You are on page 1of 4

Economists usually oppose price

controls for a few key reasons:


1. Cause shortages or surpluses

Price controls like price ceilings (maximum legal prices) prevent prices from reaching the
natural market equilibrium that balances supply and demand. This causes shortages, excess
demand and usually black markets. Price floors (minimum prices) cause surpluses and excess
supply piling up if set above equilibrium.

1. Reduce incentives and efficiency

Price controls hamper incentives for producers to supply enough output to meet demand, by
not allowing them to receive market prices. This reduces economic efficiency, as the
allocation of resources in the economy is interfered with by the control.

1. Don't address underlying causes

Price controls only target the symptom (prices) rather than the underlying causes like high
costs or monopoly power. They can hide the source issues in an economy that better policy
and deregulation could solve over time.

1. Difficult to enforce

Applying, monitoring and enforcing price controls extensively is challenging for the
government. This can lead to black market trade undermining the control.

Instead most economists argue that free market prices, with appropriate competition
regulation and lighter handed policies, lead to superior economic outcomes. Hence they
usually oppose direct price control intervention except perhaps temporarily in extreme
situations like wars.

Why Do not two indifference


curves intersect each other ?
two indifference curves cannot intersect each other due to the assumption in consumer
preference theory of convex preferences and non-satiation. Here are the reasons why
indifference curves cannot intersect:

1. Indifference curves represent combinations of goods or baskets that provide the


consumer equal satisfaction and utility. A higher indifference curve yields higher utility.
2. If two indifference curves intersected, it would imply a contradiction - that two different
baskets provide the same utility at the intersection point.
3. For example, Basket A on indifference curve IC1 and Basket B on IC2 intersect at point P.
If the consumer is indifferent between A and B, it violates the assumption that IC2 lies
above IC1 and should yield higher utility.
4. The non-satiation assumption states that more of a good is always preferred. Convex
preference assumption states that consumers have diminishing rates of substitution
along an indifference curve.
5. These assumptions mean indifference curves have diminishing slopes and represent
progressively higher utility, preventing intersections between them for a rational
consumer.

In essence, intersecting indifference curves violate the premises consumer preference theory
is built on by implying equivalent preference between unequal baskets. This cannot occur
with rational, optimizing economic agents that have convex, continuous, non-satiated
preferences.

A Tax that has no deadweight loss


Cannot generate any revenue for
the government is a stat explain
why or why not?
his statement is false. A tax that has no deadweight loss can still generate tax revenue for the
government.

The key reasons are:

1. Lump-sum taxes have no deadweight loss: A lump-sum tax is a fixed dollar amount per
person that does not change behavior. Since people pay the same regardless of
decisions, there is no excess burden or deadweight loss created. Yet, it does provide
revenue.
2. Revenue is still collected: Just because a tax does not lead to economic inefficiency does
not mean no tax is paid. With lump-sum taxes, the full tax amount charged is collected as
revenue for the government even though it does not affect behavior.
3. No excess burden ≠ No tax: Deadweight loss measures the net loss of consumer and
producer surplus from reduced output/consumption. If there is no behavioral change and
thus no loss of surplus, deadweight loss is zero. But the actual tax revenues transferred
to the government can still be substantial.

So in essence - it is possible and common for efficient taxes with no deadweight costs to still
generate tax revenue. The key is they do not disturb economic decisions at the margin while
raising funds. Therefore, the statement is incorrect. Taxes without deadweight loss can and
often do generate revenue.

Explain relationship between


slope of the Demand and the price
of elasticity?
There is an inverse relationship between the slope of a demand curve and the price elasticity
of demand. Here is the connection:

1. Price elasticity of demand measures the percentage change in quantity demanded in


response to a 1 percent change in price.
2. Demand curves that are relatively flatter (more horizontal) have larger price elasticities.
This means quantity demanded changes more significantly when price changes.
3. Steeper demand curves (more vertical) have smaller elasticities. This indicates quantity
does not change much with a price variation.
4. The slope of a demand curve at a point is equal to the inverse of the elasticity at that
point (Slope = -1/Ed).
5. Intuitively, flatter curves allow quantity to change more freely in response to price
changes compared to steeper curves where quantity is restricted and cannot vary much.

In essence, the inverse slope of a demand curve reflects the sensitivity of quantity to price
changes - perfectly captured by the price elasticity.

what are some key economic


problems associated with public
goods?
1. Free-rider problem: Public goods are non-excludable, meaning it is difficult to prevent
people from using/benefiting from them even if they don't pay. This creates an incentive
for people to free ride and not contribute towards paying for public goods.
2. Underprovision: Since people have an incentive to free ride, there tends to be
underprovision of public goods in a pure market economy. The non-excludability makes it
difficult to charge people, so private companies lack incentives to provide enough public
goods.
3. Overuse: Rival public goods that are non-excludable can lead to problems of overuse or
overconsumption, such as traffic congestion on public roads. Since access is open to all
and unrestricted, demand exceeds optimal supply.
4. High production costs: The characteristics of public goods like non-rivalry and non-
excludability make them difficult and costly to produce for private firms looking to make
profits. This is why public goods are usually provided by the government using taxpayer
money.

You might also like