You are on page 1of 19

Article

Urban Studies
2020, Vol. 57(1) 56–74
Ó Urban Studies Journal Limited 2019
Exploring the theories, determinants Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
and policy options of street vending: DOI: 10.1177/0042098019835736
journals.sagepub.com/home/usj
A demand-side approach

Eghosa O Igudia
University of Northampton, UK

Abstract
Street vending has become an increasingly common feature of urban centres for several
decades, with a relatively high proportion of developing countries’ populations depending on it
for employment, income or survival. Taking a supply-side approach, studies have shown that the
responses of urban planners to street vending have followed the modernism theory. In this paper,
we take a demand-side (buyer-focused) approach to studying street vending, which has received
little attention to date from the academic community. Employing data from Lagos state, Nigeria,
we report four explanations underpinning the demand side of street vending: formal economy
failures, social/redistributive explanations, financial gains and a multifeature explanation. These
are, in turn, explained by the marital status, level of education and perception of individuals. Our
findings highlight the need for urban planners to embrace pragmatic policies in addressing these
demand-side drivers of street vending and use of urban space, rather than criminalising its actors.

Keywords
demand side, determinants, emerging market, hawkers, policy, street vending, theories

᪈㾱
ࠐॱᒤᶕˈ㺇ཤ䍙আаⴤᱟ෾ᐲѝᗳⲴ‫਼ޡ‬⢩ᖱˈ㘼൘ਁኅѝഭᇦˈӪਓѝ∄ֻ⴨ሩ䖳儈
Ⲵ䜘࠶‫׍‬䎆㺇ཤ䍙আ䀓ߣቡъǃ᭦‫⭏઼ޕ‬ᆈ䰞仈DŽ䚥ᗚ‫׋‬㔉‫ח‬䘋䐟Ⲵ⹄ウ㺘᰾ˈ෾ᐲ㿴ࡂ
㘵ሩ㺇ཤ䍙আⲴ৽ᓄ䚥ᗚ⧠ԓѫѹ⨶䇪DŽ൘ᵜ᮷ѝˈᡁԜ䟷⭘䴰≲‫˄ח‬䟽⛩‫⌘ޣ‬Ҡᯩ˅䘋
䐟ᶕ⹄ウ㺇ཤ䍙আDŽаⴤԕᶕˈ䘉⿽ᯩ⌅ࠐѾ⋑ᴹਇࡠᆖᵟ⭼Ⲵ‫⌘ޣ‬DŽᡁԜ࡙⭘ᶕ㠚ቬᰕ
࡙ӊ᣹਴ᯟᐎⲴᮠᦞˈᣕ੺Ҷ᭟᫁㺇ཤ䍙আ䴰≲‫Ⲵח‬ഋ⿽䀓䟺˖↓㿴㓿⍾ཡ᭸ǃ⽮Պ/޽
࠶䝽䀓䟺ǃ䍒࣑᭦⳺䀓䟺઼ཊ⢩ᙗ䀓䟺DŽ৽䗷ᶕˈ䘉Ӌ৸ᱟ⭡ႊါ⣦ߥǃਇᮉ㛢〻ᓖ઼њ
Ӫᝏ⸕ᶕ䀓䟺ⲴDŽᡁԜⲴ⹄ウ㔃᷌ᕪ䈳ˈ෾ᐲ㿴ࡂ㘵䴰㾱䟷ਆ࣑ᇎⲴ᭯ㆆᶕ䀓ߣ㺇ཤ䍙আ
઼෾ᐲオ䰤֯⭘Ⲵ䘉Ӌ䴰≲‫ח‬傡ࣘഐ㍐ˈ㘼нᱟሩަ㹼Ѫ㘵䘋㹼ࡁһᇊ㖚DŽ
‫ޣ‬䭞䇽
䴰≲‫ח‬ǃߣᇊഐ㍐ǃᯠ‫ޤ‬ᐲ൪ǃሿ䍙ǃ᭯ㆆǃ㺇ཤ䍙আǃ⨶䇪

Received March 2018; accepted February 2019


Corresponding author:
Eghosa O Igudia, University of Northampton, Waterside
Campus, Northampton, NN1 5PH, UK.
Email: eghosa.igudia@northampton.ac.uk
Igudia 57

Introduction In recent years, however, crackdowns on


vending have started to focus on patrons. For
Street vendors, a major sub-group within the
example, in 2016, the government of Lagos
informal economy,1 are individuals or ‘small-
state implemented a law that prosecutes both
business entrepreneurs, generally own-
vendors and their patrons. To date, however,
account or self-employed’, who engage in
little is known about the motives for patronis-
manufacturing and/or street-trading of ‘legal
ing street vendors, as few studies explore the
or socially acceptable goods and services’,
motives for buying vended products (Culiberg
particularly in mobile forms, fixed or semi-
and Bajde, 2014; Williams and Martinez-
fixed stalls, public/private spaces, whether
Perez, 2014). Specific to Nigeria, no such
regulated or otherwise; ‘thus [flouting] either
study exists. We contribute to the theoretical
business regulation, planning codes or other
and empirical literature by employing data
legal requirements’ (Basinski, 2009; Brown
collected from Lagos state to investigate, first,
et al., 2010: 667; Cross, 2000; Onodugo et al.,
the motives for patronising street vendors,
2016). They play important roles in the urban
and, thereafter, respondents’ perceptions and
economy by manufacturing and/or selling
socioeconomic–demographic attributes relat-
essential and unique goods and services at
ing to these motives.
relatively cheap prices and convenience to
The study is underpinned by the assertion
consumers (Martinez et al., 2017; Wongtada,
that vending thrives only when there are
2014). In developing countries, street vending
buyers of hawked goods/services. Thus, hav-
constitutes around three-quarters of small-
ing full information about vendors’ patrons
and medium-scale enterprises (SMEs), and
is as important as information on street ven-
provides employment, income or the means of
dors. In focusing on the former, this paper
survival for a relatively high proportion of the
undertakes a critical analysis of the three
urban population; it alleviates poverty, and it
main theories on buying from street vendors:
offers flexibility and autonomy to those
financial gains (FG), social redistribution
engaged in it (Brown et al., 2010; Cross, 2000;
(SR), and formal economy failures (FEF).
Maneepong and Walsh, 2013; Onodugo et al.,
From this we derive our research questions:
2016; Skinner, 2008: 30). However, corre-
What factors influence the decisions of indi-
sponding policies are ‘ambivalent’ (Xue and
viduals to buy goods/services from street
Huang, 2015: 156), ranging from support for
vendors rather than a formal shop? What
street vendors and accommodation, through
are the characteristics of these patrons?
to the repression of street vendors. Specific to
What is the best policy option following the
the latter, street vending has been criminalised
evidence from this study? To answer these
in many cities, including Lagos, Nigeria – the
questions, we set up seven hypotheses based
subject of this study. Underpinning a repres-
on theory and tested them in our specific
sive policy approach is the modernisation or
context. Specifically, we employed data col-
urbanisation theory. Here, vendors are viewed
lected from 160 individuals in Lagos state,
as a nuisance, disrupting urban planning and
who have bought products from street ven-
traffic, and carrying out criminal activities in
dors. Throughout this paper, the terms ‘ven-
the urban centre (Crossa, 2008; Xue and
dors’ and ‘hawkers’ or ‘hawking’ and
Huang, 2015). Thus, accompanying policies
‘vending’ are used interchangeably.
focus mostly on deterrence, with harsh punish-
The remainder of the paper is structured
ments for street vendors carrying out legitimate
as follows. Next, we present the background
economic activities (Cross, 2000; Crossa,
to the study, then we review the literature
2008).
analysing the demand side of street vending.
58 Urban Studies 57(1)

This is followed by methods, results and dis- criminalises street vending. Beyond confis-
cussion, and conclusions. cating vendors’ wares, the Law specifies a jail
term of between six and 12 months or a fine
of between 90,000 Naira (US$671.89)3 and
Background to the study 180,000 Naira (US$1343.78) for offenders.
The literature is replete with theories Street venders typically do not have money
explaining street vending and the informal to pay these fines, thus spending up to 12
economy (for example, see Cross, 2000; De months in jail becomes the de facto penalty
Soto, 1989; Hart, 1973; Huang et al., 2017; for vending on Lagos streets.
Maloney, 2004; Skinner, 2008).2 Most, how- Further, the same law potentially crimina-
ever, focus on the supply side. To avoid lises buying from street vendors. Offenders
replicating these widely discussed studies, we are fined 90,000 Naira and/or sent to prison
focus attention here on the modernism the- for six months. The Lagos state govern-
ory. This addresses the repression (or cri- ment’s justification for implementing these
minalisation) of street vending, hence is laws is based on the modernism argument:
particularly relevant to our paper. In the clearing environmental nuisance, security
next section, we move on to present a critical threats to citizens and projecting a good-
review of demand-side theories, this paper’s looking image of the state (AFP, 2016;
primary focus. Lawanson and Omoegun, 2018; Xue and
In this paper, modernism (Scott, 1998) Huang, 2015). Clearly, in the policy makers’
explains state/urban planners’ hostile response view, street vending is not wanted in the
to street vending. Modernism argues that, in Lagos ultra-modern, megacity project
relation to vending, an investment-friendly (Basinski, 2009; Lawanson and Omoegun,
urban centre with a good-looking image is 2018) because, as a nuisance, it distorts the
prioritised; consequently, urban planners urban centre and violates land use acts, state
criminalise and crack down on vending laws and labour regulations (Adedeji et al.,
because vendors are viewed as irritants who 2014; Cross, 2000; Wongtada, 2014).
make the urban centre unattractive to inves- Consequently, street vending must be
tors (Bromley and Mackie, 2009; Crossa, stopped/banned.
2008; Onodugo et al., 2016; Swanson, 2007). Enforcing a ban on street vending has,
Cross (2000: 30) sums it up this way: however, led to violent evictions of, and
‘Modernism often implied crackdowns on assaults on, vendors in Lagos. Even so, there
street vendors because of the ideals of public are doubts about the success of such poli-
order and state control.’ cies. Specifically, Cross (2000), Basinski
The modernism view underpins policy (2009) and Crossa (2016) show that policies
responses to street vending in many coun- promoting violent evictions of street vendors
tries. Laws prohibiting street vending have are often unsuccessful. This creates a situa-
been implemented in Lagos, Nigeria (Roever tion that can best be described as a game of
and Skinner, 2016). Similar laws, violent hide-and-seek. Street vendors continue to
evictions and harassment of vendors have operate, but cautiously, to avoid detection
been reported in Zimbabwe, Ghana, Hong by law enforcement officers (they sell when
Kong, Mexico City and South Africa (Cross, the latter are out of sight but run/hide when
2000; Roever and Skinner, 2016; Tibaijuka, they are visible). We were told during field-
2005). Specific to Lagos, the Street Trading work that street vendors now give ‘signals’
and Illegal Market (Prohibition) Law (1984, or make telephone calls to each other to
1996, 2003) prohibits and potentially avoid capture by law enforcement officers.
Igudia 59

Thus, despite the ban, street vending has not growth through this means (Igudia et al.,
stopped in Lagos (Basinski, 2009). We may 2016; Meagher and Yunusa, 1996).
find explanations in historical, supply, However, the three tiers of government tend
demand and socioeconomic factors. These to pursue different, even conflicting, agen-
(except demand, discussed in a later section) das. While local authorities grant/sell
are discussed next, after which we present operating-rights to street vendors, the State
some facts about Lagos. government, through law enforcement offi-
With a population of around 15 million cers, represses and arrests vendors, confis-
people, Lagos state is the largest commercial cating their wares (Basinski, 2009). The
centre in Nigeria and one of the fastest federal government, meanwhile, views the
growing cities in the world (Basinski, 2009). informal economy as a potential catalyst for
Nigeria is the most populous country in economic growth.
Africa with over 185 million people, an On the supply side, factors such as migra-
urban-population growth rate in 2016 of tion, limited formal-sector job opportunities
4.3%, and arguably Africa’s largest econ- and a high population growth rate are
omy with GDP in 2014 of US$568.50 billion responsible for the growth of street vending
(World Bank, 2018). Lagos contributes 32% in Lagos (Hyde, 2018; Igudia et al., 2016).
and 65% to Nigeria’s GDP and VAT Additionally, the government’s inconsistent
receipts, respectively. There is a significant modernisation policies have led to the
informal economy contributing to Lagos, repeated demolition of existing markets,
which provides employment for about 70% with former owners priced out of the new
of Nigerians, and ‘street vendors are the stores/markets turning to street vending
most visible manifestation’ of this (Basinski, (Lawanson and Omoegun, 2018; The
2009: 3). Guardian, 2016). As such, Lagos’s street ven-
As for the factors responsible for its dors, whilst heterogeneous in terms of age,
importance, historically street vending in gender, marital status, educational attain-
Lagos has been influenced by multiple fac- ment and product offerings, share a com-
tors: migration, fluctuating income levels, mon denominator in that they engage in
heavy vehicular traffic-congestion (which is street vending because there is no alternative
responsible for a loss of three hours travel- (AFP, 2016; Basinski, 2009; Hyde, 2018).
ling time daily and which has entrenched a Thus, people with(out) formal education,
culture of commuting-shopping), and inade- adequate skills/training, unable to find
quate urban planning – all of which have formal-sector jobs or secure a permanent
become synonymous with a densely popu- shop location, are left with the option of
lated Lagos (AFP, 2016; Basinski, 2009; vending (selling food, non-food, drinks, gro-
Gandy, 2006). As Nigeria’s former capital ceries, mobile phones/data, books, hard-/
city, Lagos attracts domestic and foreign software, shoe-shine services, etc.) for subsis-
migrants but, with limited formal-sector jobs tence returns, to pay rent and their or their
available, these migrants often turn to vend- childrens’ school fees (AFP, 2016; Basinski,
ing to survive (Basinski, 2009; Lawanson 2009; The Guardian, 2016).
and Omoegun, 2018). Also important are Finally, socioeconomic and demographic
Nigeria’s economic crises of the 1980s and factors influence participation in the informal
the resulting structural adjustment pro- economy, with diverse results reported in the
gramme (SAP), which pushed many into the literature. A relatively higher proportion of
informal economy, with national policy women, individuals with a low level of educa-
makers’ hoping to stimulate Nigeria’s tion, low skills, low wages/income, and a high
60 Urban Studies 57(1)

level of poverty, operate in the informal econ- thus far received little attention to determine
omy (Becker, 2004; International Labour the full nature of those root causes.
Organization (ILO), 1972; Schneider et al.,
2001; Verick, 2006). Specifically, more
women than men participate on the Explaining street vending: A demand-side
demand side (Sookram and Watson, 2008), approach
buying from street vendors in the search Studies on the demand side of street vending
for lower prices (Williams and Martinez- are few, but Williams and Martinez-Perez
Perez, 2014). Conversely, some studies find (2014) and Culiberg and Bajde (2014) are
that higher education attainment and among the exceptions. Our paper builds on
higher wages/income lead to higher partici- both studies. We explore, apply and extend
pation in the informal economy (for exam- the three demand-side theories defined by
ple, see Sookram and Watson, 2008). Williams and Martinez-Perez (2014): the
Although, Sookram and Watson reported financial gains (FG), social/redistributive
these results without offering any explana- (SR) and formal economy failures (FEF)
tion, the literature on tax and the informal explanations. Also, we adapt ‘perception’
economy has shown that fiscal knowledge from Culiberg and Bajde (2014) and explore
acquired from higher levels of education its role in furthering our understanding of
leads to tax avoidance or evasion, hence these theories. Whereas Culiberg and Bajde
increased participation in informality studied the personal morals and perceptions
(Helhel and Ahmed, 2014). The literature is of individuals about consumption tax eva-
also inconclusive on participants’ age sion, we take a broader look by exploring
(Sookram and Watson, 2008), although the links between motives and perception.
Williams and Martinez-Perez (2014) find Specifically, following Sookram and Watson
that younger and older people buying from (2008) and Williams and Martinez-Perez
vendors are motivated by lower prices and (2014) we employ theories, perception and
formal economy failures, respectively. (socio)economic variables to investigate the
Marital status influences demand-side par- demand side of street vending.
ticipation (Schneider et al., 2001), but The FG explanation covers buying from
cohabiting or divorced people with chil- vendors on rational grounds. Beyond the
dren buy from street vendors because of low-income population (Martinez et al.,
lower prices (Williams and Martinez-Perez, 2017) and the rich in poor neighbourhoods
2014). Specific to Lagos, Basinski (2009) (Cross, 2000), FG theory argues that individ-
shows that street vendors are typically aged uals patronise street vendors because of
between 12 and 66 years, are at least sec- anticipated/calculated financial gains. They
ondary school graduates, largely women, carry out a cost–benefit or ‘risk–reward’
married with children, self-employed, work analysis of their options, then break ‘the law
long hours but earn different levels of [patronise vendors] when the expected pen-
wages. alty and probability of detection are smaller
These mixed results demonstrate that than the profits’ (Williams and Martinez-
multiple factors explain street vending par- Perez, 2014: 803; Sookram and Watson,
ticipation. Laws prohibiting and criminalis- 2008). This plausibly explains the resilience
ing it are short-term, suboptimal fixes, which of street vending in Lagos, despite laws crim-
leave root causes unaddressed. There is thus inalising it. Basinski (2009) shows that Lagos
an urgent need for more studies in this area, vendors are ready to take risks, vend and
especially on the demand side, which has face the consequences, since they have no
Igudia 61

alternative source of livelihood. Conversely, care for others. Buying products from kin
people with dependent children buy from operating as vendors can be a way of show-
vendors to save money (Williams and ing commitment to kinship, even beyond
Martinez-Perez, 2014). Further, following family to include members of the same reli-
Martinez et al. (2017), it appears that people gion, business associates and friends.
patronise vendors in Lagos because they are
poor and earn a low income.4 With 87 mil- Hypothesis (H2). Social/redistributive motives
lion Nigerians (44.3% of Nigeria’s popula- drive individuals to patronise street vendors.
tion) living in extreme poverty, weak GDP According to the FEF explanation, individ-
growth (0.8% in 2017), rising unemployment uals patronise street vendors because of the
(highest among youths and graduates), and ‘failures of the formal economy’, including
wages of less than US$2 a day for those in delays in the provision, ‘lack of availability
employment (NGN18,000 or US$59, and reliability’, and the ‘quality’ of goods/
monthly minimum wage)5 (Kharas et al., services of formal firms (Williams and
2018; WPC, 2018), buying cheaper products Martinez-Perez, 2014: 803; see also Biles,
from street vendors offers most Nigerians an 2009; De Soto, 1989; Maloney, 2004).
opportunity to save. Typically, vendors make it possible for indi-
viduals to have easy and quick access to
Hypothesis (H1). The financial gain motive goods/services, irrespective of location and
drives individuals to buy products from time. Specific to Lagos, FEF arises from
street vendors. inadequate urban planning and infrastruc-
tural development, high population density
For its part, the SR rationale follows a post- and regular traffic congestion (Basinski,
structuralist perspective of the informal 2009; Gandy, 2006). Commuters have
economy. It argues that individuals purchase responded to these failures by shopping in
goods/services from street vendors to build traffic as vendors are selling their wares
or enhance social relations and ties such as through the windows of customers’ cars
kin, pursue social and redistributive pur- which, unlike supermarkets, is available,
poses (Round and Williams, 2008), resist accessible and convenient (Basinski, 2009;
anti-social practices (e.g. corruption) and the Hanafi, 2018; Hyde, 2018). Thus, unlike
exploitation of workers in the neoliberal eco- commuters shopping online in advanced
nomic system (Biles, 2009; Whitson, 2007), countries, commuters in Lagos do their
or support environments where individuals shopping from street vendors. Further, mul-
can transform work identity or discover tinational enterprises (MNEs) in Nigeria’s
their true selves (Williams and Nadin, 2010). telecommunications (e.g. MTN) and food
Here, ‘participants in informal markets [are and beverages industries (e.g. UAC foods)
seen] as social actors [and not] economic have modelled their business around vend-
actors’ (Williams and Martinez-Perez, 2014: ing, as their products are mostly sold on the
803). For example, during fieldwork some street (Neuwirth, 2011; The Guardian, 2016).
participants told us they patronise street
vendors out of ‘pity’; to ‘help or support’ Hypothesis (H3). The unavailability of prod-
them. SR is better understood when the cul- ucts in the formal market, and/or the faster
ture of close family kinship of Nigerian peo- or better-quality service of the informal
ple is considered. A popular mantra is ‘be economy, drive individuals to buy from
your brother’s keeper’; literally interpreted, street vendors.
62 Urban Studies 57(1)

In a study of the determinants of the infor- best practicable option for this study. First,
mal economy, Sookram and Watson (2008) they ensure the data collected cover a wide
report the strong influence of perception. range of geographical areas and are repre-
Similarly, in applying and extending ‘Jones’s sentative of the true population, considering
issue contingent model’, Culiberg and Bajde the huge cost and time required to cover the
(2014) report the strong influence of ‘moral entire population. Second, considering the
philosophy and perception’, and that per- spate of kidnappings in Nigeria at the time,
ception influences moral judgement and it was a realistic and practical way of gaining
intentions. Trivedi et al., (2003) observe that respondents’ trust in collecting the required
the moral reasoning, value orientation, and information. Third, avoiding a house-to-
social and political environments of individ- house survey gave respondents additional
uals influence their perceptions. We accept comfort and reduced any suspicion that they
these narratives and argue that respondents could be traceable (also see endnotes 7, 11).
have formed perceptions based on their In stage one, we employed a ‘street-by-
moral reasoning, orientation and experi- street survey’ (Reddy et al., 2003: 137), with
ences regarding Lagos’s street vendors/vend- a spatial random sampling method
ing and government policy. This justifies our (Williams and Round, 2009). The former
decision to investigate how their perception involves administering a survey instrument
relates to their motives for patronising to members of the public who cooperate,
vendors. whilst the latter involves selecting every
alternate location and participant for sam-
Hypotheses (H4–7): The stronger the percep- pling (see Igudia et al., 2016). Thus, we went
tion that: to business premises/workshops, public
H4: ‘hawkers are poor, disadvantaged’, the places and bus terminals to select every
higher the incentive to patronise on SR alternate adult who was willing to complete
grounds; our questionnaire. Where an individual
H4b. ‘hawking is helpful to hawkers’, the declined, the next person was sampled and
higher the incentive to patronise street the one after was skipped. We listed in
vendors; alphabetical order the ‘ten (10) most well-
H5. ‘hawkers pay no tax’, the higher the established street vending locations in Lagos
incentive to patronise them on FG grounds; state’ (Anetor, 2015: 36).6 Then, we selected
H6. ‘hawkers pay multiple fees’, the higher randomly for the survey the following five,
the incentive to patronise them on FEF/SR starting with the second, then every alternate
grounds; location: Ajah, Iyana-Ipaya, Mile2, Orile
H7. ‘Government overregulates, disturbs and Yaba. We administered 120 question-
hawkers’, the stronger the incentive to naires at each location, generating 600 com-
patronise street vendors. pleted responses. However, not all were
usable.
In stage two, we employed other criteria to
Methods select from the 600 responses. This involved a
We employ data collected in a two-stage purposeful selection, where only participants
process between May and August 2017 from who answered yes to the question ‘have you
vendors’ patrons in Lagos, Nigeria. In addi- ever bought a good or service from a street
tion to gaining empirical support (Arimah, hawker’ were selected (Williams and
2011; Reddy et al., 2003; Williams and Martinez-Perez, 2014, employed a similar
Round, 2009), our sampling methods are the question in their study). This yielded a total
Igudia 63

of 160 (out of 600) relevant responses, used in without offering any suggestion of possible
this study. The extra step was taken to ensure reasons.9 Interestingly, responses to this ques-
the information used in the study is from tion extend the literature, because cited
respondents who have bought from street motives for patronising street vendors in
vendors, in line with the aim of this study. Nigeria were not only consistent with
To help administer the questionnaire, literature-defined theories (FEF, FG and SR),
three indigenous assistants, who had recently but also a new, fourth explanation emerged.
completed their secondary school education We term this the multifeature motive.10
and who spoke the native Yoruba language, Finally, we employ multinomial logistic
were recruited and trained. Training the regression to determine the attributes of
administrators to avoid leading answers was these four explanations. Multinomial logistic
part of our efforts to reduce interviewer bias. regression is appropriate for analysing data
To check their understanding of the process, employed in this study; specifically, a nom-
they administered an early version of the inal dependent variable, with multiple cate-
questionnaire to 30 people. Feedback from gorical and ordinal explanatory variables
the pilot study influenced the design of (Sookram and Watson, 2008; Williams and
the final questionnaire. For example, we Martinez, 2014). The key question we seek
changed some words in the survey instru- to answer is, what factors, attributes or char-
ment: ‘vendor/(ing)’ to ‘hawker/(ing)’. acteristics relate to motives for buying from
Further, employing administrators improved street vendors? Our hypotheses, formulated
the quality and quantity of data we were to answer the question, are based on existing
able to gather, as the assistants helped to theory and literature: H1–H3 follow
debunk suspicion about the survey.7 Williams and Martinez-Perez (2014); H4–H7
We collected information on respondents’ follow Sookram and Watson (2008) and the
age, gender, education, marital status, income, evidence from the wider literature on factors
employments/business-enterprises, participa- influencing vending patronage. Finally, we
tion in street vending, perception and reasons test for internal consistency and the reliabil-
for buying from street vendors (but we did not ity of the variables survey instrument and
include a question on why they sell; this has achieve an acceptable Cronbach alpha coef-
been addressed in the literature). To ensure ficient of over 0.7 (Table 1).
response consistency and mitigate problems
associated with surveying the informal econ-
omy, some questions were repeated, but
Results and analysis
worded differently. To reduce biases associated Cronbach’s reliability test results are pre-
with collected opinions, both open and closed sented in Table 1 (for full-detailed results,
questions were employed (see Huang et al., see the extended appendix, available online).
2017; Iyenda, 2005).8 For example, we asked Following Field’s (2005) suggestions, a
‘why did you patronise street hawkers?’ Cronbach’s alpha of 0.7 or more (as reported

Table 1. Reliability analysis.

Number of variables Cronbach a

1 Reliability test for dichotomous variables 10 0.858


2 Reliability test for Likert-scale variables 10 0.712
64 Urban Studies 57(1)

Table 2. Respondents’ demographics and some Nigeria. Participants are relatively educated,
important descriptive statistics. with the highest proportion (40.6%) having
secondary school education (SSE), although
Item % of total
12.5% of participants have no formal educa-
(N = 160)
tion at all.
Gender: About half (49.4%) of respondents are
Male 51.3 self-employed. The rest either own/run a
Female 48.8 business alongside their main employment
Age:
16–25 14.4 (13.2%) or are in full-time employment
26–30 37.5 (18.1%). The highest proportion (41.3%) of
31–35 19.4 respondents carry out home services (gate-
36–40 13.8 man, laundry, plumber, electrician) or pure
41–64 15.0 services (mechanic, hair dressing, tailoring,
Mean: 32; Std deviation: 7.5; Mode,
Median: 30 repairs). Next is the proportion of respon-
Education: dents who trade (36.4%). Comparing gen-
None (no formal education) 12.5 ders, the highest proportion (33.3%) of
SSE (Senior School Education) 40.6 female respondents engage in petty/kiosk
HND/OND /NCEa 25.6 trade, followed by home/pure service
BSc/Degree 21.3
Employment status: (29.5%), then professionals (19.5%). For
Employed + run own-business 13.2 male participants, the highest proportion
Private/government employee 18.2 (43.9%) provide home/pure services, fol-
Fully self-employed 49.7 lowed by trade (31.7%), then professionals
Don’t know 18.9
(20.7%). Further, about three-quarters of
Main job/business activity:
Home/pure service 41.3 respondents whose main jobs/businesses are
Sales/trader 36.4 home/pure services provision (74.1%) and
Professionals 22.4 sales/trading (76.9%) have been involved in
Involved in supply-side street hawking the supply side of hawking, in contrast with
by main job/business activity:
one-third of professionals (34.4%) who have
Home/pure service 74.1
Sales/trader 76.9 been involved as vendors.
Professionals 34.4

Note: aHND: Higher National Diploma; OND: Ordinary Reasons for patronising street hawkers in
National Diploma; NCE: National Certificate in Education;
N: total responses.
Nigeria: A demand-side approach
Responses to the following open-ended ques-
tion are depicted in Table 3: Why did you
here: 0.712 and 0.858) is acceptable. We are patronise street hawkers? (This gains empiri-
therefore confident that the variables used in cal support from Huang et al., 2017). With
this study are consistent and reliable. just over one-half (53.3%) of respondents
In Table 2 we present the demographics patronising street vendors because they pro-
of respondents and some important descrip- vide accessible, fast and reliable goods/ser-
tive statistics. With 51.2% and 48.8% for vices, the FEF explanation is clearly the
men and women, respectively, both genders strongest rationale for patronising street ven-
are reasonably represented in this study. dors in Lagos, Nigeria. This is followed by
Although the highest proportion of partici- the FG rationale, with just above one-tenth
pants is aged 26–30, respondents were drawn (12.5%) of respondents; split between
across all ages of the active labour force in ‘cheaper than their cost in shop’ (10.5%) and
Igudia 65

Table 3. Respondents’ reasons for patronising street vendors in Nigeria.

Motive: % of total

Social redistributive rationale (help hawkers, networking/win customers) 9.9


Financial gains (cheaper/better than shop, save expenses/less cost) 12.5
Multifeature (only job known/survival, get quick/reliable money/income, easy sales) 24.3
Formal economy (accessible, reliable, save time) 53.3

Note: total responses (N): 160; respondents’ cited words in parentheses.

‘save on expenses, reduce cost’ (2%). Finally, that the informal economy/street vending is
with around one-tenth (9.8%) of respondents self-sustaining.
(split between ‘networking’ (2.6%) and ‘help Finally, the multifeature rationale is dif-
hawkers’ (7.2%)), the SR rationale is con- ferent from the three main explanations
firmed as the third main motive for patronis- (FEF, FG and SR) because of the core inten-
ing vendors in Lagos. These results confirm tions of individuals in this category: ulti-
Hypotheses 1–3. mately to sell, having started by buying from
However, a unique, fourth motive for existing vendors. As depicted in Table 3, the
patronising street vendors emerged from the words used by respondents categorised as
results. We call it the multifeature motive, multifeature relate to the supply side, whilst
with 24.3% of respondents patronising ven- words describing the three main theories
dors ‘to make easy income or sales’ (13.8%) relate to the demand side, of street vending.
and ‘to reduce stress, survive or do the only For example, FEF respondents use such
job known’ (10.5%) (Table 3). With the mul- words as ‘accessible’, ‘reliable’, ‘save time’,
tifeature motive, respondents patronise street whilst such words as ‘quick money’, ‘reliable
vendors for two reasons: to buy and to sell. money’, ‘easy sales’ were used for multifea-
They buy from street vendors to build a net- ture. Similarly, FG involves words such as
work of customers, which they in turn ‘make ‘cheaper’, ‘better than shop’, ‘save expenses’,
quick sales [to, in order to] reduce stress and ‘less costly’, whilst multifeature uses ‘reduce
survive in the only job/business I know’ stress’, ‘survival’, ‘only job known’.
(respondents’ words). Further, multifeature
leverages on the three main motives to build
Attributes explaining the demand-side
its unique identity: individuals want FG
because patronising street vendors provides theories of street vending
them with the platform to get quick and reli- The results in Table 4 show that four percep-
able money/income; they build a network of tion and two demographic/socioeconomic
people (SR), who in turn become a stream of variables are statistically important. Two
customers to whom they make quick sales; perception variables, ‘hawkers are poor/dis-
and they patronise street vendors because advantaged’ and ‘hawking is helpful to haw-
there are FEF, which they want to avoid, as kers’, measure perceptions of street vendors/
this ‘creates lot of stress’ (respondents’ vending, whilst the other two, ‘hawkers pay
words) for them. Thus, multifeature partici- multiple fees’ and ‘hawkers pay no tax’,
pants reduce the survival-related stress cre- measure perceptions of urban policy and
ated by FEF, by participating in both the tax, respectively. Marital status and educa-
supply and the demand side of vending. tion level are the relevant demographic/
Further, multifeature participants suggest socioeconomic variables, implying gender
66 Urban Studies 57(1)

Table 4. Multinomial logistic model results: motives of street vending and attributes.

Attributes Rationale Coefficient at different reference categories


SR FG MF FEF

Gender: Female SR 0 49.86(0.995) 50.7(0.99) 50(0.993)


FG 249.86(0.99) 0 0.8(0.42) 239(0.996)
MF 250.7(0.99) 20.84(0.42) 0 20.14(0.87)
FEF 250.6(0.99) 20.7(0.49) 0.14(0.87) 0
Marital status: Married SR 0 238.1(0.995) 236.2(0.995) 235(0.995)
FG 38.1(0.995) 0 1.85(0.062) 2.63(0.013)
MF 36.2(0.995) 21.85(0.062) 0 0.77(0.37)
FEF 35.4(0.995) 22.63(0.013) 20.77(0.37) 0
Education level: SSE & SR 0 16.94(0.995) 35.1(0.99) 36(0.99)
below FG 216.9(0.998) 0 18.2(0.998) 19.6(0.998)
MF 218.7(0.000)a 216.8(0.000)a 0 1.43(0.36)
FEF 236.6(0.99) 219.6(0.000) 21.4(0.36) 0
Hawkers are poor, SR 0 234.9(0.99) 233.7(0.99) 236(0.99)
disadvantaged: FG 34.94(0.99) 0 1.2(0.36) 21.68(0.198)
(Disagreed) MF 33.7(0.99) 21.21(0.36) 0 22.89(0.011)
FEF 36.6(0.99) 1.68(0.198) 2.89(0.011) 0
Hawking helpful to SR 0 18.3(0.995) 15.9(0.996) 19(0.995)
hawkers: (Disagreed) FG 218.35(0.995) 0 22.4(0.054) 0.74(0.56)
MF 215.9(0.996) 2.4(0.054) 0 3.14(0.004)
FEF 219.1(0.995) 20.74(0.56) 23.14(0.004) 0
Hawkers pay no tax: SR 0 220.1(0.000) 20.5(0.79) 0.5(0.79)
(Disagreed) FG 20.1[0.000] 0 19.6[0.000] 20.6[0.000]
MF 0.54(0.79) 219.59(0.000) 0 1.04(0.26)
FEF 20.5(0.79) 220.6[0.000] 21.04(0.257) 0
Hawkers pay multiple SR 0 20.5(0.998) 2.57(0.28) 20.68(0.72)
fees: (Disagreed) FG 220.5(0.998) 0 217.9(0.998) 221.2(0.998)
MF 22.57(0.28) 17.94(0.998) 0 23.25(0.026)
FEF 0.068(0.72) 21.2(0.998) 3.25(0.026) 0
Government SR 0 65.2(0.996) 70.5(0.995) 50(0.99)
overregulates, disturbs FG 265.2[0.000] 0 5.3[0.000] 215.3[0.000]
hawkers: (Disagreed) MF 270.1[0.000] 25.31[0.005] 0 220.6[0.000]
FEF 249.87(0.99) 15.3(0.999) 20.59(0.998) 0
Likelihood ratio 75.8***
Chi-square 114.49***
Pseudo R-square (Nalkerke) 0.8

Notes: ***, **, and * means 1%, 5%, and 10% levels of significance, respectively; p-values in parentheses; standard errors
in square brackets; aeduclevel(1); SSE: secondary school education; SR: social redistributive; FG: financial gains, MF:
multifeature; FEF: formal economy failures.

and age are statistically non-significant.11 economy (De Soto, 1989; Maloney, 2004;
So, too, is the variable ‘government over- Sookram and Watson, 2008) is not a rele-
regulates, disturbs hawkers’, implying that vant determinant of demand-side participa-
regulatory burden, a key determinant of tion. This is consistent with the findings of
supply-side and dual (supply and demand) Sookram and Watson (2008: 1541) that
participation in the street vending/informal ‘excessive government regulation’ does not
Igudia 67

Table 5. Difference between the rationale of street vending and the vendors’ attributes.

Formal Social Financial Multifeature


economy redistributive gains

Marital status Single n.s. Married Single


Education level Top-level Mid-level Lowest level/none Top-level
Perception 1: SH do not pay tax Agreed Agreed n.s. Agreed
Perception 2: SH pay multiple fees Disagreed n.s. Agreed Agreed
Perception 3: SH are poor, Disagreed n.s. n.s. Agreed
disadvantaged
Perception 4: SHng helps vendors to Agreed n.s. Agreed Agreed
escape poverty

Notes: SH: street vendors; SHng: street hawking; n.s.: statistically non-significant.

‘encourage participation’ on the demand Social redistributive rationale (SR): indi-


side of the informal economy, but it does viduals with an intermediate level of educa-
encourage ‘dual participation’. tion (above SSE but below BSc/degree) are
With both the Likelihood ratio (75.8) and less likely to buy products from street ven-
Chi-square (114.49) significant at the 1% dors for multifeature rather than SR rea-
level, and a pseudo-R2 of 0.80, these six vari- sons. Also, individuals who disagreed with
ables capture 80% of the factors explaining the statement, ‘hawkers pay no tax’ are less
respondents’ motives for patronising street likely to buy from vendors for SR than for
vendors in Nigeria. The sign of an attribute the FG motive.
demonstrates how it explains a theory/ Financial gains explanation (FG): relative
motive, relative to the referenced theory/ to singles, married people are more likely to
motive. Where positive (negative), the com- buy products from street vendors for FG than
pared theory is more (less) likely than the for multifeature and FEF motives. Relative to
referenced theory to be plausible. Next, we those with a BSc/degree, individuals with the
undertake a detailed presentation of results lowest levels of educational attainment (SSE
in Table 4. and below) and intermediate-level educational
Formal economy failures (FEF): relative attainment are, respectively, less likely to buy
to singles, married people are less likely to from vendors for FEF and multifeature
buy products from vendors for FEF than motives than for the FG motive. Individuals
for the FG motive. Compared with those who disagreed with the statement ‘hawking is
with a degree, individuals with the lowest helpful to street hawkers’ are less likely to
levels of educational attainment (SSE and patronise vendors for FG than for the multi-
below) are less likely to buy from vendors feature motive. Those who disagreed with the
for FEF than for the FG motive. Individuals statement ‘hawkers pay no tax’ are less likely
who disagreed with the statements ‘hawkers to buy from vendors for SR and multifeature
are poor and disadvantaged’ and ‘hawkers pay motives than for the FG motive.
multiple fees’ are more likely to buy from ven- Multifeature explanation (MF): relative
dors for FEF than for the multifeature motive. to singles, married people are less likely to
Conversely, individuals who disagreed with buy products from street vendors on the
the statement, ‘hawking is helpful to hawkers’ basis of multifeature than the FG motive.
are less likely to buy from street vendors for Relative to the highest educational levels,
FEF than for the multifeature motive. individuals with intermediate-level
68 Urban Studies 57(1)

educational attainment are less likely to buy Contrasting Culiberg and Bajde (2014), peo-
from vendors for multifeature than for SR ple who buy for SR motives do not patronise
and FG motives. Individuals who disagreed street vendors in Lagos to avoid/evade tax,
with the statements ‘hawkers are poor and but to build kinship. To speculate, the cul-
disadvantaged’ and ‘hawkers pay multiple ture of ‘be your brother’s keeper’ is strong in
fees’ are less likely to buy from vendors for Nigeria. So, it is common practice for family
multifeature than for FEF motives. members and religious/business associates to
Conversely, individuals who disagreed with buy products from a vendor-member to
the statement, ‘hawking is helpful to haw- show loyalty and maintain kinship, rather
kers’ are more likely to buy from vendors than to buy from outsiders/formal shops.
for multifeature than for FG and FEF Individuals who cite FG as a motive for
motives. buying from street vendors are likely to be
Finally, we present in Table 5 a summary married and to have the lowest levels of for-
of the unique attributes of these motives. mal education. Results confirm the findings
One may view the multifeature motive as a of Williams and Martinez-Perez (2014) that
reflection of the other three motives since it people with dependants buy from street ven-
leverages on them. However, as discussed dors for the lower price (FG) motive
above, results in Table 5 clearly show that (Basinski, 2009, reports similar results for
multifeature has a unique identity. married women). Results also support
Meagher and Yunusa’s (1996) observation
that working-class income affects the
Further discussion demand side of Nigeria’s informal economy
Individuals who cite FEF as a motive for and Martinez et al.’s (2017) argument that
buying goods/services from street vendors people patronise vendors because they are
are likely to be single and highly educated. poor and earn a low income, as the low level
The government’s failure to plan for and to of educational attainment suggests those
solve traffic-congestion problems (FEF) who patronise vendors for the FG motive
causes young professionals to patronise are unlikely to have attained high-paying
street vendors since vendors are available formal sector jobs – hence they earn low
and accessible. For example, to avoid late wages (Verick, 2006). With 44.3% of
arrival at work, young professionals leave Nigerians living in extreme poverty (WPC,
for work at least two hours early and, since 2018), respondents perceive that vending
they work Mondays to Fridays, they do not provides a poverty escape route, although
have time to shop at supermarkets. Thus, vendors are burdened with multiple fees.
they patronise street vendors for their daily Thus, for married women, buying from
food (e.g. snacks, drinks) and non-food (e.g. street vendors represents an opportunity to
mobile phones/data, hard-/software) needs, save, and thus escape from poverty.
as their only option (AFP, 2016; Hanafi, Individuals who participate in the
2018). This relationship is confirmed by their demand side of street vending for multifea-
perception that, although street vendors are ture reasons are likely to be single and
poor/disadvantaged and/or pay multiple highly educated. As noted earlier, these indi-
fees, vending helps vendors escape poverty.12 viduals have dual objectives for patronising
Individuals who cite SR as a motive for vendors: to buy and to sell. This is con-
buying from vendors are likely to have firmed by their perception that vendors are
attained mid-level education and are plausi- poor/disadvantaged, pay multiple fees, but
bly of the opinion that vendors pay tax. that vending enables them to escape poverty,
Igudia 69

as they do not pay tax.13 These individuals and multifeature reasons (buy and sell).
can be MNE representatives who patronise However, significant differences exist in the
street vendors to make them distributors perception of individuals patronising street
(Neuwirth, 2011), or traders in their own vendors for FG and multifeature motives, as
right, who in the process of going about explained earlier and confirmed by the
their business find the need to buy food/ results in Table 5. These results confirm
water or other items from vendors. We Sookram and Watson’s (2008) findings that
reiterate our earlier thesis that multifeature married people participate in the informal
participants suggest street vending is self- economy’s demand side, but they contrast
sustaining. with Williams and Martinez-Perez’s (2014)
findings that younger and older people buy-
ing from street vendors are motivated by
Conclusions lower prices and FEF, respectively.
This study extends the street-vending litera- Descriptive analysis shows differences in
ture by reporting four motives for which respondents’ gender and main job/occupa-
individuals engage on the demand-side of tion type but, in support of Asiedu and
street vending: FEF, SR, FG and multifea- Agyei-Mensah (2008), they are statistically
ture rationales. FEF (formal economy fail- non-significant. However, it contrasts with
ures) is the main motive for patronising the findings of Williams and Martinez-Perez
street vendors in Nigeria (over one-half, (2014) and Sookram and Watson (2008),
53.3%, of respondents). This contrasts with who reported significant differences between
Williams and Martinez-Perez’s (2014) find- men and women participating in the demand
ings that seeking lower prices (FG: financial side of the informal economy.
gains) is the highest-ranked single motive for The multiple factors reported in this study
buying from vendors; however, it does sup- highlight the need for pragmatic policies to
port their argument of a significant country/ tackle street vending in Lagos, Nigeria. Such
regional variation in the main motive for a one-size-fits-all and extreme policy as ban-
patronising vendors. For Lagos, our find- ning/criminalising vending represents a sub-
ings call into question the ban on or crimi- optimal and unstable equilibrium. Therefore,
nalisation of street vending, since policy as has been recommended elsewhere (Asiedu
makers are largely responsible for the main and Agyei-Mensah 2008; Basinski, 2009;
trigger, FEF. As explained earlier, the gov- Cross 2000), policy makers should ‘consult’
ernment’s failure to address traffic conges- with, rather than ‘confront’, street vendors,
tion on Lagos’s roads and consequent loss accommodating and allowing them to co-
of daily travelling time (FEF) underpins exist with the formal sector. One way of
individuals/young professionals’ patronage doing this is to ensure an honest, open and
of vendors in Lagos. continuous dialogue between policy makers,
Also reported are six variables relating to street vendors and their patrons. This is sup-
these motives: marital status, level of educa- ported by our findings that over one-half of
tion and four perception variables. Married patrons have cited FEF as their main motive.
individuals with low levels of formal educa- Finally, policy makers should facilitate an
tion attainment will likely patronise street environment that encourages all citizens to
vendors for FG reasons (lower price/to achieve their full economic potential, and
save), whilst single, highly educated individ- not criminalise those going about their legiti-
uals will likely patronise vendors for FEF mate business. This can be achieved by
reasons (accessible, available, convenient) ensuring policy consistency, redefining or
70 Urban Studies 57(1)

reclassifying what they recognise as ‘infor- Funding


mal activity’ (Xue and Huang, 2015), by The author(s) received no financial support for
deregulating the sector to allow informal the research, authorship, and/or publication of
economy/street vending to exist as an ‘incu- this article.
bator’ for business start-ups (Cross, 2000) or
by creating a vending drive-through market. Notes
However policy makers approach this chal- 1. The informal economy is defined as having
lenge, individuals participating in both the ‘three elements: informal employment (those
demand and supply side of vending should doing informal-type jobs, regardless of loca-
have the resources and opportunities to tion/enterprise[-type]); employment in the
achieve their full economic potential. informal economy (those working in infor-
To conclude, we hope this article stimu- mal sector enterprises, regardless of job-
type); and all legal activities that contribute
lates further research, as we cannot claim it
to GDP, but not captured by official statis-
provides answers to all possible questions tics, for various reasons’ (Igudia et al., 2016:
relating to the demand side of street vending. 154). Informal employment is ‘divided into
To enhance generalisation, future studies may two types: informal waged employment and
employ larger samples to reflect the popula- self-employment’ (Huang et al., 2017: 3).
tion of Lagos state and Nigeria. Findings Street vendors are a type of ‘informal self-
reported in this study were based on 160 employment’ (Huang et al., 2017: 3).
responses, although this figure compares well 2. The dualist, neo-Marxist, legalist, voluntar-
with those used in the literature.14 Moreover, ist, modernisation, structuralist, excessive
efforts were made to achieve high quantity/ state regulations, neoliberal and postmo-
dernism theories have been discussed exten-
quality samples.15 In addition, further studies
sively by these authors.
into what social ties mean and how they relate
3. Using an average of 2003 daily Naira–US
to vending would be helpful. Finally, whilst Dollar exchange rate: US$1.00 to
we have tried to reduce bias,16 we accept that NGN133.95 (obtained from the Central
it cannot fully be eliminated. We may thus Bank of Nigeria, https://www.cbn.gov.ng).
have omitted from this study a proportion of 4. Meagher and Yunusa (1996) note that
street vending patrons with uncaptured working-class income affects the demand
diverse motives. Nevertheless, to conclude, we side of the Nigerian informal economy.
restate this paper’s contributions: it reports 5. Using CBN published exchange rate
four motives for participating on the demand (NGN305.00:US$1.00) as at 20 August 2018.
side of street vending, including a new multi- 6. These are Agege, Ajah, Berger, Iyana-Ipaja,
Maryland, Mile2, Obalende, Orile, Oshodi
feature motive, which are, in turn, explained
and Yaba.
by the marital status, level of education and
7. Some respondents were suspicious of the
perceptions of street vending of individuals. purpose of the survey as they thought it had
Findings highlight the need for urban plan- been commissioned by the Lagos state gov-
ners to embrace pragmatic policies in addres- ernment to obtain information on street ven-
sing these demand-side drivers of street dors and patrons.
vending and use of the urban space, rather 8. Reja et al. (2003) and Geer (1991) note that
than criminalising its actors. open-ended questions generate genuine con-
cerns, spontaneous and unbiased responses,
and reduce biases arising from researchers’
Declaration of conflicting interests suggestions.
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of 9. Bias may arise from coding and analysing
interest with respect to the research, authorship, responses to open-ended questions. To
and/or publication of this article. reduce this bias, we first noted all the
Igudia 71

different words used by respondents, then References


we grouped the words into similar themes. Adedeji JA, Fadamiro AJ and Adeoye AO (2014)
For the question above, 17 different words Spatial implications of street trading in
were used, but many of the words mean the
Osogbo Traditional City Centre, Nigeria.
same thing (e.g.: ‘save time’, ‘quick’, ‘fast’;
Architecture Research 4(1A): 34–44.
‘reduce cost’, ‘cheaper than shop’, ‘save
Agence-France-Presse (AFP) (2016) No hawking.
money’). Through thematic analysis, we
No trading. Lagos bans street selling. The
were able to give the same code to words/
National, 27 July. Available at: https://www.the
sentences expressing the same meaning (see
national.ae/world/no-hawking-no-trading-lagos-
Table 3).
bans-street-selling-1.169735?videoId=56881577
10. We show in the discussion of Table 3, especially
36001 (accessed 17 July 2018).
the last paragraph, the justification for introdu-
Anetor F (2015) An investigation into the value
cing multifeature as a stand-alone motive.
of street vending in Nigeria: A case of Lagos
11. Income is excluded from this study, as
State. Journal of Marketing and Consumer
responses to the income question appear
Research 11: 35–41.
inaccurate and inconsistent. Although not
Arimah B (2001) Nature and determinants of the
without precedent (Arima, 2011, observed
linkages between informal and formal sector
that research participants often do not give
enterprises in Nigeria. African Development
accurate answers to questions relating to
Bank 13(1): 114–144.
their income), at the time we conducted the
Asiedu AB and Agyei-Mensah S (2008) Traders
fieldwork, the spate of kidnappings in
on the run: Activities of street vendors in the
Nigeria was at an all-time high. Hence, there
was a general lack of trust, which limited the Accra metropolitan area, Ghana. Norwegian
quantity and quality of income-related Journal of Geography 62(3): 191–202.
information we were able to gather. Basinski S (2009) All Fingers Are Not Equal: A
12. This assertion was confirmed when we re- Report on Street Vendors in Lagos. Lagos,
ran the multiple logistic model with Agreed Nigeria: CLEEN Foundation.
and Disagreed as dummy and redundant Becker KF (2004) The informal economy: Fact
variables, respectively. See Appendix. finding study. SIDA. Available at: http://
13. Results confirmed: see endnote 12; Appendix. www.sida.se/English/About-us/Publication_
14. Sample employed by Iyenda (2005) and database.
Huang et al. (2017) to study Kinshasa and Biles J (2009) Informal work in Latin America:
China were 125 and 200 respondents, respec- Competing perspective and recent debates.
tively. Further, we found consistent responses Geography Compass 3(1): 214–236.
to common questions answered by all 600 Bromley RDF and Mackie PK (2009) Displace-
respondents in support of the literature that ment and the new spaces for informal trade in
says the Nigerian informal economy shares the Latin American city centre. Urban Studies
similarities with those of other West African 46(7): 1485–1506.
countries (Meagher and Yunusa, 1996). Brown A, Lyons M and Dankoco I (2010) Street
15. Although interviewees were generally suspi- traders and the emerging spaces for urban
cious that the survey was sponsored by the voice and citizenship in African cities. Urban
state government, research administrators Studies 47(3): 666–683.
made extra efforts to refute this, hence the suc- Cross J (2000) Street vendors, modernity and
cess of 160 correctly completed questionnaires. postmodernity: Conflict and compromise in
16. See methods section. the global economy. International Journal of
Social Policy 20(1/2): 29–51.
Crossa V (2008) Resisting the entrepreneurial city:
ORCID iD Street vendors’ struggle in Mexico City’s his-
Eghosa O Igudia https://orcid.org/0000-0002- toric center. International Journal of Urban and
2566-3199 Regional Research 33(1): 43–63.
72 Urban Studies 57(1)

Crossa V (2016) Reading for difference on the Iyenda G (2005) Street enterprises, urban liveli-
street: De-homogenising street vending in hoods and poverty in Kinshasa. Environment
Mexico City. Urban Studies 53(2): 287–301. & Urbanisation 17(2): 55–67.
Culiberg B and Bajde D (2014) Do you need a Kharas H, Hamel K and Hofer M (2018) Future
receipt? Exploring consumer participation in development. The start of a new poverty nar-
consumption tax evasion as an ethical dilemma. rative. Brookings Publications. Available at:
Journal of Business Ethics 124: 271–282. https://www.brookings.edu/blog/future-devel
De Soto H (1989) The Other Path: The Invisible opment/2018/06/19/the-start-of-a-new-poverty-
Revolution in the Third World. New York: narrative/.
HarperCollins Press. Lawanson T and Omoegun A (2018) In transiting
Field A (2005) Discovering Statistics Using SPSS. to Africa’s model megacity . where is Lagos
2nd edn. London: SAGE Publishing. for everyday people? Available at: https://
Gandy M (2006) Planning, anti-planning and the ng.boell.org/2018/03/05/transiting-africa%E2
infrastructure crisis facing metropolitan Lagos. %80%99s-model-megacity-where-lagos-every
Urban Studies 43(2): 371–396. day-people.
Geer JG (1991) Do open-ended questions mea- Maloney F (2004) Informality revisited. World
sure ‘salient’ issues? Public Opinion Quarterly Development 24(10): 1611–1619.
55(3): 360–370. Maneepong C and Walsh JC (2013) A new gener-
Hanafi A (2018) Different ways Lagos hawkers ation of Bangkok street vendors: Economic
trick motorists into buying fake products in crisis as opportunity and threat. Cities 34:
traffic. Punch Newspapers. Available at: 37–43.
https://punchng.com/different-ways-lagos-haw Martinez L, Short JR and Estrada D (2017) The
kers-trick-motorists-into-buying-fake-products- urban informal economy: Street vendors in
in-traffic/. Cali, Colombia. Cities 66: 34–43.
Hart K (1973) Informal income opportunities and Meagher K and Yunusa M (1996) Passing the
urban employment in Ghana. Journal of Mod- buck. Structural adjustment and the Nigerian
ern African Studies 11(1): 61–89. informal sector. UNRISD Discussion Papers
Huang G, Zhang H and Xue D (2017) Beyond 75. Available at: http://www.unrisd.org/
unemployment: Informal employment and unrisd/website/document.nsf/0/0C598C026C
heterogeneous motivations for participating in 83F2DC80256B67005B6C16 (accessed 14
street vending in present-day China. Urban December 2012).
Studies 55(12): 2743–2761. Neuwirth R (2011) The Shadow Superpower. Avail-
Helhel Y and Ahmed Y (2014) Factors affecting able at: https://foreignpolicy.com/2011/10/28/
tax attitude and tax compliance: A survey the-shadow-superpower/ (accessed 14 December
study in Yemen. European Journal of Business 2011).
Management 6(22): 48–58. Onodugo VA, Ezeadichie NK, Onwuneme CA, et
Hyde P (2018) Loud and lonely on the streets – al. (2016) The dilemma of managing the chal-
The life of a Lagos hawker. Available at: lenges of street vending in public spaces: The
https://www.forbesafrica.com/economy/2018/ case of Enugu city, Nigeria. Cities 59: 95–101.
04/16/loud-lonely-streets-life-lagos-hawkwer/. Reddy M, Naidu V and Mohanty M (2003) The
Igudia E, Ackrill R, Coleman S, et al. (2016) urban informal sector in Fiji: Results from a
Determinants of the informal economy of an survey. Fijian Studies: A Journal of Contempo-
emerging economy: A multiple indicator, mul- rary Fiji 1(1): 127–154.
tiple causes (MIMIC) approach. International Reja U, Manfreda KL, Hlebec V, et al. (2003)
Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business Open-ended vs. close-ended questions in web
28(2/3): 154–177. questionnaires. Development in Applied Statis-
International Labour Organization (ILO) (1972) tics 19: 159–177.
Employment, Incomes and Equality: A Strategy Roever S and Skinner C (2016) Street vendors
for Increasing Productive Employment in and cities. Environment and Urbanisation 28(2):
Kenya. Geneva: ILO. 359–374.
Igudia 73

Round J and Williams C (2008) Everyday tactics Development, 25–27 May 2006, Berlin. Avail-
and spaces of power: The role of informal able at: www.iza.org/conference_files/
economy in post-Soviet Ukraine. Social and worldb2006/ (accessed 23 October 2010).
Cultural Geography 9(2): 171–185. Whitson R (2007) Hidden struggles: Spaces of
Schneider F, Braithwaite V and Reinhart M power and resistance in informal work in
(2001) Individual behaviour in Australia’s urban Argentina. Environment and Planning A
shadow economy: Facts, empirical findings and 19(10): 2916–2934.
some mysteries. Working Paper 19. Australian Williams C and Nadin S (2010) Entrepreneurship
National University. and the informal economy: An overview. Jour-
Scott JC (1998) Seeing Like a State: How Certain nal of Development Entrepreneurship 15(4):
Schemes to Improve the Human Condition 361–378.
Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Williams C and Round J (2009) Out of the mar-
Press. gins: Re-theorizing the role of the informal
Skinner C (2008) Street trade in Africa: A review. economy in Ukraine. International Journal of
Women in Informal Employment: Globalizing Economic Perspectives 3(1): 43–58.
and Organizing (WIEGO) Working Paper 5. Williams CC and Martinez A (2014) Entrepre-
Available at: http://www.wiego.org/sites/ neurship in the informal economy. A product
default/files/publications/files/Skinner_WIEGO_ of too much or too little state intervention?
WP5.pdf (accessed 22 February 2017). Entrepreneurship and Innovation 15(4):
Sookram S and Watson PK (2008) Small- 227–237.
business participation in informal sector of an Williams CC and Martinez-Perez A (2014) Why
emerging economy. Journal of Development do consumers purchase goods and services in
Studies 44(10): 1531–1553. the informal economy? Journal of Business
Swanson K (2007) Revanchist urbanism heads Ethics 67(5): 802–806.
south: The regulation of indigenous beggars Wongtada N (2014) Street vending phenomena:
and street vendors in Ecuador. Antipode 39(4): A literature review and research agenda. Thun-
708–728. derbird International Business Review 56(1):
The Guardian (2016) From hawkers to criminals: 55–75.
How the Lagos ban on street selling hurts the World Bank (2018) Open data. Nigeria. Available
city. Available at: https://www.theguardian. at: https://data.worldbank.org/country/nigeria.
com/cities/2016/aug/03/hawkers-criminals- World Poverty Clock (WPC) (2018) Nigeria.
lagos-ban-street-selling. Available at: https://worldpoverty.io/.
Tibaijuka A (2005) Report of the fact-finding mis- Xue D and Huang G (2015) Informality and the
sion to Zimbabwe to assess the scope and state’s ambivalence in the regulation of street
impact of operation Murambatsvina by the vending in transforming Guangshou, China.
UN special envoy on human settlements issues Geoforum 62: 156–165.
in Zimbabwe. Available at: www.un.org/News/
dh/infocus/Zimbabwe/Zimbabwe_rpt.pdf. Appendix
Trivedi VU, Shehata M and Lynn B (2003)
Impact of personal and situational factors on Table A1 shows results of the factors that
taxpayer compliance: An experimental analy- further explain motives for street vending,
sis. Journal of Business Ethics 47: 175–197. with Agreed being the dummy, whilst
Verick S (2006) The impact of globalisation on Disagreed is redundant for perception
the informal sector in Africa. In: IZA/World variables.
Bank Conference on Employment and
74 Urban Studies 57(1)

Table A1. Multinomial logistic model results: rationale of street vending and attributes.

Attributes Rationale Coefficient at different reference categories


SR FG MF FEF

Marital status: Married SR


FG 1.68(0.097) 2.05(0.059)
MF 21.68(0.097)
FEF 22.05(0.059)
Hawkers are poor, SR
disadvantaged: (Agreed) FG 3.48(0.031)
MF 3.9(0.004)
FEF 23.48(0.031) 23.9(0.004)
Hawking helpful to hawkers: SR
(Agreed) FG
MF
FEF 3.69(0.003) 23.69(0.003)
Likelihood ratio 68.97***
Chi-square 178.69***
Pseudo R-square (Nalkerke) 0.81

Note: Only statistically significant results are included; *** 1% level of significance; p-values in parentheses; SSE:
secondary school education; SR, FG. MF, FEF, as defined in the text.

You might also like