believe James Medoff 1984). Throughout the
that this is unlikely to have been a ma- postwar period in the U.S. economy,
jor factor in the changes in the U.S. unions negotiated the wages for many
wage structure. First, only a small frac- occupations, even indirectly influenced
tion of male workers are directly af- managerial salaries (see DiNardo,
fected by the minimum wage (even in Kevin Hallock, and Pischke 2000).
1992, after the minimum wage hike of Unions also explicitly tried to compress
1990–91, only 8 percent of all workers wage differentials. This suggests that the
between the ages of 18 and 65 were decline of unions may have been a major
paid at or below the minimum wage). cause of the changes in the structure of
Although the minimum wage may in- wages.
crease the earnings of some workers Although deunionization could in
who are not directly affected, it is un- principle be an important factor in the
likely to affect the wages above the me- structure of wages, the extent and tim-
dian of the wage distribution. But as ing of deunionization suggests that it is
figure 3 shows, the difference between not the major driving force of the in-
the 90th percentile and the median crease in inequality. First, wage in-
behaves very similarly to the difference equality increased in many occupations
between the median and the 10th per- in which prices were never affected by
centile. 48 This implies that whatever unions (such as lawyers and doctors).
factors were causing increased wage Moreover, in the United States, de-
dispersion at the top of the distribution unionization started in the 1950s, a period
are likely to have been the major cause of stable wage inequality. During the
of the increase in wage dispersion 1970s, though unionization fell in the
throughout the distribution. Second, the private sector, overall unionization rates
erosion in the real value of the mini- did not decline much because of in-
mum wage started in the 1980s, creased unionization in the public sec-
whereas, as shown above, the explosion tor. Overall union density was approxi-
in overall wage inequality began in the mately constant, around 30 percent of
early 1970s (subject to the caveat raised the work force, between 1960 and 1975.
in footnote 11). It was the anti-union atmosphere of the
The declining importance of unions 1980s and perhaps the defeat of the air-
may be another important factor in the traffic controllers’ strike that led to the
largest declines in unionization, dating
48 Except during the early 1980s when there is a much of deunionization after the rapid
more rapid increase in inequality at the bottom of increase in inequality during the early
the wage distribution, most likely due to the fall-
ing real value of the minimum wage. There are 1970s. 49 Evidence from other countries
substantially larger increases in inequality at the also paints a similar picture. For exam-
bottom of the distribution among female workers ple, in the United Kingdom, wage in-
or in a sample that combines male and female
workers. This reflects the larger effect of mini- equality started its sharp increase in the
mum wage laws on female earnings. Figure 3
shows that there are factors, other than the de- 49 An interesting recent paper by Henry Farber
cline in the real value of the minimum wage, hav- and Bruce Western (2000) dates the major decline
ing a major effect on the top and the bottom of in union activity to the early 1980s, a few months
the male wage distribution. before the air-traffic controllers’ strike.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 51

mid-1970s, while union density in- pressed. Alternatively, collective deci-


creased until 1980 and started a rapid sion making within a union may reflect
decline only during the 1980s (Amanda the preferences of its median voter, and
Gosling 1998). In Canada, while union- if this median voter is an unskilled
ization rates increased from around 30 worker, he will try to increase unskilled
percent in the 1960s to over 36 percent wages at the expense of skilled wages. It
in the late 1980s (Riddell 1993, table is also possible that union members
4.1), wage inequality also increased choose to compress wages because of
(see for example Freeman and Karen ideological reasons or for social cohe-
Needels 1993, figure 2.4). sion purposes. The empirical literature
Although the timing of deunioniza- supports the notion that unions com-
tion does not appear to be consistent press wages, though it does not distin-
with this institutional change being the guish among the various reasons (see
major cause of the changes in wage in- Freeman and James Medoff 1984). I
equality, deunionization could clearly capture wage compression in a reduced
affect the wages of unskilled workers. form way with the equation
One possibility is that deunionization is wH Ah
a contributing factor. But in this case, ω= ≤ψ , (24)
wL Al
why did the unions decline while tech-
nology was rapidly becoming more skill- where ψ < 1. Unions could never attract
biased? Acemoglu, Aghion, and Violante skilled workers unless they provided
(2001) suggest that deunionization may some benefits to them to compensate for
have been caused by the technological the wage compression. Here I simply as-
developments of the past decades. Ac- sume that they provide a benefit β to all
cording to this perspective, technical workers, for example, because unions in-
change is the driving force of the crease productivity (e.g., Freeman and
changes in the wage structure, but it Medoff 1984; and Freeman and Edward
also leads to deunionization, and the re- Lazear 1995), or because they encourage
sulting deunionization can have a sig- training. Alternatively, β could be part of
nificant indirect effect on wage inequal- the rents captured by the union. The
ity, causing the wages of less-skilled zero-profit constraint for firms would be:
workers to fall. (w H − β)H + (w L − β)L ≤ AhH + AlL (in the
To see the basic argument, suppose that case where β stands for rents, the zero-
production can be carried out either in profit condition ensures that the firm
unionized or nonunionized firms. In does not wish to open a non-union
nonunionized firms, workers receive plant). Combining this equation with
their marginal products, which I denote (24), and assuming that both hold as
by Ah and Al for skilled and unskilled equality, we obtain
workers. Assume that unions always (Ah + β)H + (Al + β)L
compress the structure of wages—i.e., wH = Ah. (25)
AhH + ψ −1AlL
they reduce wage differentials between
skilled and unskilled workers. This Skilled workers will be happy to be part
wage compression could be driven by a of a union as long as w H given by (25) is
variety of factors. Acemoglu and Pischke greater than Ah. As Ah ⁄ Al increases—i.e.,
(1999), for example, argue that unions as skill-biased technical change raises
encourage productive training, and such the productivity of skilled workers rela-
training is incentive compatible for firms tive to the unskilled— w H will fall relative
only when the wage structure is com- to Ah. Therefore, skill-biased technical
52 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

change makes wage compression more 6.3 Trade, Technical Change,


costly for skilled workers, eventually de- and Inequality
stroying the coalition between skilled
Finally, I discuss another major
and unskilled workers that maintains
change affecting the U.S. economy: the
unions.
increased volume of international trade.
The important point is that deunion-
I argue that increased international
ization causes a decline in the wages of un-
trade by itself is not the cause of the
skilled workers from w L = (A A+ β)H
h + (A + β)Ll
ψAl
H+ψ AL
h
−1
l changes in the U.S. wage structure, but
to Al. Unskilled workers, who were pre-
trade may have been an important fac-
viously benefiting from wage compres-
tor in the rise of wage inequality by
sion imposed by unions, now experi-
affecting the degree of skill bias of
ence a fall in real earnings. Therefore,
technical change. This subsection is
technical change not only affects wage
somewhat different from the previous two,
inequality directly, but also induces a
since it is not about the effect of tech-
change in labor market institutions. The
nology on the organization of the labor
effect of this change in institutions on
market, but on the effect of a major
inequality can be potentially larger than
change in regulations on technological
the direct effect of technical change,
developments.
and explain the decline in the real
Standard trade theory predicts that
wages of less-skilled workers.
increased international trade with less-
Although Acemoglu, Aghion, and Vio-
developed countries (LDCs), which are
lante (2001) provide some evidence
more abundant in unskilled workers,
consistent with these patterns, whether
should increase the demand for skills in
deunionization was important in the de-
the U.S. labor market. So the increase
cline of the wages of low-skill workers and
in international trade may have been an
whether technical change is responsible
underlying cause of the changes in U.S.
for deunionization are open questions.
wage inequality.
It might also be interesting to investi-
To discuss these issues, consider the
gate whether changes in technology
two-good interpretation of the model in
may have also affected the coalition
section 3. Consumer utility is defined
supporting the minimum wage, and
over [Yρl + Yρh]1 ⁄ ρ, with the production
hence played a role in the decline in
functions for two goods being Yh = AhH
the minimum wage during the 1980s.
and Yl = AlL. Both goods are now tradable.
For example if unions, which have tra-
For simplicity, let me just compare the
ditionally supported minimum wages,
U.S. labor market equilibrium without
were weakened by the technological de-
any trade (as characterized in section 3)
velopments of that decade as argued in
to the equilibrium with full international
this subsection, technical change may
trade without any trading costs.
have indirectly contributed to the weak-
Before trade, the U.S. relative price
ening of the coalition in support of the
of skill-intensive goods, ph ⁄ pl, is given by
minimum wage. 50 ρ−1
ph  AhH 
pUS = = , (26)
pl  AlL 
50 Finally, both the decline in the role that
unions play and in the value of the minimum wage
may have been caused by changes in certain social
norms, for example, the norm of “equal work
equal pay.” The decline of the same norms could 1996). Unfortunately, there is currently little re-
also be responsible for the increase in inequality search on the effect of social norms on inequality
(e.g., the emergence of the winner-take-all society and on why inequality norms may have changed
as claimed by Robert Frank and Philip Cook over the past thirty years.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 53

where H and L denote the supplies of since the producers face the same rela-
skilled and unskilled labor in the United tive price of skill-intensive goods, and
States. The skill premium is then simply have access to the same technologies.
equal to the ratio of the marginal value Before trade, however, the skill pre-
products of the two types of workers, mium in the LDCs was ω ^=p ^Ah ⁄ Al,
that is, ω US = pUSAh ⁄ Al. Next, suppose where p ^⁄AL
^ = (AhH ^)ρ − 1 is the relative
l
that the United States starts trading with price of skill-intensive goods in the
a set of LDCs that have access to the LDCs before trade. The same argument
same technology as given by Ah and Al, as above implies that p ^ > pW , i.e., trade
but are relatively scarce in skills. Denote with the skill-abundant United States re-
the total supplies of skilled and unskilled duces the relative price of skill-intensive
workers in the LDCs by H ^ and L ^ where goods in the LDCs. This implies that
^ ^
H ⁄ L < H ⁄ L, which simply reiterates that ωW < ω^; after trade wage inequality
the United States is more abundant in should fall in the LDCs.
skilled workers than the LDCs. Although in theory increased trade
After full trade opening, the product with the LDCs can be the cause of the
markets in the United States and the rapid increase in the demand for skills,
LDCs are joined, so there will be a most evidence suggests that the direct
unique world relative price. Since the effect of increased international trade
supplies of skill- and unskill-intensive on the U.S. labor market has been rela-
goods are Ah(H + H ^ ) and A (L + L ^), the tively minor. First, as equation (27)
l
relative price of the skill-intensive good shows, the effect of international trade
will be works through a unique intervening
^ ) ρ − 1 mechanism: more trade with the LDCs
 Ah(H + H increases the relative price of skill-
p =
W
^)  < pUS. (27)
 A l (L + L  intensive goods, p, and affects the skill
premium via this channel. In fact, in
The fact that pW > pUS follows immedi-
^⁄L ^ < H ⁄ L. Intuitively, once this simple framework, the percentage
ately from H
increase in the skill premium is propor-
the United States starts trading with
tional to the percentage increase in the
skill-scarce LDCs, demand for skill-
relative price of skill-intensive goods.
intensive goods increases and pushes the
Perhaps the most damaging piece of
prices of these goods up.
evidence for the trade hypothesis is that
Labor demand in this economy is de-
most studies suggest the relative price
rived from product demands. The skill
of skill-intensive goods did not increase
premium therefore follows the relative
over the period of increasing inequality.
price of skill-intensive goods. After
Robert Lawrence and Slaughter (1993)
trade opening, the U.S. skill premium
found that during the 1980s the relative
increases to
price of skill-intensive goods actually
Ah
ωW = pW > ω US (28) fell. Jeffrey Sachs and Howard Shatz
Al (1994) found no major change or a
where the fact that ω W > ω US is an imme- slight decline. A more recent paper by
diate consequence of pW > pUS. There- Krueger (1997) criticized the methods
fore, trade with less developed countries and data used by these studies, and
increases wage inequality in the United found an increase in the relative price
States. of skill-intensive goods. Nevertheless,
The skill premium in the LDCs will the increase in these prices is relatively
also be equal to ω W after trade opening small, so would not be able to account for
54 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

the large increase in the skill premium the same point by showing that the con-
experienced in the U.S. economy. tent of unskilled labor embedded in the
Second, with trade as the driving U.S. imports is small relative to the
force, increased production of skill- changes in the supply of skills taking
intensive goods should be drawing place during this period. 51
workers away from other sectors. In Although the above arguments sug-
contrast, as documented by Murphy gest that increased international trade
and Welch (1993), Berman, Bound, and with the LDCs is not the major cause of
Griliches (1994) and Autor, Katz, and the changes in the wage structure by it-
Krueger (1998), all sectors, even those self, they do not rule out a powerful ef-
producing less-skilled goods, increased fect of international trade when it inter-
their demands for more-educated work- acts with technical change. In a world
ers. This pattern is not consistent with with endogenous technical change, in-
trade being the main driving force of creased international trade could affect
the increase in the demand for skilled the types of technologies developed and
workers (though one has to bear in adopted by firms, and have a large ef-
mind the increase in outsourcing in fect through this channel. This possibil-
interpreting this fact; see Robert ity was first raised by Wood (1994), who
Feenstra and Hanson 1999). argued that trade with the LDCs will
Third, a direct implication of the lead to defensive skill-biased innova-
trade view is that, as shown above, tions. Wood, however, did not develop
while demand for skills and inequality the mechanism through which such de-
increased in the United States, the con- fensive innovations could occur. I now
verse should have happened in the illustrate how trade causes skill-biased
LDCs that have started trading with technical change using the endogenous
the more skill-abundant U.S. economy. The technology model developed in section
evidence, however, suggests that more 5.2 (this analysis draws on Acemoglu
of the LDCs experienced rising in- 1999b).
equality after opening to international Suppose that the United States starts
trade (see Hanson and Ann Harrison trading with the LDCs as discussed
1994; or Donald Robbins 1995). Al- above, and assume that the LDCs al-
though the increase in inequality in a ways use U.S. technologies. Therefore,
number of cases may have been due to the supply of skilled and unskilled
concurrent political and economic re- goods in the LDCs is Yh = AhH ^ and
forms, the preponderance of evidence ^ ^ ^
Yl = AlL where as before H ⁄ L < H ⁄ L.
is not favorable to this basic implication The immediate effect will be an
of the trade hypothesis. increase in the relative price of
Finally, a number of economists have skill-intensive goods as illustrated by
pointed out that U.S. trade with the
51 This is probably the weakest criticism against
LDCs is not important enough to have a
the trade view, and many studies have pointed out
major impact on the U.S. product mar- how international trade could have a larger effect
ket prices and consequently on wages. on U.S. labor market prices in the presence of la-
Paul Krugman (1995) illustrates this bor market rents. For example, George Borjas and
Valerie Ramey (1995), Dani Rodrik (1997), and
point by undertaking a calibration of a Dube and Reddy (1999) have argued that the
simple North-South model. Katz and threat of international trade may reduce wages,
Murphy (1992), Berman, Bound, and especially in sectors with substantial rents, and
this change in bargaining power may affect the
Griliches (1994) and George Borjas, earnings of unskilled workers more, increasing
Freeman, and Katz (1997) emphasize inequality.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 55

equation (27). Now, recall from the librium price of skill-intensive goods
analysis in section 5.2 that there is a cannot change either. Combining equa-
relative price effect on the direction of tions (18) and (27) gives the post-trade
technical change (because developing skill bias of technology as
technologies to produce the more ex-
AW  (H + H^ ) −1 H 1 ⁄ (1 − ρ)
pensive good is more profitable). There- h  
fore, trade, by making the skill-intensive = ^)   L 
AW ( L + L
l    
goods more expensive, encourages more
ρ ⁄ (1 − ρ)
skill-biased technical change. AUS
h H
To determine exactly how the direc- > = 
AUS
l L
tion of technical change will be affected
where AUSh ⁄ Al
US
by trade, we need to know the market is the pre-trade skill bias
sizes for new technologies after trade of technology in the United States.
opening. It is plausible to assume that The implication is that when the di-
trade opening with the LDCs will not rection of technical change is endoge-
have a major effect on the enforcement nous, trade between the United States
of intellectual property rights in the and the LDCs will induce skill-biased
South. In that case, trade opening will technical progress. The result is not
induce skill-biased technical change in only that trade leads to an increase in
the United States. Specifically, as long skill premia, but that this can happen
as after trade opening the United States without the counterfactual implications
does not start producing technologies of the standard trade models discussed
for unskilled workers in the LDCs, the above.
relative market sizes for the two types The first implication of this induced
of technologies remain at H/L. This im- skill bias is that the impact of trade on
plies that the technology market clear- labor markets may be much larger than
ing condition, equation (18), no longer predicted by the standard trade models,
holds. In particular, since pW h H > pl L
W which helps against the criticism that
from equation (27), there will now only the amount of trade the United States
be incentives for skill-biased technical undertakes with the LDCs is not large
change. This process continues until enough. Second, because trade causes
pW = pWh ⁄ p l = (H ⁄ L) , so that incentives
W −1 skill-biased technical change, the fact
to develop the two different types of that all sectors have increased the em-
technologies are balanced. This implies ployment of skilled workers is consis-
that the skill bias of technical change is tent with trade being the underlying
still determined by equation (18) from cause of the increase in inequality.
section 5.2, i.e., by U.S. domestic rela- Third, for the same reason, there is a
tive supplies alone. Intuitively, the rela- force counteracting the decline in in-
tive price of skill-intensive goods plays equality in the LDCs implied by trade:
two roles in this model. The first is to these economies use U.S. technologies,
clear the market for goods (i.e., equa- which are becoming more skill-biased.
tion 27), and the second is to ensure Finally, and quite strikingly, trade
equilibrium in the technology market leaves the relative price of skill-intensive
(cfr. equation 18). Since the technology goods in the United States unchanged
market clearing condition relates the in the long-run. Recall that changes in
relative price of skill-intensive goods to relative prices are the usual intervening
the relative supplies in the U.S. market, mechanism in trade models, so a num-
which do not change, the long-run equi- ber of studies have concluded that trade
56 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

has not been an important factor in the 7. Changes in Residual Inequality


increase in inequality because the rela-
tive price of skill-intensive goods has The previous sections highlighted
not increased much (e.g., Lawrence and that there are major unanswered ques-
Slaughter 1994; Sachs and Shatz 1995). tions regarding the causes of the in-
In this model, the long-run relative crease in inequality, the reasons for the
price of skill-intensive goods in the faster skill-biased technical change in
United States is unaffected by trade. the past few decades, and the determi-
More generally, induced skill-biased nants of the fall in the wages of low-
technical change in the United States skill workers. These questions awaiting
implies that trade will increase the further research notwithstanding, we
price of skill-intensive goods by only have a reasonably simple and useful
a limited amount, while still having framework, and the beginnings of con-
a major effect on the U.S. labor sistent answers. In contrast, in this and
market. the next section, I discuss areas where
Notice finally that the interaction be- answers are much more tentative, and
tween international trade and technical there is a greater need for future re-
change may help to explain the decline search. I begin with residual inequality.
in the wages of low-skill workers. In- A major issue that most models dis-
creased international trade acts as an cussed so far failed to address is the dif-
increase in the supply of unskilled ferential behavior of returns to school-
workers, and as shown in our basic ing and residual inequality during the
framework in section 3, this would put 1970s. I argue in this section that an
downward pressure on unskilled wages. explanation for this pattern requires
Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1987), for models with multi-dimensional skills.
example, provide evidence that in- 7.1 A Single Index Model
creased international trade during the of Residual Inequality
1980s reduced the wages of high
school graduate workers (though they The simplest model of residual in-
also suggest that the effect of the immi- equality is a single index model, in
gration of less-skilled workers was which there is only one type of skill,
greater). though this skill is only imperfectly ap-
Overall, international trade could still proximated by education (or experi-
be a major driving force of the changes ence). Expressed alternatively, in a sin-
in the wage structure. However, for gle index model observed and
increased trade to have such a large unobserved skills are perfect substi-
effect on the structure of wages—and to tutes. Consider, for example, the model
avoid the aforementioned counterfac- developed above, but suppose that in-
tual implications—it must cause a stead of skills, we observe education,
change in the path of technological e.g., whether the individual is a college
progress. So the combination of trade graduate, which is imperfectly corre-
opening and endogenous technical lated with true skills. A fraction φc of
change gives an alternative theory for college graduates are highly skilled,
acceleration: skill-biased technical change while a fraction φn < φc of noncollege
accelerates, neither exogenously nor in graduates are highly skilled. Denote
response to the changes in the supply the skill premium by ω = w H ⁄ w L. The
of skilled workers, but due to trade college premium, i.e., the ratio of
opening. average college to noncollege wages, is
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 57

w C φcw H + (1 − φc)w L zero disturbance term. Here γt is the price


ωc = = of observed skills, while θt is the price
w N φnw H + (1 − φn)w L
of unobserved skills. The education
φcω + (1 − φc) premium can be written as
= ,
φnω + (1 − φn)
ln ω t ≡ E(ln w it | hit = 1) − E(ln w it | hit = 0)
while within-group inequality, i.e., the
= γt + θt(A1t − A0t)
ratio of the wage of high-wage college
graduates (or noncollege graduates) to where A1t ≡ E(ln w it | hit = 1) and A0t is
that of low-wage college graduates (or defined similarly. Residual inequality
noncollege graduates), is ω within = ω (since can be measured by Var(Ait | h = 0) and
high-wage workers in both groups earn Var(Ait | h = 1) .
w H , while low-wage workers earn w L). To simplify the discussion, assume
As long as φc and φn remain constant, ω c that there is perfect sorting into educa-
and ω within will always move together. tion, in the sense that there exists a
Therefore, an increase in the returns to threshold a− such that all individuals
observed skills—such as education—will with unobserved ability above a− obtain
also be associated with an increase in the education. Then within-group inequal-
returns to unobserved skills. ity among high and low-education work-
This framework provides a natural ers will move in opposite directions as
starting point, linking between- and long as the price of observed skills, θ, is
within-group inequality. It predicts that constant: as a− declines (and average
within- and between-group inequality education increases), Var(Ait | h = 1) will
should move together. But during the increase, but Var(Ait | h = 0) will fall. In-
1970s, returns to schooling fell while tuitively, there are more and more
residual (within-group) inequality in- “marginal” workers added to the high-
creased sharply. We can only account education group, creating more unob-
for this fact by positing a decline in φc served heterogeneity in that group and
relative to φn of a large enough magni- increasing within-group inequality. But
tude to offset the increase in ω ; this in contrast, the low-education group be-
would ensure that during the 1970s the comes more homogeneous. Therefore,
college premium could fall despite the without a change in the prices for unob-
increase in within-group inequality. A served skills, this approach cannot ac-
large decline in φc relative to φn would count for the simultaneous increase
predict a very different behavior of the in inequality among both low- and
college premium within different co- high-education groups. 52
horts. Yet the appendix shows little evi- 7.3 Churning and Residual Inequality
dence in favor of this. I therefore con-
Another approach emphasizes that
clude that the single index model cannot
workers of all levels of education may
explain the changes in residual inequality
face difficulty adapting to changes. This
during the 1970s and the 1980s.
52 A natural variation on this theme would be a
7.2 Sorting and Residual Inequality
situation in which γ and θ move together. How-
Another approach would combine ever, this will run into the same problems as the
single index model: if γ and θ always move to-
educational sorting with an increase in gether, then such a model would predict that
the demand for skills. Suppose that within-group inequality should have fallen during
wages are given by ln w it = θtai + γthi + εit the 1970s. Therefore, models based on sorting also
require a mechanism for the prices of observed
where hi is a dummy for high education, and unobserved skills to move differently during
ai is unobserved ability, and εit is a mean the 1970s.
58 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

has been argued by Piore and Sabel 1970s. Therefore, a mechanism that
(1984), and more recently by Aghion, could lead to differential behavior in
Howitt, and Violante (2000) and Gould, the prices to observed and unobserved
Moav, and Weinberg (2000). Violante skills is still necessary. 54
(2000) offers an alternative, but related
theory, where increased churning is 7.4 A Two-Index Model
driven by the greater productivity gap of Residual Inequality
between different firms (because of
Since models based on a single index
faster embodied technical change) and
of skill (or models where different types
increased skill dynamics of ex ante
of skills are perfect substitutes) are in-
identical workers (which he contrasts
consistent with the differential behavior
with the argument that it is innate abil-
of returns to schooling and within-group
ity differences that matter). According
inequality during the 1970s, an obvious
to all these approaches, an increase in
next step is to consider a two-index
inequality results from more rapid tech-
model where observed and unobserved
nical change, not because of skill bias
skills are imperfect substitutes. There
but because of increased “churning” in
are good reasons to expect that in the
the labor market. Aghion, Howitt, and
real world skills are multidimensional.
Violante (2000), for example, suggest
For example, the social psychologist
that only some workers will be able to
Howard Gardner (1988) makes a strong
adapt to the introduction of new tech-
case that we should always think of
nology, and this will increase wage
skills as multidimensional, and that the
inequality.
standard IQ measures fail to capture
An advantage of this approach is that
this multidimensionality. There is a
it is in line with the increased earnings
long tradition in economics building on
instability pointed out by Gottschalk
the Roy model which uses models with
and Robert Moffit (1994). However,
multidimensional skills to analyze wages
there is relatively little evidence, other
and returns to schooling (e.g., Robert
than this increase in earnings instabil-
Willis and Sherwin Rosen 1975). In the
ity, supporting the notion that there is
context of the determinants of earnings,
more churning in the labor market. The
a recent paper by Bowles, Gintis, and
data on job creation and job destruction
reported by Steven Davis, John Halti- 54 An interesting theory similar to the churning

wanger, and Scott Schuh (1996) shows models that could lead to such a differential be-
havior is advanced by Galor and Tsiddon (1997).
no increase in job reallocation during They draw a distinction between ability and edu-
the 1980s or the early 1990s, and most cation, and argue that returns to ability increase
evidence does not indicate much of a faster during periods of rapid technological
change. If we view the 1970s as a period of rapid
decline in job stability over this period technological change, as suggested above, this the-
(e.g. Francis Diebold, David Neumark, ory would imply an increase in the returns to abil-
and Daniel Polsky 1997; or Henry ity (unobserved skills) during this period. Never-
theless, this explanation is still not consistent with
Farber 1995). 53 Also theories based on the facts because high-ability individuals are more
churning do not naturally predict a di- likely to be high education, so rapid technological
vergence between returns to education progress should also increase returns to schooling.
Perhaps a combination of this mechanism with dif-
and residual inequality during the ferential sorting into education, or with imperfect
substitution between high- and low-education
53 More recent evidence indicates that there workers, might be able to account for the diver-
may have been a decrease in job tenure during the gence between returns to schooling and residual
later parts of the 1990s (see Neumark, Polsky, and inequality during the 1970s, but such a model has
Daniel Hansen 1999). not been developed yet.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 59

Osborne (2001) also forcefully argues of more-educated workers that triggers


that there are many dimensions to skills more rapid skill-biased technical change.
including the ability to function in hier- Because technology adjusts sluggishly,
archies and other social situations. To the first effect of an increase in the sup-
discuss these issues, I now consider a ply of educated workers, as in the 1970s,
simple two-index model (see Acemoglu will be to depress returns to schooling.
1998). Suppose that there are four This will continue until technology has
types of workers, differentiated by both changed enough to offset the direct ef-
education and unobserved skills. The fect of the higher supply of skills (see
economy has an aggregate production figure 7). This change in returns to
function schooling has no obvious implication for
within-group inequality in a multi-skill
Y = [(AluLu)ρ + (AlsLs)ρ + (AhuH u)ρ set-up, since it is the education skills
+ (AhsH s)ρ]1 ⁄ ρ, that are becoming abundant, not unob-
where Lu is the supply of low-skill low- served skills—in fact, in equation (29),
education workers, and other terms are within-group inequality is invariant to
defined similarly. Within-group inequal- changes in the supply of educated work-
ity corresponds to the ratio of the wages ers unless there is a simultaneous change
of skilled low-education workers to those in φh and φl.
of unskilled low-education workers, Under the plausible assumption that
and/or to the ratio of the wages of skilled more skilled workers within each educa-
high-education workers to those of un- tion group also benefit from skill-biased
skilled high-education workers. A natural technical progress, technical change
starting point is to presume that the frac- spurred by the increase in the supply
tion of high-skill workers in each education of educated workers will immediately
group is constant, say at φl = Ls ⁄ Lu and benefit workers with more unobserved
φh = H s ⁄ H u > φl, which implies that there skills, raising within-group inequality.
are more high-ability workers among high- Therefore, an increase in the supply of
education workers. With this assumption, educated workers will depress returns
within-group inequality will be to schooling, while increasing within-group
ρ
inequality. After this initial phase, tech-
w Ls  Als  −(1 − ρ) nical change will increase both returns to
= φ and
w Lu  Alu  l ρ (29) schooling and within-group inequality. 55
w Hs  Ahs  −(1 − ρ)
= φ .
w Hu  Ahu  h 55 If the 1960s are also characterized by steady
skill-biased technical change, equation (29) sug-
The college premium, on the other gests that there should have been an increase in
hand, is residual inequality during this decade as well. The
ρ ρ ρ ρ −(1 − ρ) data presented in section 2 do not support this
φh Ahs + Ahu  1 + φl  H prediction. Therefore, it seems that to explain the
ω= ρ ρ ρ   L . basic trends, one needs to posit that improvements
φl Als + Alu  1 + φh    in technology take the form ln A j(t) = γ ′j + γj ⋅ t with
γhs = γhu > γls = γlu during regular times, but when
Using this framework and the idea of en- there is an acceleration in skill bias, the pattern
dogenous technology, we can provide an changes to favor workers with more unobserved
skills, i.e., γhs > γhu and γls > γlu . Although this as-
explanation for the differential behavior sumption can generate stable residual inequality
of returns to schooling and within-group before the 1970s, and an increase in residual in-
inequality during the 1970s. Recall that equality during the 1970s, it is simply reverse engi-
neered to fit the facts. Future research to inves-
according to the endogenous technology tigate whether there are natural reasons for this
approach, it is the increase in the supply pattern to arise would be useful.
60 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Overall, single index models are not substantially in the United States and
capable of explaining the changes in re- the United Kingdom, but remained
sidual inequality over the past thirty fairly stable in many continental Euro-
years, and we do not yet know how im- pean economies (see for example Davis
portant various factors are. Analysis of 1995; Gottschalk and Timothy Smeeding
the determinants of residual inequality 1999).
and the reasons why there was an explo- The standard explanation for this
sion in overall inequality beginning in divergent behavior, succinctly summa-
the 1970s remains a major research rized by Krugman (1994) and OECD
area. (1994), and sometimes referred to as
the Krugman hypothesis, maintains that
8. Cross-Country Patterns inequality did not increase as much (or
not at all) in Europe because labor mar-
So far, I have focused on U.S. wage ket institutions there encourage wage
inequality patterns and on the incen- compression, limiting the extent of in-
tives to develop new technologies com- equality. This can be captured in the
ing from the U.S. supply of skills. The competitive framework of section 3,
cross-country dimension presents a where firms are always along their rela-
number of challenges, in particular be- tive demand curve, by assuming that
cause it is difficult to explain why in- labor market institutions impose an ex-
equality increased much more in some ogenous skill premium ω − = w ⁄ w . This
H L
countries than others. In addition, for implies:
the endogenous technology view, it is ρ ⁄ (1 − ρ)
important to know whether it is the H  Ah  − −1 ⁄ (1 − ρ). (30)
= ω
relative supply of skills in each country l  Al 
or in the world as a whole that deter-
mines the direction of technical change. where the level of employment of un-
I now briefly discuss these issues. skilled workers, l, will generally be less
8.1 Differences in Inequality Patterns than their labor supply L because of
wage compression. A more compressed
Although the tendency toward wage structure—i.e., a lower ω − —will in-
greater inequality has been a feature in crease the unemployment of unskilled
many developed and less developed workers, given by L − l.
countries (see Freeman and Katz 1995; The view that wages are more com-
and Berman and Machin 2000), there pressed in Europe clearly has some
are also marked differences in the be- merit. Francine Blau and Lawrence
havior of within- and between-group in- Kahn (1995) show that the major differ-
equality across these countries. Katz, ence in overall inequality between the
David Blanchflower, and Gary Loveman United States and many continental
(1995), Murphy, Riddell, and Romer European economies is not in the 90–
(1998), and Card and Lemieux (2000) 50 differential, but in the 50–10 differ-
show that the differential behavior of ential. This suggests that the minimum
the supply of skills can go a long way wage, strong unions, and generous
toward explaining the differences in transfer programs in Europe are in
the returns to schooling, especially be- part responsible for the relative wage
tween the United States, Canada, and compression in Europe.
the United Kingdom. Nevertheless, it is Nevertheless, the Krugman hypothe-
puzzling that wage inequality increased sis runs into two difficulties. First, unless
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 61

there are extremely rigid institutions a possibility, we have no direct evi-


that fix the skill premium exogenously, dence to assess how far off the relative
skill-biased technical change should demand curve European economies
increase wage inequality irrespective may be, and how they would respond to
of the degree of exogenously imposed skill-biased technical change when they
wage compression. In contrast, in many are away from the relative demand
continental European economies, most curve for skills. 56
notably in Germany, wage inequality My preferred approach to explaining
was very stable (see, e.g., Freeman and cross-country differences is to consider
Katz 1995). the effect of labor market institutions
Second, the Krugman hypothesis on technology choices. In particular,
makes an explicit prediction: profit- the European labor market institutions,
maximizing employment decisions of which compress the structure of wages,
firms should lead to a decline in the will give greater incentives to adopting
employment of unskilled workers rela- labor-complementary technologies, and
tive to that of skilled workers. In fact, will reinforce wage compression. I give
skill-biased technical change might a simple example to illustrate the point
even reduce the unemployment rates of here. Suppose the productivity of a
skilled workers. Yet, in Europe, the un- skilled worker is Ah = aη, whereas the
employment of skilled and unskilled productivity of an unskilled worker is
workers increased together (e.g. Stephen Al = a, where a is a measure of aggre-
Nickell and Brian Bell 1996; Krueger gate technology in use, and η > 1. Sup-
and Pischke 1997), and unskilled em- pose that wages are determined by rent
ployment did not grow faster in the sharing, unless they fall below a legally
United States than in European econo- mandated minimum wage, in which
mies (Card, Kramartz, and Lemieux case the minimum wage binds. Hence,
1996; Krueger and Pischke 1997). − }, where j = l or h, and β
w j = min {βAj,w
It is possible that bargaining arrange- is worker’s share in rent sharing. Note
ments in Europe between firms and that the cost of technology upgrading
unions, imply not only wage compres- does not feature in this wage equation,
sion, but also deviations from the rela- because rent sharing happens after
tive demand curve for “skills” given by technology costs are sunk. To capture
(30). This may be because European in- wage compression, suppose the mini-
stitutions force firms to pay uniform mum wage is binding for unskilled
wages to all educated workers irrespec- workers in Europe. Now consider tech-
tive of their exact skills (marginal prod- nology adoption decisions. In particular,
uct), making the employment of skilled 56 An alternative view suggested by Nickell and
workers less profitable as well. Alterna- Bell (1996) explains the differences in the wage
tively, if unions represent both skilled structure across countries by differences in the
and unskilled workers, and are commit- skill distribution. According to this view, because
of the relative weakness of the U.S. high school
ted to wage compression, they may not system, American noncollege workers are less
want to suffer a large decrease in the skilled than their European counterparts. How-
employment of unskilled workers, and ever, recent work by Dan Devroye and Freeman
(2001) shows that differences in skill distribution
prefer to make certain concessions in have little to do with cross-country differences in
wage levels in order to induce firms to wage dispersion. They document that dispersion
employ more unskilled workers at a of internationally comparable test scores among
native-born Americans are similar to those in
compressed wage structure. Although Europe, but wage inequality among native-born
such deviations from equation (30) are Americans is much higher.
62 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

firms can either produce with some productivity of unskilled workers (see
existing technology, a, or upgrade to a Acemoglu and Pischke 1999 for this
superior technology, a′ = a + α, at cost γ. argument in the context of training).
The profit to upgrading the technology As long as the cost of upgrading to
used by a skilled worker is (1 − β)αη − γ, the new technology, γ, is small, i.e., less
both in the United States and Europe. than γU , firms will upgrade both with
The new technology will therefore be skilled and unskilled workers in the
adopted when United States and Europe. In this case,
cross-country inequality levels will be
γ ≤ γS ≡ (1 − β)αη. stable. This corresponds to the situation
Note that there is a holdup problem, dis- in the 1950s and the 1960s. In contrast,
couraging upgrading: a fraction β of the if γ is high, for example, because the
productivity increase accrues to the technological improvements of the 1980s
worker due to rent sharing (Paul Grout are more expensive to implement, there
1984; Acemoglu 1996). may be a divergence in inequality be-
The incentives to upgrade the tech- tween the two economies. For instance,
nology used by unskilled workers, on if γ ∈(γU ,α), then new technology will not
the other hand, differ between the be adopted with unskilled workers in
United States and Europe. In the the United States, but it will be used
United States, this profit is given by with unskilled workers in Europe. As a
(1 − β)α − γ. So, the new technology will
result, while wage inequality increases
be adopted with unskilled workers if in the United States, it will remain
stable in Europe. Therefore, a simple
γ ≤ γU ≡ (1 − β)α. story for cross-country differences in
inequality trends emerges from this
Clearly, γU < γS, so adopting new tech- model: wage compression encourages
nologies with skilled workers is more the use of more advanced technologies
profitable. The returns to introducing with unskilled workers, and acts to rein-
the new technology are different in force itself in Europe. In contrast, tech-
Europe because the minimum wage is nological developments can harm the
binding for unskilled workers. To sim- earnings of low-skill U.S. workers who
plify the discussion, suppose that even are not protected by this type of wage
after the introduction of new technology, compression. Whether the interaction
the minimum wage binds, i.e., between wage compression and tech-
w
− > β(A + α) . Then, the return to intro- nology choice could be important in ex-
ducing the new technology in Europe plaining European inequality and un-
with unskilled workers is α − γ, and firms employment patterns is an area for
will do so as long as γ < α. Since α > γU , future study.
firms in Europe have greater incentives
8.2 International Determinants
to introduce advanced technologies with
of Technology
unskilled workers than in the United
States. This is because the binding mini- The endogenous technology frame-
mum wage in Europe makes the firm the work developed above links the skill
full residual claimant of the increase in bias of technology to the relative supply
the productivity of unskilled workers. of skills. There are a number of inter-
This highlights that in an economy with a esting and difficult issues that arise
compressed wage structure, firms may when we consider the international di-
have a greater incentive to increase the mension. Here I simply mention some
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 63

preliminary approaches, but clearly be unable to pay for these technologies


much theoretical and empirical work because of credit problems.
remains to be done. It is also worth noting that even when
A first extension of the endogenous a country is using U.S. technologies, its
technology idea to an international con- effective skill bias may be influenced by
text might be to suppose that skill bias its domestic skill supply. This is be-
in each country is determined by the cause U.S. technologies need to be
country’s relative supply of skills. Yet it adapted to local conditions, and firms
may be more plausible to imagine a will have a greater incentive to do this
situation where new technologies spread when there is a larger supply of workers
across countries. In this case, it may be to use these technologies. So it may be
the incentives in the technologically not only technological change that is
most advanced country (the technologi- endogenous to relative supplies, but
cal leader) that determine the skill bias also technology adoption.
of world technologies. This description Finally, another interesting cross-
may be adequate for understanding the country dimension comes from looking
skill bias of technologies used by less at wage inequality trends in LDCs. As
developed countries (see for example discussed in section 6.3, the first-order
Acemoglu 1999b). But it is also possible predictions of the standard trade theory
for other technologically advanced econo- are not borne out: instead of a decline
mies to pursue a different path of tech- in inequality, which would have been
nological development than the leader, expected due to the greater integration
in which case domestic incentives may of these economies into world trade,
be important in shaping skill bias. inequality increased in most LDCs. A
What determines the skill bias of recent paper by Berman and Machin
technologies developed by the techno- (2000) shows an interesting pattern:
logical leader? This depends on the while there has been rapid skill upgrad-
market sizes for different types of tech- ing in many middle income countries,
nologies, hence on the international there is much less evidence for rapid
enforcement of intellectual property skill upgrading in the poorest econo-
rights. For example, in the discussion mies. A possible explanation for these
on the effect of trade on technology, I patterns is that middle income countries
supposed that there were no intellec- are adopting advanced technologies
tual property rights for United States much more rapidly than the poorest
companies enforced in less developed countries, and since these technologies
economies. In this case, incentives to are more skill-biased, these economies
develop new technologies are shaped by are undergoing rapid skill upgrading
the United States (or OECD) supplies. and increases in inequality. Further-
This may be a good starting point, since more, if, as claimed by Acemoglu and
even when property rights are enforced, Zillibotti (2001), new technologies de-
there will be a number of difficulties veloped in the rich economies are typi-
facing U.S. companies marketing their cally “too skill-biased” for LDCs, the
technologies in other countries, espe- recent acceleration in skill bias could
cially in the case of technologies that have negative implications for the
will be used with relatively low-skill LDCs. More generally, the impact of
workers. For example, technologies may technologies developed in the advanced
need to be adapted to conditions in lo- economies on LDC labor markets is an
cal markets, or producers in LDCs may area that requires further research.
64 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

9. Conclusion ers has induced the development of


skill-complementary technologies.
This essay discussed the link between
6. The acceleration in skill-biased tech-
technical change and the labor market,
nical change is then likely to have
with special emphasis on the recent
been a response to the rapid increase
changes in the U.S. wage structure. In
in the supply of skills during the past
this process, I surveyed part of the
several decades, though this perspec-
large literature on the determinants of
tive does not suggest that we are nec-
the rise in inequality, and put forth a
essarily in the midst of a “Technologi-
different interpretation of the changes
cal Revolution”; what has changed
in technologies and their impact on the
is not necessarily the overall rate of
labor market than the most widely ac-
progress, but the types of technologies
cepted view. It is difficult to summarize
that are being developed.
this large literature, and therefore, even
7. The recent technological develop-
more difficult to summarize this es-
ments are also likely to have affected
say. Nevertheless, it may be useful to
the organization of the labor mar-
reiterate some of the main points:
ket—including the way firms organize
1. The behavior of wages and returns to production, labor market policies, and
schooling in the United States indi- the form of labor market “institu-
cates that technical change has been tions”—and may have had a large
skill-biased during the past sixty effect on the structure of wages
years, and probably for most of the through this channel.
twentieth century.
Many of these conclusions are tenta-
2. Though more controversial, the evi-
tive. There is much research to be done
dence also points to an acceleration
to understand the process of technical
in skill bias during the past few
change and how it impacts the labor
decades.
market. In particular, what determines
3. In contrast, much of what we know sug-
wage differences among observationally
gests that technical change was not skill-
similar workers, why the trajectories of
biased during the nineteenth century,
the Anglo-Saxon and continental Euro-
and most likely, it was skill-replacing.
pean economies have diverged, and how
4. We can understand the behavior of
technical change and institutional
technical change by recognizing that
change interact are important areas for
the development and use of technol-
future research.
ogy respond to profit incentives. When
developing skill-biased techniques is
Appendix
more profitable, new technology will
tend to be skill-biased. According to this A1. Data Sources
perspective, the early nineteenth cen- The samples are constructed as in Katz and
tury was characterized by skill-replacing Autor (2000). I thank David Autor for providing
me with data from this study. Data from 1939,
developments because the increased 1949, and 1959 come from 1940, 1950, and 1960
supply of unskilled workers in the censuses. The rest of the data come from 1964–97
English cities made the introduction of March CPSs. The college premium is the coeffi-
cient on workers with a college degree or more
these technologies profitable. relative to high school graduates in a log weekly
5. In contrast, the twentieth century has wage regression. The regression also includes
been characterized by skill-biased dummies for other education categories, a quartic
in experience, three region dummies, a nonwhite
technical change because the rapid dummy, a female dummy, and interactions be-
increase in the supply of skilled work- tween the female dummy and the nonwhite dummy
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 65

TABLE A1
ANNUALIZED CHANGES IN OVERALL AND RESIDUAL WAGE INEQUALITY (FROM KATZ AND AUTOR)

Census March CPSs May CPSs (ORGs)


90–10 50–10 90–10 50–10 90–10 50–10
Changes in overall inequality
1960s 0.10 0.03 –0.03 –0.11 — —
1970s 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.11 0.01 0.10
1980s 0.17 0.06 0.20 0.09 0.26 0.10
1990s — — 0.11 –0.03 0.05 0.00
Changes in residual inequality
1960s 0.03 0.01 –0.01 –0.01 — —
1970s 0.09 0.05 0.11 0.08 0.11 0.08
1980s 0.07 0.02 0.12 0.06 0.15 0.08
1990s — — 0.07 0.03 0.06 0.02

Note: The numbers give 10 × annualized changes from Table 4 of Katz and Autor (2000). 90–10 is the difference
between the 90th and 10th percent of the log wage or residual distribution, and 50–10 is the difference between the
median and 10th percent of the corresponding distribution. The residuals are estimated from log earnings regres-
sions with nine education dummies, a quartic in experience and their interactions. See notes to Tables 3 and 4 in
Katz and Autor (2000).

and the experience controls. The sample includes sources: decennial censuses, and March CPSs and
all full-time full-year workers between the ages of May CPSs (and later Outgoing Rotation Group
18 and 65, and except those with the lowest 1 per- files—ORGs). These numbers show no significant
cent earnings. Earnings for top coded observations change in residual or overall inequality during the
are calculated as the value of the top code times 1960s, and consistent increases in inequality from all
1.5. The relative supply of skills is calculated from sources during the 1970s and the 1980s. For example,
a sample that includes all workers between the the data from the Census and the March CPSs indi-
ages of 18 and 65. It is defined as the ratio of cate that the 90–10 differential increased about 0.10 a
college equivalents to non-college equivalents, cal- year between 1970 and 1979, while the 50–10 dif-
culated as in Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) ferential increased by about 0.11 a year during the
using weeks worked as weights. In particular, col- same period. The May CPS data show a smaller
lege equivalents = college graduates + 0.5 × work- increase in the 90–10 differentials during this pe-
ers with some college, and noncollege equivalents = riod, but a comparable increase in the 50–10 dif-
high school dropouts + high school graduates + 0.5 × ferential. Overall, although there is less uniformity
workers with some college. among data sources regarding the behavior of re-
Samples used for overall and residual wage in- sidual inequality than returns to schooling (see
equality include only white male full-time full year Katz and Autor 2000), there is considerable evi-
workers between the ages of 18 and 65, and ex- dence that residual and overall inequality started
clude those earning less than half the real value to increase during the 1970s.
of the 1982 minimum wage converted from nomi-
nal dollars using the personal consumption expen- A3. Can Composition Effects Explain
diture deflator (see Katz and Autor 2000). Earn- Inequality Changes?
ings for top coded observations are calculated as A possible explanation for the patterns we ob-
the value of the top code times 1.5. serve could be changes in the distribution of un-
A2. The Behavior of Overall Inequality observed skills— or more concretely, composition
effects. For example, the average ability of workers
During the 1970s
with high education may have increased relative to
In an important paper on the effect of labor that of workers with low education over time.
market institutions on inequality, DiNardo, Here, I document that the increase in the returns
Fortin, and Lemieux (1995) provide evidence sug- to education and residual inequality are not smply
gesting that in the May CPSs, there is no increase due to composition effects. Note first that compo-
in inequality during the 1970s. In table A1, I dis- sition effects cannot by themselves explain the re-
play numbers from the survey by Katz and Autor cent changes in inequality: as noted in subsection
(2000), who report changes in residual inequality 7.2, composition effects suggest that inequality
for the past four decades from three different among educated and uneducated workers should
66 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

TABLE A2
COMPOSITION EFFECTS

Born in 19– 06–10 11–15 16–20 21–25 26–30 31–35 36–40 41–45 46–50 51–55
Year ↓ →
Panel A
1950 1.448 1.370 1.175 1.093
1960 1.551 1.564 1.525 1.421 1.303 1.132
1970 1.680 1.656 1.613 1.539 1.392 1.153
1980 1.567 1.560 1.538 1.402 1.222 1.063
1990 1.798 1.761 1.723 1.674
Panel B
∆ ln ω 50−60 0.103 0.194 0.350 0.328
∆ ln ω 60−70 0.155 0.234 0.311 0.407
∆ ln ω 70−80 –0.047 0.021 0.146 0.249
∆ ln ω 80−90 0.260 0.359 0.500 0.611
Panel C
∆ 2 ln ω50−70 0.051 0.040 –0.040 0.079
∆ 2 ln ω60−80 –0.201 –0.213 –0.165 –0.158
∆ 2 ln ω70−90 0.307 0.338 0.354 0.362

Note: The top panel gives the college premium from the census indicated at the beginning of the row for cohorts
born in the five-year intervals indicated at the head of the column. For example, the first number is for individuals
born between 1906–10 from the census of 1950. The college premium is defined as the wages of workers from that
cohort with a college degree or more divided by the wages of workers from that cohort with twelve years of
schooling. The bottom panel gives the change in the college premium for a given cohort between the two indicated
dates and the difference between the wage growth of two neighboring cohorts as indicated by equations (34) and
(35). All data are from the decennial censuses for white males born in the United States.

move in opposite directions. This suggests that Consider changes in cohort quality first. If, as
changes in the true returns to skills have played at many claim, the U.S. high school system has be-
least some role in the changes in inequality. come worse, we might expect a decline in A 0t with-
More generally, to get a sense of how important out a corresponding decline in A 1t. As a result,
composition effects may be, consider a variant of A 1t − A 0t may increase. Alternatively, as a larger
equation (13) above with two education levels, high fraction of the U.S. population obtains higher edu-
h = 1 and low h = 0, and suppose wages are given by cation, it is natural that selection into education
(i.e., the abilities of those obtaining education)
ln w it = a i + γth i + εit (31) will change. It is in fact possible that those who
are left without education could have very low un-
where h i is a dummy for high education, ai is un- observed ability, which would translate into a low level
observed ability, and εit is a mean zero disturbance of A 0t, and therefore into an increase in A 1t − A 0t.
term. Define the (log) education premium—the Although these scenarios are plausible, theoret-
difference between the average wages of high and ically the opposite can happen as well. For exam-
low education workers—can be written as ple, many academics who have been involved in
the U.S. education system for a long time com-
ln ω t ≡ E(ln w it | h i = 1) − E(ln w it | h i = 0)
plain about the decline in the quality of universi-
= γt + A 1t − A 0t ties, while the view that American high schools
where A 1t ≡ E(ai | h i = 1) and A 0t is defined simi- have become much worse is not shared universally
larly. The increase in the education premium can (e.g., Krueger 1998). The selection argument is
be caused by an increase in γt (a true increase in also more complicated than it first appears. It is
the returns to skills) or an increase in A 1t − A 0t. true that, as long as those with high unobserved
There are basically two reasons for an increase in abilities are more likely to obtain higher educa-
A 1t − A 0t: (1) changes in cohort quality, or (2) tion, an increase in education will depress A 0t. But
changes in the pattern of selection into education. it will also depress A 1t. To see why, assume that
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 67
there is perfect sorting—i.e., if an individual with
ability a obtains education, all individuals with TABLE A3
ability a′ > a will do so as well. In this case, there CHANGES IN INEQUALITY BY COHORT
will exist a threshold level of ability, a−, such that (FROM JUHN ET AL. 1993)
only those with a > a− obtain education. Next con-
sider a uniform distribution of ai between b0 and
b0 + b1 . Then,
Panel A: 90–10 Differentials for Log Weekly Wages

1 a− a− + b0 Year of
A0 = −
a − b0
∫b0 ada = 2 market entry 1964 1970 1976 1982 1988
and 1983–88 1.38
1 b0 + b1 b0 + b1 + a− 1977–82 1.27 1.38
A1 = ∫
b1 − b0 − a− a−
ada =
2
. 1971–76 1.13 1.24 1.38
1965–70 1.08 1.12 1.29 1.42
So both A 0 and A 1 will decline when a− decreases to 1959–64 1.13 1.01 1.13 1.30 1.40
a− ′. Moreover, A 1 − A 0 = b1 ⁄ 2, so it is unaffected by 1953–58 1.02 1.07 1.16 1.32 1.43
the decline in a−. Intuitively, with a uniform distri- 1947–52 1.02 1.11 1.15 1.30
bution of ai, when a− increases, both A 0 and A 1 fall 1941–46 1.02 1.07 1.16
by exactly the same amount, so the composition
effects have no influence on the education pre- 1935–40 1.06 1.09
mium. Clearly, with other distributions of ability, 1929–34 1.09
this extreme result will no longer hold, but it re- Panel B: 90–10 Differentials for Log Wage Residuals
mains true that both A 0 and A 1 will fall, and
whether this effect will increase or decrease the Year of
education premium is unclear. Overall, therefore, market entry 1964 1970 1976 1982 1988
the effects of changes in composition on education
premia is an empirical question. 1983–88 1.09
Empirically, the importance of composition ef- 1977–82 1.06 1.16
fects can be uncovered by looking at inequality 1971–76 .96 1.09 1.18
changes by cohort (see McKinley Blackburn, 1965–70 .86 .96 1.12 1.23
David Bloom, and Freeman 1992; Juhn, Murphy, 1959–64 .92 .86 .98 1.12 1.21
and Pierce 1993). To see this, rewrite equation
1953–58 .88 .91 .99 1.15 1.26
(31) as
1947–52 .89 .94 .99 1.14
ln w ict = a ic + γth ic + εcit (32) 1941–46 .94 .94 1.05
1935–40 .95 .98
where c denotes a cohort—i.e., a group of indi-
viduals who are born in the same year. I have im- 1929–34 .99
posed an important assumption in writing equa-
tion (32): returns to skills are assumed to be the Note: This table replicates Table 3 of Juhn, Murphy,
same for all cohorts and ages; γt—though clearly and Pierce (1993). The top panel reports the 90–10
they vary over time. We can now define cohort differential for log weekly wages of the cohorts that
specific education premia as
have entered the labor market in the corresponding
ln ω ct ≡ E(ln w ict | h i = 1) − E(ln w ict | h i = 0) six-year interval. Panel B gives the 90–10 differential
= γt + A 1ct − A 0ct for the residuals from a regression of log weekly wages
on education controls.
where A 1ct ≡ E(aic | h i = 1) and A 0ct is defined simi-
larly. Under the additional assumption that there
is no further schooling for any of the cohorts year t, and that γst = γs + γt (this assumption is
over the periods under study, we have also not necessary, but simplifies the discussion).
ln ω ct = γt + A 1c − A 0c, which implies Then ∆ ln ω c,t′ − t = γs′ − γs + γt′ − γt, where obviously
s′ − s = t′ − t. Now consider a different cohort, c′′
∆ ln ω c,t′ − t ≡ ln ω ct′ − ln ω ct = γt′ − γt, (33) that is age s′ in the year t and age s in the year t′′.
Then ∆ ln ω c′′,t − t′′ = γs′ − γs + γt − γt′′. So, the true
i.e., changes in the returns to education within a change in the returns to skills between the dates t′′
cohort will reveal the true change in the returns. and t′ is
Yet, the assumption that returns to skills are con-
stant over the lifetime of an individual may be too ∆ 2 ln ω ≡ ∆ ln ω c,t′ − t − ∆ ln ω c′′,t − t′′ = γt′ − γt′′. (34)
restrictive. Murphy and Welch (1992), for exam-
ple, show quite different age-earning profiles by Using data from the 1950–90 censuses, table A2
education. Nevertheless, a similar argument can gives some of the single and double differences of
be applied in this case too. For example, sup- cohort inequality for white men aged 26–55. The
pose ln ω cst = γst + A 1c − A 0c for cohort c of age s in single differences show increases in the returns to
68 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
college within most cohorts, with the exception of tion and Inequality,” MIT mimeo, forthcoming
the years between 1970 and 1980. Therefore, Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Pol.
these increases are likely to reflect differential age Acemoglu, Daron and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1999.
effects by education. In contrast, the numbers in “The Structure of Wages and Investment in
panel C for the 1950–70 period show no increases, General Training,” J. Polit. Econ. 107:3, pp.
suggesting that the double difference does a good 539–72.
job of controlling for composition effects. The Acemoglu, Daron and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2001.
numbers for the 1960–80 period are negative, “Productivity Differences,” Quart. J. Econ.
which likely reflect the decline in the college pre- 116:2, pp. 563–606.
mium between 1960 and 1980. The final row gives Aghion, Philippe. 2000. “Technical Change, Insti-
the most important results of this table. The 1970– tutions, and the Dynamics of Inequality,” Har-
90 double differences are large and positive, sug- vard mimeo; forthcoming Econometrica.
gesting that the true returns to education in- Aghion, Philippe and Peter Howitt. 1998. Endoge-
creased over this time period. Interestingly, nous Growth Theory. MA: MIT Press.
despite the well-known evidence that the college Aghion, Philippe; Peter Howitt and Gianluca Vio-
premium increased faster for younger workers lante. 2000. “Technology, Knowledge, and In-
over the 1980s, the results in table A2 show that equality,” mimeo, Harvard U.
the true increase in returns to skills between 1970 Ahmad, Syed. 1966. “On the Theory of Induced
and 1990 are comparable for cohorts born be- Invention,” Econ. J. 56, pp. 344–57.
tween 1936 and 1955. These results therefore in- Angrist, Joshua. 1995. “The Economic Returns to
dicate that the major component of the increase in Schooling in the West Bank and Gaza Strip,”
that college premium during the 1980s and 1990s Amer. Econ. Rev. 85:5, pp. 1065–87.
was changes in true skill prices, not composition Appelbaum, Eileen and Rosemary Batt. 1994. The
effects. New American Workplace. NY: ILR Press.
Table A3, which replicates table 3 from Juhn, Autor, David; Alan Krueger and Lawrence Katz.
Murphy, and Pierce (1993), shows that the in- 1998. “Computing Inequality: Have Computers
crease in overall and residual inequality cannot be Changed the Labor Market?” Quart. J. Econ.
explained by composition effects either. Panel A 113:4, pp. 1169–213.
shows that the 90–10 differential for cohorts en- Autor, David; Frank Levy and Richard Murnane.
tering the market between 1935 and 1964 is ap- 2001. “The Skill Content of Recent Technologi-
proximately constant between 1964 and 1970, but cal Change: An Empirical Exploration,” MIT
increases sharply for each cohort between 1970 mimeo.
and 1976, and then increases further between Bailey, Martin and Robert Gordon. 1988. “The
1982 and 1988. Panel B shows a similar picture for Productivity Slowdown: Measurement Issues
log wage residuals. These results suggest that the and Explosion of Computer Power,” Brookings
changes in the structure of wages observed over Pap. Econ. Act., Macroecon. 2, pp. 379–431.
the past thirty years cannot be explained by pure Bairoch, Paul. 1988. Cities and Economic Develop-
composition effects, and reflect mainly changes ment: From the Dawn of History to the Present.
in the true returns to observed and unobserved Christopher Braider, trans. Chicago: U. Chi-
skills. cago Press.
Bartel, Ann P. and Frank Lichtenberg. 1987. “The
REFERENCES Comparative Advantage of Educated Workers
in Implementing New Technology,” Rev. Econ.
Abramovitz, Moses. 1956. “Resource and Output Statist. 69:1, pp. 1–11.
Trends in the United States since 1870,” Amer. Bartel, Ann and Nachum Sicherman. 1998. “Tech-
Econ. Rev. 46, pp. 5–23. nological Change and the Skill Acquisition of
Acemoglu, Daron. 1996. “A Microfoundation for Young Workers,” J. Labor Econ. 16:4, pp. 718–55.
Social Increasing Returns in Human Capital Ac- Beaudry, Paul and David Green. 1999. “What Is
cumulation,” Quart. J. Econ. 111:3, pp. 779– Driving U.S. and Canadian Wages: Exogenous
804. Technical Change or Endogenous Choice of
——— . 1998. “Why Do New Technologies Com- Technique?” NBER work. paper 6853.
plement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Berman, Eli; John Bound and Zvi Griliches. 1994.
Wage Inequality,” Quart. J. Econ. 113:4, pp. “Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor
1055–89. within U.S. Manufacturing Industries: Evidence
——— . 1999a. “Changes in Unemployment and from the Annual Survey of Manufactures,”
Wage Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Quart. J. Econ. 109, pp. 365–67.
Some Evidence,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 89:5, pp. Berman, Eli; John Bound and Stephen Machin.
1259–78. 1998. “Implications of Skill-Biased Technologi-
——— . 1999b. “Patterns of Skill Premia,” NBER cal Change: International Evidence,” Quart. J.
work. paper 7018. Econ. 113, pp. 1245–80.
——— . 2000 “Labor- and Capital-Augmenting Berman, Eli and Stephen Machin. 2000. “SBTC
Technical Change,” NBER work. paper 7544. Happens! Evidence on the Factor Bias of Tech-
Acemoglu, Daron; Phillipe Aghion and Gianluca nological Change in Developing and Developed
Violante. 2001. “Technical Change, Deunioniza- Countries,” Boston U. mimeo.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 69
Blackburn, McKinley; David Bloom and Richard ture of Wages and Employment: A Comparison
Freeman. 1992. “Changes in Earnings Differen- of the United States, Canada and France,” Can.
tials in the 1980s: Concordance, Convergence, J. Econ.
Causes, and Consequences,” NBER work. pa- Caroli, Eve and John van Reenen. 1999. “Wage
per 3901. Inequality and Organizational Change,” UCL
Blau, Francine D. and Lawrence M. Kahn. 1996. mimeo.
“International Differences in Male Wage In- Caselli, Francesco. 1999. “Technological Revolu-
equality: Institutions versus Market Forces,” J. tions,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 89:1, pp. 78–102.
Polit. Econ. 104:4, pp. 791–836. Cohen, Sarit and Chang-Tai Hsieh. 2000. “Macro-
Borghans, Lex and Bas Ter Weel. 2000. “Do We economic and Labor Market Impact of Russian
Need Computer Skills to Use a Computer: Evi- Immigration in Israel,” Princeton U. mimeo.
dence from the United Kingdom,” Maastricht David, Paul. 1975. Technical Choice, Innovation
mimeo. and Economic Growth: Essays on American and
Borjas, George J.; Richard B. Freeman and British Experience in the Nineteenth Century.
Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. “How Much Do Immi- London: Cambridge U. Press.
gration and Trade Affect Labor Market Out- David, Paul. 1990. “The Dynamo and the Com-
comes?” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 0:1, pp. 1– puter: An Historical Perspective on the Modern
67. Productivity Paradox,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 80:2,
Borjas, George J. and Valerie Ramey. 1995. “For- pp. 355–61.
eign Competition, Market Power and Wage In- Davis, Steven J. 1992. “Cross-Country Patterns of
equality,” Quart. J. Econ. 110:4, pp. 1075–110. Changes in Relative Wages,” in NBER Macro-
Boskin Michael; Ellen Dulberger, Robert Gordon, economics Annual 1992. Olivier Jean Blanchard
Zvi Griliches and Dale Jorgenson. 1998. “Con- and Stanley Fischer, eds. Cambridge and Lon-
sumer Prices, the Consumer Price Index, and don: MIT Press, pp. 239–92.
the Cost of Living,” J. Econ. Perspect. 12:1, pp. Davis, Steven J.; John Haltiwanger and Scott
3–26. Schuh. 1996. Job Creation and Destruction.
Bound, John and George Johnson. 1992. “Changes MA: MIT Press.
in the Structure of Wages in the 1980s: An Devroye, Dan and Richard Freeman. 2000. “Does
Evaluation of Alternative Explanations,” Amer. Inequality in Skills Explain Inequality of Earn-
Econ. Rev. 82:3, pp. 371–92. ings across Countries?” Harvard U. mimeo.
Bowles, Samuel; Herbert Gintis and Melissa Os- Diebold, Francis; David Neumark and Daniel
borne. 2001. “The Determinants of Earnings: A Polsky. 1997. “Job Stability in the United
Behavioral Approach,” J. Econ. Lit. 39:4, pp. States,” J. Labor Econ. 15:2, pp. 206–33.
1137–76. DiNardo, John; Nicole Fortin and Thomas
Braverman, Harry. 1974. Labor and Monopoly Lemieux. 1995. “Labor Market Institutions and
Capital: The Degradation of Work in the Twen- the Distribution of Wages, 1973–1992: A Semi-
tieth Century. NY: Monthly Review Press. parametric Approach,” Econometrica 64:5, pp.
Brendt, Ernie; Catherine Morrison and Larry 1001–44.
Rosenblum. 1994. “High-tech Capital Forma- DiNardo, John; Kevin Hallock and Jorn-Steffen
tion and Labor Composition in U.S. Manufac- Pischke. 2000. “Unions and Managerial Pay,”
turing Industries: An Exploratory Analysis,” J. London School Econ. mimeo.
Econometrics 65, pp. 9–43. DiNardo, John and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1997.
Bresnahan, Timothy F. 1999. “Computerization “The Returns to Computer Use Revisited: Have
and Wage Dispersion: An Analytical Reinter- Pencils Changed the Wage Structure Too?”
pretation,” Stanford U. mimeo. Quart. J. Econ. 112:1, pp. 291–303.
Bresnahan, Timothy F.; Erik Brynjolfsson and Doms, Mark; Timothy Dunne and Kenneth
Lorin M. Hitt. 1999. “Information Technology, Torske. 1997. “Workers, Wages and Technol-
Workplace Organization and the Demand for ogy,” Quart. J. Econ. 112, pp. 217–52.
Skilled Labor: Firm-level Evidence,” NBER Duranton, Gilles. 2001. “The Economics of Pro-
work. paper 7136. duction Systems: Segmentation and Skill-Biased
Cappelli, Peter and Steffanie Wilk. 1997. “Under- Change,” mimeo, London School of Economics.
standing Selection Processes: Organization De- Entorf, Horst and Francis Kramartz. 1998. “Does
terminants and Performance Outcomes,” Unmeasured Ability Explain the Higher Wages
mimeo, Wharton School, U. Pennsylvania. of New Technology Workers?” Europ. Econ.
Card, David E. and Alan Krueger. 2000. “School Rev. 41, pp. 1489–509.
Quality and Black–White Relative Earnings: A Farber, Henry. 1995. “Are Lifetime Jobs Disap-
Direct Assessment,” Quart. J. Econ. 107, pp. pearing? Job Duration in the United States,”
151–200. NBER work. paper 5014.
Card, David and Thomas Lemieux. 2001. “Can Farber, Henry and Bruce Western. 2000. “Round
Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to Up the Usual Suspects: The Decline of Unions
College for Younger Men?” Quart. J. Econ. in the Private Sector,” Princeton U. Ind. Rel.
116:2, pp. 705–46. work. paper 437.
Card, David; Francis Kramartz and Thomas Feenstra, Robert and Gordon Hanson. 1999. “The
Lemieux. 1996. “Changes in the Relative Struc- Impact of Outsourcing and High-Technology
70 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
Capital on Wages: Estimates for the United States, Gordon, Robert. 1990. Measurement of Durable
1979–1990,” Quart. J. Econ. 114:3, pp. 907–40. Goods Prices. IL: U. Chicago Press.
Foster, Andrew and Mark Rosenzweig. 1996. ——— . 1998. “Current Productivity Puzzles from
“Technical Change in Human Capital Return a Long-term Perspective,” Northwestern U.
and Investments: Evidence from the Green mimeo.
Revolution,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 86, pp. 931–53. Gosling, Amanda. 1998. “The Determination of
Frank, Robert H. and Phillip J. Cook. 1995. The Union Status and Wages in British Estab-
Winner-Take-All Society. NY: Free Press. lishments,” U. Essex, discuss. paper 491.
Freeman, Richard. 1976. The Overeducated Gottschalk, Peter. 1997. “Inequality in Income,
American. NY: Academic Press. Growth and Mobility: The Basic Facts,” J. Econ.
——— . 1986. “Demand for Education,” in Hand- Perspect. 11, pp. 21–40.
book of Labor Economics, Vol. I. Orley Ashen- Gottschalk, Peter and Robert Moffitt. 1994. “The
felter and Richard Layard, eds. North-Holland: Growth of Earnings Instability in the U.S.
Elsevier. Labor Market,” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 2,
——— . 1991. “How Much Has De-unionization pp. 217–72.
Contributed to the Rise of Male Earnings In- Gottschalk, Peter and Timothy M. Smeeding.
equality?” NBER working paper 3826. 1997. “Cross-National Comparisons of Earnings
Freeman, Richard and Lawrence F. Katz. 1995. and Income Inequality,” J. Econ. Lit. 35:2, pp.
“Introduction and Summary,” in Differences 633–87.
and Changes in Wage Structures. R. Freeman Gould, Eric D.; Omer Moav and Bruce A. Wein-
and L. Katz, eds. Chicago: U. Chicago Press. berg. 2000. “Precautionary Demand for Educa-
Freeman, Richard and Edward Lazear. 1995. “An tion, Inequality, and Technological Progress,”
Economic Analysis of Works Councils,” in mimeo, MIT.
Works Councils: Consultation, Representation, Green, Constance M. 1956. Eli Whitney and the
and Cooperation in Industrial Relations. Joel Birth of American Technology. MA: Little,
Rogers and Wolfgang Streeck, eds. NBER Brown.
Compar. Labor Markets Series, Chicago: U. Greenwood, Jeremy; Zvi Hercowtiz and Per
Chicago Press. Krusell. 1997. “Long-Run Implications of
Freeman, Richard and James Medoff. 1984. What Investment-Specific Techological Change,”
Unions Do. NY: Basic Books. Amer. Econ. Rev. 87:3, pp. 342–62.
Freeman, Richard and Karen Needles. 1993. “Skill Greenwood, Jeremy and Mehmet Yorukoglu.
Differences in Canada in an Era of Rising La- 1997. “1974,” Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser.
bor Market Inequality,” in Small Differences Public Pol. 46, pp. 49–95.
That Matter. D. Card and R. Freeman, eds. Griliches, Zvi. 1957. “Hybrid Corn: An Explora-
Chicago: U. Chicago Press and NBER. tion in the Economics of Technological
Friedberg, Rachel. 1997. “The Impact of Mass Mi- Change,” Econometrica 25, pp. 501–22.
gration on the Israeli Labor Market,” RI: Brown ——— . 1969. “Capital-Skill Complementarity,”
U. Population Studies and Training Center Rev. Econ. Statist. 51, pp. 465–68.
work. paper 97–11. Grossman, Gene and Elhanan Helpman. 1991. In-
Galor, Oded and Daniel Tsiddon. 1998. “Techno- novation and Growth in the Global Economy.
logical Progress, Mobility and Economic MA: MIT Press.
Growth,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 87, pp. 363–82. Grout, Paul. 1984. “Investment and Wages in the
Galor, Oded and Omer Maov. 2000. “Ability Bi- Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargain-
ased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality ing Approach,” Econometrica 52, pp. 449–60.
and Economic Growth,” Quart. J. Econ. 115, Habakkuk, H. J. 1962. American and British Tech-
pp. 469–98. nology in the Nineteenth Century. London:
Gandal, Neil; Gordon H. Hanson and Matthew J. Cambridge U. Press.
Slaughter. 2000. “Technology, Trade, and Ad- Hanson, Gordon H. and Ann Harrison. 1995.
justment to Immigration in Israel,” mimeo, “Trade Technology, and Wage Inequality: Evi-
Dartmouth College. dence from Mexico,” NBER work. paper 5110.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence F. Katz. 1995. “The Hayami, Yujiro and Vernon Ruttan. 1970. “Factor
Decline of Non-Competing Groups: Changes in Prices and Technical Change in Agricultural
the Premium to Education, 1890 to 1940,” Development: the U.S. and Japan, 1880–1960,”
NBER work. paper 5202. J. Polit. Econ. 77, pp. 1115–41.
——— . 1998. “The Origins of Technology–Skill Hornstein, Andres and Per Krusel. 1996. “Can
Complementarity,” Quart. J. Econ. 113:3, pp. Technology Improvements Cause Productivity
693–732. Slowdowns?” NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
——— . 2000. “Education and Income in the Early pp. 209–59.
20th-century: Evidence from the Prairies,” Ichniowski, Casey; Kathryn Shaw and Giovanna
forthcoming, J. Econ. Hist. Prennushi. 1997. “The Effects of Human Re-
Goldin, Claudia and Robert A. Margo. 1992. “The source Management Practices on Productivity:
Great Compression: The Wage Structure in the A Study of Steel Finishing Lines,” Amer. Econ.
United States at Mid-Century,” Quart. J. Econ. Rev. 87:3, pp. 291–313.
107:1, pp. 1–34. James, John A. and Jonathan S. Skinner. 1985.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 71
“The Resolution of the Labor-Scarcity Para- mentary and Inequality,” U. Rochester mimeo;
dox,” J. Econ. Hist. 45, pp. 513–50. forthcoming Econometrica.
Jerome, Harry. 1934. Mechanization in History. Lawrence, Robert and Matthew Slaughter. 1993.
NY: NBER. “Trade and U.S. Wages: Giant Sucking Sound
Johnson, George. 1997. “Changes in Earnings In- or Small Hiccup?” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 2,
equality: The Role of Demand Shifts,” J. Econ. pp. 161–226.
Perspect. 11, pp. 41–54. Leamer, Edward E. 1995. “Trade, Wages and
Jorgensen, Dale W. and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2000. Revolving-Door Ideas,” NBER work. paper
“Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic 4716.
Growth in the Information Age,” Brookings Lee, David S. 1999. “Wage Inequality in the U.S.
Pap. Econ. Act. 1, pp. 125–236. During the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling
Juhn, Chinhui; Kevin M. Murphy and Brooks Minimum Wage?” Quart. J. Econ. 114, pp. 941–
Pierce. 1993. “Wage Inequality and the Rise in 1024.
Returns to Skill,” J. Polit. Econ. 101, pp. 410– Lloyd-Ellis, Huw. 1999. “Endogenous Technologi-
42. cal Change and Wage Inequality,” Amer. Econ.
Katz, Lawrence and David Autor. 2000. “Changes Rev. 89:1, pp. 47–77.
in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequal- Machin, Stephen and John Van Reenen. 1998.
ity,” in Handbook of Labor Economics vol. III. “Technology and Changes in Skill Structure:
Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds. Amster- Evidence from Seven OECD Countries,”
dam: Elsevier. Quart. J. Econ. 113:4, pp. 1215–44.
Katz, Lawrence and Kevin Murphy. 1992. Marglin, Stephen A. 1974. “What Do Bosses Do?
“Changes in Relative Wages: Supply and De- The Origins and Functions of Hierarchy in
mand Factors,” Quart. J. Econ. 107, pp. 35–78. Capitalist Production,” Rev. Radical Polit. Econ.
Katz, Lawrence; Gary W. Loveman and David G. 3, pp. 33–60.
Blanchflower. “A Comparison of Changes in the Mishel, Lawrence and Jared Bernstein. 1994. “Is
Structure of Wages in Four OECD Countries” the Technology Black Box Empty? An Empiri-
in Differences and Changes in Wage Structures. cal Examination of the Impact of Technology on
R. Freeman and L. Katz, eds. IL: U. Chicago Wage Inequality and the Employment Struc-
Press. ture,” mimeo, Econ. Policy Institute.
Kendrick, John W. 1961. Productivity Trends in ——— . 1998. “Technology and the Wage Struc-
the United States. NJ: Princeton U. Press. ture: Has Technology’s Impact Accelerated
Kennedy, Charles. 1964. “Induced Bias in Innova- since the 1970s?” Res. Lab. Econ. 17, pp. 305–
tion and the Theory of Distribution,” Econ. J. 55.
74, pp. 541–47. Mishel, Lawrence; Jared Bernstein and John
Kiley, Michael. 1999. “The Supply of Skilled La- Schmitt. 1998. “Wage Inequality in the 1990s:
bor and Skill-Biased Technological Progress,” Measurement and Trends,” mimeo, Econ. Pol-
Econ. J. 109, pp. 708–24. icy Institute.
Kremer, Michael and Eric Maskin. 1999. “Segre- Mobius, Marcus. 2000. “The Evolution of Work,”
gation by Skill and the Rise in Inequality,” Har- mimeo, MIT.
vard mimeo. Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Levers of Riches: Techno-
Krueger, Alan. 1993. “How Computers Have logical Creativity and Economic Progress. NY:
Changed the Wage Structure: Evidence from Oxford U. Press.
Microdata, 1984–1989,” Quart. J. Econ. 110, ——— , ed. 1993. The British Industrial Revolu-
pp. 33–60. tion: An Economic Perspective. CA: Westview
——— . 1997. “Labor Market Shifts and the Price Press.
Puzzle Revisited,” Princeton U. Ind. Rel. work. Murnane, Richard J. and Frank Levy. 1996.
paper 375. Teaching the Basic New Skills. NY: Free Press.
——— . 1998. “Reassessing the View That Amer. Murphy, Kevin M.; W. Craig Riddell and Paul M.
Schools Are Broken,” Princeton U. Ind. Rel. Romer. 1998. “Wages, Skills and Technology in
work. paper 395. the United States and Canada,” in General Pur-
——— . 1999. “Measuring Labor’s Share,” Amer. pose Technologies. E. Helpman, ed. MA: MIT
Econ. Rev. 89, pp. 45–51. Press.
Krueger, Alan B. and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1997. Murphy, Kevin M. and Finis Welch. 1992. “The
“Observations and Conjectures on the U.S. Em- Structure of Wages,” Quart. J. Econ. 107, pp.
ployment Miracle,” NBER work. paper 6146. 255–85.
Krugman, Paul. 1994. “Part and Prospective ——— . 1993. “Industrial Change and the Rising
Causes of High Unemployment,” in Reducing Importance of Skill,” in Uneven Tides. S.
Unemployment: Current Issues and Policy Op- Danziger and P. Gottschalk, eds. NY: Russell
tions. MO: Fed. Reserve Bank Kansas City. Sage.
——— . 1995. “Growing World Trade: Causes and ——— . 2000. “Wage Differentials in the 1990s: Is
Consequences,” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 1, the Glass Half Full or Half Empty?” unpub. pa-
pp. 327–77. per.
Krusell, Per; Lee Ohanian, Victor Rios-Rull and Nelson, Richard and Edmund Phelps. 1966. “In-
Giovanni Violante. 2000. “Capital Skill Comple- vestment in Humans, Technological Diffusion
72 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
and Economic Growth,” AEA Papers Proceed- Sachs, Jeffrey and Howard Shatz. 1994. “Trade
ings 56, pp. 69–75. and Jobs in U.S. Manufacturing,” Brookings
Newell, Richard; Adam Jaffee and Robert Stavins. Pap. Econ. Act. 0:1, pp. 1–69.
1999. “The Induce Innovation Hypothesis and Samuelson, Paul. 1965. “A Theory of Induced In-
Energy-Saving Technological Change,” Quart. novations Along Kennedy-Weisacker Lines,”
J. Econ. 114, pp. 907–40. Rev. Econ. Statist. 47, pp. 444–64.
Nickell, Stephen and Brian Bell. 1996. “The Col- Scherer, Michael. 1984. Innovation and Growth.
lapse in Demand for the Unskilled and Unem- MA: MIT Press.
ployment across the OECD,” Oxford Rev. Econ. Schiff, Ze’ev and Ehud Ya’ari. 1989. Intifada, The
Pol. 11, pp. 40–62. Palestinian Uprising—Israel’s Third Front. NY:
Neumark, David; Daniel Polsky and Daniel Han- Simon and Schuster.
sen. 1999. “Has Job Stability Declined Yet? Evi- Schmookler, Jacob. 1966. Invention and Economic
dence for the 1990s,” J. Lab. Econ. 17:4, S29– Growth. MA: Harvard U. Press.
64. Schultz, Theodore. 1975. “The Value of the Ability
Nye, David E. 1990. Electrifying America: Social to Deal with Disequalibria,” J. Econ. Lit. 13,
Meanings of a New Technology, 1880–1940. pp. 827–46.
MA: MIT Press. Thesmar, David and Mathias Thoenig. 2000. “Crea-
OECD. 1994. Jobs Study. Vols. 1 and 2. Paris and tive Destruction and Firm Organization Choice:
Washington, DC: OECD. A New Look into the Growth–Inequality Rela-
Oliner, Stephen and Daniel Sichel. 1994. “Com- tionship,” Quart. J. Econ. 115:4, pp. 1209–38.
puters and Output Growth Revisited: How Big Tinbergen, Jan. 1975. Income Difference: Recent
Is the Puzzle?” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 0:2, Research. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
pp. 273–317. Violante, Giovanni L. 2000. “Technological Accel-
Pierce, Brooks. 2001. “Compensation Inequality,” eration, Skill Transferability and the Rise in Re-
forthcoming, Quart. J. Econ. sidual Inequality,” University College London
Piketty, Thomas and Emannuel Saez. 2001. “In- mimeo.
come Inequality in the United States, 1913– Welch, Finis. 1970. “Education in Production,” J.
1998,” MIT and Harvard mimeo. Polit. Econ. 78, pp. 312–27.
Piore, Michael and Charles Sabel. 1984. The Sec- ——— . 1973. “Black–White Differences in Re-
ond Industrial Divide. NY: Basic Books. turns to Schooling,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 63:5, pp.
Reynolds, Lloyd G. 1951. The Structure of Labor 893–907.
Markets; Wages and Labor Mobility in Theory Williamson, Jeffrey. 1990. Coping with City
and Practice. NY: Harper. Growth During the British Industrial Revolu-
Riddell, Craig. 1993. “Unionization in Canada and tion. MA: Cambridge U. Press.
the United States: A Tale of Two Countries,” in Williamson, Jeffrey G. and Peter H. Lindert. 1980.
Small Differences That Matter. David Card American Inequality: A Macroeconomic His-
and Richard Freeman, eds. IL: U. Chicago tory. NY: Academic Press.
Press. Willis, Robert and Sherwin Rosen. 1975. “Educa-
Robbins, Donald J. 1995. “Trade and Inequality in tion and Self-Selection,” J. Polit. Econ. 87, pp.
Seven Developing Countries: Summary and 817–36.
Synthesis of Country Studies,” Harvard, HIID Wood, Adrian. 1994. North–South Trade, Employ-
mimeo. ment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Skill Driven World. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Far? Washington DC: Institute Int. Econ. Woolf, Arthur G. 1984. “Electricity, Productivity,
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological and Labor Saving: American Manufacturing
Change,” J. Polit. Econ. 98:5, S71–S102. 1900–1929,” Explor. Econ. Hist. 21:2, pp. 176–
Rubinstein, Yonna and Dani Tsiddon. 1999. “Cop- 91.
ing with Technological Progress: The Role of Zuboff, Shohana. 1988. In the Age of the Smart
Ability in Making Inequality So Persistent,” Tel Machine: The Future of Work and Power. NY:
Aviv U. work. paper. Basic Books.
This article has been cited by:

1. Chunbing Xing, Shi Li. 2012. Residual wage inequality in urban China, 1995–2007. China
Economic Review 23:2, 205-222. [CrossRef]
2. Ashish Arora, Lee G. Branstetter, Matej Drev. 2012. Going Soft: How the Rise of Software Based
Innovation led to the Decline of Japan's IT Industry and the Resurgence of Silicon Valley. Review
of Economics and Statistics 120515125242009. [CrossRef]
3. Steven Lugauer. 2012. The supply of skills in the labor force and aggregate output volatility.
Research in Economics . [CrossRef]
4. Xin Meng, Kailing Shen, Sen Xue. 2012. Economic Reform, Education Expansion, and Earnings
Inequality for Urban Males in China, 1988-2009. Journal of Comparative Economics . [CrossRef]
5. Rainer Klump, Peter McAdam, Alpo Willman. 2012. THE NORMALIZED CES PRODUCTION
FUNCTION: THEORY AND EMPIRICS. Journal of Economic Surveys no-no. [CrossRef]
6. Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx. 2012. Are Occupations Paid What They are Worth? An
Econometric Study of Occupational Wage Inequality and Productivity. De Economist . [CrossRef]
7. Giuseppe Croce, Emanuela Ghignoni. 2012. Demand and Supply of Skilled Labour and
Overeducation in Europe: A Country-level Analysis. Comparative Economic Studies . [CrossRef]
8. Fabián Slonimczyk, Peter Skott. 2012. Employment and distribution effects of the minimum wage.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization . [CrossRef]
9. Po-Chi Chen, Ming-Miin Yu. 2012. Total factor productivity growth and directions of technical
change bias: evidence from 99 OECD and non-OECD countries. Annals of Operations Research
. [CrossRef]
10. Priya Brata Dutta. 2012. Skilled–unskilled wage inequality, product variety and unemployment: A
static general equilibrium analysis. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development
1-25. [CrossRef]
11. PEDRO E. MONCARZ. 2012. TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND WAGE PREMIUM IN
ARGENTINA: THE ROLE OF TRADE FACTOR INTENSITY. The Developing Economies
50:1, 40-67. [CrossRef]
12. André Varella Mollick. 2012. Income inequality in the U.S.: The Kuznets hypothesis revisited.
Economic Systems 36:1, 127-144. [CrossRef]
13. Scott Albrecht, Roberto Patricio KorzeniewiczGlobalization and Inequality . [CrossRef]
14. Peter McAdam, Alpo Willman. 2012. MEDIUM RUN REDUX. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1-33.
[CrossRef]
15. Oliver Farhauer, Alexandra Kröll. 2012. Diversified specialisation—going one step beyond
regional economics’ specialisation-diversification concept. Jahrbuch für Regionalwissenschaft .
[CrossRef]
16. YASUHIRO SATO, KAZUHIRO YAMAMOTO. 2012. TRADE IMPACTS ON SKILL
ACQUISITION VIA VARIETY EXPANSION*. Japanese Economic Review no-no. [CrossRef]
17. Manash Ranjan Gupta, Priya Brata Dutta. 2012. Skilled–unskilled wage inequality, product
variety, public input and increasing returns: A static general equilibrium analysis. Economic
Modelling . [CrossRef]
18. T. Schoellman. 2012. Education Quality and Development Accounting. The Review of Economic
Studies 79:1, 388-417. [CrossRef]
19. Fatih Guvenen, Burhanettin Kuruscu. 2012. UNDERSTANDING THE EVOLUTION OF
THE US WAGE DISTRIBUTION: A THEORETICAL ANALYSIS. Journal of the European
Economic Association no-no. [CrossRef]
20. Fabián Slonimczyk. 2011. Earnings inequality and skill mismatch in the U.S.: 1973–2002. The
Journal of Economic Inequality . [CrossRef]
21. Andreas Hornstein, , Per Krusell, , Giovanni L. Violante. 2011. Frictional Wage Dispersion
in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment. American Economic Review 101:7, 2873-2898.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
22. Pedro Carneiro, , Sokbae Lee. 2011. Trends in Quality-Adjusted Skill Premia in the United States,
1960–2000. American Economic Review 101:6, 2309-2349. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
23. Gregory Gilpin, Michael Kaganovich. 2011. The quantity and quality of teachers: Dynamics of
the trade-off. Journal of Public Economics . [CrossRef]
24. Francesca Mazzolari, Giuseppe Ragusa. 2011. Spillovers from High-Skill Consumption to Low-
Skill Labor Markets. Review of Economics and Statistics 110929132532008. [CrossRef]
25. Kitae Sohn. 2011. The dynamics of the evolution of the Black–White test score gap. Education
Economics 1-14. [CrossRef]
26. Francisco A. Gallego. 2011. Skill Premium in Chile: Studying Skill Upgrading in the South. World
Development . [CrossRef]
27. Eugene Beaulieu, Michael Benarroch, James D. Gaisford. 2011. Intra-industry Trade
Liberalization: Why Skilled Workers are More Likely to Support Free Trade. Review of
International Economics 19:3, 579-594. [CrossRef]
28. Tomoaki Yamada. 2011. Income risk, macroeconomic and demographic change, and economic
inequality in Japan. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control . [CrossRef]
29. Arnaud Dupuy. 2011. A Microfoundation for Production Functions: Assignment of Heterogeneous
Workers to Heterogeneous Jobs. Economica n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
30. Hesham M. Abdel-Rahman. 2011. PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION, SKILL DISTRIBUTION,
AND SYSTEMS OF CITIES IN A NORTH-SOUTH TRADE MODEL. Review of Urban &
Regional Development Studies 23:2-3, 137-161. [CrossRef]
31. FRÉDÉRIC DOCQUIER, LUCA MARCHIORI. 2011. The impact of MENA-to-EU migration in
the context of demographic change. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 1-42. [CrossRef]
32. John Van Reenen. 2011. Wage inequality, technology and trade: 21st century evidence. Labour
Economics . [CrossRef]
33. Angel Gavilan. 2011. Wage inequality, segregation by skill and the price of capital in an
assignment model. European Economic Review . [CrossRef]
34. Lawrence Uren, Gabor Virag. 2011. SKILL REQUIREMENTS, SEARCH FRICTIONS, AND
WAGE INEQUALITY*. International Economic Review 52:2, 379-406. [CrossRef]
35. Alessandra Cataldi, Stephan Kampelmann, François Rycx. 2011. Productivity-Wage Gaps Among
Age Groups: Does the ICT Environment Matter?. De Economist . [CrossRef]
36. Michelle Alexopoulos, Jon Cohen. 2011. Volumes of evidence: examining technical change in the
last century through a new lens. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique
44:2, 413-450. [CrossRef]
37. Carlo V. Fiorio. 2011. Understanding Italian Inequality Trends*. Oxford Bulletin of Economics
and Statistics 73:2, 255-275. [CrossRef]
38. Manash Ranjan Gupta, Priya Brata Dutta. 2011. Skilled–unskilled wage inequality and
unemployment: A general equilibrium analysis. Economic Modelling . [CrossRef]
39. Margarita Katsimi, Thomas Moutos. 2011. Inequality and the US import demand function. Journal
of International Money and Finance 30:3, 492-506. [CrossRef]
40. Samuel Muehlemann, Stefan C. Wolter. 2011. Firm-sponsored Training and Poaching
Externalities in Regional Labor Markets. Regional Science and Urban Economics . [CrossRef]
41. Anthony B. Atkinson, , Thomas Piketty, , Emmanuel Saez. 2011. Top Incomes in the Long Run
of History. Journal of Economic Literature 49:1, 3-71. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
42. Guido Cazzavillan, Krzysztof Olszewski. 2011. Skill-biased technological change, endogenous
labor supply and growth: A model and calibration to Poland and the US. Research in Economics
. [CrossRef]
43. Chiara Broccolini, Alessia Lo Turco, Andrea Presbitero, Stefano Staffolani. 2011. Individual
Earnings, International Outsourcing and Technological Change: Evidence from Italy.
International Economic Journal 25:1, 29-46. [CrossRef]
44. Markus Klein. 2011. Trends in the association between educational attainment and class
destinations in West Germany: Looking inside the service class. Research in Social Stratification
and Mobility . [CrossRef]
45. Davide Antonioli, Rocco Manzalini, Paolo Pini. 2011. Innovation, workers skills and industrial
relations: Empirical evidence from firm-level Italian data. Journal of Socio-Economics .
[CrossRef]
46. Alessio Moro. 2011. BIASED TECHNICAL CHANGE, INTERMEDIATE GOODS, AND
TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1-20. [CrossRef]
47. Gonzague Vannoorenberghe. 2011. Trade between symmetric countries, heterogeneous firms,
and the skill premium. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 44:1,
148-170. [CrossRef]
48. Kristian Behrens, Yasuhiro Sato. 2011. MIGRATION, SKILL FORMATION, AND THE WAGE
STRUCTURE*. Journal of Regional Science 51:1, 5-30. [CrossRef]
49. MICHAL JERZMANOWSKI, MALHAR NABAR. 2011. FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND
WAGE INEQUALITY: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. Economic Inquiry no-no. [CrossRef]
50. Timothy M. Smeeding, Jeffrey P. ThompsonRecent Trends in Income Inequality 32, 1-50.
[CrossRef]
51. Óscar Afonso. 2011. R&D Direction and North-South Diffusion, Human Capital, Growth, and
Wages. Economics Research International 2011, 1-14. [CrossRef]
52. Manash Ranjan Gupta, Priya Brata Dutta. 2011. Skilled-unskilled wage inequality and imitation in
a product variety model: A theoretical analysis. The Journal of International Trade & Economic
Development 1-28. [CrossRef]
53. Miguel A. León-Ledesma, Peter McAdam, Alpo WillmanChapter 15 Aggregation, the Skill
Premium, and the Two-Level Production Function 11, 417-436. [CrossRef]
54. John A. List, Imran RasulField Experiments in Labor Economics 4, 103-228. [CrossRef]
55. Bulent Unel. 2010. Analyzing skilled and unskilled labor efficiencies in the US. Journal of
Macroeconomics 32:4, 957-967. [CrossRef]
56. Benoit Dostie, Rajshri Jayaraman, Mathieu Trepanier. 2010. What (if any) are the returns to
computer use?. Applied Economics 42:30, 3903-3912. [CrossRef]
57. Edward Nissan, George Carter. 2010. Social identity and schooling inequality. Journal of
Economics and Finance . [CrossRef]
58. Adriaan Kalwij, Arie Kapteyn, Klaas Vos. 2010. Retirement of Older Workers and Employment
of the Young. De Economist 158:4, 341-359. [CrossRef]
59. Samir Amine, Pedro Lages Dos Santos. 2010. The influence of labour market institutions on job
complexity. Research in Economics . [CrossRef]
60. Hwan-Joo Seo, Young Soo Lee, Jai-Joon Hur, Jin Ki Kim. 2010. The impact of information and
communication technology on skilled labor and organization types. Information Systems Frontiers
. [CrossRef]
61. Paolo Naticchioni, Andrea Ricci, Emiliano Rustichelli. 2010. Far away from a skill-biased change:
falling educational wage premia in Italy. Applied Economics 42:26, 3383-3400. [CrossRef]
62. André Varella Mollick. 2010. The world elasticity of labor substitution across education levels.
Empirical Economics . [CrossRef]
63. Miguel A. León-Ledesma, , Peter McAdam, , Alpo Willman. 2010. Identifying the Elasticity
of Substitution with Biased Technical Change. American Economic Review 100:4, 1330-1357.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
64. Samir Amine, Pedro Lages Dos Santos. 2010. Technological choices and unemployment benefits
in a matching model with heterogenous workers. Journal of Economics 101:1, 1-19. [CrossRef]
65. Uwe Jirjahn, Kornelius Kraft. 2010. TEAMWORK AND INTRA-FIRM WAGE DISPERSION
AMONG BLUE-COLLAR WORKERS. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 57:4, 404-429.
[CrossRef]
66. TETSUGEN HARUYAMA, CAMPBELL LEITH. 2010. UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE
PRODUCTIVITY SLOWDOWN: AN EFFCIENCY WAGE PERSPECTIVE. Japanese
Economic Review 61:3, 301-319. [CrossRef]
67. Hui Jin, Dale W. Jorgenson. 2010. Econometric modeling of technical change. Journal of
Econometrics 157:2, 205-219. [CrossRef]
68. Elena Ketteni, Theofanis Mamuneas, Thanasis Stengos. 2010. THE EFFECT OF INFORMATION
TECHNOLOGY AND HUMAN CAPITAL ON ECONOMIC GROWTH. Macroeconomic
Dynamics 1-21. [CrossRef]
69. Ted Davis, David M. Hart. 2010. International Cooperation to Manage High-Skill Migration: The
Case of India-U.S. Relations. Review of Policy Research 27:4, 509-526. [CrossRef]
70. DAVID KALIST, STEPHEN SPURR, TATSUMA WADA. 2010. Immigration of Nurses.
Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 49:3, 406-428. [CrossRef]
71. Francesco Bogliacino, Mario Pianta. 2010. Innovation and Employment: a Reinvestigation using
Revised Pavitt classes. Research Policy 39:6, 799-809. [CrossRef]
72. Zheng Shi, Zheng Wen, Jin Xia. 2010. A Simple, Analytically Solvable, Dual-Space Economic
Agglomerations Model. Networks and Spatial Economics 10:2, 261-271. [CrossRef]
73. F. A. Gallego, R. Woodberry. 2010. Christian Missionaries and Education in Former African
Colonies: How Competition Mattered. Journal of African Economies 19:3, 294-329. [CrossRef]
74. Francisco A Gallego. 2010. Historical Origins of Schooling: The Role of Democracy and Political
Decentralization. Review of Economics and Statistics 92:2, 228-243. [CrossRef]
75. Dao-Zhi Zeng, Laixun Zhao. 2010. Globalization, interregional and international inequalities.
Journal of Urban Economics 67:3, 352-361. [CrossRef]
76. Kitae Sohn. 2010. Acting White: A Critical Review. The Urban Review . [CrossRef]
77. OSCAR AFONSO. 2010. GROWTH AND WAGE INEQUALITY IN A SCALE-
INDEPENDENT MODEL WITH R&D AND HUMAN-CAPITAL ACCUMULATION. The
Manchester School 78:2, 149-182. [CrossRef]
78. Mathias Thoenig, Thierry Verdier. 2010. A macroeconomic perspective on Knowledge
Management. Journal of Economic Growth 15:1, 33-63. [CrossRef]
79. Alberto Baccini, Martina Cioni. 2010. Is technological change really skill-biased? Evidence from
the introduction of ICT on the Italian textile industry (1980-2000). New Technology, Work and
Employment 25:1, 80-93. [CrossRef]
80. Robert Stehrer. 2010. The effects of factor and sector biased technical change revisited. Economic
Change and Restructuring 43:1, 65-94. [CrossRef]
81. Chi-Keung Marco Lau. 2010. Convergence Across the United States: Evidence from Panel ESTAR
Unit Root Test. International Advances in Economic Research 16:1, 52-64. [CrossRef]
82. Sandra E Black, Alexandra Spitz-Oener. 2010. Explaining Women's Success: Technological
Change and the Skill Content of Women's Work. Review of Economics and Statistics 92:1,
187-194. [CrossRef]
83. Christophe Hachon. 2010. Éducation et progressivité des systèmes de retraite. Revue économique
61:4, 751. [CrossRef]
84. PAUL BEAUDRY, PATRICK FRANCOIS. 2010. Managerial Skills Acquisition and the Theory
of Economic Development. Review of Economic Studies 77:1, 90-126. [CrossRef]
85. Michael Gebel, Friedhelm Pfeiffer. 2010. Educational Expansion and Its Heterogeneous Returns
for Wage Workers. Schmollers Jahrbuch 130:1, 19-42. [CrossRef]
86. Dean Hyslop, Dave Maré. 2009. Skill Upgrading in New Zealand, 1986â2001. Australian
Economic Review 42:4, 422-434. [CrossRef]
87. Martin Groß. 2009. Markt oder Schließung? Zu den Ursachen der Steigerung der
Einkommensungleichheit. Berliner Journal für Soziologie 19:4, 499-530. [CrossRef]
88. Johannes Giesecke, Roland Verwiebe. 2009. Wachsende Lohnungleichheit in Deutschland.
Berliner Journal für Soziologie 19:4, 531-555. [CrossRef]
89. Chul-In Lee, Gary Solon. 2009. Trends in Intergenerational Income Mobility. Review of
Economics and Statistics 91:4, 766-772. [CrossRef]
90. Robert D. Plotnick. 2009. Measuring Poverty and Assessing the Role of Income Transfers in
Contemporary Antipoverty Policy: Comments on Besharov and Call. Policy Studies Journal 37:4,
633-644. [CrossRef]
91. Tetsugen Haruyama. 2009. COMPETITIVE INNOVATION WITH CODIFIED AND TACIT
KNOWLEDGE. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 56:4, 390-414. [CrossRef]
92. Michael Gebel, Johannes Giesecke. 2009. Labour market flexibility and inequality: the changing
risk patterns of temporary employment in West Germany. Zeitschrift für ArbeitsmarktForschung
42:3, 234-251. [CrossRef]
93. NOEL GASTON, GULASEKARAN RAJAGURU. 2009. The Long-run Determinants of
Australian Income Inequality. Economic Record 85:270, 260-275. [CrossRef]
94. Chris Edmond, Laura Veldkamp. 2009. Income dispersion and counter-cyclical markups#. Journal
of Monetary Economics 56:6, 791-804. [CrossRef]
95. Bruce Western, Deirdre Bloome. 2009. VARIANCE FUNCTION REGRESSIONS FOR
STUDYING INEQUALITY. Sociological Methodology 39:1, 293-326. [CrossRef]
96. Ivan T. Kandilov. 2009. THE EFFECTS OF TRADE WITH DEVELOPING COUNTRIES ON
THE REGIONAL DEMAND FOR SKILL IN THE U.S.: EVIDENCE FROM COUNTY DATA.
Journal of Regional Science 49:3, 459-482. [CrossRef]
97. Piero Esposito, Robert Stehrer. 2009. The sector bias of skill-biased technical change and the rising
skill premium in transition economies. Empirica 36:3, 351-364. [CrossRef]
98. Marco Lilla, Stefano Staffolani. 2009. The evolution of wage inequality in Italy. Applied
Economics 41:15, 1873-1892. [CrossRef]
99. Jin Hwa Jung, Kang-Shik Choi. 2009. Technological Change and Returns to Education: The
Implications for the S&E Labor Market. Global Economic Review 38:2, 161-184. [CrossRef]
100. Elisabetta Croci Angelini, Francesco Farina, Mario Pianta. 2009. Innovation and wage polarisation
in Europe. International Review of Applied Economics 23:3, 309-325. [CrossRef]
101. Francesco Bogliacino. 2009. Poorer workers. The determinants of wage formation in Europe.
International Review of Applied Economics 23:3, 327-343. [CrossRef]
102. David Card. 2009. Immigration and Inequality. American Economic Review 99:2, 1-21. [Citation]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
103. BRUCE IAN CARLIN, SIMON GERVAIS. 2009. Work Ethic, Employment Contracts, and Firm
Value. The Journal of Finance 64:2, 785-821. [CrossRef]
104. Rosario Crinò. 2009. OFFSHORING, MULTINATIONALS AND LABOUR MARKET: A
REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE. Journal of Economic Surveys 23:2, 197-249.
[CrossRef]
105. Matthias Weiss. 2009. On the evolution of wage inequality in Acemoglu's model of directed
technical change. Applied Economics Letters 16:6, 591-595. [CrossRef]
106. JAN LUITEN VAN ZANDEN. 2009. The skill premium and the ‘Great Divergence’. European
Review of Economic History 13:01, 121. [CrossRef]
107. Johannes Giesecke, Roland Verwiebe. 2009. The Changing Wage Distribution in Germany
between 1985 and 2006. Schmollers Jahrbuch 129:2, 191-201. [CrossRef]
108. Elise Huillery. 2009. History Matters: The Long-Term Impact of Colonial Public Investments in
French West Africa. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1:2, 176-215. [Abstract]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
109. Christopher H. Wheeler. 2009. Technology and industrial agglomeration: Evidence from computer
usage. Papers in Regional Science 88:1, 43-62. [CrossRef]
110. Rosa Capolupo. 2009. The New Growth Theories and Their Empirics after Twenty Years.
Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal . [CrossRef]
111. HEIDRUN C. HOPPE, BENNY MOLDOVANU, ANER SELA. 2009. The Theory of Assortative
Matching Based on Costly Signals. Review of Economic Studies 76:1, 253-281. [CrossRef]
112. Dimitrios Pontikakis. 2009. The occupational domain and initial earnings of recent Irish graduates:
Is a science and technology degree good for you?. International Journal of Manpower 30:6,
591-613. [CrossRef]
113. Valeria Mastrostefano, Mario Pianta. 2009. Technology and jobs. Economics of Innovation and
New Technology 18:8, 729-741. [CrossRef]
114. Kartik Athreya, Xuan S. Tam, Eric R. Young. 2009. Unsecured credit markets are not insurance
markets#. Journal of Monetary Economics 56:1, 83-103. [CrossRef]
115. Clayne Pope. 2009. Measuring the distribution of material well-being: U.S. trends#. Journal of
Monetary Economics 56:1, 66-78. [CrossRef]
116. Allen J. Scott. 2008. Production and work in the American metropolis: a macroscopic approach.
The Annals of Regional Science 42:4, 787-805. [CrossRef]
117. Oliver Falck, Stephan Heblich. 2008. Modern Location Factors in Dynamic Regions. European
Planning Studies 16:10, 1385-1403. [CrossRef]
118. Daron Acemoglu, Amy Finkelstein. 2008. Input and Technology Choices in Regulated Industries:
Evidence from the Health Care Sector. Journal of Political Economy 116:5, 837-880. [CrossRef]
119. Philip N Jefferson. 2008. Educational Attainment and the Cyclical Sensitivity of Employment.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 26:4, 526-535. [CrossRef]
120. Andre Varella Mollick. 2008. The Rise of the Skill Premium in Mexican Maquiladoras. Journal
of Development Studies 44:9, 1382-1404. [CrossRef]
121. David Domeij. 2008. Rising Earnings Inequality in Sweden: The Role of Composition and Prices.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110:3, 609-634. [CrossRef]
122. Philipp Koellinger. 2008. The relationship between technology, innovation, and firm performance
—Empirical evidence from e-business in Europe. Research Policy 37:8, 1317-1328. [CrossRef]
123. Patrick A. Puhani. 2008. Transatlantic Differences in Labour Markets: Changes in Wage and
Non-Employment Structures in the 1980s and the 1990s. German Economic Review 9:3, 312-338.
[CrossRef]
124. Maurizio Iacopetta. 2008. Technological progress and inequality: an ambiguous relationship.
Journal of Evolutionary Economics 18:3-4, 455-475. [CrossRef]
125. Nathalie Chusseau, Michel Dumont, Joël Hellier. 2008. EXPLAINING RISING INEQUALITY:
SKILL-BIASED TECHNICAL CHANGE AND NORTH–SOUTH TRADE. Journal of Economic
Surveys 22:3, 409-457. [CrossRef]
126. JULIE A. SILVA. 2008. International Trade and the Changing Demand for Skilled Workers in
High-Tech Manufacturing. Growth and Change 39:2, 225-251. [CrossRef]
127. Leonhard Becker, Thomas Liebig, Alfonso Sousa-Poza. 2008. Migration Policy and Industrial
Structure: The Case of Switzerland. International Migration 46:2, 81-107. [CrossRef]
128. Stephen Machin. 2008. An Appraisal of Economic Research on Changes in Wage Inequality.
Labour 22:s1, 7-26. [CrossRef]
129. Paolo Naticchioni, Andrea Ricci, Emiliano Rustichelli. 2008. Wage Inequality, Employment
Structure and Skill-biased Change in Italy. Labour 22:s1, 27-51. [CrossRef]
130. Pablo Acosta, Gabriel V. Montes-Rojas. 2008. Trade Reform and Inequality: The Case of Mexico
and Argentina in the 1990s. The World Economy 31:6, 763-780. [CrossRef]
131. Manitra A. Rakotoarisoa, Sung-soo Kim. 2008. Does Trade, Technology, or Education Expel
Traditional Sectors? Some Evidence from the Collapse of the Silk Sector in South Korea*. Asian
Economic Journal 22:2, 113-132. [CrossRef]
132. Manitra A. Rakotoarisoa, Sung-soo Kim. 2008. Does Trade, Technology, or Education Expel
Traditional Sectors? Some Evidence from the Collapse of the Silk Sector in South Korea. Asian
Economic Journal 22:2, 113-132. [CrossRef]
133. Subhadip Ghosh. 2008. FDI and the skill premium in a North-South global economy. The Journal
of International Trade & Economic Development 17:2, 181-195. [CrossRef]
134. André Varella Mollick. 2008. Relative wages, labor supplies and trade in Mexican manufacturing:
Evidence from two samples. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 17:2,
213-241. [CrossRef]
135. David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, Melissa S. Kearney. 2008. Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality:
Revising the Revisionists. Review of Economics and Statistics 90:2, 300-323. [CrossRef]
136. Stacey H Chen. 2008. Estimating the Variance of Wages in the Presence of Selection and
Unobserved Heterogeneity. Review of Economics and Statistics 90:2, 275-289. [CrossRef]
137. Natália Barbosa, Ana Paula Faria. 2008. Technology adoption: does labour skill matter? Evidence
from Portuguese firm-level data. Empirica 35:2, 179-194. [CrossRef]
138. Jonathan Heathcote, Kjetil Storesletten, Giovanni L. Violante. 2008. Insurance and opportunities:
A welfare analysis of labor market risk#. Journal of Monetary Economics 55:3, 501-525.
[CrossRef]
139. Cathleen D. Zick, W. Keith Bryant, Sivithee Srisukhumbowornchai. 2008. Does housework matter
anymore? The shifting impact of housework on economic inequality. Review of Economics of the
Household 6:1, 1-28. [CrossRef]
140. WESHAH A. RAZZAK, JASON C. TIMMINS. 2008. A MACROECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE
ON SKILL SHORTAGES AND THE SKILL PREMIUM IN NEW ZEALAND. Australian
Economic Papers 47:1, 74-91. [CrossRef]
141. Uwe Sunde. 2008. Human Capital Formation, Education and Earnings Inequality. Applied
Economics Quarterly 54:1, 7-26. [CrossRef]
142. Rui Castro, Daniele Coen-Pirani. 2008. WHY HAVE AGGREGATE SKILLED HOURS
BECOME SO CYCLICAL SINCE THE MID-1980s?. International Economic Review 49:1,
135-185. [CrossRef]
143. Coen Teulings, Thijs van Rens. 2008. Education, Growth, and Income Inequality. Review of
Economics and Statistics 90:1, 89-104. [CrossRef]
144. Nathalie Chusseau, Joël Hellier. 2008. Social policies and R&D subsidies: Impact on inequality,
unemployment, growth and the tax burden. International Journal of Manpower 29:3, 239-262.
[CrossRef]
145. ANTONIO CABRALES, ANTONI CALVÓ-ARMENGOL, NICOLA PAVONI. 2008. Social
Preferences, Skill Segregation, and Wage Dynamics. Review of Economic Studies 75:1, 65-98.
[CrossRef]
146. Antonio Garofalo, François Rycx, Concetto Paolo Vinci. 2008. Unemployment, innovation and
R&D: introduction. International Journal of Manpower 29:3, 192-197. [CrossRef]
147. DAVINA C. LING, ERNST R. BERNDT, RICHARD G. FRANK. 2008. ECONOMIC
INCENTIVES AND CONTRACTS: THE USE OF PSYCHOTROPIC MEDICATIONS.
Contemporary Economic Policy 26:1, 49-72. [CrossRef]
148. Luca Pieroni, Fabrizio Pompei. 2008. Labour market flexibility and innovation: geographical and
technological determinants. International Journal of Manpower 29:3, 216-238. [CrossRef]
149. David Rigby, Sebastien Breau. 2008. Impacts of Trade on Wage Inequality in Los Angeles:
Analysis Using Matched Employer-Employee Data. Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 98:4, 920-940. [CrossRef]
150. PETER DOLTON, GERRY MAKEPEACE, HELEN ROBINSON. 2007. USE IT OR LOSE
IT? THE IMPACT OF COMPUTERS ON EARNINGS. The Manchester School 75:6, 673-694.
[CrossRef]
151. Isaac Ehrlich, Jinyoung Kim. 2007. The Evolution of Income and Fertility Inequalities over the
Course of Economic Development: A Human Capital Perspective. Journal of Human Capital 1:1,
137-174. [CrossRef]
152. A. Dupuy. 2007. Will the skill-premium in the Netherlands rise in the next decades?. Applied
Economics 39:21, 2723-2731. [CrossRef]
153. Thomas Lemieux. 2007. The changing nature of wage inequality. Journal of Population
Economics 21:1, 21-48. [CrossRef]
154. Klaus Wälde, Pia Weiß. 2007. International competition, downsizing and wage inequality. Journal
of International Economics 73:2, 396-406. [CrossRef]
155. Thomas Liebig, Patrick A. Puhani, Alfonso Sousa-Poza. 2007. TAXATION AND INTERNAL
MIGRATION?EVIDENCE FROM THE SWISS CENSUS USING COMMUNITY-LEVEL
VARIATION IN INCOME TAX RATES. Journal of Regional Science 47:4, 807-836. [CrossRef]
156. Francisco L. Rivera-Batiz. 2007. How Do Migrants from Latin America and the Caribbean Fare
in the US Labour Market?. The World Economy 30:9, 1399-1429. [CrossRef]
157. Jimy M. Sanders. 2007. OCCUPATIONAL GROWTH AND THE EXPANSION OF
EDUCATIONALLY-RELATED EARNING GAPS. Sociological Spectrum 27:5, 555-584.
[CrossRef]
158. Pablo Acosta, Leonardo Gasparini. 2007. Capital Accumulation, Trade Liberalization, and Rising
Wage Inequality: The Case of Argentina. Economic Development and Cultural Change 55:4,
793-812. [CrossRef]
159. Michael Peneder. 2007. A sectoral taxonomy of educational intensity. Empirica 34:3, 189-212.
[CrossRef]
160. R IWAHASHI. 2007. A theoretical assessment of regional development effects on the demand for
general education. Economics of Education Review 26:3, 387-394. [CrossRef]
161. XAVIER CHOJNICKI, FRÉDÉRIC DOCQUIER. 2007. Fiscal Policy and Educational
Attainment in the United States: A Generational Accounting Perspective. Economica 74:294,
329-350. [CrossRef]
162. Sucharita Ghosh, Steven Yamarik. 2007. International Trade, Technology, and the Wage Gap:
Evidence from Granger-causality Tests. Review of International Economics 15:2, 321-346.
[CrossRef]
163. Oriana Bandiera, Iwan Barankay, Imran Rasul. 2007. Incentives for Managers and Inequality
Among Workers: Evidence From a Firm-Level Experiment*. Quarterly Journal of Economics
122:2, 729-773. [CrossRef]
164. Kang-Shik Choi, Jinook Jeong. 2007. Does unmeasured ability explain the wage premium
associated with technological change?: Quantile regression analysis. Applied Economics 39:9,
1163-1171. [CrossRef]
165. Christopher H. Wheeler. 2007. Do localization economies derive from human capital
externalities?. The Annals of Regional Science 41:1, 31-50. [CrossRef]
166. Alain-Désiré Nimubona, Désiré Vencatachellum. 2007. Intergenerational education mobility of
black and white South Africans. Journal of Population Economics 20:1, 149-182. [CrossRef]
167. John R. Carter. 2007. An Empirical Note on Economic Freedom and Income Inequality. Public
Choice 130:1-2, 163-177. [CrossRef]
168. Winfried Koeniger, Marco Leonardi. 2007. Capital deepening and wage differentials: Germany
versus US. Economic Policy 22:49, 71-116. [CrossRef]
169. Ekkehart Schlicht. 2007. Wage Dispersion, Over-Qualification, and Reder Competition.
Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal . [CrossRef]
170. Petri Böckerman. 2007. Polytechnic graduate placement in Finnish manufacturing. Journal of
Education and Work 20:1, 1-16. [CrossRef]
171. Andreas Knabe, Ronnie Schöb, Joachim Weimann. 2006. Marginal Employment Subsidization:
A New Concept and a Reappraisal. Kyklos 59:4, 557-577. [CrossRef]
172. Antonio Avalos, Andreas Savvides. 2006. The Manufacturing Wage Inequality in Latin America
and East Asia: Openness, Technology Transfer, and Labor Supply. Review of Development
Economics 10:4, 553-576. [CrossRef]
173. A MARCHANTE, B ORTEGA, R PAGAN. 2006. Determinants of skills shortages and hard-to-
fill vacancies in the hospitality sector. Tourism Management 27:5, 791-802. [CrossRef]
174. Bas Jacobs, Frederick Van der Ploeg. 2006. getting european universities into shape. European
Political Science 5:3, 288-303. [CrossRef]
175. ROBERTO EZCURRA, PEDRO PASCUAL, MANUEL RAPÚN. 2006. THE SPATIAL
DISTRIBUTION OF WELFARE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION. Tijdschrift voor Economische
en Sociale Geografie 97:4, 331-342. [CrossRef]
176. ROBERT BAUMANN. 2006. Changes in the Appalachian Wage Gap, 1970 to 2000. Growth and
Change 37:3, 416-443. [CrossRef]
177. Aimee Chin, Chinhui Juhn, Peter Thompson. 2006. Technical Change and the Demand for Skills
during the Second Industrial Revolution: Evidence from the Merchant Marine, 1891–1912. Review
of Economics and Statistics 88:3, 572-578. [CrossRef]
178. Bas Jacobs, Frederick van der Ploeg. 2006. Guide to reform of higher education: a European
perspective. Economic Policy 21:47, 535-592. [CrossRef]
179. Thomas Moutos. 2006. TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE, INEQUALITY AND WORK
SHARING. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 53:3, 305-318. [CrossRef]
180. G. Arabsheibani, Francisco Carneiro, Andrew Henley. 2006. Changes in human capital and
earnings inequality: Recent evidence from Brazil 1. The Journal of Development Studies 42:5,
837-867. [CrossRef]
181. Jérôme Vandenbussche, Philippe Aghion, Costas Meghir. 2006. Growth, distance to frontier and
composition of human capital. Journal of Economic Growth 11:2, 97-127. [CrossRef]
182. Richard H. Steckel, Jayanthi Krishnan. 2006. THE WEALTH MOBILITY OF MEN AND
WOMEN DURING THE 1960s AND 1970s. Review of Income and Wealth 52:2, 189-212.
[CrossRef]
183. PAUL FRIJTERS, ROBERT GREGORY. 2006. From Golden Age to Golden Age: Australia's
'Great Leap Forward'?*. Economic Record 82:257, 207-224. [CrossRef]
184. ERNESTO AGUAYO-TELLEZ. 2006. Income Divergence between Mexican States in the 1990s:
The Role of Skill Premium. Growth and Change 37:2, 255-277. [CrossRef]
185. Katrin Schleife. 2006. Computer Use and Employment Status of Older Workers - An Analysis
Based on Individual Data. Labour 20:2, 325-348. [CrossRef]
186. Thomas Lemieux. 2006. Increasing Residual Wage Inequality: Composition Effects, Noisy Data,
or Rising Demand for Skill?. American Economic Review 96:3, 461-498. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
187. Carsten Ochsen. 2006. Zukunft der Arbeit und Arbeit der Zukunft in Deutschland. Perspektiven
der Wirtschaftspolitik 7:2, 173-193. [CrossRef]
188. Daniel Fernandez Kranz. 2006. Why has wage inequality increased more in the USA than in
Europe? An empirical investigation of the demand and supply of skill. Applied Economics 38:07,
771-788. [CrossRef]
189. Phillip Brown, Hugh Lauder. 2006. Globalisation, knowledge and the myth of the magnet
economy. Globalisation, Societies and Education 4:1, 25-57. [CrossRef]
190. Christopher Brown, Randall Kesselring. 2006. Declining marriage ratios of young black women:
Testing alternative economic hypotheses. The Review of Black Political Economy 33:4, 27-48.
[CrossRef]
191. Karl Taylor. 2006. UK Wage Inequality: An Industry and Regional Perspective. Labour 20:1,
91-124. [CrossRef]
192. Arnaud Dupuy, Andries de Grip. 2006. Elasticity of substitution and productivity, capital and skill
intensity differences across firms. Economics Letters 90:3, 340-347. [CrossRef]
193. G GONZAGA, N MENEZESFILHO, C TERRA. 2006. Trade liberalization and the evolution of
skill earnings differentials in Brazil. Journal of International Economics 68:2, 345-367. [CrossRef]
194. Oscar Afonso. 2006. Skill-biased technological knowledge without scale effects. Applied
Economics 38:1, 13-21. [CrossRef]
195. Emmanuelle Walkowiak. 2006. Renouvellement de la main-d'œuvre et modernisation des
entreprises. Revue économique 57:6, 1205. [CrossRef]
196. K LOMMERUD, F MELAND, O RUNESTRAUME. 2006. Globalisation and union opposition
to technological change. Journal of International Economics 68:1, 1-23. [CrossRef]
197. Peter HowittChapter 35 Coordination Issues in Long-Run Growth 2, 1605-1624. [CrossRef]
198. Franco PeracchiChapter 5 Educational Wage Premia and the Distribution of Earnings: An
International Perspective 1, 189-254. [CrossRef]
199. David Fryer, Desire Vencatachellum. 2005. Returns to Education in South Africa: Evidence from
the Machibisa Township. African Development Review 17:3, 513-535. [CrossRef]
200. Volker Grossmann. 2005. White-collar employment, inequality, and technological change.
Journal of Economics 10:S1, 119-142. [CrossRef]
201. Hartmut Egger, Volker Grossmann. 2005. Non-Routine Tasks, Restructuring of Firms, and
Wage Inequality Within and Between Skill-Groups. Journal of Economics - Zeitschrift für
Nationalökonomie 86:3, 197-228. [CrossRef]
202. Antonio Ciccone, Giovanni Peri. 2005. Long-Run Substitutability Between More and Less
Educated Workers: Evidence from U.S. States, 1950–1990. Review of Economics and Statistics
87:4, 652-663. [CrossRef]
203. Hesham M. Abdel-Rahman. 2005. Skill distribution and income disparity in a North-South
trade model. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'<html_ent glyph="@eacute;"
ascii="e"/>conomique 38:4, 1298-1326. [CrossRef]
204. Timothy Dunne, Kenneth Troske. 2005. TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION AND THE SKILL MIX
OF US MANUFACTURING PLANTS. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 52:3, 387-405.
[CrossRef]
205. Oswald Mascarenhas, Ram Kesavan, Michael Bernacchi. 2005. Governmental and Corporate
Role in Diffusing Development Technologies: Ethical Macromarketing Imperatives. Journal of
Nonprofit & Public Sector Marketing 13:1, 271-291. [CrossRef]
206. FILIPE ALMEIDA-SANTOS, KAREN MUMFORD. 2005. EMPLOYEE TRAINING AND
WAGE COMPRESSION IN BRITAIN*. The Manchester School 73:3, 321-342. [CrossRef]
207. CHRISTOPHER H. WHEELER. 2005. Cities, Skills, and Inequality. Growth and Change 36:3,
329-353. [CrossRef]
208. Vijay K. Mathur, Sheldon H. Stein. 2005. Do amenities matter in attracting knowledge workers
for regional economic development?*. Papers in Regional Science 84:2, 251-269. [CrossRef]
209. B BALTAGI, D RICH. 2005. Skill-biased technical change in US manufacturing: a general index
approach. Journal of Econometrics 126:2, 549-570. [CrossRef]
210. Arnaud Dupuy, Lex Borghans. 2005. Supply and demand, allocation and wage inequality: an
international comparison. Applied Economics 37:9, 1073-1088. [CrossRef]
211. Emmanuel Saez , Michael R. Veall. 2005. The Evolution of High Incomes in Northern America:
Lessons from Canadian Evidence. American Economic Review 95:3, 831-849. [Citation] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
212. Chong Xiang. 2005. New Goods and the Relative Demand for Skilled Labor. Review of Economics
and Statistics 87:2, 285-298. [CrossRef]
213. S ZHU. 2005. Can product cycles explain skill upgrading?. Journal of International Economics
66:1, 131-155. [CrossRef]
214. Mark P. Moore, Priya Ranjan. 2005. Globalisation vs Skill-Biased Technological Change:
Implications for Unemployment and Wage Inequality*. The Economic Journal 115:503, 391-422.
[CrossRef]
215. Francine D. Blau, Lawrence M. Kahn. 2005. Do Cognitive Test Scores Explain Higher U.S. Wage
Inequality?. Review of Economics and Statistics 87:1, 184-193. [CrossRef]
216. Kang-Shik Choi, Jinook Jeong. 2005. Technological change and wage premium in a small open
economy: the case of Korea. Applied Economics 37:1, 119-131. [CrossRef]
217. S ZHU, D TREFLER. 2005. Trade and inequality in developing countries: a general equilibrium
analysis. Journal of International Economics 65:1, 21-48. [CrossRef]
218. Andreas Hornstein, Per Krusell, Giovanni L. ViolanteChapter 20 The Effects of Technical Change
on Labor Market Inequalities 1, 1275-1370. [CrossRef]
219. Toshihiko Mukoyama. 2004. Diffusion and Innovation of New Technologies under Skill
Heterogeneity. Journal of Economic Growth 9:4, 451-479. [CrossRef]
220. Oded Galor, Omer Moav. 2004. From Physical to Human Capital Accumulation: Inequality and
the Process of Development. Review of Economic Studies 71:4, 1001-1026. [CrossRef]
221. Kari Hämäläinen, Petri Böckerman. 2004. Regional Labor Market Dynamics, Housing, and
Migration. Journal of Regional Science 44:3, 543-568. [CrossRef]
222. O ATTANASIO. 2004. Trade reforms and wage inequality in Colombia*1. Journal of
Development Economics 74:2, 331-366. [CrossRef]
223. Daron Acemoglu, David H. Autor, David Lyle. 2004. Women, War, and Wages: The Effect of
Female Labor Supply on the Wage Structure at Midcentury. Journal of Political Economy 112:3,
497-551. [CrossRef]
224. JEREMY ATACK, FRED BATEMAN, ROBERT A. MARGO. 2004. Skill Intensity and Rising
Wage Dispersion in Nineteenth-Century American Manufacturing. The Journal of Economic
History 64:01. . [CrossRef]
225. Peter Dolton, Gerry Makepeace. 2004. Computer Use and Earnings in Britain*. The Economic
Journal 114:494, C117-C129. [CrossRef]
226. Jorge Saba Arbache, Andy Dickerson, Francis Green. 2004. Trade Liberalisation and Wages in
Developing Countries*. The Economic Journal 114:493, F73-F96. [CrossRef]
227. Michael Keating. 2003. The Labour Market and Inequality. The Australian Economic Review 36:4,
374-396. [CrossRef]
228. Jurgen Meckl, Benjamin Weigert. 2003. Globalization, technical change and the skill premium:
magnification effects from human - capital investments. The Journal of International Trade &
Economic Development 12:4, 319-336. [CrossRef]
229. David H. Autor, Frank Levy, Richard J. Murnane. 2003. The Skill Content of Recent
Technological Change: An empirical exploration*. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:4,
1279-1333. [CrossRef]
230. Bas ter Weel. 2003. The Structure of Wages in the Netherlands, 1986-98. Labour 17:3, 361-382.
[CrossRef]
231. Yoshiaki Azuma, Herschel I. Grossman. 2003. Educational Inequality. Labour 17:3, 317-335.
[CrossRef]
232. Esperanza Vera-Toscano, Alfons Weersink, Euan Phimister. 2003. Earnings Mobility of Rural
versus Urban Workers in Canada. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne
d'agroeconomie 51:2, 241-258. [CrossRef]
233. Hans-Joachim Voth. 2003. Living Standards During the Industrial Revolution: An Economist's
Guide. American Economic Review 93:2, 221-226. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
234. Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez. 2003. Income Inequality in The United States, 1913–1998*.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:1, 1-39. [CrossRef]
235. Daron Acemoglu. 2003. Cross-country Inequality Trends*. The Economic Journal 113:485, F121-
F149. [CrossRef]
236. Sylvain E. Dessy, Desire Vencatachellum. 2003. Explaining cross-country differences in policy
response to child labour. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d`Economique 36:1,
1-20. [CrossRef]
237. David Knoke, Song YangFATTENIN’ FROGS FOR SNAKES? COMPANY INVESTMENTS
IN JOB SKILLS TRAINING 12, 3-30. [CrossRef]

You might also like