You are on page 1of 20

THE ECONOMIC RECORD, VOL. 79, NO.

246, SEPTEMBER, 2003, 279–296

Adverse Selection and the Decline in Private Health


September
3O
78riginal
Blackwell
Oxford,
The
ECOR
2003
0013-0249
Economic
Economic
The Article
UK
Decline 2002
Publishing
Record
Record
in Health Ltd.
Insurance

Insurance Coverage in Australia: 1989–95*


GARRY F. BARRETT AND ROBERT CONLON
School of Economics, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia

The decline in private health insurance coverage over the period


1989 –95 is analysed using the ABS National Health Surveys.
Individuals’ health status and health risk behaviours are found to be
significant determinants of their decision to purchase private health
insurance. At a point in time, the pool of the insured is very hetero-
geneous, with a mix of both good and bad health risks. It is found that
the decline in insurance coverage over the period 1989–95 coincided
with an increase in the degree of ‘adverse selection’ within the insured
population.

I Introduction In recent years the role of governments in the


Total expenditure on health services in Australia future funding of health care services has become
was just under $61 billion in 2000–01 or an important political and economic issue. While
approximately 9 per cent of GDP. This obviously private health insurance funds have played a sig-
represents a substantial resource cost and is a nificant part in funding health care in Australia
concern for public policy. The potential growth in for some time,1 many have seen that role being
future health care expenditures is a further concern threatened by declining membership of private
to both Commonwealth and State governments insurance funds and with it, a rising concern that
which provide an overwhelming proportion of the health care will be an ever increasing drain on
funds. If past experience is a guide, the potential public revenues. As an illustration, in mid-1984
problem is significant. Health expenditure per about 50 per cent of the population had private
person in constant prices rose by nearly 40 per hospital cover, in 1990 about 44 per cent, and by
cent over the period 1990–91 to 2000–01 (AIHW mid-2000 this had fallen to just over 31 per cent
2002, tables 2, 3.1, 6, 8, 9). With an ageing popu- (Industry Commission 1997, p. xxx). These fig-
lation, and increasing availability of new and ures and the likelihood, without intervention, of
more expensive medical technologies, it is diffi- continued declines provided the impetus for the
cult to see anything other than real expenditures health insurance initiatives introduced by the
continuing to rise, and possibly accelerate, in the Commonwealth government in recent years.
future. In a context in which the Commonwealth govern-
ment is seeking to shift more of the financial burden
of health care to the private sector, we analyse the
* We thank two anonymous referees, Colin Cameron,
1
Denzil Fiebig, seminar participants at UNSW and The private sector funds about 30 per cent of all
participants at the ‘Regulating Private Health Insurance’ health care, though less than 10 per cent is provided
Workshop, ANU, June 2002, for very helpful comments. from private health insurance; the remainder comes from
Correspondence: Garry F. Barrett, School of out-of-pocket private expenditures (about 15 per cent)
Economics, University of New South Wales, Sydney and other non-government sources (about 5 per cent;
2052, NSW, Australia. Email: g.barrett@unsw.edu.au AIHW 2001, p. 10).

279
© 2003. The Economic Society of Australia. ISSN 0013–0249
280 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

determinants of private health insurance coverage. treatment in either a private hospital or as a private
The analysis contributes to the literature by: patient in a public hospital (most by far, but not
all of whom are privately insured) have a choice
• analysing in detail the relationship between a
of doctor. For a particular service Medicare pays
comprehensive set of health risk factors, for all
75 per cent of the fee appearing in the Medical
family members, and the demand for private
Benefits Schedule (MBS). The remaining 25 per
health insurance;
cent of the MBS fee is coverable by private insur-
• analysing the incidence of private health insurance ance, but any charge in excess of the Schedule fee
coverage at two points in time, 1989 and 1995, – the ‘gap’ – until recently had to be paid by the
between which a dramatic decline in private health patient. Charges associated with the services of
insurance coverage was observed; the hospital such as operating theatre fees and
accommodation are all payable by the patient, but
• evaluating whether the shrinking pool of those pri-
fully insurable.
vately insured was increasingly composed of ‘high
The regulatory framework of the health insur-
risk’ consumers, reflecting what may be termed an
ance system is provided by The Health Insurance
‘adverse selection’ spiral underlying the contrac-
Act. Insurers must be registered under the Act, and
tion in the market for private health insurance.
accept all applicants. Insurers may not discriminate
We find a range of health risk behaviours are on bases of sex, race, the use of services and, until
significantly related to the decision to purchase recently, age in setting premiums or paying bene-
private health insurance in 1989 and 1995. At any fits to those insured.2 Such attributes are related to
time, it is apparent that the pool of the insured is health risk (and hence expected costs to an insurer)
very heterogeneous, comprising a mix of both bad and the requirement that insurers must ignore these
health risks (indicating adverse selection) and good risks in setting premiums is known as ‘community
health risks (consistent with risk-averse preferences). rating.’ There are obvious distortions caused by
However, we find that the decline in insurance community rating and funds having high propor-
coverage over the period 1989–95 coincided with tions of high risk members are compensated
an increase in the degree of ‘adverse selection’ in through a reinsurance pool.3,4
the pool of the privately insured.
The structure of the paper is as follows. A brief
outline of the Medicare system is provided in the 2
From 1 July 2000 private health funds were able to
following section. Section III describes the find-
charge premiums on the basis of age of entry to private
ings of previous research, and in section IV the health insurance (known as ‘lifetime community rating’).
theoretical model and statistical framework of the Individuals (and families) pay an extra 2 per cent in
present analysis is presented. The data sets used premiums for each year over the age of 30 they are when
for the empirical analysis are described in section they first take out private hospital cover, subject to a
V and the results are presented and discussed in maximum 70 per cent surcharge.
3
section VI. The final section contains concluding The reinsurance arrangements redistribute funds
comments and suggestions for future research. among insurers favouring those with above average
claims for people in specified categories, such as those
who are 65 years and over, and those who have been
II Outline of Health Insurance in Australia
hospitalised for more than 35 days in a year. People in
Under Medicare, introduced in 1984, compulsory these two groups incur 48 per cent of claims costs
primary insurance provided basic public hospital (Owens 1999, p. 174). The reinsurance arrangements
care and core medical services. Consumers could may influence the marketing strategies of health funds
purchase supplementary (secondary) insurance and thus the demand for insurance; taking account of
from a private health insurance fund that would such strategic supply-side behaviour is beyond the scope
provide a potentially higher quality of hospital of the present analysis.
4
care (either in a private hospital or as a private An assumption underlying our analysis is that
patient in a public hospital) and/or ancillary services hospital insurance policies were close to identical over
the study period 1989–95. There was relatively little
not covered by Medicare (e.g. dental services). The
variation across health funds in the hospital insurance
substance of these arrangements has now operated products offered during this time due to, at least in part,
for nearly 20 years. Those who choose not to take the operation of the regulatory environment (Industry
out private cover may be treated in a public Commission 1997). During this period most funds
hospital without charge by registered practitioners offered three tiers of cover (basic, intermediate and
nominated by the hospital. Those choosing private high).
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 281

III Previous Research were more likely to purchase some or all categor-
Under the Medicare arrangements operating in ies of insurance as were those with tertiary, or at
1989 and 1995, health insurance choice essentially least some form of post-school education (Butler
entailed a simple decision – whether or not to 1999; Savage & Wright 1999). Married respond-
purchase secondary insurance from a private fund. ents were more likely to take out coverage
Analysis of the determinants of this type of (Cameron & McCallum 1995), though family size
decision is particularly suited to the use of binary apparently has been of little influence on the pur-
discrete choice models using either the logit or chase decision (Cameron & Trivedi 1991). Age has
probit forms of the probability function. Repre- also been shown to have a significant influence
sentative of the approach, Cameron and Trivedi on insurance choice. Cameron et al. (1988), Ngui
(1991) specified a conditional expected utility et al. (1990) and Savage and Wright (1999) have
function that is associated with alternative health all found age has a positive and significant impact
care regimes. The consumer chooses the regime on the probability of having insurance cover.
that maximises expected utility. Other studies Of course age is related to health risk and health
using a similar approach include Scotton (1969), status, but it is perhaps surprising that when spe-
Cameron et al. (1988), Ngui et al. (1990), Cameron cific measures of these risks have been examined,
and McCallum (1995), Hopkins and Kidd (1996), the evidence that such factors affect insurance
Schofield (1996), Butler (1999) and Savage and choice has been equivocal. In a system where pre-
Wright (1999).5 miums are determined by community-rating rather
Beginning with Scotton’s (1969) pioneering than risk-rating, Cameron and McCallum (1995)
work, income has been found to be a dominant considered the question of whether long-term
influence on health insurance choice in Australia. health risk is a major determinant of health insur-
Savage and Wright (1999) found significant posi- ance choice. They concluded that any relationship
tive effects of income on private insurance choice between choice and health status/health risk is
for singles, couples and couples with dependents. weak. The findings of Cameron and Trivedi (1991)
Their results are consistent with those of Ngui suggested those choosing insurance were more
et al. (1990), Cameron et al. (1988) and Cameron likely to be women and older people (who tend to
and Trivedi (1991). In other countries, Propper be relatively heavy health care consumers), and
(1989) obtained similar results for families in Eng- coverage increased with age at an increasing rate.
land and Wales as did Hurd and McGarry (1997) Additional indicators of health status were not
for the elderly in the USA. found to have a significant effect on the insurance
Of the other possible determinants of the deci- decision.
sion to purchase insurance, an obvious candidate is Not only is a consumer’s knowledge of being
price. However few studies have attempted to esti- at risk by being a member of a particular group of
mate price elasticities of demand owing to the lack people with high-risk characteristics (e.g. those
of price information in standard data sets used by who know they have high cholesterol) likely to
researchers in this area and, importantly, the lim- influence their insurance decision, his/her attitude
ited nominal price variation across individuals and to risk is also of likely importance. Hopkins and
families observed in the highly regulated health Kidd (1996) and Butler (1999) found that smokers
insurance market. An exception is Butler (1999) are less likely to purchase insurance. Smoking
who constructed ‘effective prices’ from informa- behaviour is viewed in these studies as a proxy for
tion on insurance fund premium revenue (averaged risk-aversion.
over policies sold) and the expected benefits paid Several recent papers examined the empirical
out by age category. Butler’s (1999) point estimate evidence for adverse selection in health insurance
of the own-price elasticity of demand for hospital markets in the United States. In these studies
insurance was – 0.50. ‘adverse selection’ is defined as the situation
The available evidence suggests that socio- where consumers have differential health risks but
economic variables act on choice in the expected are not charged a premium equal to the expected
ways. Those who are employed (whether full- or marginal cost of their insurance. As a result, ‘high
part-time), and those in white collar occupations risk’ consumers find insurance most attractive and
will tend to take out more generous and expensive
5
Some of these studies also looked at other aspects of policies relative to ‘low risk’ consumers (Cutler &
health care, such as the effect of insurance status on an Zeckhauser 1998). This may set off a spiral,
individual’s utilisation of hospital services. whereby insurers realise greater than expected
282 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

costs and respond by increasing premiums, leading where xi denotes individual/family characteristics
lower risk consumers to quit the market, causing a and other conditioning variables, β (the parameter
further round of premium increases and market vector to be estimated) is the impact of those charac-
contraction. In the extreme, this may lead to the teristics on the decision to purchase insurance, εi
collapse of the insurance market.6 Cutler and is a random error term and i indexes individuals.
Reber (1998) found that an ‘adverse selection We do not observe the net expected utility of
death spiral’ was responsible for the demise of the purchasing insurance but rather a binary variable
Harvard University health insurance plan in the indicating whether the net expected utility is
1990s. Similarly, Thomasson (2002) found that positive and the individual was observed to purchase
(voluntary) community rating of health insurance insurance. The probability that an individual pur-
by the Blue Cross and Blue Shield health funds chases PHI is modelled as
in the fledgling health insurance market of the
1950s became untenable owing to the problems Pr(PHI = 1) = Pr(EVi > 0) = F( β 'xi) (2)
of adverse selection. However, Buchmueller and
DiNardo (2002) evaluated the effect of mandated where F(.) denotes the standard normal distri-
community rating in the market for individual bution function. This corresponds to the standard
health insurance (as distinct from group, workplace probit model, which is estimated using maximum
based, plans) in several states, and found no evi- likelihood techniques (see Greene (1997, pp. 662–
dence of an adverse selection spiral in jurisdictions 75) for further details).
where community rating was adopted.
V Data
IV Model The data analysed in this study are from the
We consider the decision to purchase private Australian Bureau of Statistics National Health
health insurance (PHI) using the theoretical model Surveys conducted in 1989–90 (NHS89) and 1995
presented by Cameron and Trivedi (1991). The (NHS95).8 We examine the decisions by both
decision to purchase PHI is treated as a choice ‘singles’ and ‘families’ to purchase private health
between two discrete alternatives. The first is for (hospital) insurance. The set of records for
the consumer to rely upon the universal cover individuals indicating their income unit status as
provided by Medicare and not purchase private ‘single person’ comprised the sample of single
insurance.7 The second is to purchase supple- adults. The set of ‘family’ records were those who
mentary cover offered by private health funds. The indicated their income unit status was ‘married
net expected utility of purchasing PHI is assumed couple with dependent child(ren)’, ‘married couple
to be given by the linear index function without dependent child(ren)’ and ‘single parent
with dependent child(ren)’. The basic unit of
EVi = β 'xi + εi (1) observation in the NHS is the individual – and an
important feature of these data is that individual
records can be matched into income units. This
6 allows us to control for the characteristics of every
The original treatment of adverse selection was
presented in Rothschild et al. (1976). Strictly, adverse member of a family. To construct the estimation
selection occurs where consumers have hidden infor- samples we excluded income units where the
mation regarding expected health insurance costs that ‘head’ was less than 20 years of age or was a full-
insurers are unable to use in the setting of actuarially time student. In addition, for the family samples,
fair premiums. However, ‘adverse selection’ as used in income units were excluded where the reported
the empirical literature, and adopted in this paper, more insurance status of the ‘head’ and ‘spouse’ were
generally refers to situations where high risk consumers inconsistent.9
differentially prefer insurance (or purchase more
generous insurance). This may occur due to the problems
8
of hidden information or as a consequence of the A detailed data description is contained in an
community rating (rather than risk rating) of insurance appendix available on request from the authors.
9
premia. This lead to the exclusion of 614 and 329 observa-
7
In fact, uninsured individuals (and families) may tions in 1989 and 1995, respectively. When these observa-
either rely upon Medicare or they may ‘self-insure’ and tion were included in the analysis, and either the ‘head’s’
directly purchase private hospital treatment. We are or ‘spouse’s’ insurance status is used for the family, the
unable to distinguish between these two situations with estimation results were very similar, and the qualitative
the NHS data. inferences were identical, to those reported in the text.
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 283

The dependent variable in the analysis is a insurance within the separate single and family
binary variable indicating whether or not the samples in each year of the surveys. Second, wait-
individual or family had private health insurance ing times – a means of rationing public hospital
which provided cover for the costs of in-hospital resources and one indicator of the ‘quality’ of the
procedures. The explanatory variables may be services publicly provided under Medicare – may
broadly classified into two groups. The first be important determinants of decisions regarding
includes the basic demographic and socioeconomic the purchase of insurance, but there is no such
variables such as sex, age marital status, the information available from the NHS. Here again,
number of dependent children (where relevant), to the extent that waiting times differ by state, the
immigrant status, state of residence, education and state dummies will capture this variation.
gross annual income of each single or family
member. This set of explanatory variables also VI Results
includes controls for main source of income,
labour force status, and an indicator of whether a (i) Summary Statistics
person worked full-time or part-time. There is also For our samples of ‘potentially insurable’ consu-
a variable indicating whether the person has a mers, the decline in the prevalence of private health
government health card (which entitles them to insurance (hospital cover) between 1989 and 1995,
subsidised health care). shown in Tables 1 and 2, was marked.10 In 1989
The second group of explanatory variables pro- approximately 36 per cent of singles had health
vides information on the prevalence of health con- insurance and by 1995 this had fallen to 26 per
ditions among respondents (and their families), and cent. Although private health insurance was more
behaviour that is likely to affect their health. Here prevalent among families, with 52 per cent of
we focus on a narrow set of relatively common families purchasing insurance in 1989, there was
specific conditions by controlling for the presence a similar decline in coverage of 11 per cent – to
of diabetes, high blood pressure and high choles- 41 per cent in 1995.
terol, as well as the number of recent and chronic The sample summary statistics indicate a number
(long-term) conditions, and individuals’ self- of changes in the Australian population over the
assessed health status (SAHS). We also control for period 1989–95. There was a decline in the (self-
a wide range of health risk behaviours. The set of reported) prevalence of the specific conditions of
behaviours will reflect individuals’ attitudes to risk high blood pressure and high cholesterol for both the
(since the behaviour affects the probability of singles and family samples, and a slight increase in
different health states occurring), the rate of time the prevalence of diabetes between the two surveys.
preference (as it is the realisation of future states At the same time there was an increase in the
that are affected) and the expected future demand number of recent, and especially chronic, health
for health care services. Specifically, we control conditions. Nevertheless, the proportion of indi-
for adults’ consumption of alcohol, smoking status, viduals who assessed their own health status as
body mass (whether an individual is underweight, good to excellent increased by about 5 per cent to
of acceptable weight or overweight), and the level around 80 per cent among both singles and adults
of regular exercise (low, moderate or vigorous). in families.
Although the NHS are a rich source of informa- In terms of health risk factors, over the study
tion for studying the demand for health insurance, period there was an increase in the proportion of
they have important limitations. First, the surveys the samples who were low-risk drinkers (among
do not record the insurance premiums faced by the singles sample). For the sample of families the
consumers. However, health insurance funds are converse was observed. Both singles and family
state-based, and given the policy of community members indicated a decline in the prevalence of
rating, single adults and families within each state smoking between the two surveys, while the
generally have access to the same set of policies. incidence of being overweight increased. Indeed,
Within a state, the family rate for health insurance by 1995 more than one third of the singles and
is equal to twice that of single adults. Although we approximately half of the adults in families indi-
do not directly control for the price of insurance cated they were overweight according to National
contracts, we divide the sample of consumer units Health and Medical Research Council criteria.
into single adults and families and include controls
for state of residence. The state dummy variables 10
Complete summary statistics and estimation results
will therefore capture variation in the price of are available on request from the authors.
284 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

Table 1
Summary Statistics Describing Personal Characteristics by Insurance Status for Single Men and Women

1989 1995

Explanatory Variables All Insured Uninsured All Insured Uninsured

Private (Hospital) Insurance 0.3606 1.0000 0.0000 0.2600 1.00000 0.0000


Female 0.5047 0.5525 0.4777 0.5060 0.6130 0.4684
Single, Never Married 0.5897 0.6109 0.5777 0.5600 0.5287 0.5710
Separated, Divorced, Widowed 0.4103 0.3891 0.4223 0.4400 0.4713 0.4290
Immigrant 0.2277 0.1756 0.2570 0.2300 0.1861 0.2455
Income ($10 000) 2.2851 2.7590 2.0179 2.1488 2.6584 1.9698
Government Health Card Holder 0.3456 0.2223 0.4151 0.4346 0.3168 0.4760
Age 44.195 44.491 44.027 46.017 50.559 44.422
State
NSW† 0.3575 0.3556 0.3586 0.3451 0.3014 0.3605
Vic. 0.2661 0.2972 0.2485 0.2587 0.2862 0.2490
Qld 0.1586 0.1155 0.1829 0.1821 0.1730 0.1853
SA 0.0798 0.0907 0.0737 0.0799 0.1025 0.0719
WA 0.0901 0.0938 0.0880 0.0826 0.0849 0.0817
Tas. 0.0234 0.0217 0.0243 0.0254 0.0296 0.0239
ACT 0.0148 0.0132 0.0158 0.0095 0.0066 0.0106
NT 0.0097 0.0123 0.0083 0.0167 0.0157 0.0170
Education
High School† 0.5855 0.5132 0.6262 0.5895 0.5241 0.6125
Post Secondary Qualification 0.3142 0.3447 0.2970 0.2913 0.3007 0.2880
Degree 0.1003 0.1420 0.0767 0.1130 0.1653 0.0947
Left School by Age 15 0.2380 0.1686 0.2771 0.2273 0.1909 0.2401
Labour Force Status
Employed† 0.6000 0.6724 0.5592 0.5509 0.5677 0.5450
Unemployed 0.0527 0.0175 0.0726 0.0576 0.0113 0.0739
Not in the Labour Force 0.3473 0.3101 0.3682 0.3915 0.4211 0.3811
Hours
Full Time† 0.5205 0.6021 0.4744 0.4613 0.5018 0.4471
Part Time 0.0781 0.0686 0.0835 0.0895 0.0658 0.0979
Specific Health Conditions
Diabetes 0.0255 0.0192 0.0290 0.0378 0.0422 0.0362
High Blood Pressure 0.2085 0.2022 0.2120 0.1787 0.2239 0.1628
High Cholesterol 0.0883 0.0924 0.0861 0.0641 0.0870 0.0560
Number of Recent Conditions 1.9408 2.0232 1.8944 2.0050 2.3352 1.8890
Number of Chronic Conditions 1.8800 1.9468 1.8424 2.6153 2.9696 2.4909
Self-Assessed Health Status
Poor 0.0569 0.0376 0.0677 0.0605 0.0490 0.0646
Fair 0.1836 0.1545 0.2001 0.1436 0.1233 0.1508
Good/Excellent† 0.7595 0.8079 0.7322 0.7958 0.8277 0.7846
Drinking
Low Risk Drinker† 0.8542 0.8715 0.8444 0.8981 0.8977 0.8983
Medium Risk Drinker 0.0818 0.0804 0.0826 0.0596 0.0638 0.0581
High Risk Drinker 0.0640 0.0481 0.0730 0.0423 0.0386 0.0436
Smoking
Never Smoked† 0.5029 0.5798 0.4595 0.4958 0.6117 0.4551
Ex-Smoker 0.1797 0.1849 0.1768 0.2174 0.2234 0.2153
Current Smoker 0.3174 0.2353 0.3637 0.2868 0.1649 0.3296
Weight: Head
Underweight 0.1349 0.1246 0.1407 0.1145 0.1246 0.1110
Acceptable Weight† 0.4935 0.5041 0.4875 0.4949 0.4748 0.5020
Overweight 0.3716 0.3713 0.3718 0.3906 0.4006 0.3870
Exercise
Low Exercise 0.6483 0.6396 0.6531 0.6761 0.6752 0.6765
Moderate Exercise† 0.1632 0.1726 0.1578 0.1595 0.1682 0.1564
Vigorous Exercise 0.1886 0.1878 0.1890 0.1644 0.1566 0.1671
Observations 9 777 3 557 6 220 4 567 1 252 3 315

† Indicates the omitted (reference) category in the estimation.


2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 285

When families and singles data are subdivided health insurance. For example, the estimates imply
into two groups: those with insurance and those that, relative to an individual with an income of
without, a number of features emerge. One striking $23 000 (approximately the sample average), an
feature is the low incidence of coverage of lone otherwise identical individual with $69 000 income
parent families compared with families composed was 18 per cent more likely to purchase insurance.
of two adults with children. Another feature is the However, the positive marginal effect of income on
strong (and expected) positive association between the probability of insurance coverage declines as
private health insurance coverage and income, income increases.
especially among families. In 1989 the average After controlling for demographic and socio-
total income of head and partner was about economic factors there is significant variation in
$57 000 for those with insurance, and $37 000 for insurance coverage across the states and territories,
those without; in 1995 the corresponding figures with the highest incidence in South Australia and the
were $63 000 and $41 000 (all in 1995 $). Northern Territory, and the lowest in Queensland.
Of the health risk behaviours examined here, one This regional variation may, in part, be due to vari-
feature stands out: the remarkably high propor- ation in the price of insurance across the states
tions of singles and families who were current and territories,11 as well as stated-based differences
smokers and who were not covered by insurance. in institutional features such as South Australia’s
The apparent relationship between smoking and history of no ‘gap’ payments for hospital services,
fund membership runs counter to the adverse Queensland’s history of free access to public hos-
selection hypothesis. Rather, the evidence from pital care and state-based differences in the quality
this and other health related activities (drinking of public hospital care (such as the well-publicised
and exercise) reflects an individual’s attitude towards length of waiting lists for elective procedures). Age
risk, with those who are more risk-averse also being is also clearly a strong determinant of insurance
most likely to purchase private health insurance. coverage. There is a progressive increase in the
While these bivariate comparisons are useful, it probability of insurance coverage with age. For
is obvious that potentially important influences on instance, individuals aged 20–24 years are 35 per
the decision to purchase health insurance such as cent less likely to purchase health insurance com-
income, age and health behaviours are interrelated. pared to an otherwise identical individual aged
An advantage of the multivariate probit analysis over 70 years.
that follows is the ability to examine the contribu- The likelihood ratio test statistic for the null
tion of a single determinant while controlling for hypothesis that the set of health status and health
the influences of the others. risk indicators are jointly insignificant is 194.2
leading to the strong rejection of the null.12 Collec-
(ii) Probit Analysis tively, the health status/health risk activity vari-
ables are significantly related to the decision to
Sample of single adults purchase insurance even after controlling for the
Estimation results for the samples of single adults demographic and socioeconomic characteristics.
are presented in Table 3. To aid interpretation, the However the three specific health conditions exam-
estimated marginal effects of the variables on the ined were not individually significant in explaining
probability of purchasing private insurance (and the decision to take out private insurance. The
the asymptotic standard error of the marginal numbers of recent and chronic conditions were
effects) are presented. The model specification is found to be statistically significant. In particular,
based on that used by Cameron and Trivedi (1991) having an additional recent condition is associated
augmented with a comprehensive set of measures with an increase of 1.6 per cent in the likelihood
of individuals’ health status and health risk of having health insurance. Individuals who report
behaviours. The results for 1989 show that, other their SAHS to be poor or fair were significantly
things equal, individuals who are female, never
married, and Australian born were significantly 11
more likely to purchase insurance. Not surprisingly, However, variation in the pattern of coverage across
states is only weakly correlated with variation in the
if an individual has a government health card, he/ price of insurance (as presented by Butler 1999) across
she is substantially less likely to purchase private states.
insurance. Consistent with the results of Cameron 12
The test statistic is distributed χ 2 with 15 degrees
and Trivedi (1991) and other researchers, income of freedom. The critical value at the 1 per cent level of
is a very important determinant of the demand for significance is 30.58.
286 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

Table 2
Summary Statistics Describing Personal Characteristics by Insurance Status for Families

1989 1995

Explanatory Variables All Insured Uninsured All Insured Uninsured

Private (Hospital) Insurance 0.5195 1.0000 0.0000 0.4081 1.0000 0.0000


Single Parent 0.0898 0.0355 0.1484 0.0933 0.0282 0.1382
Number of Children 1.1026 1.0733 1.1343 1.0559 0.9890 1.1020
Child Aged < 5 Years 0.3089 0.2919 0.3272 0.2857 0.2236 0.3285
Family Size 3.0128 3.0378 2.9858 2.9626 2.9608 2.9638
Ave No. Recent Children’s Conditions 0.7031 0.7201 0.6847 0.6137 0.6355 0.5987
Ave No. Chronic Children’s Conditions 0.3272 0.3372 0.3164 0.4116 0.4113 0.4119
Government Health Card Holder 0.2772 0.1415 0.4239 0.3570 0.1925 0.4705
Immigrant – Head 0.3145 0.2657 0.3673 0.3054 0.2333 0.3552
Head Income ($10 000) 3.2819 3.9484 2.5614 3.2949 4.2974 2.6037
Partner Income ($10 000) 1.4627 1.7347 1.1685 1.7287 2.0108 1.5342
Age: Head 45.502 46.154 44.797 46.383 49.298 44.373
Age: Partner 39.593 42.015 36.974 40.732 45.599 37.378
State
NSW† 0.3395 0.3578 0.3197 0.3389 0.3431 0.3360
Vic. 0.2569 0.2745 0.2377 0.2449 0.2431 0.2461
Qld 0.1672 0.1249 0.2129 0.1797 0.1768 0.1818
SA 0.0902 0.0934 0.0866 0.0849 0.0838 0.0856
WA 0.0958 0.0966 0.0950 0.1000 0.1027 0.0981
Tas. 0.0274 0.0290 0.0256 0.0265 0.0270 0.0261
ACT 0.0155 0.0165 0.0143 0.0107 0.0092 0.0118
NT 0.0076 0.0071 0.0082 0.0144 0.0143 0.0145
Education: Head
High School† 0.4536 0.3874 0.5251 0.4566 0.3637 0.5207
Post Secondary Qualification 0.4342 0.4568 0.4098 0.4022 0.4220 0.3885
Degree 0.1122 0.1558 0.0651 0.1363 0.2097 0.0858
Left School by Age 15 Years 0.2316 0.1800 0.2874 0.1931 0.1559 0.2187
Labour Force Status: Head
Employed† 0.7269 0.8200 0.6263 0.6859 0.7721 0.6265
Unemployed 0.0380 0.0131 0.0649 0.0421 0.0110 0.0635
Not in the Labour Force 0.2351 0.1668 0.3088 0.2720 0.2169 0.3100
Specific Health Conditions: Head
Diabetes 0.0267 0.0246 0.0290 0.0309 0.0263 0.0341
High Blood Pressure 0.1885 0.1940 0.1826 0.1479 0.1669 0.1347
High Cholesterol 0.1271 0.1520 0.1001 0.0867 0.1072 0.0725
Number of Recent Conditions 1.5828 1.5486 1.6198 1.6853 1.7679 1.6283
Number of Chronic Conditions 1.7970 1.8170 1.7754 2.5019 2.6835 2.3767
Self-Assessed Health Status: Head
Poor 0.0471 0.0274 0.0684 0.0404 0.0203 0.0543
Fair 0.1581 0.1294 0.1891 0.1235 0.0841 0.1507
Good/Excellent† 0.7948 0.8432 0.7425 0.8360 0.8956 0.7950
Drinking: Head
Low Risk Drinker† 0.9206 0.9227 0.9184 0.9074 0.9074 0.9074
Medium Risk Drinker 0.0439 0.0442 0.0435 0.0532 0.0607 0.0480
High Risk Drinker 0.0355 0.0331 0.0381 0.0394 0.0320 0.0446
Smoking: Head
Never Smoked† 0.3630 0.4183 0.3032 0.3660 0.4337 0.3194
Ex-Smoker 0.3285 0.3474 0.3081 0.3730 0.4114 0.3465
Current Smoker 0.3085 0.2344 0.3887 0.2610 0.1549 0.3342
Weight: Head
Underweight 0.0562 0.0339 0.0803 0.0490 0.0222 0.0675
Acceptable Weight† 0.4505 0.4465 0.4549 0.4075 0.3937 0.4171
Overweight 0.4933 0.5196 0.4648 0.5435 0.5841 0.5155
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 287

Table 2
Continued

1989 1995

Explanatory Variables All Insured Uninsured All Insured Uninsured

Exercise: Head
Low Exercise 0.6919 0.6750 0.7102 0.6868 0.6467 0.7145
Moderate Exercise† 0.1486 0.1547 0.1421 0.1585 0.1858 0.1397
Vigorous Exercise 0.1594 0.1703 0.1477 0.1547 0.1676 0.1459
Education: Partner
High School† 0.5512 0.5299 0.5741 0.5558 0.5196 0.5808
Post Secondary Qualification 0.2864 0.3410 0.2275 0.2458 0.3015 0.2074
Degree 0.0588 0.0809 0.0349 0.1024 0.1472 0.0715
Left School by Age 15 Years 0.1911 0.1571 0.2278 0.1621 0.1332 0.1820
Labour Force Status: Partner
Employed† 0.4610 0.5483 0.3666 0.4820 0.5827 0.4125
Unemployed 0.0348 0.0255 0.0448 0.0206 0.0075 0.0296
Not in the Labour Force 0.4144 0.3906 0.4402 0.4041 0.3816 0.4196
Specific Health Conditions: Partner
Diabetes 0.0204 0.0165 0.0245 0.0263 0.0206 0.0301
High Blood Pressure 0.2018 0.2044 0.1990 0.1331 0.1520 0.1200
High Cholesterol 0.0957 0.1029 0.0878 0.0636 0.0738 0.0566
Number of Recent Conditions 1.8085 1.9529 1.6525 1.9263 2.2078 1.7322
Number of Chronic Conditions 1.7045 1.8426 1.5552 2.4057 2.6946 2.2066
Self-Assessed Health Status: Partner
Poor 0.0333 0.0283 0.0387 0.0307 0.0281 0.0325
Fair 0.1432 0.1259 0.1620 0.1102 0.0824 0.1293
Good/Excellent† 0.7328 0.8103 0.6490 0.7658 0.8613 0.6999
Drinking: Partner
Low Risk Drinker† 0.8285 0.8804 0.7725 0.8592 0.9055 0.8274
Medium Risk Drinker 0.0595 0.0610 0.0579 0.0381 0.0532 0.0277
High Risk Drinker 0.0222 0.0230 0.0212 0.0093 0.0131 0.0067
Smoking: Partner
Never Smoked† 0.5324 0.6075 0.4513 0.5305 0.6239 0.4661
Ex-Smoker 0.1782 0.1962 0.1586 0.2161 0.2440 0.1969
Current Smoker 0.1996 0.1607 0.2417 0.1600 0.1039 0.1987
Weight: Partner
Underweight 0.1372 0.1384 0.1360 0.1045 0.1070 0.1028
Acceptable Weight† 0.4526 0.5045 0.3964 0.4277 0.4822 0.3900
Overweight 0.3204 0.3215 0.3192 0.3745 0.3826 0.3689
Exercise: Partner
Low Exercise 0.6896 0.7247 0.6517 0.6931 0.7198 0.6748
Moderate Exercise† 0.1276 0.1378 0.1166 0.1340 0.1506 0.1226
Vigorous Exercise 0.0930 0.1020 0.0833 0.0795 0.1014 0.0644
Observations 13 274 6 965 6 309 6 565 2 698 3 867

† Indicates the omitted (reference) category in the estimation.

less likely, other things equal, to purchase private Turning to health risk behaviours, high risk
insurance compared to those who assessed their drinkers were significantly less likely to purchase
health to be good or excellent. The estimated impact insurance. There was a very strong relationship
of SAHS is counter to that implied by adverse between smoking status and private insurance
selection, and may reflect strategic behaviour by coverage. Current smokers were 12 per cent less
individuals with poorer SAHS to rely upon Medi- likely, and ex-smokers 4 per cent less likely, to have
care services or perhaps the variables capture a private insurance than non-smokers, other things
non-linearity in the effect of income. being equal. The relationship between insurance
288 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

Table 3
Marginal Effects of Covariates on Probability of Private Health Insurance Coverage, Single Men and Women

Coefficient (Standard Error)

1989 1995

Female 0.0798 (0.0125) 0.0812 (0.0155)


Single, Previously Married −0.0800 (0.0158) −0.0784 (0.0191)
Immigrant −0.1055 (0.0117) −0.0663 (0.0145)
Government Health Card Holder −0.2090 (0.0205) −0.1336 (0.0272)
Income ($10 000) 0.0549 (0.0071) 0.0449 (0.0086)
Income† −0.0034 (0.0009) −0.0026 (0.0007)
State
Vic. 0.0500 (0.0132) 0.0760 (0.0184)
Qld −0.0906 (0.0146) 0.0395 (0.0204)
SA 0.0901 (0.0211) 0.1544 (0.0307)
WA 0.0317 (0.0194) 0.0737 (0.0286)
Tas. 0.0112 (0.0349) 0.1085 (0.0502)
ACT −0.0684 (0.0394) 0.0061 (0.0742)
NT 0.1343 (0.0557) −0.0314 (0.0463)
Age
20 –24 Years −0.1203 (0.0247) −0.1637 (0.0238)
25–29 Years −0.1521 (0.0229) −0.1406 (0.0230)
30–34 Years −0.1282 (0.0250) −0.1118 (0.0262)
35–39 Years −0.0753 (0.0293) −0.0714 (0.0308)
45– 49 Years −0.0006 (0.0344) −0.0346 (0.0359)
50–54 Years 0.0978 (0.0379) 0.0285 (0.0454)
55–59 Years 0.1384 (0.0390) 0.0595 (0.0498)
60– 64 Years 0.2124 (0.0397) 0.1756 (0.0577)
65– 69 Years 0.2070 (0.0429) 0.1898 (0.0607)
70+ Years 0.2301 (0.0381) 0.2424 (0.0529)
Specific Health Conditions
Diabetes −0.0454 (0.0325) 0.0097 (0.0345)
High Blood Pressure −0.0247 (0.0144) 0.0147 (0.0197)
High Cholesterol 0.0034 (0.0192) 0.0112 (0.0275)
No. Recent Conditions 0.0165 (0.0041) 0.0185 (0.0049)
No. Chronic Conditions 0.0162 (0.0042) 0.0103 (0.0047)
Self-Assessed Health Status
Poor −0.0646 (0.0239) −0.0435 (0.0277)
Fair −0.0352 (0.0145) −0.0297 (0.0197)
Health Risk Behaviours:
Drinking
Medium Risk Drinker −0.0170 (0.0187) 0.0207 (0.0289)
High Risk Drinker −0.0501 (0.0211) 0.0850 (0.0392)
Smoking
Ex-Smoker −0.0415 (0.0138) −0.0716 (0.0147)
Current Smoker −0.1179 (0.0116) −0.1247 (0.0142)
Weight
Underweight −0.0337 (0.0155) 0.0278 (0.0225)
Overweight 0.0182 (0.0114) 0.0132 (0.0143)
Exercise
Low Exercise 0.0037 (0.0141) 0.0061 (0.0180)
High Exercise −0.0065 (0.0170) −0.0286 (0.0214)
LLF −5 431.5 −2 154.4
Pseudo R2 0.1502 0.1767

† Income is measured in deviations from the sample mean.


The models also included controls for education, main source of income, labour force status, occupation and full-time/part-time status.
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 289

coverage and body mass is more mixed, since There are also significant differences in the esti-
individuals who are underweight are less likely to mated relationship between age and the probability
purchase insurance while those who are over- of buying private health insurance. In particular,
weight are more likely to have private insurance. there is a positive monotonic relationship between
Exercise however, as an indicator of health risk, is age and the probability of insurance coverage,
not significantly associated with the decision to though the gradient of the relationship was lower
purchase private insurance. Overall, it may be con- in 1995 than in 1989 for those aged more than
cluded that the evidence regarding health risk 49 years. Nevertheless, in both years the pattern is
factors does not support adverse selection but the consistent and pronounced: relative to the omitted
opposite: individuals who have healthier risk age group (age 40–44 years), it was significantly
behaviour are the ones most likely to purchase less probable for those in younger age groups to
insurance. These results imply that an important purchase insurance; more strongly, for those in
element in the decision to purchase insurance is older age groups, particularly those older than
simply risk aversion, with the more risk averse 54 years, the contrary was true. An implication of
adopting less risky behaviours and taking out private these estimates is that the aggregate decline in
insurance. cover over time cannot simply be explained by the
Model 2 duplicates model 1 for the 1995 sample. reluctance of the most recent birth cohorts to pur-
Wald tests reject the hypothesis that the vector chase private insurance.
of coefficient estimates are equal in the two sample The estimated impact of several health indicators
years. Comparing estimates across the columns, an proved to be robust over the data period. These
important difference between the estimates for factors were the positive effect of the number of
1995 and 1989 is the reduced importance of having health conditions on the likelihood of purchasing
a government health card (coinciding with an increase private insurance, and the negative estimated rela-
in the incidence of possessing a health card) and tionship between current smoker status and the
income in determining insurance status. Further likelihood of purchasing private insurance. How-
investigation of the decline in the estimated ever, the negative relationship between two health
impact of income on the decision to purchase risks (drinking and body mass) and insurance
insurance reveals a very substantial decline in coverage were no longer significant. In all, the
insurance coverage among single men and women estimates indicate that over the period 1989–95 the
in the highest income bracket (income over positive association between several health risk
$75 000). This suggests that the smaller income and status variables (age, specific health condi-
elasticity of demand for health insurance of single tions) and the probability of insurance coverage
men and women in 1995 is mainly due to those in was more pronounced, while the negative associ-
the highest income group deciding to self-insure. ation between other health risk behaviours and
Results for the 1995 sample also highlight insurance coverage (risk-seeking) was less evident,
important regional differences in the change in pri- which suggests that the degree of adverse selection
vate insurance coverage over time. By 1995 single in the pool of privately insured single adults
adults in Queensland were as likely as otherwise increased over time.
identical men and women in New South Wales,
Western Australia and the territories to purchase Sample of families
private insurance. South Australia and Tasmania The model estimates for the sample of families
had significantly smaller declines in the probability are presented in Table 4. Focusing on the results
of taking out private insurance, and hence a greater for 1989, the estimates show that lone parent
likelihood of having private insurance in 1995. The families are substantially less likely to purchase
decline in the probability of coverage in most private insurance than families of two adults (with
states and territories may represent the natural or without) dependent children. Rather than the
evolution of the health insurance markets under total number of children per se, it is the presence
Medicare toward the situation in Queensland where of young children (aged less than 5 years), and the
there has been a long tradition of free public hos- average number of recent health conditions of
pital care. The state dummy variables also capture children, that is important in explaining the
the impact of variation in the price of insurance decision by families to purchase insurance. If an
across the regions, and so state-specific trends in adult has a health card then the family is much
price (or product quality) may also be reflected in less likely to have private insurance, other things
the estimated coefficients for state of residence. equal.
290 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

Table 4
Marginal Effects of Covariates on Probability of Private Health Insurance Coverage, Families

Coefficient (Standard Error)

1989 1995

Married without Children −0.0360 (0.0226) −0.0701 (0.0304)


Single Parent −0.1182 (0.0530) −0.1088 (0.0623)
Number of Children −0.0125 (0.0076) −0.0221 (0.0111)
Child Aged < 5 0.0377 (0.0110) 0.0438 (0.0158)
Ave No. Recent Children’s Conditions 0.0191 (0.0071) 0.0195 (0.0098)
Ave No. Chronic Children’s Conditions 0.0064 (0.0096) 0.0035 (0.0111)
Government Health Card Holder −0.2033 (0.0173) −0.1381 (0.0241)
Immigrant: Head −0.0901 (0.0130) −0.0981 (0.0171)
Immigrant: Partner −0.1090 (0.0136) −0.1131 (0.0175)
Income
Head ($10 000) 0.0591 (0.0047) 0.0409 (0.0065)
Head† −0.0056 (0.0007) −0.0020 (0.0006)
Partner ($10 000) 0.0174 (0.0077) 0.0160 (0.0095)
Partner† −0.0020 (0.0011) −0.0001 (0.0008)
State
Vic. 0.0284 (0.0132) 0.0292 (0.0225)
Qld −0.1664 (0.0156) −0.0083 (0.0261)
SA 0.0523 (0.0179) 0.0535 (0.0249)
WA −0.0025 (0.0178) 0.0362 (0.0282)
Tas. 0.0202 (0.0199) 0.0464 (0.0365)
ACT −0.0941 (0.0371) 0.0504 (0.0328)
NT −0.0211 (0.0632) −0.0778 (0.0287)
Age: Head
20–24 Years −0.2085 (0.0375) −0.1477 (0.0486)
25–29 Years −0.1125 (0.0274) −0.0903 (0.0378)
30–34 Years −0.0551 (0.0235) −0.0532 (0.0315)
35–39 Years −0.0458 (0.0197) −0.0431 (0.0265)
45–49 Years 0.0093 (0.0216) 0.0709 (0.0293)
50–54 Years 0.0398 (0.0268) 0.1666 (0.0374)
55–59 Years 0.0520 (0.0327) 0.1767 (0.0460)
60–64 Years 0.1081 (0.0375) 0.2262 (0.0545)
65–69 Years 0.1018 (0.0450) 0.3003 (0.0629)
70+ Years 0.1076 (0.0481) 0.3190 (0.0662)
Specific Health Conditions: Head
Diabetes 0.0187 (0.0311) −0.0215 (0.0417)
High Blood Pressure 0.0218 (0.0139) 0.0263 (0.0228)
High Cholesterol 0.0615 (0.0154) 0.0282 (0.0262)
Number of Recent Conditions 0.0026 (0.0044) 0.0080 (0.0058)
Number of Chronic Conditions 0.0050 (0.0041) 0.0077 (0.0052)
Self-Assessed Health Status: Head
Poor −0.0740 (0.0267) −0.1274 (0.0367)
Fair −0.0220 (0.0149) −0.0971 (0.0223)
Drinking: Head
Medium Risk Drinker −0.0078 (0.0246) 0.0063 (0.0309)
High Risk Drinker −0.0490 (0.0269) −0.0412 (0.0355)
Smoking: Head
Ex-Smoker −0.0242 (0.0122) −0.0466 (0.0160)
Current Smoker −0.0725 (0.0128) −0.1033 (0.0182)
Weight: Head
Underweight −0.0634 (0.0243) −0.0361 (0.0371)
Overweight 0.0330 (0.0106) 0.0265 (0.0143)
Exercise: Head
Low Exercise −0.0637 (0.0234) −0.0574 (0.0193)
Vigorous Exercise 0.0306 (0.0103) −0.0127 (0.0240)
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 291

Table 4
Continued

Coefficient (Standard Error)

1989 1995

Age: Partner
20–24 Years −0.1084 (0.0356) −0.1352 (0.0448)
25–29 Years −0.0601 (0.0282) −0.1193 (0.0354)
30–34 Years −0.0267 (0.0247) −0.0463 (0.0328)
35–39 Years −0.0334 (0.0217) 0.0017 (0.0290)
45– 49 Years 0.0264 (0.0239) 0.0201 (0.0307)
50–54 Years 0.0477 (0.0308) −0.0046 (0.0389)
55–59 Years 0.0597 (0.0372) 0.1757 (0.0509)
60–64 Years 0.1214 (0.0401) 0.1435 (0.0602)
65–69 Years 0.0928 (0.0459) 0.1424 (0.0675)
70+ Years 0.0653 (0.0504) 0.0949 (0.0728)
Specific Health Conditions: Partner
Diabetes −0.0986 (0.0353) −0.0430 (0.0436)
High Blood Pressure −0.0160 (0.0134) 0.0055 (0.0239)
High Cholesterol 0.0126 (0.0177) 0.0134 (0.0302)
Number of Recent Conditions 0.0140 (0.0042) 0.0167 (0.0056)
Number of Chronic Conditions 0.0073 (0.0041) 0.0014 (0.0052)
Self-Assessed Health Status: Partner
Poor 0.0196 (0.0290) 0.0108 (0.0445)
Fair −0.0233 (0.0153) −0.0821 (0.0234)
Drinking: Partner
Medium Risk Drinker −0.0688 (0.0208) 0.0167 (0.0363)
High Risk Drinker −0.0180 (0.0338) 0.0913 (0.0737)
Smoking: Partner
Ex-Smoker −0.0243 (0.0134) −0.0199 (0.0170)
Current Smoker −0.1154 (0.0133) −0.1137 (0.0194)
Weight: Partner
Underweight −0.0188 (0.0151) 0.0083 (0.0240)
Overweight 0.0027 (0.0116) −0.0004 (0.0155)
Exercise: Partner
Low Exercise 0.0252 (0.0149) 0.0180 (0.0199)
Vigorous Exercise 0.0045 (0.0210) 0.0364 (0.0300)
LLF −7 106.28 −3 283.83
Pseudo R2 0.2263 0.2614

† ‘Head’ and ‘partner’ incomes are measured in deviations from their respective sample means.
The models also included separate controls for education, main source of income, labour force status, occupation and full-time/part-time
status of both the family ‘head’ and ‘partner’.

Income is a statistically and economically signi- of purchasing private health insurance is stronger
ficant determinant of coverage, and interestingly than that found for single adults.
head’s income is much more strongly associated The pattern of coefficient estimates for the state
with the decision to purchase private insurance dummy variables mirrors that found for singles,
than partner’s income. Consequently, it is not but the size of the marginal effects is larger for the
simply total family income, but also whether the family samples. The positive, monotonic relation-
income is received by the head or partner, that is ship between the age of the family head on the
important to the insurance decision. Further, the probability of coverage is similar to, though
marginal effect of head’s income (and hence head stronger than that found for single adults in 1989.
and partner income combined) on the probability The relationship between age of partner and the
292 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

probability of coverage is substantially weaker marginal effect of holding a government health


than that found for head, though this may be card in 1995 was less than that found with the
explained by the high correlation in head and 1989 sample.
partner’s age and the importance of head’s age is The responsiveness of the demand for health
capturing part of the importance of partner’s age. insurance to income was clearly very important in
Overall, the pattern of coefficients for the other 1995, but again, the magnitude of the marginal
socioeconomic characteristics is similar to that dis- effect of head and especially partner’s income (the
cussed above in relation to single adults. latter being insignificant in 1995) was less than
Of the specific health conditions, the family that found for 1989.
head having ‘high cholesterol’ and partner having By 1995 most of the coefficients for the state of
‘diabetes’ was significantly related to the pur- residence variables were individually insignificant.
chase of private insurance. The number of partner’s Thus, by 1995 most of the other states and territo-
recent conditions was positively related to the ries of Australia converged toward the situation
demand for insurance. The point estimates suggest observed in Queensland. Consistent with the find-
that families headed by an individual who assesses ings for single adults, the trend of declining private
their own health status as ‘poor’ were less likely to hospital cover across most of Australia is again
purchase insurance. Families headed by high risk generally consistent with a natural evolution of the
drinkers or where the partner is a ‘medium risk’ market for secondary hospital insurance under the
drinker were less likely to have private insurance. institutional arrangements of Medicare toward an
More important quantitatively, is the smoking sta- ‘equilibrium’ represented by Queensland with its
tus of the family head and partner. Families where unique institutional history of ‘free’ hospital care.
the head or partner are ex-smokers and especially There are important differences in the pattern of
where they were current smokers, were substan- estimates for age of head and partner by sample
tially less likely to have private insurance coverage. year. The age-probability-of-cover gradient was
Families headed by adults who are underweight steeper for both head of family and partner in
(overweight) were less (more) likely to have private 1995, and the former exceeds that found for single
health cover, while exercise was found not to be adults. This steeper gradient implies an even
significantly correlated with the decision to purchase greater concentration of elderly people in the pool
private insurance, other things equal. of the privately insured and thus is indicative of a
As found for single adults in 1989, there is greater degree of adverse selection in the insurance
substantial heterogeneity in the pool of families market in 1995 compared to 1989.
insured. The model estimates reveal that factors Other significant differences in estimates across
associated with both bad health risks (reflecting the samples relate to the health factors. The three
adverse selection) and good risks (reflecting risk specific health conditions were insignificant in
aversion) were important in determining the private 1995 in explaining the decision to purchase private
health insurance coverage of families. However, insurance. The number of recent conditions experi-
comparing the estimates for the 1989 sample with enced by the partner of the family head were
those for 1995 may reveal the degree to which significantly and quantitatively more important in
these separate factors became more or less pro- 1995. Coupled with the increase in the average
nounced in determining the trend in insurance number of recent and chronic conditions reported
coverage among families. over the study period, this suggests a further dimen-
In comparing the models’ estimates across time, sion in which the degree of adverse selection in
a number of important differences are apparent. the pool of the insured may have increased over
First, the estimates show that families without chil- time as coverage has declined.
dren were disproportionately likely to drop private Moreover, the estimates for 1995 indicate that in
cover over the time period from 1989. The pres- families where the head of family’s (or partner’s)
ence of a young child, and the average number of SAHS is fair or poor the likelihood of private
recent conditions of dependent children continued insurance coverage was lower . The smoking beha-
to be significantly associated with the decision by viour of the adults in the family was also signifi-
families to purchase private insurance. Similarly, cantly related to the probability of purchasing
an adult in the family having a government health private insurance. Families where the head (part-
card was associated with a substantially lower ner) currently smoked were 10 (11) percentage
probability of having private health insurance, points less likely to purchase health insurance than
other things equal. However, the magnitude of the an otherwise identical family where the head (or
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 293

partner) had never smoked. Again, smoking status in 1995 based on the 1995 coefficients, which
appears to be a robust indicator of an individual’s reflects the observed behaviour in 1995. The 95
attitude toward risk. per cent confidence interval for the mean pre-
Overall, the changes in the demand for private dicted level of insurance coverage in 1995,14 using
insurance among families between 1989 and 95 the 1989 and 1995 coefficients, is plotted against
suggest a greater degree of adverse selection in the age in Figures 1 and 2 for the Single and Family
pool of insured families. Given the decline in the samples, respectively. Age (or age of family ‘head’)
proportion of those covered by insurance, the like- is shown on the horizontal axis since age is readily
lihood of a family being covered in 1995 was more observable and strongly correlated with health
strongly (and positively) correlated with the age of status and expected medical costs.15 The decline in
head and partner, and number of partner’s recent insurance coverage over time implies that the mean
conditions. However, there were some countervail- predicted probability of coverage based on the
ing effects, with significant relationships between a 1989 coefficients will in general be higher than
lack of private cover and the family head or part- that based on the 1995 coefficients. If the decline
ner being a smoker, or assessing their own health in coverage was uncorrelated with insurance risk
as relatively poor or fair. In the next section we then the decline will be uniform across all age groups,
assess whether the net effect of these changes and the two profiles should be approximately
was to increase or decrease the concentration of parallel. Alternatively, if the lower insurance risks
‘high health risks’ within the pool of the privately were disproportionately likely to drop cover, then
insured. the decline in the mean predicted probability of
cover would be greatest among the younger age
(iii) Testing for an Adverse Selection Spiral groups and least among the elderly.16
The analysis has so far considered multiple Figures 1 and 2 clearly show that the decline
dimensions of individual (and family) health risks in coverage was most concentrated among the
and hence of the ‘insurance risk’ they pose to private younger age groups. The tightness of the confi-
health funds. Along several important dimensions, dence intervals indicates that the differences in the
there is a stronger positive association between the mean predicted levels of insurance coverage are
health risk and the likelihood of holding insurance, statistically significant for almost every age group.
while on other dimensions, that association is For singles, if the demand for private health insur-
either weaker or in fact negative. In this section we ance had remained stable over the period 1989–95,
attempt to assess whether, on balance across these a much larger fraction of the young and middle
various dimensions, the net ‘insurance risk’ posed age groups (ages 20–49) is predicted to take out
by the insured has increased or decreased over private cover than actually did, while coverage
time. In this way, we seek to test whether there is among the oldest (ages 70+) is predicted to be
evidence of an adverse selection spiral underlying slightly less than the coverage observed in 1995.
the falling demand for private health insurance Figure 2, for families, shows an even more pro-
over the period 1989–95. nounced decline in cover among the low cost
To test for an ‘adverse selection’ spiral, the (younger) insurance risks. Comparing the predicted
probit model estimates were used to predict the probabilities of cover by age group shows the
probability of private health insurance coverage. increasing probability of cover with age until the
We focus on the 1995 sample and calculate the pre- mid-50 s, then a decline in the probability of cover
dicted probability of coverage using the coeffi- with age which eventually plateaus around age 65
cients estimated with the 1989 sample and 1995 (the age of eligibility, for males, for the Age Pen-
sample, respectively.13 By using the 1989 coeffi- sion in Australia, which includes access to a health
cients, we construct a counterfactual pool of the concession card). From Figure 2, it is apparent that
insured which would have resulted if consumers the counterfactual predicted probability of cover
in 1995 had behaved in the same manner as the
consumers did in 1989. This counterfactual is then 14
compared to the predicted probability of coverage To construct the confidence interval, the standard
error of the mean predicted level of coverage was
calculated using the delta method (Greene 1997, p. 124).
13 15
By concentrating on the 1995 sample we do not Note, though, that the predicted probabilities do
have to consider the effect of changing population take account of all the available characteristics of the
demographics, allowing us to isolate the effect of individual income units.
16
changing behaviour on the pattern of insurance coverage. We thank Colin Cameron for suggesting this test.
294 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

Figure 1
Predicted Pr(PHI = 1) Singles, 1995

(which assumes the demand for insurance is stable health risks. The former is consistent with risk-
over time) is much higher for the youngest age averse preferences; the latter, the presence of
groups (20 – 44 years of age), moderately higher for adverse selection. The empirical results of this
middle age groups and marginally lower for the paper reflect this mix.
oldest groups (aged 65+ years). Overall, there is For singles the significance of age and the
unequivocal evidence that over the 1989–95 period number of health conditions that characterised
those individuals and families who represented fund membership in 1989 is indicative of adverse
better insurance risks (from the point of view of selection. But there were contrary indications as
insurers), based on observable and unobservable well. The health status and health risk indicators
attributes, were most likely to quit the pool of the generated estimates contrary to the hypothesis of
insured. On this basis, at least part of the decline adverse selection in the decision to take out private
in insurance coverage between 1989 and 95 repre- insurance. Those with worse (self-assessed) health,
sents an ‘adverse selection spiral’. Nevertheless, risky drinking behaviour and who smoked were all
the population of the insured in 1995 remained less likely to purchase health insurance than other-
heterogeneous, and included both good and bad wise identical individuals who did not have these
risks, therefore it is unlikely that the declining attributes. Thus, contrary to the adverse selection
‘quality’ of the pool of the insured alone can hypothesis, these results suggest, all else equal,
account for the decline in health fund membership. that the pool of the insured represent better health
risks than the population at large. They imply that
VII Conclusion a significant element in the decision to purchase
At any time the composition of health fund insurance is simply risk aversion, with the more
membership comprises a mix of low and high cost risk-averse adopting lower risk behaviours, of
2003 THE DECLINE IN HEALTH INSURANCE 295

Figure 2
Predicted Pr(PHI = 1) Families, 1995

which one is purchasing private health insurance. being a high-risk drinker and/or smoker, and/or
Analysis of NHS95 indicated that over the period assessing his/her own health as relatively fair or
1989–95 the positive association between several poor. Again, on balance it is found that the degree
health risk and status variables (age, and specific of adverse selection increased over time.
health conditions) and the probability of insurance This study has looked at the determinants of the
coverage was more pronounced, while the negative decision to take out private health insurance and
association between other health risk behaviours how their importance changed over time. There are
and insurance coverage was less evident. On bal- many questions still to be answered. What is the
ance, it was found that the degree of adverse selec- prevalence of ‘hit and run’ and ‘hit and stay’ member-
tion in the pool of privately insured single adults ship? The former is temporary membership by
increased over time. those anticipating/planning a medical procedure;
Changes in the demand for private insurance the latter, membership by those reaching (older)
among families between 1989 and 95 also suggest age groups where there is an increasing likelihood
an increasing degree of adverse selection in the of the need for medical care. Both of these are
pool of the insured. Given the decline in the pro- manifestations of moral hazard. Related to this,
portion of those covered by insurance over the what determines the duration of fund membership,
period, the likelihood of a family being covered in and what is the prevalence of the ‘churning’ in the
1995 was more strongly (and positively) correlated market? How common is switching between funds
with the age, and number of recent health condi- and what are the determinants of such behaviour?
tions of the partner. Counteracting these effects What are the implications for private health insurers
were significant relationships between a lack of of the decline in fund membership due to the
private cover and the adult members of the family exit of long-term members and the increasing
296 ECONOMIC RECORD SEPTEMBER

importance of demographic groups that have rarely Cutler, D.M. and Zeckhauser (1998) ‘Adverse Selection in
had private cover (e.g. younger age groups, immigrants). Health Insurance’. In: Garber, A.M. (ed.) Frontiers in
With access to appropriate data, policy evalua- Health Policy Research, Vol. 1, The MIT Press, Cam-
tions may also be conducted to determine respon- bridge MA.
Greene, W.H. (1997) Econometric Analysis. Prentice Hall,
siveness of demand for insurance to a broad range New Jersey.
of factors (including tax and price incentives). Given Hopkins, S. and Kidd, M.P. (1996) ‘The Determinants of
the coalition government’s commitment to private the Demand for Private Health Insurance under Medi-
health insurance shown by the magnitude of subsidies care’. Applied Economics 28, 1623–32.
it currently provides for private cover ($2–3 billion Hurd, M.D. and McGarry, K. (1997) ‘Medical Insurance
each year), it would be useful to know just how and the Use of Health Care Services by the Elderly’.
effective the subsidies have been and the respon- Journal of Health Economics 16, 129–54.
siveness of consumers and potential consumers of Industry Commission (1997) Private Health Insurance,
insurance to changes in the policy regime. Industry Commission, Canberra.
Ngui, M.C., Burrows and Brown (1990) ‘Health Insurance
Choice: An Econometric Analysis of ABS Health and
REFERENCES Health Insurance Surveys’, in Selby Smith, C. (ed.) Eco-
nomics and Health: 1989 Proceedings of the Eleventh
Australian Institute for Health and Welfare (2001) Health Australian Conference of Health Economists, Public
Expenditure Bulletin no. 17, Catalogue HWE 18. Sector Management Institute, Monash University,
Australian Institute for Health and Welfare (2002) Health Clayton, Victoria.
Expenditure in Australia, Catalogue HWE 20. Owens, H. (1999) ‘Health Insurance’, in Mooney, G. and
Buchmueller, T. and DiNardo, J. (2002) ‘Did Community Scotton, R. (eds) Economics and Australian Health
Rating Induce an Adverse Selection Death Spiral? Evidence Policy, Allen & Unwin, St Leonards, NSW.
from New York, Pennsylvania and Connecticut’. American Propper, C. (1989) ‘An Econometric Analysis of the Demand
Economic Review 92, 280–94. for Private Health Insurance in England and Wales’,
Butler, J. (1999) Estimating Elasticities of Demand for Pri- Applied Economics 21, 777–92.
vate Health Insurance in Australia. National Centre for Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. (1976) ‘Equilibrium in Com-
Epidemiology and Population Health, ANU, Canberra. petitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics
Cameron, C. and McCallum (1995) ‘Private Health of Imperfect Information’, Quarterly Journal of Econom-
Insurance Choice in Australia: The Role of Long-Term ics 90, 630 – 49.
Utilisation of Health Services’, in Lapsley, H. (ed.) Savage, E. and Wright, D. (1999) ‘Health Insurance and
Economics and Health: 1995, Proceedings of the Seventeenth Health Care Utilization: Theory and Evidence from
Australian Conference of Health Economists, School of Australia 1989– 90’, Mimeograph, University of Sydney,
Health Services Management, University of New South Sydney.
Wales, Sydney. Schofield, D. (1996) ‘The Distribution and Determinants of
Cameron, C. and Trivedi, P. (1991) ‘The Role of Income Private Health Insurance in Australia in the 1990s’, in
and Health Risk in the Choice of Health Insurance’. Harris, A. (ed.) Economics and Health: 1996, Proceed-
Journal of Public Economics 45, 1–28. ings of the Eighteenth Australian Conference of Health
Cameron, C., Trivedi, P., Milne, F. and Piggott, J. (1988) ‘A Economists, School of Health Services Management,
Microeconometric Model of the Demand for Health Care University of New South Wales, Sydney
and Health Insurance in Australia’. Review of Economic Scotton, R.B. (1969) ‘Membership of Voluntary Health
Studies 55, 85–106. Insurance’. Economic Record 45, 69–83.
Cutler, D.M. and Reber, S.J. (1998) ‘Paying for Health Thomasson, M. (2002) Did Blue Cross and Blue Shield
Insurance: The Trade-off Between Competition and Suffer from Adverse Selection? Evidence from the 1950s,
Adverse Selection’. Quarterly Journal of Economics Working Paper No. 9167, National Bureau of Economic
113, 433–66. Research, Cambridge MA.
Copyright of Economic Record is the property of Wiley-Blackwell and its content may not be copied or emailed
to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However,
users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like