You are on page 1of 12

Progress in Human Geography

http://phg.sagepub.com/

Geographies of development II: Cash transfers and the reinvention of development for the
poor
Richard Ballard
Prog Hum Geogr 2013 37: 811 originally published online 17 January 2013
DOI: 10.1177/0309132512474739

The online version of this article can be found at:


http://phg.sagepub.com/content/37/6/811

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

Additional services and information for Progress in Human Geography can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://phg.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://phg.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

>> Version of Record - Nov 14, 2013


OnlineFirst Version of Record - Jan 17, 2013

What is This?

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Progress report
Progress in Human Geography
37(6) 811–821
Geographies of development II: ª The Author(s) 2012
Reprints and permission:

Cash transfers and the sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav


DOI: 10.1177/0309132512474739
phg.sagepub.com
reinvention of development
for the poor

Richard Ballard
University of KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa

Abstract
Since the mid-1990s, a number of governments in the global South have instituted programmes which
provide regular cash grants to poor people. The results of cash transfer programmes have impressed those
searching for ways to improve welfare: the depth of poverty has been reduced, more children are being edu-
cated and vaccinated, and the poor are more likely to get jobs and start enterprises. Advocates of social
democracy are hopeful that this heralds the possibility of comprehensive social protection. Experiments in
welfare in the global South do not, however, inevitably signal an epochal shift to a postneoliberal era. They
form part of an increasingly heterodox approach which combines an enduring emphasis on liberalized
economic growth with bolder biopolitical interventions for the poor.

Keywords
biopolitics, cash transfers, postneoliberalism, social democracy, welfare

I Development’s epiphany Oportunidades, included a ‘scholarship’ for


children who attended school and obliged bene-
In 1995, when the Mexican GDP contracted by
ficiaries to visit clinics for health lectures and
6%, the newly elected government and World
check-ups. In less than a decade, it reached a
Bank advisors doubted that existing poverty
quarter of the Mexican population. It resulted
alleviation measures were going to be enough
in improved school attendance and completion,
for many vulnerable people to endure the crisis.
a reduction in malnutrition-related stunting,
Subsidies for tortillas and other staples were not
healthier children, and falling extreme poverty.
reaching many of the rural poor, beneficiaries
were not being identified consistently, distribu-
tion was subject to clientalism, and administra- Corresponding author:
tive costs were high (Levy, 2006; Molyneux, Built Environment and Development Studies, University of
2008). Besides, researchers were concerned that KwaZulu-Natal, Durban, South Africa.
food provision schemes addressed only one of Email: ballardr@ukzn.ac.za
poverty’s many dimensions (Levy, 2006). So
N.B. The first in this series of Progress reports —
they tried something else. They established a ‘Geographies of ‘Geographies of development: Without
programme to give money to the poor. The pro- the poor’— can be found listed as an Article in issue
gramme, initially known as Progresa and later 36(5) of Progress in Human Geography.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
812 Progress in Human Geography 37(6)

Strikingly, 94% of the budget reached benefici- II Reproducing ‘surplus’


aries because running costs were low. populations
Former World Bank president James Wolfen-
Rising wages and the appearance of large mid-
sohn argues that, unlike the many successful
dle classes in the global South have vindicated,
development projects that are small and short-
for many, the role of economic growth in
lived, cash transfer programmes are able to ben-
development. Kharas and Rogerson (2012)
efit large populations over a sustained period of
argue, for example, that economic growth will
time (Levy, 2006: Foreword). Early innovations
largely vanquish poverty in middle-income
in Mexico, Brazil, Honduras and Bangladesh
countries by 2025. Yet against these enduring
inspired cash transfer programmes in 45 coun-
forms of market faith there has been a broad
tries in the global South, reaching 110 million
recognition that economic growth does not, in
families (Hanlon et al., 2010), and have even
itself, translate into advances for many poor
reformulated social policy in parts of the global
people. Bakker and Gill argue that the
North (Peck and Theodore, 2010). Although
‘extended power of capital’ is at odds with
cash-based welfare has a long history in the
‘progressive forms of social reproduction’
North, its uptake in the South has been described
(Bakker and Gill, 2003: 18). They identify a
as a revolution (Barrientos and Hulme, 2009;
‘crisis of social reproduction’ (p. 28; see also
Houtzager, 2008; The Economist, 2012a).
Bezuidenhout and Fakier, 2006: 462; Hunter,
The bourgeoning literature on biopolitics
2011: 1104), which stems from the inability
draws attention to the kinds of mechanisms gov-
of people to reproduce themselves through
ernments use to sustain the lives of populations
money wages or social wages (Hart, 2002; on
living within their territories (Foucault, 2008;
social reproduction, see also Bakker and Sil-
Hannah, 2012; Li, 2009; Ong, 2006). As the
vey, 2008; Katz, 2004; Roberts, 2008).
literature reviewed in this report shows, cash
A minority of working people in many parts
transfers have emerged as an important instru-
of the world are waged or salaried employees,
ment in conducting development for the poor.
and many of those who are ‘surplus’ to the
In contrast to the sink-or-swim approach of
requirements of the labour market are self-
market fundamentalism, or more proactive
employed in the informal sector (Denning,
attempts to unleash the entrepreneurial power
2010; ILO, 2010). The welfare systems that did
of the poor through microcredit (Roy, 2010),
emerge in the global South during the 20th
cash transfers and other distributive mechanisms
century produced limited groups of rights-
give form to more overtly ‘pastoral’ relationships
bearing workers (Barchiesi, 2011; Chari, 2010;
between states and populations (Huxley, 2007:
Ferguson, 2009). Those beyond these social
197). Support for these techniques of govern-
contracts manage risk within their families and
ment comes not only from World Bank-aligned
social networks, with very little help from the
policy, which sees cash transfers as a means to
state (Soares, 2012). According to the Interna-
re-orientate the poor to take responsibility for
tional Labour Organization (ILO), four-fifths
their own development, but also from those who
of the world’s population does not have access
see the potential for establishing distributive
to social security (ILO, 2008, 2010). Further-
mechanisms to ameliorate the effects of globali-
more, a waged or salaried job is no longer a
zation and economic marginalization. Critics, by
certain route to intergenerational upward mobi-
contrast, argue that redistribution is limited by
lity. Trade liberalization and the mobility of
enduring commitments to liberalized economic
production have weakened the ability of workers
growth, which compromise the ability of large
to secure decent conditions from capital and
numbers of people to escape poverty.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Ballard 813

consumers (Seekings, 2008b). Rather than parti- commitment to tackling poverty has been the
cipating in a secure proletariat, many are exposed undertaking, in 2000, by all UN member states
to the uncertainty and hyper-exploitation of what to meet the Millennium Development Goals by
is being called the ‘precariat’ (Standing, 2011). 2015 (Giovannini, 2008; Roy, 2008). Moder-
In response, states and multilateral agencies ate Third Way governments, such as those
have undergone a variety of ‘realignment[s]’ led by Fernando Henrique Cardoso in Brazil,
away from market orthodoxy (Leiva, 2008: Patricio Aylwin and Frei Ruiz-Tagle in Chile,
xvii). This has been described by some as a and Thabo Mbeki in South Africa, attempted to
Polanyian counter-movement which mitigates marry the objectives of social growth and social
the dislocating effects of market expansion justice (Taylor, 2006). In the 2000s, popular frus-
(Craig and Porter, 2006; Sandbrook, 2011; tration fuelled the success of parties further to the
Watts, 2009). A host of other neologisms left, such as the Workers’ Party in Brazil
attempt to capture the various responses to the (Cameron, 2009; Goldfrank, 2009; Grugel and
crises of unemployment and social protection Riggirozzi, 2012). The more radical, including
since the 1990s: the Third Way, the post- Venezuela and Bolivia, count themselves as
Washington consensus, postneoliberalism, the experiments in 21st-century socialism (Gibbs,
new new deal, and neostructuralism. They are 2006; Meltzer, 2009).
certainly not synonyms, but all question the Yet, for many commentators, there is no
adequacy of the deregulated market. Some ‘sharp rupture’ (Leiva, 2008: xxxi) from neoli-
argue that neoliberalism has lost at least some beralism to postneoliberalism (Bebbington and
of its ideological hegemony because of the Humphreys Bebbington, 2011; Hart, 2009) and
exacerbation of poverty in the wake of liberali- some prefer to classify shifts since the 1990s as
zation, the financial crisis following 2008 (Peck ‘inclusive neoliberalism’ (Craig and Porter,
et al., 2009) and the fading power of the USA 2006: 63; Hickey, 2010) or ‘roll-out neoliberal-
(Agnew, 2009). Keynesian social spending is ism’ (Peck et al., 2009: 106). Neoliberal globa-
no longer taboo (Smith, 2011) and there is solid lization has ‘relative ecological dominance’
commitment to un-neoliberal principles such as (Jessop, 2010: 33) as a result of the path estab-
‘universal access to urban services’ (Parnell and lished by neoliberal reforms (Taylor, 2009).
Robinson, 2012: 608). Although parties in power might be less
Erstwhile advocates of the tough love of the expressly neoliberal, there are nevertheless
market in the 1980s, such as the World Bank, ongoing processes of neoliberalization (Bren-
have, since the 1990s, recognized the need for ner et al., 2010). New left governments continue
interventionist poverty reduction (Craig and to rely on many of the macro-economic frame-
Porter, 2006; Roy, 2010; Ruckert, 2009; Tay- works established under more explicitly
lor, 2009). Structural Adjustment Programmes market-oriented regimes (Macdonald and
morphed into Poverty Reduction Strategy Ruckert, 2009; Webber, 2009). Grugel and
Papers, which were, supposedly, drafted by Riggirozzi (2012: 6) suggest that the primary
recipient countries themselves rather than difference between neoliberalism and postneo-
imposed, and World Bank lending for social liberalism is ‘in government attitudes to the
development increased as a proportion of poor and discourses of citizenship rather than
loans (Vetterlein, 2012). Donors have come economic management as such’ (see also Brand
to accept that regular social transfers are more and Sekler, 2009). The result is a heterodox mix
appropriate than emergency aid for popula- in which the state attempts to harness existing
tions whose vulnerability is not transient (Ellis socio-economic platforms to incorporate mar-
et al., 2009). The most prominent collective ginalized groups (Luna and Filgueira, 2009).

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
814 Progress in Human Geography 37(6)

However, breezy win-win narratives finesse are contracting information corporations to


what Leiva calls a ‘heterodox paradox’ (Leiva, develop biometric registration systems in order
2008: xxvii) in which attempts to address the to stabilize information on the populations they
needs of the poor are limited by the demands govern (Szreter and Breckenridge, 2012). A
of affluent groups and capital. new biometric identity scheme launched in
India aimed to register 200 million people by
the end of 2012 to enable the extension of social
III Throw money at the problem security (The Economist, 2012b). As Brecken-
Within this heterodox milieu, the introduction ridge argues, these technologies occupy an
of cash-based social policy measures has ambiguous position in that they appear to be
assumed a variety of forms. The most popular coercive and also represent the possibility of
are those that target the most vulnerable parts reducing patronage-based distribution and
of the life cycle: grants for children and pen- achieving much higher levels of coverage than
sioners transform those who are normally would otherwise be possible (Breckenridge,
dependants into breadwinners (Bähre, 2011). 2005).
Income protection for working-age adults is a Although advocates of cash transfers gener-
more difficult sell. A vociferous campaign for ally stress that they are not a panacea for all
a universal basic income grant in South Africa social ills, they do attribute a number of
has failed despite chronic levels of unemploy- advances to cash transfers. They have helped
ment (Seekings, 2008a). Argentina is relatively to reduce income inequality (ILO, 2011; Soares
unusual for having introduced a cash transfer for et al., 2010), the depth of poverty has fallen
the unemployed in the wake of its 2001 collapse (Woolard and Leibbrandt, 2010) and some
(Grugel and Riggirozzi, 2012). Ethiopia and households have been able to escape poverty
India, rather, give cash to unemployed individ- (Lloyd-Sherlock et al., 2012). Cash transfers
uals through public works programmes (Hanlon have improved household consumption (Soares
et al., 2010; Li, 2009). In targeting welfare, et al., 2010) with associated improvements in
states use various kinds of means testing or geo- nutrition and expenditure on children (CASE,
graphic targeting that ‘delimit ‘‘the poor’’’ as a 2008; Hanlon et al., 2010). Cash transfers may
homogenized beneficiary group (Williams result in lower rates of child labour (Soares
et al., 2012: 995). Policy debates revolve around et al., 2010). School attendance has increased
inclusion errors and exclusion errors: in their and dropout rates have decreased. Health and
efforts to avoid paying those considered not nutrition measures have improved. Many
poor enough, means tests run the risk of exclud- schemes claim gender empowerment by, for
ing those who are in fact struggling to survive. example, countering tendencies to keep girls out
Yet, regardless of intended patterns of inclu- of school (Molyneux, 2008) or by making ben-
sion, Gupta’s (2012) ethnographic analysis of efit payments through women, with the ratio-
the workings of bureaucracy in India shows the nale that women are better stewards of the
alarmingly arbitrary way in which individuals money than men, and that this may improve the
access social protection. power of women in households (ILO, 2011).
Nevertheless, cash transfers have resulted in Mindful that cash transfers might be regarded
the improvement of bureaucratic capacity. as little more than charity (e.g. Woolcock,
Some countries, such as South Africa, have 2012), advocates attach much importance to the
dramatically improved birth registration (Lund, way in which they facilitate income-generating
2012). However, since more than a third of activity, through both entrepreneurialism and
births worldwide are not registered, many states employment. Economists argue that poverty

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Ballard 815

creates risk aversion, and a regular income pro- poor to behave in ways that will improve their
vides safer conditions to take the risks needed to capacity and earnings. Behavioural economists
start businesses (Levy, 2006). It may provide such as Thaler and Sunstein advocate the use
capital or leverage for microfinance to establish of mechanisms to ‘nudge’ people to make better
enterprises (Hanlon et al., 2010). Enterprises are choices, and call this model ‘libertarian patern-
more viable because local demand increases alism’ (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008: 5). But these
from households that now have more cash to are crude tools with complex outcomes. Chil-
spend. In South Africa, pensions paid to women dren in Brazil might attend school because of
over 60 free up working-age mothers to look for conditions imposed, but they perform below par
work (Posel et al., 2006). Cash transfers, there- (Soares, 2012). Without concomitant increases
fore, aim to engender long-term autonomy as in budgets for services, incentives to get people
well as help to meet short-term consumption to use services simply result in overcrowded and
needs. understaffed schools and healthcare facilities.
This aim becomes even more explicit when Furthermore, grant conditions may undermine
cash transfers entail conditions. Many (although rather than advance gender empowerment as
not all) schemes are classified as conditional they affirm ‘more ‘‘traditional’’ divisions of
cash transfers because they require beneficiaries labour and responsibility’ such as motherhood,
to fulfil specified conditions in order to continue and force women to jump through hoops to
receiving grants. Those who would otherwise be access their benefits (Molyneux, 2008: 38).
concerned about dependency on hand-outs Much like many of the rationales behind micro-
might be appeased by the fact that recipients finance, this essentializes gendered roles such
have to ‘earn’ their grant by keeping their chil- as caring, maternal and responsible women in
dren in school and having them vaccinated contrast to unreliable men (Rankin, 2002;
(Fiszbein and Schady, 2009; Levy, 2006). The Young, 2010).
result of improved education, health and civic Upon his election to the presidency of the
responsibility will be improved human capacity World Bank in 2012, Jim Yong Kim confirmed
and, therefore, populations that are able to the Bank’s commitment to distributional inter-
advance themselves over the long term. Condi- ventions to tackle poverty. However, this does
tional cash transfers are, then, a form of govern- not signal mainstream development’s abandon-
mentality which enables authorities to try to ment of neoliberalism for welfarism. Proponents
‘shape the conduct of diverse actors without of free markets have always been reconciled to
shattering their formally autonomous character’ the need to intervene in the case of market failure
(Miller and Rose, 2008: 39; see also Hossain, (Collier, 2012; Esping-Andersen, 1999). In man-
2010; Li, 2007). Modest cash transfers give aging market failure, these policies do not aim to
households the freedom of consumers to meet decommodify people; that is, to reduce their
some of their needs, but place expectations on dependence on the market (Esping-Andersen,
them that they will find exit routes from poverty 1990; Taylor, 2009). The appearance of cash-
by making good health, education and civic based forms of social support is appealing to
choices to become more capable of earning an some economists not as a route to establishing
income (Hickey, 2010). more extensive redistribution but simply as a
This is consistent with the rhetoric of ‘eco- way of allowing support to become demand-
nomic freedom’ which underpins other kinds driven rather than supply-driven (Kharas and
of interventions such as microfinance (Roy, Rogerson, 2012). Grant payments are, by design,
2010: 21). As Roy points out, these notions of too modest to address poor households’ needs
freedom are normative in that they expect the fully. In a cover story announcing the welfare

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
816 Progress in Human Geography 37(6)

revolution in Asia, The Economist insisted that attached, shows that school attendances have
Asian governments had learned from the mis- improved as a result of cash alone (Hanlon
takes of other welfare experiments and ‘have lit- et al., 2010; Lund et al., 2009). Some are also
tle desire to replace traditions of hard work and in favour of universal grants, and against means
thrift with a flabby welfare dependency’ testing which has long been criticized by social
(2012a: 9). democrats for stigmatizing the poor (Adésı́nà,
2007). The possibility of ‘social democracy for
the tropics’ (Leftwich, 2005: 597) appears, for
IV An un-Fordist compact? some, to be on the cards (see also Sandbrook
While advocates of liberalized economic et al., 2007; Vellinga, 2007).
growth cautiously embrace cash transfers, those Yet contemporary projects for social democ-
of a more social democratic orientation hope to racy need to contend with very different circum-
install a global social contract which helps gov- stances to those of the 20th century, in which the
ernments to meet basic human rights and bounded national state was regarded as the
achieve social justice (ILO, 2008). The ILO and appropriate geographical frame for mechanisms
other organizations have launched the ‘Social of distributional justice (Fraser, 2008). Trade
Security for All’ campaign, which proposes a liberalization obviates the possibility of passing
‘global social protection floor’. Cash transfers on the costs of good conditions of employment
would form part of a package of cash and to investors and consumers (Seekings, 2008b).
service-based mechanisms to put in place a ‘vir- Financial liberalization allows capital flight and
tuous circle of development that provides an the escape of what should be national wealth
exit route from poverty’ (ILO, 2011: 12). The (Fine et al., 2011). Mass unemployment means
ILO argues that even relatively poor countries more people living in poverty and proportion-
can afford to make progressive improvements ally fewer taxpayers, and therefore that welfare
to the coverage and quality of social protection will be spread thinly over the large ‘residuum’.
over time through their own revenue and with Although the contemporary development zeit-
the support of international donors (ILO, geist has given renewed priority to the problem
2008). Yet most of the world’s poor are now of under-consumption, there is little interest in
located in middle-income countries (Sumner, curbing over-consumption or instituting puni-
2012) with increasing financial resources to tive redistribution. As demonstrated by litera-
devote to poverty reduction. Famously, the ture reviewed in the first report in this series
Bolsa Famı´lia in Brazil costs 0.5% of the GDP, (Ballard, 2012), states regard successful accu-
reaches a quarter of the population and has mulation by middle classes and elites as part
contributed to a reduction in income inequality of the good story of the economic growth and
(Palma, 2011). through which the global South is taking on a
There is now a vocal lobby which argues that ‘developed’ status (see also Chatterjee, 2008).
social protection can become redistributive if it If new experiments in social policy do consti-
is made to reach progressively more people with tute a revolution, then they might best be
more money and services (Adésı́nà, 2007; Bar- described with Gramsci’s notion of a ‘passive
rientos and Hulme, 2009; Devereux and revolution’ (Morton, 2013), which entails top-
Sabates-Wheeler, 2004; Hanlon et al., 2010; down responses to bottom-up demands, so that
Mkandawire, 2004; Vellinga, 2007). This lobby existing elites can manage the inclusion of
rejects the need for conditions, which it argues marginalized groups rather than lose control as
are redundant anyway. The South African Child they would in a conventional revolution. Many
Support Grant, which does not have conditions programmes originated with progressive

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Ballard 817

technocrats who, in their creation of schemes, upon the poor themselves and use grants to alter
bypassed not only the intended beneficiaries but the behaviour of the poor. Enthusiasm for what
also civil society and parts of government itself Roy (2010: 73) calls ‘the democratization of
(Fenwick, 2009; Houtzager, 2008; Li, 2009; capital’ obscures important truths such as how
Lund, 2008). This top-down emphasis does not poverty is produced, and how women are bur-
negate the possibility of significant gains for the dened with the responsibilities for poverty. The
poor. Ferguson and Li have both argued that this role of cash transfers within broader structures
moment represents an important opening for the of social reproduction has emerged as a funda-
implementation of life-sustaining distributional mental development problem.
mechanisms, regardless of whether they might
come from above or be recognizably neoliberal Acknowledgements
(Ferguson, 2007, 2009, 2012; Li, 2009). I am very grateful for the editorial guidance of Vicky
The poor do have political influence, cer- Lawson and for the inputs by Matt Birkinshaw,
Sharad Chari, Kerry Chance, Gill Hart, Mark Hunter,
tainly. Parties that intend to gain or retain power
Margaret Jack, Francie Lund, Gregory Morton and
need to confront poverty in visible ways. They
Dori Posel on earlier drafts.
use distribution systems to ward off ‘extre-
mism’ (Li, 2009) and ‘contain dissent’ (Hart, References
2006: 991). Yet, as Boito (2010) argues in the Adésı́nà JO (2007) Social policy and the quest for inclusive
case of Brazil, the power of the poor is limited development: Research findings from sub-Saharan
because they hand responsibility for improve- Africa. Social Policy and Development Programme
ments to the state. The extent to which social Paper 33. Geneva: United Nations Research Institute
movements and other popular groupings mobi- for Social Development.
lize around the protection, design, implementa- Agnew J (2009) Money games: Currencies and power in
tion and uptake of systems of social protection the contemporary world economy. Antipode 41:
will determine whether or not cash transfers 214–238.
Bähre E (2011) Liberation and redistribution: Social
become a site of ‘biopolitical struggle’ (Chari,
grants, commercial insurance, and religious riches in
2010). This, and other forms of development
South Africa. Comparative Studies in Society and
by the poor, will be the subject of the final report History 53: 371–392.
in this series. Bakker I and Gill S (2003) Ontology, method, and hypoth-
eses. In: Bakker I and Gill S (eds) Power, Production
and Social Reproduction: Human In/Security in the
V Conclusion Global Political Economy. Basingstoke: Palgrave Mac-
Cash transfers have been championed by a social millan, 17–41.
justice lobby which recognizes that the poor do Bakker I and Silvey R (2008) Beyond States and Market:
not bear complete responsibility for their poverty The Challenges of Social Reproduction. Abingdon:
and that universal, non-conditional and increas- Routledge.
ingly generous distributional systems are Ballard R (2012) Geographies of development: Without
the poor. Progress in Human Geography 36: 562–571.
required to achieve social justice and human
Barchiesi F (2011) Precarious Liberation: Workers, the
rights. However, as literature on postneoliberal-
State, and Contested Social Citizenship in Postapart-
ism shows, there is no easy return to the welfare heid South Africa. Scottsville: University of
state’s ‘ascending road of social betterment’ (Tit- KwaZulu-Natal Press.
muss, 1958: 34) after the detour of neoliberalism. Barrientos A and Hulme D (2009) Social protection for the
Cash transfers have also been enfolded within poor and poorest in developing countries: Reflections
mainstream development approaches which on a quiet revolution. Oxford Development Studies
locate responsibility for transcending poverty 37: 439–456.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
818 Progress in Human Geography 37(6)

Bebbington A and Humphreys Bebbington D (2011) An Esping-Andersen G (1999) Social Foundations of Postin-
Andean avatar: Post-neoliberal and neoliberal strate- dustrial Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
gies for securing the unobtainable. New Political Econ- Fenwick TB (2009) Avoiding governors: The success of
omy 16: 131–145. Bolsa Famı́lia. Latin American Research Review 44:
Bezuidenhout A and Fakier K (2006) Maria’s burden: 102–131.
Contract cleaning and the crisis of social reproduction Ferguson J (2007) Formalities of poverty: Thinking about
in post-apartheid South Africa. Antipode 38: 462–485. social assistance in neoliberal South Africa. African
Boito A (2010) Social class and politics in Brazil: From Studies Review 50: 71–86.
Cardoso to Lula. In: Saad-Filho A and Yalman GL Ferguson J (2009) The uses of neoliberalism. Antipode 41:
(eds) Economic Transitions to Neoliberalism in 166–184.
Middle-Income Countries: Policy Dilemmas, Eco- Ferguson J (2012) What comes after the social? Historiciz-
nomic Crises, Forms of Resistance. Abingdon: Routle- ing the future of social assistance and identity registra-
dge, 190–201. tion in Africa. In: Breckenridge K and Szreter S (eds)
Brand U and Sekler N (2009) Postneoliberalism: Catch-all Registration and Recognition: Documenting the Per-
word or valuable analytical and political concept? Aims son in World History. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
of a beginning debate. Development Dialogue 51: 5–14. 495–516.
Breckenridge K (2005) The biometric state: The promise Fine B, Ashman S and Newman S (2011) Amnesty interna-
and peril of digital government in the new South Africa. tional? The nature, scale and impact of capital flight
Journal of Southern African Studies 31: 267–282. from South Africa. Journal of Southern African Studies
Brenner N, Peck J and Theodore N (2010) Variegated neo- 37: 7–25.
liberalization: Geographies, modalities, pathways. Glo- Fiszbein A and Schady N (2009) Conditional Cash Trans-
bal Networks 10: 182–222. fers: Reducing Present and Future Poverty. Washing-
Cameron MA (2009) Latin America’s left turns: Beyond ton, DC: The World Bank.
good and bad. Third World Quarterly 30: 331–348. Foucault M (2008) The Birth of Biopolitics. Basingstoke:
Chari S (2010) State racism and biopolitical struggle: The Palgrave Macmillan.
evasive commons in twentieth-century Durban, South Fraser N (2008) Scales of Justice: Reimagining Political
Africa. Radical History Review 108: 73–90. Space in a Globalizing World. Cambridge: Polity.
Chatterjee P (2008) Democracy and economic transforma- Gibbs T (2006) Business as usual: What the Chavez era
tion in India. Economic and Political Weekly 19 April: [Venezuela] tells us about democracy under globalisa-
53–62. tion. Third World Quarterly 27: 265–279.
Collier SJ (2012) Neoliberalism as big Leviathan, or . . . ? Giovannini F (2008) Towards an intellectual leadership:
A response to Wacquant and Hilgers. Social Anthropol- Rediscovering the role of the United Nations in the
ogy 20: 186–195. 21st century. Planning Theory and Practice 9:
Community Agency for Social Enquiry (CASE) (2008) 254–260.
Review of the Child Support Grant: Uses, Implementa- Goldfrank B (2009) Neoliberalism and the left: National
tion and Obstacles. Johannesburg: CASE. challenges, local responses, and global alternatives. In:
Craig D and Porter D (2006) Development Beyond Neoli- Burdick J, Oxhorn P and Roberts KM (eds) Beyond Neo-
beralism? Governance, Poverty Reduction and Politi- liberalism in Latin America? Societies and Politics at the
cal Economy. Abingdon: Routledge. Crossroads. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 43–60.
Denning M (2010) Wageless life. New Left Review 66: Grugel J and Riggirozzi P (2012) Post-neoliberalism in
79–97. Latin America: Rebuilding and reclaiming the state
Devereux S and Sabates-Wheeler R (2004) Transforma- after crisis. Development and Change 43: 1–21.
tive social protection. Working Paper 232. Brighton: Gupta A (2012) Red Tape: Bureaucracy, Structural
Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex. Violence, and Poverty in India. Durham, NC: Duke
Ellis F, Devereux S and White P (2009) Social Protection University Press.
in Africa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Hanlon J, Barrientos A and Hulme D (2010) Just Give
Esping-Andersen G (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Money to the Poor: The Development Revolution from
Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity. the Global South. Sterling, VA: Kumarian Press.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Ballard 819

Hannah MG (2012) Biopower, life and left politics. Anti- Leftwich A (2005) Politics in command: Development
pode 43: 1034–1055. studies and the rediscovery of social science. New
Hart G (2002) Disabling Globalization: Places of Power in Political Economy 10: 573–607.
Post-apartheid South Africa. Pietermaritzburg: Univer- Leiva FI (2008) Latin American Neostructuralism: Con-
sity of Natal Press. tradictions of Post-Neoliberal Development. Minnea-
Hart G (2006) Denaturalizing dispossession: Critical eth- polis, MN: Minnesota University Press.
nography in the age of resurgent imperialism. Antipode Levy S (2006) Progress Against Poverty: Sustaining Mex-
38: 977–1004. ico’s Progresa-Oportunidades Program. Washington,
Hart G (2009) D/developments after the meltdown. Anti- DC: Brookings Institution Press.
pode 41: 117–141. Li TM (2007) The Will to Improve: Governmentality,
Hickey S (2010) The government of chronic poverty: From Development and the Practice of Politics. Durham,
exclusion to citizenship? Journal of Development Stud- NC: Duke University Press.
ies 46: 1139–1155. Li TM (2009) To make live or let die? Rural dispossession
Hossain N (2010) School exclusion as social exclusion: and the protection of surplus populations. Antipode 41:
The practices and effects of a conditional cash transfer 66–93.
programme for the poor in Bangladesh. Journal of Lloyd-Sherlock P, Saboia J and Ramı́rez-Rodrı́guez B
Development Studies 46: 1264–1282. (2012) Cash transfers and the well-being of older peo-
Houtzager PP (2008) The silent revolution in anti-poverty ple in Brazil. Development and Change 43(5):
programmes: Minimum income guarantees in Brazil. 1049–1072.
IDS Bulletin 38: 56–63. Luna JP and Filgueira F (2009) The left turns as multiple
Hunter M (2011) Beneath the ‘Zunami’: Jacob Zuma and paradigmatic crises. Third World Quarterly 30:
the gendered politics of social reproduction in South 371–395.
Africa. Antipode 43: 1102–1126. Lund F (2008) Changing Social Policy: The Child Support
Huxley M (2007) Geographies of governmentality. In: Grant in South Africa. Cape Town: HSRC Press.
Crampton JW and Elden S (eds) Space, Power and Lund F (2012) Children, citizenship and child support: The
Knowledge: Foucault and Geography. Aldershot: Ash- Child Support Grant in post-apartheid South Africa. In:
gate, 185–204. Breckenridge K and Szreter S (eds) Registration and
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2008) Can low- Recognition: Documenting the Person in World His-
income countries afford basic social security? Social tory. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 475–494.
Security Policy Briefings Paper 3. Geneva: ILO. Lund F, Noble M Barnes H, et al. (2009) Is there a rationale
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2010) World for conditional cash transfers for children in South
Social Security Report 2010/11: Providing Coverage Africa? Transformation 70: 70–91.
in Times of Crisis and Beyond. Geneva: ILO. Macdonald L and Ruckert A (2009) Post-neoliberalism in
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2011) Social the Americas: An introduction. In: Macdonald L and
Protection Floor for a Fair and Inclusive Globaliza- Ruckert A (eds) Post-Neoliberalism in the Americas.
tion. Geneva: ILO. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 1–18.
Jessop B (2010) The continuing ecological dominance of Meltzer J (2009) Hugo Chávez and the search for post-
neoliberalism in the crisis. In: Saad-Filho A and Yal- neoliberal policy alternatives in Venezuela. In: Macdo-
man GL (eds) Economic Transitions to Neoliberalism nald L and Ruckert A (eds) Post-Neoliberalism in the
in Middle-income Countries: Policy Dilemmas, Eco- Americas. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 89–104.
nomic Crises, Forms of Resistance. Abingdon: Routle- Miller P and Rose N (2008) Governing the Present. Cam-
dge, 24–38. bridge: Polity.
Katz C (2004) Growing up Global: Economic Restructur- Mkandawire T (2004) Social policy in a development con-
ing and Children’s Everyday Lives. Minneapolis, MN: text: Introduction. In: Mkandawire T (ed.) Social Pol-
University of Minnesota Press. icy in a Development Context. Basingstoke: Palgrave
Kharas H and Rogerson A (2012) Horizon 2025: Creative Macmillan, 1–33.
Destruction in the Aid Industry. London: Overseas Molyneux M (2008) Conditional cash transfers: A ‘path-
Development Institute. way to women’s empowerment’? Pathways Working

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
820 Progress in Human Geography 37(6)

Paper 5. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies, Seekings J (2008a) Deserving individuals and groups: The
University of Sussex. post-apartheid state’s justification of the shape of South
Morton AD (2013) Traveling with Gramsci: The spatiality Africa’s system of social assistance. Transformation
of passive revolution. In: Ekers M, Hart G Kipfer S, 68: 28–52.
et al. (eds) Gramsci: Space, Nature, Politics. Malden, Seekings J (2008b) Welfare regimes and redistribution in
MA: Wiley-Blackwell, 47–64. the South. In: Shapiro I, Swenson PA and Donno D
Ong A (2006) Neoliberalism as Exception: Mutations in (eds) Divide and Deal: The Politics of Distribution in
Citizenship and Sovereignty. Durham, NC: Duke Democracies. New York: New York University Press,
University Press. 19–42.
Palma JG (2011) Homogeneous middles vs. heterogeneous Smith G (2011) Selective hegemony and beyond, popula-
tails, and the end of the ‘Inverted-U’: It’s all about the tions with ‘no productive function’: A framework for
share of the rich. Development and Change 42: 87–153. enquiry. Identities 18: 2–38.
Parnell S and Robinson J (2012) (Re)theorizing cities from Soares FV, Ribas RP and Osório RG (2010) Evaluating the
the global South: Looking beyond neoliberalism. impact of Brazil’s Bolsa Famı́lia: Cash transfer pro-
Urban Geography 33: 593–617. grams in comparative perspective. Latin American
Peck J and Theodore N (2010) Recombinant workfare, Research Review 45: 193–190.
across the Americas: Transnationalizing ‘fast’ social Soares S (2012) Bolsa Famı́lia, its design, its impacts and
policy. Geoforum 41: 195–208. possibilities for the future. Working Paper 98. Brasilia:
Peck J, Theodore N and Brenner N (2009) Postneoli- Institute for Applied Economic Research, International
beralism and its malcontents. Antipode 41(s1): Policy Center for Inclusive Growth.
94–116. Standing G (2011) The Precariat: The New Dangerous
Posel D, Fairburn J and Lund F (2006) Labour migration Class. London: Bloomsbury Academic.
and households: A reconsideration of the effects of the Sumner A (2012) Where do the world’s poor live? A new
social pension on labour supply in South Africa. Eco- update. IDS Working Paper 393. Brighton: Institute of
nomic Modelling 23: 836–853. Development Studies, University of Sussex.
Rankin K (2002) Social capital, microfinance, and the pol- Szreter S and Breckenridge K (2012) Editors’ introduc-
itics of development. Journal of Feminist Economics 8: tion: Recognition and registration: The infrastructure
1–24. of personhood in world history. In: Breckenridge K and
Roberts A (2008) Privatizing social reproduction: The pri- Szreter S (eds) Registration and Recognition: Docu-
mitive accumulation of water in an era of neoliberal- menting the Person in World History. Oxford: Oxford
ism. Antipode 40: 535–560. University Press, 1–36.
Roy A (2008) Global norms and planning forms: The Mil- Taylor M (2006) From Pinochet to the ‘Third Way’:
lennium Development Goals. Planning Theory and Neoliberalism and Social Transformation in Chile.
Practice 9: 251–274. London: Pluto Press.
Roy A (2010) Poverty Capital: Microfinance and the Mak- Taylor M (2009) The contradictions and transformations
ing of Development. New York: Routledge. of neoliberalism in Latin America: From structural
Ruckert A (2009) The World Bank and the poverty reduc- adjustment to ‘empowering the poor’. In: Macdonald
tion strategy of Nicaragua: Toward a post-neoliberal L and Ruckert A (eds) Post-Neoliberalism in the Amer-
world development order? In: Macdonald L and icas. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 21–36.
Ruckert A (eds) Post-Neoliberalism in the Americas. Thaler RH and Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: Improving
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 135–150. Decisions About Health, Wealth and Happiness. New
Sandbrook R (2011) Polanyi and post-neoliberalism in the Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Global South: Dilemmas of reembedding the economy. The Economist (2012a) Asia’s next revolution. 8
New Political Economy 16: 415–443. September: 9.
Sandbrook R, Edelman M Heller P, et al. (2007) Social The Economist (2012b) Indian politics: Unfinished
Democracy in the Global Periphery: Origins, Chal- journey. 24 March: 25–27.
lenges, Prospects. Cambridge: Cambridge University Titmuss R (1958) Essays on the Welfare State. London:
Press. George Allen and Unwin.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014
Ballard 821

Vellinga M (2007) Social democratisation and development Woolard I and Leibbrandt M (2010) The evolution and
strategy: An alternative to neoliberalisation in Latin impact of unconditional cash transfers in South Africa.
America? Journal of Third World Studies 24: 85–107. Working Paper 51. Cape Town: South Africa Labour
Vetterlein A (2012) Seeing like the World Bank on pov- and Development Research Unit, University of Cape
erty. New Political Economy 17: 35–58. Town.
Watts MJ (2009) Now and then. Antipode 41: 10–26. Woolcock M (2012) Dueling development visions:
Webber JR (2009) From naked barbarism to barbarism Shaping the World Bank for the future. Blog: Let’s
with benefits: Neoliberal capitalism, natural gas policy, Talk Development, World Bank. Available at:
and the Evo Morales government in Bolivia. In: Mac- http://blogs.worldbank.org/developmenttalk/dueling-
donald L and Ruckert A (eds) Post-Neoliberalism in the development-visions-shaping-the-world-bank-for-the-
Americas. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 105–119. future.
Williams G, Thampi BV Narayana D, et al. (2012) The poli- Young S (2010) The ‘moral hazards’ of microfinance:
tics of defining and alleviating poverty: State strategies Restructuring rural credit in India. Antipode 42:
and their impacts in rural Kerala. Geoforum 43: 991–1001. 201–223.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at NATIONAL CHUNG HSING UNIV on March 26, 2014

You might also like