You are on page 1of 17

Global Portfolio Optimization

Author(s): Fischer Black and Robert Litterman


Source: Financial Analysts Journal , Sep. - Oct., 1992, Vol. 48, No. 5 (Sep. - Oct., 1992),
pp. 28-43
Published by: Taylor & Francis, Ltd.

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/4479577

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Taylor & Francis, Ltd. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Financial Analysts Journal

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Global Portfolio Optimization

Fischer Black and particular view influences These unreasonable results stem
Robert Litterman portfolio weights, in accor- from two well recognized prob-
lems. First, expected returns are
dance with the degree of
very difficult to estimate. Inves-
confidence with which he tors typically have knowledgeable
Quantitative asset alloca-
holds the view. views about absolute or relative
tion models have not
returns in only a few markets. A
played the important role standard optimization model,
they should in global port- however, requires them to pro-
folio management. A good Investors with global portfolios of vide expected returns for all as-
equities and bonds are generally sets and currencies. Thus inves-
part of the problem is that
aware that their asset allocation tors must augment their views
such models are difficult to decisions-the proportions of with a set of auxiliary assump-
use and tend to result in funds they invest in the asset tions, and the historical returns
portfolios that are badly classes of different countries and they often use for this purpose
behaved. the degrees of currency hedg- provide poor guides to future re-
ing-are the most important in- turns.
Consideration of the global vestment decisions they make. In
CAPM equilibrium can sig- deciding on the appropriate allo- Second, the optimal portfolio as-
cation, they are usually comfort- set weights and currency posi-
nificantly improve the use- able making the simplifying as-
tions of standard asset allocation
fulness of these models. In sumption that their objective is to models are extremely sensitive to
particular, equilibrium re- maximize expected return for a the return assumptions used. The
turns for equities, bonds given level of risk (subject, in two problems compound each
and currencies provide most cases, to various types of other; the standard model has no
neutral starting points for constraints). way to distinguish strongly held
views from auxiliary assumptions,
estimating the set of ex-
Given the straightforward mathe- and the optimal portfolio it gen-
pected excess returns matics of this optimization prob- erates, given its sensitivity to the
needed to drive the portfo- lem, the many correlations expected returns, often appears
lio optimization process. among global asset classes re- to bear little or no relation to the
This set of neutral weights quired in measuring risk, and the views the investor wishes to ex-
large amounts of money involved, press. In practice, therefore, de-
cn
can then be tilted in accor-
one might expect that, in today's spite the obvious conceptual
dance with the investor's
computerized world, quantitative attractions of a quantitative ap-
views. models would play a dominant proach, few global investment
LU

role in the global allocation pro- managers regularly allow quanti-


If the investor has no par- cess. Unfortunately, when inves- tative models to play a major role
LU
ticular views about asset tors have tried to use quantitative in their asset allocation decisions.
LU
returns, he can use the models to help optimize the crit-
neutral values given by the ical allocation decision, the un- This article describes an ap-
reasonable nature of the results proach that provides an intuitive
z equilibrium model. If the
has often thwarted their efforts.' solution to the two problems that
D
investor does have one or have plagued quantitative asset
When investors impose no con-
-J
more views about the rela- straints, the models almost always allocation models. The key is
tive performances of assets, ordain large short positions in combining two established tenets
z or their absolute perfor- many assets. When constraints of modern portfolio theory-the
rule out short positions, the mod- mean-variance optimization
mances, he can adjust
els often prescribe "corner" solu- framework of Markowitz and the
U
z equilibrium values in ac- capital asset pricing model
tions with zero weights in many
Z cordance with those views. assets, as well as unreasonably (CAPM) of Sharpe and Lintner.2
Furthernore, the investor large weights in the assets of mar-
28 can control how strongly a kets with small capitalizations. Copyright 1991 by Goldman Sachs.

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Glossary *'Risk Premiums: drive optimization analysis. Equi-
Means implied by the equilib- librium risk premiums provide a
*"Asset Excess Returns: rium model. center of gravity for expected re-
In this article, returns on as- turns. The expected returns used
sets less the domestic short rate in our optimization will deviate
(see formulas in footnote 5). from equilibrium risk premiums
Our approach allows the investor in accordance with the investor's
loBalance: to combine his views about the explicitly stated views. The extent
A measure of how close a outlook for global equities, bonds of the deviations from equilib-
portfolio is to the equilibrium and currencies with the risk pre- rium will depend on the degree
portfolio. miums generated by Black's glo-
of confidence the investor has in
bal version of CAPM equilibri-
each view. Our model makes ad-
*Bencbmark Portfolio: um.3 These equilibrium risk
justments in a manner as consis-
The standard used to define premiums are the excess re-
tent as possible with historical
the risk of other portfolios. If turns that equate the supply and
covariances of returns of different
a benchmark is defined, the demand for global assets and cur-
risk of a portfolio is measured assets and currencies.
rencies.
as the volatility of the tracking
error-the difference between As we have noted, and will illus- Our use of equilibrium allows
the portfolio's rerturns and trate, the mean-variance optimiza- investors to specify views in a
those of the benchmark. tion used in standard asset alloca- much more flexible and powerful
tion models is extremely sensitive way than is otherwise possible.
* Currency Excess Returns: to the expected return assump- For example, rather than requir-
Returns on forward contracts tions the investor must provide. ing the investor to have a view
(see formulas in footnote 5). In our model, equilibrium risk about the absolute return on ev-
premiums provide a neutral ref- ery asset and currency, our ap-
l-Expected Excess Returns: erence point for expected re- proach allows the investor to
Expected values of the distri- turns. This, in turn, allows the specify as many or as few views as
bution of future excess re- model to generate optimal port- he wishes. In addition, the inves-
turns. folios that are much better be- tor can specify views about rela-
haved than the unreasonable tive returns and can specify a
*Equilibrium: portfolios that standard models degree of confidence about each
The condition in which means typically produce, which often in- view.
(see below) equilibrate the clude large long and short posi-
demand for assets with the tions unless otherwise con-
A set of examples illustrates how
outstanding supply. strained. Instead, our model
the incorporation of equilibrium
gravitates toward a balanced-i.e.,
into the standard asset allocation
loEquilibrium Portfolio: market-capitalization-weighted-
model makes it better behaved
The portfolio held in equilib- portfolio that tilts in the direction
and enables it to generate insights
rium; in this article, market of assets favored by the investor.
for the global investment man-
capitalization weights, 80%
ager. To that end, we start with a w

currency hedged. Our model does not assume that


discussion of how equilibrium uJ
the world is always at CAPM equi-
*Means: librium, but rather that when ex- can help an investor translate his 0
rn

Expected excess returns. pected returns move away from views into a set of expected re-
0

their equilibrium values, imbal- turns for all assets and currencies. co

*Neutral Portfolio: ances in markets will tend to push We then follow with a set of ap-
uJ
La
An optimal portfolio given them back. We thus think it is plications of the model that illus- H

neutral views. reasonable to assume that ex- trate how the equilibrium solves 2
lU
VI

pected returns are not likely to the problems that have tradition-
z
NoNeutral Views: deviate too far from equilibrium ally led to unreasonable results in D

Means when the investor has values. This suggests that the in- standard mean-variance models. 0

no views. vestor may profit by combining -

his views about returns in differ- Neutral Views


*Normal Portfolio: Why should an investor use a
ent markets with the information z

The portfolio that an investor contained in equilibrium pricesglobal equilibrium model to help -j

feels comfortable with when and returns. make his global asset allocation u
z
he has no views. He can use decision? A neutral reference is a
z
the normal portfolio to infer a Our approach distinguishes be- critically important input in mak-
benchmark when no explicit ing use of a mean-variance opti-
twveen the views of the investor
benchmark exists. and the expected returns that mization model, and an equilib- 29

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table I Historical Excess Returns, January 1975-August 1991* tions that bear no obvious rela-
tion to the expected excess return
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia assumptions. When we constrain
shorting, we have positive weights
Total Mean Excess Return
in only two of the 14 potential
Currencies -20.8 3.2 23.3 13.4 12.6 3.0
Bonds 15.3 -2.3 42.3 21.4 -4.9 -22.8 -13.1
assets. These portfolios are typical
Equities 112.9 117.0 223.0 291.3 130.1 16.7 107.8 of those generated by standard
optimization models.
Annualized Mean Excess Return
Currencies -1.4 0.2 1.3 0.8 0.7 0.2
The use of past excess returns to
Bonds 0.9 -0.1 2.1 1.2 -0.3 -1.5 -0.8
Equities 4.7 4.8 7.3 8.6 5.2 0.9 4.5
represent a "neutral" set of views
is equivalent to assuming that the
Annualized Standard Deviation
constant portfolio weights that
Currencies 12.1 11.7 12.3 11.9 4.7 10.3
Bonds 4.5 4.5 6.5 9.9 6.8 7.8 5.5
would have performed best his-
Equities 18.3 22.2 17.8 24.7 16.1 18.3 21.9 torically are in some sense neu-
tral. In reality, of course, they are
* Bond and equity returns in U.S. dollars, currency not neutral at all, but rather and
hedged are a in exce
offered rate (LIBOR); returns on currencies are in excess of the one-month forward rates. very special set of weights that go
short assets that have done poorly
and go long assets that have done
well in the particular historical
rium provides the appropriate Of course, besides equilibrium
neutral reference. Most of the risk premiums, there are several
period.
time investors have views- other naive approaches investors
Equal Means
feelings that some assets or cur- might use to construct an optimal
The investor might hope that as-
rencies are overvalued or under- portfolio when they have no
valued at current market prices. views about assets or currencies.
suming equal means for returns
An asset allocation model can across all countries for each asset
We examine some of these-the
help them to apply those views to historical average approach, the
class would result in an appropri-
ate neutral reference. Table IV
their advantage. But it is unrealis- equal mean approach and the
gives an example of the optimal
tic to expect an investor to be risk-adjusted equal mean ap-
portfolio for this type of analysis.
able to state exact expected ex- proach-below.
Again, we get an unreasonable
cess returns for every asset and
portfolio.7
currency. The equilibrium, how- Historical Averages
ever, can provide the investor an The historical average approach Of course, one problem with this
appropriate point of reference. assumes, as a neutral reference, approach is that equal expected
that excess returns will equal excess returns do not compen-
Suppose, for example, that an in- their historical averages. The sate investors appropriately for
vestor has no views. How then, problem with this approach is the different levels of risk in as-
can he define his optimal portfo- that historical means provide very sets of different countries. Inves-
lio? Answering this question dem- poor forecasts of future returns. tors diversify globally to reduce
on onstrates the usefulness of the For example, Table I shows many risk. Everything else being equal,
equilibrium risk premium. negative values. Table III shows they prefer assets whose returns
cn what happens when we use such are less volatile and less corre-
0
U
In considering this question, and returns as expected excess return lated with those of other assets.
others throughout this article, we assumptions. We may optimize
use historical data on global eq- expected returns for each level of Although such preferences are
LL uities, bonds and currencies. We risk to get a frontier of optimal obvious, it is perhaps surprising
use a seven-country model with portfolios. The table illustrates how unbalanced the optimal
cca
monthly returns for the United the frontiers with the portfolios portfolio weights can be, as Table
States, Japan, Germany, France, that have 10.7% risk, with and IV illustrates, when we take "ev-
the United Kingdom, Canada and without shorting constraints.6 erything else being equal" to
Australia from January 1975 such a literal extreme. With no
through August 1991.4 We can make a number of points constraints, the largest position is
about these "optimal" portfolios. short Australian bonds.
z
Table I presents the means and First, they illustrate what we mean
30 standard deviations of excess re- when we claim that standard Risk-Adjusted Equal Means
turns and Table II the correla- mean-variance optimization mod- Our third naive approach to de-
tions. All the results in this article els often generate unreasonable fining a neutral reference point is
are given from a U.S. dollar per- portfolios. The portfolio that does to assume that bonds and equities
spective; use of other currencies not constrain against shorting has have the same expected excess
would give similar results.5 many large long and short posi- return per unit of risk, where the

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table II Historical Correlations of Excess Returns, January 1975-August 1991

Germany France Japan

Equities Bonds Currency Equities Bonds Currency Equities Bonds Currency


Germany
Equities 1.00
Bonds 0.28 1.00
Currency 0.02 0.36 1.00

France
Equities 0.52 0.17 0.03 1.00
Bonds 0.23 0.46 0.15 0.36 1.00
Currency 0.03 0.33 0.92 0.08 0.15 1.00

Japan
Equities 0.37 0.15 0.05 0.42 0.23 0.04 1.00
Bonds 0.10 0.48 0.27 0.11 0.31 0.21 0.35 1.00
Currency 0.01 0.21 0.62 0.10 0.19 0.62 0.18 0.45 1.00
UK
Equities 0.42 0.20 -0.01 0.50 0.21 0.04 0.37 0.09 0.04
Bonds 0.14 0.36 0.09 0.20 0.31 0.09 0.20 0.33 0.19
Currency 0.02 0.22 0.66 0.05 0.05 0.66 0.06 0.24 0.54

Us
Equities 0.43 0.23 0.03 0.52 0.21 0.06 0.41 0.12 -0.02
Bonds 0.17 0.50 0.26 0.10 0.33 0.22 0.11 0.28 0.18

Canada
Equities 0.33 0.16 0.05 0.48 0.04 0.09 0.33 0.02 0.04
Bonds 0.13 0.49 0.24 0.10 0.35 0.21 0.14 0.33 0.22
Currency 0.05 0.14 0.11 0.10 0.04 0.10 0.12 0.05 0.06
Australia
Equities 0.34 0.07 -0.00 0.39 0.07 0.05 0.25 -0.02 0.12
Bonds 0.24 0.19 0.09 0.04 0.16 0.08 0.12 0.16 0.09
Currency -0.01 0.05 0.25 0.07 -0.03 0.29 0.05 0.10 0.27

United Kingdom United States Canada Australia

Equities Bonds Currency Equities Bonds Equities Bonds Currency Equities Bonds
UK
Equities 1.00
Bonds 0.47 1.00
Currency 0.06 0.27 1.00
US.
Equities 0.58 0.23 -0.02 1.00 an
Bonds 0.12 0.28 0.18 0.32 1.00

Canada LU

Equities 0.56 0.27 0.11 0.74 0.18 1.00 0


Bonds 0.18 0.40 0.25 0.31 0.82 0.23 1.00 U
Currency 0.14 0.13 0.09 0.24 0.15 0.32 0.24 1.00

Australia LU

Equities 0.50 0.20 0.15 0.48 -0.05 0.61 0.02 0.18 1.00
LU
Bonds 0.17 0.17 0.09 0.24 0.20 0.21 0.18 0.13 0.37 1.00
Currency 0.06 0.05 0.27 0.07 -0.00 0.19 0.04 0.28 0.27 0.20
4:
z

31
-J

risk measure is simply the volatil- is no better. One problem with This approach, and the others we
z
ity of asset returns. Currencies in this approach is that it hasn't have so far used, are based on
this case are assumed to have no taken the correlations of the asset what might be called the "de-
excess return. Table V shows the 4:
returns into account. But there is mand for assets" side of the equa-
optimal portfolio for this case. z
another problem as well-per- tion-that is, historical returns
Now we have incorporated vola- haps more subtle, but also more and risk measures. The problem
tilities, but the portfolio behavior serious. with such approaches is obvious

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table III Optimal Portfolios Based on Historical Average Approach The equilibrium degree of hedg-
ing-the "universal hedging con-
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia stant"-depends on three aver-
ages-the average across countries
Unconstrained
of the mean return on the market
Currency -78.7 46.5 15.5 28.6 65.0 -5.2 portfolio of assets, the average
Exposure (%)
across countries of the volatility
Bonds (%) 30.4 -40.7 40.4 -1.4 54.5 -95.7 -52.5
Equities (%) 4.4 -4.4 15.5 13.3 44.0 -44.2 9.0 of the world market portfolio,
and the average across all pairs of
With Constraints Against Shorting Assets countries of exchange rate volatil-
Currency -160.0 115.2 18.0 23.7 77.8 -13.8 ity.
Exposure (%)
Bonds (%) 7.6 0.0 88.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 It is difficult to pin down exactly
Equities (%) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
the right value for the universal
hedging constant, primarily be-
cause the risk premium on the
market portfolio is a difficult
when we bring in the supply side rency risk up to the point where
number to estimate. Neverthe-
of the market. the additional risk balances the less, we feel that universal hedg-
expected return. Under certain ing values between 75% and 85%
Suppose the market portfolio simplifying assumptions, the per- are reasonable. In our monthly
comprises two assets, with centage of foreign currency risk data set, the former value corre-
weights 80% and 20%. In a simple hedged will be the same for in- sponds to a risk premium of 5.9%
world, with identical investors all vestors of different countries- on U.S. equities, while the latter
holding the same views and both giving rise to the name "universal corresponds to a risk premium of
assets having equal volatilities, ev-
hedging" for this equilibrium. 9.8%. For this article, we will use
eryone cannot hold equal weights
of each asset. Prices and expected
excess returns in such a world
would have to adjust as the excess
Table IV Optimal Portfolios Based on Equal Means
demand for one asset and excess
supply of the other affect the mar-
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
ket.
Unconstrained
The Equilibrium Approach Currency 14.5 -12.6 -0.9 4.4 -18.7 -2.1
To us, the only sensible definition Exposure (%)
of neutral means is the set of Bonds (%) -11.6 4.2 -1.8 -10.8 13.9 -18.9 -32.7
expected returns that would Equities (%) 21.4 -4.8 23.0 -4.6 32.2 9.6 10.5
"clear the market" if all investors
With Constraints Against Shorting Assets
had identical views. The concept
ra Currency 14.3 -11.2 -4.5 0.2 -25.9 -2.0
on of equilibrium in the context of a
cx: Exposure (%)
global portfolio of equities,
Bonds (%) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
bonds and currencies is similar,
LL
m
0 Equities (%) 17.5 0.0 22.1 0.0 27.0 8.2 7.3
although currencies do raise a
0 complicating question. How
:
LU
m
much currency hedging takes
place in equilibrium? The answer
LU
Table V Optimal Portfolios Based on Equal Risk-Adjusted Means
F-
is that, in a global equilibrium,
0)
LI, investors worldwide will all want
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
z
to take a small amount of cur-
ax:
D rency risk.8 Unconstrained
0
Currency 5.6 11.3 -28.6 -20.3 -50.9 -4.9
This result arises because of a Exposure (%)
curiosity known in the currency Bonds (%) -23.9 12.6 54.0 20.8 23.1 37.8 15.6
world as "Siegel's paradox." The Equities (%) 9.9 8.5 12.4 -0.3 -14.1 13.2 20.1
-j
z
basic idea is that, because inves-
With Constraints Against Shorting Assets
U tors in different countries mea-
Currency 21.7 -8.9 -14.0 -12.2 -47.9 -6.7
sure returns in different units,
z Exposure (%)
32 each will gain some expected re-
Bonds (%) 0.0 0.0 0.0 7.8 0.0 19.3 0.0
turn by taking some currency Equities (%) 11.1 9.4 19.2 6.0 0.0 7.6 19.5
32 risk. Investors will accept cur-

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table VI Equilibrium Risk Premiums (% annualized excess returns) To see why this is so important,
we start by illustrating the ex-
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia treme sensitivity of portfolio
Currencies 1.01 1.10 1.40 0.91 0.60 0.63 weights to the expected excess
Bonds 2.29 2.23 2.88 3.28 1.87 2.54 1.74 returns and the inability of inves-
Equities 6.27 8.48 8.72 10.27 7.32 7.28 6.45 tors to express views directly as a
complete set of expected returns.
We have already seen how diffi-
cult it can be simply to translate
an equilibrium value for currency between investor views on the no views into a set of expected
hedging of 80%. Table VI gives one hand and a complete set of excess returns that will not lead
the equilibrium risk premiums expected excess returns for all an asset allocation model to pro-
for all assets, given this value of assets on the other-is not usu- duce an unreasonable portfolio.
the universal hedging constant.9 ally recognized. In our approach, But suppose that the investor has
views represent the subjective already solved that problem, us-
Consider what happens when we feelings of the investor about rel- ing equilibrium risk premiums as
adopt these equilibrium risk pre- ative values offered in different the neutral means. He is comfort-
miums as our neutral means markets.10 If an investor does not able with a portfolio that has mar-
when we have no views. Table VII have a view about a given market, ket capitalization weights, 80%
shows the optimal portfolio. It is he should not have to state one. hedged. Consider what can hap-
simply the market-capitalization And if some of his views are more pen when this investor now tries
portfolio with 80% of the cur- strongly held than others, he to express one simple, extremely
rency risk hedged. Other portfo- should be able to express the modest view.
lios on the frontier with different differences.
levels of risk would correspond Suppose the investor's view is
to combinations of risk-free bor- Most views are relative. For exam- that, over the next three months,
rowing or lending plus more or ple, the investor may feel one the economic recovery in the
less of this portfolio. market will outperform another. United States will be weak and
Or he may feel bullish (above bonds will perform relatively well
By itself, the equilibrium concept neutral) or bearish (below neu- and equities poorly. The inves-
is interesting but not particularly tral) about a market. As we will tor's view is not very strong, and
useful. Its real value is to provide show, the equilibrium allows the he quantifies it by assuming that,
a neutral framework the investor investor to express his views this over the next three months, the
can adjust according to his own way, instead of as a set of ex- U.S. benchmark bond yield will
views, optimization objectives pected excess returns. drop 1 basis point rather than rise
and constraints.

Table VII Equilibrium Optimal Portfolio


Expressing Views
Investors trying to use quantita-
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
tive asset allocation models must
translate their views into a com- Currency 1.1 0.9 5.9 2.0 0.6 0.3 r'i
Exposure (%)
plete set of expected excess re-
Bonds (%) 2.9 1.9 6.0 1.8 16.3 1.4 0.3 0)
turns on assets that can be used as Equities (%) 2.6 2.4 23.7 8.3 29.7 1.6 1.1 0a

a basis for portfolio optimization.


As we will show here, the prob-
oL
lem is that optimal portfolio LU
m
LU
weights from a mean-variance L1J

Table VIII Optimal Portfolios Based on a Moderate View


model are incredibly sensitive to
minor changes in expected ex- D
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
cess returns. The advantage of z
incorporating a global equilib- Unconstrained
rium will become apparent when Currency -1.3 8.3 -3.3 -6.4 8.5 -1.9
we show how to combine it with Exposure (%)
an investor's views to generate Bonds (%) -13.6 6.4 15.0 -3.3 112.9 -42.4 0.7 -J

well-behaved portfolios, without Equities (%) 3.7 6.3 27.2 14.5 -30.6 24.8 6.0

requiring the investor to express


With Constraints Against Shorting Assets
a complete set of expected excess U
Currency 2.3 4.3 5.0 -3.0 9.2 -0.6 z
returns.
Exposure (%) z
Bonds (%) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 35.7 0.0 0.0
We should emphasize that the Equities (%) 2.6 5.3 28.3 13.6 0.0 13.1 1.5
distinction we are making 33

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1 basis point, as is consistent with 2. We assume that both are a function of the equilibrium
the equilibrium risk premium.11 sources of information are risk premiums, the expected value
Similarly, the investor expects uncertain and are best ex- of the common factor, and the
U.S. share prices to rise only 2.7% pressed as probability distri- expected values of the indepen-
over the next three months, butions. dent shocks to each asset. For
rather than to rise the 3.3% con- 3. We choose expected excess example, the expected excess re-
sistent with the equilibrium view. returns that are as consistent turn of asset A, which we write as
as possible with both E[RA], is given by:
To implement the asset allocation sources of information.
optimization, the investor starts E[RA] = 7TA + yAE[Z] + E[vj.
with expected excess returns The above description captures
equal to the equilibrium risk pre- the basic idea, but the implemen- We are not assuming that the
miums and adjusts them as fol- tation of the approach can lead to world is in equilibrium (i.e., that
lows. He moves the annualized some novel insights. We will now E[Z] and the E[vi]s are equal to
expected excess returns on U.S. show how a relative view about zero). We do assume that the
bonds up by 0.8 percentage two assets can influence the ex- mean, E[RA], is itself an unob-
points and the expected excess pected excess return on a third servable random variable whose
returns on U.S. equities down by asset.12 distribution is centered at the
2.5 percentage points. All other equilibrium risk premium. Our
expected excess returns remain Three-Asset Example uncertainty about E[RA] is due to
unchanged. Table VIII shows the Let us first work through a very our uncertainty about E[Z] and
optimal portfolio, given this view. simple example of our approach. the E[vi]s. Furthermore, we as-
After this illustration, we will ap- sume the degree of uncertainty
Note the remarkable effect of this ply it in the context of our seven- about E[Z] and the E[vi]s is pro-
very modest change in expected country model. Suppose we portional to the volatilities of Z
excess returns. The portfolio know the true structure of a and the vis themselves.
weights change in dramatic and world that has just three assets, A,
largely inexplicable ways. The op- B and C. The excess return for This implies that E[RA] is distrib-
timal portfolio weights do shift each of these assets is known to uted with a covariance structure
out of U.S. equity into U.S. bonds, be generated by an equilibrium proportional to E. We will refer
as might be expected, but the risk premium plus four sources to this covariance matrix of the
model also suggests shorting Ca- of risk-a common factor and expected excess returns as rY.
nadian and German bonds. The independent shocks to each of Because the uncertainty in the
lack of apparent connection be- the three assets. We can express mean is much smaller than the
tween the view the investor is this model as follows: uncertainty in the return itself, r
attempting to express and the op- will be close to zero. The equilib-
timal portfolio the model gener- rium risk premiums together
RA = 'TA + YAZ + VA)
ates is a pervasive problem with with rX determine the equilib-
standard mean-variance optimiza- rium distribution for expected
RB = 7rB + YBZ + VB,
tion. It arises because there is a excess returns. We assume this
complex interaction between ex- information is known to all; it is
pected excess returns and the vol- RC = 'TC + YCZ + VC, not a function of the circum-
LU atilities and correlations used in
stances of any individual investor.
measuring risk. where:
In addition, we assume that each
UJ
0

Combining Investor R, = the excess return on the


ith asset, investor provides additional in-
LU
Views with Market formation about expected excess
,wi = the equilibrium risk pre-
Equilibrium mium on the ith asset,
returns in the form of views. For
How our approach translates a example, one type of view is a
few views into expected excess yi = the impact on the ith as- statement of the form: "I expect
z
set of Z,
cc returns for all assets is one of its asset A to outperform asset B by
Z = the common factor, and Q," where Q is a given value.
more complex features, but also
-J one of its most innovative. Here is vi = the independent shock
the intuition behind our ap- to the ith asset. We interpret such a view to mean
z proach. that the investor has subjective
In this world, the covariance ma- information about the future re-
U 1. We believe there are two trix, E, of asset excess returns is turns of A relative to B. One way
z
distinct sources of informa- determined by the relative im- we think about representing that
z
tion about future excess re- pacts of the common factor and information is to act as if we had a
turns-investor views and the independent shocks. The ex- summary statistic from a sample
34 market equilibrium. pected excess returns of the assets of data drawn from the distribu-

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table IX Expected Excess Annualized Percentage Returns Combin- In the more general case where
ing Investor Views With Equilibrium we are not 100% confident, we
can think of a view as represent-
Germany France Japan UK US Canada Australia ing a fixed number of observa-
Currencies 1.32 1.28 1.73 1.22 0.44 0.47 tions drawn from the distribution
Bonds 2.69 2.39 3.29 3.40 2.39 2.70 1.35 of future returns. In this case, we
Equities 5.28 6.42 7.71 7.83 4.39 4.58 3.86 follow the "mixed estimation"
strategy described in Theil.14 Al-
ternatively, we can think of the
view as directly reflecting a sub-
jective distribution for the ex-
tion of future returns, data in the means of the random compo- pected excess returns. In this
which all we were able to observe nents. case, we use the Black-Litterman
is the difference between the re- approach, given in the appen-
turns of A and B. Alternatively, we We have the equilibrium distribu- dix.15 The formula for the ex-
can express the view directly as a tion for E[R], which is given by pected excess returns vector is
probability distribution for the Normal (w, rY,), where w = {WTA, the same from either perspective.
difference between the means of 7B' 7r} We wish to calculate a
the excess returns of A and B. It conditional distribution for the In either approach, we assume
doesn't matter which of these ap- expected returns, subject to the that the view can be summarized
proaches we use to think about restriction that the expected re- by a statement of the form
our views; in the end we get the P*E[RI' = Q + s,where PandQ
turns satisfy the linear restriction
same result. are given and e is an unobserv-
E[RA1 - E[RB] = Q. We can write
this restriction as a linear equa- able, normally distributed ran-
In both approaches, though, we tion in the expected returns:13 dom variable with mean 0 and
need a measure of the investor's variance fl. fl represents the un-
confidence in his views. We use P * E[R]' = Q, certainty in the view. In the limit,
this measure to determine how as Q goes to zero, the resulting
much weight to give to the view where P is the vector [1, -1, 0O. mean converges to the condi-
when combining it with the equi- tional mean described above.
librium. We can think of this de- The conditional normal distribu-
gree of confidence as determin- When there is more than one
tion has the following mean:
ing, in the first case, the number view, the vector of views can be
of observations that we have from represented by P * E[R]' = Q + ,
77" + Ty,.p, .[P - T .pt]- I
the distribution of future returns where we now interpret P as a
or as determining, in the second, matrix, and e is a normally dis-
the standard deviation of the I +Q -[ P -1 V, tributed random vector with
probability distribution. mean 0 and diagonal covariance
which is the solution to the prob- matrix fQ. A diagonal fl corre-
In our example, consider the lim- lem of minimizing sponds to the assumption that the
iting case: The investor is 100% views represent independent
sure of his view. We might think (E[R] - )T 1(E[R] - 7) draws from the future distribu-
of this as the case where we have tion of returns, or that the devia-
,0
an unbounded number of obser- subject to P * E[R]I = Q. tions of expected returns from
vations from the distribution of the means of the distribution rep-
future returns, and where the av- For the special case of 100% con- resenting each view are indepen- UJ

erage value of RA - RB from these fidence in a view, we use this dent, depending on which ap- UJ

data is Q. In this special case, we conditional mean as our vector of proach is used to think about LU

can represent the view as a linear expected excess returns. subjective views. The appendix H

restriction on the expected ex-


cess returns-i.e., E[RA] - E[RBI
= Q.
z
Table X Optimal Portfolio Combining Investor Views With
In this special case, we can com-
Equilibrium
pute the distribution of E[R] = -J

{E[R,j, E[RB], E[RJ} conditional Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
z
on the equilibrium and this infor-
Currency 1.4 1.1 7.4 2.5 0.8 0.3
mation. This is a relatively z
Exposure (%)
straightforward problem from
Bonds (%) 3.6 2.4 7.5 2.3 67.0 1.7 0.3
multivariate statistics. To simplify, Equities (%) 3.3 2.9 29.5 10.3 3.3 2.0 1.4
assume a normal distribution for 35

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table XI Economists' Views

Germany France Japan UK US Canada Australia


Currencies
July 31, 1991
Current Spot Rates 1.743 5.928 137.3 1.688 1.151 1.285
Three-Month Horizon
Expected Future Spot 1.790 6.050 141.0 1.640 1.000 1.156 1.324
Annualized Expected
Excess Returns -7.48 -4.61 -8.85 -6.16 0.77 -8.14
Interest Rates
July 31, 1991
Benchmark Bond Yields 8.7 9.3 6.6 10.2 8.2 9.9 11.0

Three-Month Horizon
Expected Future Yields 8.8 9.5 6.5 10.1 8.4 10.1 10.8

Annualized Expected
Excess Returns -3.31 -5.31 1.78 1.66 -3.03 -3.48 5.68

gives the formula for the ex- exceeds that of B by more than it own independent shock. Al-
pected excess returns that com- does in equilibrium. From this, though we should impute some
bine views with equilibrium in we clearly ought to impute that a change in the factor from the
the general case. shock to the common factor is the higher return of A relative to B,
most likely reason A will outper- the impact on C should be less
Now consider our example, in form B. If so, C ought to perform than in the previous case.
which asset correlations result better than equilibrium as well.
from the impact of one common The conditional mean in this case In this case, the conditional mean
factor. In general, we will not is [3.9, 1.9, 2.9]. Indeed, the inves- is [2.3, 0.3, 1.3]. Here the implied
know the impacts of the factor on tor's view of A relative to B has effect of the common-factor shock
the assets-that is, the values of raised the expected return on C on asset C is lower than in the
yA, yB and yYc But suppose the by 1.9 percentage points. previous case. We may attribute
unknown values are [3, 1, 2]. Sup- most of the outperformance of A
pose further that the independent But now suppose the indepen- relative to B to the independent
shocks are small, so that the assets dent shocks have a much larger shocks; indeed, the implication
are highly correlated with volatil- impact than the common factor. for E[RB] is negative relative to
ities approximately in the ratios Let the I matrix be as follows: equilibrium. The impact of the
3:1:2. independent shock to B is ex-
19.0 3.0 6.0 pected to dominate, even though
Suppose, for example, the covari- the contribution of the common
(r 3.0 11.0 2.0
ance matrix is as follows: factor to asset B is positive.
6.0 2.0 14.0]
0)
Note that we can identify the im-
LU
m
LU [9.1 3.0 6.0
Suppose the equilibrium risk pre- pact of the common factor only if
0 3.0 1.1 2.0
miums are again given by [1, 1, 1]. we assume that we know the true
U 6.0 2.0 4.1 Now assume the investor expects structure that generated the cova-
0~
that A will outperform B by 2%. riance matrix of returns. That is
LU
Assume also, for simplicity, that true here, but it will not be true in
the percentage equilibrium risk This time, more than half of the general. The computation of the
z
premiums are equal-for exam- volatility of A is associated with its conditional mean, however, does
VI
D ple, [1, 1, 1]. There is a set of
:: market capitalizations for which
-J that is the case.
r-J Table XII Optimal (Unconstrained) Portfolio Based on Economists'
U Views
z Now consider what happens
when the investor expects A to
: Germany France Japan UK US Canada Australia
outperform B by 2%. In this ex-
Currency 16.3 68.8 -35.2 -12.7 29.7 -51.4
Z ample, virtually all of the volatility
z Exposure (%)
of the assets is associated with Bonds (%) 34.5 -65.4 79.2 16.9 3.3 -22.7 108.3
movements in the common fac- Equities (%) -2.2 0.6 6.6 0.7 3.6 5.2 0.5
36 tor, and the expected return of A

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table XIII Optimal Portfolio With Less Confidence in the Econo- tion we focus more specifically
mists' Views on the concept of a "balanced"
portfolio and show an additional
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia feature of our approach: Changes
Currency -12.9 -3.5 -10.0 -6.9 -0.4 -17.9 in the "confidence" in views can
Exposure (%) be used to control the balance of
Bonds (%) -3.9 -21.0 19.6 2.6 7.3 -13.6 42.4 the optimal portfolio.
Equities (%) 0.8 2.2 24.7 7.1 26.6 4.2 1.2

We start by illustrating what hap-


pens when we put a set of strong-
er views, shown in Table XI, into
not depend on this special knowl- only the returns to U.S. bonds and our model. These happen to have
edge, but only on the covariance U.S. equities, holding fixed all been the short-term interest rate
matrix of returns. other expected excess returns. and exchange rate views ex-
Another difference is that here we pressed by Goldman Sachs econ-
Finally, let's look at the case specify a differential of means, omists on July 31, 1991.16 We put
where the investor has less confi- letting the equilibrium determine 100% confidence in these views,
dence in his view. We might say the actual levels of means; above solve for the expected excess re-
(E[RA] - E[RB]) has a mean of 2we had to specify the levels di- turns on all assets, and find the
and a variance of 1, and the cova- rectly. optimal portfolio, shown in Table
riance matrix of returns is, as it XII. Given such strong views on
was originally: Table IX shows the complete set so many assets, and optimizing
of expected excess returns when without constraints, we generate
[9.1 3.0 6.0 we put 100% confidence in a view a rather extreme portfolio.
that the differential of expected
3.0 1.1 2.0
excess returns of U.S. equities Analysts have tried a number of
6.0 2.0 4.1] over bonds will be 2.0 percentage approaches to ameliorate this
points below the equilibrium dif- problem. Some put constraints
In this example, however, the ferential of 5.5 percentage points. on many of the asset weights. We
conditional mean is based on an Table X shows the optimal port- resist using such artificial con-
uncertain view. Using the formula folio associated with this view. straints. When asset weights run
given in the appendix, we find up against constraints, the portfo-
that the conditional mean is given These results contrast with the lio optimization no longer bal-
by: inexplicable results we saw ear- ances return and risk across all
lier. We see here a balanced port- assets.
[3.3, 1.7, 2.5]. folio in which the weights have
tilted away from market capitali- Others specify a benchmark
Because the investor has less con- zations toward U.S. bonds and portfolio and limit the risk rela-
fidence in his view, the expected away from U.S. equities. We now tive to the benchmark until a rea-
relative return of 2% for A - B is obtain a portfolio that we con- sonably balanced portfolio is ob-
reduced to a value of 1.6, which is sider reasonable, given our view. tained. This makes sense if the a')
closer to the equilibrium value of objective of the optimization is to
0. There will also be a smaller Controlling the Balance manage the portfolio relative to a
effect of the common factor on of a Portfolio benchmark. We are uncomfort- co

the third asset because of the In the previous section, we illus- able when it is used simply to
uncertainty of the view. trated how our approach allows make the model better behaved. LU
ax

us to express a view that U.S.


Seven-Country Example bonds will outperform U.S. equi- An alternate response when the
Now we will attempt to apply our ties, in a way that leads to a well- optimal portfolio seems too ex- H
LU
view that bad news about the U.S. behaved optimal portfolio that treme is to consider reducing the
economy will cause U.S. bonds to expresses that view. In this sec- confidence expressed in some or z
outperform U.S. stocks to the ac-
tual data. The critical difference
between our approach here and Table XIV Optimal Portfolio With Less Confidence in Certain Views
our earlier experiment that gen- z

erated Table VIII is that here we


Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia -J
say something about expected re-
Currency -10.0 -0.4 -4.8 -2.8 -6.2 -7.8
turns on U.S. bonds versus U.S. 0L
Exposure (%)
equities and we allow all other Bonds (%) -10.3 -34.3 25.5 1.6 22.9 -2.4 28.1
expected excess returns to adjust Equities (%) 0.1 2.3 25.9 7.0 26.3 6.0 1.3
accordingly. Before we adjusted

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table XV Alternative Domestic-Weighted Benchmark Portfolio invested in the domestic short-
term interest rate. In many cases,
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia however, an alternative bench-
Currency 1.5 1.5 7.0 3.0 2.0 0.0 mark is called for.
Exposure (%)
Bonds (%) 0.5 0.5 2.0 1.0 30.0 1.0 0.0 Many portfolio managers are
Equities (%) 1.0 1.0 5.0 2.0 55.0 1.0 0.0 given an explicit performance
benchmark, such as a market-
capitalization-weighted index. If
an explicit performance bench-
all of the views. Table XIII shows many. These are not the biggest mark exists, then the appropriate
the optimal portfolio that results yield changes that we expect, but measure of risk for the purpose
when we lower the confidence in they are the forecasts that we of portfolio optimization is the
all of our views. By putting less most strongly want to represent volatility of the tracking error of
confidence in our views, we gen- in our portfolio. We put less con- the portfolio vis-a-vis the bench-
erate a set of expected excess fidence in our views of interest mark. And for a manager funding
returns that more strongly reflect rate moves in the United States a known set of liabilities, the ap-
equilibrium. This pulls the opti- and Australia. propriate benchmark portfolio
mal portfolio weights toward a represents the liabilities.
more balanced position. When we put equal confidence in
For many portfolio managers, the
our views, we obtained the opti-
performance objective is less ex-
We define balance as a measure mal portfolio shown in Table XIII.
plicit, and the asset allocation de-
of how similar a portfolio is to the The view that dominated that
cision is therefore more difficult.
global equilibrium portfo- portfolio was the interest rate de-
For example, a global equity port-
lio-that is, the market-capitaliza- cline in Australia. Now, when we
folio manager may feel his objec-
tion portfolio with 80% of the put less than 100% confidence in
tive is to perform in the top rank-
currency risk hedged. The dis- our views, we have relatively
ings of all global equity managers.
tance measure we use is the vol- more confidence in some views
Although he does not have an
atility of the difference between than in others. Table XIV shows
explicit performance benchmark,
the returns on the two portfolios. the optimal portfolio for this case.
his risk is clearly related to the
stance of his portfolio relative to
We find this property of balance Benchmarks
the portfolios of his competitors.
to be a useful supplement to the One of the most important, but
standard measures of portfolio often overlooked, influences on Other examples are an over-
optimization, expected return the asset allocation decision is the funded pension plan or a univer-
and risk. In our approach, for any choice of the benchmark by sity endowment where matching
given level of risk there will be a which to measure risk. In mean- the measurable liability is only a
continuum of portfolios that max- variance optimization, the objec- small part of the total investment
imize expected return depending tive is to maximize return per objective. In these types of situa-
on the relative levels of confi- unit of portfolio risk. The inves- tions, attempts to use quantitative
on dence that are expressed in the tor's benchmark defines the point approaches are often frustrated
views. The less confidence the of origin for measuring this risk. by the ambiguity of the invest-
investor has, the more balanced
LU
In other words, it represents the ment objective.
his portfolio will be. minimum-risk portfolio.
When an explicit benchmark
Suppose an investor does not In many investment problems, does not exist, two alternative ap-
Lii
have equal confidence in all his risk is measured as the volatility proaches can be used. The first is
views. If the investor is willing to of the portfolio's excess returns. to use the volatility of excess re-
cL/
rank the relative confidence lev- This is equivalent to having no turns as the measure of risk. The
els of his different views, then he benchmark, or to defining the second is to specify a "normal"
can generate an even more pow- benchmark as a portfolio 100% portfolio, one that represents
erful result. In this case, the
H-
model will move away from his
less strongly held views more
Table XVI Current Portfolio Weights for Implied-View Analysis
quickly than from his more
-J strongly held ones.
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia
0
Currency 4.4 3.4 2.0 2.2 2.0 5.5
z We have specified higher confi-
Exposure (%)
dence in our view of yield de- Bonds (%) 1.0 0.5 4.7 2.5 13.0 0.3 3.5
clines in the United Kingdom and Equities (%) 3.4 2.9 22.3 10.2 32.0 1.7 2.0
38 yield increases in France and Ger-

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Table XVII Annualized Expected Excess Returns Implied by a views of the portfolio shown in
Given Portfolio Table XVI, given that the bench-
mark is, alternatively, (1) a mar-
Germany France Japan UK US. Canada Australia ket-capitalization-weighted port-
folio, 80% hedged, or (2) the
Views Relative to the Market-Capitalization Benchmark
domestic-weighted alternative
Currencies 1.55 1.82 -0.27 1.22 0.63 2.45
shown in Table XV. Unless a port-
Bonds 0.30 -0.30 -0.58 1.03 -0.13 -0.01 1.22
folio manager has thought care-
Equities 2.82 3.97 -0.30 6.73 4.15 5.01 5.88
fully about what his benchmark is
Views Relative to the Domestic-Weighted Benchmark and where his allocations are rel-
Currencies 0.05 0.20 0.50 0.54 0.01 0.90
ative to it, and has conducted the
Bonds -0.01 0.21 0.72 0.85 -1.45 -1.01 0.18 type of analysis shown here, he
Equities 2.24 2.83 5.24 4.83 -1.49 0.28 2.38 may not have a clear idea of what
views his portfolio represents.

Quantifying the Benefits


the desired allocation of assets in model establishes a correspon- of Global Diversification
the absence of views. Such a port- dence between views and optimal While most investors demon-
folio might, for example, be de- portfolios. Rather than treating a strate a substantial bias toward
signed with a higher-than-market quantitative model as a black box, domestic assets, many recent
weight for domestic assets in or- successful portfolio managers use studies have documented a rapid
der to represent the domestic na- a model to investigate the nature growth in the international com-
ture of liabilities without attempt- of this relationship. In particular, ponents of portfolios worldwide.
ing to specify an explicit liability it is often useful to start an analy- It is perhaps not surprising, then,
benchmark. sis by using a model to find the that investment advisers have
implied investor views for which started to question the traditional
An equilibrium model can help in an existing portfolio is optimal arguments that support global di-
the design of a normal portfolio relative to a benchmark. versification. This has been partic-
by quantifying some of the risk ularly true in the United States,
and return tradeoffs in the ab- For example, we assume a port- where global portfolios have
sence of views. The optimal port- folio manager has a portfolio with tended to underperform domes-
folio in equilibrium is market- weights as shown in Table XVI. tic portfolios in recent years.
capitalization-weighted and is The weights, relative to those of
80% currency hedged. It has an his benchmark, define the direc- Of course, what matters for inves-
expected excess return (using tions of the investor's views. By tors is the prospective returns
equilibrium risk premiums) of assuming the investor's degree of from international assets, and as
5.7% and an annualized volatility risk aversion, we can find the noted in our earlier discussion of
of 10.7%. expected excess returns for neutral views, the historical re-
which the portfolio is optimal. turns are of virtually no value in
A pension fund wishing to in- projecting future expected excess CN

crease the domestic weight of its In this type of analysis, different returns. Historical analyses con- a'
portfolio to 85% from the current benchmarks may imply very dif- tinue to be used in this context
Lr
market capitalization of 45%, and ferent views for a given portfolio. simply because investment advis- 0a
U
not wishing to hedge the cur- Table XVII shows the implied ers argue there is nothing better m
0
rency risk of the remaining 15%
in international markets, might LU

consider an alternative portfolio Table XVIII The Value of Global Diversification (expected excess LU
LU

such as the one shown in Table returns in equilibrium at a constant 10.7% risk)
XV. The higher domestic weights
~:
lead to an annualized volatility 0.4 Basis-Point Percentage z

percentage points higher than Domestic Global Difference Gain D


0
and an expected excess return 30
basis points below those of the Wlthout Currency Hedging -J

optimal portfolio. The pension Bonds Only 2.14 2.63 49 22.9


Equities Only 4.72 5.48 76 16.1
fund may or may not feel that its z
Bonds and Equities 4.76 5.50 74 15.5
preference for domestic concen- -j

tration is worth those costs. u


With Currency Hedging z

Bonds Only 2.14 3.20 106 49.5


Implied Views Equities Only 4.72 5.56 84 17.8
z

Once an investor has established Bonds and Equities 4.76 5.61 85 17.9
his objectives, an asset allocation 39

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
to measure the value of global bond portfolio manager, both in Our simulations of all three strat-
diversification. absolute and percentage terms. egies use the same basic method-
The gains for an equity manager, ology, the same data and the same
We would suggest that there is or a portfolio manager with both underlying securities. The strate-
something better. A reasonable bonds and equities, are also sub- gies differ in the sources of views
measure of the value of global stantial, although much smaller as about excess returns and in the
diversification is the degree to a percentage of the excess returns assets to which those views are
which allowing foreign assets into applied. All the simulations use
of the domestic portfolio. These
a portfolio raises the optimal our approach of adjusting ex-
results also appear to provide a
portfolio frontier. A natural start- pected excess returns away from
justification for the common prac-
ing point for quantifying this the global equilibrium as a func-
tice of bond portfolio managers
value is to compute it based on tion of investor views.
to hedge currency risk and of
the neutral views implied by a
equity portfolio managers not to
global CAPM equilibrium. In each of the simulations, we test
hedge. In the absence of currency
a strategy by performing the fol-
There are some limitations to us- views, the gains to currency hedg-
lowing steps. Starting in July 1981
ing this measure. It assumes that ing are clearly more important in
and continuing each month for
there are no extra costs to inter- both absolute and relative terms
the next 10 years, we use data up
national investment; thus relaxing for fixed income investors.
to that point in time to estimate a
the constraint against interna- covariance matrix of returns on
tional investment cannot make Historical Simulations
equities, bonds and currencies.
the investor worse off. On the It is natural to ask how a model
We compute the equilibrium risk
other hand, in measuring the such as ours would have per- premiums, add views according
value of global diversification this formed in simulations. However, to the particular strategy, and cal-
way, we are also assuming that our approach does not, in itself, culate the set of expected excess
markets are efficient and there- produce investment strategies. It returns for all securities based on
fore we are neglecting to capture requires a set of views, and any combining views with equilib-
any value that an international simulation is a test not only of the rium.
portfolio manager might add model but also of the strategy
through having informed views producing the views. We then optimize the equity,
about these markets. We suspect bond and currency weights for a
that an important benefit of inter- One strategy that is fairly well given level of risk with no con-
national investment that we are known in the investment world, straints on the portfolio weights.
missing here is the freedom it and that has performed quite well We calculate the excess returns
gives the portfolio manager to in recent years, is to invest funds that would have accrued in that
take advantage of a larger number in high-yielding currencies. Be- month. At the end of each month,
of opportunities to add value than low, we show how a quantitative we update the data and repeat the
are afforded by domestic markets model such as ours can be used calculation. At the end of 10 years,
alone. we compute the cumulative ex-
to optimize such a strategy. In
cess returns for each of the three
particular, we will compare the
We use the equilibrium concept strategies and compare them with
historical performance of a strat-
here to calculate the value of glo- one another and with several pas-
egy of investing in high-yielding
bal diversification for a bond sive investments.
LU
currencies with two other strate-
0
portfolio, an equity portfolio and
gies-(1) investing in the bonds
U a portfolio containing both bonds The views for the three strategies
0 of countries with high bond
and equities (in each case both represent very different informa-
yields and (2) investing in the
LU

m with and without allowing cur- tion but are generated using sim-
equities of countries with high
LLI rency hedging). We normalize ilar approaches. In simulations of
.u ratios of dividend yield to bond
the portfolio volatilities at the high-yielding currency strat-
yield.
10.7%-the volatility of the mar- egy, our views are based on the
H
z
L#) ket-capitalization-weighted port- assumption that the expected ex-
-J
w folio, 80% hedged. Table XVIII Our purpose is to illustrate how a cess returns from holding a for-
shows the additional return avail- quantitative approach can be eign currency are above their
able from including international used to make a useful compari- equilibrium value by an amount
Z:
assets relative to the optimal do- son of alternative investment equal to the forward discount on
mestic portfolio with the same strategies. We are not trying to that currency.
degree of risk. promote or justify a particular
U strategy. We have chosen to focus For example, if the equilibrium
z
What is clear from this table is on these three primarily because risk premium on yen, from a U.S.
z
-

that global diversification pro- they are simple, relatively compa- dollar perspective, is 1% and the
vides a substantial increase in ex- rable, and representative of stan- forward discount (which, because
40 pected return for the domestic dard investment approaches. of covered interest rate parity,

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure A Historical Cumulative Monthly Returns, U.S.-dollar-based perspective global market-capitalization-
weighted average ratio of divi-
dend to bond yield.
$ 600

For example, if the equilibrium


500 r Currency Strategy risk premium on equities in a
Equilibrium given country is 6.0% and the
dividend to bond yield ratio is 0.5
400 1
with a world average ratio of 0.4,
then we assume the expected ex-
300- cess return for equities in that
country to be 11%. We compute

00 X t ~~~~~~~~~~Equity Strategy|
expected excess returns on cur-
200 - Bond Strategy
rencies and bonds by assuming
100% confidence in these views
for equities and adjusting the re-
turns away from equilibrium in
the appropriate manner.
0u

June-'81 Sept-'82 Dec.-'83 Mar.-'85 June-'86 Sept-'87 Dec.-'88 Mar.-'90 June-'91


Figures A and B show the results
graphically. Figure A compares
the cumulative value of $100 in-
approximately equals the differ- views and adjusting returns away vested in each of the three strate-
ence between the short rate on from equilibrium in the appropri- gies as well as in the equilibrium
yen-denominated deposits and ate manner. portfolio, which is a global mar-
the short rate on dollar-denomi- ket portfolio of equities and
nated deposits) is 2%, then we In simulations of a strategy of bonds, with 80% currency hedg-
assume the expected excess re- investing in equity markets with ing. The strategies were struc-
turn on yen currency exposures high ratios of dividend yield to tured to have risk equal to that of
to be 3%. We compute expected bond yield, we generate views by the equilibrium portfolio. While
excess returns on bonds and eq- assuming that expected excess re- the graph gives a clear picture of
uities by adjusting their returns turns on equities are above their the relative performances of the
away from equilibrium in a man- equilibrium values by an amount different strategies, it cannot eas-
ner consistent with 100% confi- equal to 50 times the difference ily convey the tradeoff between
dence in the currency views. between the ratio of dividend to risk and return that can be ob-
bond yield in that country and the tained by taking a more or less
In simulations of a strategy of
investing in fixed income markets
with high yields, we generate Figure B Historical Risk/Return Tradeoffs, July 1981 - August 1991
views by assuming that expected
(N

excess returns on bonds are


10-
above their equilibrium values by
LU

an amount equal to the difference 9 Currency Strategy


between the bond-equivalent cn
8
yield in that country and the glo-
bal market-capitalization-
Equity Strategy
weighted average bond-equiva-
6 - U.S. Equities U
lent yield.
S; 5- / wGlobal Unhedged E
z
For example, if the equilibrium P4 / ^Equilibrium
Global Hedged 0

risk premium on bonds in a given V 4-

country is 1% and the yield on the 4 / / Bond Strategy


10-year benchmark bond is 2 per-
centage points above the world 2- 2U.S. / z
lIBOR S. Bonds
average yield, then we assume the -J

expected excess return for bonds U

in that country to be 3 %. We 0-

z
compute expected excess returns 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
on currencies and equities by as-
suming 100% confidence in these Risk (%) 41

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
aggressive position for any given views. By adjusting the confi- 6. The equilibrium-risk-premi-
strategy. dence in his views, the investor ums vector HI is given by Hl =
can control how strongly the 8K:W, where 5 is a proportion-
Figure B makes such a compari- views influence the portfolio ality constant based on the for-
son. Because the simulations have weights. Similarly, by specifying a mulas in Black."8
no constraints on asset weights, ranking of confidence in different
the risk/return tradeoffs obtained views, the investor can control 7. The expected excess return,
by combining the simulation which views are expressed most E[R], is unobservable. It is as-
portfolios with cash are linear strongly in the portfolio. The in- sumed to have a probability
and define the appropriate fron- vestor can express views about distribution that is propor-
tier for each strategy. We show the relative performance of assets tional to a product of two nor-
each frontier, together with the as well as their absolute perfor- mal distributions. The first
risk/return positions of several mance. distribution represents equi-
benchmark portfolios-domestic librium; it is centered at 1I
bond and equity portfolios, the We hope that our series of exam- with a covariance matrix r-,
equilibrium portfolio and global ples-designed to illustrate the where r is a constant. The sec-
market-capitalization-weighted insights that quantitative model- ond distribution represents
bond and equity portfolios with ing can provide-will stimulate the investor's views about k
and without currency hedging. investment managers to consider, linear combinations of the el-

What we find is that strategies of


or perhaps to reconsider, the ap- ements of E(R]. These views
plication of such modeling to are expressed in the following
investing in high-yielding curren-
their own portfolios. form:
cies and in the equity markets of
countries with high ratios of div-
Appendix PE[R] = Q +
idend yields to bond yields have
performed remarkably well over
1. n assets-bonds, equities and Here P is a known k * n matrix, Q
the past 10 years. By contrast, a
currencies-are indexed by i is a k-dimensional vector, and ? is
strategy of investing in high-
= n,...,n. an unobservable normally distrib-
yielding bond markets has not
uted random vector with zero
added value. Although past per-
2. For bonds and equities, the mean and a diagonal covariance
formance is certainly no guaran-
market capitalization is given matrix Q.
tee of future performance, we
by Mi.
believe that these results, and
8. The resulting distribution for
those of similar experiments with 3. Market weights of the n assets E[R is normal with a mean
other strategies, suggest some in- are given by the vector W = E[RI:
teresting lines of inquiry.
{W1, ... ., W,J. We define the
Wis as follows: E[R] = [(72)-1 + Pf-V1P]-1
Conclusion
Quantitative asset allocation mod- If asset i is a bond or equity: [(,Ty, - lrH + P'0 - 1Q].
els have not played the important
role that they should in global
r54 Mi In portfolio optimization, we use
portfolio management. We sus- Wi= E[R] as the vector of expected
0) pect that a good part of the prob-
excess returns.
0)
lem has been that users of such
cl:
If asset i is a currency of the jth
models have found them difficult
Footnotes
to use and badly behaved. country: 1. For some academic discussions of
LLJ

0~ this issue, see R. C Green and B.


We have learned that the inclu- Wi = AWjcl
LU Hollifeld, "When Will Mean-Vari-
4
LL
sion of a global CAPM equilib- ance Efficient Portfolios Be Well
z
rium with equities, bonds and
where Wjc is the country weight Diversified?" Journal of Finance,
L/,I
currencies can significantly im- (the sum of market weights for forthcoming, and M j Best and
LU
r-
prove the behavior of these mod- bonds and equities in the jth R. R. Grauer, "On the Sensitivity of
els. In particular, it allows us to country) and A is the universal Mean-Variance Efficient Portfolios
distinguish between the views of to Changes in Asset Means: Some
Ul
4
:D hedging constant.
-J the investor and the set of ex- Analytical and Computational Re-
4
F- sults," Review of Financial Studies 4
z pected excess returns used to 4. Assets' excess returns are
4 (1991), pp. 16-22.
drive the portfolio optimization. iven by a vector R= 2. H Markowitz, "Portfolio Selection,"
This distinction in our approach R1, . . .,
z
Journal of Finance, March 1952; j
allows us to generate optimal Lintner, "The Valuation of Risk As-
4-
portfolios that start at a set of 5. Assets excess returns are nor- sets and the Selection of Risky In-
neutral weights and then tilt in mally distributed with a cova- vestments in Stock Portfolios and
42 the direction of the investor's riance matrix L:. Capital Budgets," Review of Eco-

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
nomics and Statistics, February 8. See Black, "Universal Hedging," op.
1965; and W F Sbarpe, "Capital cit
Asset Prices: A Theory of Market 9. The "universal hedging" equilib-
Equilibrium Under Conditions of rium is, of course, based on a set of
Risk, " Journal of Finance, September simplifying assumptions, such as a
1964 world with no taxes, no capital
3. F Black, "Universal Hedging: How constraints and no inflation. Ex-
to Optimize Currency Risk and Re- change rates in this world are the
ward in International Equity Port- rates of exchange between the dif-
folios," Financial Analysts JoumaL ferent consumption bundles of indi-
July/August 1989. viduals of diferent countries. While
4 In actual applications of the model, some may find the assumptions that
we typically include more asset
justify universal hedging overly re-
classes and use daily data to mea- strictive, this equilibrium does have
sure more accurately the current the virtue of being simpler than
state of the time-varying risk struc- other global CAPM equilibriums
ture. We intend to address issues that have been described elsewhere.
concerning uncertainty of the cova- (See B. H. Solnik, "An Equilibrium
riances in another paper. For the Model of the International Capital
purposes of this article, we treat the Market," Journal of Economic The-
true covariances of excess returns ory, August 1974, or F. L. A.
as known. Grauer, R. H Litzenberger and R. E
5. We define excess return on curren- Stehle, "Sharing Rules and Equilib-
cy-hedged assets to be total return rium in an International Capital
less the short rate and excess return Market Under Uncertainty, " Journal
on currency positions to be total of Financial Economics 3 (1976),
return less the forward premium. In pp. 233-56) While these simplifying
Table II, all excess returns and vol-
assumptions are necessary to justify
atilities are percentages. The curren- the universal hedging equilibrium,
cy-hedged excess return on a bond we could easily apply the basic idea
or equity at time t is given by: of this article-combining a global
equilibrium witb investors'
Pt + l/Xt + 1 views-to another global equilib-
Et = * 100 rium derived from a different, less
Pt/xt
restrictive, set of assumptions.
10. Views can represent feelings about
- (1 + Rt)FXt -Rt, the relationships between observable
conditions and such relative values.
where P, is the price of the asset in 11. In this article we use the term
foreign currency, Xt the exchange "strength" of a view to refer to its
rate in units offoreign currency magnitude. We reserve the term
per US dollar, R, the domestic short "confidence" to refer to the degree of
rate and FX, the return on a for- certainty with which a view is held.
ward contract, all at time t. The 12. We try here to develop the intuition
return on a forward contract or, behind our approach using some a)

equivalently, the excess return on a basic concepts of statistics and ma- 0)


foreign currency, is given by: trix algebra. A more formal mathe- U
ui

matical description is given in the 0

appendix.
Ftt +1 - t1 1
FXt= ' 100, 13. A 'prime" symbol (e.g., P') indicates co
xt a transposed vector or matrix. :

14. H Theil, Principles of Econometrics LLJ

where F't+' is the one-periodfor- (New York: Wiley and Sons, 1971). LX

ward exchange rate at time t. 15. F Black and R. Litterman, "Asset


6 We choose to normalize on 10. 7% Allocation: Combining Investor z
risk here and throughout the article Views with Market Equilibrium"
0
because it happens to be the risk of (Goldman, Sachs & Co., September
the market-capitalization-weighted
L/,
1990). -

80% currency-hedged portfolio that 16 For details of these views, see the
will be held in equilibrium in our following Goldman Sachs publica- z
model. tions: The International Fixed In-
-J
7. For the purposes of this exercise, we come Analyst August 2, 1991, for
interest rates and The International U
arbitrarily assigned to each country z
the average historical excess return Economics Analyst, July/August
z
across countries, as follows-.2 for 1991, for exchange rates. L4

currencies, 0.4 for bonds and 5.1 17. We discuss this situation later.
for equities. 18. Black, "Universal Hedging," Op. Cit 43

This content downloaded from


103.210.49.131 on Mon, 04 Sep 2023 10:59:08 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like