You are on page 1of 18

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/240293866

Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Article in Interfaces · June 2003


DOI: 10.1287/inte.33.3.24.16009

CITATIONS READS
27 13,409

3 authors, including:

Charles L. Munson Jianli hu


Washington State University Princess Alexandra Hospital (Queensland Health)
39 PUBLICATIONS 1,628 CITATIONS 57 PUBLICATIONS 2,078 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Charles L. Munson on 13 December 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


This article was downloaded by: [134.121.103.10] On: 16 November 2014, At: 22:22
Publisher: Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences (INFORMS)
INFORMS is located in Maryland, USA

Interfaces
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://pubsonline.informs.org

Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains


Charles L. Munson, Jianli Hu, Meir J. Rosenblatt,

To cite this article:


Charles L. Munson, Jianli Hu, Meir J. Rosenblatt, (2003) Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains. Interfaces
33(3):24-39. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/inte.33.3.24.16009

Full terms and conditions of use: http://pubsonline.informs.org/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used only for the purposes of research, teaching, and/or private study. Commercial use
or systematic downloading (by robots or other automatic processes) is prohibited without explicit Publisher
approval, unless otherwise noted. For more information, contact permissions@informs.org.

The Publisher does not warrant or guarantee the article’s accuracy, completeness, merchantability, fitness
for a particular purpose, or non-infringement. Descriptions of, or references to, products or publications, or
inclusion of an advertisement in this article, neither constitutes nor implies a guarantee, endorsement, or
support of claims made of that product, publication, or service.

© 2003 INFORMS

Please scroll down for article—it is on subsequent pages

INFORMS is the largest professional society in the world for professionals in the fields of operations research, management
science, and analytics.
For more information on INFORMS, its publications, membership, or meetings visit http://www.informs.org
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated
Supply Chains
Charles L. Munson • Jianli Hu
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

College of Business and Economics, Washington State University,


PO Box 644736, Pullman, Washington 99164-4736
munson@wsu.edu • hu@mail.wsu.edu

Meir J. Rosenblatt
(deceased)
formerly Professor at Washington University in St. Louis, Missouri, and
Technion—Israel Institute of Technology
This paper was refereed.

Supply-chain management has become a prominent area for teaching and research. Aca-
demics and managers realize that communication and coordination among members of a
supply chain enhance its effectiveness, creating financial benefits to be shared by the mem-
bers. We have collected numerical examples covering (1) location decisions, (2) centralized
warehousing, (3) lot sizing with deterministic demand, (4) demand forecasting, (5) pricing,
and (6) lot sizing with stochastic demand in a newsvendor environment. The examples are
suitable for classroom use, and they illuminate the rewards supply-chain members can obtain
by eliminating naturally occurring supply-chain inefficiencies and the costs of not doing so.
(Professional: OR/MS education. Supply-chain management.)

W hen each member of a group tries to maximize


his or her own benefit without regard to the
impact on other members of the group, the overall
dination and its benefits. The examples we present
span issues of location, warehousing, inventory, infor-
mation sharing, and pricing. They are generally
effectiveness of the group may suffer. Such inefficien- simplified versions of ideas that can be found in the
cies often creep in when rational members of supply literature tailored for classroom use. We introduce
chains optimize individually instead of coordinating each example with a nontechnical discussion of the
their efforts. Nowadays, companies should not act in experiences of Isaac’s Ice Cream, a fictitious sole pro-
isolation, as success in the global marketplace requires prietorship.
whole supply chains to compete against other sup- Examples 1 and 2 concern horizontal coordination,
ply chains (Davis 1994). Supply-chain members must that is, coordination among entities on the same level
recognize the natural inefficiencies that may develop of the supply chain. Examples 3 through 6 describe
and work to eliminate them, so that the supply chain vertical coordination, that is, coordination among enti-
ties on different levels of the supply chain (for exam-
as a whole can compete effectively.
ple, a retailer and its supplier).
Real-world examples of supply-chain coordination
abound (Lee and Ng 1998, Munson et al. 1999).
More concretely, students of business can work Example 1: Location Decisions
through numerical examples to better understand Isaac’s Ice Cream had been selling very well in the city,
and appreciate from a theoretical perspective the but Isaac wished to expand his market to reach sum-
simple but powerful concept of supply-chain coor- mertime tourists by selling his ice cream from small

Interfaces © 2003 INFORMS 0092-2102/03/3303/0024$05.00


Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003, pp. 24–39 1526-551X electronic ISSN
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

n n n n n
customers customers customers customers customers
MM0 MM1 MM2 MM3 MM4
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

Figure 1: In a four-mile stretch of road with five mile markers, MMi i = 0     4, the same number of cus-
tomers, n, cluster around each of the five mile markers. The franchise must decide where along the road to
locate two franchisees.

carts along the boardwalk on the beach. He offered franchisors generally strive for many locations, even
these “franchises” to two young entrepreneurs, Sally if their market areas overlap (Marsh 1992). How-
and Pete. Isaac obtained permits allowing both carts ever, the franchisees who own the individual out-
to locate anywhere along the four-mile boardwalk. lets generally want to maximize their market access,
Moving these rolling stores to new locations entailed and they do not want their service areas cannibal-
essentially no setup cost. Believing that Sally and Pete ized by another franchisee. Therefore, the franchisor
would know best where to locate because they were may sometimes need to control the allocation of ter-
close to the customers, Isaac allowed them to locate ritories served or the locations of the franchisees. In
anywhere they wished, suggesting only that they stay one case, KFC tried to appease franchise owners by
out of each other’s way. On the first day, Sally took a offering a pass-through royalty equal to two percent
cart and told Pete that she would cover the north end of the sales made by new outlets opening near them
of the boardwalk and he could have the south end. (Ruffenach 1992). Sally and Pete’s conflict illustrates
Pete agreed, and they went their separate ways. the detrimental effects to individual franchisees and
Sally parked her cart about one mile from the the entire franchise of letting franchisees choose their
north end of the boardwalk. Morning sales were own locations. Game theory texts (for example, Ras-
steady; however, she noticed that the only buyers musen 1989) include more general Hotelling models
were those walking from the north end, while quite (games).
a few strollers walking past from the south already Suppose that a franchisor wishes to open fast-food
had ice cream. So, Sally walked a few hundred yards restaurants along a stretch of road four miles long.
south and, to her dismay, noticed that Pete’s cart was Potential customers cluster along mile markers (MM)
right there, almost three full miles from the south 0, 1, 2, 3, and 4, with n customers in each cluster
end. Infuriated, Sally snuck around Pete’s back and (Figure 1). Customer demand is sensitive primarily to
set up her cart in a new location about 300 yards distance traveled. Specifically, for each customer, D =
south of Pete. Similar maneuvering continued back ab − d, where D = weekly demand, a is a constant >
and forth all day. At 5:00, Isaac found Sally and Pete’s 0, b is a constant > 4, and d is the distance traveled in
carts right across from each other halfway down the miles. Both the franchisor and the franchisees wish to
four-mile boardwalk. The two were covered with ice maximize weekly demand.
cream, apparently from an altercation. People strolled
by, refreshments from nearby concession stands in
hand. What happened? Case 1: Two Franchisees Whose
Locations Are Coordinated by
A franchise has multiple outlets to serve customers, the Franchisor
spread out over a town, a state, a country, or even If the franchisor can locate the two franchisees any-
multiple continents. To maximize market coverage, where along the four-mile stretch of road, total

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 25
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

demand for the entire franchise will be maximized greater demand, and the total franchise will receive a
when the first franchise (F1) is located at mile demand of na5b − 3.
marker 1 (MM1) and the second (F2) is located at mile
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

marker 3 (MM3). (We can easily verify this result by


enumerating the possible scenarios.)
Example 2: Centralized
The total distance customers travel will be 3n miles, Warehousing
and total franchise demand will equal nab − 1 + Over time, Isaac’s Ice Cream has grown and now sells
nab − 0 + nab − 1 + nab − 0 + nab − 1 = na5b − 3. certain products through 200 company-owned retail
As we might expect, this demand exceeds that obtain- outlets split equally between two states. In both states,
able by only one franchisee. In the single-franchisee Isaac leases warehouse space for storage of goods
case, simple enumeration shows that the location of strictly by the square foot. In the firm’s first state of
the single franchisee should be at MM2, and the operation, it leased warehouse space near each shop.
franchise demand will equal nab − 2 + nab − 1 + However, when Isaac expanded to the second state
nab − 0 + nab − 1 + nab − 2 = na5b − 6. he tried storing goods for all 100 shops in that state
at a central location. Although transportation costs
and lead times are somewhat higher in the second
Case 2: Two Franchisees That state, Isaac is puzzled when he reviews his books
because the second state performs much better on cer-
Control Their Own Locations tain other criteria.
In this case, F1 and F2 act in their own interest to While each of the 100 warehouses in the original
maximize their own demand, knowing that the other state stores fewer goods and has fewer orders to fill
franchisee exists and then reacting accordingly. With- than the centralized warehouse in the second state
out loss of generality, assume that F1 chooses its does, the sum of the individual warehouse costs is
location first. To maximize its own demand, it will much larger. In fact, the total warehousing costs are
locate at MM2. F2 then has two choices: (1) to also 90 percent lower in the second state. Isaac has heard
locate at MM2, or (2) to locate somewhere other than of economies of scale, but this result surprises him
MM2. If F2 also locates at MM2, the two franchisees because he is not paying any fixed land or building
will share the demand of na5b − 6, and each will costs at the warehouses; he pays only for storage
end up with half of it. On the other hand, F2 could space and ordering and receiving costs. In addition,
capture the entire demand from two other locations, the firm has always carried safety stock to protect
say MM0 and MM1, by locating somewhere between against unusually high demand. For consistency, Isaac
them (say MM0 + 0 5). In that case, F2’s total demand keeps the same amount of total system safety stock in
would be nab − 0 5 + nab − 0 5 = na2b − 1, which both states. To his surprise, stores in the original state
is less than its MM2 location demand of na5b −6/2 = receive 70 percent service, while stores in the new
na 5/2b − 3 = na 2b + b/2 − 3 > na2b − 1, since state receive (essentially) 100 percent service. “How
b > 4. can this be?” Isaac wonders. “How can centraliza-
Therefore, assuming that demand is primarily a tion dramatically decrease my costs while dramati-
function of distance, two rational franchisees choosing cally increasing my service level?”
their locations simultaneously to maximize their own
profits will both locate at the midpoint of the stretch In this example, we consider two benefits of cen-
of road, sharing the same total franchise demand, tralized warehousing: (1) economies of scale in setup
na5b − 6, that one franchisee alone would have had. and holding costs, and (2) risk pooling in a stochastic-
On the other hand, either through contractual agree- demand environment. Centralized warehousing can
ment or through the franchisor’s direction and coor- be implemented by single companies for their field
dination, the two franchisees can cooperate and locate sites, franchisors for their franchisees, or even suppli-
at MM1 and MM3 (Case 1). Both will then experience ers for their competing customers.

Interfaces
26 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Economic Order Quantity Costs underage costs of K. For N clients, the total expected
The economic-order-quantity (EOQ) model nicely overage and underage costs for that level of the sup-
illustrates the economies-of-scale benefits of central- ply chain are NK. On the other hand, if the supplier
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

ization. For simplicity, assume that each client (retailer combines the demands of its clients and warehouses
or franchisee) has the same holding cost H , setup the items centrally, the demand distribution for all
cost S, and annual demand D. Further assume that clients combined is also normal with mean N and
the supplier’s (or central warehouser’s) holding and variance N 2 , and the
√ total expected
√ overage and
setup costs are also H and S, respectively. The underage costs are K N 2 = N K. Just as√in the
EOQ cost for each client warehousing on its own is EOQ example, the savings percent equals 1 − N /N .

2DSH For N clients, the total √ EOQ costs for that
level of the supply chain are N 2DSH . On the other Risk Pooling—Safety Stocks and
hand, if the supplier combines the demands of every
client and warehouses Service Levels
 the items centrally, then the
total EOQ costs are 2NDSH. Students of business typically learn how to compute
Therefore, the savings percent for the channel safety stocks under continuous-review and periodic-
obtainable from centralized warehousing is review inventory systems with normally distributed
√ √ √ demands (Krajewski and Ritzman 2002). Specifi-
N − N  2SDH N cally, the safety stock equals z, where z represents
√ = 1−
N 2SDH N the number of standard deviations above the mean
Thus, with only four client sites, the channel saves 50 needed to achieve a desired cycle service level and
percent on holding and setup costs. The amount rises  is the standard deviation of demand over the pro-
to 80 percent for 25 sites and 90 percent for 100 sites. tection interval. By using centralization, the supplier
(Obtaining these savings may require additional costs (1) can decrease the total system safety stock, or
for centralization, such as increased transportation.) (2) can increase service levels using the same total
system safety stock.
If we assume that each of N clients has the same,
Risk Pooling—Newsvendor but independent, normal probability demand distri-
Environment bution with mean  and variance  2 , then the total
Eppen (1979) illustrates the risk-pooling benefits amount of safety stock for that level of the supply
(“statistical economies of scale”) of centralized ware- chain is Nz. On the other hand, if the supplier com-
housing in a one-period newsvendor environment bines the demands of all the clients and warehouses
with normal probability distributions. Evans (1997) the items centrally, the demand distribution for all
and many other authors of operations management clients combined is also normal with mean N and
2
textbooks describe how to determine the optimal variance
√ √ , and the total amount of safety stock is
N
order quantity in this environment to minimize z N = N z. As
2
√ in the EOQ example, the savings
expected overage and underage costs. Eppen (1979) percent equals 1 − N /N .
shows that firm i choosing its optimal order quan- If instead the centralized warehouser keeps the
tity has expected overage and underage costs equal total safety stock the same as the clients did ware-
to Ki , where i is firm i’s standard deviation of housing on their own, the new √ higher z-value can
demand. (Eppen gives the value of K, but it is not be
√ imputed as follows: Nz old  = N znew , or znew =
needed for classroom use of this example.) N zold . By coordinating just a few clients, a supply
If we assume that each client has the same over- chain can attain a much higher level of service with
age and underage costs per unit, and the same, but the same amount of safety stock (Table 1).
independent, normal probability demand distribution The percent of cost savings from centralizing safety
with mean  and variance  2 , then each client ware- stocks varies with the number of clients (Table 2).
housing on its own has total expected overage and These savings are applicable to all three situations:

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 27
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Cycle Service Level (1) EOQ costs, (2) newsvendor model costs, and
Number of 7000% 8000% 9000% (3) risk pooling of safety stocks. Clearly, coordinating
Clients (N) (zold = 05244) (zold = 08416) (zold = 12816) just a few clients can produce significant savings.
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

2 7708% 8830% 9650%


3 8181% 9275% 9868%
4 8529% 9538% 9948% Example 3: Coordinated Lot Sizes
5 8795% 9701% 9979%
6 9005% 9804% 9992% with Deterministic Demand
7 9173% 9870% 9997% Isaac’s Ice Cream produces 1 million boxes of a spe-
8 9310% 9914% 9999%
cial frozen treat per year exclusively for a large gro-
9 9422% 9942% 9999%
10 9514% 9961% 10000%
cery chain. The chain has been ordering 8,165 boxes
11 9590% 9974% 10000% at a time (presumably its EOQ) approximately every
12 9654% 9982% 10000% three days. In college, Isaac heard that manufactur-
13 9707% 9988% 10000% ers should produce in an integer multiple of demand
14 9751% 9992% 10000%
when orders are lumpy. Because this product has an
15 9789% 9994% 10000%
25 9956% 10000% 10000% expensive setup cost and a very fast production rate,
50 9999% 10000% 10000% Isaac has found it cheapest to produce 48,990 boxes
100 10000% 10000% 10000% at a time (every 18 days).
This lumpy demand seems beneficial; Isaac notices
Table 1: This table displays the cycle service levels obtained from central-
that his total annual setup and holding costs amount
izing decentralized service levels of 70, 80, and 90 percent. For the same
level of safety stock, centralized warehousing √provides an increased cycle to $91,856, whereas the EOQ model tells him that his
service level according to the formula znew = Nzold . costs would be $100,000 if demand were not lumpy.
That revelation makes him wonder, “Is my incom-
Number of Cost ing demand lumpy enough? If my customer ordered
Clients (N) Savings (%) larger amounts less frequently, would I save even
more money?” Realizing that his firm could also pro-
2 29.29
duce about 49,000 units at a time by making four
3 42.26
4 50.00 times incoming orders of 12,250 units, Isaac computes
5 55.28 the costs and learns that he could save $4,086 by
6 59.18 doing so. He wonders whether passing some of the
7 62.20 savings along to the grocery chain in the form of a
8 64.64
9 66.67
quantity discount would induce the chain to increase
10 68.38 its order size accordingly.
11 69.85
12 71.13
13 72.26 Most students learn about the EOQ model and pos-
14 73.27 sibly some of its extensions, such as the EOQ with
15 74.18 finite production rate or the EOQ with all-units quan-
25 80.00
tity discounts (Krajewski and Ritzman 2002). How-
50 85.86
100 90.00
ever, they seldom explore the effect that those lumpy
1000 96.84 orders of size Q∗ have on the suppliers. While opti-
mal for a retailer acting alone, the EOQ is seldom
Table 2: With regard to (1) EOQ costs, (2) newsvendor model costs, or (3) optimal for a supply chain consisting of the retailer
safety-stock costs under continuous or periodic review systems, central-
√ and its supplier. Based on this realization, Hewlett-
ized warehousing reduces those costs by a percentage equal to 1− N/N.
Packard uses a mathematical program to determine

Interfaces
28 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

inventory levels for some products at both its dis- Step 1: Compute
tribution centers and dealer stores, thereby minimiz-   
ing systemwide inventory levels (Lee and Billington 1 4S H − Hs 
n∗ = 1 + 1 + Max 0 s r
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

1995). 2 Sr Hs
In this example, we assume that a single retailer
Step 2: Compute
operates under the typical EOQ assumptions, and it
purchases its product from a single supplier (with an S = Ss /n∗ + Sr and H = n∗ − 1Hs + Hr
essentially infinite production rate). Under these con-
ditions, it is optimal for the supplier’s lot size to be Step 3: Compute
an integer multiple, n, of the retailer’s lot size (Lee
and Rosenblatt 1986). Q∗ = 2DS/H

Notation The terms S and H represent the system setup cost


D = annual demand. per retailer’s order and the annual holding cost per
Ss = supplier’s setup cost. unit for the system, respectively. The retailer orders
Sr = retailer’s setup cost. Q∗ and the supplier orders n∗ Q∗ . At those quantities,
Hs = supplier’s annual holding cost per unit. the total system setup and holding cost equals T C ∗ =

Hr = retailer’s annual holding cost per unit. 2DS H .
Q = retailer’s order size. For example, consider a product with an annual
n = supplier’s integer lot-size multiplier. demand of 25,000 units, Ss = $200, Sr = $40 50, Hs =
nQ = supplier’s lot size. $2 00, and Hr = $2 50.
x = the greatest integer ≤ x. If the firms act independently, the retailer will order
its EOQ of 900 units, and n∗ will equal 3, implying
From Munson and Rosenblatt (2001), we can derive that the supplier’s lot size will be 3900 = 2700 units.
the following formulas. Total annual supply-chain The total system cost of these lot sizes equals $5,902,
holding and setup costs are equal to and the retailer’s portion is $2,250.
        On the other hand, if the firms optimize jointly,
D n − 1Q D Q n∗ = 1, S = $240 50, H = $2 50, and Q∗ = 2193 units.
TC = Ss + Hs + Sr + Hr
nQ 2 Q 2 Thus, the retailer orders 2,193 units and so does the
supplier (1(2,193)). The total system cost using these
The first two terms represent the supplier’s annual
values is $5,483, which is 7.1 percent lower than
setup and holding costs, respectively, and the second
the cost when the firms do not coordinate.
two terms represent the retailer’s annual setup and
The supplier’s costs decrease with joint optimi-
holding costs, respectively.
zation by $3652 − $2280 = $1372. However, the
When the parties optimize independently, the
retailer’s costs increase (because it no longer orders
retailer orders Q∗ and the supplier orders n∗ Q∗ , where
its EOQ) by $3203 − $2250 = $953. Therefore, some
 of the supplier’s savings should be redistributed in
2DS r
Q∗ = compensation to the retailer. A quantity discount for
Hr
ordering 2,193 units instead of 900 units is an excel-
and lent way to entice the retailer to agree to this change
   in policy. Monahan (1984), Lee and Rosenblatt (1986),
1 8DS s and Weng and Wong (1993) present generalized ver-
n∗ = 1+ 1+ sions of this problem. Munson and Rosenblatt (2001)
2 Hs Q∗ 2
show that the savings continue to grow when the sup-
When they optimize jointly, they go through three ply chain is expanded to three levels by including the
steps: supplier’s supplier in the model.

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 29
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Cost Savings from just drop everything to fill your orders. We go for
Ss /Sr Q∗new /Q∗old Coordination (%) weeks at a time hearing nothing from you, and then
all of a sudden you place an order for three months’
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

1 141 572 worth of demand. I don’t get it. One of your grocery
2 173 1340
retailers gave me data on her sales of your ice cream
3 200 2000
4 224 2546 sandwiches last month. Other than a few spikes on
5 245 3001 weekends, her sales have been very steady. Yet I never
6 265 3386 know what to expect from you. I can’t afford to hold
7 283 3715 inventory for you for months at a time. Do you have
8 300 4000 steady sales at all of the grocery outlets? If so, why
9 316 4250
do I get these crazy orders from you? I never know
10 332 4472
15 400 5294 what to expect! We’re family. Talk to me!”
20 458 5834
50 714 7253
Many business school students get the opportu-
100 1005 8029
nity to play the beer game during their college
Table 3: This table displays the benefits from lot-sizing coordination careers (Sterman 1989, 1992). In this popular role-
between a retailer and its supplier when the supplier uses a lot-for-lot playing game, students act out the roles of a retailer,
production policy. The retailer should increase its order size by a factor
 wholesaler, distributor, or manufacturer in a supply
of Ss /Sr + 1 (Monahan 1984). The system percentage cost savings from chain who are determining order sizes in attempts

coordination equals 1 − 2 Ss /Sr + 1/2 + Ss /Sr .
to minimize back-order and inventory-holding costs.
Although players are rewarded based on the total
In the special case in which the supplier always costs of their team, they invariably play the game
utilizes a lot-for-lot production policy (n∗ = 1), the by focusing on minimizing their own costs indepen-
benefits of coordination increase as the ratio of the dently. An important feature of the game is that the
supplier’s setup cost to the retailer’s setup cost members of the supply chain can communicate only
increases (Table 3). Other things being equal, it is through the orders they place, that is, only the retailer
more important to the supply chain for the retailer to sees the final consumer demand.
increase its order size when a lot-for-lot supplier has Typically the game results in wide oscillations in
a large setup cost. inventory, back orders, and order sizes, which are
most pronounced for the upstream players, that is, for
the distributor and especially for the manufacturer.
Example 4: Coordinated Demand Procter and Gamble executives have coined the term
Forecasting bullwhip effect to describe this phenomenon in their
Isaac’s Ice Cream sells certain ice cream sandwiches firm’s supply chain. Lee et al. (1997b) have identified
to regional food wholesalers who distribute them four major sources of the bullwhip effect that are con-
through local grocery stores. Isaac’s sister Janet sup- sistent with rational managerial behavior: (1) demand
plies most of the primary ingredients. One day Janet forecast updating, (2) order batching, (3) price fluctu-
and Isaac met for their annual review. The whole- ation, and (4) rationing and shortage gaming. Kamin-
salers had been complaining to Isaac about late deliv- sky and Simchi-Levi (1998) report the results of a com-
eries, yet eight times during the last year he was puterized beer game that allows for easy manipula-
forced to purchase extra storage space for finished tion of some of the game’s parameters. They have
goods because he had run out of room at the factory. successfully used the game in classroom settings.
He had been late with many deliveries because the Examples abound of high-profile manufacturers
supplies from Janet had arrived late to him. suffering the impacts of poor forecasting. For instance,
“It’s not my fault,” Janet exclaimed. “I’m running a in the mid-1990s, IBM and Apple Computers made
small company. I do have other customers, and I can’t forecast errors that caused them huge losses and

Interfaces
30 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

eroded their market shares. The effects rippled up vidual players and the other with all players using
and down their supply chains (Fisher et al. 1997). the retailer’s forecasts.
To improve forecasting, some firms have strived to Our model illustrates a two-firm channel using sim-
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

increase information sharing throughout their supply ple (naive) forecasting and one-period lead times. It
chains. For example, JCPenney has reported almost can be extended to include more channel members,
daily communications for one of its clothing lines more complicated forecasting schemes, or longer lead
back through the manufacturer (Robinson Manufac- times, as desired by the instructor. We simulate a 20-
turing), the textile mill (Milliken and Company), and
period game with a retailer receiving orders from con-
even the fiber producer (Du Pont) (Thornton 1995).
sumers and placing orders with its wholesaler. The
Using a simplified beer game setting with no player
wholesaler has unlimited production capacity. A one-
discretion, we can unambiguously demonstrate the
period lead time applies to all orders. We use naive
benefits of coordinating demand forecasts. Lee et al.
(1997a, b) suggest sharing information about con- forecasts, that is, we use this period’s demand as the
sumer demand with all supply-chain members or next period’s forecast. Both players use an order-up-
having one member perform forecasting for all the to policy, in which the order size equals next period’s
members. Students can gain an understanding of forecast minus the inventory position, which includes
the potential power of this strategy by building two current inventory plus scheduled receipts minus back
spreadsheet models, one with forecasting by the indi- orders. In each period, the retailer moves first and the

A B C D E F G H I J K L
1 Retailer Wholesaler
2 Next Next
3 Consumers' Period's On-Hand Order In-Transit Period's On-Hand Order In-Transit
4 Period Orders Forecast Inventory Back Orders Placed Inventory Forecast Inventory Back Orders Placed Inventory
5 0 5 0 5 5 0 5
6 1 5 5 5 0 0 0 0 10 0 0 0
7 2 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 5 0 0 0
8 3 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
9 4 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
10 5 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
11 6 20 20 0 15 35 5 35 0 30 65 65
12 7 20 20 0 30 20 50 20 15 0 5 5
13 8 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
14 9 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
15 10 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
16 11 50 50 0 30 80 20 80 0 60 140 140
17 12 30 30 0 40 10 70 10 70 0 0 0
18 13 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 40 0 0 0
19 14 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 10 0 20 20
20 15 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 0 0 30 30
21 16 10 10 20 0 0 0 0 30 0 0 0
22 17 10 10 10 0 0 0 0 30 0 0 0
23 18 50 50 0 40 90 30 90 0 60 150 150
24 19 10 10 0 20 0 60 0 90 0 0 0
25 20 10 10 30 0 0 0 0 90 0 0 0
26 Total 70 175 410 395 150 490

Figure 2: The Excel Microsoft simulation of a simplified beer game displays inventory and back orders for a
two-firm supply chain with forecasting based on each party’s own demand. We provide formulas in Table 4.

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 31
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

A B C D E F G H I J K L
31 Retailer Wholesaler
32 Next Next
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

33 Consumers' Period's On-Hand Order In-Transit Period's On-Hand Order In-Transit


34 Period Orders Forecast Inventory Back Orders Placed Inventory Forecast Inventory Back Orders Placed Inventory
35 0 5 0 5 5 0 5
36 1 5 5 5 0 0 0 5 10 0 0 0
37 2 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 5 0 0 0
38 3 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
39 4 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
40 5 5 5 0 0 5 5 5 0 0 5 5
41 6 20 20 0 15 35 5 20 0 30 50 50
42 7 20 20 0 30 20 50 20 0 0 20 20
43 8 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
44 9 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
45 10 20 20 0 0 20 20 20 0 0 20 20
46 11 50 50 0 30 80 20 50 0 60 110 110
47 12 30 30 0 40 10 70 30 40 0 0 0
48 13 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 10 0 20 20
49 14 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 0 0 30 30
50 15 30 30 0 0 30 30 30 0 0 30 30
51 16 10 10 20 0 0 0 10 30 0 0 0
52 17 10 10 10 0 0 0 10 30 0 0 0
53 18 50 50 0 40 90 30 50 0 60 110 110
54 19 10 10 0 20 0 60 10 50 0 0 0
55 20 10 10 30 0 0 0 10 50 0 0 0
56 Total 70 175 410 230 150 450

Figure 3: This Microsoft Excel simulation of a simplified beer game displays inventory and back orders for a two-
firm supply chain with forecasting for both parties based on the actual consumers’ orders. We provide formulas
in Table 4. Compared to Figure 2 (uncoordinated forecasting), the wholesaler’s total on-hand inventory is 42
percent smaller when demand information is shared.

wholesaler follows. Each player first moves in-transit forecasting information between the parties. For this
inventory, then fills back orders and new orders to example, when demand information is shared, the
the extent possible, and then places new orders (to be wholesaler’s total on-hand inventory held over 20
received in the succeeding period, subject to availabil- periods is 165 units (42 percent) smaller than the
ity). Both players begin with five units in inventory case of no information sharing. In the uncoordinated
and five units in transit (to be received in period 1). case (Figure 2), the wholesaler is overreacting to the
This type of simulation can be shown in class or retailer’s catch-up orders by assuming that future
underlying consumer demand will be larger than it
given as a computer assignment for students. Fig-
actually turns out to be. Lee et al. (1997a, b) provide
ures 2 and 3 show the Microsoft Excel spreadsheets
real-world examples of successful information shar-
used in our example. Table 4 presents the applicable
ing among supply-chain members.
formulas. In Figure 2, the wholesaler’s forecast equals
the order received from the retailer in that period. In
Figure 3, the wholesaler’s forecast equals the retailer’s Example 5: Coordinated Pricing
forecast, which equals the consumer orders in that Each year Isaac’s Ice Cream sells its special blend at
period. Figure 3 represents sharing of demand or the state fair. The fair lasts for only a few days, and

Interfaces
32 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Cell Formula Explanation

C6 = B6 Retailer’s forecast equals this period’s consumer demand.


Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

D6 = MAXD5 + G5 − E5 − B6 0 Retailer’s ending inventory after this period.


E6 = MAXE5 + B6 − D5 − G5 0 Retailer’s ending back orders after this period.
F6 = MAXC6 − D6 + J5 − E6 0 Order-up-to policy = next period’s forecast − inventory position.
G6 = MINF6 + J5 I5 + L5 Amount put into shipment from the wholesaler this period.
H6 = F6 Wholesaler’s forecast equals retailer’s order size this period.
I6 = MAXI5 + L5 − J5 − F6 0 Wholesaler’s ending inventory after this period.
J6 = MAXJ5 + F6 − I5 − L5 0 Wholesaler’s ending back orders after this period.
K6 = MAXH6 − I6 − J6 0 Order-up-to policy = next period’s forecast − inventory position.
L6 = K6 Assuming the wholesaler has infinite production capacity.

Change for Figure 3


H36 = B36 Wholesaler’s forecast equals this period’s consumer demand.

Table 4: These are the Microsoft Excel formulas for the forecasting simulation shown in Figures 2 and 3.

Isaac sells this particular item only at this annual fair. is, by selecting the output level at which marginal
Thus, he must determine ahead of time the appro- revenue equals marginal cost (Mansfield 1983). But
priate quantity to produce and deliver. He sells the what happens if a retailer and its supplier are both
ice cream through an independently operated booth monopolists and part of the retailer’s marginal cost
at the fair that sells many other food items. Isaac has is the wholesale price? The supply chain loses money
been successfully selling his special blend of ice cream when the firms do not coordinate their pricing but
for a number of years, and, by monitoring the price instead rely on the traditional, sequential method in
the booth charges consumers, he has determined that which the supplier first sets the wholesale price and
demand is very price sensitive. the retailer reacts accordingly, as shown in Exam-
Last year Isaac charged his retailer $3.00 per pint, ple 5. This example is most appropriate for goods
and it cost him $1.00 per pint to produce. The retailer that cannot be stored for long, that is, goods that
charged $4.00 per pint and sold 2,000 units. The are perishable or have short life cycles. The computer
retailer’s variable costs consisted primarily of the industry represents such an environment with short
wholesale price paid to Isaac. Isaac’s research indi- and price-sensitive demand. Some computer firms
cated that he could double sales to 4,000 units if the have suffered losses in recent years because of their
retailer reduced the price to $3.00. The math seemed poor pricing and forecasting practices (Weng 1999).
simple to Isaac: “This year I’ll lower the wholesale
price to $2.50 and tell my retailer to sell the ice Case 1: A System with One Retailer
cream for $3.00 per pint. I’ll earn $6,000 instead of
and One Supplier
$4,000, and the retailer will still earn $2,000, so he
Let the retailer’s demand curve be P = 900 − 2Q
will be no worse off.” However, the retailer ignored
(where P is the retail price and Q is the quantity
Isaac’s suggestion and only lowered the price to $3.75,
sold), and let the marginal costs (exclusive of whole-
inducing a demand of 2,500 units. Compared to last
sale price) be $10 and $90 for the retailer and sup-
year, Isaac’s profits fell from $4,000 to $3,750, but
plier, respectively. Total revenue for the retailer is
the retailer’s profits rose from $2,000 to $3,125. What
P × Q = 900Q − 2Q2 . Marginal revenue is the deriva-
happened?
tive of total revenue with respect to Q, which equals
900 − 4Q. If the firms are considered as one organi-
Students taking any introductory microeconomics zation, then the optimal quantity Q∗ solves marginal
class learn that a monopolist will maximize profits by revenue = marginal cost: 900 − 4Q = 100, or Q∗ =
following the golden rule of output determination, that 200. A $500 price induces a demand of 200 units, so

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 33
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

the total channel profits are 200 $500 − $10 + $90 = nel profits to share between the two parties. Any all-
$80000. units quantity discount between $100 and $200 per
Next, consider independent optimization. The sup- unit for orders of size 200 will create $20,000 of new
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

plier knows that the retailer will set marginal rev- wealth for the channel, and neither firm will be worse
enue equal to marginal cost, that is, 900 − 4Q = 10 + off than with no discount. For example, a discount
W , where W is the wholesale price charged to the of $100 per unit would allocate all of the new prof-
retailer. So, the supplier faces a demand curve from its to the supplier, a discount of $150 per unit would
the retailer of W = 890 − 4Q. With this linear demand evenly split the increased profits, or a discount of $200
function, the supplier’s total revenue is W × Q = per unit would allocate all of the new profits to the
890Q − 4Q2 , and the marginal revenue should equal retailer. (Jeuland and Shugan 1983 provide a general-
the supplier’s marginal cost, that is, 890 − 8Q = 90, ized version of this problem.)
implying that Q∗ = 100. After plugging Q∗ into the Students may wonder why the supplier does not
supplier’s demand function, the profit-maximizing simply lower W to the point where 200 units max-
wholesale price becomes W ∗ = 890 − 4100 = $490. Of imizes the retailer’s profit. To find that W , set the
course, with a wholesale price of $490, the retailer will retailer’s marginal revenue equal to its marginal
also maximize profits by selling 100 units, which will cost, that is, 900 − 4200 = 10 + W , or W ∗ = $90. At
be induced by a retail price of P ∗ = 900 − 2100 = this wholesale price, total channel profits are indeed
$700. With these values, the supplier’s profit equals $80,000, but the retailer captures all of it while the
100$490 − $90 = $40000, which is one-half of the supplier’s profit equals $0. Thus, while lowering W
amount achievable through cooperative optimization. always helps the total channel, it always hurts the
Furthermore, the retailer’s profit equals 100 $700 − supplier, who would likely be unwilling to comply
$10 + $490 = $20000, which is one-fourth of the unless the retailer somehow transferred some money
amount achievable through cooperative optimization. back. A quantity discount avoids such complications.
Total channel profits are $40000 + $20000 = $60000.
Cooperative optimization produces $20,000 (33 per- Case 2: A System with One Retailer
cent) more than independent optimization would pro- and N − 1 Supplier Tiers
duce. (It can be shown (Appendix) that the 33 percent Consider a supply chain with one retailer and N − 1
profit increase holds for any linear demand function supplier tiers. For example, a supply chain consisting
and associated marginal costs.) of a retailer, the retailer’s supplier, and the retailer’s
In class, it is also interesting to see if students can supplier’s supplier would contain two supplier tiers.
determine ways to achieve the desired cooperation If the retailer has a linear demand curve of the form
between the retailer and the wholesaler. The goal is to P = a − bQ (a b > 0), the system percentage profit
get the retailer to sell 200 units by setting a retail price increase from coordinated pricing vs. individual opti-
of $500. However, the retailer will not comply as long mization is
as the wholesale price remains $490. The actual coop- 22N −2 − 2N + 1
eration mechanism used will depend on the relation- 2N − 1
ship between the two firms and their relative power.
(The proof is in the Appendix.) Substantial potential
Students may come up with such ideas as the sup-
benefits to system profits from coordinating pricing
plier imposing a retail price of $500 or a minimum are particularly prevalent in supply chains with mul-
order quantity of 200 units. In addition, either firm tiple tiers (Table 5).
could vertically integrate to eliminate the problem.
A quantity discount approach represents an excel-
lent coordination mechanism. If the retailer actually
Example 6: Coordinated
did lower its price to $500, then the retailer’s profit Newsvendor Lot Sizes
would become $0, but the supplier’s profit would Isaac’s Ice Cream sells “homemade” vanilla shakes
double to $80,000. Now there are $20,000 of new chan- daily at Sunnyside Park during the summertime. The

Interfaces
34 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Number of Supplier Profit supply-chain members share risks is by having the


Tiers (N − 1) Increase % supplier sell some goods on consignment, whereby
the goods remain the supplier’s property even though
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

1 3333
located at the retailer. Businesses with very uncertain
2 12857
3 32667
demand, such as jewelers, may be particularly likely
4 72581 to promote consignment (Munson et al. 1999).
5 152540 The newsvendor problem is often taught in intro-
6 312520 ductory operations management classes. The problem
arises when a retailer must make a one-time pur-
Table 5: This table displays the benefits from coordinated pricing between
chase of a single product to meet uncertain customer
a retailer and its N − 1 tiers of single suppliers when the retailer has
a linear demand curve of the form P = a − bQ a b > 0. The system
demand. For a simple one-level newsvendor prob-
percentage profit increase equals (22N−2 − 2N + 1/2N − 1). lem, if we let O denote the overage cost per unit
and U denote the underage cost per unit, the optimal
order size Q∗ is chosen such that F Q∗  = U /O + U ,
pint-sized shakes are sold by the driver of an ice
where F x is the cumulative distribution function of
cream truck who stores the mixture in a cooler that
the random customer demand X (Evans 1997). How-
keeps it frozen for only a few hours. After that, the
ever, the order quantity that maximizes profits for
driver can sell any remaining (melted) mixture to
the retailer may not maximize the total supply-chain
Pete’s Pig Farm for 87.5 cents per pint. The truck
profits when we also consider the cost structure of
driver places her order at night and makes one trip
the retailer’s supplier. Example 6 illustrates how to
to Isaac’s factory the next morning on her way to the
coordinate lot sizes in a two-level newsvendor envi-
park. Isaac produces exactly the amount ordered. The
ronment. We show that risk pooling via vertical coor-
driver pays Isaac $2.00 per pint, and she sells it in
dination leads to higher order quantities (with a lower
shake form for $4.00 per pint. (Her other marginal
risk of unmet demand but a higher risk of ending
costs for these shakes are minimal.) Daily demand
seems to vary fairly evenly (that is, with no noticeable with excess supply) and, more important, leads to
mode) between 50 and 250 units. Isaac produces the higher profits for the channel.
mixture at a cost of $1.00 per pint. We assume that the supplier has a lot-for-lot policy
Home for the summer from business college, the and will order and sell to the retailer the amount the
truck driver’s daughter tells her that the best possi- retailer requests. Let Ps and Pr be the prices charged
ble amount for her to order every day is 178 pints. by the supplier and retailer, respectively. Let Cs be
However, Isaac’s son attends the same business col- the supplier’s manufacturing cost per unit, and let Cr
lege, and he is convinced that the truck driver should be the retailer’s cost per unit, exclusive of purchasing
be trying to sell 242 units per day. Obviously, Isaac’s cost Ps . Let V be the salvage value of any unsold units
expected profits would rise, but that order size seems at the end of the selling season. Let Qc∗ and Qu∗ be the
very risky for the truck driver, so her expected profits optimal order size under a coordinated system and
would likely fall. How can Isaac convince the truck an uncoordinated system, respectively. (We derive the
driver to order so many more units? And if he com- following results in the Appendix.)
pensates her for the greater risk, will any excess prof- If the retailer acts independently, the lot size should
its remain for him? be chosen such that F Qu∗  = Pr − Cr − Ps /Pr − V .
The lot size in a coordinated system should be chosen
such that F Qc∗  = Pr − Cr − Cs /Pr − V . The (non-
In Example 2, we explored the risk-pooling bene-
negative) profit increase for the supply chain due to
fits of horizontal coordination in a newsvendor envi-
coordination is
ronment. In this example, we explore the benefits of
vertical coordination in a supply chain consisting of  Qc∗
Pr − Cs − Cr Qc∗ − Qu∗  − Pr − V  F x dx
a single retailer and a single supplier. One way that Qu∗

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 35
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

The order size will be increased when there is coor- 50%

Supply-Chain Profit Increase


dination between the two firms because Cs < Ps . The
40%
supplier’s profits increase with the joint optimization,
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

but the retailer’s profits decrease. Therefore, some of 30%


the increase in total channel profits should be redis-
tributed to the retailer as an incentive for coordination 20%

through quantity discounts or some other method. 10%


Typical classroom examples illustrate the basic
newsvendor problem by using either the normal or 0%
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8
the uniform distribution. We can use the following Coefficient of Variation
equation using the Excel commands NORMSDIST
and NORMDIST to approximate the expected profit Figure 4: Sensitivity analysis on the numerical example for the coordi-
of ordering Q units when the demand is normally nated newsvendor lot sizes with normally distributed demand shows that,
distributed with mean  and standard deviation  when all the other parameters remain unchanged, the percent of profit
(modified from Chopra and Meindl 2001): increase becomes larger when the coefficient of variation increases (by
increasing the standard deviation of demand). This suggests that the ben-
  
Q− efits from channel coordination are greater when the demand has more
* = U + O  · NORMSDIST variability.

 
Q−
−  · NORMDIST  0 1 0
 order size is Qc∗ = NORMINV60/30 + 60 1000
When the demand is uniformly distributed in the 500 = 1215 units. Total channel profits are $60 +
interval (a, b, the expected profit of ordering the opti- $30 1000 · NORMSDIST1215 − 1000/500 − 500·
mal quantity equals NORMDIST1215 − 1000/500 0 1 0 = $43638,
which represents a 17.34 percent improvement over
b − aU 2 independent optimization.
* = aU +
2U + O Sensitivity analysis performed on this example by
(We provide the derivation in the Appendix.) altering the standard deviation (thus changing the
For a numerical example of a normal distribution, coefficient of variation) suggests that the value of
assume that the market demand for the product fol- coordination increases as the uncertainty of demand
lows a normal distribution with a mean of 1,000 units increases (Figure 4).
and a standard deviation of 500 units. In addition, Suppose that the cost factors remain unchanged,
Cs = Cr = $20, Ps = $50, Pr = $100 (thus both the sup- but demand is uniformly distributed between 5,000
plier and the retailer have the same $30 profit margin), and 15,000 units. Without coordination, the retailer
and V = $10. will set its order quantity at Qu∗ = 5000 + 15000 −
If the firms act independently, U = 30 and O = 60, −5000 30/60 + 30 = 8333 units. Its expected prof-
so the retailer will order (using the Excel com- its are 5000$30 + 15000 − 5000$302  / 2$30 +
mand NORMINV) Qu∗ = NORMINV30/60 + 30 $60 = $200000. The supplier’s profits equal $50 −
1000 500 = 785 units. The retailer’s expected prof- $208333 = $249990. Thus, the total channel profits
its are $30 + $60 1000 · NORMSDIST785 − 1000/ are $200000 + $249990 = $449990.
500 − 500 · NORMDIST785 − 1000/500 0, 1, 0 = Alternatively, if the two firms are considered
$13638 The supplier’s profits are $50 − $20785 = as one organization, Qc∗ = 5000 + 15000 − 5000×
$23550. Consequently, the total channel profits are 60/30 + 60 = 11667 units. Total channel profits are
$13638 + $23550 = $37188. 5000$60 + 15000 − 5000$602  / 2$60 + $30 =
Alternatively, if the two firms are considered as $500000, representing an 11.11 percent improvement
one organization, U = 60 and O = 30, and the best over independent optimization.

Interfaces
36 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Conclusion Appendix
Cooperation between supply-chain members may be Proofs for Example 5: Coordinated
easier said than done. Chopra and Meindl (2001)
Pricing with Multiple Supplier Tiers
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

describe major obstacles to supply-chain coordina-


tion falling into five categories: incentive obstacles, The following propositions extend the coordinated
information-processing obstacles, operational obsta- pricing strategy to a supply chain with one retailer and
cles, pricing obstacles, and behavioral obstacles. N − 1 single supplier tiers. Let *c represent the system
Taken to the extreme, our arguments here might profit under coordinated pricing, and let *u represent
imply that firms should simply vertically integrate to the system profit under uncoordinated pricing. Let Ci
bypass certain obstacles and create the natural incen- be the marginal cost of firm i (i = 1 2  N ) where
tive to cooperate throughout the supply chain and i = 1 denotes the retailer, i = 2 denotes the retailer’s
thus to eliminate the inefficiencies that arise. How- supplier, i = 3 denotes the retailer’s supplier’s sup-
ever, most real-world companies do not vertically plier, and so forth. With the exception of firm N (the
integrate to an extreme, which implies that strong bar- most upstream member of the supply chain), Ci does
riers to vertical integration exist as well (Williamson not include the purchase price. Let Pi denote the price
1985). Instead, forward-looking members of supply charged by firm i The decision variable Q represents
chains are finding innovative ways to create a spirit the quantity sold to final customers, and Q∗ repre-
of cooperation. sents the optimal (profit-maximizing) quantity. The
A basic premise of supply-chain management is retailer faces a deterministic linear demand curve of
that communication and coordination can greatly the form P1 = a − bQ (a b > 0).
enhance the effectiveness of the supply chain, creat- Proposition 1. If there is coordination among the N
ing financial benefits that the cooperating members of firms,
the chain can share. Mechanisms to encourage coop-
 
eration can take a variety of forms, including quan- 1 N
1 N
2

tity discounts (Chopra and Meindl 2001). As with any Q∗ = a − Ci and *c = a − Ci


2b i=1
4b i=1
group of entities, when all members effectively inte-
grate their efforts, synergies may emerge. In supply Proof. If the N firms are considered as one orga-
chains in particular, the actions of rational managers nization, marginal revenue = a − 2bQ, and marginal
of firms acting independently create natural ineffi- 
cost = i Ci . Setting these equal yields the Q∗
ciencies that would not exist if the supply-chain mem- stated in the proposition. Plugging this into the
bers coordinated their efforts. Numerical examples retailer’s demand function yields the retail price
can clearly illustrate these effects. We have collected 
P1 = a + i Ci /2. With no intercompany transac-
examples suitable for classroom use that arise in com- 
tions, the system profit is *c = Q∗ P1 − i Ci  =
mon areas where companies use and abuse power: 
a − i Ci 2 /4b. 
inventory control, pricing control, information con-
trol, control over the channel structure, and opera- Proposition 2. If there is no coordination among the
tions control (Munson et al. 1999). Similar examples N firms,
could be developed to address other issues, such as 
transportation costs or joint advertising ventures. We ∗ 1  N
Q = N a − Ci
hope that future managers will recognize that success 2 b i=1
in today’s global marketplace demands close attention
to all supply-chain functions and a constant search and
for ways to work with supply-chain partners to bet-  2
 2−N 2−2N
 1 N
ter compete together against other powerful supply *u = 2 −2 a − Ci
4b
chains. i=1

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 37
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

Proof. The tier 1 supplier (i = 2) knows that the Expected Profit. Define f x as the density func-
retailer will choose the quantity that equates its tion of random demand X. Under independent opti-
marginal revenue (a − 2bQ) with its marginal cost mization, by adding the supplier’s profit to Chopra
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

(C1 + P2 ). Solving for P2 yields the derived demand and Meindl’s (2001) expected profit function for the
curve facing the tier 1 supplier: P2 = a − C1  − 2bQ. retailer, we obtain
Continuing in this fashion up the supply chain,  Qu∗

 *Qu  = xU u − Qu∗ − xOu f x dx
0

m−1

Pm = a − Ci − 2m−1 bQ
i=1
+ Qu∗ Uu f x dx + Ps − Cs Qu∗
Qu∗
 Qu∗
for m = 1 2  N . The uppermost supplier, N , has
= Pr − Cs − Cr Qu∗ − Pr − V  F x dx
a marginal revenue of 0
 Alternatively, if the two firms coordinate, the

N −1
a− Ci − 2N bQ expected system profit becomes
i=1  Qc∗
*Qc∗  = xU c − Qc∗ − xOc f x dx
and a marginal cost of CN . Equating these and solving 0
for Q yields the Q∗ stated in Proposition 2. The profit 
+ Qc∗ Uc f x dx
for firm m equals Q∗ Pm − Pm+1 − Cm  (where PN +1 = 0), Qc∗
which reduces to  Qc∗
 2
= Pr − Cs − Cr Qc∗ − Pr − V  F x dx
2m−2N +1 N 0
a − Ci The profit change, 0*, due to coordination is *Qc∗  −
4b i=1
*Qu∗ , which reduces to
Summing these over all N firms produces a geometric  Qc∗
progression that reduces to the system profit stated in Pr − Cs − Cr Qc∗ − Qu∗  − Pr − V  F x dx
Qu∗
Proposition 2. 
To show that 0* is nonnegative, we utilize the non-
Proposition 3. The system percentage profit increase decreasing property of F x, that is
from coordinated pricing vs. individual optimization is  Qc∗
22N −2 − 2N + 1/2N − 1. Q∗ −Qu∗ Pr −Cs −Cr 
F x dx ≤ Qc∗ −Qu∗ F Qc∗  = c
Qu∗ Pr −V
Proof. From Propositions 1 and 2, *c − *u /*u =
Therefore,
1 − 22−N − 22−2N  /22−N − 22−2N . Multiplying the
numerator and denominator by 22N −2 yields the result 0* ≥ Pr − Cs − Cr Qc∗ − Qu∗ 
stated in Proposition 3. 
− Pr − V Qc∗ − Qu∗ Pr − Cs − Cr /Pr − V 
=0 
Proofs for Example 6: Two-Level
Newsvendor Problem Expected Profit for the Uniform Distribution. If
demand is uniformly distributed between a and b, the
Lot Sizes. If the retailer acts independently, its expected profit of ordering Q units is
underage and overage costs are Uu = Pr −Cr +Ps  and
 Q  b
Ou = Cr + Ps  − V , respectively. The ratio Uu /Ou + Uu  *Q = xU − Q − xO f x dx + QUf x dx
reduces to [Pr − Cr + Ps  /Pr − V . If the firms coor- a Q

dinate, the system underage and overage costs are  Q


= QU − U + O F x dx
Uc = Pr − Cr + Cs  and Oc = Cr + Cs  − V , respectively. a
The ratio Uc /Oc + Uc  reduces to Pr − Cr + Cs  /  Q x−a
Pr − V .  = QU − U + O dx
a b−a

Interfaces
38 Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003
MUNSON, HU, AND ROSENBLATT
Teaching the Costs of Uncoordinated Supply Chains

The optimal Q∗ for the uniform distribution is a + , Shu Ming Ng, eds. 1998. Global Supply Chain and Technol-
b − a U /O + U ]; therefore, ogy Management. POMS Series in Technology and Operations
  Management, Vol. 1. Production and Operations Management
b − aU
Downloaded from informs.org by [134.121.103.10] on 16 November 2014, at 22:23 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

∗ Society, Miami, FL.


*Q  = U a + , Meir J. Rosenblatt. 1986. A generalized quantity discount
U +O
   pricing model to increase supplier’s profits. Management Sci.
U +O 1 b − aU 2 32(9) 1177–1185.
− a+ , V. Padmanabhan, Seungjin Whang. 1997a. Information dis-
b−a 2 U + O
 tortion in a supply chain: The bullwhip effect. Management Sci.
  43(4) 546–558.
b − aU 1 2
−a a + + a , , . 1997b. The bullwhip effect in supply chains. Sloan
U +O 2
Management Rev. 38(3) 93–102.
b − aU 2 Mansfield, Edwin. 1983. Principles of Microeconomics, 4th ed. W. W.
= aU +  Norton and Co., New York.
2U + O Marsh, Barbara. 1992. Franchise realities: Sandwich-shop chain
surges, but to run one can take a heroic effort. Wall Street Jour-
nal (September 16) A6.
References Monahan, James P. 1984. A quantity discount pricing model to
Chopra, Sunil, Peter Meindl. 2001. Supply Chain Management: Strat- increase vendor profits. Management Sci. 30(6) 720–726.
egy, Planning, and Operation. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, Munson, Charles L., Meir J. Rosenblatt. 2001. Coordinating a three-
NJ. level supply chain with quantity discounts. IIE Trans. 33(5)
Davis, Donald. 1994. Partnerships pay off. Manufacturing Systems 371–384.
(November) 4–14. , , Zehava Rosenblatt. 1999. The use and abuse of power
Eppen, Gary D. 1979. Effects of centralization on expected costs in in supply chains. Bus. Horizons 42(1) 55–65.
a multi-location newsboy problem. Management Science 25(5) Rasmusen, Eric. 1989. Games and Information: An Introduction to
498–501. Game Theory. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, U.K.
Evans, James R. 1997. Production/Operations Management: Quality, Ruffenach, G. 1992. Chicken chain’s strategy ruffles franchisees’
Performance, and Value, 5th ed. West Publishing Co., Minneapo- feathers. E. Jerome McCarthy, William D. Perreault Jr., eds.
lis/St. Paul, MN. Applications in Basic Marketing: Clippings from the Popular Busi-
Fisher, Marshall, Janice Hammond, Walter Obermeyer, Ananth ness Press, 1992–1993 ed. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL,
Raman. 1997. Configuring a supply chain to reduce the cost of 110–111.
demand uncertainty. Production Oper. Management 6(3) 211–225. Sterman, John D. 1989. Modeling managerial behavior: Mispercep-
Jeuland, Abel P., Steven M. Shugan. 1983. Managing channel prof- tions of feedback in a dynamic decision making experiment.
its. Marketing Sci. 2(3) 239–272. Management Sci. 35(3) 321–339.
Kaminsky, Philip, David Simchi-Levi. 1998. A new computerized . 1992. Teaching takes off: Flight simulators for management
beer game: A tool for teaching the value of integrated sup- education. OR/MS Today (October) 40–44.
ply chain management. Hau L. Lee, Shu Ming Ng, eds. Global Thornton, M. 1995. Tomorrow’s blueprint. Apparel Indust. Magazine
Supply Chain and Technology Management. POMS Series in Tech- 56(3) QR10–QR14.
nology and Operations Management, Vol. 1. Production and Weng, Z. Kevin. 1999. The power of coordinated decisions for short-
Operations Management Society, Miami, FL, 216–225. life-cycle products in a manufacturing and distribution supply
Krajewski, Lee J., Larry P. Ritzman. 2002. Operations Management: chain. IIE Trans. 31(11) 1037–1049.
Strategy and Analysis, 6th ed. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA. , R. T. Wong. 1993. General models for the supplier’s all-unit
Lee, Hau L., Corey Billington. 1995. The evolution of supply- quantity discount policy. Naval Res. Logist. 40(7) 971–991.
chain-management models and practice at Hewlett-Packard. Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism:
Interfaces 25(4) 42–63. Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. The Free Press, New York.

Interfaces
Vol. 33, No. 3, May–June 2003 39

View publication stats

You might also like