You are on page 1of 11

REVIEW ARTICLE

Not created equal: Institutional constraints


and the democratic peace
________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________

Matthew S. Dabrosa and Mark W. Petersenb


a
Assistant Professor of Political Science, Western Connecticut State University, 181 White Street,
Danbury, CT, USA.
E-mail: dabrosm@wcsu.edu
b
Assistant Professor of Political Science, Bethany College, Bethany, West Virginia, USA.
E-mail: mpetersen@bethanywv.edu
Abstract | A prominent explanation for the democratic peace is that democracies are by institutional
design less likely to go to war than autocracies. In this review essay of the institutional constraints
literature, we draw on research in comparative politics and other disciplines to suggest there is more
intra-regime variation than generally accounted for by standard theories, encouraging scholars to
revisit how constraints have been conceptualized. The prowess some democrats display in
circumventing constitutional restrictions or shaping public opinion, and the ability of certain groups
to limit autocrats’ actions, may have a significant impact on executive power in war, and we suggest
that exploring these potential sources of variation in future research will lead to a more nuanced
understanding of the relationship between regime type and interstate conflict.
International Politics Reviews (2013) 1, 27–36. doi:10.1057/ipr.2013.5
Keywords: institutional constraints; democratic peace; regime type

Introduction draw on research in comparative politics, economics and


It has become axiomatic that democracies initiate military communications to suggest there is a greater degree of
conflicts against each other less frequently than auto- intra-regime variation than accounted for by standard the-
cracies. Several explanations have been offered for this ories, encouraging scholars to revisit how constraints have
empirical regularity, ranging from ideas about the pacific been conceptualized. In no way does our review call the
effects of dyadic interactions between democracies to the overarching premise of this research program into ques-
notion that domestic democratic norms restrain aggressive tion, as the evidence that institutional constraints limit
international behavior. Another possibility that has gained democrats’ ability to wage war is overwhelming. Instead,
prominence in recent years is that institutional constraints we are suggesting how much these constraints matter likely
make it difficult for democratic leaders to mobilize their transcends the democracy–autocracy continuum, and we
countries’ resources for war, relative to autocrats. propose that exploring this possibility in future research
In this review essay, we evaluate the institutional con- will lead to the development of a more nuanced under-
straints literature, focusing on how well it captures the standing of the relationship between regime type and war.
within-regime dynamics of executive constraint in war. We Given the shakeup of many longstanding autocracies by

INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEWS IPR | VOLUME 1 SEPTEMBER 2013 27


| |
© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Dabros and Petersen

the disparate Arab Spring movement, how institutions more easily able to wage war than democrats. Other poli-
matter across democratic, hybrid and autocratic regimes tical and economic elites are the only actors who poten-
has seldom been more salient in world politics. This is tially possess the resources and authority to challenge their
especially true, given the risk of war posed by emerging policies, but by securing elite support leaders are able to
democracies (Mansfield and Snyder, 2002, 2007, 2009). acquire broad authority over military affairs.
Autocrats obtain elite approval in a relatively simple
manner: by using their authority over government expen-
Institutional Constraints: Theoretical Rationale ditures to provide private goods (Bueno de Mesquita et al,
The central theoretical premise in the literature is that a 1999), perhaps in the form of lucrative business contracts,
leader’s ability to wage war is conditioned by domestic jobs, tax breaks or government subsidies. Providing these
political structures. Leaders have a high level of control goods not only increases the likelihood executives will be
over military affairs in non-democracies that place few supported in their war efforts, but also reduces the prob-
restrictions on executive actions, and leaders have com- ability that elites will remove them from office in the event
paratively less authority in democracies with electoral of military defeat. However, as Maoz and Russett (1993)
competition, universal suffrage, multiple power centers observe, ‘once the support of [these] key legitimizing
(for example, legislatures, viable party systems) and other groups is secured, the government can launch its policy
constraints on executive power. The basis for this idea is with little regard to public opinion or for due political pro-
found in Kant’s (1795/1932) famous essay on Perpetual cess’ (p.626). Wars can be initiated quickly, so long as
Peace, and its modern version began to take shape in the elites – the main constraint on executive power – have
now seminal pieces by Small and Singer (1976) and given their consent.
Rummel (1979, 1983). A large number of books and arti- Democratic executives must overcome a more varied set
cles have since addressed this proposition (for example, of constraints in their pursuit of military action. This does
Morgan and Campbell, 1991; Bueno de Mesquita and not mean that elites can no longer pressure leaders, only
Lalman, 1992; Maoz and Russett, 1993; Fearon, 1994; that the factors that limit executive power have multiplied.
Bueno de Mesquita and Siverson, 1995; Bueno de Electoral competition is perhaps the most obvious con-
Mesquita et al, 1999; Lai and Slater, 2006; Mansfield and straint in democracies (Morgan and Campbell, 1991; Reiter
Snyder, 2007), and though these authors each offer a and Tillman, 2002), and as citizens exercise the ultimate
unique take on the basic theory, their ideas are similar in sanction over politicians – removal from office – execu-
many respects. In this section, we describe standard the- tives must convince them that their policies are the right
ories of institutional constraints, although the reader should policies. This is particularly true in instances of military
be aware that nuances among scholars have been omitted. conflict, where citizens bear the largest burdens (for exam-
Many theories start by making assumptions typical of ple, as soldiers). Leaders must persuade them that war is
rationally based understandings of political behavior, spe- the correct policy choice, either made necessary by cir-
cifically that executives are utility maximizers whose pri- cumstance or as one that promises to provide long-term
mary objective other than retaining office is determining benefits. This is a difficult decision for citizens to make,
public policy (see especially Bueno de Mesquita and and they are often reluctant to accept that military conflict
Siverson, 1995; Bueno de Mesquita et al, 1999). Their is unavoidable. Incumbents who spurn popular preferences
ability to reach this goal is subject to a vector of institu- on military matters and plow ahead with hawkish policies
tional constraints, which defines how much authority they run the considerable risk of electoral defeat, especially
have over public policy. Within the foreign policy context, when political opponents are proposing more pacific
there are a number of potential factors that might limit their action.
ability to mobilize resources for war, but four have stood The idea that democratic executives are susceptible to
out within the literature: the ability of elites to overthrow electoral competition gives rise to a related constraint on
the executive, the level of electoral competition, the fre- executive power, namely, that the timing of elections affect
quency of elections and the amount of power wielded by the likelihood they will pursue military conflict (Stoll,
other political institutions. 1984; Gaubatz, 1991; Miller, 1995; Smith, 1996; Leblang
The effects these factors have on executive war initia- and Chan, 2003). Unlike autocrats, whose positions are
tion depend on whether a country is autocratic or demo- never challenged by the electoral process, democrats must
cratic. Certain combinations of constraints allow leaders to be particularly careful of going to war immediately before
initiate conflict with minimal fear their power will be chal- an election (Gaubatz, 1991). Executives know that initiat-
lenged, whereas other combinations prevent them from ing conflict at the same time the public is deciding whether
acting militarily without consulting other political actors. to retain them in office will not bode well politically if the
In particular, the absence of institutionalized forms of decision proves unpopular; hence, they expend consider-
popular control in non-democracies means autocrats are able effort avoiding war under these circumstances. Once

| |
28 SEPTEMBER 2013 VOLUME 1 www.palgrave-journals.com/ipr

© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved


Not created equal

the election cycle has been successfully weathered, how- existence and timing of electoral competition and the
ever, incumbents have leeway to order military strikes, influence of other governing institutions will generate two
knowing that there is time to justify their actions before the types of executive behavior in conflict situations, one each
next election. Nevertheless, even at this stage, that next for autocrats and democrats. Autocrats in countries without
election looms in democrats’ minds, forcing them to weigh electoral competition or a meaningful division of powers
more carefully than autocrats the costs and benefits of will cater to elite demands in the form of private goods, and
interstate conflict. their corresponding latitude in military matters will be
The dispersion of power within and between branches high. Democratic leaders required to share power and
of government imposes a third noticeable limitation on compete in regular, free and fair elections must consider
executive power in democratic systems (Morgan and how the public and other institutions will respond to war
Campbell, 1991; Kaarbo, 1996; Clark, 2000; Ireland and initiation, generally finding that their authority over these
Gartner, 2001; Reiter and Tillman, 2002; Palmer et al, matters is limited. Wars launched without due considera-
2004). With respect to the distribution of authority across tion for these political actors never occur in democracies,
institutions, at least in presidential systems, the fact that or at least only rarely, because executives who act uni-
each branch of government is responsible for different laterally are removed from office or otherwise restrained.
aspects of statecraft creates constitutional and practical
limitations on the power of a single individual. In particular,
executives are often required to obtain the approval of Institutional Constraints: The Empirical Evidence
other political officials before proceeding with military There is a large body of empirical evidence to support these
activities (see, especially, Morgan and Campbell, 1991). The theories of institutional constraints, as well as the larger
president of the United States might be commander-in-chief democratic peace proposition (Chan, 1984; Benoit, 1996;
of the armed forces, for example, but the decision to raise Cederman and Rao, 2001; for reviews of specific find-
an army and declare war theoretically rests with Congress; ings, see Ray, 1995; Chan, 1997; Maoz, 1998).1 These
further powers were delegated to the legislature with the findings are generally robust regardless of the time period
passage of the War Powers Resolution of 1973, again in under investigation, sample composition or research
theory. Congressional authority in military matters, especially method, and they remain strong even when control vari-
as it pertains to financing, may encourage the president ables that might mitigate the impact of institutional con-
to listen to and at times negotiate with House and Senate straints (for example, major power status or shared borders
leaders. This negotiation process might find the president with non-democracies; Reiter and Tillman, 2002) are
attempting non-military solutions or agreeing to limit the included in the analysis. For example, in their examination
scope, means and duration of the dispute. of 37 democratic countries between 1919 and 1992, Reiter
In parliamentary systems, the frequent necessity of coa- and Tillman (2002) determined that war initiation varied
lition governments and the corresponding diffusion of inversely with electoral competition, and Prins and Sprecher
power across several political parties with seats in the leg- (1999) found that the separation of powers limited executive
islature likewise checks executive authority. Plans for authority in their study of Western Parliamentary democ-
military action must be vetted through many competing racies between 1946 and 1989; these results are consistent
interests, any one of whom may have incentives to prevent with those of Ireland and Gartner (2001; 18 countries
hostilities. A key member of a coalition government known between 1917 and 1990), Leblang and Chan (2003; 24
for its pacific nature may refuse to support military action, interstate conflicts between 1946 and 2000) and Elman
for example, and its threats to withdraw from the governing (2000; case studies between 1800 and the late 1900s).
alliance may compel its partners to rethink their foreign The literature has not yet reached consensus on how
policy positions. strongly these mechanisms constrain executive power in
The ability of minor parties to check executive power war. Whereas Ireland and Gartner (2001) suggest that coa-
declines markedly in two-party states, of course, but lition and majority governments participate in conflicts in
opposition parties retain some authority. Opposition parties similar amounts, with minority governments participating
provide alternatives to the status quo, and a majority of the least, Prins and Sprecher (1999) find coalitions partake
parliamentary systems allow them to force elections when in one and a half times more interstate disputes than single-
they believe the party in power no longer retains the con- party governments (p.282). Leblang and Chan (2003), on
fidence of the population. Realizing that opposition leaders the other hand, find no real conflict differences between
represent an ever-present threat to their power, parliamen- types of democratic government. They argue, too, that the
tary leaders ensure that they have broad-based political and timing of the election has no bearing on whether democrats
popular support before initiating hostilities. will enter a conflict, although Gaubatz (1991) provides
In short, standard theories of institutional constraints evidence to the contrary that executives are significantly
predict that elite threats to executive dominance, the less likely to start military disputes immediately before

INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEWS IPR | VOLUME 1 SEPTEMBER 2013 29


| |
© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Dabros and Petersen

national elections. For Leblang and Chan (2003), the key this assumption is incorrect in a major way: institutional
mechanism is proportional representation, which reduces variations that exist within democracies might prompt
the likelihood of war more than any other constraint in their executives in different types of democratic systems to
study. Note, however, that even though these studies dis- behave differently toward war (Morgan and Campbell,
agree about which mechanisms are most salient, they con- 1991; Mansfield and Snyder, 1995a, b, 2002; Elman,
cur that some combination of constraints genuinely restrain 2000; Ireland and Gartner, 2001; Reiter and Tillman,
a democrat’s ability to wage war. 2002; Leblang and Chan, 2003).
Nevertheless, the prevailing notion of authoritarian
regimes continues to be that meaningful constraints on
Rethinking Institutional Constraints executive power are largely nonexistent. Maoz and Russett
There is clear evidence of a systematic relationship captured the sentiments of a majority of democratic peace
between institutional constraints and executive authority in researchers when, in their seminal 1993 article, they wrote
war. Nevertheless, work done in comparative politics, that interstate conflict can most often be explained by ‘the
economics and communications raises questions about lack of structural constraints on the mobilization and esca-
how institutional constraints have been conceptualized by lation process of (non-democracies)’ and the tendency of
the institutional constraints literature, particularly as it per- autocracies to ‘operate under relatively few structural con-
tains to how strongly leaders in each regime type are straints’ (p.626). Few scholars then or since have ques-
restrained. First, the comparative literature on hybrid tioned Maoz and Russett on this point, and indeed much of
regimes highlights the strong possibility that limitations on the existing scholarship is based on the idea that autocrats
autocratic power are much greater than commonly are at most weakly constrained by elites within their own
acknowledged. Electoral competition and the separation of country, the possibility of mass uprising aside. Thus,
powers might not play the same role in autocracies and although the literature on how specific democratic pro-
hybrid regimes as they do in consolidated democracies, but cesses affect the likelihood of war is growing, the possibi-
where they exist, they encourage rulers to consider other lity that a similar situation exists in autocracies has
actors’ preferences before moving ahead with personal received little scholarly attention.
agendas; non-democratic mechanisms of restraint might Ongoing research in comparative politics has none-
also limit the range of actions autocrats can take. Second, theless demonstrated that qualitative, intra-regime varia-
research into the principal-agent problem indicates that the tions occur, especially among countries in transition from
institutional constraints literature may in some respects autocracy to democracy – an observation that has spawned
overestimate the level of constraint placed on executive a plethora of articles devoted to ‘hybrid regimes’, which
power. The existence of principal-agent problems in are defined as governments that manifest authoritarian as
democracies implies that executives might have wide lati- well as democratic characteristics (Schmitter and Karl,
tude to craft public policy, even in war, depending on the 1991; Karl, 1995; Collier and Levitsky, 1997; Diamond,
context and despite the nominal presence of institutiona- 2002; Levitsky and Way, 2002; Schedler, 2002; Van de
lized restraints. By raising these issues, we are not imply- Walle, 2002; Case, 2005; Klick, 2005; Wintrobe, 2007;
ing that the institutional constraints literature is incorrect; Hellwig and Samuels, 2008; Diamond, 2008). As Schmitter
rather, we contend institutions matter in democratic and and Karl (1991) state, ‘There are many types of democracy,
autocratic regimes in ways that have yet to be emphasized and their diverse practices produce a similarly varied set of
fully by the existing literature. More remains to be said effects. The specific form democracy takes is contingent
about how democrats might have less constraints and upon a country’s socioeconomic conditions as well as its
autocrats more constraints than is widely recognized. entrenched state structures and policy practices’ (p.76). This
is certainly true of non-democracies as well (see, for exam-
Undifferentiated autocrats and the homogeneity of ple, Geddes, 1999), and the varying institutional processes
regimes that exist in different types of non-democracies might
Similar to all rational choice perspectives on politics, stan- prompt executives to respond to similar situations in con-
dard theories of institutional constraints make homogeniz- trasting ways. What is more, as Carothers (2002) observes,
ing assumptions about the units being observed. This is to there should be no implicit expectation that these ‘hybrid
say that leaders of military juntas are expected to behave regimes’ are making their way from autocracy to democracy;
very similarly in war as rulers of one-party governments, rather, it is merely important to note that they are mixing
who are themselves presumed to act similarly to hereditary elements of both regime types and therefore their institutions
monarchs. In early conceptualizations of the theory, this are important and relevant in unique ways.
same principle was supposed to hold true with respect to A very small body of research focuses on how different
democracies (see Elman, 2000). However, as discussed types of autocrats might respond to potential international
above, a growing number of researchers have argued that disputes, acknowledging that some executives might be

| |
30 SEPTEMBER 2013 VOLUME 1 www.palgrave-journals.com/ipr

© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved


Not created equal

more limited in foreign affairs than others (Peceny et al, and those who proceed militarily may find themselves
2002; Butler and Peceny, 2003; Peceny and Butler, 2004; stripped of power.
Weeks, 2008). Nearly all of these articles concentrate on Systematic empirical research is needed to evaluate
how varying sizes of the ‘selectorate’ (see, for example, these statements, but at least one historical example – the
Bueno de Mesquita et al, 2003) in personalist dictatorships, downfall of the USSR’s Nikita Khrushchev – provides
one-party states and military dictatorships might induce anecdotal evidence for some of these points. For much of
executives to behave differently in war. The limited his reign, Khrushchev exercised substantial authority
research available suggests that one-party governments are within the Soviet Union, some opposition to his rule not-
the least conflict-prone of the three because a larger number withstanding (McClellan, 1998; MacKenzie and Curran,
of political actors hold power in these regimes (see espe- 2002; Dziewanowski, 2003). In mid-1962, in what is now
cially Peceny and Butler, 2004). These authors have made known as the Cuban Missile Crisis, Khrushchev ordered
significant improvements in our understanding of the ballistic missiles to be installed in Cuba. This and other
domestic processes that exist in authoritarian countries, but directives made during the subsequent crisis with the Uni-
they leave room for further exploration into which, when ted States were unilateral decisions, ordered by the incum-
and how domestic actors might exert their influence. This is bent without the knowledge or approval of influential
to say that a greater degree of attention needs to be given to political and military elites (Dziewanowski, 2003, pp.319–
the specific ways that authority is restrained in autocratic 321). Although elites were unable (or unwilling) to prevent
regimes. Khrushchev from bringing the USSR to the brink of war at
One obvious constraint on executive power in an auto- the time, his bungling of the situation led them to assert
cracy is the elites. The constraining effects of elite groups their influence not long after. Citing ‘wild schemes; half-
has been acknowledged by nearly all proponents of the baked conclusions and hasty decisions and actions
institutional argument as the key mechanism of executive divorced from reality; bragging and bluster; attraction to
control, of course, but rarely does their influence receive rule by fiat’ and other qualities unbecoming of a leader, the
much additional consideration. In fact, superficial com- party elites removed Khrushchev from power in October,
ments to the contrary, elite interests are infrequently treated 1964 (Pravda, quoted in Dziewanowski, 2003, pp.327–
as noteworthy restraints on executive power. All dictators 328). Khrushchev presumably proved unable to assuage
have to do is buy them off with private goods in order for elite anger through private goods, and even though other
their ultimate control over the war-making process to be factors were present, there is little doubt his end-run around
assured, according to much of the literature. elite preferences during the Cuban Missile Crisis was a
Intuitively, however, it is difficult to accept the idea that major reason for his political demise.
providing private goods is always enough to convince In addition to elite opposition, leaders from hybrid
elites to cede influence over the incumbent, especially in regimes often face constraints similar to those that exist in
matters of war, or that a leader will be able to glean the consolidated democracies. Although these constraints do
amount of goods required to secure their assent. It is an not have the same force as they do in established democ-
understatement that war is a serious matter for all those racies, they are institutions ‘through which opposition for-
involved, and even elites who might bear no direct invol- ces may periodically challenge, weaken, and occasionally
vement in the fighting have to consider whether the poten- even defeat autocratic incumbents’ (Levitsky and Way,
tial benefits of war outweigh the financial and political 2002, p.54). As Levitsky and Way (2002) point out, free
risks. We might expect elite groups to impose constraints and regular elections are commonly held in non-democ-
on the executive when they conclude that war is unneces- racies, and though they may not be entirely fair or untain-
sary or unworthy of the risks, even when private goods are ted, their outcomes are sometimes in doubt. As in
being offered. Particularly if these elites are military or consolidated democracies, it stands to reason the prob-
political officials whose support is crucial, the chances that ability an incumbent will suffer electoral defeat is heigh-
they will successfully restrain autocratic prerogatives may tened when war is on the horizon. The population
be large. Similarly, it is difficult to imagine that the provi- recognizes that it will bear the brunt of interstate conflict
sion of private goods tends to persuade elites to overlook and may be more willing to vote for opposition candidates
military defeat and retain the executive. Young men and under these circumstances, especially if such individuals
women have died, assets have been wasted, the country’s are promoting anti-war platforms. As autocrats often want
standing in international affairs has been damaged and the to retain the pretense of legitimacy by winning elections,
leader has failed to prove himself/herself militarily. Con- they might therefore pursue more peaceful policies. Lea-
sidering the implications these circumstances might have ders bent on pursuing hawkish agendas can, of course,
on the country, a larger number of goods than are available bypass public opinion by rigging the election, but this car-
may be needed for elites to absolve the leader of policy ries substantial risks. Incumbents who ‘win’ elections
failures. Incumbents likely recognize this possibility exists, despite intense opposition may quickly succumb to popular

INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEWS IPR | VOLUME 1 SEPTEMBER 2013 31


| |
© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Dabros and Petersen

pressure and be forced from office, as the political uphea- information about incumbent actions, especially in less-
vals that occurred in Peru, Mexico and elsewhere during developed democracies. Few television and radio stations,
the late 1900s and early 2000s illustrate. low levels of newspaper circulation, high illiteracy rates
Levitsky and Way (2002) also observe that though in and extensive mass apathy toward politics all limit the
hybrid regimes the legislature’s purpose may be to rubber information available to a country’s population. This
stamp executive decisions, ‘they occasionally become makes it difficult in the aggregate for citizens to uncover
focal points of opposition activity’, especially as multiple the details of domestic and foreign policies or judge how
political parties are often represented in the chamber well their executive is behaving. Even when this informa-
(p.56). Although legislators may not have the legal tion is ostensibly available, citizens must be able to obtain
authority to prevent an autocrat from imposing a preferred and process the material if they are to make informed
policy, they may be able to reveal its weaknesses, offer judgments about executive performance – for instance, by
alternatives or encourage the public to protest its passage. purchasing and reading a newspaper. In cases of foreign
Hence, in the prelude to war especially, they may be will- policy crises, citizens must also have enough information
ing to speak out against the conflict, pass resolutions con- to reach a decision on its severity and the necessity of
demning aggressive action or otherwise emphasize that war military action.
is not their preferred choice. Faced with such political These observations suggest that executives consider
hostility, executives may be more cautious in foreign citizen knowledge levels before establishing public policy.
affairs, including when pursuing policies that might lead to Research into redistributive politics, for instance, demon-
interstate conflict. strates that incumbents provide more public goods in high-
In summary, the ability of elite groups and other poli- information societies rather than low, presumably because
tical institutions to restrain executive power suggests, in they worry politically conscious citizens will equate low
theory at least, that autocrats must overcome larger num- levels of goods with poor executive performance (Besley
bers of political constraints in their pursuit of interstate war and Burgess, 2002; Adsera et al, 2003; Stromberg, 2004).
than has heretofore been explored in the literature. A similar decision-making calculus is likely at work in the
Depending on the circumstances, executives may be unable foreign policy arena, with democrats in low-information
to muster the political support needed to initiate hostilities, societies less constrained in military affairs than those
and, even when they are able to, enough time may have whose citizens are more aware of politics. Specifically,
passed for peaceful solutions to emerge. Scholars wishing executives gauge how much information the population
to increase the power of their models will likely find by has about foreign events and decide based on this assess-
taking into account these finer differences among similar- ment whether and how to proceed with military action.
type regimes, they can provide more detailed explanations Citizens receive less consideration when information is
of how, when and why institutions matter. hard to come by than when it is widely distributed. In the
case of low-information democracies, leaders know that
Democrats and the principal-agent problem citizens are mainly ignorant of foreign events and they are
The idea from economics that agents will seek ways to able to use this fact to exercise independent control over
undermine their principals has been extended to a host of military affairs. When information is freely available and
political relationships (Weingast, 1984; Kalt and Zupan, citizens are more knowledgeable about foreign events, on
1990; Songer et al, 1994). Much research focuses on the the other hand, incumbents have to be especially careful
implications of this behavior, as well as how citizen- about when and how they choose to launch interstate dis-
principals can craft mechanisms that alert them to when putes. They must take time to discuss the nature of the
political agents are acting self-interestedly. That principal- conflict, the pitfalls of peaceful alternatives and the justifi-
agent problems occur in executive handling of foreign and cation for war, lest their disregard for public opinion
domestic affairs has been recognized by numerous scho- imperil their electoral prospects.
lars, but the idea has yet to be fully integrated into the dis- To be clear, we are not implying that leaders are some-
cussion of institutional constraints and the likelihood of how able to hide interstate disputes from the population, in
war. This section focuses on how principal-agent effects high- or low-information societies. Instead, what this
manifest themselves in democracies and perhaps afford argument suggests is that the types of actions executives
executives broader authority in war than is captured by can take, and how quickly, varies according to the level of
theories of institutional constraints. information citizens have about a given issue. Democratic
A major way that principal-agent problems arise in any executives likely behave differently depending on how
country – democratic or autocratic – is in the flow of well informed the public is of foreign affairs. The less
information received by citizens (Keefer and Khemani, information the population has, the faster and more
2003, 2004). As these authors point out, there are many frequently incumbents can initiate military action; the
barriers that preclude the population from receiving reliable more informed, the longer the waiting period. Even in

| |
32 SEPTEMBER 2013 VOLUME 1 www.palgrave-journals.com/ipr

© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved


Not created equal

high-information societies, however, mass ignorance of public’s understanding of international events. In a tele-
certain events at a minimum allows executives to give vised speech given in early August 1964, President John-
quick approval to quasi-military operations. In the United son advised citizens that the North Vietnamese had
States, for instance, most citizens were likely unaware of launched an unprovoked attack on two US naval vessels
clandestine CIA forays into Pakistan, Western Europe and sailing in the Gulf of Tonkin. There was again no con-
elsewhere in search of suspected terrorists, at least until the clusive evidence that an attacked had commenced, but as in
information found its way into the mainstream media. By the case of the Maine, the executive failed to mention these
that time, however, several missions had already been ambiguities. Instead, Johnson used a potential attack on US
undertaken. troops to rally initial support for what became the Vietnam
Executives consider not only the amount of material War, with the ensuing Gulf of Tonkin Resolution accord-
available to citizens, but also their control over the dis- ing him wide powers in dealing with North Vietnamese
semination of foreign policy and military information. A ‘aggression’ (Tindall and Shi, 2004, pp.1122–1123).
leading theory of media politics suggests that journalistic Although public support for the war was ephemeral at best,
coverage of foreign affairs is ‘indexed’ to those in power: the fact remains that a skewed presentation of events was
the more power these actors have over a given policy sphere, what allowed the conflict to escalate.
the greater the attention their perspective receives from the Perhaps the most well-known example of a US pre-
media (Hallin, 1986; Bennett, 1990; Zaller and Chiu, 1996; sident using his control of the news to ‘sell’ war in recent
Livingstone and Bennett, 2003; Bennett et al, 2006; Bennett memory is the 2003 US-led invasion of Iraq. As docu-
et al, 2007). In foreign policy matters such as war, execu- mented by Bennett et al (2007), the Bush Administration’s
tives – not legislators or other officeholders – dominate media blitz began in mid-September 2002. For the next
media coverage because they are the ones who receive the several months, administration officials wove a grim tale
latest intelligence briefings and have direct responsibility for about the dire consequences that would befall the United
overseeing interstate disputes, who can provide reporters States should it fail to challenge Saddam Hussein’s pursuit
with the most salient information on military matters and of weapons of mass destruction. Said Secretary of Defense
who can blacklist journalists who portray them unflatter- Rumsfeld, ‘Imagine a September 11 with weapons of mass
ingly (see especially Bennett et al, 2007). Opposition view- destruction. It’s not 3000, it’s tens of thousands of innocent
points never receive much attention according to indexing men, women, and children’ and Secretary of State Rice,
theory – in some instances being harshly stifled – and, ulti- ‘We don’t want the smoking gun to be a mushroom cloud’
mately, the public perceives the conflict almost exclusively (as quoted in Bennett et al, 2007, p.19). The public now
through the lens of the executive office. realizes the evidence provided in support of these state-
Incumbents are able to use their control over press cov- ments was incomplete, patently false or disputed by intel-
erage of foreign affairs to shape public opinion and to ligence experts, but at the time it was presented to the
understand international disputes. This appears to be a American people as fact by trusted political figures who
time-honored tradition in autocracies as well as democ- knew differently. Whether this evidence was concocted to
racies, including in such consolidated democracies as the justify an interstate conflict many years in the making, as
United States. Following the destruction of the US warship some commentators have suggested (Bennett et al, 2007),
Maine on 15 February 1898, for instance, warmongers in or the unintended consequence of policy failures that
the McKinley administration either allowed or encouraged inexplicably emerged from an administration’s earnest
journalists to affix blame for the accident on Spain, even desire to protect its citizens is a matter for historians to
though the ship’s captain expressly cautioned against such decide. However, whatever the reason, the information
attribution. Commented Assistant Secretary of the Navy used to rally public support for the invasion is another
Theodore Roosevelt, the destruction was ‘an act of dirty illustration of how an executive can successfully circum-
treachery on the part of the Spaniards’, later saying ‘we vent key constraints on his power.
will have this war for the freedom of Cuba …’ (as cited in Within the context of the institutional constraints litera-
Tindall and Shi, 2004, pp.760–761). Although Roosevelt ture, an obvious objection to indexing theory is that even if
had no direct evidence that the Spanish were responsible the executive is somehow able to mislead the public by
for the sinking, these and other comments gave citizens controlling the media, political opponents will nevertheless
what turned out to be the mistaken impression that the find ways to meaningfully challenge hawkish policies and
United States had fallen victim to a sneak attack by a for- prevent the country from moving toward war. Perhaps
eign nation. Hence, when war came, it was with the support legislation will be introduced in the legislature prohibiting
of a large segment of the population. military action or maybe political allies will withdraw their
Half a century later, in a situation similar to the support; there is a long list of possibilities. However, as
destruction of the Maine, the US executive branch was Bennett et al (2007) point out, history again indicates that
again able to use its control of the media to affect the these possibilities do not always materialize or are swiftly

INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEWS IPR | VOLUME 1 SEPTEMBER 2013 33


| |
© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Dabros and Petersen

quashed by the incumbent. Recall that of the relatively few competition and other institutions limit their actions, hawks
officials who rallied against US military action in Iraq, will take the steps necessary (such as those described
most were quickly and severely punished by the adminis- above) to overcome opposition to their foreign policy
tration. Once Senator Ted Kennedy claimed that the Bush preferences.
administration had skewed intelligence on Iraq, he was In summary, the nature of the principal-agent relation-
‘quickly dismissed by the Republican rapid-response net- ship may mean that democrats are less constrained than
works as a traitorous liberal throwback’ (Bennett et al, theories of institutional constraints typically allow. Speci-
2007, p.18); Senator Richard Durbin was ridiculed by the fically, research in economics and communications sug-
administration’s allies and forced to apologize after com- gests executives are able to use citizen ignorance and
paring the tragedy of Abu Ghraib with the Nazis torture control over the media to their advantage as they make
machine; and CIA operative Valerie Plame’s identity was decisions regarding war. Leaders first consider their perso-
compromised soon after her husband, Ambassador Joseph nal preferences toward executive power and war, assess
Wilson, criticized the administration’s justification for war. whether other political officials have the authority to chal-
The message was obvious: public opposition to the Iraq lenge the favored position, judge how well citizens are able
War on the part of political officials would not be tolerated to evaluate performances and evaluate how risky opportu-
by the Bush administration. By responding in these and nistic behavior would be to their careers. Decisions about
similar ways, executives are able to silence in practice war are then made accordingly. There are certainly intra-
those officials whose power is equivalent to them in theory regime differences in the opportunities an executive has to
(Bennett et al, 2007). exploit information barriers, as well as personal willingness
The public’s inability to be assured of a leader’s true to engage in self-interested behavior. Personal preferences
preferences for war is a third way that the principal-agent and information effects are both meaningful factors in an
relationship can affect executive behavior. It reasons poli- executive’s decision-making calculus; hence, even in the
ticians take office with preset dispositions about whether presence of a host of hypothetical constraints on executive
and how wars should be fought. The decision to go to war power, the principal-agent relationship may grant the
is often politically motivated, to be sure, but it is also executive expansive authority to initiate and manage inter-
influenced by their beliefs about the nature of their posi- national military disputes.
tion, what their responsibilities for protecting their citizens
entail and the utility of fighting in general. Some executives
are willing to accept that military action is a useful and Conclusion
justified policy choice based on these ideological princi- Research indicates that executives take domestic threats to
ples, whereas others maintain that war is an abhorrent pol- political power seriously as they evaluate the benefits of
icy used only as a last resort. starting wars, with democrats more restrained on these
These beliefs affect both incumbents’ policy positions issues than autocrats. However, the point we are making in
and how they behave during interstate disputes. There is an this review essay is that democratic and autocratic regimes
extensive literature on the US Congress, which examines are not homogenous. On the contrary, work done in com-
whether leaders maintain their ideological dispositions parative politics and other disciplines shows that regimes
while in office. The consensus is that ideological ‘shirking’ are dynamic, with governing structures that vary greatly
does not occur. Legislators vote in a manner consistent from one country to the next. Democrats are restrained by
with their stated ideological position throughout their electoral competition and the division of political powers,
careers, even in the final term when electoral threats are to be sure, but citizen ignorance and executive control over
nonexistent (Lott, 1987; Vanbeek, 1991; Lott and Davis, the media may nevertheless grant them expansive authority
1992; Kau and Rubin, 1993; Bender and Lott, 1996). over war. Autocrats may not have to subject themselves to
These articles provide some evidence that politicians take regular national elections or share authority with other
personal preferences into account as they make decisions, institutions, but elite preferences, quasi-electoral competi-
not always basing their behavior on how the public will tion and the ability of legislators and political parties to
respond. As it pertains to interstate war, therefore, we can protest aggressive military rhetoric might reduce the num-
expect ideology to impact whether an executive favors ber of policy opportunities available to incumbents.
military action, even in the presence of electoral competi- The implications of this review are twofold. First, in a
tion, the division of powers and other institutional con- research program that is built upon the notion that regime
straints. An incumbent who is by nature more favorable to type matters, variation within them must be taken ser-
war may pursue aggressive policies more quickly and with iously. It is not enough to note that liberal democracies do
less provocation than a pacifist, even though the constraints not fight each other and call it a day. If this were the case, it
are similar for both. Whereas those with less inclination would not matter if the democratic peace was produced
toward conflict might be satisfied with allowing electoral rationally, institutionally, culturally or otherwise. Clearly,

| |
34 SEPTEMBER 2013 VOLUME 1 www.palgrave-journals.com/ipr

© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved


Not created equal

it does matter, because policies are predicated on certain Although the institutional constraints argument has offered
sets of beliefs. Wilsonian idealism, for instance, might tremendous insights into why democracies go to war less
work if all that matters is democracy. However, if parti- frequently than autocracies, its conclusions about certain
cular institutions matter, if consensus matters, then recog- types of political behavior are at odds with other research
nizing empirical patterns presented by regime type is traditions. This review has highlighted two of these differ-
insufficient. ences, the presence of executive constraints in hybrid
Second, the above is especially true with respect to regimes and the existence of principal-agent effects in
recent additions to the club of democratized nations. Egypt, democracies, identifying instances where autocrats and
for instance, having overthrown its longstanding autocratic democrats alike maybe more or less restrained than current
leader, might now work toward democracy, might remain theories of institutional constraints suggest. The next step is
as a hybrid regime moving toward democracy (or in stasis) to explore what empirical conclusions arise when ideas
or may slide back into autocratic rule. However, to about the structure of hybrid regimes and the principal-
claim that Egypt would behave neatly based on a strict agent problem are incorporated into the notion of institu-
categorical definition of its regime type is far less likely tional constraints, as well as how these additions affect
than its foreign policy would be constrained, effectively or executive decision making in war.
not, by its new institutions. The same is true for the bevy of
states that follow in its wake.
Each country is different, and, even though there are Note
commonalities among them, variations in the nature, qual- 1 Widely cited critiques of the democratic peace proposi-
ity and quantity of institutionalized constraints might allow tion include Layne (1994), Spiro (1994), Farber and
executives in similar-type regimes to behave dissimilarly. Gowa (1997) and Rosato (2003).

References
Adsera, A., Boix, C. and Payne, M. (2003) Are you being served? Political Cederman, L. and Rao, M.P. (2001) Exploring the dynamics of the democratic
accountability and quality of government. The Journal of Law, Economics, peace. The Journal of Conflict Resolution 45(6): 818–833.
and Organizations 19(2): 445–490. Chan, S. (1984) Mirror, mirror, on the wall … are the freer countries more
Bender, B. and Lott, J.R. (1996) Legislator voting and shirking: A critical pacific? The Journal of Conflict Resolution 28(4): 617–648.
review of the literature. Public Choice 87(1–2): 67–100. Chan, S. (1997) In search of democratic peace: Problems and promise. Mer-
Bennett, W.L. (1990) Toward a theory of press-state relations in the United shon International Studies Review 41(1): 59–91.
States. Journal of Communication 40(2): 103–125. Clark, D.H. (2000) Agreeing to disagree: Domestic institutional con-
Bennett, W.L., Lawrence, R.G. and Livingstone, S. (2006) None dare call it gruence and U.S. dispute behavior. Political Research Quarterly 53(2):
torture: Indexing and the limits of press independence in the Abu Ghraib 375–400.
scandal. Journal of Communication 56(3): 467–485. Collier, D. and Levitsky, S. (1997) Democracy with adjectives: Conceptual
Bennett, W.L., Lawrence, R.G. and Livingstone, S. (2007) When the Press innovation in comparative research. World Politics 49(3): 430–451.
Fails: Political Power and the News Media from Iraq to Katrina. Chicago, Diamond, L. (2002) Thinking about hybrid regimes. Journal of Democracy 13
IL: University of Chicago Press. (2): 22–35.
Benoit, K. (1996) Democracies really are more pacific (in general): Reex- Diamond, L. (2008) The Spirit of Democracy. New York: Henry Holt.
amining regime type and war involvement. The Journal of Conflict Reso- Dziewanowski, M.K. (2003) Russia in the Twentieth Century. 6th edn. Upper
lution 40(4): 636–657. Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2002) The political economy of government Elman, M.F. (2000) Unpacking democracy: Presidentialism, parliamentarism,
responsiveness: Theory and evidence from India. The Quarterly Journal of and theories of democratic peace. Security Studies 9(4): 91–126.
Economics 117(4): 1415–1451. Farber, H.S. and Gowa, J. (1997) Common interests or common polities?
Bueno de Mesquita, B. and Lalman, D. (1992) War and Reason. New Haven, Reinterpreting the democratic peace. The Journal of Politics 59(2):
CT: Yale University Press. 393–417.
Bueno de Mesquita, B. and Siverson, R.M. (1995) War and the survival of Fearon, J.D. (1994) Domestic political audiences and the escalation of inter-
political leaders: A comparative study of regime types and political national disputes. American Political Science Review 88(3): 577–592.
accountability. American Political Science Review 89(4): 841–855. Gaubatz, K.T. (1991) Electoral cycles and war. Journal of Conflict Resolution
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R.M. and Smith, A. (1999) 35(2): 212–244.
An institutional explanation of the democratic peace. American Political Geddes, B. (1999) What do we know about democratization after twenty
Science Review 93(4): 791–807. years? Annual Review of Political Science 2(1): 115–144.
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R.M. and Morrow, J.D. (2003) Hallin, D.C. (1986) The Uncensored War: The Media and Vietnam. Berkley,
The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. CA: University of California Press.
Butler, C.K. and Peceny, M. (2003) Authoritarian regimes and inter- Hellwig, T. and Samuels, D. (2008) Electoral accountability and the variety of
national conflict. Paper presented at the 2003 Annual Meeting of the democratic regimes. British Journal of Political Science 38(1): 65–90.
European Consortium for Political Research; 18–21 September, Marburg, Ireland, M.J. and Gartner, S.S. (2001) Time to fight: Government type and
Germany. conflict initiation in parliamentary systems. The Journal of Conflict Reso-
Carothers, T. (2002) The end of the transition paradigm. Journal of Democ- lution 45(5): 547–568.
racy 13(1): 5–21. Kaarbo, J. (1996) Power and influence in foreign policy decision making: The
Case, W. (2005) Southeast Asia’s hybrid regimes: When do voters change role of junior coalition partners in German and Israeli foreign policy.
them? Journal of East Asian Studies 5(2): 215–237. International Studies Quarterly 40(4): 501–530.

INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEWS IPR | VOLUME 1 SEPTEMBER 2013 35


| |
© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved
Dabros and Petersen

Kalt, J.P. and Zupan, M.A. (1990) The apparent ideological behavior of leg- Palmer, G., London, T.R. and Regan, P. (2004) What’s stopping you? The
islatures: Testing for principal-agent in slack in political institutions. Jour- sources of political constraints on international conflict behavior in parlia-
nal of Law and Economics 33(1): 103–131. mentary democracies. International Interactions 30(1): 1–24.
Kant, I. (1795/1932) Perpetual Peace. New York: Columbia University Press. Peceny, M. and Butler, C.K. (2004) The conflict behavior of authoritarian
Karl, T.L. (1995) The hybrid regimes of Central America. Journal of regimes. International Politics 41(4): 565–581.
Democracy 6(3): 72–86. Peceny, M., Beer, C.C. and Sanchez-Terry, S. (2002) Dictatorial peace?
Kau, J.B. and Rubin, P.H. (1993) Ideology, voting, and shirking. Public American Political Science Review 96(1): 15–26.
Choice 76(1–2): 151–172. Prins, B.C. and Sprecher, C. (1999) Institutional constraints, political opposi-
Keefer, P. and Khemani, S. (2003) The Political Economy of Public Expen- tion, and interstate dispute escalation: Evidence from parliamentary sys-
ditures. Mimeo. The World Bank. tems, 1946–89. Journal of Peace Research 36(3): 271–287.
Keefer, P. and Khemani, S. (2004) Why do the Poor Receive Poor Services? Ray, J. (1995) Democracy and International Conflict: An Evaluation of
Economic and Political Weekly 39(9): 935–943. the Democratic Peace Proposition. Columbia, SC: University of South
Klick, J. (2005) Limited autocracy. Review of Law and Economics 1(2): Carolina Press.
293–304. Reiter, D. and Tillman, E.R. (2002) Public, legislative, and executive con-
Lai, B. and Slater, D. (2006) Institutions of the offensive: Domestic sources of straints on the democratic initiation of conflict. The Journal of Politics
dispute initiation in authoritarian regimes, 1950–1992. American Journal 64(2): 810–826.
of Political Science 50(1): 113–126. Rosato, S. (2003) The flawed logic of democratic peace theory. American
Layne, C. (1994) Kant or cant: The myth of democratic peace. International Political Science Review 97(4): 585–602.
Security 19(2): 5–49. Rummel, R.J. (1979) Understanding Conflict and War. Beverly Hills, CA:
Leblang, D. and Chan, S. (2003) Explaining wars fought by established Sage.
democracies: Do institutional constraints matter? Political Research Quar- Rummel, R.J. (1983) Libertarianism and international violence. Journal of
terly 56(4): 385–400. Conflict Resolution 27(1): 27–71.
Levitsky, S. and Way, L.A. (2002) The rise of competitive authoritarianism. Schedler, A. (2002) The menu of manipulation. Journal of Democracy 13(2):
Journal of Democracy 13(2): 51–65. 36–50.
Livingstone, S. and Bennett, W.L. (2003) Gatekeeping, indexing, and live- Schmitter, P.C. and Karl, T.L. (1991) What democracy is … and is not.
event news: Is technology altering the construction of news? Political Journal of Democracy 2(3): 75–88.
Communication 20(4): 363–380. Small, M. and Singer, J.D. (1976) The war proneness of democratic regimes.
Lott, J.R. (1987) Political cheating. Public Choice 52(2): 169–187. Jerusalem Journal of International Relations 1(1): 41–64.
Lott, J.R. and Davis, M.L. (1992) A critical review and extension of the poli- Smith, A. (1996) Diversionary foreign policy in democratic systems. Inter-
tical shirking literature. Public Choice 74(4): 461–484. national Studies Quarterly 40(1): 133–153.
MacKenzie, D. and Curran, M.W. (2002) A History of Russia, the Soviet Songer, D.R., Segal, J.A. and Cameron, C.M. (1994) The hierarchy of justice:
Union, and Beyond. 6th edn. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomas Learning. Testing a principal-agent model of Supreme Court-Circuit court interac-
Mansfield, E.D. and Snyder, J. (1995a) Democratization and war. Foreign tions. American Journal of Political Science 38(3): 673–696.
Affairs 7(3): 79–97. Spiro, D.E. (1994) The insignificance of the liberal peace. International
Mansfield, E.D and Snyder, J. (1995b) Democratization and the danger of Security 19(2): 50–86.
war. International Security 20(1): 5–38. Stoll, R.J. (1984) The guns of November: Presidential reelection and the
Mansfield, E.D. and Snyder, J. (2002) Incomplete democratization and the use of force, 1947–1982. Journal of Conflict Resolution 28(2): 231–286.
outbreak of military disputes. International Studies Quarterly 46(4): Stromberg, D. (2004) Radio’s impact on public spending. The Quarterly
529–549. Journal of Economics 119(1): 189–221.
Mansfield, E.D. and Snyder, J. (2007) Electing to Fight: Why Emerging Tindall, G.B. and Shi, D.E. (2004) America: A Narrative History. 6th edn.
Democracies Go to War. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Vol. 1. New York: W.W. Norton.
Mansfield, E.D. and Snyder, J. (2009) Pathways to war in democratic transi- Van de Walle, N. (2002) Africa’s range of regimes. Journal of Democracy
tions. International Organization 63(2): 381–390. 13(2): 66–80.
Maoz, Z. (1998) Realist and cultural critiques of the democratic peace. Inter- Vanbeek, J.R. (1991) Does the decision to retire increase the amount of poli-
national Interactions 24(1): 1–89. tical shirking? Public Finance Quarterly 19(4): 444–456.
Maoz, Z. and Russett, R. (1993) Normative and structural causes of democratic Weeks, J.L. (2008) Autocratic audience costs: Regime type and signaling
peace, 1946–1986. American Political Science Review 87(3): 624–638. resolve. International Organization 62(1): 35–64.
McClellan, W. (1998) Russia: The Soviet Period and After. 4th edn. Upper Weingast, B.R. (1984) The congressional-bureaucratic system: A principal agent
Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. perspective (with applications to the SEC). Public Choice 44(1): 147–191.
Miller, R.A. (1995) Domestic structures and the diversionary use of force. Wintrobe, R. (2007) Dictatorship: Analytical approaches. In: C. Boix and
American Journal of Political Science 39(3): 760–785. S. Stokes (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Politics. Oxford:
Morgan, T.C. and Campbell, S.H. (1991) Domestic structure, decisional con- Oxford University Press.
straints, and war: So what Kant democracies fight? The Journal of Conflict Zaller, J. and Chiu, D. (1996) Government’s little helper: U.S. press coverage of
Resolution 35(2): 187–211. foreign policy crises, 1945–1991. Political Communication 13(4): 385–405.

|
36 SEPTEMBER 2013 VOLUME 1| www.palgrave-journals.com/ipr

© 2013 Macmillan Publishers Limited. All rights reserved


Reproduced with permission of copyright owner. Further
reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like