You are on page 1of 32

Chapter 2

Approaches to economic
geography

Topics covered in this chapter of cultural, institutional, evolutionary and


relational perspectives.
³ The development of economic geography as an ³ Our favoured approach, which can be
academic discipline. characterised as an open and plural
³ The main approaches adopted by economic
geographical political economy, informed by
geographers, covering: the insights generated by institutional and
evolutionary approaches.
O spatial analysis, emphasising scientific
methods and quantitative modelling;
O the ‘new economic geography’ based on
the application of economic methods to
2.1 Introduction
geographical questions;
A key starting point for this chapter is to recognise
O geographical political economy;
that no academic subject has a natural existence.
O ‘new’ approaches in economic geography,
Instead, as Trevor Barnes (2000) argues, subjects must
covering the key theoretical departures
since the 1990s, namely the development be ‘invented’ in the sense of being created by people
at particular times. Accordingly, the first economic

26
Approaches to economic geography

geography course was taught at Cornell University in itself as a strongly factual and practical enterprise
1893, the first English-language textbook, George G. (see section 2.2):
Chisholm’s Handbook of Commercial Geography, was
As a discipline it [EG] grew less out of concerns
published in 1889 and the journal Economic Geogra-
by economists to generalise and theorise, than the
phy established in 1925. The neighbouring discipline of
concerns of geographers to describe and explain the
economics was also established in the late nineteenth
individual economics of different places, and their
century, along with a number of other social sciences.
connections one to another.
From the start, however, the two disciplines assumed
(Barnes and Sheppard 2000: 2–3)
different characteristics.
Economics views the economy as governed by mar- The practical character of economic geography was
ket forces which basically operate in the same fashion established by commercial geography which was
everywhere, irrespective of time and space. The mar- highly prominent from the 1880s to the 1930s. This
ket is comprised of a multitude of buyers and sellers – was based on the ‘great geographical fact’ that different
the forces of demand and supply – who dictate how parts of the world yield different products, underpin-
scarce resources are allocated through their decisions ning the system of global commerce (Barnes 2000: 15).
about what to produce and consume. Mainstream The development of commercial geography was cru-
neoclassical economics is underpinned by the idea of cial in establishing economic geography as a distinct
‘economic “man”’, assuming that people act in a ratio- sub-discipline, helping to define many of its endur-
nal and self-interested manner, continually weighing ing characteristics such as an avoidance of theory, an
up alternatives on the basis of cost and benefits, almost emphasis on factual detail, a celebration of numbers
like calculating machines. The market is viewed as and a reliance on geographical categories made visi-
an essentially self-regulating mechanism, tending ble by the map (ibid.: 16). From the 1930s, however,
towards a state of equilibrium or balance through the the focus of economic geography “shifted from the
role of the price mechanism in mediating between the general commercial relations of a global system to the
forces of demand and supply (Figure 2.1). geography of narrowly bounded, unique regions, espe-
Whilst economics developed as a theoretical dis- cially those close to home” (ibid.: 18). This was the era
cipline adopting the methods of natural sciences like of regional geography, defined by Hartshorne (1939)
physics and chemistry, economic geography established as a project of ‘areal differentiation’ which describes
and interprets the variable character of the earth’s sur-
face, expressed through the identification of distinct
regions.
S More generally, a clear contrast can be drawn between
the formal and theoretical approach of mainstream neo-
classical economics and geography’s more open-ended
Price
ethos and more substantive concerns. Whilst geogra-
phy can be seen as synthetic in nature, focusing on the
relationships between, rather than the separation of,
D processes and things, mainstream economics is ana-
lytic, seeking to separate the economy from its social
and cultural context (Table 2.1). Key features of each of
Quantity
the first three approaches to economic geography exam-
ined in this chapter are set out in Table 2.2 (the four new
Figure 2.1 Demand and supply curves approaches are presented later), providing an important
Source: Lee 2002: 337. backdrop to the ensuing discussion.

27
Foundations

Table 2.1 Economics and economic geography

Mainstream neoclassical economics Economic geography

Nature of discipline Analytic, separate economy Synthetic, concerned with relations between
from context and into particular processes and things
components
Definition of the economy Autonomous sphere with its own Grounded in wider social, political and
rules and ‘laws’ cultural relations
Foundations of economic Rational actions of self-interested Individuals and groups acting in particular
processes individuals geographical contexts. Emphasis depends
upon particular approach adopted (Chapter 2)
Substantive concerns Workings of the economy and its The spatial distribution of economic
main components phenomena
Importance of geography Ignored, universal economic forces Fundamental, purpose of discipline
operate in the same way everywhere
View of uneven development A temporary phenomenon which will Tends to be persistent and deep-rooted
be eliminated by market forces

Table 2.2 Approaches to economic geography I

Spatial analysis New economic Geographical political


geography (NEG) economy (GPE)

Supporting philosophy Positivism (Box 2.1) Implicit positivism Dialectical materialisma


Main source of ideas Neoclassical economics Neoclassical Marxist economics, sociology
economics, revised to and history
accommodate imperfect
competition and
increasing returns
Conception of the Driven by rational choices Driven by rational Structured by social relations
economy of individual actors choices of individual of production. Driven by search
actors for profit and competition
Geographical orientation Wider forms of spatial Wider forces shaping Wider processes of capitalist
(place or wider processes) organisation economic landscape development
Geographical focus Urban regions in North Urban regions in North Major cities in industrial
America, Britain and America and Europe regions in Europe and North
Germany America. Cities and regions in
global South
Key research topics Industrial location; urban Industrial location, Urbanisation processes;
settlement systems; spatial agglomeration, industrial restructuring
diffusion of technologies; urbanisation in developed countries;
land use patterns global inequalities and
underdevelopment
Research methods Quantitative analysis based Mathematical modelling Reinterpretation of secondary
on survey results and data according to political-
secondary data economic categories.
Interviews and surveys
a
Dialectical means that social change is seen in terms of a struggle between opposing forces (Box 2.2). Materialism stresses the real social and economic conditions of
existence (production, labour, class relations, technology, resources) over ideas and culture, effectively privileging matter over mind.

28
Approaches to economic geography

2.2 Spatial analysis The new scientific geography spread to other depart-
ments in the US whilst the Universities of Cambridge
By the mid-1950s, considerable dissatisfaction was and Bristol became key centres in the UK in the 1960s.
being directed towards regional geography. A new gen- Progress was such that Burton (1963: 151) could pro-
eration of researchers increasingly came to reject the claim the ‘quantitative revolution’ complete, defined
idea that regional synthesis was the proper goal of geog- “as a radical transformation of the spirit and purpose
raphy, seeking to develop a more scientific approach. of geography”. Economic geography was at the fore-
The attack on the traditional establishment found par- front of this movement, viewed as an area that was
ticularly cogent expression in a 1953 paper by Fred K. particularly suited to the application of quantitative
Schaefer, who called for geographers to employ scien- methods.
tific methods in a search for general theories and laws Real world conditions were increasingly favourable
of location and spatial organisation (Scott 2000). This to this new approach in the late 1950s and 1960s as
argument drew directly on the established positivist policy-makers focused on economic and urban prob-
philosophy of science (Box 2.1). lems in developed countries, providing funds for
Schaefer’s philosophical arguments fitted with a research and a demand for academic analysis and advice.
new style of practical research being developed at A period of sustained economic growth and an under-
the Universities of Iowa and Washington, Seattle, lying faith in science and technology created an
where younger geographers were using statistical and optimistic ‘can do’ attitude with urban and regional
mathematical methods to analyse problems of indus- planning embraced as the means of addressing prob-
trial location, distance and movement (Barnes 2000). lems of location, land use management and transpor-
A vibrant spatial analysis research programme devel- tation. In this context, regional geography appeared
oped at Seattle, for example, focusing on issues of increasingly backward and anachronistic, with its tra-
industrial location and land use patterns, urbanisation ditionalist focus on rural areas and its concern with
and central place theory, transport networks and the description and classification offering little of practical
geographical dynamics of trade and social interaction. value to the planner or developer.

Box 2.1

Positivism

This is a philosophy of science orig- Positivism holds that a real world classic deductive method (moving
inally associated with the French exists independent of our knowledge from theory to practical research),
philosopher and sociologist Auguste of it. This real world has an under- scientists formulate hypotheses –
Comte (1798–1857) and devel- lying order and regularity which sci- formal statements of how a force or
oped further by the Vienna Circle of ence seeks to discover and explain. relationship is thought to operate in
thinkers in the 1920s and 1930s. Facts can be directly observed and the real world – which are then tested
It gained some acceptance as an analysed in a neutral manner. The against data collected by the scientist
account of the goals of natural sci- separation of fact and value is a through experiment or measurement.
ence in the post-war period, although central tenet of positivism; personal Hypotheses that are supported by ini-
specific aspects of it sparked debate. beliefs and positions should not influ- tial testing must then be verified or
Since the 1970s particularly, some ence scientific research. The aim of proved correct through objective and
social scientists (including many science is to generate explanatory replicable procedures. If verification
human geographers) have rejected laws which explain and predict events is successful, they gain the status of
positivism. and patterns in the real world. In the scientific laws.

29
Foundations

z data representing real world conditions. As one of the


pioneers of quantitative economic geography, Harold
McCarty of the University of Iowa, put it, “economic
C geography derives its concepts largely from the field
of economics and its method largely from the field of
geography” (McCarty 1940, quoted in Barnes 2000: 22).
The tradition of German location theory provided a
c
body of economic theory applied to geography that the
new economic geography of the 1950s and 1960s could
draw upon. The work of theorists such as Von Thunen,
Weber, Christaller and Losch was applied to the cir-
P cumstances of North America and the UK in the 1960s,
being used to explain and predict land use patterns, the
a b location of industry and the organisation of settlements
and market areas. Weber’s theory of industrial location
emphasised the importance of transport costs in deter-
M1 M2 mining where a factory or plant would be located in
x y
C = Point of consumption relation to the sources of raw materials and the market
M1 = Source of material 1 area, represented in terms of a locational triangle (Fig-
M2 = Source of material 2
ure 2.2). Point P is where the costs of transporting the
Figure 2.2 Weber’s locational triangle material to the factory and the finished goods to market
Source: Knox and Agnew 1994: 77.
are minimised. If the raw materials lost weight during
manufacturing, the factory would be drawn towards
Neoclassical economic theory provided a ready the material sources. If, on the other hand, distribution
source of concepts for quantitative economic geography costs were higher than the costs of transporting mate-
in the 1960s (Box 2.2). Geographers sought to apply the rials, the industry would be drawn towards its market.
same style of deductive theorising and analysis, moving Weber formulated this model in 1929, a time in which
from simplifying assumptions to the development and heavy industries based in coalfield regions dominated
testing of hypotheses and models against numerical the economic landscape.

Box 2.2

The neoclassical model of regional convergence

The neoclassical model of regional concerned with the movement of wages) are perfectly flexible; fac-
convergence has been influential in the relevant factors of production, tors of production are homogeneous
framing both analyses of regional capital and labour (given that land rather than comprised of different
disparities as well as discussion of is immobile), between regions. The types and groups; and the owner
policy solutions. Like neoclassical key simplifying assumptions that it and bearers of labour and capital are
economic theory more generally, makes include: markets are char- fully informed about factor prices in
it presents a simplified model that acterised by perfect competition, all regions (Armstrong and Taylor
focuses on the operation of a small constant not increasing returns to 2000: 141).
number of key variables, based on a scale in production; migration of Based upon these assumptions,
number of highly restrictive assump- labour and capital is costless and the model predicts that the movement
tions. In particular, the model is unrestricted; factor prices (e.g. of labour and capital between regions

30
Approaches to economic geography

Box 2.2 (continued)

will iron out regional disparities in The movements of labour and capi- again in the period of economic crisis
output or income and foster conver- tal are undoubtedly crucial factors in between 2008 and 2011 (European
gence in the long run. This occurs shaping regional difference, whilst Commission 2014: 3). This suggests
because labour and capital move in there is a discernible tendency for that if there is a trend toward regional
opposite directions (Pike et al. 2017: growth and in-migration to generate convergence, it is a slow and discon-
63). Initially, labour will flow from increasing costs in high-wage regions. tinuous one.
low-wage to high-wage regions. Over Yet the evidence for this bringing The disjuncture between the neo-
time, however, high-wage regions will about regional convergence is rather classical model and real world trends
tend to offer lower rates on return to mixed. From a historical perspective, can be explained by the unrealistic
capital (profits). Accordingly, capital a period of strong economic growth theories that the model is based on.
will flow out of high-wage regions and marked regional convergence In practice, migration is not cost-
to low-wage regions where costs in Western Europe gave way from the less, information is not fully avail-
are lower and returns are higher. mid-1970s to one of slower growth able and competition is not perfect.
This market adjustment mechanism and greater inequality (Dunford and Despite this, the model retains some
brings about regional convergence in Perrons 1994). More recently, regional influence among some economists
the long term. inequalities as measured by GDP and policy-makers, informing, for
The simplicity and clarity of this per head in the EU fell from 3.8 to instance, the World Bank’s expecta-
model help to explain its influence in 2.5 times higher in the 20 per cent tions of long-run regional convergence
informing research and policy. It does most developed regions compared to in developing countries after a period
identify some of the key forces and the 20 per cent least developed ones of divergence in its World Develop-
trends shaping regional disparities. between 2000 and 2008, only to rise ment Report 2009 (see Box 2.3).

Theoretical system of regional centres

Plauen Grading of centres


L

P
Wiesbaden G
Frankfurt
Mainz B
K
Darmstadt
Prague A
M
Mannheim
Heidelberg Nuremburg K. 21-km ring
(schematic)
Metz
B. Ring
Saarbrucken Regensburg L. Systems
Karlsruhe
Principal & interconnection
Straubing Secondary of L centres

Saarburg
Strasbourg Passau
Stuttgart
Landshut
Augsburg
Ulm

0 10 20 30 40 Miles
Freiburg Munich 0 20 40 60 Km

Mulhouse Salzburg

Basle

St Gothard
Zurich
Innsbruck

Figure 2.3 Central places in southern Germany


Source: Christaller 1966: 224–5.

31
Foundations

Perhaps the best known of the German locational industrial location and urbanisation. In 2008, Krug-
models is Christaller’s central place theory. Based on man was awarded the Nobel Prize for economics for his
the assumption of economic rationality and the exis- work on economic geography and international trade.
tence of certain geographical conditions such as uni- The NEG applies the methods of mainstream
form population distribution across an area, central economics, devising models based on a number of
place theory offers an account of the size and distribu- simplifying assumptions, described as “silly but con-
tion of settlements within an urban system. The need venient” (Krugman 2000: 51). It retains much of the
for shop owners to select central locations produces a basic architecture of neoclassical economics, requiring
hexagonal network of central places, organised into a explanations that are based in the rational decisions of
distinct hierarchy of lower- and higher-order centres individual actors, what economists call microfounda-
(Figure 2.3). tions. For the first time, however, patterns of industrial
The so-called quantitative revolution transformed location could be modelled from these microfounda-
the nature of economic geography “from a field-based, tions. This breakthrough was made possible because
craft form of inquiry to a desk-bound technical one in economics was now able to incorporate imperfect com-
which places were often analysed from afar . . .” (Barnes petition through a model developed by Dixit and Stiglitz
2001: 553). Instead of directly observing and mapping in 1977. Rather than assuming perfect competition, this
regions in the field, economic geographers now tended model recognised that some markets can be dominated
to use secondary information and statistical methods by a limited number of powerful firms. This is import-
to analyse patterns of spatial organisation from their ant from an economic geography perspective since this
desks. While not all practitioners of economic geogra- monopoly power creates increasing returns for these
phy adopted the new methods, spatial analysis came to firms. Increasing returns essentially refer to economies
occupy centre-stage with those who refused to follow its of scale where additional investment in production
approach increasingly relegated to the sidelines (ibid.). capacity generates increased profits. This can again be
By the late 1960s, however, the mood was changing contrasted with neoclassical economics which assumed
again with a growing number of geographers beginning that decreasing or constant returns were the norm,
to question ‘the spirit and purpose’ of this new quanti- equating to no economies of scale (Figure 2.4). Inter-
tative geography (see section 2.4). estingly, the NEG dealt with transportation costs – a
key issue in economic geography and regional science –
through an ‘iceberg’ metaphor whereby it is assumed
2.3 The new economic that part of the good simply ‘melts away’ in transit,
geography
Historically, economists have not been very interested Increasing Returns
Output Y

in geography, viewing it as rather irrelevant to their goal Constant Returns


of understanding the general working of the economy.
This began to change in the early 1990s as the prom-
inent economist Paul Krugman started to apply eco- Decreasing Returns
nomic methods and tools to the analysis of economic
geography topics. Krugman termed this new approach
the ‘new economic geography’ (NEG), although many
economic geographers argued that it should more accu-
rately be called the ‘new geographical economics’ as it
represented a new form of geographically oriented eco-
nomics. The field has grown rapidly as it has attracted Input X
many economists to apply mathematical modelling Figure 2.4 Returns to scale
techniques to questions of uneven development, Source: FAO 2010: 10.

32
Approaches to economic geography

simplifying the model by avoiding the need to include The NEG has become increasingly influential
transport as an additional industry. with policy-makers and at both the international and
NEG models assess the tension between the forces national scales, as demonstrated by its wholesale adop-
in the economic landscape that encourage geographical tion in the World Bank’s World Development Report 2009
concentration in one or more regions and those favour- (Box 2.3). In part, this reflects the ability of its math-
ing the geographical dispersal of production to a large ematical, model-based approaches to address ‘what
number of locations. Centripetal forces favouring geo- if ’ questions in the sense of how economic outcomes
graphical concentration are identified as the effects of might be changed by altering underlying parameters
market size, a large and specialised labour market and or decisions, offering potential guidance to policy-
access to information from other firms located there. makers (Krugman 2011). At the same time, the deductive
The main centrifugal forces encouraging dispersal, approach of the NEG provides a rather narrow account
conversely, are immobile factors of production such of uneven development, concentrating only on a small
as land and, to a considerable extent, labour, and the number of variables that can be measured and modelled.
costs of concentration such as congestion. Much actual In particular, it concentrates on the most tangible loca-
research has been devoted to assessing the interaction tion factors such as economies of scale, transport costs
between these forces under different conditions. Small and market size, ignoring the more invisible or intangi-
changes in, for example, transport costs or technology ble sources of geographical concentration, particularly
can ‘tip’ the economy from a pattern of dispersal to one information spillovers, learning and informal relations
of concentration. The typical outcome of concentration between firms. This is highly problematic since the lat-
processes will be a simple core-periphery pattern whilst ter have become probably the most important sources
dispersal will create a number of specialised and rela- of spatial concentration and uneven development in the
tively evenly sized centres of industry. For Krugman world today as transport costs have fallen and interna-
and many other proponents of the NEG, this provided tional connections have growth (Storper 2011).
a plausible explanation of real world patterns such as The new economic geography, therefore, focuses
the development of the US manufacturing belt in the on the same basic questions which have long inter-
north-east and Midwest in the nineteenth century (Fig- ested economic geographers, but adopts a distinctive
ure 3.10) and the emergence of a clear core-periphery approach based on the methods of economics. For many
pattern in China in recent decades (Box 1.3). economic geographers, it is simply a more sophisticated

Box 2.3

Reshaping economic geography: the World Development Report 2009

In the World Development Report between the geographical areas in The ‘main message’ of the Report
(WDR) 2009, the World Bank used which economic activity is concen- is that economic growth will inev-
the NEG both to frame its analy- trated and the areas that are lagging itably be unbalanced and that
sis of development conditions and behind. Division is relevant in terms this should be accepted since any
trends and identify broad policy of the effects of economic borders attempt to spread out economic
directions. It was structured by a and divisions in relation to national activity (for example through regional
3D perspective of density, distance markets, distinct regulations and policies) will discourage it (ibid.: xvi).
and division (World Bank 2009). separate currencies. While density Three principal drivers of balanced
Density refers to the concentration is most prevalent at the local scale, growth are discussed in the second
of people and firms in space, best distance is associated with the part of the report – the market forces
represented by the growth of cities. (intra) national scale and division of agglomeration, migration, and spe-
Distance is related to the distance with the international. cialisation and trade. The WDR 2009

33
Foundations

Box 2.3 (continued)

argues that unbalanced growth is still regional integration between coun- omitted entirely from the report while
compatible with inclusive develop- tries (for example Western and East- the role of institutions and policy is
ment through economic integration ern Europe, South America, southern simply to facilitate the role of the
to ensure that people who are ini- Africa) to increase market size and market forces promoting economic
tially located in places distant from foster specialisation. integration. Characteristically, the
economic opportunity will benefit. Despite its geographical focus economistic vision of the WDR 2009
This is dependent on the promotion and the wealth of interesting data ignores the more critical work of
of three main sets of policies: urban- and analysis it contained, the WDR geographers and other social scien-
isation which should be encouraged 2009 was not universally welcomed tists (Rigg et al. 2009). As such, it is
by governments through the provision by geographers. The narrow and testament to both the power and the
of effective institutions, connected definitive picture of development pre- limitations of the NEG as a research
infrastructure and some limited tar- sented in the WDR 2009 echoes the programme in economic geography,
geted interventions to improve poor abstract ‘bird’s eye’ view offered by offering a simplified and compelling
neighbourhoods and slums; territo- the NEG, isolating a few key forces vision of economic development, but
rial development that is designed to without any appreciation of geograph- one that fails to learn the broader les-
integrate all areas, particularly by ical complexity and context (Storper sons of development from the Euro-
encouraging the mobility of people 2011). The social and environmen- pean and North American experience
from lagging to growing areas; and tal origins and effects of poverty are (Storper 2011).

version of the spatial analysis popular in the 1960s, origins lie in the classical political economy of Adam
sharing its underlying limitations and generating “a dull Smith and David Ricardo in the late eighteenth and
sense of déjà vu” (Martin 1999: 70). As indicated above, nineteenth centuries, becoming most associated with
a particular weakness is the characteristic tendency to Marx’s radical critique and reformulation of their work
“focus on what is easier to model rather than on what is (Box 2.4). Geographical political economy (GPE)
probably most important in practice” (Krugman 2000: emerged in the 1970s as geographers sought to apply
59). At the same time, whilst this approach can never the insights of Marxist political economy to questions
hope to capture the complexity and richness of the real of urban and regional restructuring and change. It pro-
economic landscape, its analytical clarity, use of general vides a broad and powerful approach to the economy
models and sense of purpose does perhaps carry some that views capitalism as just one form of economic
lessons for economic geography proper (Storper 2011). organisation (albeit a dominant one), sees geography
as actively produced through the development and
restructuring of the economy, and emphasises the need
Reflect to link economic relations to parallel bio-physical,
social and cultural processes (Sheppard 2011).
Do you think that economic geographers should adopt
similar methods and perspectives to economists or
should they seek to differentiate themselves?
2.4.1 The origins of GPE
In the late 1960s and early 1970s, quantitative economic
2.4 Geographical political geography was subject to criticism for its lack of social
economy relevance and concern (section 2.2). To a new genera-
tion of geographers, it seemed as if the discipline was
Political economy should be seen as a broad frame- narrowly focused on technical issues of urban and
work of analysis, encompassing a range of strands and regional planning to the neglect of deeper questions
traditions, rather than as a single theory or concept. Its about how society was organised. The key issues here

34
Approaches to economic geography

were racial divisions in US cities, the Vietnam War


(symbolising the imperialism of US foreign policy), Thesis
gender inequalities and the rediscovery of poverty in
inner city ghettos. Geography remained largely silent
about such questions, leading Harvey (1973) to call for
a revolution in geographic thought:

The quantitative revolution has run its course, and


diminishing marginal returns are apparently setting Synthesis Antithesis
in . . . There is an ecological problem, an urban
problem, an international trade problem, and yet
we seem incapable of saying anything of depth or
profundity about any of them.
(Harvey 1973: 128–9) Figure 2.5 Dialectics
Source: Johnston and Sidaway 2004: 231.

In response to these pressing social issues, a group of


characterised by continual change and flux, driven by the
geographers in the US particularly sought to fashion a
search for profits in the face of competition:
new radical geography. This movement began at Clark
University in Massachusetts, where a group of post- The bourgeoisie [capitalists] cannot exist with-
graduate students, led by Richard Peet, launched Anti- out constantly revolutionising the instruments of
pode: A Radical Journal of Geography in 1969. production, and thereby the relations of produc-
This radical new geography turned to political econ- tion, and with them the whole relations of soci-
omy for its intellectual foundations. The work of Marx in ety . . . Constant revolutionising of production,
particular provided a framework for the critical analysis uninterrupted disturbance of all social conditions,
of advanced capitalism. Once again, economic geogra- everlasting uncertainty and agitation distinguish
phy was at the forefront of these developments. In gen- the bourgeois epoch from all earlier ones. All fixed,
eral, Marxism emphasises processes and relationships fast-frozen relations . . . are swept away, all new
rather than fixed things, adopting a dialectical perspec- formed ones become antiquated before they can
tive which sees change as driven by the tensions between ossify. All that is solid melts into air, all that is holy
opposing forces, usually in the form of thesis – antithesis – is profaned . . .
synthesis (Figure 2.5). Capitalist society in particular is (Marx and Engels [1848] 1967: 83)

Box 2.4

The political economy tradition and the origins of a Marxist approach

It is important to set Marx’s contri- (Figure 2.5). During the 1840s, dramatic changes that were sweeping
bution to political economy within however, he became increasingly society in the mid-nineteenth century
its historical context. Born in 1817, concerned with economic issues, fas- (Dowd 2000).
Marx’s early academic career was cinated by the rise of industrial and Smith, whose great work The
as a student of German philosophy, urban society. His big theoretical Wealth of Nations was published in
influenced by Hegel’s dialectical project, culminating in the three vol- 1776 and Ricardo, whose Principles
approach, in which human rela- umes of Capital, became one of revis- of Political Economy and Taxation
tions are conceived in terms of the ing the classical political economy of appeared in 1817, were great advo-
struggle between opposing forces Smith and Ricardo to understand the cates of the market and free trade.

35
Foundations

Box 2.4 (continued)

Smith’s guiding philosophy was eighteenth-century enlightenment of capital (money, factories and
that greater wealth would accrue to which sought to overthrow the ancien equipment), creating a class of cap-
the community of nations if govern- regime and which influenced the italists and a class of labourers who
ments desisted from intervening in French Revolution and American War must sell their labour in exchange for
the economy. Ricardo argued that a of Independence. Whilst Marx, writ- a wage. The difference between the
system of international trade without ing over half a century after Smith, value of what the labourer actually
tariffs (import taxes) would encourage also recognised that capitalism was produces and what he/she is paid in
much greater efficiency since each more progressive than feudal soci- wages is retained and accumulated
country would specialise and produce ety, unlike Smith he was able to wit- by the capitalist as surplus value
goods that they were relatively more ness the negative consequences of or profit, representing the basis for
efficient at, therefore benefiting the industrial capitalism. The growth of class exploitation. The development
broader commonwealth of nations the factory system, mass urbanisa- of factories under capitalism brings
(Box 3.3). tion and the development of a large large numbers of workers together
Both, however, were writing during industrial working class, many living in industrial cities, providing them
the very early stages of industrial in conditions of appalling poverty with the means of organising against
capitalism when feudalism allied to and squalor, had transformed Smith’s the system that exploits them. When
mercantilism – national protectionism – capitalist utopia into William Blake’s coupled with the inevitable over-
were viewed as impediments to social ‘dark satanic mills’. production that would result from the
progress. For Smith, the development According to Marx, class struggle is continual expansion of production,
of market relations and competition the basic driving force of history, from driven by competition, the growing
would produce a more progressive the relations of master and slave, to power of the working class would
and equal society than feudalism, feudal lord and serf to capitalist and eventually bring down the system and
liberating the individual from tradi- labourer. Under the capitalist mode usher in a new socialist era. In this
tional social bonds. In this sense, of production, class relations are way, capitalism acts as its own grave-
he was very much in tune with the structured by the private ownership digger (Dowd 2000: 87).

From this perspective, particular geographical objects, The first phase of Marxist geography concentrated
for example cities or a transport system, exist as an on establishing how capitalism produces specific geo-
expression of wider relationships and are subject to graphical landscapes (Smith 2001). In The Limits to
transformation through the movement of broader Capital, Harvey (1982) identified a central contradic-
forces of change. tion between the geographical fixity and motion of cap-
ital. There is a need, on the one hand, for fixity of capital
2.4.2 The development of in one place for a sustained period, creating a built envi-
ronment of factories, offices, houses, transport infra-
Marxist theory
structures and communication networks that enables
Whilst the writings of Marx provided only a few scat- production to take place. Such fixity is countered by
tered comments and insights into the geography of the need for capital to remain mobile, on the other
capitalism, Marxist geographers such as David Har- hand, enabling firms to respond to changing economic
vey have sought to build on these by developing a conditions by seeking out more profitable locations
distinctively Marxist analysis of geographical change (Box 2.5). This may require them to withdraw from
(Box 2.5). From this perspective, the economic landscape existing centres of production in which they have
is shaped by the conflict-laden relationship between invested heavily. Capital is never completely mobile, but
capital and labour, mediated by the state, providing a must put down roots in particular places to be effec-
stark contrast to the harmonious equilibrium state of tively deployed. Nonetheless, its relative mobility lends
regional balance posited by neoclassical economic capital an important spatial advantage over labour
theory (Box 2.2). which is more place-bound.

36
Approaches to economic geography

Harvey argues that capital overcomes the friction of obsolete and redundant in the face of more attractive
space or distance through the production of space in investment opportunities elsewhere. In these circum-
the form of a built environment that enables production stances, capital is likely to abandon existing centres of
and consumption to occur. Indeed, such investment in production and establish a new ‘spatial fix’ involving
the built environment can act as a ‘spatial fix’ to capi- investment in different regions (Box 2.5). The deindus-
talism’s inherent tendency towards over-production by trialisation of many established centres of production
absorbing excess capital, performing an important dis- in the ‘rustbelts’ of North America and Western Europe
placement function. As economic conditions change, since the late 1970s and the growth of new industry in
however, these infrastructures can themselves become ‘sunbelt’ regions and the newly industrialising coun-
a barrier to further expansion, appearing increasingly tries of East Asia can be understood in this light.

Box 2.5

Neil Smith’s ‘see-saw’ theory of uneven development

One of the most notable contribu- rising land prices, lower unemploy- urban scale at which capital is most
tions to Marxist economic geogra- ment and the development of trade mobile, resulting in, for example,
phy is Neil Smith’s theory of uneven unions, reducing profit rates. In other the rapid gentrification (upgrading
development. Processes of uneven regions, underdevelopment leads to through the attraction of investment
development, according to Smith, low wages, high unemployment and and new middle-class residents) of
are the result of a dialectic of spatial the absence of trade unions, creating previously declining inner city areas
differentiation and equalisation that a basis for profit that attracts capital like Glasgow’s Merchant City (Figure
is central to the logic of capitalism, investment. Over time, capital will 2.6). Conversely, patterns of uneven
transforming the complex mosaic ‘see-saw’ from developed to under- development exhibit most stability
of landscapes inherited from pre- developed areas, ‘jumping’ between at the global scale where the divide
capitalist systems. Capital moves to locations in its efforts to maintain between developed and developing
the areas which offer highest profits profit levels. It is this movement countries remains as wide as ever,
for investors, resulting in the economic of capital that creates patterns of although East Asia has risen to the
development of these areas. The geo- uneven development. In this sense, core of the world economy through
graphical concentration of production “capital is like a plague of locusts. It sustained economic growth since
in such locations results in differenti- settles on one place, devours it, then the 1960s.
ation as they experience rapid devel- moves on to plague another place”
opment whilst other regions are left (Smith 1984: 152).
behind. As a result, living standards According to Smith,
and wage rates vary markedly between the production of
regions and, especially, countries. At space under capital-
the same time, the tendency towards ism leads to the emer-
equalisation reflects the importance gence of three primary
of expanding the market for goods geographical scales of
and services, implying a need to economic and politi-
develop newly incorporated colonies cal organisation: the
and territories so as to generate the urban, the national
income to underpin consumption. and the global. The
Over time, the process of eco- dynamic nature of
nomic development in a particular the uneven develop- Figure 2.6 Urban gentrification in Glasgow
region tends to undermine its own ment process is most Source: RCAHMS Enterprises: Resource for Urban Design
foundations, leading to higher wages, pronounced at the Information (RUDI). Licensor www.scran.ec.uk.

37
Foundations

Although Marxist and neoclassical economic theo- is the cloning branch plant, where the whole process of
ries are polar opposites in many respects, there is some production takes place at each site and only manage-
overlap in their accounts of uneven regional develop- ment functions are stretched over space. Second, part
ment (see Box 2.2). They both emphasise the movement process production is defined by the separation of the
of capital and labour to more developed regions and the production process as well as management, such that
tendency for rising costs in such regions to trigger sub- different functions are carried out in different places.
sequent flows of capital towards less developed regions Only one specific part is concentrated in each plant.
where costs are lower. While the neoclassical model Each one of these two types of industrial organisa-
sees this as resulting in regional convergence in the long tion results in a different pattern of uneven develop-
term, the Marxist approach views it as part of periodic ment and regional inequality. Typically, headquarters
processes of economic restructuring, generating shift- functions were located in core regions such as south-
ing patterns of uneven regional development. east England or New York where there were supplies
The second phase of Marxist geography began in of qualified ‘white collar’ labour, whilst more skilled
the early 1980s, concentrating on developing Marxist production work tended to be concentrated in estab-
analyses of specific situations and circumstances. One lished manufacturing regions like the West Midlands of
key research question was how particular places were England or Midwest of the US, and routine assembly
affected by wider processes of economic restructuring. was relocated to peripheral regions such as north-east
In a landmark text, Doreen Massey (1995) investigated England or the US south in the 1970s on the basis of
the changing location of industry in Britain, develop- their lower-cost supplies of labour. More recently, of
ing the concept of ‘spatial divisions of labour’. This course, it has become clear that production is not just
emphasised how unequal social relations are played out reorganised within firms on a national basis, but also
across space, particularly in terms of how capital seeks between firms on a global basis with many leading
to exploit geographical differences in the supply, skills electronics firms, for example, concentrating routine
and costs of labour. From this perspective, regional production and assembly in developing countries like
inequality reflects the relationships between regions China (section 3.5).
and the roles that they play in the wider capitalist econ-
omy, not just their internal characteristics as in tradi-
tional theories. At the same time, local conditions also 2.4.3 The regulation
shape the broader process and relations as geography,
approach
in the form of regional differentiation, becomes inter-
nal to the workings of the economy as part of firms’ Another strand of Marxist-informed research which
investment and decision-making criteria. was very influential in economic geography during the
The theory of spatial divisions of labour reflects a 1990s is the regulation approach. Derived from the
move away from the traditional model of local firms, work of a group of French economists in the 1970s,
where all production functions were locally concen- the regulation approach stresses the important role that
trated in the same area (Figure 2.7). The other two wider processes of social regulation play in stabilising
models reflect the spatial stretching of production over and sustaining capitalist development. These wider
time, underpinned by the growth of large corporations processes of regulation find expression in specific insti-
and advanced transportation and communication sys- tutional arrangements which mediate and manage the
tems. These two types of spatial structure involve the underlying contradictions of the capitalist system (see
separation of production functions over space, partic- Chapter 3), expressed in the form of periodic crises,
ularly in the division between headquarters activities enabling renewed growth to occur. This occurs through
(investment, supervision and control) and routine the coming together and consolidation of specific
work. This was evident in the growth of branch plants modes of regulation, referring to the institutions and
in the shape of factories performing specific production conventions which shape the process of capitalist devel-
tasks on behalf of the wider corporation. The first type opment. Regulation is focused on five key aspects of

38
Approaches to economic geography

1. The locationally-concentrated spatial structure

all administration all administration all administration


and control and control and control

total process of total process of total process of


production production production

(No intra-firm hierarchies)

2. The cloning branch-plant spatial structure

branch administration
and control

total process of
HQ administration production
and control

total process of
production branch administration
and control

total process of
production

(Hierarchy of relations of ownership and possession only)

3. The part-process spatial structure

HQ administration branch administration branch administration


and control and control and control

one part of one part of one part of


production process production process production process
only only only

(Plants distinguished and connected by place both in relations of ownership and possession and
in the technical division of labour)

Figure 2.7 Examples of possible spatial structures


Source: Massey 1995: 75.

39
Foundations

capitalism in particular: labour and the wage relation, ‘post-Fordist’ regime of accumulation based on flexible
forms of competition and business organisation, the production became prominent in the 1980s. Theories
monetary system, the state and the international regime of post-Fordism emphasise the role of small firms,
(Boyer 1990). When these act in concert, a period of advanced information and communication technol-
stable growth, known as a regime of accumulation, ogies and more segmented and individualised forms
ensues. of consumption (Chapter 11). Whether these features
Two regimes of accumulation can be identified since amount to a distinctive and coherent regime of accu-
the 1940s (Table 2.3). After the global economic depres- mulation remains questionable, however, with mass
sion of the 1930s, a new regime of Fordism emerged, production remaining important in some sectors. One
named after the American car manufacturer, Henry key trend has been the abandonment of Keynesian pol-
Ford, who pioneered the introduction of mass pro- icies since the 1970s in favour of a neoliberal approach
duction techniques. Fordism was based on a crucial which seeks to reduce state intervention in the econ-
link between mass production and mass consumption, omy and embrace the free market, stressing the virtues
provided by rising wages for workers and increased of enterprise, competition and individual self-reliance.
productivity in the workplace. The state adopted an
interventionist approach, informed by the theories of 2.4.4 The relevance and
the British economist John Maynard Keynes which value of Marxist political
stressed the important role of government in managing
the overall level of demand in the economy to secure
economy
full employment. By the late 1980s, Marxist geography was becoming
Fordism experienced mounting economic problems subject to increasing criticism, informed by the emer-
from the early 1970s, however, and elements of a new gence of postmodern thought (Box 2.7). Marxism

Table 2.3 Fordist and post-Fordist modes of regulation

Fordism Post-Fordism

The wage-relation Rising wages in exchange for productivity Flexible labour markets based on
gains. Full recognition of trade union rights. individual’s position in market. Limited
System of national collective bargaining recognition of trade unions
Forms of competition Dominance of large corporations. Key role of small- and medium-sized
and business Nationalization of key sectors such as enterprises (SMEs) alongside large
organization utilities corporations. Privatization of state
enterprises and general liberalization
of the economy
The monetary system Monetary policy focused on demand Focus on reducing inflation, relying on high
management and maintaining full interest rates if necessary. International
employment. Use of interest rates to monetary integration and coordination, for
facilitate economic expansion and example the European single currency
contraction
The state Highly interventionist. Adoption of Reduce state intervention in the economy.
Keynesian policies of demand management. Abandonment of Keynesian policies for
Provision of social services through welfare neoliberalism. Efforts to reduce welfare
state. Goals of full employment and modest expenditure and privatize services
income redistribution
The international Cold War division into capitalist and Increased global economic integration.
regime communist blocs. Bretton Woods system of System of floating exchange rates. Renewed
fixed exchange rates, anchored to the US emphasis on free trade and openness to
dollar. Promotion of free trade, monetary foreign investment. Imposition of neoliberal
stabilization and ‘Third World’ development adjustment policies on developing countries

40
Approaches to economic geography

seemed to have also become rather out of touch with These are important criticisms, although it is ques-
the ‘new times’ of the 1980s, marked by the dominance tionable whether Marxist geography really was as
of neoliberal ideas, particularly in the UK and US. In economically determinist as its critics allege (Hudson
the realm of left-wing politics too, the focus was shift- 2006). We do not think that they mean that GPE is no
ing from the traditional ‘politics of distribution’ con- longer relevant or useful and should be abandoned
cerned with work, wages and welfare to a ‘politics of (Box 2.6). It remains influential in economic geography,
identity’ promoting the rights of various groups such with some of its key arguments around the unstable and
as women, ethnic minorities and gay people to rec- crisis-prone character of capitalism as a mode of produc-
ognition and justice (Crang 1997). Such claims were tion, the inseparability of the economy from the social,
channelled through broader social movements rather political and ecological spheres, and the need to relate
than the traditional labour movement. regional problems to wider processes of uneven devel-
Three main criticisms of Marxism in geography can opment continuing to be accepted by many researchers
be identified: in the field. In many respects, the relevance of GPE has
been reinforced by the post-2008 financial crisis and
³ Its apparent neglect of human agency in terms of an
recession, emphasising the unequal impact of these epi-
impoverished view of individuals and a failure to
sodes on particular groups of people and places.
recognise human autonomy and creativity. Instead,
Partly in response to the above criticisms and reflect-
Marxists tend to privilege wider social forces such
ing its encounters with other contemporary perspectives
as class and see people as bearers of class pow-
such as the cultural ‘turn’, institutionalism, and evolu-
ers and identities, reading off their behaviour
tionary economic geography, GPE has become increas-
from this.
ingly diffuse and plural in the 1990s and beyond. This
³ Its emphasis on economic forces and relations. draws attention to the diverse strands of research that
Whilst the Marxist concept of production is, as we GPE continues to inform, often alongside other theo-
have seen, much broader than conventional notions retical influences, making it harder to identify a single
of the economy, Marxists have been criticised for school of GPE compared to the 1980s and early 1990s
stressing the determining role of economic forces. (Jones 2015). These other theories and approaches have
Culture and ideas are often viewed as products of helped to raise important new questions about knowl-
this economic base. edge, identity, evolution and practice, whilst also shed-
³ Its overwhelming emphasis on class, and neglect ding new light on older economic geography questions
of other social categories like gender and race. such as agglomeration and the sources of urban and
Leading Marxists such as Harvey were attacked regional growth. As such, the approach that we adopt
by feminist geographers in the early 1990s for in this book is best characterised as an ‘open’ and plural
their neglect of gender issues, which they were version of GPE that is responsive to the evolution of cap-
accused of subsuming within a class-based Marxist italism as its main object of analysis and receptive to the
analysis. insights offered by other perspectives (Box 2.6).

Box 2.6

Is Marxist-informed GPE still relevant?

In the 1980s and 1990s, a wholesale West and the collapse of commu- the ‘end of history’ by the conservative
abandonment of Marxist and socialist nism in the Soviet Union and Eastern American writer Francis Fukuyama in
thinking occurred in the face of the Europe. The fall of the Berlin Wall in the sense that liberal democracy and
upsurge of neoliberal thinking in the 1989 was heralded as bringing about market capitalism had won the battle

41
Foundations

Box 2.6 (continued)

of ideas over socialism. The spirit of short-lived, listeners voted Marx the retains a sense of social and political
market triumphalism associated with greatest philosopher of all time in commitment, emphasising issues of
globalisation in the 1990s has, how- a BBC Radio 4 poll in 2005. The inequality and injustice and the need
ever, subsequently been punctured late British Marxist historian, Eric to change the world as well as inter-
as the limitations of global capital- Hobsbawm, explained this in terms pret it.
ism have been highlighted by the of the “stunning prediction of the At the same time, we recognise
anti-globalisation movement and the nature and effects of globalisation” that GPE does not hold all the
2008 financial crisis and subsequent found in The Communist Manifesto answers, containing several limita-
recession. (quoted in Seddon 2005). tions and weaknesses. This points
As part of the more sober climate We believe that GPE is still rele- to the need for a modified approach
of the late 1990s and early 2000s, vant because of its value as a holistic which can incorporate insights from
Marx was rediscovered. Triggered by framework for understanding the evo- other sources, particularly the cul-
the 150th anniversary of the publi- lution of the global capitalist system. tural, institutional and evolutionary
cation of The Communist Manifesto Marx’s primary contribution to knowl- perspectives that economic geogra-
in 1998 and the financial crises edge was as an analyst of capitalism phers have turned towards over the
then engulfing East Asia and Russia, not as an architect of communism. past couple of decades (section 2.5).
“impeccably bourgeois magazines” Whilst he offered only a few scat- In particular, these approaches can
such as the Financial Times and New ted comments about geography, this provide a stronger sense of agency,
Yorker published articles heralding has been rectified by Marxist geog- recognition of the social and insti-
Marx’s thought (Smith 2001: 5). raphers like Harvey and Smith who tutional construction of markets,
Writing in the New Yorker, John have developed theories of uneven sensitivity towards difference and
Cassidy praised Marx as the ‘next development. In the absence of other concern with the evolution of cities
big thinker’, citing his relevance to approaches which can match its his- and regions. In short, we favour an
the workings of the global financial torical-geographical reach and analyt- open and plural GPE which does not
system and stating that his analy- ical purchase, GPE provides the most claim to have a monopoly on truth,
ses will be worth reading “as long suitable framework for analysing the is receptive to insights from other
as capitalism endures” (quoted in ‘big questions’ concerning the eco- perspectives and which evolves in
Rees 1998). Although Wall Street’s nomic geography of global capital- line with capitalism as its object of
discovery of Marx was predictably ism (Swyngedouw 2000). GPE also analysis.

economic processes. These approaches derive the-


Reflect oretical inspiration from various sources, including
postmodernism, post-structuralism, cultural studies,
Do you agree that GPE is still relevant to the analysis anthropology, economic sociology and institutional
of the uneven development of the capitalist economy? and evolutionary economics. In general, they have
served to direct attention towards questions of differ-
ence, embeddedness, evolution and practice that were
previously marginalised and neglected within economic
2.5 New approaches in geography. These ‘new’ approaches remain distinct
economic geography from the NEG by emerging within the sub-discipline
of economic geography proper rather than economics.
A new set of approaches have emerged in economic To a considerable extent, these ‘new’ approaches
geography since the early 1990s, emphasising the cul- in economic geography have been defined against
tural, institutional and evolutionary foundations of the ‘old’ economic geography of spatial analysis and

42
Approaches to economic geography

Marxian political economy. These perspectives have reflecting the increasingly hybrid and fast-moving
been variously criticised for ignoring the wider social nature of the field. They are often characterised as
and cultural practices which shape economic life and ‘turns’ in economic geography that involve a reorien-
for viewing economic actors in essentialist and reduc- tation of the field (or, at least, significant parts of it),
tionist ways – a critique that could be extended to the towards a fresh set of concepts and research questions.
NEG. These new approaches have not always remained Four such ‘turns’ are discussed in the remainder of this
separate from work in GPE, however, despite their ini- section: cultural economic geography, institutional eco-
tial counter-posing, with important areas of overlap nomic geography, evolutionary economic geography
and cross-fertilisation developing as indicated above, and relational economic geography (Table 2.4).

Table 2.4 Approaches to economic geography II

Cultural economic Institutional economic Evolutionary economic Relational economic


geography geography geography (EEG) geography

Supporting Postmodernism, Institutionalism Evolutionary Post-structuralism,


philosophy post-structuralism, approaches in institutionalism,
feminism and post- natural and social actor-network
colonialism sciences approaches
Main source of ideas Cultural studies, Institutional Evolutionary Philosophy,
philosophy, literary economics, economic economics, biology economic
studies sociology sociology, science
and technology
studies
Conception of the Shaped by wider Importance of social Historically evolving Embedded in
economy social and cultural context. Informal sets of activities wider social and
relations conventions and and relations; driven economic relations
norms shape by innovation and and grounded in
economic action subject to path practice
dependence
Geographical Emphasis in Emphasis on Concerned with both Concerned with
orientation (place or individual places and individual places the broader evolution particular places
wider processes) sites in context of in context of of economic and sites in
wider relations globalisation landscapes and context of wider
adaptation of cities networks
and regions
Geographical focus Key sites of Growth regions in Largely confined to Diverse, case
consumption, global developed countries global North; strong studies from global
financial centres, European orientation North and South
workplaces
Key research topics Identity, Social and Path dependence Everyday activities
performance, institutional and lock-in; path through actor-
discourse, industrial foundations branching; the networks and
cultures of economic spatial evolution of communities of
development; industries; industrial practice; relational
territorial clusters cities and regions
embeddedness;
geographies of
knowledge
Research methods Interviews, focus Case studies Varied, covering both Case studies
groups, textual (interviews, surveys, quantitative analysis (interviews, surveys,
analysis, ethnography documentary analysis) and case studies ethnography)

43
Foundations

2.5.1 Cultural economic the importance of difference and variety and the
geography effects of broader social categories and discourses
(Box 2.7).
Cultural approaches in economic geography were In response to the broader cultural ‘turn’, some
inspired by the wider cultural ‘turn’ in human economic geographers have sought to adapt their
geography and the social sciences in the late 1980s interests, approaches and methods, incorporating
and 1990s, creating a ‘new cultural geography’. This notions of difference, identity and language into their
viewed culture as a process through which individu- research. The links between economy and culture
als and social groups make sense of the world, often are of central importance here with many observers
defining their identity against ‘other’ groups regarded agreeing that the economy has become increasingly
as different according to categories such as nationality, cultural in terms of the growing importance of sec-
race, gender and sexuality (Jackson 1989). Meaning is tors such as entertainment, retail and tourism whilst
generated through language which, instead of simply culture has become increasingly economic, viewed as
reflecting an underlying reality, actively creates that a set of commodities that can be bought and sold in
reality through discourses – networks of concepts, the market.
statements and practices that produce distinct bodies The adoption of cultural approaches in economic
of knowledge. The cultural turn has been closely tied geography has focused attention on the links between
to the rise of postmodernist and post-structuralist economic action and social and cultural practices in
philosophies which stress the fractured nature of indi- different places. As Wills and Lee (1997: xvii) put it,
vidual identities, the social construction of meaning, “the point is to contextualise rather than undermine

Box 2.7

Postmodernism

Postmodernist ideas have attracted uncover the changing organisation to a range of different phenomena
widespread interest since the 1980s, of society are rejected as a prod- including human groups and cul-
coming to exert considerable influ- uct of the privileged position and tures, buildings, urban neighbour-
ence in architecture, the humanities authority of the observer rather than hoods, texts and artistic products.
and the social sciences. Ley (1994: being accepted as objective repre- This basic attention to difference
466) defines postmodernism as “a sentations of the realities that they quickly attracted the interest of
movement in philosophy, the arts purport to explain. Instead of func- geographers, reflecting the fact that
and social sciences characterised by tioning as a set of universal truths, “the discipline has always . . . dis-
scepticism towards the grand claims then, knowledge should be regarded played a sensitivity to the specific
and grand theory of the modern era, as partial and situated in particular kinds of differences to be found
and their privileged vantage point, places and times. Postmodernists between different (and ‘unique’)
stressing in its place openness to reject conventional notions of scien- places, districts, regions and coun-
a range of voices in social enquiry, tific rationality and progress, favour- tries” (Cloke et al. 1991: 171). For
artistic experimentation and political ing an open interplay of multiple Gregory ([1989] 1996), postmod-
empowerment”. local knowledges. ernism provides an opportunity for
As this quote indicates, pluralism Rather than assuming that social geographers to return to the notion
is a key characteristic of postmodern life has an underlying order and of areal differentiation, emphasised
thought in terms of embracing the coherence, postmodernists celebrate by traditional regional geography,
knowledge claims of different social difference and variety. Difference but armed with a new ‘theoretical
groups. Grand theories or ‘meta- and variety are held to be a basic sensitivity’ derived from work in cul-
narratives’ (big stories) claiming to characteristic of the world, applied tural studies in particular.

44
Approaches to economic geography

the economic, by locating it within the cultural, social ³ Research on the importance of personal contact
and political relations through which it takes on and interpretative skills in financial and business
meaning and direction”. This has involved a refram- services. This has focused on the cultural practices
ing of the economic, demonstrating how economic which underpin communication and interaction,
relations are saturated with issues of identity, mean- the sites in which this takes place and the conse-
ing and representation. Four main strands of cultur- quences for our understanding of financial markets.
ally informed research in economic geography can be Research on financial centres such as the City of
identified: London, for example, has shown the importance of
social networks and trust, encouraging geographical
³ Consumption, with studies focusing, for instance, on concentration through the need for regular face-to-
the creation and experience of particular landscapes face contact.
of consumption such as shopping malls, supermar- ³ Corporate cultures and identities. Research has
kets and heritage parks (see Chapter 11). focused on how managers and workers create dis-
³ Gender, performance and identity in the work- tinctive corporate cultures through particular dis-
place and labour market. This work focuses on courses and day-to-day practices. Of particular
how employees perform particular roles and tasks interest here is Erica Schoenberger’s work on large
at work, often informed by cultural and gendered American corporations such as Xerox, DEC and
norms. One of the most notable studies on this is Lockheed, showing the limitations of such cultures
Linda McDowell’s research on work cultures in mer- in dealing with a turbulent and unpredictable eco-
chant banks in the City of London (see Box 2.8). nomic environment.

Box 2.8

Capital culture: gender and work in the City

Linda McDowell’s research on the work, the research assesses men’s employment trends and relations
construction and performance of experiences in addition to women’s. within companies could be com-
gender relations in the City of Lon- At the same time, the extent to which bined with first-hand accounts of
don represents one notable exam- the City has become more open to how individual employees have
ple of culturally informed economic women and the career prospects it managed and negotiated processes
geography research, linking eco- offers them remain key issues. of employment change within the
nomic issues to wider social and Capital Culture illustrates another workplace. Through the case study
cultural relations and focusing on key feature of culturally oriented interviews in particular, the research
questions of discourse, identity and economic geography by employing examined people’s everyday work
power. McDowell aims to understand a range of research methods, going experience, assessing how they
how an international financial centre beyond the conventional reliance assumed and performed particu-
like the City of London actually oper- on questionnaires and statistics to lar gender roles. The importance of
ates, “viewing it through the lens employ qualitative methods involv- image, bodies and the presentation
of the lives and careers of individ- ing direct fieldwork. McDowell of self are major themes. A key con-
ual men and women working in the focused on the merchant bank sec- clusion is that changing work rela-
City’s merchant banks at the end of tor, utilising postal questionnaires tions and power structures in the
this period of radical change [the sent out to all such banks in the City City still favour men as “the cultural
late 1980s and early 1990s] both in and detailed face-to-face interviews construction of the banking world
the global economy and in the city” with employees of three. remains elitist and masculinist”
(McDowell 1997: 4). In focusing on This multi-method approach (ibid.: 207).
gender segregation and identity at meant that information on changing

45
Foundations

2.5.2 Institutional economic economy as a separate domain driven by the rational


geography decisions of individual actors, economic sociologists,
following Polanyi, argue that the economy is socially
Economic geographers have drawn upon concepts constructed with social norms and institutions playing
from institutional economics which emphasise the a key role in shaping economic action (see Box 1.6).
social context of economic life and the role of insti- Rather than representing an external interference with
tutions in shaping and ‘embedding’ economic action. the ‘free’ operation of markets, as portrayed by neoclas-
Here, institutions are broadly defined as the ‘rules of the sical economics, institutions serve to enliven, stabilise
game’, incorporating both formal and tangible rules and and regulate economic relations. An important dis-
laws and more informal and intangible conventions and tinction is that between the institutional environment,
norms. According to one comprehensive definition, referring to both the informal conventions and formal
institutions incorporate: rules that enable and control the behaviour of economic
actors, and institutional arrangements, referring to par-
Formal regulations, legislation, and economic
ticular organisational forms (such as markets, firms,
systems as well as informal societal norms that reg-
local authorities, trade unions), that reflect and embody
ulate the behaviour of economic actors: firms, man-
this wider environment (Martin 2000).
agers, investors, workers. They govern the workings
Characteristically, institutionally inclined economic
of labour markets, education and training systems,
geographers have ‘spatialised’ the sociological concept
industrial relations regimes, corporate governance,
of ‘embeddedness’, emphasising how particular forms
capital markets, the strength and nature of domestic
of economic activity are not only grounded in social
competition, and associative behaviour. . . .
relations, but also rooted in particular places through
Collectively, they define the system of rules that
the concept of territorial ‘embeddedness’. In a study
shape the attitudes, values, and expectations of
of advanced manufacturing technologies in southern
individual economic actors. Institutions are also
Ontario, for instance, Gertler (1995) shows the impor-
responsible for producing and reproducing the
tance of ‘being there’ in facilitating adoption of the
conventions, routines, habits, and ‘settled habits of
technologies by ensuring close links between producers
thought’ that, together with attitudes, values, and
(organisations who actually develop, distribute and sell
expectations, influence actors’ economic decisions.
aspects of the technology) and users (manufacturing
(Gertler 2004: 7–8).
firms). A shared ‘embeddedness’ in a distinctive indus-
This understanding of institutions as sets of rules, trial culture enabled users and producers to develop
habits and values is informed by the ‘old’ institutional appropriate training regimes and industrial practices,
economics of the late nineteenth and early twentieth involving the sharing of information and knowledge.
centuries, rather than the ‘new’ neoclassically oriented This does not mean, however, that industrial cultures
institutionalism developed by mainstream economists. are always defined geographically or that learning and
It maintains that economic life cannot be understood interaction cannot occur over longer distances, utilis-
simply by reference to the rational actions of individ- ing information and communication technologies. An
ual actors, paralleling cultural approaches in extend- awareness of the importance of this issue has fostered
ing the definition of the economic beyond the scope of an interest in the development and organisation of
conventional models. Indeed, institutions are import- knowledge within large firms, raising questions about
ant because they link ‘the economic’ and ‘the social’ how such global and local knowledges are combined.
through a set of habits, practices and routines which Institutionalist ideas encouraged the rise of a ‘new
help to structure and stabilise economic activity. regionalism’ in economic geography which empha-
A related set of ideas from economic sociology have sises the importance of social and cultural conditions
also been influential in stressing that economic pro- within regions in helping to promote or hinder eco-
cesses are grounded or ‘embedded’ in social relations. nomic growth. In particular, inherited institutional
In contrast to the orthodox economic conception of the frameworks and routines are held to be of considerable

46
Approaches to economic geography

importance in influencing how particular regions development interaction takes place” (Figure 2.8). All
respond to the challenges of globalisation. Individual too frequently, however, development strategies are
places therefore have attracted renewed attention, as simply transferred from place to place whilst paying
institutional economic geographers have attempted to little attention to local institutional conditions. This
identify the social and cultural foundations of economic gives rise to three contrasting scenarios (Figure 2.9).
growth and prosperity in successful regions such as ‘Sil- In the first, an imbalanced ‘penny farthing’ scenario
icon Valley’ in California, the industrial districts of cen- is apparent, whereby a huge strategy front wheel is
tral and north-eastern Italy and Baden-Wurttemberg. undermined by a tiny institutional rear wheel (Fig-
This is associated with a focus on the role of local and ure 2.9a). In the second ‘square wheels’ case, poorly
regional institutions in mobilising resources for devel- rounded strategies are matched by inadequate insti-
opment, particularly Amin and Thrift’s (1994) concept tutional conditions, meaning that the process of eco-
of ‘institutional thickness’. Four levels of ‘institutional- nomic development cannot move forward (Figure
isation’ are identified: the number of institutions pres- 2.9b). In the third, worst-case, scenario, a basic ‘bicy-
ent; the degree of inter-institutional interaction; the cle frame’ situation indicates a lack of any real strategy
formation of coalitions; and the development of a com- and weak local institutions, offering little basis for eco-
mon agenda between key institutions and actors. nomic development (Figure 2.9c).
Institutional approaches emphasise the context- Whilst institutional approaches and the ‘new region-
specific nature of economic development, stressing the alism’ have been highly influential in economic geogra-
need to avoid ‘one size fits all’ policy prescriptions that phy since the 1980s, they have attracted some criticism.
are simply parachuted into a particular city or region In particular, they have been criticised for remaining
from outside. As the economic geographer Andres rather descriptive and failing to adequately specify
Rodríguez-Pose (2013: 1042) argues, a well-designed the mechanisms which link institutions and territo-
regional economic development strategy can be com- rial embeddedness as conditions for economic devel-
pared to a bicycle, requiring “two well rounded wheels: opment to regional growth and learning as outcomes.
a back institutional wheel with efficient formal and While much attention has been devoted to successful
informal institutions propelling the bicycle forward growth regions and industrial districts at particular
and a front development strategy wheel tailor-made points in time (the 1980s and 1990s), there are exam-
to match the institutional environment in which the ples of both institutionally ‘thin’ growth regions – for

Strategy Institutions

Figure 2.8 The regional development bicycle

47
Figure 2.9 Typical mismatch between development strategies and institutions: (a) ‘penny farthing’
equilibrium; (b) ‘square wheels’; and (c) ‘bicycle frame’ situation
Sources: (a) Graves & Green Engravings, Boston; (b) Michael Vroegop; (c) Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2013).
Approaches to economic geography

example ‘Motor Sport Valley’ in south-east England – In addition, EEG is informed by Nelson and Win-
and institutionally ‘thick’ but unsuccessful regions such ter’s (1982) evolutionary theory of economic change.
as the Ruhr in Germany (see Box 2.9) and north-east Firm routines are central to economic evolution, being
England. More fundamentally perhaps, the underly- regarded as analogous to genes in biological theory.
ing focus on regions as bounded spatial units has been They can be seen as organisational skills, relying on a
called into question by the ‘relational turn’ in economic stock of tacit (practical) knowledge. Routines provide
geography which emphasises the importance of the the basis for competition between firms, with the ‘fit-
broader networks and relations that link different places test’ routines being selected through the market and
in an increasingly globalised world (section 2.5.4). retained and passed on as a firm grows.
Another influence is the economist Paul David’s con-
cept of path dependence. David defines this as a pro-
2.5.3 Evolutionary economic cess of economic development in “which important
geography influences can be exerted by temporally remote events,
including happenings dominated by chance elements
In recent years, evolutionary economic geography
rather than systemic forces” (David 1985: 332). The pro-
(EEG) has become one of the most vibrant sub-fields of
cess is illustrated by the example of the QWERTY key-
economic geography, focusing attention on how the eco-
board which emerged as the industry standard following
nomic landscape is transformed over time. Informed by
the introduction of the typewriter in the late nineteenth
concepts from evolutionary economics and biology, EEG
century. The underlying point here is that the decisions
is principally concerned with processes of path depen-
of economic actors are shaped and informed by past
dence and lock-in (see below), the clustering of indus-
decisions and experiences. As Walker (2000) puts it:
tries in space and the role of innovation and knowledge
in shaping economic development. Evolution provides a One of the most exciting ideas in contemporary
particular way of thinking about change, inspired by the economic geography is that industrial history is
Darwinian concepts of variety, selection and retention, literally embodied in the present. That is, choices
although not crude notions such as the ‘survival of the made in the past – technologies embodied in
fittest’, or the genetic determination of behaviour. machinery and product design, firm assets gained
One source of inspiration for EEG is the famous Aus- as patents or specific competencies, or labour skills
trian economist, Joseph Schumpeter’s, definition of cap- acquired through learning – influence subsequent
italism as a process of ‘creative destruction’. This is the choices of methods, design and practices.
result of innovation and technological change, driven (Walker 2000: 126)
by the search for profit and wealth creation. It means
that new products, technologies, firms, industries and The term ‘lock-in’ is frequently employed to describe how
jobs are constantly being added to the economy, while path-dependent economic activities can become overly
old firms, technologies, products, industries and jobs rigid and trapped as a result of past choices. This has been
become uncompetitive and disappear (Boschma and the focus of one key strand of work in EEG, particularly
Martin 2007: 537). in the context of old industrial regions (Box 2.9).

Box 2.9

Regional path dependency and lock-in: the case of the Ruhr, Germany

Probably the best-known account of iron and steel complex of the Ruhr Rhine-Westphalia, the Ruhr is the
regional path dependence in EEG is in the 1970s and 1980s. Located traditional economic heartland of
Gernot Grabher’s work on the coal, in the north-western lander of North Germany, operating as a polycentric

49
Foundations

Box 2.9 (continued)

industrial region of over 5 million peo- This meant that any downturn in trade union branches, chambers
ple, comprised of a number of large demand for iron and steel would of commerce – to change policy
cities such as Dortmund, Bochum and have immediate effects on the mechanisms to encourage innova-
Essen. The industrial decline of the supplier base as well as the core tion and learning. In the Ruhr, such
region began in the 1960s, resulting firms. lock-in was underpinned by coop-
in an intense structural crisis in the b) Cognitive lock-in which relates to erative relations between industry,
late 1970s and early 1980s. This how firms thought and operated, regional government (the land of
reflected a process of lock-in, based pointing to a kind of world view North Rhine-Westphalia), unions
upon the trap of ‘rigid specialisation’ and ‘groupthink’. In particular, and local authorities. This conser-
that emanated from the close intra- they assumed that the pattern vative culture of consensus was
regional interdependence of the coal, of stable demand would persist, expressed in terms of strong politi-
iron and steel complex. Coal supplied meaning that the slump of the cal support for the heavy industries,
the iron and steel industries, while early 1970s was interpreted as prompting several programmes of
individual steel producers specialised a short-term ‘blip’ rather than investment in the 1970s.
in different products and used a net- as the start of long-term decline.
work of dedicated suppliers, including Cognitive lock-in implies a failure Ultimately, however, the crisis of the
machine-building, electronics and to develop appropriate collective late 1970s and 1980s broke these
commercial services. learning mechanisms that allow lock-ins, resulting in the substan-
Grabher distinguishes between firms not only to experiment and tial destruction of the region’s heavy
three main dimensions of lock-in in innovate, but also to be able to industrial path. Firms responded not
the Ruhr: read the signs of external change only through large-scale plant clo-
and act appropriately. They sures and job losses, but also by reor-
a) Functional lock-in refers to the responded to the slump of the ganising their business and moving
close links between the core firms, 1970s by investing heavily in into related production sectors and
the major iron and steel manufac- existing technology and process markets. This can be understood as
turers, and their suppliers, based innovation (more of the same) a process of ‘path branching’ (see
upon the long-term stability and rather than diversifying into new below). Firms moved into sectors
predictability of demand for iron markets. such as environmental technology
and steel. As a result, suppliers did c) Political lock-in reflects the fail- which accounted for over 600 firms
not undertake their own research ure of regional political actors – and 100,000 jobs by the early 1990s
and development or marketing. for example local government, (Grabher 1993: 269).

In an effort to move beyond the restrictive theory development, in turn, leads to either a dynamic process
of path dependency derived from the work of David, of path renewal or ‘lock-in’ (Box 2.9). In addition, Mar-
the economic geographer Ron Martin (2010) develops tin distinguishes between an enabling and constraining
a more open model of local industrial evolution which institutional environment for the emergence of new
usefully distinguishes between a preformation phase technologies and industries.
dominated by pre-existing economic and technological The process of regional diversification or branching
conditions, together with the resources, competences, is viewed as a key mechanism of path creation in EEG,
skills and experiences inherited from previous local involving the development of new industrial growth
patterns of economic development, and a path creation paths in a city or region. Branching is underpinned
phase where experimentation and competition between by the concept of related variety, defined in terms of
different economic agents leads to the emergence of a regions possessing a number of complementary sec-
new path (Figure 2.10). This gives way to a subsequent tors with overlapping knowledge bases and technolog-
path development phase based on the development of ical capabilities. A key research finding here, originally
local increasing returns and network linkages. Path based on Swedish data, is that industries are more

50
Approaches to economic geography

Constraining environment for Path as


the emergence of new Movement to
technologies and Stable State
Reinforcement of Local
industries selected Industrial or
technologies and Technological
increasing Stasis
rigidification of
Preformation Path Path associated
Phase Creation Development structures,
Preexisting local Phase Phase networks, and
economic and Purposive or Emergence and knowledges of
technological intentional development of firms
structures, experimentation local increasing
knowledges, and and competition returns and Path as
competences among agents network Dynamic
leads to the externalities Process
local emergence assists the Conversion, Adaptation
of a new path development of layering, and and Mutation
the path recombinant of a Local
effects lead to Industry or
Enabling environment for incremental, path- Technology
dependent
the creation and emergence
evolution and
of new technologies and renewal of a local
industries industry or
technology

Figure 2.10 Towards an alternative model of local industrial evolution


Source: Martin 2010: 21.

likely to grow in a region if they were technologically routines and capabilities are passed from parent firms
related to pre-existing industries in that region (Neffke to their offspring, challenging the traditional explana-
et al. 2011). The processes by which branching actually tion of clustering processes in terms of factors exter-
occurs at the firm level have received less attention in nal to individual firms, principally specialised pools of
EEG, however, particularly in terms of how firms and knowledge, labour and suppliers (Boschma and Fren-
other organisations identify opportunities and transfer ken 2015).
their knowledge and competencies into new sectors The development of EEG as an exciting field of
and markets. research has been accompanied by periodic debates
Informed by earlier work on industry life cycles, about its scope and direction. While Boschma and
another strand of research in EEG has focused on the Frenken’s (2006) strong founding statement drew some
spatial evolution of industries. An analysis of the UK sharp distinctions between EEG and institutional eco-
automotive (car) industry, for example, shows how it nomic geography and the NEG, others have called for
emerged out of the pre-existing bicycle and coaching closer links to other approaches, namely institution-
industries between 1898 and 1922 (Boschma and Went- alism and GPE, on the one hand, and relational eco-
ing 2007). Through this process of regional branch- nomic geography, on the other (Hassink et al. 2014;
ing from related industries, car manufacture became MacKinnon et al. 2009). EEG remains diverse, being
concentrated in the West Midlands around Coventry characterised by the deployment of a range of theories
and Birmingham. The process of spin-off was a very and methods. The distinction between quantitative
important mechanism of diversification with many and qualitative methods is particularly pronounced,
firms founded by people who had left existing firms, with some researchers relying on statistical and formal
bringing their knowledge and experience with them. modelling techniques that are similar to mainstream
This suggests that industrial clusters can emerge from economics and the NEG, whilst others espouse more
the industrial dynamics of spin-off, whereby successful qualitative, case study-based approaches.

51
Foundations

2.5.4 Relational economic group ratification of culturally informed corporate deci-


geography sions, and the recruitment of Mormon employees.
Relational conceptions of space have fostered a new
In recent years, economic geography has been influ- concern with ‘the relational region’ which reimagines
enced by the rise of relational thinking in geography. This regions as open and discontinuous spaces, defined by
builds on Doreen Massey’s ‘global sense of place’ which the wider social relations in which they are situated
defines place as constructed out of the coming together (Box 2.10). They are created for particular purposes
of wider social relations (section 1.2.3). According to by, for instance, policy-makers, social movements or
Massey (2005: 9–12), the relational approach to space academic analysts, meaning that they have no essential
is grounded in three basic propositions. First, space character or identity outside of these acts of creation
should be seen as the product of interrelations, meaning and definition. John Allen, Massey and Allan Cochrane
that places and their identities are created through such (1998), based at the Open University, illustrate these
relations, rather than pre-existing in an a priori fashion. arguments by an analysis of south-east England, the
Second, space emphasises the possibility of multiplicity, emblematic growth region of neoliberal Britain since
created out of the different relationships that link places the 1980s. Within the Southeast, areas of economic
together, resonating with the postmodernist concern for decline and deprivation exist, complicating and con-
difference. Third, space is always changing and becoming founding the overarching image of growth and pros-
rather than being static or fixed. From this perspective, perity, while the boundaries of the region can be seen as
globalisation marks a new era of space/place relations, open and porous (Figure 2.11). This relational theory of
focusing attention on economic networks and wider cir-
cuits of knowledge generation and exchange rather than
bounded regions. Tokyo
Global financial markets
Relational economic geography is concerned with
International labour markets
economic action and interaction which it views as being
Branch outlets (foreign banks)
embedded in wider social and economic relations. It
Decentralization of branch offices
is particularly associated with the study of networks,
defined as “socio-economic structures that connect
people, firms and places to one another and that enable 0 50 miles
knowledge, commodities and capital to flow within 0 80km
and between regions” (Aoyama et al. 2011: 181). In this
respect, it overlaps significantly with the recent emphasis
on economic practices, defined as the diverse and mun-
dane actions by which diverse actors and communities
‘make do’ and ‘get by’ to meet their material needs and
ensure their social reproduction (Stenning et al. 2010:
64). According to Jones and Murphy (2011), this con-
cern with practice should not be seen as a major theoret-
ical ‘turn’ in its own right, but as a way of understanding
New York
broader processes, for instance consumption, through an
emphasis on ‘ordinary’ actions and seemingly ‘mundane’
activities. For example, Al James’s (2007) study of cul-
tural embeddedness in Utah’s high-tech economy found
Europe
that Mormon religious values were upheld by a range of
day-to-day practices within firms. These include the rein-
Figure 2.11 International financial links of south-
forcement of group norms through routine association east England
with other employees, observation of fellow workers, the Source: Allen et al. 1998: 49.

52
Approaches to economic geography

Box 2.10

Transnational communities and regional development

Anna-Lee Saxenian’s work on transna- engineering and who became entre- developed countries like Israel which
tional communities of engineers and preneurs in the US. Increasingly, had traditionally exported engineers
entrepreneurs provides a useful illus- these individuals formed communities to the US – before spreading to India
tration of relational approaches to of technically skilled immigrants with and China from the late 1990s. This
regional development. Saxenian is work experience and connections to transnational movement of entrepre-
renowned for her previous work on Silicon Valley and related American neurs and engineers in the IT sector
Silicon Valley in California (Box 3.8), technology centres. underpins Saxenian’s key argument
and she has maintained this focus in In the 1960s and 1970s, the rela- that the traditional pattern of ‘brain
her recent research, while modifying tionship between the home countries drain’, for the originating countries,
her approach to take account of the of these Asian engineers and the US is being replaced by a mutually ben-
transnational links and flows. as the receiving country conformed eficial one of ‘brain circulation’. As
Saxenian (2006) argues that the to the classic pattern of migration such, the ‘new Argonauts’ are replac-
past couple of decades have seen the between the rich and poor worlds. ing the old pattern of one-way flows
rise of what she calls the ‘new Argo- From the late 1980s, however, Sax- of skilled people from the periphery
nauts’ in the form of engineers and enian argues, a new trend emerged to the core with new, two-way link-
entrepreneurs who operate interna- as US-educated engineers began to ages. This is fuelling growth and
tionally, often having moved overseas return to their home countries. This employment creation in the (former)
for education or employment and reflected the economic growth of periphery through the infusion of
having gone on to launch new firms these countries and the development skills, capital and technology incu-
in the countries they moved to. The of information and communication bated in the core. It remains unclear,
main example of such Argonauts dis- technologies (ICTs) which created however, how widespread such
cussed by Saxenian are first-generation new opportunities for firms and indi- Argonaut-based ‘brain circulation’ is
immigrants to the US from Asian viduals to operate internationally. compared to traditional ‘brain drain’
countries such as India, China and Initially, this reverse flow was con- beyond the specific countries she
Taiwan who gained technical skills in fined to Taiwan – and other more discusses.

broadly. The traditional framework based on regional


Reflect classification and description gave way to a more quan-
titative approach in the late 1950s and early 1960s,
Which of the new approaches discussed in this section based on the development of concepts and techniques
do you consider to offer the most promising perspec- of spatial analysis. This was, in turn, superseded by GPE
tive for economic geography? Justify your answer. in the 1970s and 1980s before the introduction of a
range of new approaches in the 1990s and 2000s. These
periodic shifts in intellectual orientation should be seen
the region has been accompanied by a critique of ‘new as changes in broad focus and direction rather than as
regionalist’ thinking, rejecting its portrayal of regions wholesale transformations, with research in the earlier
as internally coherent and externally bounded. spatial analysis and GPE remaining important.
Our favoured approach in this book can be described
2.6 Summary as ‘new’ GPE, signalling that it has moved beyond the
rather clunky and deterministic theories of the 1970s
Prevailing approaches to economic geography have and early 1980s to become more flexible and open to the
changed considerably over time, as we have demon- importance of context, difference and identity, partly as
strated, mirroring the development of geography more a result of encountering the new approaches outlined

53
Foundations

in the previous sections. In particular, our approach is bring elements of the different approaches together? If
a plural GPE that combines the breadth and analytical so, which ones?
power of GPE thinking with an evolutionary focus on
historical transformation and change and a sensitiv-
ity to context and differences associated with the cul- Key reading
tural and institutional ‘turns’. It represents, as such, a Barnes, T.J. (2000) Inventing Anglo-American economic
“culturally-sensitive political economy” rather than a geography. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T.J. (eds) A Compan-
“politically-sensitive cultural economy” (Hudson 2005: ion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 11–26.
15). Our approach can be described as broadly regula- An engaging account of the formation and early development
tionist in nature, stressing the important role that wider of economic geography. Stresses how academic subjects are
processes of social regulation play in stabilising and invented as specific projects at particular times and in par-
sustaining capitalism. ticular places by groups of people. Covers the traditional
From a base in GPE, we examine the uneven devel- approach and spatial analysis.
opment of capitalism, “the individual economics of
Barnes, T.J. (2012) Economic geography. In Johnston, R.J.,
different places, and their connections one to another”
Gregory, D., Pratt, G. and Watts, M. (eds) The Dictionary
(Barnes and Sheppard 2000: 2–3) in this book. In
of Human Geography, 5th edition. Oxford: Blackwell,
adopting a broad, synthetic conception of the econ- pp. 178–81.
omy, we recognise the importance of the links between Provides a concise summary of economic geography’s con-
the economy, institutions and culture, and assess some cerns and methods. Outlines how the subject has evolved
connections between them in specific geographical over time and highlights a range of examples of contemporary
settings. Our approach also takes difference and vari- economic geography research.
ety seriously, emphasising the distinctive character of
individual places, but insisting that we need to consider Gertler, M.G. (2010) Rules of the game: the place of institu-
how geographical difference is produced and repro- tions in regional economic change. Regional Studies 41: 1–15.
duced through wider processes of economic develop- Offers a comprehensive and accessible definition of institu-
tions and discusses several strands of institutionalist research
ment and state intervention.
in economic geography and regional studies, arguing that they
have failed to take institutions seriously. Sets out an alternative
Exercise approach to studying institutions for economic geography.

A major supermarket chain is proposing to open a new Scott, A.J. (2000) Economic geography: the great half cen-
out-of-town superstore near to the town or city where tury. In Clark, G., Feldmann, M. and Gertler, M. (eds) The
you live. Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Oxford
How would spatial analysis, GPE and the cultural or University Press, pp. 18–44.
institutional approaches examine and understand this An upbeat review of the development of economic geogra-
issue? What aspects of the development would each phy in the post-war period. Focuses particularly on the spatial
approach focus attention on: for example, people’s expe- analysis and political economy approaches, highlighting spe-
rience of shopping, the broader policies and practices cific research topics such as localities and the rediscovery of
of the corporation in question, finding the optimum regions since the 1980s.
location, the links between consumption and identity,
Sheppard, E., Barnes, T.J., Peck, J. and Tickell, A. (2004)
the impact on local shops, analysing the characteristics
Introduction: reading economic geography. In Barnes, T.,
of the local market, assessing why customers shop in
Peck, J., Sheppard, E. and Tickell, A. (eds) Reading Eco-
major superstores, competition amongst supermarket nomic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 1–9.
chains, relationships with suppliers? A concise and authoritative summary of the field from the
On this basis, assess the strengths and weaknesses introduction to a selection of key journal articles in economic
of each approach. Which, if any, offers the ‘best’ under- geography. Introduces the subject matter of economic geog-
standing of the issue? Why? Is it appropriate to try and raphy before providing an essential history of it in two pages.

54
Approaches to economic geography

This is followed by an explanation of the immediate context Boschma, R. and Frenken, K. (2006) Why is economic
for the companion and a useful guide on critical reading geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an
techniques. evolutionary economic geography. Journal of Economic
Geography 6: 273–302.
Sheppard, E., Barnes, T.J. and Peck, J. (2012) The long Boschma, R. and Frenken, K. (2015) Evolutionary economic
decade: economic geography unbound. In Barnes, T.J., geography. Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography
Peck, J. and Sheppard, E. (eds) The Wiley-Blackwell Com- 15.18. Utrecht: Utrecht University, Urban and Regional
panion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 1–24. Research Centre. At http://econ.geog.uu.nl/peeg/peeg.
An important introduction to economic geography as an html.
academic subject area from a recent handbook which pro- Boschma, R.A. and Martin, R. (2007) Constructing an
vides a comprehensive guide to the subject. This introduc- evolutionary economic geography. Journal of Economic
tion highlights some of the key themes and recent debates in Geography 7: 537–48.
economic geography, as well as introducing the contents of Boschma, R.A. and Wenting, R. (2007) The spatial evolution
the handbook. of the British automobile industry: does location matter?
Industry and Corporate Change 16: 213–38.
Boyer, R. (1990) The Regulation School: A Critical
Useful websites Introduction. New York: Columbia University Press.
Burton, I. (1963) The quantitative revolution and theoretical
www.egrg.rgs.org/
geography. Canadian Geographer 7: 151–62.
The website of the Economic Geography Research Group
Christaller, W. (1966) Central Places in Southern Germany,
of the Royal Geographical Society (with the Institute of the
translated by Baskin, C.W. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
British Geographers). This site is mainly used by academic
Prentice-Hall.
researchers in the field, so much of the material is likely to be
Cloke, P., Philo, C. and Sadler, D. (1991) Approaching Human
difficult. It is worth exploring the site, however, to get a feel
Geography: An Introduction to Contemporary Theoretical
for the types of issues and topics that economic geographers
Debates. London: Paul Chapman.
conduct research on.
Crang, P. (1997) Introduction: cultural turns and the
(re)constitution of economic geography. In Lee, R.
and Wills, J. (eds) Geographies of Economies. London:
References
Arnold, pp. 3–15.
Allen J., Massey D. and Cochrane A. (1998) Rethinking the David, P.A. (1985) Clio and the economics of QWERTY.
Region. London: Routledge. American Economic Review 75: 332–7
Amin, A. and Thrift, N. (1994) Living in the global. In Dowd, D. (2000) Capitalism and its Economics: A Critical
Amin, A. and Thrift, N. (eds) Globalisation, Institutions History. London: Pluto.
and Regional Development in Europe. Oxford: Oxford Dunford, M. and Perrons, D. (1994) Regional inequality,
University Press, pp. 1–22. regimes of accumulation and economic development in
Aoyama, Y., Murphy, J.T. and Hanson S. (2011) Key Concepts contemporary Europe. Transactions, Institute of British
in Economic Geography. London: Sage. Geographers NS 19: 163–82.
Armstrong, H. and Taylor, J. (2000) Regional Economics and European Commission (2014) Investment for Jobs and
Policy, 3rd edition. London: Blackwell. Growth: Promoting Development and Good Governance
Barnes, T.J. (2000) Inventing Anglo-American economic in EU Regions and Cities, 6th Report on Economic,
geography. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T.J. (eds) Social and Territorial Cohesion. At http://ec.europa.
A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, eu/regional_policy/sources/docoffic/official/reports/
pp. 11–26. cohesion6/6cr_en.pdf.
Barnes, T.J. (2001) Retheorising economic geography: from FAO (Food and Agriculture Organisation) (2010) Measuring
the quantitative revolution to the ‘cultural turn’. Annals of and assessing capacity in fisheries: 2 issues and methods.
the Association of American Geographers 91: 546–65. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper 433/2. Rome: Food and
Barnes, T.J. and Sheppard, E. (2000) The art of economic Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations.
geography. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T.J. (eds) Gertler, M.S. (1995) ‘Being there’: proximity, organisation and
A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, culture in the development and adoption of advanced
pp. 1–8. manufacturing technologies. Economic Geography 71: 1–26.

55
Foundations

Gertler, M.S. (2004) Manufacturing Culture: The Institutional Lee, R. (2002) Nice maps, shame about the theory? Thinking
Geography of Industrial Practice. Oxford: Oxford geographically about the economic. Progress in Human
University Press. Geography 26: 333–55.
Grabher, G. (1993) The weakness of strong ties: the lock-in Ley, D. (1994) Postmodernism. In Johnston, R.J., Gregory,
of regional development in the Ruhr area. In Grabher, D. and Smith, D.M. (eds) The Dictionary of Human
G. (ed) The Embedded Firm: On the Socio-economics of Geography, 3rd edition. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 466–8.
Industrial Networks. London: Routledge, pp. 255–77. MacKinnon, D., Cumbers, A., Birch, K., Pike, A. and
Gregory, D. [1989] (1996) Areal differentiation and post- McMaster, R. (2009) Evolution in economic geography:
modern human geography. In Agnew, J., Livingstone, institutions, political economy and regional adaptation.
D.N. and Rogers, A. (eds) Human Geography: An Economic Geography 85: 129–50.
Essential Anthology. London: Blackwell, pp. 211–32. Martin, R. (1999) The new ‘geographical turn’ in economics:
Hartshorne, R. (1939) The Nature of Geography: A Critical some critical reflections. Cambridge Journal of Economics
Survey of the Present in the Light of the Past. Lancaster, 23: 65–91.
PA: The Association. Martin, R. (2000) Institutionalist approaches to economic
Harvey, D. (1973) Social Justice and the City. London: geography. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T. (eds)
Arnold. Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell,
Harvey, D. (1982) The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Blackwell. pp. 77–97.
Hassink, R., Klaerding, C. and Marques, P. (2014) Advancing Martin, R. (2010) Rethinking regional path dependence:
evolutionary economic geography by engaged pluralism. beyond lock-in to evolution. Economic Geography 86:
Regional Studies 48: 1295–307. 1–27.
Hudson, R. (2005) Economic Geographies: Circuits, Flows and Marx, K. and Engels, F. [1848] (1967) The Communist
Spaces. London: Sage. Manifesto. London: Penguin.
Hudson, R. (2006) On what’s right and keeping left: Or Massey, D. (1995) Spatial Divisions of Labour: Social
why geography still needs Marxian political economy. Structures and the Geography of Production, 2nd edition.
Antipode 38: 374–95. London: Macmillan.
Jackson, P. (1989) Maps of Meaning: An Introduction to Massey, D. (2005) For Space. London: Sage.
Cultural Geography. London: Unwin Hyman. McDowell, L. (1997) Capital Culture: Gender at Work in the
James, A. (2007) Everyday effects, practices and causal City. Oxford: Blackwell.
mechanisms of ‘cultural embeddedness’: learning from Neffke, F., Henning, M. and Boschma, R. (2011) How do
Utah’s high tech regional economy. Geoforum 38: 393–413. regions diversify over time? Industry relatedness and the
Johnston, R.J. and Sidaway, J.D. (2004) Geography and development of new growth paths in regions. Economic
Geographers: Anglo-American Human Geography Since Geography 87: 237–65.
1945, 6th edition. London: Arnold. Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982) An Evolutionary Theory
Jones, A. (2015) Geographies of production I: political of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
economic geographies: a pluralist direction? Press.
Progress in Human Geography. OnlineFirst, doi Pike, A., Rodríguez-Pose, A. and Tomaney, J. (2017) Local
10.1177/0309132515595553. and Regional Development, 2nd edition. London:
Jones, A. and Murphy, J.T. (2011) Theorising practice in Routledge.
economic geography: foundations, challenges and Rees, J. (1998) The return of Marx? International Socialism
possibilities. Progress in Human Geography 35: 266–92. 79. Available at http://pubs. socialistreviewindex.org.uk/
Knox, P. and Agnew, J. (1994) The Geography of the World isj79.rees.htm. Accessed 2 November 2005.
Economy, 2nd edition. London: Arnold. Rigg, J., Bebbington, A., Gough, K.V., Bryceson, D.F.,
Krugman, P. (2000) Where in the world is the ‘new economic Agergaard, J., Fold, N. and Tacoli, C. (2009) The
geography’?. In Clark, G., Feldmann, M. and Gertler, M. World Development Report 2009 ‘reshapes’ economic
(eds) The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. geography: critical reflections. Transactions, Institute of
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 49–60. British Geographers NS 34: 128–36.
Krugman, P. (2011) The new economic geography, now Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2013) Do institutions matter for
middle-aged. Regional Studies 45: 1–8. regional development? Regional Studies 47: 1034–47.

56
Approaches to economic geography

Saxenian, A.L. (2006) The New Argonauts: Regional Practice and Social Reproduction in Post-Socialist Cities.
Advantage in a Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
Harvard University Press. Storper, M. (2011) From retro to avant-garde: a
Scott, A.J. (2000) Economic geography: the great half commentary on Paul Krugman’s ‘the new economic
century. In Clark, G., Feldmann, M. and Gertler, M. (eds) geography, now middle-aged’. Regional Studies 45: 9–16.
The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Swyngedouw, E. (2000) The Marxian alternative: historical-
Oxford University Press, pp. 18–44. geographical materialism and the political economy of
Seddon, M. (2005) Kapital gain: Karl Marx is the Home capitalism. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T.J. (eds)
Counties favourite. The Guardian, 14 July. A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell,
Sheppard, E. (2011) Geographical political economy. Journal pp. 40–59.
of Economic Geography 11: 319–31. Walker, R. (2000) The geography of production. In Sheppard,
Smith, N. (1984) Uneven Development: Nature, Capital and E. and Barnes, T.J. (eds) A Companion to Economic
the Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell. Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 111–32.
Smith, N. (2001) Marxism and geography in the Anglophone Wills, J. and Lee, R. (1997) Introduction. In Lee, R. and
world. Geographishce Revue 3: 5–22. Available at www. Wills, J. (eds) Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold,
geographische-revue.de/gr2-01.htm. pp. xi–xviii.
Stenning, A., Smith, A., Rochovska, A. and Swiatek, D. World Bank (2009) World Development Report 2009: Reshaping
(2010) Domesticating Neo-Liberalism: Spaces of Economic Economic Geography. Washington, DC: World Bank.

57

You might also like