You are on page 1of 7

Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Business Research

Inter-organizational cooperation in buyer–supplier relationships: Both perspectives


Kyung Kyu Kim a,1, Seung-Hoon Park b, Sung Yul Ryoo a,⁎, Sung Kook Park a
a
Graduate School of Information, Yonsei University, Republic of Korea
b
Backbone Network Purchasing Department, Purchasing Strategy Office, KT, Republic of Korea

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Most empirical investigations of inter-organizational cooperation within channel dyads investigate the
Received 1 February 2008 phenomenon from the perspective of only one partner. However, because investigating from both partners'
Received in revised form 1 February 2009 perspectives is important especially when interdependencies exist between the channel partners, this study
Accepted 1 April 2009
attempts to examine both perspectives in buyer–supplier relationships and explain why differences, if any,
arise. The data that this study requires were collected from buyers responsible for supplier relationships in a
Keywords:
Supply chain management
Korean telecommunication service provider and from their partners. The results show that switching costs
Inter-organizational cooperation and inter-organizational trust are significant determinants of cooperation for buyers; technological
Buyer–supplier relationship uncertainty and the reciprocity of the relationship are significant determinants for the suppliers. In both
Telecommunication industry sample sets, goal consistency significantly affects inter-firm cooperation.
© 2009 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction activities. Arkader (2001) has found that buyers' perspectives are
different from suppliers' in regard to both the facilitators and the
In the new economy, as firms become more dependent on outside barriers of buyer–supplier relationships. For instance, buyers identify
partners to meet sophisticated customer needs, managing inter- “problems due to environmental factors (especially, adverse logistics
organizational relationships effectively becomes important to gaining and tax systems)” as important barriers to cooperative relationships,
a competitive advantage. Consequently, inter-organizational coopera- while suppliers identify “organizational barriers (mainly, the exis-
tion receives considerable research attention. However, most empiri- tence of functional resistance and the loss of power by buyers in the
cal investigations of inter-organizational cooperation within channel purchasing departments)” (p. 92). Therefore, this study attempts to
dyads have investigated the phenomenon from the perspective of only accommodate both partners' perspectives in the buyer–supplier rela-
one partner (e.g., Bensaou, 1997; Kim and Umanath, 2005). Investi- tionships to determine whether the perspectives differ, and, if so, to
gating inter-organizational cooperation from the perspective of both explain why.
partners is important, especially when channel partners depend on This study develops a comprehensive model of the determinants of
each other. Channel relationships that are asymmetric in dependence inter-organizational cooperation by synthesizing various theories
and power are more dysfunctional and less stable than symmetric relevant to inter-organizational relationships. The study then tests
relationships (Kumar and van Dissel, 1996). When dependence this research model by using matched samples from a buyer and
asymmetries occur, factors that influence the partner's cooperative supplier in the Korean telecommunication industry. The telecommu-
actions differ according to the partner's status in the channel, that is, nication industry includes the telecommunication equipment manu-
whether they have relative power or relative dependence. facturing industry as well as the telecommunication service industry.
While the buyer's perspective in buyer–supplier relationships The manufactures of telecommunication equipment produce compo-
receives much attention (for exceptions, see Helper (1991) who nents that can be integrated into a whole system based on a certain
focuses on the supplier's perspective), prior studies have shown a agreed-upon protocol. Meanwhile, telecommunication service provi-
discrepancy in the perspectives between buyers and suppliers. For ders deliver services through an integrated system with these
example, Forker et al. (1999) report that both parties have different components. Effective service delivery requires mutual adjustments
views on the buyer's implementation of the supplier's development and cooperation between the telecommunication service providers
and their equipment manufacturers, because modular technologies
must be integrated. Further, customer needs are constantly evolving in
this industry, as is the technology required to meet customer needs. In
⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +82 10 5309 9105.
E-mail addresses: kyu.kim@yonsei.ac.kr (K.K. Kim), eworld@paran.com (S.-H. Park),
this type of environment, both trading partners benefit from
ryusr@yonsei.ac.kr (S.Y. Ryoo), skpark@yonsei.ac.kr (S.K. Park). cooperation because of the considerable interdependence between
1
Tel.: +82 2 2123 4525. the buyers and suppliers.

0148-2963/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2009.04.028
864 K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869

2. Literature review access valuable partner-held resources motivates inter-organizational


exchange.
2.1. Resource Dependence Theory (RDT) Social capital theorists have focused much attention on the struc-
tural properties of these relationships (Adler and Kwon, 2002), such
According to the RDT, few firms can internally control all the as the tie strength at the dyadic level (Granovetter, 1973). While
resources required to function effectively (Reid et al. 2001). Sourcing strong ties are important conduits of resource exchange, Levin and
inputs from the market makes the firm dependent on other firms for Cross (2004) assert that the relational dimension of social capital, for
critical resources and thus increases the likelihood of unpredictable example, organizational trust, mediates the relationship between tie
events. This resource dependence perspective suggests that bilateral strength and resource exchange. Tsai and Ghoshal (1998) likewise find
relationships emerge as individual organizations attempt to secure that at the department level the structural dimension of social capital
necessary resources (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). If a firm is deficient in stimulates trust and the perceived fairness of the relationship, which,
a particular resource domain and possession of that resource is in turn, leads to the exchange of more resources between depart-
deemed essential for gaining a competitive advantage, then the firm ments. In high-trust relationships, organizations tend to be more open
will take purposive actions to acquire the resource (Reid et al., 2001). to the potential for value creation through exchanging and combining
Alliances are more likely to form for firms with a mutual need to resources. Social capital enables supply chain participants to become
exchange resources (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996). more engaged in social exchange and to take actions that would
Supply relations are crucial for any organization that subcontracts otherwise be considered risky (Putnam, 1993). Furthermore, the
portions of component design and production. Telecommunication relational dimension of social capital refers to resources that provide
equipment manufacturing, for example, involves a number of complex shared representations, interpretations, and systems of meaning
production activities that require capital-intensive investments as among the parties (Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998). When the
well as the development of an extensive sector of smaller firms that participants in a dyad have the same goals and values, they are
are devoted to component manufacturing. Existing studies based on more likely to form a cooperative relationship. Social capital theory
RDT perspectives identify antecedents for the successful cooperation identifies the antecedents for cooperative relationships such as inter-
between firms and their partners such as a firm's dependence on its organizational trust, goal consistency, and reciprocity.
partner (e.g., Kumar et al., 1995) and the governance mechanisms of In summary, RDT suggests that firms seek to reduce uncertainty
these relationships (e.g., Dyer and Singh, 1998). and manage dependence by structuring their exchange relationships
through various governance mechanisms. Thus, switching costs are
considered a proxy for dependence, and technological uncertainty is
2.2. Transaction Cost Economics (TCE)
considered a proxy for uncertainty. TCE asserts that opportunistic
trading partners could exploit relationship-specific investments, since
TCE provides important theoretical background for decisions about
these investments increase the firm's dependence. To protect these
whether the activities of a firm's value chain should be placed within
investments, TCE maintains that hierarchies such as vertical integra-
the corporation or outsourced in a contractual relationship. Coase
tion and/or goal alignment with proper incentive mechanisms can
(1937) asserts that the most efficient governance mechanism for an
serve as safeguards. Thus, in addition to the RDT variables, equity
exchange interaction is determined by minimizing the sum of the
ownership and goal consistency are considered determinants of inter-
production and transaction costs. Williamson (1991) also explains
firm cooperation. Social capital theory identifies inter-organizational
why transaction costs occur by using a model of market failure. Two
trust, reciprocity, and continuity as essential for inter-organizational
factors, human factors and environmental factors, may contribute to
relationships.
market failure. Human factors include limited rationality and
opportunistic behavior, while environmental factors consist of
3. Hypotheses formulation
uncertainty resulting from technological changes and the complexity
of external markets.
3.1. Technological uncertainty
TCE explains that inter-firm cooperation can overcome the
limitations of restricted rationality, secure economic efficiency with
Environmental uncertainty refers to (1) the degree of change that
reduced transaction costs, and realize transaction stability from
is unpredictable in the external environment (Huber and Daft, 1987)
opportunistic threats. That is, a hybrid form of inter-organizational
and (2) the lack of information about environmental factors that affect
governance, such as a mixture of complete market transactions and
decision-making. Among the many environmental factors that
hierarchy transactions, leads to efficient transaction costs or resolves
contribute to uncertainty in the telecommunication industry, techno-
uncertainty. In buyer–supplier relationships, TCE asserts that uncer-
logical change is the most significant. In the telecommunication
tainty can arise from the environment and/or from the trading partner
device market, predicting which technology standards or services will
(Bensaou, 1997). Uncertainty in regard to the environment results
dominate in the future is not easy. Rapid change in technology
from factors that are outside the inter-firm relationship. Uncertainty in
requires companies to process more information, which increases
regard to the trading partner occurs from the structural–economical
uncertainty for a company (Guimaraes et al., 2002).
features of the relationship and consists of two dimensions: the
The literature contains opposing views of the relationship between
governance structure of the relationship and the state of the relation-
technological uncertainty and inter-organizational cooperation. Ben-
ship originating from the climate of socio-political behavior.
saou (1997), for example, expects a negative relationship between the
two variables for the following reasons: “The inability to forecast
2.3. Social capital theory accurately new technical or design requirements for the parts and
components exchanged within the relationship may be managed more
Social capital theory asserts that relationship networks are a efficiently through no or loose coupling…and therefore less investment
valuable resource for social interactions (Bourdieu, 1986). Social in joint efforts, such as joint planning and development. By not engaging
capital is defined as “the sum of the actual and potential resources in such expensive cooperation, firms retain the flexibility to terminate a
embedded within, available through, and derived from the network of relationship and switch to partners with more appropriate technological
relationships possessed by an individual or social unit” (Nahapiet and capabilities” (p. 110). Perry et al. (2004) also expect that technological
Ghoshal, 1998, p. 243). Social capital perspectives encourage coop- uncertainty has a negative effect on investment commitment. Mean-
erative behavior such as inter-firm alliances. Specifically, a desire to while, Paulraj and Chen (2007) predict a positive relationship between
K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869 865

technological uncertainty and inter-organizational cooperation because without capital participation (Kogut, 1988). Gulati (1995) asserts that
recognizing resource dependence and promoting collective strategies to a form of alliance with equity sharing should be seriously considered
strengthen collaborative coordination between supply chain partners as an alternative because the alliance may reduce the time needed for
can alleviate technological uncertainty. negotiation. Pisano (1989) also finds that as the risk from an inter-firm
When facing high technological uncertainty, firms may choose to alliance increases, companies tend to prefer to have a relationship
either strengthen or weaken the collaborative coordination depending on based on equity sharing. This type of relationship implies that as the
several factors, such as the availability of alternative suppliers, existing equity of ownership increases, the relationship between the two
investments into the inter-organizational relationship, expected supply companies becomes closer. As such, this study considers equity
channel benefits from tight coupling, and firm-specific situations (e.g., ownership as a dimension of the governance structure that affects
criticality of the partner input to the operation of purchasing organiza- buyer–supplier cooperation. Thus, the following hypothesis:
tion). From another perspective, Dyer and Ouchi (1993) state that when
two firms are mutually dependent, they will prefer tight coupling H3. The focal firm's equity ownership relates positively to buyer–
because each organization is dependent on the other organization to supplier cooperation.
successfully cope with high technological uncertainty. For example,
Japanese automakers are renowned for their long-term tight relation- 3.4. Continuity
ships with their supplier partners despite environmental turbulence.
Japanese automakers are significantly dependent on their suppliers; the An inter-firm relationship adjusts over time. Accordingly, as the
automaker provides only general specifications, while the supplier takes transaction period between partners increases, firms must adapt to
care of all the detailed functional specifications. The suppliers are also one another, which increases the chances of future transactions. As
dependent on the automaker because of both their businesses and their the transaction period becomes longer, the expectation that the
specialized investment in the relationship. transaction relationship will continue in the future becomes more
Telecommunication equipment manufacturers and service provi- certain (Anderson and Narus, 1990). This expectation motivates a
ders are mutually dependent for similar reasons to those of Japanese partner to promote a cooperative relationship (Lusch and Brown,
automaker partnerships. Telecommunication service providers rely on 1996). This point also implies that a longer transaction period may
a few suppliers for specific parts and components because supplier's enhance the level and range of cooperation to improve transaction
products have limited external demands and thus a limited number of efficiency. Interaction over time may lead to commitment and to
suppliers. The incompatibility of technology among telecomm service relationship-specific assets such as partners' knowledge of each
providers intensifies this situation. Therefore, this study expects a other's procedures and values (Karande et al., 2008). According to
positive relationship between technological uncertainty and inter- Young-Ybarra and Wiersema (1999), shared experiences between
organizational cooperation in the telecomm industry. firms can foster trust and commitment, resulting in closer ties
between the firms. Thus, the following hypothesis:
H1. Technological uncertainty relates positively to buyer–supplier
cooperation. H4. The continuity of transactions relates positively to buyer–supplier
cooperation.
3.2. Switching costs
3.5. Goal consistency
This study focuses on the switching costs among many aspects of
dependence by considering the incompatibility of technology among Goal consistency refers to the consistency between partners in
telecomm service providers. A firm creates and modifies its assets to use organizational goals, agreed-upon priorities, and a mutual under-
for specific purposes, and as a result, their value may be diminished in a standing of their relationship (Bensaou, 1997; Krause et al., 2007).
different context. Thus, the unavailability of substitutes in a transaction Companies participating in an inter-firm relationship may have dif-
with another company creates dependence between partners (Mentzer ferent goals, and these goals may come into conflict. Inconsistent goals
et al., 2001). If a transaction-specific investment is converted into another may lead to opportunistic behaviors that may cause suboptimal
transaction, the value may be lost, forcing the trading partner to depend on performances in the supply channel. To avoid opportunistic behaviors,
existing investments (Parkhe, 1993). Therefore, a company tends to fix its companies and trading partners should share their goals and
direction of behavior once certain assets are invested (Yeh, 2005). priorities. If the goals of the companies are compatible with one
Because of the specificity of a company's assets, switching costs occur another, then their roles become clear and the acceptable range of
when a company attempts to engage in opportunistic behavior. Switching collaborative activities becomes more defined. Thus, the activities that
costs include the costs of abandoning existing assets specific to a arise from anxiety about mutual trust would be reduced.
partnership when a company terminates a transaction with an existing Furthermore, if a company is concerned that a partner may
partner and seeks a new partner. When switching costs are low, an opportunistically use information acquired from a cooperative
organization may change its partner without incurring significant costs relationship, cooperation becomes difficult. In this particular case,
and is hence less inclined to cooperate with its partners. However, as a making goals consistent may help to set the norms of acceptable
company bears more costs to establish a new relationship with another behaviors and reduce the uncertainty of a trading partner's opportu-
partner, the tendency to maintain the existing relationship intensifies. This nism. Therefore, the following hypothesis:
factor restricts opportunistic behavior and promotes a more cooperative
relationship among existing partners. In the case of mutual dependence H5. Goal consistency relates positively to buyer–supplier cooperation.
when switching costs from both partners' perspectives are high, firms may
have strong motivations to cooperate. Thus, the following hypothesis: 3.6. Reciprocity of the relationship

H2. Switching costs relate positively to buyer–supplier cooperation. Reciprocity of the relationship refers to the degree of fairness that
the participating companies perceive about sharing risk, burdens, and
3.3. Equity ownership benefits (Bensaou, 1997). Companies often accept a temporary loss if
that loss will be fairly distributed in the long run. If companies
TCE classifies the governance structure of inter-firm relationships perceive that risk sharing, cost sharing and profit distribution are
in terms of equity ownership. Firms can cooperate either with or reciprocal, each partner seeks to maintain the cooperative
866 K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869

relationship. As such, the reciprocity of the relationship could affect All of the buyers and their counterpart suppliers were invited to
the level of buyer–supplier cooperation. Therefore, the following participate in the study. Two follow-up emails were sent five and ten
hypothesis: days, respectively, after the initial contact. Respondents sent the
completed questionnaires to the primary author. A total of 100
H6. The reciprocity of the relationship relates positively to buyer– responses from buyers (response rate of 75.7%) and 98 responses from
supplier cooperation. suppliers (response rate of 74.2%) were received within 14 days. Of
those responses, 69 cases were paired responses. To evaluate any
systematic differences between paired responses and non-paired
3.7. Inter-organizational trust
responses in the sample, ANOVAs were performed on all independent
variables. No statistically significant differences occur among the
Morgan and Hunt (1994) define trust as conviction about the
companies at the 0.05 level of significance.
certainty and honesty of a trading partner, while Zaheer et al. (1998)
define trust as the collective trust that every member of an
organization puts into another trading partner. Trust between two 4.2. Measures
partners affects the relationship in three ways: (1) a reduction of
perceived risk regarding opportunistic behavior; (2) expectations that All measures used in this study were drawn from previous studies
short-term unfairness would be solved in the long-term; and (3) a and adapted to serve the purposes of this study. Table 1 describes the
reduction in the transaction costs inherent to exchange relationships. operational definitions of the research variables and their sources.
Further, inter-organizational trust is necessary to dissolve potential Pretests were performed to ensure that the target informants
conflicts easily (Anderson and Weitz, 1992) and reinforce long-term understood the wording that the authors used. The respondents
orientations with partners (Ryu et al., 2007). Therefore, the following were asked to indicate their responses to each of the survey questions,
hypothesis: which have a seven-point scale anchored with “Strongly Disagree”
and “Strongly Agree.” Multiple-choice questions measured the equity
H7. Inter-organizational trust between buyers and suppliers relates ownership ratio and the continuity of the relationship.
positively to buyer–supplier cooperation.
4.3. Data analysis
4. Methodology
Since the original questions underwent minor wording changes to
4.1. Sample and data collection customize the questionnaire to a supply channel setting, this study
performed principal components analysis on the data to ascertain the
Since a supply channel is a dyadic environment, this research integrity of the dimensionality sought. The analysis with Varimax
examines the phenomenon from the perspectives of both the buyer rotation provided preliminary validation of the conceptualized
and supplier in a dyad. The data required for this study were collected constructs.
(1) from the buyers responsible for the supplier relationships in a Table 2 provides the standardized parameter estimates (factor
major telecommunication service company headquartered in Korea; loadings) of the items over the underlying dimensions for both the
and (2) from the suppliers that provide the telecommunication buyer and supplier samples. The frequently cited standard of 0.60 was
devices to the buyer. At the time the data were collected, the annual applied as the cut off value for the factor loadings. As a result, one
sales of the central organization for the year 2006 was U$12.6 billion, question for inter-organizational trust was eliminated.
and 132 buyers were in the purchasing division. The buyers were Tables 3 and 4 present the descriptive statistics and bi-variate
organized around the devices and services (i.e., Switching, Terminal, correlations among the research variables. The internal reliability tests
Line Materials, etc.) that they were procuring for the company. using Cronbach's Alpha showed that all measures for the constructs
Typically, most of the buyers are responsible for multiple components, exceeded Nunnally and Bernstein's (1994) threshold value of 0.70.
and they often use multiple suppliers to obtain each component. Thus,
the buyers selected an important component and a major supplier for 4.4. Testing of the hypotheses
the component and then responded to the questionnaire in the
context of an ongoing relationship with the supplier. Information Table 5 summarizes the results of the regression analyses that were
about the chosen supplier was also solicited in order to collect data used for testing the hypotheses. In the buyer sample set, contrary to
about the supplier's view of the relationship. The annual sales of expectations, technological uncertainty (H1, t = − 0.04, p = 0.97) was
suppliers for the year 2006 were as follows: 56.1% made less than U not significant, while the switching costs (H2, t = 2.55, p = 0.01)
$10 million, 15.3% made between U$10 million and U$100 million, and significantly influenced inter-organizational cooperation. Neither the
28.6% made over U$100 million. equity ownership ratio (H3, t = 0.90, p = 0.37) nor the continuity of

Table 1
Operationalization of the variables.

Variables Operational definitions Sources


Technological The likelihood of changes in four areas (i.e., functionality improvements, price/performance Bensaou, 1997
uncertainty improvements, major product innovations, major manufacturing innovations) during the next three years
Switching costs Degree of the lost benefit or cost in four dimensions (i.e. time, economic costs, cognitive costs, cognitive Morgan and Hunt, 1994; Whitten and Wakefield,
effort to search for alternatives) by the termination of inter-organizational relationships 2006
Equity ownership Extent of shared equity between partners Kim and Umanath, 2005
Continuity Continuity of transactions between partners Kim and Umanath, 2005
Goal consistency Extent of reciprocal understanding between partners Bensaou, 1997
Reciprocity of Extent of reciprocity between partners Bensaou, 1997
the relationship
Inter-organizational Degree of the firm's aggregate level of trust Moorman et al., 1993
trust
Cooperation Degree of cooperation between partners Bensaou, 1997
K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869 867

Table 2 organizational cooperation. The reciprocity of the relationship (H6,


Factor loadings of the measures. t = 1.59, p = 0.12) did not significantly influence cooperation.
Factor Item Factor loading In the supplier sample set, the results were quite different from
Buyer Supplier those of the buyer sample set. Technological uncertainty (H1, t =
Technological TU1: How likely will major changes occur in 0.79 0.86 −2.97, p = 0.00) had a significant negative association with inter-
uncertainty regards to functionality improvements organizational cooperation (contrary to expectations), while the
during the next three years impact of switching costs (H2, t = − 1.85, p = 0.07) was not
TU2: How likely will major changes occur in 0.81 0.89 significant. As in the buyer sample set, neither the equity ownership
regards to price/performance improvements
during the next three years
ratio (H3, t = 1.20, p = 0.23) nor the continuity of the relationship
TU3: How likely will major changes occur in 0.84 0.68 (H4, t = 0.46, p = 0.65) was significant. Both goal consistency (H5,
regards to major product innovations during t = 4.34, p = 0.00) and the reciprocity of the relationship (H6,
the next three years t = 3.58, p = 0.00) had significant associations with cooperation,
TU4: How likely will major changes occur in 0.86 0.62
while inter-organizational trust (H5, t = 0.53, p = 0.60) did not.
regards to major manufacturing innovations
during the next three years As the differences in the results show, switching costs and inter-
Switching costs SC1: Switching to another partner takes a 0.88 0.92 organizational trust are significant determinants of cooperation from
long time the perspective of the buyers, but not for suppliers. In addition,
SC2: Switching to another partner results in 0.86 0.88 technological uncertainty (although negatively related to inter-firm
significant economic costs
SC3: Switching to another partner results in 0.83 0.90
cooperation) and the reciprocity of the relationship are significant
significant cognitive costs from the perspective of suppliers, but not from that of buyers.
SC4: Switching to another partner results in 0.79 0.82
significant search costs 5. Discussion
Goal consistency GC1: We and our partner understand each 0.77 0.68
other's goals
GC2: We and our partner understand each 0.66 0.57 This paper contributes in two ways to the existing literature. First, a
other's priorities comprehensive general model of inter-organizational cooperation in
GC3: We and our partner understand each 0.84 0.64 buyer–supplier relationships is developed by synthesizing three
other's products and processes relevant theories, that is, RDT, TCE, and social capital theory. Second,
GC4: We and our partner understand each 0.74 0.74
other's roles and responsibilities
by comparing the perspectives of both the buyer and supplier, this
Reciprocity of RR1: We share risks with the partner 0.88 0.78 paper identifies differences in the determinants of inter-organiza-
the relationship RR2: We share burdens with the partner 0.90 0.84 tional cooperation. The results of this study demonstrate that striking
RR3: We share benefits with the partner 0.86 0.77 differences exist between the two perspectives. These differences can
Inter- OT2: Even if we are unable to monitor our 0.86 0.77
be explained by the dependence asymmetry in the supply channel in
organizational trust partners, we trust that they are fulfilling
their obligations which buyers enjoy relative power over their suppliers (Kumar et al.,
OT3: We trust our partners to do things we 0.86 0.73 1995).
cannot do ourselves The majority of suppliers of components of telecommunication
OT4: We trust our partners to carry out 0.79 0.74 equipment face more restricted markets for materials, capital, and
important project-related activities
OT5: We generally trust our partners 0.80 0.72
labor. Dependence on a central organization (i.e., the buyer in this
Cooperation CO1: We generally cooperate with partners 0.73 0.76 study) with broader exchange capabilities poses a troublesome
in long-range planning problem for organizations with narrower exchange possibilities
CO2: We generally cooperate with partners 0.86 0.74 operating exclusively in a well-defined segment of a producer's
in product planning
market (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). Since the supplier is in a
CO3: We generally cooperate with partners 0.88 0.79
in product engineering dependent relationship with a powerful partner, the reciprocity of
CO4: We generally cooperate with partners 0.75 0.83 the relationship is important to ensuring voluntary cooperation with
in process engineering the buyer. However, reciprocity is less important to buyers, because
CO5: We generally cooperate with partners 0.84 0.79 buyers can exercise direct control over dependent suppliers whenever
in tooling development
CO6: We generally cooperate with partners 0.67 0.66
necessary.
in technical assistance A central organization has to develop a higher level of architectural
CO7: We generally cooperate with partners 0.64 0.76 knowledge of the equipment and to transfer part of its knowledge to
in training/education the supplier for production. This situation requires a significant
investment of time and effort from the buyer. If a supplier behaves
opportunistically after the buyer has made these investments, then
the relationship (H4, t = −0.02, p = 0.98) was significant. By contrast, the buyer would have to bear significant switching costs to develop a
goal consistency (H5, t = 4.98, p = 0.00) and inter-organizational new supplier relation. Thus, switching costs are an important factor in
trust (H7, t = 3.96, p = 0.00) had significant relationships with inter- determining a buyer's cooperation. In addition, if the buyer does

Table 3
Descriptive statistics for the buyer sample.

Factor No. of item Mean (Strd. Dev.) Cronbach's Alpha TU SC EO CO GC RR IT


Technological uncertainty (TU) 4 4.5 (1.4) 0.88 1
Switching costs (SC) 4 4.3 (1.4) 0.88 .09 1
Equity ownership (EO) 1 1.1 (0.1) N.A. − .05 .04 1
Continuity (CO) 1 4.7 (1.6) N.A. − .08 .08 .07 1
Goal consistency (GC) 4 5.4 (1.1) 0.91 .45** .20* .03 .06 1
Reciprocity of the relationship (RR) 3 4.0 (1.2) 0.89 .23* − .07 .03 .00 .29** 1
Inter-organizational trust (IT) 4 4.8 (1.2) 0.93 .24* .24* .01 − .03 .57** .17 1
Inter-organizational cooperation (IC) 7 4.9 (1.2) 0.95 .31* .33** .09 .03 .69** .28** .63**

Notes: **p b 0.05, ***p b 0.01.


868 K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869

Table 4
Descriptive statistics for the supplier sample.

Factor No. of item Mean (Strd. Dev.) Cronbach's Alpha TU SC EO CO GC RR IT


Technological uncertainty (TU) 4 3.9 (1.3) 0.83 1
Switching costs (SC) 4 5.1 (1.5) 0.92 .31** 1
Equity ownership (EO) 1 1.0 (0.1) N.A. .16 .10 1
Continuity (CO) 1 5.1 (1.8) N.A. − .05 .09 − .00 1
Goal consistency (GC) 4 5.2 (0.9) 0.86 − .38** − .24* − .04 .10 1
Reciprocity of the relationship (RR) 3 5.0 (1.1) 0.88 − .27** − .15 .03 .08 .69** 1
Inter-organizational trust (IT) 4 3.7 (1.3) 0.89 − .22* − .13 − .11 − .04 .45** .58** 1
Inter-organizational Cooperation (IC) 7 4.9 (1.1) 0.95 − .48** − .33** − .01 .07 .69** .59** .56**

Notes: **p b 0.05, ***p b 0.01.

not trust a supplier and is concerned that the supplier will be indicates that capital investment or joint venture was not a popular
opportunistic, the buyer may not cooperate with the supplier. The inter-firm governance structure in the Korean telecommunication
supplier's trust in the buyer is not important, however, because the industry. The continuity of the relationship resulted in two clusters;
supplier has no choice but to cooperate when the buyer exercises one short-term cluster of 2–3 years for service-specific products (e.g.,
coercive power. Internet, new services) and one long-term cluster of 7 years or more
Technological uncertainty poses an important threat to all for technology-specific products (e.g., cables, switches). Buyers prefer
participants in the telecommunication industry, but such uncertainty year-by-year short-term contracts to maintain bargaining leverage
has different implications according to the firm's status in the supply and to hedge against sudden shifts in customer preferences.
channel. For a smaller supplier who has to deal with powerful
partners, any changes in technology may lead to a termination of the 6. Conclusions
contract if the supplier's technical expertise becomes obsolete and if
the buyer is not mutually dependent on the supplier. This fear can be This paper attempts to explain the differences in the antecedents
intensified when alternative suppliers are available and the buyer's to the buyer–supplier cooperation in terms of dependence asymmetry
existing investments in the inter-organizational relationship are not between the buyer and the supplier. Increasing interdependence
large. Thus, suppliers, under conditions of high technological asymmetries may lead to higher levels of suspicion and conflict in the
uncertainty, may hesitate to fully cooperate with the buyer since the relationship. However, interdependence asymmetry does not neces-
relationship itself may be in danger. However, technological uncer- sarily cause irreversible and damaging conflict. Firms in a supply
tainty has a different implication for buyers with relative power. channel may behave differently because their strategic positions and
Although telecommunication service providers are responsible for market situations are different. Future research should explore the
adapting to major technological changes (e.g., from analog to digital or extent to which the interdependence structure influences the
from a 2G network to a 3G network) by themselves, they can pass the behaviors of firms.
risk of uncertainty in component technologies to smaller suppliers. Additional researches need to incorporate various control mechan-
When an existing supplier does not have the required technological isms without equity ownership. Dyer and Ouchi (1993) point out
capabilities to provide new services, the buyer can find or develop potential negative consequences of equity ownership: “The autonomy
another one. This point may explain why technological uncertainty and incentives that keep the company innovating and focused on
was not significant in the buyers' sample set. continuous improvement are lost” (p. 56). Thus, future research needs
Goal consistency turns out to be a significant determinant of inter- to look into various control mechanisms with or without equity
firm cooperation in both sample sets. Contrary to expectations, ownership.
however, neither the ownership ratio nor the continuity of the This study has limitations. First, this study's sample consists of one
relationship was a significant determinant. One possible explanation buyer organization and its multiple suppliers in a single industry
for this result is that the data do not have enough variation to (telecommunication industry), all of which were located in Korea. In
determine the influences of these two variables. Further scrutiny of addition, the supplier sample is skewed toward smaller firms in a
the data reveals that the average equity ownership ratio in the sample monopsonistic situation. Therefore, the results are characteristic of
was approximately 9%, which implies a relatively independent only a single company in a single country. To increase the external
relationship between the partners. Consequently, this analysis validity of the findings of this study, future research that incorporates
a sample from multiple companies in non-monopsonistic situations is
needed.
Table 5
Results of regression analyses.
Acknowledgement
Hypothesis Buyer (N = 100) Supplier (N = 98)
variables Standardized ß Probability Standardized ß Probability This research is supported by the Ubiquitous Computing and
value value Network (UCN) Project, Knowledge and Economy Frontier R&D
Technological − 0.00 0.97 − 0.22*** 0.00 Program of the Ministry of Knowledge Economy (MKE) in Korea as
uncertainty
a result of UCN's subproject 09C1-C2-10 M.
Switching costs 0.18** 0.01 − 0.13 0.07
Equity ownership 0.06 0.37 0.08 0.23
Continuity − 0.00 0.98 0.03 0.65 References
Goal consistency 0.44*** 0.00 0.41*** 0.00
Reciprocity of 0.11 0.12 0.29*** 0.00 Adler P, Kwon S. Social capital: prospects for a new concept. Acad Manag Rev 2002;27(1):
the relationship 17–40.
Inter-organizational 0.32*** 0.00 0.05 0.60 Anderson JC, Narus JA. A model of distributor firm and manufacturer firm working
trust partnerships. J Mark 1990;54(1):42–8.
Adjusted R square 0.60 0.63 Anderson E, Weitz B. The use of pledges to build and sustain commitment in
F-value 19.99*** 0.00 21.39*** 0.00 distribution channels. J Mark Res 1992;29(1):18–24.
Arkader R. The perspective of suppliers on lean supply in a developing country context.
Notes: **p b 0.05, ***p b 0.01. Integr Manuf Syst 2001;12(2):87–94.
K.K. Kim et al. / Journal of Business Research 63 (2010) 863–869 869

Bensaou M. Interorganizational cooperation: the role of information technology an Mentzer JT, Flint DJ, Hult GTM. Logistics service quality as a segment customized
empirical comparison of U.S. and Japanese supplier relations. Inf Syst Res 1997;8(2): process. J Mark 2001;65(4):82-104.
107–24. Moorman C, Deshpande R, Zaltman G. Factors affecting trust in market research
Bourdieu P. The forms of capital. In: Richardson JG, editor. Handbook of theory and relationships. J Mark 1993;57(1):81-101.
research for the sociology of education. New York: Greenwood; 1986. p. 241–58. Morgan RM, Hunt SD. The commitment–trust theory of relationship marketing. J Mark
Coase R. The nature of the firm. Economica 1937;4(16):386–405. 1994;58(3):20–38.
Dyer JH, Ouchi WG. Japanese-style partnerships: giving companies a competitive edge. Nahapiet J, Ghoshal S. Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage.
Sloan Manage Rev 1993;35(1):51–63. Acad Manag Rev 1998;23(2):242–66.
Dyer JH, Singh H. The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganiza- Nunnally J, Bernstein I. Psychometric theory. 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill; 1994.
tional competitive strategy. Acad Manag Rev 1998;23(4):660–79. Parkhe A. Strategic alliance structuring: a game theoretic and transaction cost
Eisenhardt K, Schoonhoven C. Resource-based view of strategic alliance formation: examination of interfirm cooperation. Acad Manage J 1993;36(4):794–829.
strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms. Organ Sci 1996;7(2):136–50. Paulraj A, Chen IJ. Environmental uncertainty and strategic supply management: a
Forker LB, Ruch WA, Hershauer JC. Examining supplier improvement efforts from both resource dependence perspective and performance implications. J Supply Chain
sides. J Supply Chain Manag 1999;35(3):40–50. Manag 2007;43(3):29–42.
Granovetter M. The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol 1973;78(6):1360–80. Perry ML, Sengupta S, Krapfel R. Effectiveness of horizontal strategic alliances in
Guimaraes T, Cook D, Natarajan N. Exploring the importance of business clockspeed as a technologically uncertain environments: are trust and commitment enough? J Bus
moderator for determinants of supplier network performance. Decis Sci 2002;33(4): Res 2004;57(9):951–6.
629–44. Pfeffer J, Salancik GR. The external control of organizations: a resource dependence
Gulati R. Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual perspective. New York: Harper & Row; 1978.
choice in alliances. Acad Manage J 1995;38(1):85-112. Pisano GP. Using equity participation to support exchange: evidences from the
Helper S. How much has really changed between U.S. automakers and their suppliers. biotechnology industry. J Law Econ Organ 1989;5(1):109–26.
Sloan Manage Rev 1991;15(6):15–28. Putnam RD. Bowling alone: America's declining social capital. J Democr 1993;6:65–78.
Huber GP, Daft RL. The information environments of organizations. In: Jablin FM, Reid D, Bussiere D, Greenaway K. Alliance formation issues for knowledge-based
Putnam LL, Roberts KH, Porter LW, editors. Handbook of organizational commu- enterprises. Int J Manag Rev 2001;3(1):79-100.
nication. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications; 1987. p. 130–64. Ryu S, Park JE, Min S. Factors of determining long-term orientation in interfirm
Karande K, Ha J, Singhapakdi A. The role of contextual factors in relationship relationships. J Bus Res 2007;60(12):1225–33.
commitment of buyers to foreign suppliers: a survey of Korean importers. Ind Tsai W, Ghoshal S. Social capital and value creation: the role of intrafirm networks. Acad
Mark Manage 2008;37(7):856–62. Manage J 1998;41(4):464–76.
Kim KK, Umanath NS. Information transfer in B2B procurement: an empirical analysis Whitten D, Wakefield RL. Measuring switching costs in IT outsourcing services. J Strateg
and measurement. Inf & Manage 2005;42(6):813–28. Inf Syst 2006;15(3):219–48.
Kogut B. Joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strateg Manage J Williamson OE. Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural
1988;9(4):319–32. alternatives. Adm Sci Q 1991;36(2):269–96.
Krause DR, Handfield RB, Tyler BB. The Relationships between supplier development, Yeh Y. Identification of factors affecting continuity of cooperative electronic supply
commitment, social capital accumulation and performance improvement. J Oper chain relationships: empirical case of the Taiwanese motor industry. Supply Chain
Manag 2007;25(2):528–45. Manag Int J 2005;10(4):327–35.
Kumar K, van Dissel HG. Sustainable collaboration: managing conflict and cooperation Young-Ybarra C, Wiersema M. Strategic flexibility in information technology alliances:
in interorganizational systems. MIS Quarterly 1996;20(3):279–300. the influence of transaction cost economics and social exchange theory. Organ Sci
Kumar N, Scheer L, Steenkamp J. The effects of perceived interdependence on dealer 1999;10(4):439–59.
attitudes. J Mark Res 1995;32(3):348–56. Zaheer A, McEvily B, Perrone V. Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganiza-
Levin D, Cross R. The strength of weak ties you can trust: the mediating role of trust in tional and interpersonal trust for performance. Organ Sci 1998;9(2):141–59.
effective knowledge transfer. Manag Sci 2004;50(11):1477–90.
Lusch RF, Brown JR. Interdependency, contracting, and relational behavior in marketing
channels. J Mark 1996;60(4):19–38.

You might also like