You are on page 1of 16

Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Advances in Accounting
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/adiac

Ownership type and earnings management in U.S. hospitals☆


James N. Cannon a, Melvin A. Lamboy-Ruiz b, Olena V. Watanabe c, *
a
Utah State University, United States of America
b
Georgia Southern University, United States of America
c
Iowa State University, United States of America

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: We examine variation in accrual-based and real earnings management in U.S. hospitals by ownership type, using
Hospitals a stable comprehensive sample of hospitals from 2011 through 2016. We expect managers' reporting incentives
Earnings management to differ between ownership type (for-profit versus non-profit), resulting in differing uses of accrual and real
Non-profit organizations
earnings manipulations. First, we document that non-profit hospitals exhibit lower levels of both income-
increasing and income-decreasing earnings manipulations than for-profit hospitals do. Second, we find that
compared to non-profit hospitals, for-profit hospital managers use discretionary accruals (in particular) to create
larger reserves when pre-managed earnings are high and to increase reported earnings more when pre-managed
earnings are low. Together, these findings suggest that, relative to non-profit hospital managers, for-profit
hospital managers have incentives to report higher and more consistent earnings.

1. Introduction maximization incentives set by capital providers, non-profits have


break-even profitability expectations that result from offsetting in­
This study examines how ownership type (for-profit versus non- centives to sustain operations, on the one hand, and to serve under­
profit) shapes accrual and real earnings management in U.S. hospi­ privileged constituencies, on the other (Balakrishnan, Eldenburg,
tals.1 Given the economic and social significance of the hospital sector, Krishnan, & Soderstrom, 2010; Eldenburg, Gunny, Hee, & Soderstrom,
representing approximately $3 trillion, 17.5%, and $9523 per capita of 2011).2
the 2014 U.S. gross domestic product (Eldenburg, Krishnan, & Krishnan, In direct contrast to for-profit organizations, non-profits are pro­
2017), it is important to study hospitals' reporting quality. When eval­ hibited from distributing residual income to internal or external stake­
uating reporting quality of U.S. hospitals, contrasting for-profit and non- holders (Eldenburg, Gaertner, & Goodman, 2015). However, despite this
profit hospitals is relevant because, while for-profits face profit- mission constraint, empirical evidence has reliably demonstrated that


We thank the Editor and the anonymous referee, Mark Bagnoli, Katheryn Jervis, Sue Ravenscroft, Casey Rowe, Naomi Soderstrom, Susan Watts, and the
anonymous reviewers for the 2020 AAA Annual Meeting and the 2020 AAA Diversity Section Meeting for their insightful comments and suggestions. We also thank
participants at the workshops at Cornell University, Iowa State University, Oklahoma State University, Purdue University, University of Illinois–Chicago, the 2013
AAA Government and Non-profit Midyear Meeting, the 2013 AAA Annual Meeting, and the 2016 AAA Management Section Midyear Meeting.
* Corresponding author.
E-mail address: watanabe@iastate.edu (O.V. Watanabe).
1
Unlike for-profit hospitals, non-profit hospitals do not have a standard set of owners, so perhaps referring to hospital mission would more aptly identify the
differences in non-profit and for-profit hospital behavior. However, to be consistent with the terminology used in existing literature (e.g., Eldenburg et al., 2017), we
delineate these two types of hospitals with the term ownership.
2
In contrast to the limited earnings management research in the healthcare industry, there is a substantial stream of empirical literature that documents accrual
and real earnings management across industries in for-profit settings (see the review in Dechow et al., 2010).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.adiac.2022.100612
Received 22 September 2021; Received in revised form 20 May 2022; Accepted 10 June 2022
Available online 24 June 2022
0882-6110/© 2022 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

non-profit hospitals and other non-profit organizations have incentives ROS). In contrast, for higher levels of pre-managed ROS (quintiles 3, 4
to maintain economic viability by improving their operating perfor­ and 5), for-profit hospitals engage in income-decreasing earnings man­
mance, which often effectively emulates the incentive contracts of for- agement to a greater degree than non-profit hospitals. Together with our
profit firms (Brickley & Van Horn, 2002; Duggan, 2000; Eldenburg analyses of earnings dispersion, these findings suggest that non-profit
et al., 2011; Nguyen & Soobaroyen, 2019). At the same time, non-profit hospitals' managers use less earnings manipulation to increase or
hospital managers are subject to institutional pressures from patients, decrease earnings than do for-profit managers, and that for-profit
donors, employees, and government authorities to offer social benefits managers have greater incentives to report consistent earnings than
(Krishnan & Yetman, 2011). Thus, non-profit managers may attract non-profit managers have.
unwanted regulatory and/or social attention if they report high earn­ Our study contributes to the existing literature in that it provides
ings.3 A manager who wishes to avoid such examination is motivated to generalizable large-sample evidence of divergent earnings management
report low earnings. Therefore, their optimal reporting target may be at behavior between non-profit and for-profit hospitals in the U.S. Most of
or only slightly above zero. Empirical evidence to date documents that the existing empirical literature focuses on one state, such as California
non-profit managers do engage in accrual-based and real earnings ma­ or Maryland (e.g., Heese, 2018; Vansant, 2015; Vermeer, Edmonds, &
nipulations to reach predetermined targets (e.g., Eldenburg et al., 2011; Asthana, 2014), and non-profit hospitals alone (e.g., Eldenburg et al.,
Leone & Van Horn, 2005; Vansant, 2015). 2011; Leone & Van Horn, 2005; Vansant, 2015). In contrast, we examine
However, there have been concerns expressed in the media and over a period of six years a constant set of hospitals from 50 states and
among government officials that non-profit hospitals may be behaving the District of Columbia. By directly contrasting earnings management
like their for-profit counterparts by taking advantage of tax exemptions practices in for-profit hospitals with such practices in non-profit hospi­
to maximize earnings (e.g., Everson, 2005; Kassab, 2016; Phillips, 2007; tals, we provide evidence of how hospital ownership type influences
Rosenthal, 2013; Sesana, 2014), particularly after the implementation of reporting behavior. Specifically, we confirm a potential societal benefit
the Affordable Care Act (ACA) which may have increased revenue for to non-profit ownership––namely, that managers are less prone to
hospitals from insured patients (Diamond, 2017; Japsen, 2015). Such earnings management.
concerns motivate us to draw a clear distinction between earnings The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In section two, we review
management behavior in for-profit and non-profit hospitals. In this existing literature and set up our hypotheses. Section three describes our
paper, we investigate how accrual-based and real activities earnings empirical model and variables. In section four we describe our sample
management differ between for-profit and non-profit hospitals. Specif­ selection. We present empirical findings in section five, and in section six
ically, we compare the magnitudes of income-increasing and income- we summarize our study and report our conclusions.
decreasing accrual earnings manipulations, real patient service cost
earnings management, and real discretionary cost earnings 2. Literature review and hypotheses development
management.
To perform our analyses, we examine data from a large stable sample 2.1. Ownership type and earnings management
of U.S. for-profit and non-profit hospitals from 2011 through 2016. First,
we examine pre-managed and reported earnings (return on sales, or Accounting literature argues that managers use both accrual and real
ROS) of each ownership type in total and by the quintile of pre-managed activities manipulations to meet predetermined financial targets (e.g.,
ROS.4 We observe that positive pre-managed ROS is statistically signif­ Bartov, 1993; Burgstahler & Dichev, 1997; Dechow, Richardson, &
icantly higher in for-profits hospitals (quintiles 2–5); while negative pre- Tuna, 2003; Degeorge, Patel, & Zeckhauser, 1999; Herrmann, Inoue, &
managed ROS is significantly lower in for-profit hospitals (quintile 1). In Thomas, 2003; Roychowdhury, 2006). Moreover, a majority of corpo­
contrast, across all quintiles, for-profit hospital managers report signif­ rate managers surveyed stated that the primary reason companies
icantly higher and smoother ROS than do non-profit managers. Specif­ manage earnings is to meet predetermined benchmarks (Dichev, Gra­
ically, the standard deviation of reported ROS is lower than the standard ham, Harvey, & Rajgopal, 2013; Graham, Harvey, & Rajgopal, 2005).
deviation of pre-managed ROS in for-profits, while for non-profits there Furthermore, experimental evidence shows that for-profit company ex­
is no difference in the dispersion of pre-managed and reported ROS. ecutives and recruiting professionals prefer to hire accounting managers
Second, in our multiple regression analysis, we find that non-profit with dark personality traits (i.e., high narcissism, high Machiavel­
hospitals engage in lower levels of both income-increasing and lianism, low idealism), presumably because people with such traits are
income-decreasing discretionary accruals and real activities earnings more likely to engage in earnings management (Buchholz, Lopatta, &
manipulations than for-profit hospitals do.5 Further, we find that for- Mass, 2019; Harris, Jackson, Owens, & Seybert, 2021; Van Scotter &
profit hospitals adjust their negative pre-managed earnings up to a Roglio, 2020).
greater degree than non-profit hospitals do (quintile 1 of pre-managed Whether managers of non-profit organizations face incentives to
manage earnings in a fashion similar to those of for-profit organizations
is less clear (Eldenburg et al., 2017). Managers of for-profit entities,
3 including for-profit hospitals, have a primary goal of providing owners a
In some cases, state governments have perceived the under-provision of
public benefits to be sufficiently significant to challenge and subsequently
return on their investment, as communicated by reporting a steady
revoke a hospital's non-profit status. For instance, in 2008, the Illinois Fourth stream of increasing earnings (Demerjian, Lewis-Western, & McVay,
District Court of Appeals ruled that Provena Covenant Medical Center did not 2020). While non-profit hospitals are not constrained by the objective to
provide enough charity care in 2002 to merit $1.1 million in property tax generate a return on equity (Conrad, 1984; Forgione, 1999), they are
exemption (in Provena Covenant Medical Center v. the [Illinois] Department of rarely able to rely on subsidies and donations alone but must also rely on
Revenue). The ruling by the appellate court was upheld on March 18, 2010, by patient service revenues to sustain their operations (Balakrishnan et al.,
the Illinois Supreme Court (see http://www.illinoiscourts.gov/opinions/supre 2010; Eldenburg et al., 2017). Notably, the ACA implemented in 2012
mecourt/2010/march/107328.pdf). Further, a recent study by Bai, Zare, includes a reduction in subsidies received through the DSH program
Eisenberg, Polsky, and Anderson (2021), demonstrates that hospitals' charity (Kaiser Family Foundation, 2017), further limiting hospitals' revenue-
care expenditures do not seem to align with their charitable mission.
4 generating ability.
While hospitals do not report sales, but rather service revenues, for con­
However, stakeholders also expect managers of non-profit hospitals
venience we refer to net income scaled by net revenues as return on sales.
5
By “lower levels,” we imply that those income-increasing accruals are closer
to zero in magnitude. Similarly, lower levels of income-decreasing accruals are
also closer to zero in magnitude. The same interpretation holds for real activ­
ities earnings management.

2
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

to provide public benefits. In exchange for providing public benefits, a the effect of differing ownership type on reporting behavior.
non-profit organization is exempt from paying taxes.6 Given that tax
exemption is a benefit from the government in exchange for distributing 2.2. Income-increasing earnings management
profits in the form of uncompensated care, non-profit hospital stake­
holders do not expect such hospitals to generate and retain high earn­ Given stakeholders' different expectations for earnings from for-
ings. In fact, experimental evidence shows that respondents react profit and non-profit hospitals, we anticipate that the non-profit man­
negatively to a non-profit's tax-exempt status when it reports high profits ager's task of reporting earnings at or slightly above zero would require a
(Wilkicki, 2001). If a non-profit hospital's manager were to report different strategy of earnings management than the for-profit manager's
excessive profits, the hospital would risk having to pay federal excise tax task of consistently reporting positive earnings. For instance, both non-
or even losing its federal or state tax-exempt status. Therefore, to remain profit managers and for-profit managers may find themselves in a situ­
true to their mission and yet to appear to be financially viable, non-profit ation where (pre-managed) economic earnings are slightly below zero. A
managers' optimal strategy might be to report zero or very small positive non-profit manager may wish to increase reported earnings to zero in
earnings. Indeed, Leone and Van Horn (2005) show that non-profit order for the firm to appear as a going concern. Once assured that the
hospitals use discretionary spending and discretionary accruals to non-profit hospital is economically viable, the hospital's stakeholders
manage earnings to near-zero reported levels. Wen, Huang, Shen, and may interpret the lack of profitability as evidence that the hospital is
Zhang (2019) find that non-profit Taiwanese hospitals not only spending resources to benefit the community. In contrast, a for-profit
manipulate discretionary real expenditures, but also manipulate core manager's stakeholders are unlikely to accept zero reported earnings
activity expenditures to meet earnings benchmarks. because that signals a poor return on their financial investment, so a for-
In a related study that examines a sample of California non-profit profit manager has an additional incentive to report positive earnings.
hospitals, Eldenburg et al. (2011) show that hospital managers manip­ Continuing our discussion of incentives relating to performance,
ulate earnings by adjusting costly activities in non-core areas, that is, efficient compensation contracts have the ability to align managerial
expenditure manipulations and asset management to achieve small effort with stakeholders' interests (Banker, Lee, Potter, & Srinivasan,
positive income or to avoid large positive income. Eldenburg et al. 1996; Hemmer, 1993; John & John, 1993; Mehran, 1995; Wallace,
(2011) argue that non-profits try to avoid reporting high income in order 1997). Consequently, we expect that for-profit hospital managers are
to escape scrutiny from government officials and other stakeholders. In a partially compensated based on earnings, given that for-profit organi­
similar setting, Vansant (2015) argues for and provides evidence zations' stakeholders are generally interested in receiving a financial
consistent with nonprofit hospital managers' use of income-increasing return on their investment. Thus, in addition to providing a return to
discretionary accruals to report higher profits when charity care meets owners, we also expect for-profit hospital managers to engage in
or exceeds external stakeholders' expectations. Therefore, empirical income-increasing earnings management to maximize their personal
evidence to date supports the argument that managers of non-profit compensation, (e.g., Guidry, Leone, & Rock, 1999; Healy, 1985;
hospitals use both accrual-based and real activities earnings manage­ Holthausen, Larcker, & Sloan, 1995).
ment tools to meet zero or profitable benchmark expectations. Like for-profit managers, non-profit managers may also have in­
In contrast to our expectation that non-profit hospitals manage centives to be efficient operationally (Leone & Van Horn, 2005; Vansant,
earnings to a lower target than for-profit hospitals do, a paper by Ver­ 2015). Eldenburg and Krishnan (2008) argue and find evidence that in
meer et al. (2014) examines the aggressiveness of financial reporting in a response to compensation incentives, non-profit managers demand in­
sample of Maryland non-profit and for-profit firms using actuarial as­ formation about cost reduction and about equipment and operating
sumptions for defined benefit pension plans.7Vermeer et al. (2014) show expenditures. Moreover, existing empirical evidence also suggests that
that non-profit managers select more aggressive actuarial assumptions non-profit CEOs' compensation is related to financial performance
than for-profit managers, effectively reducing pension liabilities and (Brickley & Van Horn, 2002; Eldenburg & Krishnan, 2008; Lambert &
inflating reported earnings. The authors argue that this aggressiveness is Larcker, 1995). Furthermore, Eldenburg et al. (2015) show that finan­
due to the lack of regulatory oversight of non-profits compared to for- cial performance measures are prevalent within incentive compensation
profits. structures in large non-profit hospitals. The authors argue that a more
However, Vermeer et al. (2014) acknowledge that, in contrast with competitive environment and greater cost pressures have increased non-
other industries, non-profit and for-profit hospitals face similar regula­ profit hospitals' reliance on profit-based compensation contracts.
tory oversight. This similarity in oversight provides us the opportunity Consistent with their argument, Eldenburg et al. (2011) provide evi­
to build on the work done by Vansant (2015), which examines accrual dence that non-profit managers respond to profit-based compensation
earnings management in non-profit hospitals, and by Vermeer et al. incentives by using real activities manipulations that reduce
(2014), which compares a specific accrual estimate between for-profits expenditures.
and non-profits from various industries (and consequently, various However, unlike for-profit hospital managers, non-profit managers
regulatory environments). Further, we augment our comparison of also have incentives to conform to their hospitals' mission to provide
earnings management practices between for-profit and non-profit hos­ community benefits. Eldenburg et al. (2015) show that while for-profit
pitals by introducing real activities earnings management, following managers' compensation is negatively associated with the level of
work done by Eldenburg et al. (2011). Using the healthcare industry in charity care provided, non-profit managers are not penalized through
which regulatory oversight is relatively consistent (Eldenburg et al., compensation for charity care offerings. In addition, there is some evi­
2017) and in which managers have access to both accruals-based and dence that non-profit managers' compensation can be based on measures
real activities earnings management tools, we are better able to isolate that reduce earnings (Preyra & Pink, 2001). Thus, on average, we expect
non-profit managers to manipulate earnings using income-increasing
methods to a lesser degree than for-profit managers do. We formulate
6
Specifically, non-profit hospitals and healthcare centers are exempt from
hypothesis H1a as follows:
paying income, property, and sales tax in exchange for providing community H1a. : Income-increasing earnings management is lower in non-profit
benefits, such as uncompensated care, education, and outreach programs. hospitals than in for-profit hospitals.
7
Pension plan assumptions require a significant degree of judgment on a
manager's part. Furthermore, this judgment can have a significant impact on
reported earnings. For example, a modest change in an estimate, such as the 2.3. Income-decreasing earnings management
expected return on plan assets, can significantly affect reported earnings
(Bergstresser, Desai, and Rauh, 2006; Webster, 2004). Consider a situation where both for-profit and non-profit managers

3
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

have positive (pre-managed) economic earnings. In this case, a for-profit 3. Measurement of variables and model specification
manager's stakeholders may interpret the positive economic earnings as
evidence that the hospital is providing an adequate return on their Our main variables of interest are proxies for earnings management
financial investment. In contrast, a non-profit manager's stakeholders using discretionary accruals and real activities manipulations.
may infer from the profitability that the non-profit hospital is not ful­
filling its responsibility to provide community benefits to the degree that 3.1. Discretionary accruals manipulations
it could or should. Furthermore, profitable non-profit hospitals may be
pressured by third-party payers to reduce reimbursable charges and/or Following Heese (2018), we use the Jones (1991) discretionary ac­
may find a decrease in contributions by donors who do not see profitable cruals model to calculate discretionary accruals by estimating the
hospitals to be a charity in need (Leone & Van Horn, 2005). Thus, on following regression by hospital:
average, we expect non-profit managers to use income-decreasing
ACCt /At− = α0 + α1 1/At− 1 + α2 ΔNETREV t /At− 1 + α3 PPEt /At− 1 + εt (1)
earnings management methods to a greater degree than for-profit 1

managers do, as formally hypothesized below:


where ACCt/At− 1 is total accruals scaled by beginning-of-year total as­
H1b. : Income-decreasing earnings management is higher in non-profit sets. Following Hribar and Collins (2002), we compute total accruals
hospitals than in for-profit hospitals. (ACCt) as the change in current assets less change in current liabilities
adjusted for depreciation expense, change in cash, and change in short-
2.4. Inter-period earnings management term debt (i.e., ΔCA – ΔCL – ΔCASH + ΔSTDEBT – DEP EXP).8ΔNE­
TREVt/At− 1 is change in net patient revenue scaled by the beginning-of-
Our preceding discussion takes the perspective of a single period's year total assets balance. PPEt/At− 1 is gross property, plant, and equip­
performance. It is possible, though, that managers manipulate earnings ment also scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. The residuals from
to more consistently meet stakeholders' expectations over time (DeFond & model (1) proxy for abnormal accruals (AM), also referred to as
Park, 1997; Demerjian et al., 2020). Consider a situation where both a discretionary accruals.
non-profit and a for-profit hospital have negative pre-managed earnings.
Both the non-profit and for-profit managers may consider taking a “big 3.2. Real activities manipulations
bath” by creating reserves intended to increase or smooth future earn­
ings by booking additional income-decreasing accruals or by engaging in To estimate abnormal real activities, we use a model employed by
additional spending in that period of losses (Kirschenheiter & Melamud, Roychowdhury (2006), Zang (2012), and Heese (2018). We employ the
2002). However, in an earlier study, Holthausen et al. (1995) find no model to measure abnormal patient service costs and abnormal discre­
evidence that CEOs manage earnings downward when they do not meet tionary expenses by firm9:
performance benchmark minimums. Conversely, Haggard, Howe, and
PATSERV t /At− = β0 + β1 1/At− 1 + β2 NETREV t /At− 1 + τt (2)
Lynch (2015) show that earnings do become smoother after managers
1

engage in big bath behavior. DISX t /At− = γ 0 + γ 1 1/At− 1 + γ2 NETREV t− 1 /At− 1 + υt (3)
While it is likely that for-profit hospital managers and their stake­
1

holders benefit from reporting a smooth series of consistently growing where PATSERVt/At− 1 is patient service costs scaled by beginning-of-
earnings (Demerjian et al., 2020), we expect that these incentives are year total assets and DISXt/At− 1 is discretionary expenditures (sum of
generally smaller for non-profit managers and their stakeholders for two R&D and general and administrative expenses), scaled by beginning-of-
reasons. First, we do not expect that non-profit managers need to year total assets. NETREVt/At− 1 is net revenue scaled by beginning-of-
manage earnings upward to the same degree that for-profit managers do year total assets. The residual from model (2) is our proxy for
to satisfy stakeholders. Second, there is likely to be less scrutiny applied abnormal patient service costs, and the residual from model (3) is our
to a non-profit that reports negative earnings than to a for-profit hospital proxy for abnormal discretionary expenses.10 We split abnormal patient
that does. Consequently, when pre-managed earnings are negative, we service costs and abnormal discretionary expenses into separate proxies
expect non-profit managers to engage in income-increasing earnings for real earnings management because we expect that managers make
management to a lesser degree than for-profit managers do. different trade-offs when deciding whether to adjust patient-service-
H2a. : In cases of pre-managed losses, income-increasing earnings man­ related costs or discretionary expenditures. Specifically, we expect
agement is lower in non-profit hospitals than in for-profit hospitals. that hospital managers are less likely to reduce costs related to revenue-
generating patient care activities in an effort to increase reported
Now consider a situation where both a for-profit and a non-profit earnings. In contrast, managers may add discretionary costs, less likely
hospital have large positive pre-managed earnings. The for-profit and to generate revenue, as they strive to decrease reported earnings.
non-profit managers may consider creating reserves intended to defer Because positive discretionary costs and expenditures are opposite in
current earnings into future periods by booking income-decreasing ac­ their impact on earnings from positive values of discretionary accruals,
cruals or by engaging in additional spending (Guidry et al., 1999; Healy, consistent with Roychowdhury (2006) and Heese (2018), we multiply
1985; Holthausen et al., 1995). However, although non-profit managers discretionary patient service costs and discretionary expenditures by
may have an incentive to demonstrate that their hospitals are econom­ negative one to obtain our measures of real earnings management (RM1t
ically viable, we do not expect non-profit managers to derive benefit and RM2t). Hence, an increase (decrease) in AMt and an increase
from deferring current earnings into the future, as might be the case if (decrease) in RM1t or RM2t imply an increase (decrease) in earnings.
non-profit managers used income-decreasing accruals that reverse in a
future period. In contrast, for-profit hospital managers derive benefits
from maintaining a steady stream of consistently growing earnings 8
We employ a balance sheet approach to compute total accruals, because
(Demerjian et al., 2020). Consequently, when pre-managed earnings are MCRs do not include a statement of cash flows.
high, we expect non-profit managers to engage in income-decreasing 9
While Heese (2018) uses a predictive model for discretionary expenditures,
earnings management to a lesser degree than for-profit managers do. he does not use real earnings management through patient service costs.
10
Zang (2012) measures real earnings management as the sum of abnormal
H2b. : In cases of high pre-managed profits, income-decreasing earnings production costs and abnormal discretionary expenses. Instead of production
management is lower in non-profit hospitals than in for-profit hospitals. costs, we use patient service costs, which are the costs of medical care provided
to all patients. The values used for patient service costs are the gross costs re­
ported by hospitals, prior to any adjustments that may include accruals.

4
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

3.3. Hospital ownership measure might reduce earnings management (Dong, 2016; Eldenburg et al.,
2011; Heese, 2018; Morrisey, Wedig, & Hassan, 1996). Prior studies
Our dependent variable, designed to test H1a, H1b, and H2a, H2b, is have found that for-profit hospitals are smaller than non-profit hospitals,
a dichotomous variable NFP, which is set to one if the hospital is a non- further emphasizing the importance of controlling for size in our ana­
profit organization, and zero if the hospital is a for-profit organization lyses (Forgione, 1987; Forgione, Schiff, & Crumbley, 1996).
(Eldenburg & Krishnan, 2008). ROAt–1 is calculated by dividing the previous year's net income by
total assets as of the beginning of the previous year. We include ROAt–1
3.4. Model specification to account for the influence of firms' previous performance in setting a
benchmark for current-period earnings (Heese, 2018). We expect man­
To test our hypotheses we estimate the following ordinary least agers to be generally under more pressure to manage earnings upward
squares (OLS) regression11: when their previously reported performance was high and under more
pressure to manage earnings downward when previous performance
EM t = δ0 + δ1 NFP + δ2 NOAt–1 + δ3 Market Sharet− 1 + δ4 Sizet was low, to avoid ratcheting earnings expectations upward (Leone &
+ δ5 ROAt–1 + δ6 Occupancy Ratet + δ7 ALOSt + δ8 CMI t + δ9 %DSH t Rock, 2002).
+ δ10 TEACH + δ11 RURAL + δ12 RELIGIOUS + δ13 UCCt Occupancy Ratet captures operating efficiency by dividing the num­
∑ ∑
+ δj Yeart + δk Statet + φt (4) ber of patient-days by the number of staffed bed-days, calculated as
available beds × 365 days (Eldenburg & Krishnan, 2008; Heese, 2018).
In model (4), EMt assumes the value of each of our measures for Eldenburg et al. (2011) provide some evidence that real activities
earnings management, estimated using models (1), (2), and (3). We earnings management is associated with operating efficiency. It is
separate abnormal accruals that increase earnings from those that possible that managers are hesitant to cut costs for fear of reducing ef­
decrease earnings, and label them Pos_AMt and Neg_AMt, respectively. ficiency. It is also possible that managers feel they have more flexibility
Similarly, we separate real activities manipulations into those that have in cutting costs as demand falls when they are making efficient use of
positive and negative impacts on earnings. We label income-increasing their resources.
and income-decreasing patient care cost manipulations and discre­ ALOSt (average length of stay) is the total number of patient-days
tionary cost manipulations Pos_RM1t, Neg_RM1t, Pos_RM2t, and divided by patient discharges. We include ALOSt because the time
Neg_RM2t, respectively. NFP is a dichotomous variable identifying hos­ spent in the hospital per patient influences capacity utilization, perfor­
pital ownership as defined in the preceding section. The estimate δ1 mance, costs, and managers' expenditures on accounting information
captures a difference in earnings management in non-profit hospitals, (Bai, 2013; Eldenburg & Krishnan, 2008; Lynk, 1995), all of which might
compared to for-profit hospitals. influence managers' use of accruals and real activities earnings man­
The rest of the variables in the model represent a set of controls for agement. Prior studies have found that for-profit hospitals have shorter
alternative explanations or confounding constructs. average lengths of stay than non-profit hospitals, emphasizing the need
NOAt-1 (asset intensity) is net operating assets measured at the to include ALOSt in the model (Forgione, 1987; Forgione et al., 1996).
beginning of the year divided by the previous year's net revenues. Net CMIt (case mix index) is a measure of the intensity of patient
operating assets are equal to shareholders' equity (total fund balance in healthcare needs serviced by hospital-year, obtained from the CMS. We
non-profits) minus cash and marketable securities, and minus total lia­ include CMIt in our earnings management analyses because we believe
bilities. We expect parameter estimates on NOAt-1 that indicate a larger that variation in the mix of services rendered might influence those real
degree of accruals earnings management because the magnitude of net activities managed, and their trade-off with accruals earnings manage­
operating assets captures managers' flexibility to utilize asset-based ac­ ment (Heese, 2018). Eldenburg et al. (2017) observe that for-profit
cruals in earnings management (Barton & Simko, 2002; Heese, 2018). hospitals have less intensive case mixes than non-profit hospitals,
Conversely, we expect parameter estimates on NOAt-1 that indicate a emphasizing the importance of including CMIt in our analyses (Forgione,
smaller degree of real activities earnings management because it cap­ 1987; Forgione et al., 1996).
tures the opportunity to substitute accruals management for real activ­ %DSHt is a proxy for the number patients served who are considered
ities management. indigent. It is possible that some of these patients could pay out of pocket
Market Sharet− 1 is the lagged ratio of a hospital's net revenue to the for a portion of the medical services they received. However, we expect
total revenue of all hospitals in the county.12Market Sharet− 1 is a proxy that the payments received might be lower or incomplete relative to
for market‑leader status in the industry, to control for the positive effect payments received from insurance providers, putting downward pres­
of leadership on hospitals' ability to acquire funding (Geiger & Ittner, sure on earnings (Molnar, 2004; Rundle & Davies, 2004). Consequently,
1996). We further expect that greater market share is associated with we include %DSHt to account for any effect the downward pressure
less relative performance evaluation that forms expectations for hospi­ might have on earnings management.
tals' earnings targets (Eldenburg & Krishnan, 2008). Both of these effects TEACH, RURAL, and RELIGIOUS are indicator variables set to the
suggest that greater Market Sharet− 1 is associated with less earnings value of one if the hospital is associated with healthcare education,
manipulation. located in a rural community, and affiliated with a religious institution,
Sizet is the natural log of total assets.13 We include Sizet to control for respectively.14 We include these control variables to account for char­
governance, monitoring, and other size-related firm characteristics that acteristics common to these types of hospitals that might influence
earnings, earnings targets, earnings management flexibility, and
consequently earnings management behavior (Eldenburg & Krishnan,
11
The hospital-year is our unit of observation. Although every observation's 2008; Heese, 2018).
value fluctuates by hospital, some variable values are constant across time UCCt (proportion of uncompensated care) is measured by dividing
(NFP, TEACH, RURAL, RELIGIOUS) and others are measured with a lag (NOA, uncompensated care costs by net revenues (Lamboy-Ruiz, Cannon, &
Market Share, ROA). Thus, we include the subscript t as a time indicator but do Watanabe, 2019). We include the proportion of uncompensated care to
not include a hospital subscript.
12 account for charity care offerings that might otherwise appear to be real
We find in untabulated tests that our inferences remain unchanged if we use
the revenue-based Herfindahl-Hirschman index instead of Market Sharet− 1 in
our OLS estimations.
13 14
In additional untabulated tests, we use the number of occupied beds as a None of the hospitals in our sample changed their rural, religious or
proxy for hospital size instead of assets when estimating model (4). These tests teaching hospitals status, therefore we do not use subscript “t” for variables
do not alter our inferences. TEACH, RURAL or RELIGIOUS.

5
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

activities earnings management. Further, consistent with the argument Table 1


made by Vansant (2015), we include UCCt to capture managers' use of Sample Selection.
charity care to manage earnings to meet a particular target. Screening procedure Number of hospital-year
Finally, we include bi-directional (income-increasing and income- observations
decreasing) measures of real earnings management using patient care All reports available in Healthcare Cost Report
costs (RM1t) and discretionary costs (RM2t) as control variables when Information System for U.S. hospitals (50 states and
31,329
explaining managers' use of accruals earnings management. We do this D.C.) with stable ownership available for years
to account for the timing of managers' earnings management decisions. 2011–2016
Less: reports from government hospitals (6913)
That is, managers make their real activities earnings management de­ 24,416
cisions throughout the reporting operational period, while they engage Less: reports from specialty hospitals (9585)
in accruals earnings management after the period's operations have 14,831
concluded (Zang, 2012). Less: reports with reporting periods of less or >12
(621)
months
We also include state indicator variables to control for idiosyncratic
14,210
factors that might differ among states, including unknown regulations Less: reports with negative total assets and/or negative
that might influence the financial reporting environment and/or earn­ (1548)
gross and net patient revenues
ings benchmarks of hospitals, hence affecting their earnings manage­ 12,662
ment decisions. We include year indicator variables to control for Less: reports for hospitals that have fewer than 6
(1958)
observations for years 2011–2016
general economic conditions in each year. We estimate all OLS re­ 10,704
gressions using robust standard errors clustered at the hospital level to Less: reports with missing values for control variables (768)
account for any correlation between a given hospital's residuals across Final sample of 1656 unique hospitals 9936
years (Petersen, 2009).

entities that cannot rely solely on government subsidies to sustain op­


4. Sample selection and descriptive statistics
erations (Balakrishnan et al., 2010; Eldenburg et al., 2017; Kallapur &
Eldenburg, 2005). Next, we remove 9585 reports from specialty hospi­
We obtain hospital financial data from the Healthcare Cost Report
tals, whose production functions, patient mix, and government re­
Information System of the CMS. This database contains financial state­
imbursements differ from those of acute care general hospitals
ments and operational data for most U.S. hospitals and is one of the
(Eldenburg et al., 2011). Next, we remove 621 reports that cover either
primary public sources of comprehensive hospital financial information
fewer or >12 months per year. This report pattern is usually indicative
(Eldenburg et al., 2017). CMS collects hospital financial information
of hospitals that initiate/end their contract with the CMS, change their
annually in the form commonly known as the MCR.15 Hospitals submit
fiscal-year period, or change their ownership type (CMS, 2007). As the
an MCR to a Medicare Administrative Contractor in order to receive
next data screening, we remove MCRs with negative total assets, nega­
updated prospective payments for the following year. Due to continuous
tive gross patient revenue, and/or negative net patient revenue. We
revisions and appeals of cost reports during the reimbursement process,
require six observations for each unique hospital in our sample to ensure
the database is not static and contains only the last report submitted.16
that each hospital is present through the entire sample period. Thus, we
We follow existing literature (e.g., (Eldenburg, Hermalin, Weisbach,
remove 1958 reports from hospitals that are missing observations from
& Wosinska, 2004); Eldenburg et al., 2015; Vansant, 2015; Lamboy-Ruiz
2011 through 2016. Lastly, we remove hospital-years with missing
et al., 2019) by focusing on non-federal, general short-term acute hos­
values necessary to compute control variables. Our final sample contains
pitals, which represent 60% of all U.S. hospitals, share the same largest
9936 hospital-year observations, covering 1656 hospitals. We winsorize
client (i.e., the federal government), and have a common reimbursement
all continuous control variables at the 1% and 99% levels to control for
methodology. We begin our sample period in 2011 because this allows
potential outliers.
us to use MCRs filed under the same, most recent MCR format to mini­
Table 2, panels A and B present the sample distribution and earnings
mize the likelihood of using incomparable data.17 We outline the sample
management variable descriptive statistics by ownership type and by
selection process in Table 1.
year. The numbers of non-profit and for-profit hospitals in the sample
There are 31,329 report-years for all U.S. hospitals (excluding U.S.
are 1206 and 450, respectively. We observe that the absolute magni­
territories) with stable ownership from 2011 through 2016. We first
tudes of the for-profit hospitals' earnings management proxies are
remove 6913 reports of government hospitals. Non-profit hospitals,
greater in each year and across years than are the non-profit hospitals'
while sharing certain characteristics with government hospitals (i.e.,
earnings management proxies. In panel C, we display the distribution of
their missions include social objectives), are typically self-sustaining
hospitals by state. Five states account for 34.8% of the sample: California
(900 observations), Texas (834 observations), Florida (606 observa­
tions), Pennsylvania (594 observations), and Ohio (528 observations).
15
MCRs are submitted using various forms, containing preset worksheets, We address states with a disproportionately large number of observa­
similar to IRS tax forms. In Appendix A we reference to specific worksheets and tions in our sample in the robustness analysis section of our paper.
line items on the forms where we obtain relevant financial information. In Table 3, panels A and B we present non-profit and for-profit
16
At the end of the year, Medicare reconciles its prepayments to hospitals and
hospitals' summary statistics, respectively, for the variables used in the
the billings submitted by the hospitals with the hospital's cost report. A hospital
OLS model (4). On average, non-profit hospitals in our sample report
can appeal Medicare's final decision by submitting a new cost report. Medicare
can also request an amended report from hospitals. We obtained the latest mean positive and negative discretionary accruals (Pos_AMt and Neg_­
update of the data used in this study from the CMS database on February 2, AMt) of 0.035 and− 0.035 that are more than twice the magnitude of the
2018. means, ±0.014 and ±0.016, of the respective real activities earnings
17
MCR format changed in 2010. Prior to 2010, hospitals used the 1996 management (Pos_RM1t, Pos_RM1t and Neg_RM1t, Neg_RM1t), as a pro­
reporting format, which did not disaggregate charity care costs and bad debt portion of total assets. However, given that the mean sample return on
expense components of uncompensated care costs, among other things (Lam­ total assets (ROAt-1) is 0.066, the economic magnitudes of all earnings
boy-Ruiz et al., 2019). The 2010 MCR format has improved the presentation management measures are meaningful, ranging from 21% to 53% of
and disclosure of uncompensated care costs, which are part of patient service average return on total assets. Turning to for-profit hospitals, we observe
costs that we use to estimate one of our real earnings manipulations proxies.
much higher mean values of Pos_AMt and Neg_AMt of 0.129 and − 0.129,
While a majority of hospitals still submitted MCRs using the 1996 format in
respectively. Similar to non-profit hospitals, we see that discretionary
2010, by 2011 all hospitals used the new MCR format.

6
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Table 2
Descriptive statistics.
Panel A: Frequency of observations, and earnings management measures for non-profit hospitals by year

Fiscal Year N % Pos_AMt Pos_RM1t Pos_RM2t Neg_AMt Neg_RM1t Neg_RM2t

2011 1206 16.67% 0.028 0.016 0.018 − 0.029 − 0.010 − 0.014


2012 1206 16.67% 0.034 0.015 0.016 − 0.039 − 0.012 − 0.018
2013 1206 16.67% 0.037 0.013 0.018 − 0.037 − 0.015 − 0.016
2014 1206 16.67% 0.045 0.014 0.019 − 0.033 − 0.016 − 0.016
2015 1206 16.67% 0.038 0.013 0.013 − 0.037 − 0.015 − 0.018
2016 1206 16.67% 0.028 0.011 0.013 − 0.037 − 0.015 − 0.016
Total / Average 7236 100.00% 0.035 0.014 0.016 − 0.035 − 0.014 − 0.016

Panel B: Frequency of observations, and earnings management measures for for-profit hospitals by year

Fiscal Year N % Pos_AMt Pos_RM1t Pos_RM2t Neg_AMt Neg_RM1t Neg_RM2t

2011 450 16.67% 0.106 0.032 0.044 − 0.098 − 0.018 − 0.029


2012 450 16.67% 0.113 0.028 0.042 − 0.137 − 0.021 − 0.035
2013 450 16.67% 0.170 0.024 0.048 − 0.138 − 0.026 − 0.044
2014 450 16.67% 0.148 0.027 0.041 − 0.151 − 0.026 − 0.051
2015 450 16.67% 0.118 0.022 0.039 − 0.141 − 0.028 − 0.054
2016 450 16.67% 0.120 0.016 0.047 − 0.109 − 0.030 − 0.029
Total / Average 2700 100.00% 0.129 0.025 0.044 − 0.129 − 0.025 − 0.040

Panel C: Sample distribution by state

State N % State N %

AK 24 0.24% MT 48 0.48%
AL 96 0.97% NC 150 1.51%
AR 156 1.57% ND 18 0.18%
AZ 156 1.57% NE 84 0.85%
CA 900 9.06% NH 66 0.66%
CO 168 1.69% NJ 180 1.81%
CT 132 1.33% NM 84 0.85%
D.C. 24 0.24% NV 78 0.79%
DE 24 0.24% NY 318 3.20%
FL 606 6.10% OH 528 5.31%
GA 216 2.17% OK 198 1.99%
HI 36 0.36% OR 120 1.21%
IA 108 1.09% PA 594 5.98%
ID 42 0.42% RI 30 0.30%
IL 462 4.65% SC 132 1.33%
IN 252 2.54% SD 66 0.66%
KS 162 1.63% TN 282 2.84%
KY 234 2.36% TX 834 8.39%
LA 168 1.69% UT 132 1.33%
MA 234 2.36% VA 234 2.36%
MD 132 1.33% VT 30 0.30%
ME 60 0.60% WA 126 1.27%
MI 282 2.84% WI 252 2.54%
MN 198 1.99% WV 84 0.85%
MO 216 2.17% WY 24 0.24%
MS 156 1.57% Total 9936 100.00%

Notes:Panels A and B present overall and annual means of earnings management measures by hospital ownership type. Pos_AMt (Neg_AMt) is positive (negative)
discretionary accruals, proxied by the residuals from the discretionary accruals model of Jones (1991). Pos_RM1t (Neg_RM1t) is income-increasing (− decreasing) real
earnings manipulations, proxied by the residuals from the expected patient service cost model (2) multiplied by − 1. Patient service cost includes costs of providing
patient services for inpatient routine services, ancillary services, ambulatory services, and outpatient services, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. Pos_RM2t
(Neg_RM2t) is income-increasing (− decreasing) real earnings manipulations, proxied by the estimated residuals from the expected discretionary expenditures model
(3) multiplied by − 1. Discretionary expenditures are the sum of R&D and general and administrative expenses, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. Panel C
presents sample composition by state (including District of Columbia).

accruals are much larger in absolute magnitude that either the mean to revenue (mean NOAt–1 is 1.069) and smaller returns on assets (mean
patient service cost (+0.026, − 0.025) or discretionary cost (+0.044, ROAt–1 is 0.066), when compared with for-profit hospitals (mean NOAt–1
− 0.042) manipulations. Together, these descriptive statistics suggest is 0.648 and mean ROAt–1 is 0.225).
that for-profit managers make greater use of earnings management Non-profit hospitals have somewhat greater utilization (mean Oc­
relative to non-profit managers. cupancy Ratet of 0.679) than do for-profit hospitals (mean Occupancy
The non-profit hospitals in our sample are large-sized hospitals, with Ratet of 0.542). However, both patient lengths of stay and case mix in­
average assets of approximately $203 million (mean Sizet is 19.127), and tensity are relatively comparable (non-profit and for-profit mean ALOSt
control 47.6% of the local market share, while the for-profit hospitals of 4.385 and 4.026, and mean CMIt of 1.517 and 1.554, respectively).
have average total assets of $56 million (mean Sizet is 17.836) and We also observe that while non-profit hospitals serve a smaller pro­
control 37.0% of their market share. As might be expected given their portion of uninsured patients than do for-profit hospitals (mean %DSHt
different missions, non-profit hospitals have a larger proportion of assets of 0.268 compared with 0.288), the mean proportion of uncompensated

7
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Table 3 might be expected, none of the for-profit hospitals are affiliated with
Summary Statistics. religious organizations. Finally, non-profit hospitals are much more
Panel A: Summary statistics—non-profit hospitals likely to engage in healthcare education and research (mean TEACH of
subsample 0.424) than are for-profit hospitals (mean TEACH of 0.184).
Variable N Mean Median Std. 25th 75th
Dev. Pctl Pctl 5. Empirical analysis
Pos_AMt 3633 0.035 0.017 0.053 0.006 0.040
Pos_RM1t 3614 0.014 0.007 0.020 0.003 0.016 5.1. Univariate analysis
Pos_RM2t 3617 0.016 0.009 0.023 0.003 0.020
Neg_AMt 3603 − 0.035 − 0.017 0.053 − 0.041 − 0.007 Fig. 1 provides a visual representation and Table 4 presents a uni­
Neg_RM1t 3622 − 0.014 − 0.007 0.021 − 0.016 − 0.003
variate analysis of differences in our earnings management proxies be­
Neg_RM2t 3619 − 0.016 − 0.008 0.024 − 0.019 − 0.003
NFP 7236 1.000 1.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 tween non-profit and for-profit hospitals. First, consistent with our H1a,
NOAt–1 7236 1.069 0.921 0.594 0.665 1.323 mean and median values of Pos_AMt, Pos_RM1t, and Pos_RM2t are lower
Market 7236 0.476 0.370 0.380 0.112 1.000 in non-profit hospitals than in for-profit hospitals, with significant dif­
Sharet–1 ferences at p-values of <0.01. Second, contrary to our expectation stated
Sizet 7236 19.127 19.179 1.179 18.345 19.947
ROAt–1 7236 0.066 0.051 0.126 0.013 0.101
in H1b, mean and median values of Neg_AMt, Neg_RM1t, and Neg_RM2t
Occupancy 7236 0.679 0.695 0.232 0.514 0.839 are less negative in non-profit hospitals than in for-profit hospitals (all p-
Ratet values <0.01). Taken together, this is the first set of evidence that non-
ALOSt 7236 4.385 4.305 0.971 3.806 4.828 profit hospital managers engage in less income-increasing and income-
CMIt 7236 1.517 1.508 0.266 1.340 1.687
decreasing earnings management activities than do for-profit hospital
%DSHt 7236 0.268 0.244 0.144 0.177 0.328
TEACH 7236 0.424 0.000 0.494 0.000 1.000 managers.
RURAL 7236 0.759 1.000 0.428 1.000 1.000
RELIGIOUS 7236 0.235 0.000 0.424 0.000 0.000 5.2. Correlations
UCCt 7236 0.042 0.034 0.031 0.020 0.054

Table 5 presents the Pearson correlation coefficients among the


variables of interest. Pos_AMt, Pos_RM1t, and Pos_RM2t have negative
Panel B: Summary statistics—for-profit hospitals subsample and significant correlation coefficients with NFP (ρ = − 0.25, − 0.19, and
Variable N Mean Median Std 25th Pctl 75th Pctl − 0.31), while Neg_AMt, Neg_RM1t, and Neg_RM2t each have a positive
Dev and significant correlation with NFP (ρ = 0.25, 0.19, and 0.28). These
Pos_AMt 1347 0.129 0.026 0.296 0.009 0.098 correlations are consistent with univariate analyses reported in Table 4.
Pos_RM1t 1340 0.026 0.015 0.039 0.006 0.032 Given several high correlations among our test and control variables,
Pos_RM2t 1316 0.044 0.022 0.061 0.008 0.055
we test for potential multicollinearity by estimating variance inflation
Neg_AMt 1353 − 0.129 − 0.027 0.300 − 0.091 − 0.009
Neg_RM1t 1360 − 0.025 − 0.013 0.039 − 0.031 − 0.005
factors in our OLS analysis; none are greater than five.
Neg_RM2t 1384 − 0.042 − 0.019 0.063 − 0.049 − 0.007
NFP 2700 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 5.3. Test of hypotheses H1a and H1b
NOAt–1 2700 0.648 0.585 0.350 0.437 0.765
Market Sharet–1 2700 0.370 0.203 0.381 0.049 0.688
Table 6 reports estimation results for model (4), which we use to test
Sizet 2700 17.836 17.927 1.032 17.164 18.582
ROAt–1 2700 0.225 0.164 0.285 0.043 0.353 the association between earning management and ownership type. The
Occupancy 2700 0.542 0.520 0.263 0.327 0.753 dependent variables in columns (1), (2), (3), and (4), (5), and (6) are
Ratet income-increasing discretionary accruals (Pos_AMt), patient care cost
ALOSt 2700 4.026 4.097 1.194 3.356 4.675
manipulations (Pos_RM1t), discretionary cost manipulations (Pos_RM2t),
CMIt 2700 1.554 1.510 0.370 1.285 1.723
%DSHt 2700 0.288 0.257 0.200 0.145 0.374 and income-decreasing discretionary accruals (Neg_AMt), patient care
TEACH 2700 0.184 0.000 0.388 0.000 0.000 cost manipulations (Neg_RM1t), and discretionary cost manipulations
RURAL 2700 0.747 1.000 0.435 0.000 1.000 (Neg_RM2t), respectively. Our OLS estimations reflect an adjusted R-
RELIGIOUS 2700 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 squared between 9% and 17%.
UCCt 2700 0.035 0.027 0.032 0.013 0.047
In columns (1) and (3), the estimated coefficients on the indicator
Notes: This table presents summary statistics of variables used in the OLS re­ variable NFP are − 0.085 and − 0.022, and are statistically significant at
gressions. All variables are defined in Appendix A. the 1% level, indicating that non-profit hospitals exhibit lower income-
increasing discretionary accruals and discretionary cost manipulations
care of non-profit hospitals is 20% higher than that of for-profit hospitals relative to for-profit hospitals. These results provide evidence in support
(mean UCCt of 0.042 compared with 0.035).18 These differences suggest of H1a.
that for-profit hospitals serve a greater proportion of self-paying patients The estimated coefficients in columns (4) and (6) are 0.084 and
than do non-profit hospitals. 0.018, and are statistically significant at the 1% level. These results
Finally, we observe that the mean proportions of non-profit and for- indicate that non-profit hospitals exhibit lower income-decreasing
profits hospitals found in rural locations are comparable (mean RURAL discretionary accruals and discretionary cost manipulations relative to
of 0.759 and 0.747, respectively). Also, approximately 23.5% of non- for-profit hospitals. This evidence leads us to reject H1b and is consistent
profit hospitals are affiliated with a religious institution whereas, as with the notion that non-profit hospital managers do not have greater
incentives than for-profit hospital managers do to reduce earnings.
We observe in columns (2) and (5) no difference in the use of either
18 positive or negative patient-service-related (RM1) real earnings man­
Our means of uncompensated care costs scaled by net revenues for non-
agement between non-profit and for-profit hospitals. It appears that
profits and for-profits are somewhat similar to the 4.8% and 4.2% means re­
ported by Schuhmann (2008). We note, however, that Schuhmann's sample was where real earnings management does take place it occurs within
from 2003 to 2007 and that his data were extracted from MCRs under the 1996 discretionary (R&D and other general and administrative) expense
format. Our mean of the scaled uncompensated care costs in non-profits is the rather than in service-critical expense categories.
same as the 4.2% reported by Lamboy-Ruiz et al. (2019) for a sample of hos­ Overall, these empirical findings reflect that non-profit hospital
pitals from 2011 to 2014. managers have less incentive to create either positive or negative

8
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

0.150

Average value of the earnings management metric


0.125
0.100
0.075
0.050
0.025
0.000
(0.025)
(0.050)
(0.075)
(0.100)
(0.125)
(0.150)
Pos_AM Pos_RM1 Pos_RM2 Neg_AM Neg_RM1 Neg_RM2

Mean FP Mean NFP

Fig. 1. Earnings management by for-profit (FP) and non-profit (NFP) hospitals.

Table 4
Univariate comparisons.
Variable FP NFP NFP − FP

N Mean Median N Mean Median Diff.: Means Diff.: Medians Difference: Means Difference: Medians

T–stat Z–stat

Pos_AMt 1347 0.129 0.026 3633 0.035 0.017 − 0.094 − 0.009 − 11.59 *** − 11.59 ***
Pos_RM1t 1340 0.026 0.015 3614 0.014 0.007 − 0.012 − 0.008 − 10.69 *** − 16.03 ***
Pos_RM2t 1316 0.044 0.022 3617 0.016 0.009 − 0.027 − 0.014 − 15.96 *** − 20.38 ***
Neg_AMt 1353 − 0.129 − 0.027 3603 − 0.035 − 0.017 0.093 0.010 11.35 *** 11.03 ***
Neg_RM1t 1360 − 0.025 − 0.013 3622 − 0.014 − 0.007 0.011 0.006 10.38 *** 14.27 ***
Neg_RM2t 1384 − 0.042 − 0.019 3619 − 0.016 − 0.008 0.025 0.011 14.57 *** 18.23 ***

Notes: ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels (two-tail), respectively. This table presents comparisons of means (t-test) and medians
(Wilcoxon rank-sum test) of our earnings management measures for non-profit and for-profit hospitals. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

reserves to manipulate future earnings than do for-profit managers. Our income-increasing and income-decreasing patient care cost manipula­
findings are significant not only statistically, but also economically. In tions. This pattern suggests that case mix intensity provides hospital
particular, for-profits exhibit higher income-increasing (− decreasing) managers with more flexibility to manipulate patient care cost, relaxing
discretionary accruals of 8.5% (8.4%) of assets, and higher income- the need to manage accruals and/or discretionary costs.
increasing (− decreasing) discretionary costs-based real earnings man­ The proportion of uninsured patients (%DSHt) is associated with
agement of 2.2% (1.8%) of assets. greater use of income-increasing and income-decreasing discretionary
Turning to control variables, we observe that several of the controls cost manipulations. Similarly, teaching hospitals (TEACH) engage in
are insignificant in the regression (e.g., Market Sharet-1, Occupancy Ratet, more real activities earnings management, both income-increasing and
ALOSt, RURAL, RM1t, and RM2t). We attribute their lack of significance income-decreasing. It is possible that those hospitals caring for fewer
to our by-hospital estimation procedure for earnings management insured patients and that are affiliated with education have greater
behavior. Said another way, our earnings management models allow variation in profitability, putting pressure on those hospitals to engage
parameters to vary by hospital, accounting for variation between in non-reversing earnings management.
hospital-specific characteristics. We find that religiously affiliated hospitals (RELIGIOUS) tend to use
We do observe that previous year's net operating assets (NOAt-1) and more accruals and discretionary cost manipulations to both increase and
hospital size (Sizet) have negative associations with income-increasing decrease earnings. It is possible that these hospitals have an additional
earnings management, and positive associations with both income- oversight constituency that prefers predictable and consistent streams of
decreasing real activities earnings management proxies. These pat­ earnings. Alternatively, managers in religious hospitals may have higher
terns suggest that asset intensity and size dampen hospitals' need to expectations placed on them relative to other non-profits. For instance,
engage in earnings management. Previous year's profitability (ROAt-1) is Ballou and Weisbrod (2003) find that CEOs of religiously affiliated
only associated with income-decreasing discretionary cost manipula­ hospitals receive the highest base salary among government, secular
tions, suggesting that hospital managers use fewer income-decreasing non-profit, and religious non-profit hospitals.
discretionary cost manipulations when previous-period profitability Finally, we see that income-increasing accruals and patient care cost
was high. This relationship is consistent with hospitals using the previ­ manipulations are lower with marginal significance (p < 0.10) for hos­
ous period's earnings as a benchmark for current reported earnings. pitals that provide more uncompensated care. Similarly, income-
The intensity of hospitals' case mix (CMIt) is significant across all decreasing discretionary costs are lower (p < 0.05) for hospitals that
earnings management types and behaviors. However, the intensity is provide more uncompensated care. Recall that there exist hospital types
associated with fewer income-increasing and income-decreasing with offsetting incentives to sustain operations through profitability and
discretionary accruals and discretionary cost manipulations, but more to provide charity care (Balakrishnan et al., 2010; Eldenburg et al.,

9
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

2011). The significance of the UCCt control variable is consistent with

0.03
this type of incentive structure.

1.00
18

5.4. Test of hypotheses H2a and H2b

¡0.10

Notes: This table presents Pearson correlations for variables used in the OLS models. All bolded values represent statistical significance at the 0.10 level or above. All variables are defined in Appendix A.
0.03
1.00
17

In order to understand better the differences in for-profit and non-


profit hospital's earnings management when pre-managed earnings are

¡0.05
0.31
0.06
1.00
negative or high, we estimate pre-managed levels of return on net sales
16

(ROS). Because our earnings management proxies are scaled by


beginning-of-year assets, we first estimate pre-managed return on assets

− 0.01
− 0.01
0.14

0.22
(ROA) by calculating reported ROA and subtracting from it signed

1.00
15

discretionary accruals and both proxies for real activities. We then


multiply pre-managed ROA by a ratio of beginning-of-year assets to net

¡0.17

¡0.26
revenue, resulting in pre-managed ROS. We then split each hospital

0.31
0.40
0.06
1.00
14

type's pre-managed ROS into annual quintiles (where quintile 1 is the


lowest level of earnings, and quintile 5 is the highest level of earnings)
and perform cross-sectional OLS estimations of model (4) for each
0.05
0.29
0.31
0.22
0.02
0.03
1.00
13

quintile.
¡0.02 Fig. 2a presents mean for-profit and non-profit hospitals' pre-
managed ROS by quintile. Negative pre-managed ROS appears higher
0.50
0.35
0.12
0.45
0.38
0.10
1.00
12

(quintile 1), while positive pre-managed ROS appears lower (quintiles


2–5), in non-profit hospitals. In untabulated tests, we find these differ­
ences to be significant at p-values <0.01. In Fig. 2b, we display reported
¡0.14

¡0.12
¡0.06

¡0.09
¡0.14
0.24

0.08
1.00
0.01

ROS by ownership type, and note that non-profit managers report lower
11

ROS across all quintiles. These differences are also statistically signifi­
cant (p-values <0.01). Because we notice a linear pattern of for-profits'
¡0.14

¡0.10
0.68
0.35
0.40
0.03
0.47
0.33
0.16
1.00

mean reported earnings across quintiles, we then perform untabulated


10

tests of differences in pre-managed and reported ROS standard de­


viations by hospital ownership type. We find that the standard deviation
¡0.09
¡0.09
¡0.21
¡0.16
¡0.31
¡0.03
¡0.19
¡0.60

of reported ROS is lower than the standard deviation of pre-managed


0.15
1.00

0.00

ROS in for-profits, while for non-profits, there is no difference in the


9

standard deviation of pre-managed and reported ROS.


¡0.26

¡0.09

In Fig. 2c we present pre-managed ROS and reported ROS for both


− 0.01

− 0.01

− 0.01
0.07
0.50

0.11
0.04

0.05

0.08
1.00

for-profit and non-profit hospitals by quintile of pre-managed ROS.


8

Consistent with H2a and H2b, we observe the greatest degree of earnings
management differences between for-profit and non-profit hospitals in
¡0.36

¡0.05
¡0.06
0.33
0.12
0.45

0.25
0.15

0.22

0.28
0.09
1.00

0.01

quintiles 1 and 5. Further, it seems that in quintiles 1 and 2 (negative and


7

small positive earnings), both types of hospitals engage in income-


increasing earnings management, while in quintiles 4 and 5, they
¡0.04

¡0.17

− 0.02

exhibit patterns of “cookie jar” reserves by managing positive earnings


0.28
0.22

0.26

0.15
0.03
0.11

0.08
0.05
0.05
1.00

0.00
6

downward.
We next report OLS estimations of differences in earnings manage­
¡0.10

¡0.03
− 0.01

ment between for-profit and non-profit hospitals by quintile of pre-


0.26
0.19
0.26
0.03
0.31

0.18
0.09

0.08
0.03
0.05
1.00

0.00

managed ROS in Table 7. Because we observe in Fig. 2c generally uni­


5

directional earnings management behavior by quintile, we combine our


positive and negative earnings management metrics, and report only
¡0.03

¡0.11

¡0.06

− 0.01
0.13
0.20
0.25
0.12

0.17

0.10
0.03
0.06

0.07
0.06
0.05
1.00

estimated coefficients for variables AMt (Pos_AMt + Neg_AMt), RM1t


4

(Pos_RM1t + Neg_RM1t), and RM2t (Pos_RM2t + Neg_RM2t). Further,


because we compute pre-managed ROS by subtracting AMt, RM1t, and
¡0.27
¡0.33

¡0.31
¡0.24

¡0.28

¡0.16
¡0.05
¡0.11

¡0.08
¡0.06
¡0.05
0.06

0.17

0.04
1.00

0.00

RM2t from reported ROS, we examine an additional earnings manage­


N/A
3

ment variable, Total_EMt (AMt + RM1t + RM2t), to study overall earnings


management behavior. For brevity, we omit all included control vari­
¡0.15

¡0.27
¡0.19
¡0.24
¡0.03
¡0.31

¡0.16
¡0.10
¡0.03

¡0.08
¡0.02
¡0.05

ables and fixed effects, and only report the coefficient of interest, NFP.
0.30

0.08
1.00

0.00

0.00
N/A

Consistent with H2a, non-profit managers use significantly fewer


2

income-increasing discretionary accruals and discretionary cost ma­


¡0.17
¡0.14
¡0.25
¡0.12

¡0.17

¡0.11
¡0.04
¡0.06

¡0.07
¡0.05
¡0.04

nipulations than for-profit managers use (columns 1 and 3 coefficients


0.11
0.27

0.03

0.11

0.06
1.00

0.01
N/A

= − 0.169, − 0.018, p-values <0.01) when pre-managed earnings are


1

negative (quintile 1). Turning our attention to H2b, we see that as pre-
managed profits increase across quintiles 3, 4, and 5, non-profit man­
Occupancy Ratet
Market Sharet–1

agers use significantly fewer income-decreasing discretionary accruals


RELIGIOUS
Neg_RM1t
Neg_RM2t
Pos_RM1t
Pos_RM2t
Neg_AMt
Pos_AMt

RURAL
TEACH
NOAt–1

ROAt–1

%DSHt
ALOSt

UCCt
CMIt
Correlations.

Sizet
NFP
Table 5

10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9

10
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Table 6
OLS regressions: hospital ownership and earnings management.
Dep. var. Pos_AMt Pos_RM1t Pos_RM2t Neg_AMt Neg_RM1t Neg_RM2t

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

NFP − 0.085*** 0.000 − 0.022*** 0.084*** − 0.001 0.018***


[− 6.80] [− 0.15] [− 8.58] [6.83] [− 0.32] [7.72]
NOAt–1 − 0.009* − 0.003*** − 0.006*** 0.006 0.004*** 0.007***
[− 1.85] [− 3.67] [− 4.74] [1.09] [4.86] [5.76]
Market Sharet–1 0.013 − 0.001 0.001 − 0.005 0.001 − 0.002
[1.31] [− 0.44] [0.40] [− 0.46] [0.40] [− 0.84]
Sizet − 0.003 − 0.008*** − 0.004*** 0.005 0.008*** 0.004***
[− 0.73] [− 9.15] [− 3.78] [0.94] [9.49] [3.35]
ROAt–1 0.025 − 0.004 − 0.004 − 0.030 0.000 0.012**
[0.85] [− 0.88] [− 0.77] [− 0.99] [− 0.08] [2.10]
Occupancy Ratet − 0.018 0.004 − 0.002 0.011 − 0.001 0.005
[− 1.07] [1.50] [− 0.49] [0.68] [− 0.55] [1.19]
ALOSt 0.002 0.000 0.000 − 0.003 0.000 0.000
[0.58] [− 0.39] [− 0.16] [− 0.73] [− 0.73] [− 0.16]
CMIt − 0.038** 0.007*** − 0.007* 0.044*** − 0.008*** 0.006*
[− 2.51] [2.76] [− 1.87] [2.77] [− 3.08] [1.77]
%DSHt 0.044 0.002 0.026*** − 0.037 0.000 − 0.035***
[1.57] [0.43] [4.18] [− 1.35] [0.05] [− 5.83]
TEACH 0.007 0.004*** 0.006*** − 0.009 − 0.003*** − 0.003*
[0.96] [3.40] [3.46] [− 1.13] [− 2.94] [− 1.81]
RURAL 0.012 0.002 0.000 − 0.006 − 0.001 − 0.002
[1.30] [1.55] [0.18] [− 0.63] [− 0.76] [− 1.14]
RELIGIOUS 0.019*** 0.000 0.003** − 0.016*** 0.001 − 0.003**
[4.59] [− 0.22] [2.43] [− 3.63] [1.08] [− 2.15]
UCCt − 0.197* − 0.032* 0.026 0.122 − 0.016 0.058**
[− 1.88] [− 1.67] [0.93] [1.06] [− 0.55] [2.40]
RM1t − 0.062 − 0.046
[− 0.52] [− 0.30]
RM2t 0.113 − 0.015
[1.16] [− 0.15]
Constant 0.387** 0.146*** 0.125*** − 0.574* − 0.132*** − 0.119***
[2.42] [9.35] [6.56] [− 1.85] [− 9.33] [− 5.84]
Observations 4980 4954 4933 4956 4982 5003
Adjusted R2 0.09 0.14 0.17 0.09 0.15 0.16
State Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y
Year Fixed Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y
Clustered by hospital Y Y Y Y Y Y

Notes: ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels (two-tail), respectively. P-values are based on robust standard errors clustered at the hospital
level. All models include year and state fixed effects. T-statistics are reported in square brackets. Pos_AMt (Neg_AMt) is income-increasing (− decreasing) discretionary
accruals, proxied by the residuals from the discretionary accruals model of Jones (1991). Pos_RM1t (Neg_RM1t) is income-increasing (− decreasing) real earnings
manipulations, proxied by the residuals from the expected patient service cost model (2) multiplied by − 1. Patient service cost includes costs of providing patient
services for inpatient routine services, ancillary services, ambulatory services, and outpatient services, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. Pos_RM2t
(Neg_RM2t) is income-increasing (− decreasing) real earnings manipulations, proxied by the estimated residuals from the expected discretionary expenditures model
(3) multiplied by − 1. Discretionary expenditures are the sum of R&D and general and administrative expenses, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. NFP is a
dichotomous variable, coded 1 if a hospital is a non-profit hospital, 0 otherwise. All variables are defined in Appendix A

0.400
0.350
0.300
Average pre-managed ROS

0.250
0.200
0.150
0.100
0.050
0.000
(0.050)
(0.100)
(0.150)
(0.200)
1 2 3 4 5
Pre-managed ROS FP Pre-managed ROS NFP

Fig. 2a. Pre-managed ROS in for-profit (FP) and non-profit (NFP) hospitals by quintile of pre-managed return on sales (ROS).

11
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

0.400
0.350
0.300

Average pre-managed ROS


0.250
0.200
0.150
0.100
0.050
0.000
(0.050)
(0.100)
(0.150)
(0.200)
1 2 3 4 5

ROS FP ROS NFP

Fig. 2b. Reported return on sales (ROS) in for-profit (FP) and non-profit (NFP) hospitals by quintile of pre-managed ROS.

0.400
0.375
0.350
0.325
0.300
0.275
0.250
0.225
0.200
0.175
0.150
0.125
ROS

0.100
0.075
0.050
0.025
0.000
(0.025)
(0.050)
(0.075)
(0.100)
(0.125)
(0.150)
(0.175)
(0.200)
1 2 3 4 5

Pre-managed ROS FP ROS FP Pre-managed ROS NFP ROS NFP

Fig. 2c. Quintiles of mean reported return on sales (ROS) and pre-managed ROS in for-profit (FP) and non-profit (NFP) hospitals.

than do for-profit managers (less “cookie-jar” reserves).19 Importantly, also significant, ranging from − 17.9% to 25.7% of total assets. In short,
the differences in earnings management between non-profits and for- our analyses by quintile suggest that for-profit managers make more use
profits are driven primarily by accrual manipulations, and that the of discretionary accruals (in particular) and discretionary costs to report
greatest differences occur in the first and fifth quintile (see columns 1 consistent earnings than non-profit managers do.
and 4). Consistent with results related to H1a and H1b, with the
exception of the quintile 3 subsample, we observe insignificant co­
efficients on NFP in column (2), suggesting no difference in the use of 5.5. Robustness tests
service-critical real earnings management between non-profit and for-
profit hospitals. 5.5.1. Influential observations
We further note that the economic magnitude of the differences are While we winsorize all continuous control variables at 1% and 99%,
there is a possibility that outliers still remain and may influence our OLS
estimations. In untabulated tests, we re-estimate model (4) after
19
removing observations with studentized residuals below − 3 and above
The positive NFP coefficients in quintiles 3, 4, and 5 may create an
3. These additional tests do not alter our findings.
impression than non-profits manage earnings upward relative to for-profits.
Note that had we coded the test variable using a for-profit indicator, FP, the
resulting negative estimate would be the inverse of NFP (or the difference be­ 5.5.2. States with a disproportionately large number of observations
tween for-profits and non-profits). Therefore, for-profit managers use more Because observations from five states (CA, FL, OH, PA, and TX)
income-decreasing earnings management (i.e. “cookie-jar” reserves). Our in­ represent 34.8% of our sample, we re-estimate model (4) after excluding
terpretations are also consistent with the visuals of earnings management be­ those states from the sample. All of our inferences remain unchanged,
haviors by hospital type and pre-managed ROS quintile presented in Figure 2c. suggesting that our results are not driven by any of the larger states

12
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Table 7 relative to non-profit hospitals, for-profit hospitals use greater income-


OLS regression: hospital ownership and earnings management within quintiles increasing earnings manipulations when pre-managed earnings are
of pre-managed return on sales. negative, and greater income-decreasing earnings manipulations when
Dep. var. AMt RM1t RM2t Total_EMt(AM1t + RM1t + pre-managed earnings are high.
RM2t) Our study is motivated in part by the lack of large-sample research
(1) (2) (3) (4) directly comparing entities with different ownership structures that
correspond with different managerial incentives to report operating
Quintile 1
NFP − 0.169*** 0.002 − 0.018*** − 0.179*** performance aligned with their organizational mission. Due to its rela­
[− 7.52] [0.64] [− 4.07] [− 8.13] tively homogeneous regulatory environment and the stark ownership
N 1989 1989 1989 1989 differences between for-profit and non-profit institutions, the hospital
Adjusted industry is particularly conducive to accounting research on earnings
0.252 0.015 0.042 0.264
R2
management by ownership type. Examining the hospital industry allows
us to control for regulatory, legal, and competitive factors, while char­
Quintile 2
acteristics causing differences across hospitals such as size, occupancy
NFP − 0.002 0.001 − 0.001 − 0.002
[− 0.33] [0.55] [− 0.37] [− 0.28] ratios, case mix index, and others can be controlled for (Eldenburg et al.,
N 1987 1987 1987 1987 2017). These attributes of the hospital industry permit us to identify
Adjusted
0.139 0.03 0.029 0.175
with greater precision those differences arising from ownership type.
R2 Yet, it is not simply the convenience of the hospital industry that
motivates our study design; the healthcare industry is socially important
Quintile 3 and economically significant. Not only was national healthcare expen­
NFP 0.025*** 0.005** 0.004 0.032***
diture at 17.9% of U.S. GDP in 2016, and projected to increase to 19.7%
[4.14] [2.11] [1.62] [4.76]
N 1987 1987 1987 1987
by 2026 (CMS, 2018), at the federal level, healthcare spending is a
Adjusted significant driver of national debt (CMS, 2018; Sahadi, 2018). An ex­
0.227 0.026 0.045 0.235
R2 amination of earnings management in the hospital industry allows us to
gain a better understanding of earnings quality, an essential attribute of
Quintile 4 earnings for making informed decisions (Dechow, Ge, & Schrand, 2010;
NFP 0.038*** 0.001 0.013*** 0.049*** Francis, Olsson, & Schipper, 2008). Given the size and economic and
[4.77] [0.27] [3.38] [5.50] social relevance of the healthcare industry, it is important that stake­
N 1987 1987 1987 1987
Adjusted
holders understand the variations in reporting behaviors by different
0.164 0.006 0.05 0.194 ownership types of U.S. hospitals.
R2
Our research is not without its limitations. In order to utilize
Quintile 5 consistent CMS reporting format, our sample begins in 2011; thus, we
NFP 0.252*** − 0.002 0.017*** 0.257*** examine management behavior over a relatively short period (six years).
[8.10] [− 0.80] [4.06] [8.38] Moreover, while we control for time-invariant state-level characteristics
N 1986 1986 1986 1986 in our regressions, we do not consider any time-varying changes in
Adjusted
R2
0.221 0.035 0.087 0.24 states' regulatory environments or resources allocated to the oversight
and enforcement of healthcare programs. Flasher and Lamboy-Ruiz
Notes: ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels (two- (2019) document a positive association between resources dedicated
tail), respectively. P-values are based on robust standard errors clustered at the
to Medicaid Fraud Control Units and healthcare providers precluded
hospital level. All models include year and state fixed effects. T-statistics are
from doing business with federal and state governments. In a similar
reported in square brackets. AMt is discretionary accruals, proxied by the re­
manner, future research may examine whether earnings management by
siduals from the discretionary accruals model of Jones (1991). RM1t is real
earnings manipulations, proxied by the residuals from the expected patient U.S. hospitals is curtailed by the levels of resources dedicated at the state
service cost model (2) multiplied by − 1. Patient service cost includes costs of level for investigating and prosecuting healthcare-related fraud.
providing patient services for inpatient routine services, ancillary services, While we offer a comparison of for-profit and non-profit hospital
ambulatory services, and outpatient services, scaled by the beginning-of-year reporting decisions, we do not theorize non-profit hospitals' optimal
total assets. RM2t is real earnings manipulations, proxied by the estimated re­ levels of surplus earnings relative to that of for-profit hospitals. More
siduals from the expected discretionary expenditures model (3) multiplied by theory development and empirical evidence are necessary to help
− 1. Discretionary expenditures are the sum of R&D and general and adminis­ explain whether non-profit hospitals, which appear to engage in less
trative expenses, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. NFP is a dichot­ earnings management, are doing so to the benefit of society. We
omous variable, coded 1 if a hospital is a non-profit hospital, 0 otherwise. All
encourage future research to examine the implications of non-profit
control variables, state and year fixed effects are included in OLS models but
hospitals' operating decisions with respect to revenues and costs. In
omitted for brevity.
particular, there has been media scrutiny of non-profit hospitals'
increasing revenues concurrent with decreasing uncompensated care
represented.
costs (Balvin, 2016; Diamond, 2017; Bannow, 2018. Some see such
trends as contrary to non-profit hospitals' missions, while others may
6. Summary and conclusions
explain such trends as the reality of non-profit hospitals having fewer
uninsured patients following the adoption of ACA—naturally reducing
The purpose of our study is to examine how hospital ownership (for-
the demand for charity care—and providing services to their host
profit versus non-profit) influences earnings management by hospital
communities through alternative means, such as programs promoting
administrators. Using a large sample of U.S. hospitals from the 50 states
health and wellness (Ernst & Young, 2017; Pollack, 2018). Whether and
and the District of Columbia from 2011 through 2016, we find that non-
how non-profit hospitals should seek alternative means to contribute to
profit hospitals engage in accrual and discretionary costs-driven real
communities in exchange for their tax-exempt status is an important
earnings manipulations to a lesser degree than for-profit hospitals do.
ethical and empirical question. We leave that question for future
We also show that for-profit hospitals use earnings management tools to
research.
report earnings that are more consistent over time (i.e., that reduce re­
ported earnings dispersion). Specifically, we provide evidence that

13
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

Data availability Declaration of Competing Interest

All data are publicly available as identified in the text. None.

Appendix A. Variable definitions

Variable Name Definition Source

Dependent Variables
Accrual manipulations proxy, which equals the estimated residual from the discretionary accruals model of Jones (1991)
AMt Not directly reported
in our model (1).
Pos_AMt Positive discretionary accruals (AMt ≥ 0). Not directly reported
Neg_AMt Negative discretionary accruals (AMt < 0). Not directly reported
Estimated residual from the expected patient service cost model (2) multiplied by − 1. Patient service cost includes costs of
RM1t providing patient services for inpatient routine services, ancillary services, ambulatory services, and outpatient services, Not directly reported
scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets.
Pos_RM1t Income-increasing real patient service cost earnings manipulations (RM1t ≥ 0). Not directly reported
Neg_RM1t Income-decreasing real patient service cost earnings manipulations (RM1t < 0). Not directly reported
Estimated residual from the expected discretionary expenditures model (3) multiplied by − 1. Discretionary expenditures
RM2t Not directly reported
are the sum of R&D and general and administrative expenses, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets.
Pos_RM2t Income-increasing real discretionary expenditures earnings manipulations (RM2t ≥ 0). Not directly reported
Neg_RM2t Income-decreasing real discretionary expenditures earnings manipulations (RM2t < 0). Not directly reported
Total EMt Sum of AM1t, RM1t, and RM2t. Not directly reported

Explanatory Variables
NFP A dichotomous variable set to 1 if the hospital is non-profit, 0 if the hospital is for-profit. MCR S2I, L3, C4
MCR G, L59, C1; G, L1, C1; G, L51,
Lagged net operating assets. Net operating assets are the sum of total fund balance (i.e., stockholders' equity) minus cash
NOAt–1 C1;
and cash equivalents plus total liabilities, scaled by net revenues.
G3, L3, C1
Lagged revenue market share. Revenue market share is the percentage share of a hospital's revenues scaled by the sum of
Market Sharet–1 MCR G3, L3, C1
net revenues from all hospitals within a county in a given year.
Sizet Natural logarithm of total assets. MCR G, L36, C1
ROAt–1 Lagged ROA. ROA is net income scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. MCR G3, L29, C1
Occupancy Ratet Occupancy rate is calculated as the average daily census divided by the number of hospital beds. MCR S3I, L14, C2; S3I, L14, C3
Average length of stay represents the average number of days that a patient receiving inpatient care occupied a bed in a
ALOSt MCR S3I, L14, C8; S3I, L14, C15
hospital in year t; ALOSt is total number of patient days divided by total number of patients discharged.
Case mix index is a relative value assigned to a diagnosis-related group (DRG/MSDRG) of patients serviced by the hospital
CMIt during a year. CMI is a proxy for the allocation of resources to care for and/or treat the patients in the group. DRG stands CMSa
for “Diagnosis-Related Group.” MSDRG stands for “Medicare Severity-Diagnosis Related Group.”
The disproportionate share patient percentage is equal to the sum of the percentage of Medicare inpatient days attributable
to patients eligible for both Medicare Part A and Supplemental Security Income (SSI), and the percentage of total inpatient
%DSHt CMSb,c
days attributable to patients eligible for Medicaid but not Medicare Part A. DSH Patient Percent = (Medicare SSI Days /
Total Medicare Days) + (Medicaid, Non-Medicare Days / Total Patient Days)
TEACH Coded 1 if a hospital is affiliated with a medical school at a university. MCR S2I, L56, C1
RURAL A dichotomous variable set to 1 if the hospital is located in a rural area, 0 if the hospital is an urban area. MCR S2I, L26, C1
A dichotomous variable set to 1 if the hospital is identified by Medicare as a “Voluntary Non-profit, Church” hospital,
RELIGIOUS MCR S2I, L21, C1
0 otherwise.
Total reported uncompensated medical care (charity care) cost scaled by net revenues. Uncompensated care equals care
UCCt costs for patients that qualify under charity care provisions less payments by such patients plus non-Medicare-related bad MCR S10, L30, C1; G3, L3, C1
debt expense.

Inputs into Accrual and Real Activities Expectation Models (1–3)


Total accruals computed as change in current assets less change in current liabilities adjusted for change in cash, change in
MCR G, L11, C1; G, L45, C1; G, L1,
ACCt short-term debt, and depreciation expense (ΔCA – ΔCL – ΔCASH + ΔSTDEBT – DEPEXP), scaled by beginning-of-year total
C1; A7, L3, C9
assets.
ΔNETREVt,t–1 Change in net revenue, scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. MCR G3, L3, C1
PPEt Gross property, plant, and equipment scaled by the beginning-of-year total assets. MCR G, L30, C1–4
Total patient medical costs scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. Patient service cost includes costs of providing patient
Patient Service MCR A, L13–32, C3
services for inpatient routine services, ancillary services, ambulatory services, and outpatient services before the allocation
Costt MCR A, L133–137, C3
of non-point-of-service costs.
Discretionary expenditures are the sum of R&D and general and administrative expenses, scaled by the beginning-of-year
DISXt MCR A, L34–130, C3
total assets.
ROSt Return on sales. Net income scaled by net patient revenue. MCR G3, L3, C1
Notes: MCR data are from the 2010 format of MCR Form CMS-2552-10 available from the CMS (https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Down
loadable-Public-Use-Files/Cost-Reports/). A = Worksheet A “Reclassification And Adjustment Of Trial Balance Of Expenses”; G = Worksheet G “Balance Sheet”; G3 =
Worksheet G-3 “Statement of Revenues And Expenses”; S2I = Worksheet S-2 Part I “Hospital And Hospital Health Care Complex Identification Data”; S3I = Worksheet
S-3 Part I “Hospital And Hospital Health Care Complex Statistical Data”; S10 = Worksheet S-10 “Hospital Uncompensated And Indigent Care Data”; L# = line number
on the related worksheet; C# = column number on the respective worksheet. Not directly reported = amounts were calculated using the reported amounts on the MCR.
a, b, c
= case mix index (CMIt) and %DSHt data were extracted from the CMS at https://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Medicare-Fee-for-Service-Payment/AcuteInpatient
PPS/Acute-Inpatient-Files-for-Download-Items/CMS022630.html and defined at https://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Medicare-Fee-for-Service-Payment/AcuteInpatie
ntPPS/dsh

14
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

References Flasher, R., & Lamboy-Ruiz, M. A. (2019). Impact of enforcement on healthcare billing
fraud: Evidence from the USA. Journal of Business Ethics, 157(1), 217–229.
Forgione, D. A. (1987). Incentives and performance in the health care industry: The case of
Bai, G. (2013). How do board size and occupational background of directors influence
for/non-profit multihospital systems. Doctoral dissertation. University of
social performance in for-profit and non-profit organizations? Evidence from
Massachusetts–Amherst.
California hospitals. Journal of Business Ethics, 118, 171–187.
Forgione, D. A. (1999). Healthcare accounting research: A review of the professional
Bai, G., Zare, H., Eisenberg, M. D., Polsky, D., & Anderson, G. F. (2021). Analysis suggests
literature, models, data, and research opportunities. Research in Governmental & Non-
government and nonprofit hospitals’ charity care is not aligned with their favorable
profit Accounting, 10, 163–199.
tax treatment. Health Affairs, 40(4), 621–636.
Forgione, D. A., Schiff, A. D., & Crumbley, D. L. (1996). Assessing hospital performance:
Balakrishnan, R., Eldenburg, L., Krishnan, R., & Soderstrom, N. (2010). The influence of
An inventory of financial and nonfinancial metrics. Forum on research in healthcare
institutional constraints on outsourcing. Journal of Accounting Research, 48(4),
financial management. International Association of Management Journal, 8(2), 65–83.
767–794.
Francis, J., Olsson, P., & Schipper, K. (2008). Earnings quality. Foundations and Trends in
Ballou, J. P., & Weisbrod, B. A. (2003). Managerial rewards and the behavior of for-
Accounting, 1(4), 259–340.
profit, governmental, and nonprofit organizations: Evidence from the hospital
Geiger, D. R., & Ittner, C. D. (1996). The influence of funding source and legislative
industry. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 1895–1920.
requirements on government accounting practices. Accounting, Organizations and
Balvin, F. (2016). Association between the 2014 Medicaid expansion and US hospital
Society, 21, 549–568.
finances. Journal of the American Medical Association, 316(14), 1475–1483.
Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of
Banker, R. D., Lee, S.-Y., Potter, G., & Srinivasan, D. (1996). Contextual analysis of
corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40(1–3), 3–73.
performance impacts of outcome-based incentive compensation. Academy of
Guidry, F., Leone, A. J., & Rock, S. (1999). Earnings-based bonus plans and earnings
Management Journal, 39(4), 920–948.
management by business-unit managers. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 26,
Bannow, T. (2018). Charity care spending flat among top hospitals. Modern Healthcare,
113–142.
January 6. Accessible at: http://www.modernhealthcare.com/article/20180106/
Haggard, K. S., Howe, J. S., & Lynch, A. A. (2015). Do baths muddy the waters or clear
NEWS/180109941.
the air? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 59(1), 105–117.
Barton, J., & Simko, P. J. (2002). The balance sheet as an earnings management
Harris, L. L., Jackson, S. B., Owens, J., & Seybert, N. (2021). Recruiting dark personalities
constraint. The Accounting Review, 77, 1–27. Supplement: Quality of Earnings
for earnings management. Journal of Business Ethics. https://doi.org/10.1007/
Conference.
s10551-021-04761-z
Bartov, E. (1993). The timing of asset sales and earnings manipulation. The Accounting
Healy, P. M. (1985). The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions. Journal of
Review, 68(4), 840–855.
Accounting and Economics, 7(1–3), 85–107.
Bergstresser, D., Desai, M., & Rauh, J. (2006). Earnings manipulation, pension
Heese, J. (2018). The role of overbilling in hospitals’ earnings management decisions.
assumptions, and managerial investment decisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
European Accounting Review, 27(5), 875–900.
121(1), 157–195.
Hemmer, T. (1993). Risk-free incentive contracts: Eliminating agency cost using option-
Brickley, J. A., & Van Horn, L. R. (2002). Managerial incentives in non-profit
based compensation schemes. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 16(4), 447–473.
organizations: Evidence from hospitals. Journal of Law and Economics, 45, 227–249.
Herrmann, D., Inoue, T., & Thomas, W. (2003). The sale of assets to manage earnings in
Buchholz, F., Lopatta, K., & Mass, K. (2019). The deliberate engagement of narcissistic
Japan. Journal of Accounting Research, 41(1), 89–108.
CEOs in earnings management. Journal of Business Ethics, 167, 663–686.
Holthausen, R. W., Larcker, D. F., & Sloan, R. G. (1995). Annual bonus schemes and the
Burgstahler, D., & Dichev, I. (1997). Earnings management to avoid earnings decreases
manipulation of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19(1), 29–74.
and losses. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, 99–126.
Hribar, P., & Collins, D. W. (2002). Errors in estimating accruals: Implications for
Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). (2007). The provider reimbursement
empirical research. Journal of Accounting Research, 40(1), 105–134.
manual: Part 2. Accessible at http://www.cms.gov/Regulations-and-Guidance
Japsen, B. (2015). Hospital profits soar as Obamacare prescribes more paying patients.
/Guidance/Manuals/Paper-Based-Manuals-Items/CMS021935.html.
Forbes, March 1. Accessible at https://www.forbes.com/sites/brucejapsen/2015/0
Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). (2018). NHE fact sheet. Accessible at
3/01/hospital-profits-soar-as-obamacare-prescribes-more-paying-patients/?sh=194
https://www.cms.gov/research-statistics-data-and-systems/statistics-trends-an
79eda4da9.
d-reports/nationalhealthexpenddata/nhe-fact-sheet.html.
John, T. A., & John, K. (1993). Top-management compensation and capital structure.
Conrad, D. A. (1984). Returns on equity to not-for-profit hospitals: Theory and
Journal of Finance, 48(3), 949–974.
implementation. Health Services Research, 19(1), 41–63.
Jones, J. J. (1991). Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of
Dechow, P., Ge, W., & Schrand, C. (2010). Understanding earnings quality: A review of
Accounting Research, 29(2), 193–228.
proxies, their determinants and their consequences. Journal of Accounting and
Kaiser Family Foundation. (2017). Federal Medicaid Disproportionate Share Hospital
Economics, 50(2–3), 344–401.
(DSH) allotments. Accessible at: https://www.kff.org/medicaid/state-indicator
Dechow, P., Richardson, S., & Tuna, I. (2003). Why are earnings kinky? An examination
/federal-dsh-allotments/?currentTimeframe=0&sortModel=%7B%22colId%22:%22
of the earnings management explanation. Review of Accounting Studies, 8, 355–384.
Location%22,%22sort%22:%22asc%22%7D.
DeFond, M. L., & Park, C. W. (1997). Smoothing income in anticipation of future
Kallapur, S., & Eldenburg, L. (2005). Uncertainty, real options, and cost behaviors:
earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 23(2), 115–139.
Evidence from Washington state hospitals. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(5),
Degeorge, F., Patel, J., & Zeckhauser, R. (1999). Earnings management to exceed
735–752.
thresholds. Journal of Business, 72(1), 1–34.
Kassab, B. (2016). Florida Hospital, Orlando Health enjoy lucrative tax breaks even as
Demerjian, P. R., Lewis-Western, M. F., & McVay, S. E. (2020). How does intentional
revenues soar. Orlando Sentinel, January 28. Accessible at: http://www.orlandosent
earnings smoothing vary with managerial ability? Journal of Accounting, Auditing &
inel.com/opinion/os-hospital-tax-breaks-beth-kassab-20160127-column.html.
Finance, 35(2), 406–437.
Kirschenheiter, M., & Melamud, N. D. (2002). Can “big bath” and earnings smoothing co-
Diamond, D. (2017). How hospitals got richer off Obamacare. Politico, July 17.
exist as equilibrium financial reporting strategies? Journal of Accounting Research, 40
Accessible at: https://www.politico.com/interactives/2017/obamacare-non-profit
(3), 761–796.
-hospital-taxes/.
Krishnan, R., & Yetman, M. H. (2011). Institutional drivers of reporting decisions in non-
Dichev, I. D., Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. H., & Rajgopal, S. (2013). Earnings quality:
profit hospitals. Journal of Accounting Research, 49(4), 1001–1039.
Evidence from the field. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 56(2–3), 1–33.
Lambert, R. A., & Larcker, D. F. (1995). The prospective payment system, hospital
Dong, G. N. (2016). Earnings management in U.S. hospitals. Journal of Health and Human
efficiency, and compensation contracts for senior-level hospital administrators.
Services Administration, 39(1), 41–71.
Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 14(1), 1–31.
Duggan, M. G. (2000). Hospital ownership and public medical spending. Quarterly
Lamboy-Ruiz, M. A., Cannon, J. N., & Watanabe, O. V. (2019). Does state community
Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1343–1373.
benefits regulation influence charity care and operational efficiency in U.S. non-
Eldenburg, L. G., Gaertner, F. B., & Goodman, T. H. (2015). The influence of ownership
profit hospitals? Journal of Business Ethics, 158(2), 441–465.
and compensation practices on charitable activities. Contemporary Accounting
Leone, A. L., & Rock, S. (2002). Empirical tests of budget ratcheting and its effect on
Research, 32(1), 169–192.
managers’ discretionary accrual choices. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33(1),
Eldenburg, L. G., Gunny, K., Hee, K., & Soderstrom, N. (2011). Earnings management
43–67.
through real activities manipulation: Evidence from non-profit hospitals. The
Leone, A. L., & Van Horn, R. L. (2005). How do non-profit hospitals manage earnings?
Accounting Review, 86(5), 1605–1630.
Journal of Health Economics, 24(4), 815–837.
Eldenburg, L. G., Hermalin, B. E., Weisbach, M. S., & Wosinska, M. (2004). Governance,
Lynk, W. J. (1995). Non-profit mergers and the exercise of market power. Journal of Law
performance objectives and organizational form: Evidence from hospitals. Journal of
and Economics, 38(2), 437–461.
Corporate Finance, 10(4), 527–548.
Mehran, H. (1995). Executive compensation structure, ownership, and firm performance.
Eldenburg, L. G., Krishnan, H. A., & Krishnan, R. (2017). Management accounting and
Journal of Financial Economics, 38(2), 163–184.
control in the hospital industry: A review. Journal of Governmental & Non-profit
Molnar, M. (2004). Discount dilemma: Collecting from the uninsured. Collections & Credit
Accounting, 6(1), 52–91.
Risk, 9(10), 30–33.
Eldenburg, L. G., & Krishnan, R. (2008). The influence of ownership on accounting
Morrisey, M., Wedig, G., & Hassan, M. (1996). Do non-profit hospitals pay their way?
information expenditures. Contemporary Accounting Research, 25(3), 739–772.
Health Affairs, 15(4), 132–144.
Ernst & Young. (2017). Estimates of the federal revenue forgone due to the tax exemption of
Nguyen, T., & Soobaroyen, T. (2019). Earnings management by non-profit organizations:
non-profit hospitals compared to the community benefits they provide, 2013. American
Evidence from UK charities. Australian Accounting Review, 29(1), 124–142.
Hospital Association. Accessible at: https://www.aha.org/system/files/2018-02/ta
Petersen, M. A. (2009). Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: Comparing
x-exempt-hospitals-benefits.pdf.
approaches. Review of Financial Studies, 22(1), 435–480.
Everson, M. (2005). Letter to the senate finance committee by the commissioner of the
Phillips, M. R. (2007). Final audit report—Tax-exempt hospital industry compliance with
IRS. Accessible at: http://www.finance.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Letter%20from
community benefit and compensation practices is being studied, but further analyses
%20Everson.pdf.

15
J.N. Cannon et al. Advances in Accounting 58 (2022) 100612

are needed to address any noncompliance (audit #200610040). In Audit report Sesana, L. (2014). Why non-profits are the most profitable hospitals in the US. Arbiter
prepared for U.S. tax exempt and government entities division, Treasury inspector general News, April 8. Accessible at: http://www.arbiternews.com/2014/04/08/why-non
for tax administration. Ref #2007-10-061. Accessible at https://www.treasury.gov/t -profits-are-the-most-profitable-hospitals-in-the-us/.
igta/auditreports/2007reports/200710061fr.html. Van Scotter, J. R., & Roglio, K. D. (2020). CEO bright and dark personality: Effects on
Pollack, R. (2018). Community benefits go beyond charity care. American Hospital ethical misconduct. Journal of Business Ethics, 164, 451–475.
Association (blog), January 16. Accessible at: https://www.aha.org/news/blog/201 Vansant, B. (2015). Institutional pressures to provide social benefits and the earnings
8-01-16-community-benefits-go-far-beyond-charity-care. management behavior of non-profits: Evidence from the U.S. hospital industry.
Preyra, C., & Pink, G. (2001). Balancing incentives in the compensation contracts of non- Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(4), 1576–1600.
profit hospital CEOs. Journal of Health Economics, 20(4), 509–525. Vermeer, T. E., Edmonds, C. T., & Asthana, S. C. (2014). Organizational form and
Rosenthal, E. (2013). Benefits questioned in tax breaks for non-profit hospitals. New York accounting choice: Are non-profit or for-profit managers more aggressive? The
Times, December 16. Accessible at: http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/17/us/ Accounting Review, 89(5), 1867–1893.
benefits-questioned-in-tax-breaks-for-non-profit-hospitals.html?_r=0. Wallace, J. S. (1997). Adopting residual income-based compensation plans: Do you get
Roychowdhury, S. (2006). Earnings management through real activities manipulation. what you pay for? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(3), 275–300.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42(3), 335–370. Webster, S. A. (2004). SEC looks at auto firms in pension investigation. Detroit Free Press.
Rundle, R. L., & Davies, P. (2004). Hospitals start to seek payment upfront: HCA, tenet, October 20. Accessible at: https://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-123388568.html.
others ask patients to pay portion of bill before elective treatments. The Wall Street Wen, Y.-C., Huang, P., Shen, H.-C., & Zhang, Y. (2019). The role of organizational forms
Journal (Eastern edition, New York). June 2. Accessible at: https://www.wsj.com/ in nonprofit firms’ real earnings management: Evidence from nonprofit hospitals in
articles/SB108612290527926118. Taiwan. Advances in Accounting, 46(September). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Sahadi, J. (2018). Warren Buffet is right. Health care costs are swallowing the economy. adiac.2019.04.003
CNN Money, January 30. Accessible at: http://money.cnn.com/2018/01/30/ne Wilkicki, K. J. (2001). The effect of not-for-profit hospital reported profits and charitable
ws/economy/health-care-costs-eating-the-economy/index.html. care on perception of tax-exempt status. Journal of American Taxation Association, 23
Schuhmann, T. M. (2008). Hospital financial performance: Trends to watch; financial (2), 50–58.
indicators derived from Medicare cost report data are reliable tools for assessing the Zang, A. Y. (2012). Evidence on the tradeoff between real manipulation and accrual
effectiveness of a hospital’s operations. Healthcare Financial Management, 62(7), manipulation. The Accounting Review, 87(2), 675–703.
58–66.

16

You might also like