You are on page 1of 21

Urban Studies

http://usj.sagepub.com/

Urban Amenities and Agglomeration Economies? The Locational Behaviour and


Economic Success of Dutch Fashion Design Entrepreneurs
Rik Wenting, Oedzge Atzema and Koen Frenken
Urban Stud published online 12 November 2010
DOI: 10.1177/0042098010375992

The online version of this article can be found at:


http://usj.sagepub.com/content/early/2010/11/09/0042098010375992
A more recent version of this article was published on - May 9, 2011

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

On behalf of:
Urban Studies Journal Foundation

Additional services and information for Urban Studies can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://usj.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://usj.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

Version of Record - May 9, 2011


>> OnlineFirst Version of Record - Nov 12, 2010

What is This?

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at FORDHAM UNIV LIBRARY on November 3, 2013


1–20, 2010

Urban Amenities and Agglomeration


Economies? The Locational Behaviour
and Economic Success of Dutch Fashion
Design Entrepreneurs
Rik Wenting, Oedzge Atzema and Koen Frenken
[Paper first received, January 2008; in final form, March 2010]

Abstract
The spatial clustering of industries is traditionally explained by agglomeration economies
benefiting co-located firms. The focus on firms rather than people has been challenged
by Florida arguing that urban amenities attract creative people to certain cities. On the
basis of a questionnaire, an analysis is made of the extent to which these two mechanisms
affect the locational behaviour of Dutch fashion design entrepreneurs. It is found
that fashion design entrepreneurs consider urban amenities to be more important
than agglomeration economies for their location decision. Designers located in the
Amsterdam cluster do not profit from agglomeration economies as such, but rather
from superior networking opportunities with peers both within and outside the cluster.

1. Introduction
For a long time, economic geographers and enhance the performance of incumbents
have explained clusters using the concept through efficiency gains (Porter, 2000).
of agglomeration economies. Clusters are Industries that exhibit extreme levels of
said to emerge due to economies that firms spatial clustering are cultural industries like
realise when co-locating with firms operating architecture, media, movies, video games,
in the same industry. Clusters lower entry fashion design and the arts. For many coun-
barriers thus facilitating entrepreneurship tries, it has been found that only one or two

Rik Wenting is in the Utrecht School of Economics, Faculty of Law, Economics and Governance,
Utrecht University, Janskerkhof 12, 3512BL Utrecht, The Netherlands. E-mail: r.wenting@uu.nl.
Oedzge Atzema is in the Section of Economic Geography, Urban and Regional Research Centre
Utrecht (URU), Faculty of Geosciences, Utrecht University, P.O. Box 80115, 3508TC Utrecht, The
Netherlands. E-mail: o.atzema@geo.uu.nl.
Koen Frenken is in the Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies (ECIS), School of Innovation
Sciences, Eindhoven University of Technology, P.O. Box 513, 5600MB Eindhoven, The Netherlands.
E-mail: k.frenken@tue.nl.

0042-0980 Print/1360-063X Online


© 2010 Urban Studies Journal Limited
DOI: 10.1177/0042098010375992
2   RIK WENTING ET AL.

cities dominate economic activity in cultural industry, especially in Amsterdam (Roso,


industries (see Wenting and Frenken, 2007). 2005). The Dutch fashion design industry
Following the concept of agglomeration with Amsterdam as its centre is also illumi-
economies, Scott (2006) attributed the excep- nating as a typical ‘second-tier’ player with
tional pattern of clustering in cultural indus- Paris, London, New York, Milan and Tokyo as
tries to the disproportionate advantages that the world’s first-tier fashion centres. Hence,
creative firms experience from co-location, the Amsterdam case can be informative for
transforming the cluster into a ‘creative field’. understanding other second-tier cities around
An alternative explanation of spatial clus- the world and for designing policies that may
tering in cultural industries can be based support their further development.
on Florida (2002) who argued that spatial We proceed as follows. In the next section,
clustering is primarily the result of amenities we give a brief overview of the literature on
that attract creative workers. Examples of the clustering of cultural industries in general
urban amenities that are said to attract cre- and of the fashion industry in particular.
ative workers are a tolerant social atmosphere, Section 3 describes our data collection and
ethnic diversity and cultural activities, which descriptive statistics. In section 4, we present
are typically present in large cities.1 Given that the results on the motives underlying the loca-
many employees in cultural industries are tion choices of fashion design entrepreneurs.
creative workers, the high degree of spatial We analyse the determinants of their eco-
clustering observed in cultural industries may nomic success in section 5. Finally, we draw
well be driven by urban amenities. This line some conclusions, derive policy implications
of reasoning not only explains why spatial and discuss issues for further research.
clustering takes place in cultural industries,
but also why these clusters are typically pres- 2. Agglomeration Economies
ent in large cities. and Urban Amenities
Both explanations of spatial clustering of
cultural industries (agglomeration economies Economic geographers tend to explain the
and urban amenities) are different, but not spatial clustering of industries in terms of
mutually exclusive. It may well be the case agglomeration economies benefiting co-
that agglomeration economies and urban located firms (Gordon and McCann, 2000;
amenities both act as interwoven drivers of Porter, 2000; Parr, 2002). In particular, clus-
clustering of cultural industries. In this paper, ter formation is associated with localisation
we explore to what extent the locational or ‘Marshallian’ economies that arise from
behaviour Dutch fashion design entrepre- co-location between firms active in the same
neurs can be explained by a local ‘people’s industry (Marshall, 1920). As Parr notes
climate’ based on urban amenities, or a local
such ‘localisation economies’, which are
‘business climate’ based on agglomeration
external to the firm, are internal to the industry,
economies. We also analyse to what extent being a function of the scale of the industry at
location in a cluster enhances the economic the localisation (Parr, 2002, p. 719).
performance of entrepreneurs.
The case of the Dutch fashion design indus- It is common to distinguish between three
try is a prime example of a cultural industry different forms of localisation economies
with a strong degree of clustering with over (Gordon and McCann, 2000). First, the avail-
one in four designers living in Amsterdam ability of a pool of specialised labour benefits
(Wenting et al., 2006). Moreover, there has firms in clusters as it lowers the search costs and
been a marked growth in the Dutch fashion improves the match between labour supply and
URBAN AMENITIES   3

labour demand. Secondly, the local provision of Clusters both lower entry barriers, thus
inputs by specialised suppliers benefits firms facilitating entrepreneurship, and enhance
in clusters reducing transport and transac- the performance of incumbents through effi-
tion costs as well as lowering costs of inputs. ciency gains. As Porter formulated it
Thirdly, local knowledge spillovers between
Opportunities perceived at cluster locations
firms yield advantages for firms in clusters as
are pursued there because barriers to entry
efficiency is increased through mutual learning
are lower than elsewhere. Needed assets, skills,
without financial compensations. inputs, and staff, often readily available
The first two forms of agglomeration econo- at the cluster location, can be assembled
mies reflect the benefits from increased divi- more easily for a new enterprise. ... While
sion of labour among workers and among local entrepreneurs are likely entrants to
suppliers. In this respect, they are reminis- cluster, entrepreneurs based outside the
cent of Adam Smith’s theory of economic cluster frequently relocate, sooner or later,
growth in which growth promotes efficiency to a cluster location. The same lower entry
through increased opportunities for division barriers attract them, as does the potential to
create more economic value from their ideas
of labour. In both cases, the cluster provides a
and skills at the cluster location or the ability
local market, which is large enough to render to operate more productively (Porter 2000,
such specialised skills and specialised supply p. 263; original emphasis).
profitable.
The third form of agglomeration economies In clusters, new firms often emerge from
of knowledge spillovers is different, and less incumbent firms through spin-offs. These
undisputed, in that it refers to a pure external- spin-offs benefit especially from the knowl-
ity. For a long time, economists treated such edge gained in the parent company rather
spillovers as unbounded by space until Jaffe than from knowledge spillovers in the cluster
et al. (1993) showed that spillovers between per se. Several studies (Klepper, 2002, 2007;
inventors (as proxied by patent citations) Klepper and Sleeper, 2005; Boschma and
occur much more often within regions than Wenting, 2007; Dahl and Reichstein, 2007),
across regions. More recently, Breschi and including one on the global high fashion
Lissoni (2009) confirmed this finding and design industry (Wenting, 2008), have shown
also showed that the local nature of knowl- that the performance of parents and spin-offs
edge spillovers is caused by social networks is highly correlated, suggesting that entre-
between inventors, which function as chan- preneurs benefit from the experience from
nels for informal knowledge exchange. This previous employment. Since most spin-offs
suggests that simple co-location in a cluster locate close to the parent firm, this type of
is not sufficient for knowledge spillovers to knowledge spillover tends to be geographi-
occur; rather, social networks are necessary cally localised. The emergence of clusters
to exchange knowledge and not all firms are can thus be related to the genealogy of firm
equally well connected, both within a cluster formation with a few founding firms creating
and over larger distance (Uzzi, 1997; Hite spin-offs, which in turn create spin-offs, as in
and Hesterley, 2001; Bathelt, 2005; Boschma a snowball process.
and Ter Wal, 2007; Giuliani, 2007; Morrison, The concept of agglomeration economies has
2008). Yet, because the density of social net- been developed with reference to traditional
works is higher within clusters than between manufacturing industries. The agglomeration
clusters, co-location is expected to be, on forces operating in traditional manufacturing
average, advantageous for firm performance may apply to cultural industries as well, where
(Sorenson, 2003). we define cultural industries as all industries
4   RIK WENTING ET AL.

active in the fabrication of cultural products lifecycles of design—often seasonal—implying


characterised by symbolic value.2 In this con- a high turnover of relevant knowledge and a
text, instead of using the concept of agglom- rapid decay in its economic value. Value is
eration economies, Scott introduced the based on a symbolic rather than functional
concept of ‘creative fields’, which he defines as knowledge base (Asheim, Coenen and Vang,
2007; Asheim et al., 2007). Hence, the impor-
the locationally-differentiated web of tance of ‘being there’ increases. Being a part of
production activities and associated social the ‘local buzz’ becomes vital for gaining new
relationships that shapes patterns of insights in trends, techniques and marketing
entrepreneurship and innovation in the new
(Bathelt et al., 2004; Storper and Venables,
economy. ... The creative field functions
as a site of (a) entrepreneurial behaviour
2004). Weller (2007) argues that the opposi-
and new firm formation, (b) technical and tion between tacit and codified knowledge
organizational change, and (c) the symbolic may be less relevant in the context of fashion
elaboration and re-elaboration of cultural design. Rather, she stresses that it is the viscos-
products (Scott, 2006, p. 1). ity of knowledge that explains the concentra-
tion of the industry in key urban sites—areas
Even though Scott (2002, 2006) acknowledges in which expert knowledge is consolidated.
that creative fields might encompass differ- Power and Hauge (2008) and Entwistle
ent spatial scales, he puts a special emphasis (2006) also stressed the importance of prox-
on the regional and urban levels. He regards imity to suppliers and consumers. Fashion
clusters in cultural industries as places that are buyers act as vital links between suppliers and
endowed with rich infrastructures of special- customers, mediating on
ised production chains and skilled workers.
Note that the importance of local availability of numerous interests, tastes and identities,
deal with suppliers and come to ‘know’ their
specialised suppliers and skilled workers refers
customer(s) (Entwistle, 2006, p. 704).
to the first two forms of localisation economies.
Scott also speaks of creative fields as ‘places of One of the key reasons for the success of
trust’. Trust in a creative field is important to Parisian haute couture was the fact the city
facilitate interaction and knowledge exchange, was full of small shops of seamstresses, fabric
referring to the third form of localisation merchants and small suppliers of buttons,
economies. Interaction, collaboration and ribbons and other accessories. Indeed, the
networking are especially crucial in cultural decline of specialist shops of seamstresses in
industries, where a tension exists between Amsterdam in the 1990s has been noted as a
their atomistic and hyper-competitive market considerable loss for the Amsterdam fashion
structure (Banks et al., 2000) and their need for cluster (Raes, 2000).
symbolic knowledge exchange (Asheim and Others have pointed to sectoral variety as a
Gertler, 2005; Vinodrai, 2006; Asheim, Coenen source of intersectoral knowledge spillovers
and Vang, 2007; Asheim et al., 2007). Local (Scott, 1996; Hauge and Hracs, 2010). In the
communities of creative individuals provide literature of agglomeration economies, this is
the basis for knowledge exchange in social commonly referred to as Jacobs externalities
networks on a quid pro quo basis (Scott, 2000; (Glaeser et al., 1992). Fashion design is highly
Banks et al., 2000), similar to the role of social dependent on photography, music, media and
networks in knowledge spillovers between advertisement companies to expose the public
inventors (Breschi and Lissoni, 2009). to its goods as well as to get new symbolic
Looking at the fashion design industry input for next season’s designs. Fashion design
more specifically, one observes short product entrepreneurs thus profit from being located
URBAN AMENITIES   5

in cities with ‘related variety’ (Frenken et al., share of the flow [of creative class members]
2007). For example, in her study on the British (Florida, 2005, pp. 6–7).
fashion design industry, McRobbie (1998)
highlighted the strong dependencies between According to Florida, it is those qualities of
fashion media and fashion design. Rantisi places that attract creative people and because
(2002, 2004) also showed the importance of of their presence they attract high-tech indus-
intersectoral dependencies in the emergence tries and cultural industries. The concentra-
and development of the New York fashion tion of a diversity of talented people powers
industry. In the Dutch case, the concentra- the economic growth of creative cities
tion of fashion design in Amsterdam indeed
tolerance and low entry barriers to human
coincides with the concentration of related capital helps to attract talent and that talent
cultural industries, such as advertising, pho- is in turn associated with high technology
tography and media (Wenting et al., 2006). industry and regional growth (Florida,
The pivotal role of agglomeration econo- 2005, p. 139).
mies in clusters has recently been challenged
by Florida’s (2002) work on the creative class. In a similar vein, Gottlieb (1995) found that
Starting from the concept of occupational urban amenities with respect to the residential
structures rather than industry, Florida argues location of employees influenced the location
for an understanding of spatial clustering decision of firms.
in cultural industries based on the labour Florida’s explanation of spatial clustering
population rather than on the firm popula- in cultural industries is fundamentally dif-
tion. According to his creative capital theory, ferent from explanations based on agglom-
the existence of an attractive people climate eration economies, because he reasons from
(derived from a socially tolerant atmosphere personal motives of members of the creative
and attractive urban amenities) is key to the class rather than from the business motives
success of cultural industries in particular of firms. Following this reasoning, workers
cities (Florida, 2005). Note that cultural indus- first decide where to live according to their
tries are just a small part of the industries in preferences regarding residential amenities
which Florida’s creative class works (Florida, (Storper and Manville, 2006). Firms then fol-
2002). Nevertheless, we presume that the low these decisions in their quest for qualified
people climate argument fits to the case of workers. Baris (2003, p. 42) notes that “thus,
fashion designers—that is to say, they will have the old mode of people moving to follow jobs
distinct locational preferences, driven by per- is turned on its head”.
sonal motives rather than business motives. Florida’s work has been criticised on sev-
The personal motives of creative workers eral grounds. The cause–effect relationships
to locate in particular cities have to do with between the location decisions of workers
‘qualities of life’ that fit with their values, aes- and firms are generally expected to run both
thetics, lifestyles and consumption patterns. ways. It is, therefore, statistically hard to
Florida states that distinguish between ‘people following firms’
and ‘firms following people’ (van Oort et al.,
tolerance is the key factor in enabling places
2003). The originality of Florida’s ‘people
to mobilize and attract technology and talent
[Cities] ... that are open to immigrants, artists, climate’ has also been questioned. The role of
gays and racial integration ... gain an economic amenities has always been part-and-parcel of
advantage in both harnessing the creative mainstream views in urban development (Peck,
capabilities of a broader range of their own 2005; Markusen, 2006). Nevertheless, Florida’s
people and in capturing a disproportionate thesis has gained widespread popularity among
6   RIK WENTING ET AL.

city policy-makers and planners. The result Importantly, in this exercise, we control for
is a policy which aims to attract creative a host of other variables affecting economic
talent rather than firms by focusing on the success. Notably, we take into account the
improvement of living conditions to fit the size of the socio-professional network of an
needs of creative workers. The effectiveness entrepreneur as a proxy for knowledge spill-
of policies to attract the creative class and overs. This allows us to distinguish between
to stimulate economic growth is, however, benefits arising from co-location and benefits
disputed (Glaeser, 2005; Peck, 2005). stemming from social networks.
In our empirical analysis, we test to what
extent urban amenities on the one hand and 3.2 Data Collection
agglomeration economies on the other hand We have collected data by contacting all 1496
affect the locational decisions of fashion design firms classified as a fashion design firm by the
entrepreneurs. In fashion design, most entre- Chambers of Commerce in The Netherlands.
preneurs are self-employed or employ only one We went through a questionnaire by tele-
or two assistants. This means that the location phone with the founders of these firms, whom
decision from a worker’s perspective and from we refer to as fashion design entrepreneurs.
a firm’s perspective coincide. In our study, the We thus exclude fashion trade firms (retail
unit of analysis is the fashion design entre- or wholesale) and fashion manufacturing
preneur who founded his/her own firm. Our firms (textile and clothing manufacturing)
focus on the fashion design entrepreneur thus as well as fashion designers who work as
makes it possible to analyse the relative impor- employees. From the 1496 firms classified as
tance of personal versus business motives in fashion design firm, 511 firms appeared to be
location decisions using a questionnaire. (still) active in fashion design. Out of the 511
designers contacted, 275 questionnaires were
3. Methodology completed, resulting in a response rate of 54
per cent. The responses are representative of
3.1 Research Design the entire population concerning the variables
We ask the question whether business motives, location and firm size in terms of number of
especially related to agglomeration economies, employees.3
or personal motives, specifically concerning We asked questions about their location,
urban amenities, drive the location decision of their locational preferences, their firm’s size,
Dutch fashion design entrepreneurs. Because annual income, the number and type of col-
of the fact that the large majority of designers laborations and their product markets. We
is self-employed or leading a small firm, one aim to offer industry-wide results and hence
can analyse the business and personal motives choose to do a survey rather than in-depth
simultaneously as the employer and entre- case studies. Our results are subject to the
preneur coincide. We did so by sending out shortcomings of a closed survey instrument
a questionnaire to all known fashion design (Cumbers et al., 2003). Or as Gable states
firms in The Netherlands. We thus take an
for a survey to succeed in elucidating causal
industrial rather than occupational approach relationships or even in providing descriptive
(see Barbour and Markusen, 2007). statistics, it must contain all the right questions
In addition to comparing business and asked in the right way (Gable, 1994, p. 114).
personal motives, we also estimate a statistical
model that explains economic success by the For this reason, we formulated our questions
personal income of fashion design entrepre- on the motivations underlying location choice
neurs. In this way, we can assess whether entre- and firm characteristics as explicitly and
preneurs in clusters benefit from co-location. specifically as possible.
URBAN AMENITIES   7

3.3 Main Variables Defining cities as municipalities with over


Most fashion design entrepreneurs in The 50 000 inhabitants, over 60 per cent of all
Netherlands are located in cities, with a high fashion design entrepreneurs are located
concentration in the city of Amsterdam. This in cities, but only 49 per cent of the Dutch
finding is similar to those in other studies population as a whole. More than a quarter of
on the geography of design work (Vinodrai, all fashion design entrepreneurs (26 per cent)
2006; Reimer and Leslie, 2008) and to find- are located in the city-region of Amsterdam,
ings on the geography of the creative class against less than 8 per cent of all Dutch inhab-
(Florida, 2002; Boschma and Fritsch, 2009). itants. This renders the location quotient of
In our study, location refers to the business Amsterdam larger than 3. Figure 1 shows the
location of designers. Note, however, that absolute numbers and location quotients for
almost all designers live in the same labour all 40 labour market areas (NUTS3 regions)
market area (NUTS3 region) as they work. in The Netherlands. The location pattern of

Figure 1.   The spatial distribution of fashion designers in The Netherlands (N = 275).
Source: data collection by the authors.
8   RIK WENTING ET AL.

the fashion design industry is in line with the urban amenities: personal motives related
general geographical pattern of the cultural to the location of residence. We finally asked
industries in The Netherlands, which tend whether the location decision was driven by
to concentrate in the Amsterdam region the reputation of the location. Such locational
(Kloosterman, 2004; van Aalst et al., 2006). behaviour can be thought of as imitative
Most fashion design entrepreneurs are rather than autonomous. A reputation as a
women, accounting for 80 per cent of all major fashion city is based on the location
fashion design entrepreneurs. The lion’s decisions of fashion design entrepreneurs in
share (87 per cent) of all firms in the Dutch the past and their success. By following the
fashion design industry are self-employed. location decision of previous entrepreneurs
The remaining designer entrepreneurs gen- by locating in a reputable city, designers are
erally have one or two employees, while imitating earlier location decisions rather
only 1 per cent has more than 10 employees. than making autonomous decisions.5
Interestingly, most fashion design entrepre- Figure 2 shows the average of these values
neurs (55 per cent) earn a low income from for all respondents in The Netherlands on
their fashion design activities, where low the left side of the graph, and broken down at
income is defined as less than 20 000 euros different spatial areas on the right side of the
a year.4 Only 21 per cent earn a high income graph. Note that we only asked designers who
of over 40 000 euros a year, which leaves 24 had moved to a new location when setting
per cent with an income of between 20 000 up their business a total of 163 respondents.
and 40 000 euros. These figures suggest that To see whether creative entrepreneurs tend
the group of designers is very heterogeneous, to settle in cluster, urban or rural locations,
since many are struggling to stay in business we differentiated the results for Amsterdam,
and only a few are prospering. other cities with more than 50 000 inhabitants
and the rest of the country. A third of the
relocating entrepreneurs choose Amsterdam.
4. Locational Preferences
The results shown in the left side graphs in
We are interested in the role of urban ame- Figure 2 indicate that personal motives tend
nities and agglomeration economies in to be more important than business motives
attracting fashion design entrepreneurs to in the location decision of fashion design
a location. To this end, we only asked those entrepreneurs. The average scores for personal
entrepreneurs who had relocated to set up a motives are all higher than the scores for the
new firm about their location factors. Of our business motives. This suggests that the loca-
respondents, 35 per cent chose to move to a tion decisions of fashion design entrepreneurs
different location to set up business. These are indeed predominantly, although by no
respondents have been asked to grade the means exclusively, driven by the amenities of
extent to which each location factor was of the residential environment. We also asked
no importance (grade 1), some importance to what extent people choose to locate where
(grade 2) or much importance (grade 3) for their family and friends are. Two-thirds of the
their location decision. designers (66 per cent) considered locating near
The first three location factors concern family and friends important. We did not find
the importance of the operation of agglom- a significant difference between regions in the
eration economies: proximity to suppliers, preference for locating near family and friends.
customers and fellow designers. The last Figure 2 also shows that those who value
three questions concern the importance of certain location factors as more important
URBAN AMENITIES   9

Figure 2. Business and personal motives for entrepreneurs in fashion design in different areas
(outcome of independent samples t-tests for equality of means in parentheses; N = 163).
Source: data collection by the authors.
10   RIK WENTING ET AL.

tend to have chosen more often to locate in various locational factors. The question remains
Amsterdam. Indeed, with the exception of whether, indeed, fashion design entrepre-
a tolerant social atmosphere, t-tests show neurs benefit from agglomeration economies,
that Amsterdam entrepreneurs more often whether they are aware or not. If agglomeration
mention location factors than those located economies were to operate in the Dutch fashion
elsewhere in the country. Since many entre- design industry, designers in the Amsterdam
preneurs are located in Amsterdam, this cluster would outperform designers outside
shows that location motives and location the cluster.
decisions are indeed consistent.
Even though we concluded from the results 5.1 Dependent Variable
shown in the left side graphs in Figure 2 To analyse the agglomeration economies
that agglomeration economies (i.e. busi- hypothesis, we are in need of an unambiguous
ness motives) are valued considerably lower performance indicator. In cultural industries,
in designers’ location decisions than urban however, traditional proxies for success based
amenities (i.e. personal motives), the right on size or growth do not always apply. Profit
side graphs in Figure 2 show that the situa- is also problematic as a performance indi-
tion is more complex. Although localisation cator, because profit figures are extremely
economies might not be valued highly, they volatile and—as we discovered when carry-
are important for start-ups in Amsterdam and ing out our questionnaire—often unknown
less relevant for designers located elsewhere. To to the designer. We therefore opted for a less
the extent that agglomeration economies are at ambiguous indicator: whether a designer
play, this result implies that Amsterdam is the earns more than 20 000 euros per year from
only Dutch cluster of fashion design that has his or her fashion design activities, defined as
attained the critical mass necessary to gener- a dummy variable, named HIGH.INCOME.
ate localisation economies for entrepreneurs. Note that here we define success purely in
Amsterdam also scores significantly terms of income per year and not on the basis
higher on reputation. This indicates that of artistic value, despite the fact that some
the Amsterdam cluster profits from a self- fashion design entrepreneurs consider their
reinforcement mechanism: its reputation work as an artistic activity rather than as a
as a fashion city attracts fashion designers commercial activity. However, one can assume
whose presence adds again to its reputation, that personal income and artistic success cor-
et cetera.6 The importance of reputation as a relate, albeit less strongly than commercial
location factor for those who choose to live success and personal income. This indicator
in the cluster supports Scott’s (2006) argu- yields two groups of almost equal size with
ment that creative fields enjoy self-sustaining 55 per cent earning less than 20 000 euros
agglomeration economies. Interestingly, even per year and 45 per cent earning more than
though tolerance is rated as an important 20 000 per years. This dummy variable proxies
location decision factor, designers located the extent to which fashion entrepreneurs are
in urban areas do not rate this factor sig- able to rely solely on their design activities to
nificantly higher compared with designers make a living and in other words, corresponds
located elsewhere. Designers in Amsterdam with Florida’s (2005) view that the quality of
and rural locations value tolerance equally. economic growth is reflected in the wages and
income that people make.
5. Economic Success 5.2 Independent Variables
Our results so far were based on the subjec- Agglomeration economies. To test whether
tive perception and appreciation of these agglomeration economies exist in the
URBAN AMENITIES   11

Amsterdam cluster, we introduce a dummy reflecting the experience inherited from the
variable AMSTERDAM for those work- parent firm (Klepper, 2002; Dahl and Reichstein,
ing in the labour market region of Greater 2007). Experience is also gained by setting up
Amsterdam (NUTS3 level). In this way, we can several firms and by managing your own firm
assess whether co-location in the Amsterdam for a prolonged period of time. We thus include
cluster contributes to economic success as three variables to capture experience: a spin-
proxied by the personal income of the head off dummy (SPINOFF), a serial entrepreneur
designer. dummy (SERIAL) and the number of years a
However, the cluster benefits have to be person has been an entrepreneur independently
assessed while including alternative deter- from the type of industry (YEARS.ENT).
minants possibly affecting the success of Apart from the determinants of success
fashion design entrepreneurs (see Boschma related to co-location in the cluster, network-
and Weterings, 2005). From our theoretical ing and pre-entry experience, a number of
discussion, two alternative explanations for controls need to be taken into account that
the superior performance of firms in clusters are expected to affect fashion design entre-
were proposed: networking and pre-entry preneur incomes.
experience.
Human capital. The human capital of
Networking. The questionnaire asked the entrepreneur is also expected to be an
designers about the number of collaborations important determinant of personal incomes
with other fashion design entrepreneurs dur- as it holds for virtually all professions. In the
ing the past year. Two out of every five fashion Dutch fashion design industry, three-quarters
design entrepreneurs collaborate with other graduated from a fashion design academy,
fashion design entrepreneurs. The number which is part of the Dutch higher education
of collaborations varies between 0 and 50. system. A dummy variable (ACADEMY)
This number is captured by the variable captures all designers with a higher education
COLLABORATION. The questionnaire also background in fashion design.
asked those designers who had collaborated,
what type of collaboration was considered Full-time. One important and obvious
important for them (with the possibility to control is how many hours a week a designer
mark more than one answer): collabora- devotes to fashion design. From the question-
tion in the production of designs (COLL. naire, we know whether the designers works
PRODUCTION), collaboration in the mar- part-time or full-time, where full-time is
keting of designs (COLL.MARKETING) or defined as working more than 32 hours a week
collaboration by information and knowledge on fashion design activities. This is captured
exchange in general (COLL.INFORMATION). by a dummy variable FULLTIME. The vast
We use both the number of collaborations and majority (81.1 per cent) of our respondents
the type of collaboration considered as most are classified as full-timers.
important as explanatory variables for success.
In this way, we can test the importance of net- Market segment. Fashion design is a pecu-
works as a source of competitiveness as well as liar market in that it ranges from the design
the type that is most conducive for this success. of simple T-shirts to works of art in haute
couture. Although the price for a cloth item
Experience. Another important determinant goes up with the symbolic value added, so
of success is the experience of an entrepreneur. does its exclusivity. On average, fashion design
Earlier research in industrial dynamics has entrepreneurs active in the volatile and com-
shown that spin-offs out-perform start-ups, petitive market of high fashion have a lower
12   RIK WENTING ET AL.

average income, compared with those active in 5.3 Results


more commercially viable parts of the (mass) The correlation matrix between the inde-
market. Fashion design entrepreneurs who pendent variables is given in Table 3. The
produce for a large, mass-consumer market correlation between the variables is low,
earn more steady and higher average incomes except for COLLABORATION and three
than designers who design unique pieces of variables denoting the type of collaboration.
clothing for small, shifting market niches. The This is to be expected because we only asked
latter group often consider themselves as artists entrepreneurs with a positive number of
more than business people and accept a lower collaborations which type of collaboration
income for more artistic freedom (Wenting et they thought to be important. Because the
al., 2006). We therefore introduce two dum- number and the type of collaborations are
mies—for the middle fashion segment (PRICE. intrinsically related, and strongly correlated,
MID) and the high fashion segment (PRICE. we decided not to include them in the same
HIGH), both of which are expected to con- regression models.
tribute negatively to income compared with Regarding the correlation between other
the omitted variable (PRICE.LOW). variables, a number of interesting patterns
Tables 1 and 2 summarise all variables used can be discerned. The experience variables
in the various regression analyses. Using a SPINOFF and YEARS.ENT are significantly
binominal logistic regression, we assess which and positively correlated. This implies that
determinants have a significant effect on the spin-off firms are able to survive for lon-
personal income of Dutch fashion design ger periods of time, compared with other
entrepreneurs as a proxy for economic success. entrants in line with earlier research by

Table 1.   Definition of the variables used in the logistic regression analyses
Variable Description
HIGH.INCOME Income of more than 20,000 euros per year from fashion design activity
AMSTERDAM Located in the Amsterdam labour market region (NUTS3 level)
COLLABORATIONa Number of collaborations with fellow fashion designers
COLL.PRODUCTION Finds collaboration in production important
COLL.MARKETING Finds collaboration in marketing important
COLL.INFORMATION Finds collaboration in information and knowledge sharing important
SPINOFF Has been employed by a fashion design firm prior to start-up
SERIAL Has previously started a firm in the fashion design industry
YEARS.ENTb Number of years of experience as an entrepreneur
ACADEMY Bachelor’s degree or higher in fashion design
FULLTIME Working more than 32 hours a week on fashion design activity
PRICE.MID Is active in the middle and middle-to-high price segments
PRICE.HIGH Is active in the high and haute couture price segments
a
We log-transformed this variable to reflect the decreasing benefit of each additional collaboration
link. The exact variable definition becomes COLLABORATION = log(x+1), where x stands for the
number of collaborations as indicated in the questionnaire.
b
We log-transformed the number of years an entrepreneur has been active as an independent fashion
designer to reflect the decreasing benefit of each additional year in business. The exact variable
definition becomes YEARS.ENT = log(y+1), where y stands for the number of years an entrepreneur
has been active as an independent fashion designer as indicated in the questionnaire.
URBAN AMENITIES   13

Table 2.   Descriptive statistics of the variables used in the logistic regression analyses
Variable N Minimum Maximum Mean S.D.
AMSTERDAM 275 0.00 1.00 0.26
COLLABORATION 273 0.00 1.70 0.17 0.30
COLL.PRODUCTION 271 0.00 1.00 0.30
COLL.MARKETING 271 0.00 1.00 0.07
COLL.INFORMATION 271 0.00 1.00 0.20
SPINOFF 275 0.00 1.00 0.43
SERIAL 275 0.00 1.00 0.11
YEARS.ENT 274 0.00 1.72 0.91 0.41
ACADEMY 214 0.00 1.00 0.75
FULLTIME 275 0.00 1.00 0.81
PRICE.HIGH 268 0.00 1.00 0.32
PRICE.MID 268 0.00 1.00 0.59

Wenting (2008) on the global high fashion economies variable AMSTERDAM and our
design industry. Furthermore, a positive and control variables. Here, we test for the advan-
significant correlation between SPINOFF and tage of co-location of fashion design entrepre-
COLLABORATION shows that spin-offs tend neurs in the Amsterdam cluster. The effect is
to collaborate more with fellow fashion design positive and significant reflecting the higher
entrepreneurs, compared with other entrants. incomes of Amsterdam-based designers com-
This may reflect the fact that spin-offs con- pared with designers located elsewhere. Model
tinue to profit from networks of the parent 1 also shows the coefficients for the control
firm, as has also been found by other studies variables ACADEMY, FULLTIME, PRICE.
(Sorenson, 2003; Klepper and Sleeper, 2005).7 HIGH and PRICE.MID. The control variables
A positive and significant correlation between for higher education and full-time employ-
AMSTERDAM and COLLABORATION ment have positive coefficients, as expected,
shows that fashion design entrepreneurs in but are insignificant. Furthermore, designers
Amsterdam are more inclined to collabo- active in higher-price ‘artist’ segments earn
rate. This correlation is in line with previous significantly less income than their colleagues
studies on (social) networking in clusters active in lower-priced ‘commercial’ segments.
(Sorenson, 2003; Dahl and Pederson, 2005), The effects of our control variables on income
including studies on networking in design in all subsequent regression models are simi-
industries (Florida and Stolarick, 2005; lar to the results of model 1.
Vinodrai, 2006). Finally, the correlation In the two subsequent models, we test
between AMSTERDAM and SPINOFF shows whether socio-professional collaboration
that Amsterdam designers are more likely to with peers affects income. In model 2, we add
be spin-off entrants, compared with design- the number of collaborations and, in model
ers located elsewhere. These results are in 3, the types of collaboration that collaborat-
line with research on clusters as seedbeds ing designers find important. The number
of spin-offs (Klepper, 2002; Boschma and of collaborations contributed positively and
Wenting, 2007). significantly to income, while collaboration in
Table 4 shows the results of the multivari- production is the only type of collaboration
ate regression analyses. Model 1 presents the that contributed to income. Networking—
regression coefficients of the agglomeration and the alleged knowledge spillovers resulting
14   RIK WENTING ET AL.

from it—indeed contributes to economic

-0.831*** 1.000***
success. The latter result on the type of col-
12

laboration reflects that not all types of col-

1.000***
laboration are important for success; only
working together on the production of design
11

benefits designers. We understand this result


as stemming from the highly tacit nature of

1.000***
knowledge spillovers in cultural industries,

-0.023
-0.007
10

which means that most knowledge is trans-


ferred when two designers truly work together
1.000***

in the design process.


0.049
-0.010
0.034
9

Importantly, including the networking vari-


ables in our model renders the AMSTERDAM
1.000***

dummy variable insignificant. Thus, agglom-


0.136** 0.067
0.120** 0.024
0.009
0.005
8

eration economies are not contributing to


economic success. This result shows that spa-
1.000***

tial clustering per se is not beneficial; rather,


-0.017

0.048
-0.047
7

Amsterdam-based designers are more attrac-


Notes: *** correlation is significant at the 0.01 level; ** correlation is significant at the 0.05 level.

tive as collaboration partners—both for peers


1.000***

0.166***
Table 3.   Correlation matrix of the variables used in the logistic regression analyses

inside and outside the cluster—than designers


-0.026

-0.071
0.050
0.007
0.032

located elsewhere. Indeed, 44 per cent of the


6

networking designers outside Amsterdam


who did not collaborate locally, indicated
1.000***

-0.128**

to collaborate primarily with designers in


0.097
-0.061

0.028
0.013
-0.064
0.083
5

Amsterdam, while Amsterdam hosts only 26


per cent of all designers. This implies that
1.000***
0.221***

the cluster functions not so much as a local


-0.006
-0.005
-0.031
-0.113
0.060
0.013
-0.001
4

network, but rather as a national ‘hub’ of


network interaction. Such an interpretation is
1.000***

0.285***
0.144**

0.147**

further supported by the positive and signifi-


-0.051
-0.049
0.094
-0.071
-0.066
0.063

cant correlation between the AMSTERDAM


3

and COLLABORATION variables, which


1.000***
0.543***
0.239***
0.507***
0.177***

indicates that Amsterdam seems to offer more


-0.306
-0.096
0.049
0.028
-0.070
0.003

collaboration opportunities compared with


2

other cities. Since collaboration entails the


sharing of ideas, Amsterdam as the nation’s
1.000***

0.156***
0.145**

social network hub acts as a physical centre of


3 COLL.PRODUCTION 0.099
0.072
5 COLL.INFORMATION -0.042

0.007
0.097
0.098
0.073
-0.020
0.016
1

knowledge circulation and creativity.


In models 4 and 5, we include the experience
variables. As expected, spin-offs and the num-
4 COLL.MARKETING
2 COLLABORATION

ber of years of entrepreneurial experience


are both significant determinants of success.
1 AMSTERDAM

11 PRICE.HIGH
12 PRICE.MID
10 FULLTIME
8 YEARS.ENT

Serial entrepreneurship in fashion design,


9 ACADEMY
6 SPINOFF

however, does not affect success. Again, the


7 SERIAL

AMSTERDAM dummy is insignificant and


its coefficient gets closer to zero compared
URBAN AMENITIES   15

Table 4.   Estimates of the binominal logistic regression models (dependent variable: average
or higher income; standard errors in parentheses)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Variable (n = 203) (n = 202) (n = 201) (n = 201) (n = 200)
AMSTERDAM 0.793** 0.693 0.708 0.512 0.540
(0.353) (0.365) (0.371) (0.395) (0.400)
COLLABORATION 1.711*** 1.620***
(0.568) (0.611)
COLL.PRODUCTION 1.126*** 1.139***
(0.363) (0.389)
COLL.MARKETING -0.136 -0.001
(0.625) (0.677)
COLL.INFORMATION -0.085 -0.102
(0.407) (0.431)
SPINOFF 0.735** 0.719**
(0.359) (0.364)
SERIAL 0.246 0.173
(0.544) (0.552)
YEARS.ENT 1.727*** 1.747***
(0.463) (0.468)
ACADEMY 0.460 0.425 0.286 0.331 0.213
(0.350) (0.358) (0.367) (0.387) (0.395)
FULLTIME 0.603 0.583 0.769 0.428 0.611
(0.370) (0.381) (0.392) (0.407) (0.417)
PRICE.HIGH -1.967*** -2.027*** -2.280*** -1.948*** -2.097**
(0.709) (0.710) (0.821) (0.746) (0.848)
PRICE.MID -1.707** -1.781*** -2.097** -1.709** -1.946**
(0.688) (0.688) (0.803) (0.720) (0.826)
Constant 0.505 0.345 0.563 -1.486 -1.405
(0.740) (0.748) (0.864) (0.902) (1.021)

-2 log likelihood 259.997 249.356 245.226 229.744 226.119


Chi-squared 19.996*** 29.070*** 31.980*** 47.462*** 49.859***
R2 (Nagelkerke) 0.125 0.179 0.197 0.281 0.295
Overall percentage
correctly predicted 61.1 66.3 68.2 66.2 70.5
Notes: *** correlation is significant at the 0.01 level; ** correlation is significant at the 0.05 level.

with models 3 and 4, which further supports 6. Discussion


our conclusion that agglomeration economies
per se are absent. This reflects the positive cor- Using a questionnaire among Dutch fash-
relation between the Amsterdam variable and ion design entrepreneurs, we find that the
the experience variables. Knowledge spillovers locational behaviour of fashion design
are not of a pervasive nature, but are specific entrepreneurs is better explained by urban
to the firm and its network. We conclude amenities than by agglomeration economies.
that networking and experience are crucial The agglomeration economies thesis was
determinants of economic success.8 further analysed using data on the personal
16   RIK WENTING ET AL.

income of fashion design entrepreneurs as Our results also showed that entrepre-
a proxy for economic success. Our study neurs located in the cluster did not benefit
showed that Amsterdam-based designers from agglomeration economies per se. Being
indeed have a higher income, but that their located in the cluster had no significant effect
success cannot be attributed to agglomera- on the income of entrepreneurs. It should be
tion economies stemming from co-location. noted here that we only tested for localisation
Rather, network ties with fellow designers economies. Future research should include
and experience gained in the past explain possible effects of Jacobs externalities or
economic success. Yet, these success factors are related variety (Hauge and Hracs, 2010).
more commonly associated with Amsterdam- Where entrepreneurs in clusters differ from
based designers than with designers located those outside the cluster is that they collabo-
elsewhere. Co-location affects economic suc- rate more. This networking in turn enhances
cess indirectly by facilitating learning through economic performance. Interestingly, the
increased opportunities to gain valuable expe- cluster in Amsterdam does not only function
rience and socio-professional networking. as a local network, but also as a national ‘hub’
Our study has three important implica- of network interaction. Amsterdam-based
tions: methodological, theoretical and policy- entrepreneurs are more active in collaborating
related. Methodologically, our study points to with other firms within and outside the clus-
the value of questionnaires in studying the ter. For designers located in the cluster, col-
locational behaviour of entrepreneurs. To laboration with designers outside the cluster is
delineate entrepreneurs in a cultural industry a way to escape the risk of overembeddedness
in a precise manner, questionnaires have the (Uzzi, 1997; Uzzi and Spiro, 2005) as well as
important advantage of direct validation by involuntary spillovers to close competitors
asking people about their exact activities. (Boschma, 2005). In this way, designers can
What is more, one can directly pose questions avoid becoming too dependent on a handful
regarding location decisions and underlying of local collaboration partners, which would
motives, rather than deriving them indirectly diminish their creativity and flexibility. For
from aggregate data from statistical offices. designers outside the cluster, collaboration
Theoretically, our results suggest that with designers in the cluster provides access
Florida’s theory on the location preferences to part of the knowledge circulating in the
of the creative class is indeed an important cluster. By connecting to the network hub,
supplement to cluster theories in economic designers outside the cluster can overcome
geography. Since most fashion design firms some of their locational disadvantages.
consist solely of the entrepreneur, personal From our findings on the locational behav-
valuations regarding (urban) amenities are iour and success of fashion design entre-
an important part of location decisions. We preneurs, some policy implications follow.
find that relocating entrepreneurs are indeed First, we find that urban amenities and city
influenced, although by no means exclusively, reputation attract entrepreneurs. Therefore,
by amenities of the residential environment. investments in urban amenities and reputa-
A follow-up research question would be to tion may indeed raise the attractiveness of
know why entrepreneurs did not choose to a city to fashion design entrepreneurs. In
relocate, or in other words, what roles busi- this context, Martinez (2007) found that
ness and people climates play in retaining policy involvement in fashion events and
firms. Furthermore, future research should fashion institutes considerably contributed
also approach fashion designers who work as to the success of Antwerp as a fashion city
employees of large fashion houses, clothing (see also Christopherson, 2004). Urban
companies or retail companies. amenities and reputation may attract young
URBAN AMENITIES   17

creative entrepreneurs, but they do not Notes


impact their economic success. Indeed, most
1. Note that our definition of urban amenities
entrepreneurs do not succeed in earning an
encompasses many aspects that go beyond
income required to live comfortably in large the physiological environment of the city.
cities—and they most likely will give up It also encompasses the social and cultural
soon after. Our regression findings on the atmosphere of a place.
determinants of economic performance are 2. Definitions of creative and cultural industries
suggestive of policy advice regarding fashion tend to overlap to varying degrees in the
design schools. Fashion design students can literature and some authors oppose their
be advised to learn first from established interchangeability. Note that our definition of
designers, before venturing out on their own cultural industries is similar to that of Scott’s
(2000) of cultural industries.
as spin-offs. Furthermore, internships and
3. For more details, see Wenting et al. (2006).
active networking should be promoted. This 4. The category 20 000 to 40 000 euros income
also holds for incumbent entrepreneurs as a per annum captures the income levels around
way to share risks and exchange knowledge. the modal gross income per capita in The
Although our analysis is based on a snap- Netherlands.
shot of an otherwise evolving cluster, our 5. Note that reputation can relate to both business
results can—albeit on a more speculative and personal factors, since the reputation of
note—support a dynamic interpretation. location may refer to the ‘place to be’ to set
Our results suggest that, at least in rather up your business or the ‘place to be’ to live
small countries like The Netherlands with a comfortably. The reputation as a fashion city is
likely to benefit both the city and the fashion
domestic market of only 16 million inhabit-
entrepreneur. In other words
ants, cultural industries are most likely to    the connection between the spatial context
self-organise into a single dominant cluster. of fashion and the city is two-way: fashion
The importance of gaining experience and feeds off associations with particular
building networks attracts young designers places and those places are branded by
to Amsterdam as the dominant cluster. The their connection to fashion (Power and
attractiveness of the Amsterdam cluster is pre- Hauge, 2008, p. 133).
cisely the opportunities for collaboration—with 6. Such mechanisms are known as information
peers within and outside the cluster—as well cascades (Bikhchandani et al., 1992).
7. Spin-offs might simply be more attractive
as the amenities that are—at least partly—
collaboration partners for other designers
created by the cluster itself. The density of because they out-perform other entrants—
fashion design entrepreneurs and incubator implying an endogenous relationship between
firms in the Amsterdam cluster attracts new success and collaboration, which is a common
entrants who, after locating in the cluster, problem in social network studies.
will make the cluster even more attractive 8. Our results are in line with recent case study
for future entrepreneurs. Our conclusion is evidence on the success of London fashion
in line with that of Scott (2006) who argues designers. Malem (2008) finds that the experience
that such a reinforcing mechanism of growth and networks of the entrepreneur translate
is a central element of creative fields. Due to into leverage for contractual agreements with
licensors and allow for diversification and
the self-sustaining nature of the attractiveness
consulting strategies, all leading to the financial
of Amsterdam as the Dutch fashion capital, it success of the fashion design firm.
will be difficult for other Dutch cities to equal
Amsterdam’s success in the near future. The
city of Amsterdam now faces the challenge
References
to compete with the established centres of Aalst, I. van, Atzema, O. A. L. C., Boschma, R. A.
fashion design across the globe. and Oort, F. G. van (2006) Creatieve klasse en
18   RIK WENTING ET AL.

economische groei in stedelijk Nederland, in: from seven European countries, Economic
B. Hofstede and S. Raes (Eds) Creatief Vermogen, Geography, 85(4), pp. 391–423.
pp. 123–155. The Hague: Elsevier Overheid. Boschma, R. A. and Ter Wal, A. L. J. (2007)
Asheim, B. and Gertler, M. S. (2005) Regional Knowledge networks and innovative perfor-
innovation systems and the geographical mance in an industrial district: the case of a
foundations of innovation, in: J. Fagerberg, footwear district in the south of Italy, Industry
D. Mowery, R. Nelson (Eds) The Oxford and Innovation, 14(2), pp. 177–199.
Handbook of Innovation, pp. 291–317. Oxford: Boschma, R. A. and Wenting, R. (2007) The spatial
Oxford University Press. evolution of the British automobile industry:
Asheim, B., Coenen, L. and Vang, J. (2007) Face- does location matter?, Industrial and Corporate
to-face, buzz, and knowledge bases: sociospatial Change, 16(2), pp. 213–238.
implications for learning, innovation, and Boschma, R. A. and Weterings, A. B. R. (2005) The
innovation policy, Environment and Planning effect of regional differences on the performance
C, 25, pp. 655–670. of software firms in the Netherlands, Journal of
Asheim, B., Coenen, L., Moodysson, J. and Vang, J. Economic Geography, 5(5), pp. 567–588.
(2007) Constructing knowledge-based regional Breschi, S. and Lissoni, F. (2009) Mobility of
advantage: implications for regional innovation skilled workers and co-invention networks: an
policy, International Journal of Entrepreneurship anatomy of localized knowledge flows, Journal
and Innovation Management, 7(2/3/4/5), of Economic Geography, 9(4), pp. 439–468.
pp. 140–155. Christopherson, S. (2004) The divergent worlds
Banks, M., Lovatt, A., O’Conner, J. and Raffo, C. of new media: how policy shapes work in the
(2000) Risk and trust in the cultural industries, creative economy, Review of Policy Research,
Geoforum, 31, pp. 453–464. 21(4), pp. 543–558.
Barbour, E. and Markusen, A. (2007) Regional Cumbers, A., MacKinnon, D. and Chapman, K.
occupational and industrial structure: does (2003) Innovation, collaboration, and learn-
one imply the other?, International Regional ing in regional clusters: a study of SMEs in
Science Review, 30(1), pp. 72–90. the Aberdeen oil complex, Environment and
Baris, M. (2003) Review of Richard Florida: Planning A, 35, pp. 1689–1706.
The Rise of the Creative Class: And How It’s Dahl, M. S. and Pederson, C. Ø. R. (2005)
Transforming Work, Leisure, Community, and Knowledge flows through informal contacts in
Everyday Life, The Next American City, 1, industrial clusters: myths or realities?, Research
pp. 42–45. Policy, 33(10), pp. 1673–1686.
Bathelt, H. (2005) Cluster relations in the media Dahl, M. S. and Reichstein, T. (2007) Are you
industry: exploring the ‘distanced neighbour’ experienced? Prior experience and the survival
paradox in Leipzig, Regional Studies, 39, of new organizations, Industry and Innovation,
pp. 105–127. 14, pp. 497–511.
Bathelt, H., Malmberg, A. and Maskell, P. (2004) Entwistle, J. (2006) The cultural economy
Clusters and knowledge: local buzz, global of fashion buying, Current Sociology, 54,
pipelines and the process of knowledge pp. 704–724.
creation, Progress in Human Geography, 28, Florida, R. (2002) The Rise of the Creative Class.
pp. 31–56. New York: Basic Books.
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and Welch, I. Florida, R. (2005) The Flight of the Creative Class.
(1992) A theory of fads, fashion, custom, New York: Harper Collins.
and cultural change as informational cas- Florida, R. and Stolarick, K. (2005) Creativity,
cades, Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), connections and innovation: a study of link-
pp. 992–1026. ages in the Montreal region, Environment and
Boschma, R. A. (2005) Proximity and innovation: Planning A, 38, pp. 1799–1817.
a critical assessment, Regional Studies, 39(1), Frenken, K., Oort, F. G. van and Verburg, T. (2007)
pp. 61–74. Related variety, unrelated variety and regional
Boschma, R. A. and Fritsch, M. (2009) Creative economic growth, Regional Studies, 41(5),
class and regional growth: empirical evidence pp. 685–697.
URBAN AMENITIES   19

Gable, G. G. (1994) Integrating case study and survey Markusen, A. (2006) Urban development and
research methods: an example in information the politics of a creative class: evidence from
systems, European Journal of Information a study of artists, Environment and Planning
Systems, 3(2), pp. 112–126. A, 38(10), pp. 1921–1940.
Giuliani, E. (2007) The selective nature of knowl- Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics.
edge networks in clusters: evidence from the London: Macmillan.
wine industry, Journal of Economic Geography, Martinez, J. G. (2007) Selling avant-garde: how
7(2), pp. 139–168. Antwerp became a fashion capital (1990–2002),
Glaeser, E. (2005) Review of Richard Florida’s The Urban Studies, 44(12), pp. 2449–2464.
Rise of the Creative Class, Regional Science and McRobbie, A. (1998) British Fashion Design: Rag
Urban Economics, 35(5), pp. 593–596. Trade or Image Industry? New York: Routledge.
Glaeser, E., Kallal, H., Scheinkman, J. and Shliefer, Morrison, A. (2008) Gatekeepers of knowledge
A. (1992) Growth of cities, Journal of Political within industrial districts: who they are,
Economy, 100, pp. 1126–1152. how they interact, Regional Studies, 42(6),
Gordon, I. R. and McCann, P. (2000) Industrial pp. 817–835.
clusters: complexes, agglomeration and/or social Oort, F. G. van, Weterings, A. and Verlinde, H.
networks?, Urban Studies, 37, pp. 513–532. (2003) Residential amenities of knowledge
Gottlieb, P. D. (1995) Residential amenities, firm workers and the location of ICT firms in The
location and economic development, Urban Netherlands, Journal of Economic and Social
Studies, 32, pp. 1413–1436. Geography, 94, pp. 516–523.
Hauge, A. and Hracs, B. J. (2010) See the sound, Parr, J. B. (2002) Agglomeration economies:
hear the style: collaborative linkages between ambiguities and confusions, Environment and
Indie musicians and fashion designers in Planning A, 34, pp. 717–731.
local scenes, Industry and Innovation, 17(1), Peck, J. (2005) Struggling with the creative class,
pp. 113–129. International Journal of Urban and Regional
Hite, J. M. and Hesterley, W. S. (2001) The evo- Research, 29(4), pp. 740–770.
lution of firm networks: from emergence to Porter, M. J. (2000) Locations, clusters and com-
early growth of the firm, Strategic Management pany strategy, in: G. L. Clark, M. S. Gertler and
Journal, 22(3), pp. 275–286. M. P. Feldman (Eds) The Oxford Handbook of
Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R. (1993) Economic Geography, pp. 253–274. Oxford:
Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers Oxford University Press.
as evidenced by patent citations, Quarterly Journal Power, D. and Hauge, A. (2008) No man’s brand:
of Economics, 108(3), pp. 577–598. brands, institutions, and fashion, Growth and
Klepper, S. (2002) The capabilities of new firms Change, 39(1), pp. 123–143.
and the evolution of the U.S. automobile Raes, S. (2000) Migrating Enterprise and Migrant
industry, Industrial and Corporate Change, Entrepreneurship: How Fashion and Migration
11(4), pp. 645–666. Have Changed the Spatial Organisation of
Klepper, S. (2007) Disagreements, spinoffs, and Clothing Supply in The Netherlands, Amsterdam:
the evolution of Detroit as the capital of the Het Spinhuis Publishers.
U.S. automobile industry, Management Science, Rantisi, N. M. (2002) The local innovation system
53(4), pp. 616–631. as a source of ‘variety’: openness and adapt-
Klepper, S. and Sleeper, S. (2005) Entry by spinoffs, ability in New York city’s garment district,
Management Science, 51(8), pp. 1291–1306. Regional Studies, 36(6), pp. 587–602.
Kloosterman, R. C. (2004) Recent employment Rantisi, N. M. (2004) The ascendance of New
trends in the cultural industries in Amsterdam, York fashion, International Journal of Urban
Rotterdam, The Hague and Utrecht: a first and Regional Research, 28(1), pp. 86–106.
exploration, Tijdschrift voor Economische en Reimer, S. and Leslie, D. (2008) Design, national
Sociale Geografie, 95(2), pp. 243–252. imaginaries, and the home furnishings commod-
Malem, W. (2008) Fashion designers as business: ity chain, Growth and Change, 39(1), pp. 144–171.
London, Journal of Fashion Marketing and Roso, M. (2005) Modevormgeving in Nederland:
Management, 12(3), pp. 398–414. de ontbrekende bruggen tussen creatie en
20   RIK WENTING ET AL.

commercie. Premsela Stichting voor Nederlandse embeddedness, Administrative Science Quarterly,


Vormgeving, Amsterdam (in Dutch). 42(1), pp. 35–67.
Scott, A. J. (1996) The craft, fashion, and cultural- Uzzi, B. and Spiro, J. (2005) Collaboration and
products industries of Los Angeles: competitive creativity: the small world problem, American
dynamics and policy dilemmas in a multisec- Journal of Sociology, 111(2), pp. 447–504.
toral image-producing complex, Annals of the Vinodrai, T. (2006) Reproducing Toronto’s design
Association of American Geographers, 86(2), ecology: career paths, intermediaries, and local
pp. 306–323. labor markets, Economic Geography, 82(3), pp.
Scott, A. J. (2000) The Cultural Economy of Cities. 237–263.
London: Sage. Wasserman, S. and Faust, K. (1994) Social Network
Scott, A. J. (2002) Competitive dynamics of Analysis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge:
Southern California’s clothing industry: Cambridge University Press.
the widening global connection and its Weller, S. (2007) Fashion as viscous knowledge:
local ramifications, Urban Studies, 39(8), fashion’s role in shaping trans-national garment
pp. 1287–1306. production, Journal of Economic Geography,
Scott, A. J. (2006) Entrepreneurship, innovation 7(1), pp. 39–66.
and industrial development: geography and Wenting, R. (2008) Spinoff dynamics and the
the creative field revisited, Small Business spatial formation of the global fashion design
Economics, 26, pp. 1–24. industry, 1858–2005, Journal of Economic
Sorenson, O. (2003) Social networks and industrial Geography, 8(5), pp. 593–614.
geography, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Wenting, R. and Frenken, K. (2007) Firm
13, pp. 513–527. entry and institutional lock-in: an organiza-
Storper, M. and Manville, M. (2006) Behaviour, tional ecology analysis of the global fashion
preferences and cities: urban theory and urban design industry. Papers on Economics and
resurgence, Urban Studies, 43(8), pp. 1247–1274. Evolution No. 0714, Max Planck Institute
Storper, M. and Venables, A. J. (2004) Buzz: face- of Economics.
to-face contact and the urban economy, Journal Wenting, R., Atzema, O. and Frenken, K. (2006)
of Economic Geography, 4, pp. 351–370. Modeontwerp en ondernemerschap. Profielen,
Uzzi, B. (1997) Social structure and competi- plaatsen en prestaties. Utrecht: Universiteit
tion in inter-firm networks: the paradox of Utrecht (in Dutch).

You might also like