You are on page 1of 13

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rser

Network charging and residential tariffs: A case of household photovoltaics MARK


in the United Kingdom

Wadim Strielkowskia, Dalia Štreimikienėb, , Yuriy Bilanc
a
Energy Policy Research Group, University of Cambridge, 13 Trumpington street, CB2 1AG Cambridge, United Kingdom
b
Lithuanian Energy Institute, Breslaujos 3, Kaunas, Lithuania
c
Microeconomics Department, Faculty of Economics Science and Management, University of Szczecin, ul. Mickiewicza 64, 71-101 Szczecin, Poland

A R T I C L E I N F O A BS T RAC T

JEL Classification: Currently, about one million households in the United Kingdom (UK) have installed solar photovoltaic (PV)
Q41 panels with about two-thirds of them are using the panels for self-generating power. According to the UK
Q42 Department of Energy & Climate Change, solar PV deployment in the UK (measured in megawatt) has grown
Q48 considerably (from 95 MW in 2010 when the feed-in tariff was introduced to 11,429 MW in 2016). The
L50
popularity of the solar PV among the UK households made the government to introduce major changes to the
L94
scheme.
Keywords: Our paper focuses on the two major questions: Could it be that the system already favours richer consumers
Distributed generation
or certain types of network user who do not bear either the efficient or fair share of the total system distribution
Electricity prices
(and transmission) costs? Does the apportionment of charges between fixed, per kW peak and per kWh use of
Solar photovoltaic
Demand tariffs system charges need to be changed to be more cost reflective?
We employ the data from the smart meters readings provided by the Customer-Led Network Revolution
monitoring trial conducted with the 199 households in the Northern England that provides the data for the
household electricity use and tariff behaviour between October 2012 and July 2014.
Our analysis demonstrates that, similar to other studies conducted around the world, the increase in the solar
PV resulted in a transfer of wealth and costs between customer groups. Due to their own production, UK solar
PV consumers yield a lower share of the per kWh costs of the distribution system which leads to the increase of
per unit charges as well as the changes in the distribution of their payment between different types of
households.

1. Introduction other countries, the UK government initiated subsidies for households


installing solar photovoltaic systems (solar PV). This has been done
In 2008, the UK government adopted the 2008 Climate Act and set despite the fact that due to its geographical position and its climate, the
up a target for itself to decrease the carbon emissions by 35% in 2020, use of solar energy in the UK might be not a very practical model in
and by 80% in 2050. Although UK (alongside with France) is amongst comparison with, for example, the case of the Masdar city in the
the most reluctant countries when it comes to the binding renewable Persian Gulf with its year-round sunlight [25].
commitments which can be attributed to the regulatory issues and
administrative barriers, it is also one of the most hard-line supporters 1.1. Electricity prices and tariff methods
of carbon reduction [24]. One of the most useful ways how to achieve
this ambitious goal is the increasingly wider use of distributed renew- Electricity service is dealing with the delivery of both power (kW),
able energy (DRE), in particular domestic solar photovoltaic (PV) energy (kW h) and power quality (e.g. voltage, frequency, or blackouts
systems. In the UK, similar to many countries, it is done through and interruptions) in particular geographic locations. Electricity con-
generous capital subsidies for households installing solar PV [26,27]. sumers value each of these attributes directly, reveal their preferences
Solar energy occupies the leading position among other renewables for each attribute and theoretically and technically it seems possible to
both with regard to its popularity among the general public and with its charge for each of these dimensions of service. However, it has become
broad support by the stakeholders and policy-makers. Similar to many a tradition on electricity markets to offer customers bundled prices.


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: strielkowski@cantab.net (W. Strielkowski), dalia.streimikiene@lei.lt (D. Štreimikienė), yuriy_bilan@yahoo.co.uk (Y. Bilan).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.04.029
Received 20 July 2016; Received in revised form 10 April 2017; Accepted 17 April 2017
Available online 25 April 2017
1364-0321/ © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

From the economic point of view, the welfare Ramsey-Boiteux About 80% of non-HH users (around 23.5 million UK households)
pricing suggests that more fixed costs should be recovered from richer fall under an “Unrestricted” profile class. A further 18% of non-HH
or price-inelastic customers with a trade-off between these two users are under a “Economy 7″ class and have a two-rate meter that
characteristics, thence it seems that some network charges should be allows for a cheaper off-peak (and higher daytime) tariff. Moreover,
targeted on generation side to provide correct signals. In doing so, it Table 2 provides a comparison of distribution charges and average
would be possible to apportion fixed costs by income, property value, customer bills in the UK for the year 2013.
kW connection capacity or another indicator of income (or ability to From the overview of charges and average customer bills, it
pay, such as possession of an electric vehicle (EV) charging point) becomes apparent that between 7% and 20% of the HH customers’
which did not result in electricity market distortions. Among alter- network costs are recovered in fixed charges while about 80–90% are
native network charging principles are, for example: cost reflective recovered in kW h charges.
charging, traditional public service pricing, platform market pricing, or
customer-focused business model pricing.
As the renewable energy sources start to gain larger shares of the 1.2. UK's household solar PV and FiT
traditional electricity markets, the total system costs come down, the
total fixed costs are reduced, and system marginal costs are reduced. Domestic solar PV technology is playing an important role in the
However, the question arises: when the total system costs fall, should it transition to a low carbon energy network as one of the most affordable
be the new users or the existing users who benefit from this? and effective sources of distributed renewable energy generation. The
The solution might be in introducing new changes to the existing CLNR [10] study reported that the UK solar PV households annually
tariff methods such as maximum kW export charge, based on the generate an amount of electricity equivalent to over 40% of their
design rating of the household with PV which both consume and export annual electricity consumption and that 80% of that electricity is
their electric energy. Our paper analysis these issues and attempts to typically used on site.
find new arguments and solutions for new charges and tariffs in the UK's generation of renewable energy is fostered by Renewables
situation with photovoltaics deployment on the traditional electricity Obligation (RO). The RO was initiated in 2002 and it obliges electricity
markets. suppliers to source an increasing percentage of generation from
Currently, UK households are currently paying one of the lowest renewable sources. Electricity generators receive Renewable
retail electricity prices in the EU 15 being well under the EU 15 median Obligation Certificates (ROCs) for the renewable electricity they gen-
and belonging to the group of the EU countries with the similarly low erate from Ofgem (the Office of Gas and Electricity Markets).
electricity prices such as Finland, France or Luxemburg (and far away Both in UK and worldwide, traditional carbon fuel generators have
from the counties with the highest prices such as Denmark, Belgium to set up their prices depending on time and location of generation and
and Germany). According to DECC (2013) [13], wholesale gas and are being separately paid for capacity, energy, and ancillary services,-
electricity costs currently make up the largest proportion of an average renewable energy generators are charging FiTs for the energy they
household energy bill and constitute around 47% in 2013. produce regardless of the system condition or the network constraints
Transmission, distribution and metering costs accounted for 20%, [2].
other supplier costs and margins accounted for 19% and VAT 5%. Feed-in tariff (FIT) programs usually mean long-term contract
In 2013, the average household electricity bill in the UK was £576 under which the utility agrees to purchase the excess generation from
(in real 2012 prices and before rebates). Wholesale energy costs were a distributed generation (DG). Following these arrangements, the
estimated to make up around 37% of an average household electricity utility companies usually come up with a per-kW h purchase price
bill. According to the Customer-Led Network Revolution (CLNR) with the rates varying from utility to utility thus resulting in a lot of
project [9], in 2011 suppliers made a margin of around 4% of the contention. In the long run, the utility company pays the DG in a
total electricity cost and the distribution charges represented 16% of similar manner as they would pay a non-utility wholesale power
the cost of the electricity bill. producer. Under a FIT program, the DG is compensated at the
In the UK, the load profile (the time of the day and year that predetermined rate for their surplus power.
electricity is used) has a strong influence on the price paid per unit of In the UK, FiTs were first introduced in April 2010 to provide a
electricity by the consumers. Those customers who do not use half- fixed payment for generation from RES-E plant under 5 MW. The
hourly metered data, the exact daily consumption is not known and the tariffs can be credited with driving the rapid deployment of PV in the
periodic meter readings (typically a few times a year) is recorded and UK, pushing up installed capacity from almost zero to 2.4 GW by June
converted for billing purposes into half-hourly profiles based on 2013 (DECC, 2013 [13]).
standardised load profiles, or profile classes (see Table 1). The majority of UK solar PV installations are concentrated in the
residential and commercial sectors, while small-scale PV systems

Table 1
Electricity meters, billing type and consumption by profile classes in the UK.
Source: Adapted from [16]

Group Description General billing type Average annual consumption

Profile Class 1 Domestic Unrestricted Customers Estimated/Prepayment 2000 kW h (low)


3100 kW h (medium)
4600 kW h (high)

Profile Class 2 Domestic Economy 7 Customers Estimated 2500 kW h (low)


4300 kW h (medium)
7200 kW h (high)
Profile Class 3 Non-Domestic Unrestricted Customers Estimated 15,000 kW h
Profile Class 4 Non-Domestic Economy 7 Customers Estimated 25,000 kW h
Profile Class 5 Non-Domestic Maximum Demand (MD) Customers with a Peak Load Factor (LF) of less than 20% Estimated 82,000 kW h
Profile Class 6 Non-Domestic Maximum Demand Customers with a Peak Load Factor between 20% and 30% Estimated 110,000 kW h
Profile Class 7 Non-Domestic Maximum Demand Customers with a Peak Load Factor between 30% and 40% Estimated 130,000 kW h
Profile Class 8 Non-Domestic Maximum Demand Customers with a Peak Load Factor over 40% Estimated 150,000 kW h

462
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 2
Comparison of distribution charges and average customer bills in the UK (2013).
Source: [22].

Variable rate Fixed charge Annual averages

(p/kW h) (p/customer/ Consumption (kW h) Variable costs Fixed costs Total costs % Variable % Fixed
day) (£) (£) (£) costs costs

Electricity North West


Electricity North West 3.038 1.940 3.200 97.22 7.08 104.30 93.2% 6.8%

Northern Powergrid
Northern Powergrid 2.792 4.830 3.200 89.34 17.63 106.97 83.5% 16.5%
(Northeast)
Northern Powergrid 2.263 4.710 3.200 72.42 17.19 89.61 80.8% 19.2%
(Yorkshire)

Scottish Power
Distribution
SP Distribution 2.283 5.040 3.200 73.06 18.40 91.45 79.9% 20.1%
SP Manweb 4.114 3.730 3.200 131.65 13.61 145.26 90.6% 9.4%

SSE Power Distribution


Hydro Electric Power 3.710 6.810 3.200 118.72 24.86 143.58 82.7% 17.3%
Distribution
Electric Power Distribution 2.397 2.950 3.200 76.70 10.77 87.47 87.7% 12.3%

UK Power networks
Eastern Power Networks 2.053 4.310 3.200 65.70 15.73 81.43 80.7% 19.3%
London Power Networks 2.117 3.990 3.200 67.74 14.56 82.31 82.3% 17.7%
South Eastern Power 2.617 3.990 3.200 83.74 14.56 98.31 85.2% 14.8%

Western Power
Distribution
East Midlands 2.266 1.470 3.200 72.51 5.37 77.88 93.1% 6.9%
West Midlands 2.356 2.270 3.200 75.39 8.29 83.68 90.1% 9.9%
South Wales 3.470 2.720 3.200 111.04 9.93 120.97 91.8% 8.2%
South West 3.456 2.950 3.200 110.59 10.77 121.36 91.1% 8.9%

benefit from non-burdening administrative procedures and quick Table 3


installation [14]. The PV market in the UK is governed by two Differences in bill savings and payments from the Feed-in Tariff (FITs) scheme.
mechanisms: Source: Own calculations based on [15].


Sunderland Durham York
a generation tariff, or feed-in tariff (FiT) coupled with a feed-in
premium EPC band D or higher E or lower D or higher

• a quota system with tradable certificates (ROCs—Renewable Roof slope


Shading
30°
20% (very little)
70°
60%
50°
> 80%
Obligation Certificates). (significant) (heavy)
Roof direction South North South
The UK solar PV owners can select from the two options - Installation size small medium small
generation tariff and the quota system depending on their PV power: Peak generation in kW 1.5 kWp 2.0 kWp 1.5 kWp
Monthly electricity bill £61 £80 £55


Annual payment from £55 (4.32p/ £3 (0.74p/kW h) £27 (4.32p/
PV systems higher than 50 kW are eligible for FiTs;

generation tariff kW h) kW h)
PV systems between 50 kW and 5 MW are eligible for both; Annual fuel bill savings £44 £16 £22
• PV systems lower than 5 MW are only eligible for the quota system. Annual payment from
export tariff (4.91p/
£31 £11 £16

kWh)
Apart from FiT, UK solar PV owners can consume part of the PV Total payments and £131 £30 £65
energy produced and sell the excess to the grid. In case the PV system savings
rated power is lower than 30 kW, the producer receives a bonus
calculated by the amount of electricity fed into the grid (export tariff,
or a feed-in premium above the generation tariff). In case the rated popularity of the solar PV has been growing so fast that the government
power is higher than 30 kW, the produced can sell the surplus on the is planning major changes to be introduced to the scheme or the
electricity market at wholesale market price. scheme to be suspended altogether in 2016 (Kay, 2015).
Table 3 that follows shows the differences in bill savings and
payments from the Feed-in Tariff (FITs) scheme for selected locations 2. Literature review: solar PV boom and tariffs
in Northern England.
It is estimated that over 1 million UK households currently have Solar PV is gaining more importance and relevance both in the
solar PV panels with about two-thirds of them using the panels for developed Western economies and in the developing countries amongst
generating power [5]. According to the UK Department of Energy & which many enjoy over 300 days of sunshine and are dependent of
Climate Change (DECC, 2015) [12], solar PV deployment in the UK fossil-fuel imports. China and India are becoming big players in the
(measured in megawatt) has grown almost ten times (from 95 MW in solar business. It is estimated that in 2015 China dethroned Germany
2010 when the feed-in tariff was introduced to 8437 MW in 2015). The as the world's biggest producer of solar energy – even though the solar

463
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 4
Literature review of selected solar PV tariffs-related studies.
Source: Own results based on the review of the literature

Study Type of information Overview of main results Comments

Antonelli and A survey of the PV market in Italy Evidence of effects of land availability, The development of the PV market in Italy is led by the following drivers:
Desideri [3] (a 2008–2010 FiT scheme): solar radiation, regional GDP, and land availability; solar radiation; regional GDP; population; the interest in
studying a number of installations population on the PV distribution in the return of the investment (main driver).
of different sizes whose economic the region.
data were known and assessed. Power plants are mainly built in small The FIT schemes applied in Italy in the last five years produced one of the
Direct feedback: statistics and medium sizes in the wealthiest largest stocks of PV plants in the world in the short time. The result is an
analyses. regions, with personal investment almost uncontrolled growth until the end of 2012. However, the installation
either by families or by small and of PV plants was more a financial investment than the creation of a
medium enterprises on their rooftops. distributed and widespread consciousness about using renewable energy
Investment in large power plants was sources.
much smaller than in the less wealthy
part. This is explained by the fact that
large power plants were mainly built
by utilities or by national and
international investment funds and
firms. For this kind of investors, the
return of the investment is more
important than the location, and
regions with larger global solar
radiation, availability of land and
lower land costs were privileged.
In the poorest regions, there was a
weaker driving force to personal
investment in small domestic PV
plants on rooftops, and the smaller
number of small and medium
enterprises also affected the
number of medium sized plant.
Balta-Ozkan et al. Using spatial econometric approach The substantive drop in the cost of Demand for electricity, population density, pollution levels, education level
[4] to find the determinants of the solar PV since 2007 coupled with the of households and housing types are among the factors that affect PV uptake
regional distribution of introduction of the Feed-in Tariff in a region. Moreover, the results indicate significant regional spillover
photovoltaic deployment in the UK: (FiT) scheme in 2010 resulted in a effects on the UK solar energy market.
the data on PV deployment and FiT rapid increase in installation of PV
installations as of 30 June 2013. panels in the UK (from 26.5MWp in
The database lists installed and 2009 to over 5 GW by the end of
declared capacities (kW) for 2014).
different technology and
installation types.
Direct feedback: A variety of
installation capacities listed in
the database.
Bawakyillenuo [6] Analysis of the socio-economic and Proposed critical steps which Ghana As the Kenyan and Zimbabwean success stories revealed, with good returns
political measures that informed needs to undertake to enhance the from income generating activities in rural areas, individuals and families
the varied dissemination outcomes replication of the Kenyan and without access to the national grid will adopt PV to enhance lighting,
of the technology in Ghana, Kenya Zimbabwean PV success stories. entertainment, and education of children. The national grid should be de-
and Zimbabwe through the lens of Classification of the drivers politicized while PV is promoted, especially in the remotest parts of the
the Social Construction of underpinning the different rates of country
Technology (SCOT) theory. PV development and dissemination
Direct feedback: describes the in Kenya, Zimbabwe, and Ghana.
dissemination and utilization of
solar PV technology in Ghana,
Kenya and Zimbabwe from the
1960s to 2007.
Bobinaite and Direct feedback: a review an Solar collectors in the country could Demonstrated that seeking to expedite solar sector development in Lithuania
Tarvydas [7] example of renewable technologies compete in the district heating sector would require reviewing a feed-in tariff.
in Lithuania: development of RES even without state support. Solar collectors for heat energy production are valid in small multifamily
consumption; tendencies of new Assessment of impact of financing houses in Lithuania. It is practical to install solar collectors even under
investment into the renewable instruments on the costs of solar market conditions – using hard loans provided by banks. Solar collectors
energy sector; renewable energy energy and discuss done. could compete in the district heating market without any state support.
sector financing channels and Seeking to expedite solar sector
instruments worldwide. development in Lithuania is
essential to review feed-in tariff,
which currently is too low and
impedes implementation of solar
PV technologies.
[17,18] Direct feedback: describing and Understanding the relationships of There was used the panel data approach to investigate the relationship
analyzing the relationships between energy consumption in relation to the between energy consumption and economic growth. Panel unit root tests
energy consumption and economic economy is very important task to were applied to test the degree of integration of economic growth and energy
growth for 12 European countries; ensure a stable economic consumption and panel least squares method was applied to determine the
econometrical model of economic development. Future economic significant relationships between energy consumption and GDP. Moreover
growth with the application of growth presupposes the availability of the individual effects of every country were estimated. The studies conclude
energy consumption/ electricity increasing quantities of useful energy, that there is a strong relationship between energy consumption and
consumption as one of the so energy consumption can be very economic growth and energy consumption can be very helpful by estimating
(continued on next page)

464
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 4 (continued)

Study Type of information Overview of main results Comments

explanatory variables helpful by estimating economic economic growth.


growth.
Conclusions: it was found that An extensive literature review on the development of solar energy in the UAE
energy consumption in the analyzed for investigating: (i) methods for evaluating the solar resource, (ii) the effect
countriesis not neutral to economic of the local environmental operating conditions on the performance of
growth - Energy Consumption is a different technologies, (iii) strategies for financing projects and encouraging
pro-growth variable, Gross Fixed home-owners to install PV, and (iv) benefits of solar energy to the electricity
Capitalis a pro-growth variable as generation, water production and transportation sectors.
well, the GDP equation excludes
Total Employment. The economic
growth of analyzed European
countries is energy-dependent, so
one can state that energy
consumption is a limiting factor to
economic growth.
Mokri et al. [20] Direct feedback: assessment of the Proved the effect of the local
potential of solar energy as an environmentally operating
essential future energy source in the conditions on the performance of
oil-rich United Arab Emirates; the different technologies, strategies for
energy and electricity sectors survey financing projects and encouraging
on the base of data statistics (as home-owners to install PV. Showed
well as monthly GHI maps obtained the benefits of solar energy for the
by processing satellite and ground electricity generation, water
measurement data; the solar production and transportation
installations map for the UAE) sectors in the sun-abundant
country.
Conclusions: it was found that it Comparison between different methods used for estimating global solar
might be more beneficial to irradiation parameters in the United Arab Emirates.
integrate PV in buildings than in
large plants because building
integrated PV installations improve
the thermal performance of
building sand, therefore, reduce
their cooling (i.e. electricity)
demand, and transmission losses.
In addition, it appears that work is
under way by local authorities to
prepare the local electric grid for
integrating distributed generators
at large scale in the future.
Ondraczek et al. Direct feedback: maps of annual A first attempt at quantifying the A global map of LCOE based on population-weighted national average GHI
[23] electricity production (in kWh) of overall importance of global and country-specific WACC (reflects an assumption of countries achieving
solar PV installations, and installed variations in the cost of finance for the 2011 global average installation costs; an assumption of countries achieving
PV capacity per capita over 143 economics of solar PV, and by late-2011 installation costs found in Germany. The rank ordering of
states. The leveled cost of solar PV extension other renewable energy countries remains constant across the two assumed sets of costs.)
electricity in the set of 143 technologies. Global maps of difference between LCOE and retail electricity prices,
countries. assuming global average investment costs and German investment costs. The
authors calculated values reflect local values for GHI, WACC and residential
electricity rates.
The adoption of solar photovoltaic
(PV) technologies in the recent
years might have come at an
unnecessarily high price. The
leveled costs of electricity (LCOE) of
solar PV systems in Northern
countries may in fact be lower than
in equatorial countries, and high
latitude countries may thus not
have been an unwise location to
subsidize the adoption of solar PV
technologies. Evidence for the
efforts to expand PV installation in
equatorial developing countries
benefiting from policies designed to
make low cost finance more widely
available which supports the on-
going efforts to “de-risk” low carbon
investments.
1) Developed a global LCOE model
and populate it with input values for
all parameters that are treated
uniformly across the dataset.
2) Calculated the average electricity
yield from a prototypical solar
energy system in each of these
(continued on next page)

465
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 4 (continued)

Study Type of information Overview of main results Comments

countries (an input to the global


LCOE model).
3) Calculated the weighted average
cost of capital for each country by
relying on various sources of data,
and the cost of capital (the country-
specific discount rate in the global
model).
Verbruggen and Indirect feedback: renewable Support schemes need to capture the Renewable energy policies need a clear point of reference: because the
Lauber [31] electricity support instruments diversity of power supplies, the incumbent power systems are not sustainable they must adapt to the
based on solar PV. The performance variable nature of some renewable requirements of the renewable ones, not the other way round. Incumbent
of feed-in tariffs (FiT) and tradable supplies, and their different attributes systems carry the responsibility of paying the transition, something that
certificates (a thorough literature for the purposes of public policy. corresponds best with the polluter pays principle. Distinguished the main
review) Moreover, these schemes must take types of RE electricity support instruments.
into account the variety of generators
(including DERs) emerging in a
renewable-based system, and the new
relationships between generators and
customers.
Simshauser [29] Direct feedback: reported the The rapid increase in solar PV (from A case of Southeast Queensland in Australia which has one of the highest
results of the trial that included 6 close to zero at the start of 2009) has penetration rates of domestic solar PV in the world.
digital meters installed in 69 resulted in a massive transfer of Detailed review of the literature: electricity tariff design (1892–1976).
broadly representative Queensland wealth and costs between customer
households at the customer groups. Electricity distribution
switchboard circuit level separately network capacity is primarily driven
measuring half-hour load for by periodic demand, and household
“general power” (e.g. fridge, tumble load generally peaks in the early
dryer, washing machine, etc.), air- evening, whereas solar PV production
conditioning, electric hot water peaks during the middle of the day
systems, household lighting, oven and thus a mismatch exists.
and solar PV units were described. Reported general power load
A basic proposition to be tested: a accounted for 52% of household
tariff structure dominated by a final demand, electric hot water
flat-rate variable charge will represented 18%, air-conditioning
result in short-use (solar PV) constituted 17%, lighting consumed
customers paying too little, and additional 10%, and oven use was at
long-use (non-solar customers) 3%.
paying too much. The sole market mechanisms are
Van Els et al. [30] Direct feedback: the experience of not sufficient to guarantee economic The challenge is to make the necessary paradigm change to: (1)treat rural
using renewables (including the sustainability of the PV projects. electrification as local development, (2) institutionalizealready existing mini
solar PV) for rural electrification of That is one of the reasons why grids within the electricity sector, and (3) executethese projects with the
the Brazilian Amazon. traditional electricity distribution support of multidisciplinary teams toempower local management and
companies showed the lack of promote productive electricityuse with clear input and control of local
interest in promoting rural community to promotecommunity ownership.
electrification with other means
than grid extension. The local
development initiatives and
promoting alternative ways for
implementation renewables
through partnership between local
new actors in the electricity sector
and government and implementing
policy on a local municipal level
might bring fruits.
Zhang et al. [34] Achievements and problems in China's policy approach to renewable Progress has been made in solar PV technologies in China.
China's wind and solar PV sector energies prioritized the development A case of China: withregardto the PVsector,itwas
during 2005–2012: a description of of renewable energy manufacturing notuntilJuly2009thatthetworenewableenergypolicies—the
several empirical cases industry and only then renewable solarPVconcessionprogramandthenationwideFITspolicy—were put
energy itself, and it has not effectively inplace,mainlytriggeredbytheneedtorescuethestruggling domestic
met the ideal of appropriate PVmanufacturingindustry.
interactions between renewable
energy policy and renewable energy
industrial policy. There is a need to
foster the interactions between
renewable energy policy and
renewable energy industrial policy.
PV energy sector problems for
China: Industrial overcapacity;
Under-deployment of renewable
energy
Yu et al. [33] Direct feedback: the wild price Proposed the structural Econometric model. Detailed review of solar market policy events
fluctuations of solar PV Si feedstock decomposition of the real price of PV (throughout the world).
in both contract and spot markets Si feedstock such as the exchange rate
during 2004–2009 (a case of shocks, production cost shocks,
China). aggregate demand shocks, and
(continued on next page)

466
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 4 (continued)

Study Type of information Overview of main results Comments

demand shocks specific to feedstock


markets.
The real price of PVSF is Identification of structural shocks to solar PV Si feedstock prices during
determined by structural shocks in 2004–2009.
global markets of foreign exchange,
energy substitutes, aggregate
economic activities and PVSF, but
they are not linked to the degree
that structural shocks in each
market have the same effects on the
determination of real price
fluctuations of PVSF. Energy
markets and real economic activity
have exhibited a long-lasting
contribution to real price
fluctuations of PVSF, and demand
shocks specific to PVSF markets,
which are focused on the shocks of
unexpected demand and demand
uncertainty, and shocks of exchange
rate have been responsible for
sharper price fluctuations in the
relatively short run.
Alnaser and Direct feedback: monitoring (maps; Estimation of the cost of kWh from Listing the major renewable energy projects (mainly solar and wind) in each
Alnaser [1] statistics; photos) and describing PV: the cost of kWh from large grid of the six GCC countries. The projects made in the GCC countries allow
the status of renewable energy in connected solar thermal plant researchers and investors to size the cost of kWh from thermal, PV and wind
the Gulf countries. Description of (20 MW) – with cost of USD 72.5 energy more precisely.
the two actually installed project PV million and energy – is US ¢ 12/kWh
in United Arab Emirates. (assuming a life time of 40 years and a
discount rate of 4%) while, the cost
issue of kWh from PV electricity (in
the GCC countries) is ranging from US
¢ 27 (for ground mount) to US ¢ 35
(for roof mount).
Reiche [25] Direct feedback: the process of The key characteristics of Masdar The project is still on-going (due to the financial crisis in 2008) but it raises
transforming oil wealth into City, analysed as well as the drivers many important concerns and sets up a good example.
renewable energy leadership and a behind the project, identifies the main
transition from a 20th century, actors for its implementation, and
carbon-based economy into a 21st identifies the main obstacles to
century sustainable economy on the creation and development as well as
example (a case study of “Masdar the policy behind Masdar City.
City,” a planned carbon-neutral
town in Abu Dhabi based on solar
PV energy).

power represents just 3% of China's electricity mix, it is expanding its instruments based on solar PV and come to a conclusion that support
facilities, such as the world's biggest solar plant in the Gobi desert. schemes need to capture the diversity of power supplies, the variable
India is planning to increase its solar capacity to 100 GW (about 20 nature of some renewable supplies, and their different attributes for the
times increase) by 2020 and it is expected that the solar power would purposes of public policy. Moreover, these schemes must take into
account for 12–13% of the country's energy mix by that time. account the variety of generators (including DERs) emerging in a
There is a plethora of research literature on the deployment of solar renewable-based system, and the new relationships between generators
PV, including domestic solar PV. Table 4 that follows provides a and customers.
literature review that includes some relevant solar PV tariff-themed Moreover, Cludius et al. (2014) demonstrate that the Australian
studies from all over the world. Renewable Energy Target (RET) which spurred significant investment
Overall, it seems that PV boom might have adverse economic in renewable electricity generation also caused significant redistribu-
effects. For instance, Antonelli and Desideri [3] describe a boom in the tive transfers between different energy user classes. RET costs are
PV Italian market after the introduction of feed-in tariffs in 2005 and passed on to Australian power consumers in the form of retail
argue that the Italian PV industry was not stimulated by the incentives electricity price premiums. It appears that some energy-intensive
and the policy led to the massive creation of companies involved in PV industries are benefiting from lower wholesale electricity prices while
installation and maintenance, while the cost of the PV plants compo- being largely exempted from contributing to the costs of the scheme.
nents, design and commissioning have followed quite a particular On the other hand, many households are paying significant RET pass
trend, which is more determined by the tariffs than by the market through costs while not necessarily benefiting from lower wholesale
development and structure. They conclude by stating that it is crucial to prices.
devise the right tariff mechanisms and benefits for minimizing financial Furthermore, Ondraczek et al. [23] argue that the adoption of solar
disturbances on the market and for promote real competition instead of photovoltaic (PV) technologies in the recent years might have come at
a simple financial operation under a veil of “green economy”. an unnecessarily high price. Their results suggest that the levelled the
When it comes to PV support schemes, it appears that they need to costs of electricity (LCOE) of solar PV systems in Northern countries
be adaptive and diverse in order to provide sustainable deployment. may in fact be lower than in equatorial countries, and high latitude
Verbruggen and Lauber [31] analyse renewable electricity support countries may thus not have been an unwise location to subsidize the

467
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

adoption of solar PV technologies. They find evidence for the efforts to 3. The data: overview and analysis
expand PV installation in equatorial developing countries benefiting
from policies designed to make low cost finance more widely available The data used in this paper come from the smart meters’ readings
which supports the on-going efforts to “de-risk” low carbon invest- provided by the Customer-Led Network Revolution (CLNR) monitor-
ments. ing customer trial conducted with the 199 households in the Northern
Yu et al. [33] study the wild price fluctuations of solar PV Si England (hereinafter referred to as the CLNR project) that provides the
feedstock in both contract and spot markets during 2004–2009 and data from the study of household electricity use and tariff behaviour
propose the structural decomposition of the real price of PV Si between October 2012 and July 2014.
feedstock such as the exchange rate shocks, production cost shocks, The data included the smart meter readings from household
aggregate demand shocks, and demand shocks specific to feedstock electricity use and tariff behaviour between October 2012 and July
markets. 2014 (17/10/2012–31/07/2014). The information about each house-
Sharaf and Orhan (2015) assess the potential of concentrated hold was very detailed and included the metering from the following 36
photovoltaic thermal (CPVT) solar collectors that promises to ensure channels: air conditioner 1 power, appliance 1 power consumption,
the penetration of solar energy into modern day power generation appliance 2 power consumption, av equipment 1 power, av equipment
technologies. CPVTs‫ ׳‬flexibility, manufacturability, high efficiency, and 2 power, computer 1 power, dishwasher only power, downstairs light 1
multi-output nature inspired many innovative designs and design power, electric heater 1 power, electric heater 2 power, electric heater 3
improvements. power, fridge/freezer power, heat pump power consumption, hob
Sooriyaarachchi et al. (2015) focus on the job creation as an power, kettle power, main cooker/oven power, main freezer power,
important component of the socio-economic effects associated with main refrigerator power, main tv power, microwave power, secondary
the development and deployment of renewable energy (RE) and energy cooker power, secondary freezer power, secondary refrigerator power,
efficiency (EE) technologies including the solar PV. They show that the set top box 1 power, small appliances 1 power, small appliances 2
potential contribution of the RE and EE sectors in creating new jobs power, solar power, tumble dryer power, tv 2 power, washer dryer
might affect the public policy as well as the allocation of public power, washing machine power, water heater power, whitegoods 1
resources to promote related activities. Bawakyillenuo [6] describes power, whitegoods 4 power, whole home power import, and wine
the dissemination and utilization of solar PV technology in Ghana, cooler power.
Kenya and Zimbabwe from the 1960s to 2007. He analyses the socio- For the sake of comparison, we also used the data from the trial of
economic and political measures that informed the varied dissemina- 155 households with solar PV collected by the Customer-Led Network
tion outcomes of the technology in these countries. Furthermore, he Revolution project between June 2012 and March 2014. The data from
recommends critical steps which Ghana needs to undertake to enhance the second trial were not so detailed (there were no channels recorded
the replication of the Kenyan and Zimbabwean PV success stories. In as in the first case) and provided observations on solar power total and
addition to that, Brown et al. (2014) analyse solar home system use in the whole home power import (both measured in kW). The data needed
Lundazi, Zambia. They state that the solar technology has enabled to be adjusted to represent the 30-min data for an average day for an
clients to improve light quality in their houses or shops and in generally average household with and without solar PV which represents full
resulted in an improvement of their living standards. They demonstrate 17,520 data points for each year (48 half-hour intervals multiplied by
that increased panel effect, change of the cutting points of the regulator the 365 days). Fig. 1 depicts the generation across all customers with
and improve the users’ knowledge on proper operation of the system solar PV across weekdays and weekends in each season for 2013
are options to tackle the situation of increased loads put on the system. (kW h).
Mokri et al. [20] describe the solar energy as an essential future The two datasets in question were used for this study for a specific
energy source in the oil-rich United Arab Emirates. They show the reason: CLNR project data [9–11] were obtained from the customer
effect of the local environmental operating conditions on the perfor- trials with the UK electricity customers and yielded the most detailed
mance of different technologies, strategies for financing projects and and accurate datasets showing the consumption of electric energy and
encouraging home-owners to install PV, and benefits of solar energy to tariff behaviour in British households broken by the individual
the electricity generation, water production and transportation sectors appliances up to date. Alongside with the Low Carbon London
in the sun-abundant country. Project conducted by the UK Power Networks [32] that also aimed at
Karakaya et al. (2016) explore the business model of a local solar estimating the impact of low carbon (renewable energy sources)
company in a town of 43,000 habitants in Germany,the country with technologies on London's electricity distribution network but focused
the highest installed capacity of photovoltaic systems, to explain why more on the use of electric vehicles (EV) and reported the bulk
the diffusion rate of photovoltaic systems is decreasing and whether electricity consumption for the households as a whole, the CLNR trials
this development might be attributed to the local solar companies offered the best sets of data comparable with those from the solar PV
having a vital driving role in diffusion, or the business models and
challenges such local companies may have. They come to a conclusion
that business models and challenges such local companies have a
crucial role in this process and may not only let the company survive
but also drive the diffusion of solar photovoltaic systems in the region.
Balta-Ozkan et al. [4] use spatial econometric approach to find the
determinants of the regional distribution of photovoltaic deployment in
the UK. They show that the substantive drop in the cost of panels since
2007, coupled with the introduction of the Feed-in Tariff (FiT) Scheme
in 2010, has resulted in a rapid increase in installation of PV panels in
the UK, from 26.5MWp in 2009 to over 5 GW by the end of 2014 [4].
Their results indicate that demand for electricity, population density,
pollution levels, education level of households and housing types are
among the factors that affect PV uptake in a region. Moreover,their
results indicate significant regional spillover effects on the UK solar
energy market. Fig. 1. Generation across all solar PV households in each season for 2013 (kW h).
Source: CLNR (2014) [11]

468
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

consumer study in Southeast Queensland conducted by Simshauser Table 6


[29] and therefore applicable for computing our empirical model Household electric power by the type of equipment/household appliances (a sample of
mixed 199 households), average day values in kW.
presented in the next section.
Source: Own results
The statistical analysis of the data was performed in order to
investigate the rated peaks and the measured peaks, thus plotting the Households with solar PV Households without solar PV
entire data set was required. The validity of the classification of
measured peak is questionable for several observations, especially with Average value kW Average value kW

regard to the minimum and maximum observed extreme values. The Heat pump power consumption 1.012 Electric heater 1 0.169
statistical data analysis enabled us to provide an appropriate overview Fridge/freezer 0.137 Main freezer 0.112
of the analyzed data. Tumble dryer 0.072 Washer dryer 0.111
Looking at the data, one could establish the annual peak kWh Kettle 0.040 Main TV 0.095
Washing machine 0.032 Tumble dryer 0.095
export and import charges were the highest day for Tuesday, 11th of
Main TV 0.014 Fridge/freezer 0.095
June 2013 and lowest for Saturday, 4th of January 2014. For the sake Microwave 0.010 Secondary freezer 0.088
of comparison, we calculated the annual peak kWh export and import Whole home power import 1.562 Computer 1 0.071
charges for Low Carbon London project (UK Power Networks Smart
Solar power 0.642 AV equipment 1 0.064
Meter Energy Consumption Data in London Household) data: the
Dishwasher only 0.062
typical day was 10th of October 2013 (1.4 kWh), the highest day was AV equipment 2 0.048
16th of June 2013 (3.1 kWh), and the lowest day was 30th of December Main refrigerator 0.045
2012 (0.09 kWh). Washing machine 0.041
The households in our samples are located in the Northeast and are TV 2 0.041
Secondary cooker 0.038
served by the Npower. The company applies 4 basic methods of
Kettle 0.034
electricity payment type: monthly direct debit, prepayment, quarterly Main cooker/oven 0.029
variable direct bill, and receipt of bill. Moreover, the electricity tariff Wine cooler 0.028
can vary depending on the fix and other arrangements and it can secondary refrigerator 0.027
Set top box 1 0.026
assume over 20 different values. Table 5 that follows shows the
Small appliances 1 0.015
example of Npower residential contract prices in 2013. Small appliances 2 0.013
The data analysis and the data basic averaging and clustering (from Microwave 0.012
the largest to the smallest) revealed the following division of equipment Downstairs light 1 0.008
(appliances) for the 20 households with solar PV and 179 households
Note: Full list of appliances includes the following items: air conditioner 1 power,
without solar PV from the total sample of the 199 households of CLNR
appliance 1 power consumption, appliance 2 power consumption, av equipment 1 power,
project data (Table 6). CLNR had smart meters installed on every av equipment 2 power, computer 1 power, dishwasher only power, downstairs light 1
household appliance (e.g. TV, fridge, computer, etc.) and recorded the power, electric heater 1 power, electric heater 2 power, electric heater 3 power, fridge/
data both for the whole household and for each appliance separately. freezer power, heat pump power consumption, hob power, kettle power, main cooker/
It becomes apparent that the freezer and washer, tumble dryer oven power, main freezer power, main refrigerator power, main tv power, microwave
consume most power in both types of households. However, the heat power, secondary cooker power, secondary freezer power, secondary refrigerator power,
set top box 1 power, small appliances 1 power, small appliances 2 power, solar power,
pump and water heater also occupy the top positions in the list of
tumble dryer power, tv 2 power, washer dryer power, washing machine power, water
appliances in the case of the households with solar PV which is the heater power, whitegoods 1 power, whitegoods 4 power, whole home power import, wine
main noticeable difference. This suggests that the British households cooler power.
with solar PV might use their solar power mainly on heating their
households (which is the case of Scotland as suggested by the earlier
CLNR findings and reports on the general unified electricity tariff and

Table 5
Npower retailer contracts for 2013.
Source: Npower (2016).

Electricity

Domestic Electricity Standard Tariff Domestic Economy 7 Tariff

AREA Area MPAN Non-DD Daily DD Daily Non DD DD Unit Non-DD Daily DD Daily Non-DD Non-DD DD Unit DD Unit
Code REC ID Standing Standing Unit Rate (£) Standing Standing Unit Rate Unit Rate Rate (£) - Rate (£) -
Charge (£) Charge (£) Rate (£) Charge (£) Charge (£) (£) - Day (£) - Day Night
Night
Eastern EA 10 n/a 0.4250 n/a 0.1281 n/a 0.4340 n/a n/a 0.1476 0.0858
EMEB EM 11 n/a 0.4290 n/a 0.1318 n/a 0.4390 n/a n/a 0.1514 0.0846
London LO 12 n/a 0.4190 n/a 0.1307 n/a 0.4320 n/a n/a 0.1522 0.0862
Manweb MW 13 n/a 0.4090 n/a 0.1449 n/a 0.4310 n/a n/a 0.1721 0.0898
MEB ME 14 n/a 0.4220 n/a 0.1308 n/a 0.4320 n/a n/a 0.1501 0.0838
Northern NO 15 n/a 0.4240 n/a 0.1329 n/a 0.4350 n/a n/a 0.1527 0.0856
Norweb NW 16 n/a 0.4220 n/a 0.1400 n/a 0.4340 n/a n/a 0.1582 0.0878
Scottish- SH 17 n/a 0.4160 n/a 0.1449 n/a 0.4330 n/a n/a 0.1669 0.1050
Hydro
Scottish SP 18 n/a 0.4140 n/a 0.1296 n/a 0.4310 n/a n/a 0.1531 0.0870
Power
Seeboard SE 19 n/a 0.4270 n/a 0.1326 n/a 0.4390 n/a n/a 0.1525 0.0849
Southern SO 20 n/a 0.4170 n/a 0.1355 n/a 0.4300 n/a n/a 0.1516 0.0849
SWALEC SC 21 n/a 0.4170 n/a 0.1416 n/a 0.4300 n/a n/a 0.1602 0.0864
SWEB SW 22 n/a 0.4120 n/a 0.1405 n/a 0.4330 n/a n/a 0.1662 0.0866
Yorkshire YK 23 n/a 0.4210 n/a 0.1292 n/a 0.4310 n/a n/a 0.1492 0.0845

469
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 7
Differences in Network Charges for Residential Consumers in South Queensland.
Source: [28].

Household A Household B Household C Household D


No air-con Air con No air-con Air-con

No Solar PV No Solar PV Solar PV Solar PV

Maximum Demand 1.41 2.14 1.50 2.09


(kW)
Metered import 6253.4 7560.6 3820.1 4707.1
(kWh)
Solar Export (kWh) 0 0 2259.1 1838.8
Gross Demand 6253.4 7560.6 6253.4 7560.6
(kWh)
Number of 283,849 694,643 26,151 235,357 Fig. 3. Averaged electricity generation for solar PV households (2013).
customers Source: CLNR [11].
% of customers 23% 56% 2% 19%

consumption due to the household own production. This significantly


Base Network $1006.14 $1171.37 $698.57 $810.69 reduces their share of the per kWh costs of the distribution system.
Tariff However, the existing revenue cap regulation of the distribution
Differences A-C B-D charges means that the same revenue has been made as the number
$307.57 $360.68
of units has fallen, which means that per unit charges have risen and
the distribution of their payment between different types of households
its benefits and outcomes for the United Kingdom). has dramatically changed.
Amongst the other top appliances are the fridge, TV, computer and In order to shed some light on the new arrangements, Simshauser
the tumble dryer (its average power consumption is close or approach- [28,29] analyses four types of household: households with no PV and
ing to that of the main TV in the case of household without solar PV). no air-conditioning (the poorest group); households with air-condi-
The other appliances follow – the list is depicted in the Table 7. tioning and no PV; households with PV and no air-conditioning; and
Fig. 2 that follows shows the average day values for the “main” households with PV and air-conditioning. He looks at how the charging
(most heavily used electric appliances) in the 20 households from the mechanism has shifted the payments and considers a more cost
198 mixed households sample as well as their solar power average. reflective charging regime where each household pays a fixed charge,
Fig. 3 reports the averaged electricity generation by months. a per kW peak charge and a variable per kWh charge which better
The key findings from the CLNR study for the smart meter reflects underlying costs. Simshauser [29] suggests that households
households can be summarized as the following: with PV and air-conditioning have only a fractionally lower peak per
kW usage compared to those with no PV but air-conditioning.

• The results demonstrated that on the four days of greatest network Moreover, households with air-conditioning and no PV pay less than
they should towards distribution charges. This creates a disadvantage
stress, the peak demand average was 0.9 kW between 17:00 and
18:00. for the poorest group of households (households without PV and air-

• Electricity demand remained broadly the same at peak hours conditioning) which currently pays 307 Australian dollars p.a. more (or
about £112 (1 AUD=0.53 GBP as of 16 March 2016), i.e. around 40%
whether it is on a weekday or at the weekend.
• Households identified as ‘rural off-gas’ and ‘high income’ customer more) than those with PV and no air-conditioning (see Table 8).
These findings reveal that the starting point of charging is already
sub-groups’ had the demand that could exceed 1 kW at network
peak in winter. unfairly subsidising peaky users with air-conditioning and that the
system has rapidly become much more unfair with the high take-up of
PV. A more cost reflective three-part tariff schemes sees those with PV
4. Empirical model: results and implications and air-conditioning paying 28% more than they are paying now and
those without both paying 15% less (with the result that the poorer
Our empirical model is largely based on the model specified in households pay around 180 AUD (about £95) less). In mathematical
Simshauser [29], albeit with some extensions and modifications. terms: the relationship between kWh and kW peak observed prior to
Solar PV consumers in Southeast Queensland have lower metered the arrival of PV has fundamentally changed, such that kWh are a poor
proxy for kW peak demand.
The main computational problem one can derive from Simshauser
[29], is the interpretation of data. It is quite unclear which type of data
to use in order to run the model in a similar fashion: a) the data for the
period 1 or b) the data for the period that includes prior periods
(cumulative), or c) the data for some isolated periods of time. In
general, it is not clear whether it is possible to sum up the average
power consumption and obtain the data for the day or not. Hence, the
average power, or the standard deviation, that Simshauser [29] uses
and that most likely cannot be summed up.
Simshauser [29] uses a two-part scheme for calculating the tariff. It
includes capacity payments and pay for the consumed energy.
Simshauser [29] divides it by a fixed fee per day and a variable
payment for the consumed energy from the network, depending on the
time of day in which the cost of electricity is different. The algorithm for
Fig. 2. Average power (average day) for the “main” appliances and solar power. calculating the total revenue can be summarized as follows:
Source: Own results.

470
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

Table 8
Differences for Residential solar PV,non-PV, EV and non-EV households in Northern England.
Source: Own results.

Household A Household B Household C Household D

No Solar PV Solar PV No Solar PV + EV Solar PV + EV

Maximum Demand (kW) 1.69 1.69 1.69 1.69


Metered import (kWh) 2540.08 1800 5540.08 4800
Solar Export (kWh) 0 740.08 0 740.08
Gross Demand (kWh) 2540.08 2540.08 5540.08 5540.08
Number of customers 3,040,000 59,751 3,040,000 59,751
% of customers (referred to the main group) 98.1% 1.9% 98.1% 1.9%
Base network tariff £88.53 £67.87 £172.29 £151.63
Two-part tariff £252.83 £16.99
Demand tariff £69.99 £2.49
Differences B-A D-C
Base network tariff £20.66 £20.66
Two-part tariff £235.84
Demand tariff £67.5

Note: Two-part tariff and demand tariff are expressed in annual charges per household (£).

• The day is divided into four periods of time. Each of these periods (shoulder), 4–8 p.m. (critical-peak), 8–10 p.m.(shoulder), 10 p.m.-
has its own variable tariff rate. midnight(off-peak).
• We calculate the amount of energy consumption of the network for
the households in each of the periods in question. In order to do this, Standard-peak periods are defined as union of peak and critical-
we find the total energy consumption of household appliances for peak periods. The critical workdays are list defined, 12 'critical' days in
the period and subtract from it the amount of energy generated by summer and winter. We have a net demand for each billing day and for
PV (solar panels). If the solar PV generated more than was the total each period defined as:max (quantity consumed - quantity produced,
load of the household at a given hour of the day (half-hour 0). According to Simshauser [29], the quantity consumed/produced,
intervals), one can say that the household do not consume the i.e. net demand values should be metered in kWh. In another words,
power from the grid. net demand is kWh that the consumer (a residential household)
• Then, we calculate the total cost of electricity per day, taking into received from the supplier of electricity:
account savings from solar panels: a constant rate per day rate + qij = max[(φij −pvij ),0] (1)
sum of the products of the variable rate on the amount of energy
consumed from the network for the selected period. where:
• The procedures described in 2 and 3 are repeated for each house- φij – a total household quantity consumed by household hi in each
hold and then all the resulting values are summed up. This gives us period pj ,
the total cost of households, or the revenue for the network company pvij – a total solar PV quantity produced by the household hi in each
to which household is connected. period pj ,
qij – a Net Demand (metered quantity supplied by the grid).
Based on the tariff model presented in Simshauser [29], we We have two tariff models defined as follows:
construct an updated and optimized model with a maximum demand
of 1.05 kW for the non-solar household and 1.69 kW for a solar (PV) a) Two-part tariff model
household (the maximum demand values are approximations based on One daily charge consist of fixed charge applied to each billing
the CLNR project data). Moreover, in our simulation we use the day and flat rate variable charge multiplied by net demand(one
approximation of metered import of 1589.184 kWh for non-solar and daily charge, £) =(fixed day charge, £) +(total net demand for a
1799.939 kWh for a solar household (the approximations based on the given day,kWh) *(flat rate variable charge, £/kWh). Since we have
averaged metered import derived from the CLNR data). The gross fixed day charge in tariff, it makes sense to calculate data none less
demand in our simulation is set at 1589.184 kWh and 2540.088 kWh than on the basis of the daily data. As expressed in mathematical
respectively and the number of customers is based on the number of terms:
solar and non-solar households in Northern Powergrid (Northeast y∈{1…z} ∧ tys∈Tys (2)
England) at the time of the data collection (2013). The values of the
approximation are depicted in Table 8 that follows.Our model can be and
presented in the following manner:
Tys ( j ) = tks, pj ∈Ik (3)
Let us have a aset of households H, a aset of billing days D, a set of
half-hour (HH) periods P. Any billing day consist of 48 HH disjoint where:
intervals P. Let Z be a number of 4 period types – non-overlapping time tys - a digital meter variable tariff for period y ,
intervals that consist of HHintervals. Billing days (D) can be divided Tys - the ordered set of time-of-use tariffs.
into three types of days: Ik – a set of peak and off-peak periods
b) Demand tariff mode
• Workdays (except critical): midnight-7 a.m. (off-peak), 7 a.m.-
4 pm(shoulder), 4–8 p.m.(peak), 8–10 p.m.(shoulder), 10 p.m.- In order to calculate the Demand Tariff (δ), we need to define the
midnight(off-peak) maximum demand. It can be expressed as(maximum demand) =
• Holidays: midnight-7 a.m.(off-peak), 7 a.m.-4 p.m.(shoulder), 4– max(net demand,kW), with the maximum demand value being calcu-
8 p.m.(shoulder), 8–10 p.m.(shoulder), 10 p.m.-midnight(off-peak) lated for critical workdays only.
• Critical workdays: midnight-7 a.m.(off-peak), 7 a.m.-4 p.m. Therefore, one daily charge consist of fixed charge applied to each
billing day, a sum of variable charges applied to each of HH periods

471
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

within that day, a variable charge depending on daily period type (peak, tion behaviour [8,19].
off-peak, shoulder, etc.), and the maximum demand charge can be Moreover, one can notice the differences in between households
expressed as (daily charge, £) =(fixed day charge, £) + sum((net with and without solar PV being £235.84 in the case of two-part tariff
demand for a given period of a day, kWh) *(variable charge for period and £67.5 in the case of demand tariff. These are the amounts that the
type - peak, off-peak …, £/kWh)) +(mean (maximum demand, kW) poorest British households pay in excess per annum compared to the
+1*stdev (maximum demand, kW)) *(demand tariff, £/kW). Charges households with solar PV (similar to the case of South Queensland).
should be calculated on a daily basis for the same reason as for two- The differences in the base network tariff is £20.66 for solar and non-
part tariff model. Expressed in mathematical terms: solar (as well as EV and non-EV) households.
∀ b , i ∣ db ∩ I4 ≠ { }∶wib = max[qij ∣ pj ∊ {db ∩ I4}] Comparing the results of both models (a Simshauser [29] model
(4)
and a modified model), one can clearly see that even though the
and magnitude of the results in the UK model is several times less than in
the case of Australian model (£67.5 ($108) compared to $307.57
∀ b , i ∣ db ∩ I4 ≠ { }∶zi = 1*Stdev [wib] + Mean[wib] (5)
($360.68 respectively) in the case of Australia), the main issue remains
where: the same – namely the UK solar PV households (similar to their
wib – a calculated Maximum Demand (measured in kW), Australian counterparts) seem to besubsidized by the non-solar PV
zi – a Mean +1StdDev of all wib for each household hi . households due to the current UK tariff charges and the whole situation
The total revenues (Rim) for each of the models can now be appears to be economically ineffective.
calculated as the sum of charges calculated according to the tariff
model, for each day di for each household hi. Expressed in mathema- 5. Conclusions and discussions
tical terms:
H i =1 P j =1 Solar photovoltaics (as well as other renewable energy sources) are
Rim= ∑ (T fm * D + ∑ qij *Tvm ) (6) gradually gaining larger shares on the world's electricity markets. The
and commitments to the low-carbon future and over-enthusiastic approach
for the renewables causes the increase of governmental support and
H i =1 P j =1
RiS = Rim | RiS = ∑ (T fS * D ∑ qij*TvS ( j +zi*δ ) (7) investments into their further development and deployment. However,
as the support for the renewable energy grows, there are several
where: adverse effects, such as market distortions due to the decrease of
T fm - a fixed daily charge, revenues of generating utilities from the traditional wholesale power
Tvm – a variable energy charge. markets, issues with the intermittency of renewable energy sources that
Additionally, let us add an implication of having an electric vehicle work only in certain conditions (e.g. when the sun is shining or when
(EV) in each type of a household. Let us assume that an EV would add the wind is blowing) and thus need to be supported by the traditional
additional 3000 kWh per kW in electricity consumption (an average EV coal and gas power plants, or zero marginal running costs of the
consumption in the United Kingdom (see [21]). We repeat the renewables that reduces the incentives for the traditional energy
calculations for the households with and without solar PV but adding providers. As a result, electric energy prices go down (regardless of
some hypothetical EV consumption of 3000 kWh per kW to show the the generating source) and the revenues decrease both for traditional
implications. energy providers and for the renewable generators. The more renew-
Let us run the basic calculations for the non-solar households: able energy is introduced into the traditional energy market system, the
365*£0.0483 + 2540*£0.02792 = £17.62 + £70.91 = £88.53 (8) higher is the electricity bill.
There are different electricity tariffs charges and methods, more-
The same calculations can be done for the solar households:
over there is also a plethora of principles how to charge for electricity
365*£0.0483 + 1800*£0.02792 = 17.62 + 50.25 = £67.87 (9) networks. This way or another, any charging methodology for an
The difference is £88.53 − £67.87 = £20.66 . In addition, there is also electricity network has to deal with fixed cost recovery.
solar households’ export: 740.08kWh*£0.1292(FIT in2013) = £95.61 The commitment to the low-carbon future that many world
Let us look at the non-solar households with electric vehicles (EV): governments pledged themselves to brought about higher penetration
of renewable energy sources on the electricity markets. Higher shares
365*£0.0483 + (2540 + 3000) * £0.02792 = £17.62 + £154.67 = £172.29 of RES (such as for example solar PV panels) offers many new
(10) opportunities for amending and improving the existing system of
Solar households with EV: network charges in ways that were not originally considered before
by economists or policy-makers.
365*£0.0483 + (1800 + 3000)*£0.02792 = £17.62 + £134.01 = £151.63
Our results demonstrate that similar to the other studies conducted
(11) in other countries that have the schemes promoting residential solar
There is a difference of £20.66 which is what the solar households save PV panels, the increase in the solar PV panels energy generation lead to
by using what they are generating for charging their electric vehicles. the redistribution of wealth and costs among existing customers.
Table 8 that follows applies the model specified in (1)-(7) for Thanks to their own production of solar energy, UK solar PV house-
sample of households with and without solar PV and EV in Northeast holds bear a lower share of the per kWh costs of the distribution system
England. The last two rows of the table depict the savings that solar PV which in turn leads to the increase of per unit charges as well as to the
households and non-solar PV households (as well as EV and non-EV changes in the distribution of their payment between different types of
households) make by using either two-part tariff scheme of the demand households. The obvious conclusion that from all this is that UK solar
tariff scheme. owners do not contribute to the grid as they should be.
Looking at the results presented in Table 8, one can see that in case One of the possible solutions to bring the justice to the system
of solar PV households and EV households, the annual savings are would be to install the more cost reflective apportionment of charges
larger in case of a two-part tariff: they are 6.8 times in the case of between fixed, per kW peak and per kWh use of system charges.
households with solar PV and only 3.6 times for the households Another option is the introduction of the new type of charge at that
without solar PV. Households with solar PV are benefitting from the voltage level (e.g. kW peak export tariff).
two-part tariff scheme although their solar power generation and Moreover, it appears that the new uses of the electricity network
consumption does not seem to affect their overall electricity consump- create opportunities for reallocating charges to new users and away

472
W. Strielkowski et al. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 77 (2017) 461–473

from disadvantaged users (e.g. poor or elderly residents). New uses of photovoltaics-deployment〉 [Accessed 03 March 2016].
[13] Department of Energy and Climate Change. UK solar PV strategy part 1: roadmap
the traditional electricity market and tariffs create many promising to a brighter future. London, Department of Energy and Climate Change; 2013.
opportunities for reallocating charges from the existing users who may 〈https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/
be poor and vulnerable. file/249277/UK_Solar_PV_Strategy_Part_1_Roadmap_to_a_Brighter_Future_
08.10.pdf〉 [Accessed 20 April 2016].
Overall, the new reality that includes the growing importance of [14] Dusonchet L, Telaretti E. Comparative economic analysis of support policies for
renewables on the electricity markets, dictates the necessity to envisage solar PV in the most representative EU countries. Renew Sustain Energy Rev
and implement the new rules for network charges in order to prevent 2015;42:986–98.
[15] Energy Saving Trust. Solar Energy Calculator; 2016. 〈http://www.pvfitcalculator.
the market distortions and the unwanted consequences on both energysavingtrust.org.uk/〉 [Accessed 15 April 2016].
generating companies and consumers. [16] Haney AB, Jamasb T, Pollitt MG. Smart metering and electricity demand:
Technology, economics and international experience. CWPE 0905 & EPRG 0903
Working Paper (February); 2009.〈http://www.eprg.group.cam.ac.uk/wp-content/
Acknowledgements
uploads/2009/02/binder2.pdf〉 [Accessed 13 April 2016].
[17] Kasperowicz R. Economic growth and energy consumption in 12 European
The authors would like to thank CLNR and Northern Powergrid for countries: a panel data approach. J Int Stud 2014;7(3):112–22. http://dx.doi.org/
the data on Northern England households. They would also like to 10.14254/2071-8330.2014/7-3/10.
[18] Kasperowicz R. Electricity consumption and economic growth: evidence from
thank Ofgem's Low Carbon Network (LCN) Fund which funded the Poland. J Int Stud 2014;7(1):46–57. http://dx.doi.org/10.14254/2071-
CLNR project. 8330.2014/7-1/4.
Moreover, we would like to thank Professor Paul Simshauser for his [19] Marques CP, Almeida D. A path model of attitudinal antecedents of green purchase
behaviour. Econ Sociol 2013;6(2):135–44. http://dx.doi.org/10.14254/2071-
inspiration for this paper and Professor Michael Pollitt from Energy 789X.2013/6-2/12.
Policy Research Group, University of Cambridge for his help, assistance [20] Mokri A, Ali MA, Emziane M. Solar energy in the United Arab Emirates: a review.
and valuable comments that greatly contributed to the completion of Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2013;28:340–75.
[21] Newbery D, Strbac G. What is needed for battery electric vehicles to become socially
our research. cost competitive?. Econ Transp 2016;5:1–11.
[22] Ofgem. Common Distribution Charging Models; 2013. 〈https://www.ofgem.gov.
References uk/gas/retail-market/monitoring-data-and-statistics/〉 [Accessed 25 April 2016].
[23] Ondraczek J, Komendantova N, Patt A. WACC the dog: the effect of financing costs
on the levelized cost of solar PV power. Renew Energy 2015;75:888–98.
[1] Alnaser WE, Alnaser NW. The status of renewable energy in the GCC countries. [24] Anaya K, Pollitt M. Can current electricity markets Cope with high shares of
Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2011;15(6):3074–98. renewables? A comparison of approaches in Germany, the UK and the state of new
[2] Anaya K, Pollitt M. Integrating distributed generation: regulation and trends in York. Energy J 2016;37:71–88.
three leading countries. Energy Policy 2015;85:475–86. [25] Reiche D. Renewable energy policies in the Gulf countries: a case study of the
[3] Antonelli M, Desideri U. Do feed-in tariffs drive PV cost or viceversa?. Appl Energy carbon-neutral “Masdar City” in Abu Dhabi. Energy Policy 2010;38(1):378–82.
2014;135:721–9. [26] Sawin JL, Sverrisson F, Chawla K, Lins C, McCrone A, Musolino E, Riahi L, Sims R,
[4] Balta-Ozkan N, Yildirim J, Connor PM. Regional distribution of photovoltaic Skeen J, Sverrisson F. Renewables 2014 Global Status Report. Technical Report,
deployment in the UK and its determinants: a spatial econometric approach. Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century; 2014.〈http://www.ren21.
Energy Econ 2015;51:417–29. net/Portals/0/documents/Resources/GSR/2014/GSR2014_KeyFindings_low
[5] Barkham P. Solar power in crisis. The Guardian (20.10.2015); 2015. < 〈http:// %20res.pdf〉 [Accessed 5 March 2016].
www.theguardian.com/environment/2015/oct/20/solar-power-in-crisis-panels- [27] Sioshansi R. Retail electricity tariff and mechanism design to Incentivize distrib-
generate-power-government-subsidy〉 > [Accessed 20 March 2016]. uted renewable generation. Energy Policy (corrected proof) 2016, http://dx.doi.
[6] Bawakyillenuo S. Deconstructing the dichotomies of solar photovoltaic (PV) org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.12.041, [Accessed 10 March 2016].
dissemination trajectories in Ghana, Kenya and Zimbabwe from the 1960s to 2007. [28] Simshauser P. Network tariffs: resolving rate instability and hidden subsidies, AGL
Energy Policy 2012;49:410–21. Applied Economic and Policy Research Working Paper No.45 – Demand Tariffs;
[7] Bobinaite V, Tarvydas D. Financing instruments and channels for the increasing 2014. 〈http://aglblog.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/No.45-Demand-
production and consumption of renewable energy: lithuanian case. Renew Sustain Tariffs.pdf〉 [Accessed 25 March 2016].
Energy Rev 2014;38:259–76. [29] Simshauser P. Distribution network prices and solar PV: resolving rate instability
[8] CsigénéNagypál N, Görög G, Harazin P, PéternéBaranyi R. Future generations and and wealth transfers through demand tariffs. Energy Econ 2016;54:108–22.
sustainable consumption. Econ Sociol 2015;8(4):207–24. http://dx.doi.org/ [30] Van Els RH, de Souza Vianna JN, Brasil ACP. The Brazilian experience of rural
10.14254/2071-789X.2015/8-4/15. electrification in the Amazon with decentralized generation–the need to change the
[9] CLNR. Commercial Arrangements Study. Review of existing commercial arrange- paradigm from electrification to development. Renew Sustain Energy Rev
ments and emerging best practice; 2013. 〈http://www.element-energy.co.uk/ 2012;16(3):1450–61.
wordpress/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/CLNR-Commercial-Arrangements- [31] Verbruggen A, Lauber V. Assessing the performance of renewable electricity
Study_2013.pdf〉 [Accessed 18 March 2016]. support instruments. Energy Policy 2012;45:635–44.
[10] CLNR . Insight Report: Domestic Solar PV customers; 2013. 〈http://www. [32] UK Power Networks. Low Carbon London Project; 2014 〈http://innovation.
networkrevolution.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2015/01/CLNR-L090-Insight- ukpowernetworks.co.uk/innovation/en/Projects/tier-2-projects/Low-Carbon-
Report-Domestic-Solar-PV.pdf〉 [Accessed 23 February 2016]. London-(LCL)/〉 [Accessed 1 April 2017].
[11] CLNR. Enhanced Profiling of Domestic Customers with Solar Photovoltaics (PV); [33] Yu Y, Song Y, Bao H. Why did the price of solar PV Si feedstock fluctuate so wildly
2014. 〈http://www.networkrevolution.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/ in 2004–2009?. Energy Policy 2012;49:572–85.
CLNR-L071-Guide-to-load-and-generation-profile-datasets.pdf〉 [Accessed 22 [34] Zhang S, Andrews-Speed P, Zhao X, He Y. Interactions between renewable energy
April 2016]. policy and renewable energy industrial policy: a critical analysis of China's policy
[12] Department of Energy & Climate Change. Statistics – Solar photovoltaics approach to renewable energies. Energy Policy 2013;62:342–53.
deployment; 2015. 〈https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/solar-

473

You might also like