You are on page 1of 2

Strategy & Policy Brief #11-3, August - 2008

Transaction risks in market chains

Gerdien Meijerink, Derek Eaton, Jos Bijman

Introduction
The LNV-DGIS policy document Agriculture, Rural Entrepreneurship and Food Security has highlighted that well
functioning market chains can contribute to income generation of (small-scale) producers, transporters,
processors and service providers, thus leading to poverty reduction and economic development. However,
because market chains are often beset with transaction risks, the potential benefits are only partly realized.
For instance, many small-scale producers in Sub-Sahara Africa are currently not fully benefiting from the high
food prices because of dysfunctional markets. This brief outlines the types and sources of risks of transaction
failure (transaction risks) in market chains in developing countries and argues that the focus of policy
interventions should be targeted at reducing these transaction risks. We will illustrate this with our findings on
contract farming in oranges and pineapple in Tanzania (based on Eaton et al., 2008).

Different sources of transaction risks


There are various causes of transaction risks. In general, transactions will be prone to opportunistic behaviour,
including withholding and distorting information, or otherwise confusing or misleading partners in exchange.
Such problems increase when market participants find it difficult or costly to obtain information or when they
face limits in formulating and solving complex problems and in processing (receiving, storing, retrieving,
transmitting) information. Especially in developing countries, where information technology is less developed,
this can be an important impediment to exchange, although the use of mobile telephones is rapidly filling this
gap. Transaction risks also emanate from specific attributes of transactions, which we will discuss next.

When one or both parties have made investments that are specific to that transaction, they will run a
transaction risk. Default by the other party will lead to lost investments or an unfilled order when there is no
alternative market. Especially in “thin” markets with few buyers and sellers, transaction risks will be high.
Examples are investments made to produce a crop with specific characteristics (taste, colour, quality), or by a
specific production process (e.g. organic, Eurep/GlobalGap certified). Investments may be made to deliver on
a specific time (e.g. irrigation, greenhouses, cold storage) which is related to the product’s perishability.
Investments may be made in a certain locations where the produce grows well but which are far away from
consumer locations. The potential dependency between producer and buyer is a serious problem in many
developing countries and might lead to producers abstaining from investments that would otherwise be
efficient. In other words, they will not invest to become suppliers in modern market chains, but continue to
grow traditional commodities for which there is a secure market or for home consumption. For illustration:
farmers producing organic pineapples in Tanzania have made specific investments (e.g. equipment, boxes,
skills on how to grow organically). Farmers will lose money when the purchasing company fails to buy their
produce. Although farmers might be able to sell (part) in the regular spot markets, it will be probably at a lower
price.

Uncertainty is a basic feature of agricultural production. Uncontrollable factors such as climate and the fact
that biological processes lead to long production lags, cause volatile markets with possibly cyclically
fluctuating prices. This uncertainty leads to transaction risks because renegotiating and adaptation might be
required when unforeseen events emerge.
In contract farming for oranges for instance, when prices of into a formal (written) contract or an informal (verbal) deal.
oranges are high in times of harvesting, the farmer may sell (part As information is often asymmetrically distributed and the
of) the oranges to another buyer instead of selling to the party having information may not disclose it, contract
contracted buyer against the agreed but lower price. The buyer partners often have to spend time and effort in
has to incur costs to prevent this. strengthening their own bargaining position.
3. Monitoring and enforcement costs: these costs are related
Often contracting parties find it difficult to measure the to time put into and costs made to monitor and, if
performance of the other party in fulfilling the terms of the necessary, to enforce agreement. Monitoring can be costly
contract. For instance, it may be difficult to measure the quality because parties may have an incentive to hide their
of a product without investing in costly testing procedures. (opportunistic) actions.
Difficult and costly performance measurement leaves room for By establishing a set of rules or agreements (an institutional
opportunistic behaviour, which is a transaction risk. The effect of arrangement), a group of economic actors decrease transaction
this behavioural uncertainty is unwillingness to invest in higher risks and reduce the transaction costs in trading among each
quality. Also the low trust that is accompanied by high other. Devising new sets of rules to lower transaction risks and
behavioural uncertainty leads to additional transaction costs. For related costs can be seen as institutional innovation. Examples
instance, it is difficult to distinguish organic pineapples from are contract farming schemes or the establishment of a
those produced non-organically. The company has to incur costs producers’ organisation. However, establishing an institutional
to verify whether farmers have produced the pineapples arrangement and making it work is not easy as it might take
organically. substantial organisational skills and human capacity.

Finally, transactions usually do not take place in an isolated Institutional innovation


manner but are dependent on other transactions in the supply Institutional arrangements take place within a broader socio-
chain or in the sector1. For example, farmers first need to economic framework. This institutional environment consists of
procure inputs (cash, seeds, fertilisers) before they can start both formal and informal institutions. Formal institutions are
producing and selling. In developing countries, input markets are embodied in constitutions, laws, etc. and in government policies
often relatively undeveloped and inputs are not available at the and regulations enforced by courts, police, etc. Informal
right time, in the right quantities or at the right quality. Thus, the institutions are norms of conduct, traditions enforced by custom
lack of coordination or connectedness to other transactions or habit. A weak institutional environment, particularly in terms of
is another source of transaction risk and leads to limited legal frameworks, leads to difficulties in enforcing institutional
commercialisation of farmers who prefer to rely on subsistence arrangements. High transaction risks and a weak institutional
crops on at least part of their land. environment therefore inhibit the development of (new) market
chains.
Transaction costs
To protect oneself against (perceived) risks of transaction failure, The LNV-DGIS policy document Agriculture, Rural
market participants incur costs (called transaction costs). A large Entrepreneurship and Food Security has subscribed to the
share of transaction costs consists of the expenditure of time on proposed approach of the World Bank in its 2008 World
the part of buyers or sellers. In general, three types of Development Report to invest more in agricultural development
transaction costs related to exchange can be distinguished: through institutional innovations, development of markets that
1. Search and information costs: someone considering a are accessible to small scale farmers, and institutions for trade
transaction must search for a suitable party with whom to and markets. This brief emphasizes that intervention and support
trade and this search process involves costs. These costs should focus on minimising various forms of transaction risks.
may consist of visits to possible traders (e.g. in markets), This requires, ex ante, analysis of the extent and causes of
communication (e.g. telephone calls), looking up prices, transaction risks, and how they are distributed among the
testing and quality control. (potential) chain participants. Intervention, then, should be
2. Bargaining and decision costs: these costs relate to time targeted at reducing the transaction risks related to specific
and (legal) advice that is put into bargaining and negotiating investments, environmental and behavioural uncertainty and the
the agreement between parties. This agreement can be put need for coordination in the chain.

1
See: Dorward, A., J. Kydd, C. Poulton and D. Bezemer (2007).
Coordination risk and cost impacts on economic development in poor
rural areas, Munich Personal RePEc Archive.

You might also like