You are on page 1of 19

The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

The Leadership Quarterly


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/leaqua

Full Length Article

The impact of government integrity and culture on corporate leadership T


practices: Evidence from the field and the laboratory☆
Amon Chizemaa, , Ganna Pogrebnab,1

a
Birmingham Business School, University of Birmingham, Edgbaston, Birmingham B15 2TT, United Kingdom
b
Birmingham Business School, Economics Department, University of Birmingham, Edgbaston, Birmingham B15 2TT, United Kingdom

ABSTRACT

To understand what drives corporate leaders to choose certain corporate governance practices there is need to look beyond the individual traits of the leader,
examining the effect of the elements of the institutional environment on managerial decisions. Drawing on the contextual approach to leadership and insights from
institutional theory, this study examines the impact of government integrity on corporate governance practices. From the field study, we find that government
integrity has a positive causal effect on corporate leaders' corporate governance decisions and choices. The positive impact of government integrity on corporate
leaders' actions is also confirmed using a laboratory study, showing that a social norm of promoting leadership integrity, positively impacts on corporate respon-
sibility especially in contexts where the government lacks credibility. Specifically, we find that corruption and bribery by corporate leaders is low in contexts that are
transparent and high in contexts with low government integrity.

Introduction decisions are made within a given context (Johns, 2006; Rousseau &
Fried, 2001). Indeed, studies that examine the effect of leaders' traits
What drives corporate leaders to choose certain corporate decisions and behavioral styles without full consideration of the context are not
or practices? Moreover, what influences the manner in which they ef- necessarily invalid but incomplete.
fectively implement such decisions and practices in organizations? In Separately and, at times, collectively, insights from institutional
an attempt to answer questions of this nature, previous leadership and theory and contextual leadership (Johns, 2006; Oc, 2018) provide the
corporate governance studies, employing a leader-centric approach, basis on which a better understanding of the influence of context on
have focused on examining specific universal traits and behavioral managerial decisions and choices can be drawn. According to the in-
styles that make some leaders more effective than others (Lord, Day, stitutional perspective, human and social behaviors, among other fac-
Zaccaro, Avolio, & Eagly, 2017). For example, upper echelons theory tors, are influenced by country-level institutions, such as norms, rou-
(Hambrick & Mason, 1984) and the literature on executive personality tines and historical patterns, which determine isomorphism among
(e.g., Hiller & Hambrick, 2005; Peterson, Walumbwa, Byron, & individuals and organizations (Chizema, 2008; DiMaggio & Powell,
Myrowitz, 2009) suggest that the leadership behaviors and decisions of 1983; Scott, 2001). This sociological perspective is consistent with re-
senior executives are influenced by both demographic characteristics search in financial economics that has shown that country institutions
such as background, expertise, tenure, and age and by psychological or characteristics explain a large proportion of the variation of corpo-
characteristics such as personality. Consistent with this view, Hogan rate governance indexes across firms (Stulz, 2005). For example, a
and Kaiser (2005) note that “who we are determines how we lead” (p. study on corporate governance by Doidge, Karolyi, and Stulz (2004)
175). As such, upper echelons theory points to the key role of the top demonstrates that country-level factors influence governance practices
management team (TMT) in shaping work processes and influencing much more than do firm-or even industry-level data. Dyck and Zingales
organizational outcomes (Finkelstein & Hambrick, 1996; Hambrick & (2004) show that control premia vary systematically across countries.
Mason, 1984). The strength of these observations is probably behind Davis' (2005)
An omission in studies that have focused exclusively on the effects suggestion that the future of relevant corporate governance research
of individual characteristics of top leadership is the realization that should seek to understand the institutional context in which it occurs,


We are grateful to the action editor as well as to 3 anonymous referees for many insightful comments and suggestions, which helped to significantly improve this
manuscript. We are grateful for financial support awarded by the Research Support Fund from the College of Social Sciences at the University of Birmingham. Ganna
Pogrebna also acknowledges financial support from the UKRI projects EP/P011896/2 and ES/R007926/1.

Corresponding author is also an Extraordinary Professor at The Gordon Institute of Management Science (GIBS), University of Pretoria, South Africa.
E-mail addresses: a.chizema@bham.ac.uk (A. Chizema), gpogrebna@turing.ac.uk (G. Pogrebna).
1
Alan Turing Institute, 96 Euston Rd, Kings Cross, London NW1 2DB, United Kingdom.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.leaqua.2019.07.001
Received 1 February 2018; Received in revised form 1 July 2019; Accepted 5 July 2019
Available online 10 July 2019
1048-9843/ © 2019 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Inc. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/BY-NC-ND/4.0/).
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

in contrast to the more traditional agency or transaction cost perspec- country institutions matter (North, 1990).
tive. As explained above, sociological perspectives provide explanations
In the same vein, Porter and McLaughlin (2006) suggest that lea- of the impact of contextual factors on leadership at the macro level
dership in organizations does not take place in a vacuum (the term where, collectively, typical actions, beliefs, desires and choices among
“leadership vacuum” was first coined by House & Aditya, 1997, p. 445) members of society are constrained by informal rules or social norms
but does so in organizational and country contexts. Following their call (Hedstrom & Ylikoski, 2010). This approach is useful in understanding
for research that should make context, “a primary object of interest, ra- collective action at the national level, prompting Hedstrom and
ther than treating it as almost an afterthought” (p. 571), a stream of re- Swedberg (1998) to suggest that associations of macro factors can be
search has since explored context in attempting to understand the effect better understood by examining the behavior, beliefs and decision-
of corporate leadership on firm decisions and outcomes (Bullough, making of individuals in a given context. They suggest that the first step
Kroeck, Newbury, Kundu, & Lowe, 2012; Chizema, Kamuriwo, & involves identifying the process through which situational or contextual
Shinozawa, 2015). A common assumption in these studies is that the factors constrain individuals' action.
effectiveness of leaders' choices may be facilitated by some contexts and The second step is about identifying the action-formation mechan-
inhibited by others. isms that link individual desires and beliefs to their actions or choices.
Research on the macro context of leadership, discussed above, has The final step involves specifying the transformational approaches by
considered both the effect of formal and informal institutions on lea- which individuals, through their actions and interactions, generate
ders' choice of practices or decisions. Informal institutions are enduring various intended and unintended social outcomes.
systems of shared meanings and collective understandings that, while In this study, we explore the effects of macro factors on leadership
not codified into documented rules and standards, reflect a socially choices through two complimentary methodological approaches. First,
constructed reality that shapes cohesion and coordination among in- we use a field data analysis to show the macro-level association be-
dividuals in a society (Scott, 2001). tween government integrity and collective corporate leadership choices
A central construct from the context defined by informal institutions and outcomes. Second, we complement the first study by using a con-
is national culture that constitutes created and learned standards for trolled laboratory experiment (e.g., Zizzo, 2010) to capture the whole
perception, cognition, judgment or behavior shared by members of a chain of contextual, action-formation and transformation mechanisms
certain group or country (North, 1990). Culture refers to the “complex of corporate leadership. This approach of using field data in conjunc-
of meanings, symbols and assumptions about what is good or bad, le- tion with an experimental study has been previously employed in many
gitimate or illegitimate that underlie the prevailing practices and norms impactful leadership papers (e.g., O'Reilly, Doerr, & Chatman, 2018;
in a society.” (Licht, Goldschmidt, & Schwartz, 2005: 233). Steffens et al., 2018, to name a few).
Several attributes constitute or contribute to the whole construct of This paper makes at least three contributions to existing literature.
national culture. For example, government integrity, the quality of First, we heed the calls to determine how national context and in-
national governance in accordance with relevant moral values and stitutions shape corporate governance and leadership (Aguilera &
norms which include consistency, coherence, and lawfulness and ab- Jackson, 2003), offering insights to comparative institutional analysis
sence of corruption (OECD, 2013), relates closely to national culture. using field data. As such, we join the growing stream of literature that is
We, therefore, propose government integrity as yet another variant of transitioning from a-contextual research (Bamberger, 2008; Minichilli,
informal institutions within the realm of macro context that potentially Zattoni, Nielsen, & Huse, 2012) to the explicit consideration of contexts
bears influence on corporate leadership's decision-making and the within the domain of leadership and corporate governance (Bullough
manner in which decisions are implemented. et al., 2012; Chizema, Liu, Lu, & Gao, 2015). Second, by considering the
From public governance literature, government integrity has been impact of a macro-social context, through government integrity, on
variously defined as being consistent and coherent in principles, values, corporate governance practices, this study offers an alternative ap-
and action (Montefiore, 1999), following regime values and rules proach to the agency paradigm (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) that has
(Rohr, 1989), and acting in accordance with relevant moral values, largely dominated corporate governance studies. Finally, by conducting
norms, and rules (Huberts, Lasthuizen, & Peeters, 2006). Integrity is, a controlled laboratory study, we test how social norm of contextual
therefore, an important factor and has been considered a necessary integrity impacts on leadership choices.
quality for governments to have (OECD, 2013). The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. The following
According to the OECD (2013), government integrity is the align- section provides a review of the contextual leadership literature, fol-
ment of government and public institutions with broader principles and lowed by one that discusses government integrity and theoretical ex-
standards of conduct that contribute to safeguarding the public interest planations of organizational legitimacy. Hypotheses of the field study
while preventing corruption. Thus, government integrity could also be are then developed under the subsections. The next sections present the
observed through the quality of enforcement of a country's laws and laboratory experiment that is used to support the field study, formulates
regulations (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1998; experimental hypotheses and provides the main findings of the ex-
Rothstein & Teorell, 2008), suggesting that it is a public perception perimental study. The remaining part of the paper is devoted to a dis-
derived from the efficiency or non-efficiency levels of formal institu- cussion of the findings, contributions, limitations with the conclusion at
tions. the end.
A commonly used proxy for government integrity, which we also
use in this study, is the extent to which a state is free from corruption A contextual approach to leadership
(Fredriksson, Neumayer, & Ujhelyi, 2007). According to Fijnaut (2002),
corruption is an umbrella concept, covering all or most types of in- In its broad sense, contextual leadership examines whether situa-
tegrity violation or unethical behavior. We argue that government in- tional or contextual factors reduce or improve the impact of leadership
tegrity, the mirror image of corruption, is, therefore, an informal in- practices (Oc, 2018). Moreover, it explores how leadership takes place
stitution and thus part of the context in which corporate leadership in specific contextual settings. As described by Osborn, Hunt, and Jauch
takes place. (2002), a contextual theory of leadership is one that recognizes that
We seek to add to the stream of contextual leadership research by leadership is embedded and “socially constructed in and from a con-
examining the effect of government integrity on corporate governance text” (p. 798), and they put it well as they further claim that, “leader-
practices. We take the view that leadership is embedded in the context ship and its effectiveness, in large part, are dependent upon the context.
(Johns, 2006) and that it is socially constructed in and from a context Change the context and leadership changes” (p. 797) and the outcomes
where patterns over time must be considered and where history and change too.

2
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

In leadership research, several scholars have provided varied fra- suggestion of starting by identifying the process through which con-
meworks to understand context and its effect on leadership. For ex- textual factors determine individuals' action followed by identifying the
ample, Porter and McLaughlin (2006) proposed seven components of action-formation mechanisms that link individuals' beliefs and con-
the organizational context, including culture/climate, goals/purposes, straints to their choices.
structure and time. Ayman and Adams (2012) view leadership context A core insight from institutional theory is that organizations strive
through the lenses of cultural and organizational factors. for external legitimacy by complying with their social institutional
According to Oc (2018), a comprehensive approach to the con- contexts (Scott, 2008). From this effort, organizations expect their ac-
ceptualization of contextual leadership is one done by Johns (2006) tions to be perceived as being “desirable, proper or appropriate within
who conceptualizes context at two different levels: the omnibus and some socially constructed systems of norms, values, beliefs and defi-
discrete contexts. The omnibus context is about the broad environ- nitions” (Suchman, 1995: 574). Without legitimacy, firms may not have
mental influences and provides answers to questions of a macro nature access to resources that are important for their survival (Scott, 2001).
such as the what, why, who, when and where of contextual leadership To determine what constitutes legitimacy, firms rely on cues from
(Johns, 2006; Oc, 2018). For example, under the where of the omnibus the institutional environment. If institutional cues include corrupt or
context, the researcher could consider national culture or institutional unethical practices, such corrupt practices may have an impact on a
forces. In contrast, the discrete context is about specific situational firm's actions in its search of institutional legitimacy (Keig, Brouthers, &
variables that influence behavior directly or that are used to moderate Marshall, 2015).
relationships between variables (Johns, 2006). The discrete context Government integrity, indeed, the central contextual factor under
focuses on aspects such as task, social, physical and temporal (Johns, consideration in this study, belongs to the group of national institutions
2006; Oc, 2018). For example, under the task of the discrete context, that are classified as informal (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) and is a key
the researcher could consider task or job characteristics. institutional cue that potentially guides the behavior of firms in their
From the two levels of Johns' (2006) conceptualization of con- search for legitimacy (Rodriguez et al., 2005). As pointed out earlier, in
textual leadership, it is the omnibus context that relates to the hetero- a national context, government integrity is a behavioral expectation of
geneity of national settings and, indeed, one that is of interest to our public institutions to conduct their business in a socially accepted
study. As Oc (2018: 219) states, “…an omnibus approach to context will manner. The absence of such an expected behavior manifests in cor-
include studies that examine the top-down effects of societal trends, eco- ruption, a socially unacceptable situation, manifest in violation against
nomic conditions, national culture, or other macro level factors.” As pointed the moral norms and values for political and administrative behavior
out above, one of the dimensions of the omnibus context of leadership is (Fijnaut, 2002).
the actual location where leadership takes place. In order to succeed in corrupt environments, corporate leaders may
Drawing on the omnibus context, some studies have considered have to conform to institutional corruption pressures, gaining legiti-
contextual factors as a macro-level system-based constraint or enabler macy in the eyes of corrupt government officials and with corrupt
(e.g. institutional forces) that describes where leadership takes place, business partners (Ufere, Perelli, Boland, & Carlsson, 2012). In such
modelling their direct effect to explain variance in leadership or its environments, leading firms may have achieved their success through
outcomes across different contexts (Currie, Lockett, & Suhomlinova, corrupt practices and through forces of mimetic isomorphism
2009). For example, Bullough et al. (2012), drawing on institutional (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), the rest of the firms in the same institu-
theory, sought to find the effects of six omnibus contextual factors, tional environment may follow suit, suggesting a contagion effect of
including business environment, societal development, economics, bad corporate practices.
technology and physical infrastructure, political freedom and cultural As corruption becomes normalized as a taken-for-granted behavior
variables, on women's participation in political leadership across 181 (Ufere et al., 2012), corporate leaders in low-government-integrity
countries. Chizema, Liu, et al. (2015) draw on social role theory, em- environments may embrace the same behavior in their decision-making
ploying three social institutional forces (women's representation in and choices, manifesting through corporate irresponsibility. Ashforth
politics, economic environment, and religiosity) to explain the presence and Anand (2003) argue that when corruption becomes in-
or absence of female directors on boards across 45 countries. More stitutionalized, it becomes an integral part of day-to-day activities to
recently, Stoker, Garretsen, and Soudis (2019) show that across firms such an extent that individuals may be unable to see the in-
and countries, and controlling for individual managerial variation, the appropriateness of their behaviors. Here, the national environment of
2008 financial crisis led, on average, to an increase in directive lea- low government integrity becomes culturally accepted as normal by the
dership. collective of national actors such that the behavior at government level
Similarly, for a country-level study such as this current one, the may influence and encourage that at the corporate level.
omnibus context characterized by variation among countries' institu- For corporate leaders in environments with low government in-
tional settings provides a perfect theoretical framework to understand tegrity, the logic of corporate governance strays away from notions of
the effect of government integrity on the choices and decisions made by accountability, responsibility and transparency. There is evidence for
corporate leaders. this claim from previous studies. For example, Keig et al. (2015) argue
that firms that establish and maintain operations in portfolios of loca-
Government integrity, institutional legitimacy and corporate tions characterized by higher levels of corruption are more likely to act
leaders' decision-making irresponsibly, as such environments may allow or even encourage
corporate leaders to side-step socially responsible behavior. In an ear-
A suitable lens to explain firms' responses to government actions is lier study, Tan (2009:174) pointed out that in environments where
institutional theory (Chizema & Kim, 2010; Rodriguez, Uhlenbruck, & formal corruption flourishes due to lack of controls, firms “may become
Eden, 2005) and applying this perspective, that emphasizes contextual motivated to lower ethical standards, ranging from environmental
factors influencing corporate decisions, is an appropriate approach for negligence and abusive labor practice to corrupt human resource
our study. The use of institutional theory is also suited to our study management”. In contrast, in a recent study, Ioannou and Serafeim
because government integrity is an element of the norms and rules of (2012) found that firms headquartered in countries characterized by
states. We, therefore, draw on institutional theory to discuss the im- lower public sector corruption had higher levels of social responsibility.
plications of government integrity or its absence for the firm's organi- Moreover, competitive pressures in corrupt environments may push
zational legitimacy, consequently showing how the need for organiza- corporate leaders to make irresponsible decisions. Scholars have ob-
tional legitimacy determines corporate leaders' decisions and choices. served that operating in corrupt environments potentially increases
Our approach, here, is consistent with Hedstrom and Swedberg's (1998) direct and indirect transaction costs for the firm (Rose-Ackerman, 1975;

3
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Uhlenbruck, Rodriguez, Doh, & Eden, 2006). As Nwabuzor (2005:129) Government integrity and auditing and financial reporting
posits “companies that are burdened with under-the-table payments may try
to contain their costs by cutting corners”. Ideally, any threat to a firm's Auditing and financial reporting plays a potentially crucial role in
survival in a corrupt environment may increase the likelihood that it corporate governance. This is because for investors to be more informed
will pursue irresponsible actions to remain viable (Campbell, 2007). about their investments, basic accounting standards are needed to
Consistent with the overarching argument drawn on the contextual render company disclosures interpretable. Auditing and financial re-
leadership and institutional theory, we argue that government integrity porting are, therefore, about the transparency levels of corporations.
potentially impacts on the choice and effectiveness of corporate gov- Differences in the quality of auditing and financial reporting across
ernance practices. For example, cross-country studies have shown cor- countries have caught the attention of academics (e.g., Ball &
ruption (the absence of government integrity) to be associated with Shivakumar, 2005). These differences, that scholars attribute to the
higher corporate borrowing costs, lower stock valuations, and illegiti- national institutional setting for financial reporting (Brown, 2011),
mate and ineffective corporate governance practices (Ng, 2006). have been found even among countries that adopted International Fi-
In the sections below, we provide explanation for the four hy- nancial Reporting Standards (IFRS). Ball and Shivakumar (2005) and
potheses that government integrity impacts on corporate governance Burgstahler, Hail, and Leuz (2006), among others, have argued that
outcomes namely managerial accountability to shareholders and the standards alone will not lead to substantially similar financial reporting
board, auditing and financial reporting, protection of minority interests outcomes and that such standards may be less important than other
and corporate governance, in general. institutional features of the reporting and legal environment. Consistent
with this view, Brown, Preiato, and Tarca (2014), who studied the ef-
fect of enforcement bodies and auditing with regard to financial re-
Government integrity and managerial accountability to shareholders and the porting transparency in Europe, observe that culture and legal setting
board (including government integrity, see La Porta et al., 1998) will affect
the output of financial reporting. Picur (2004) examines a sample of 34
Accountability is said to be necessary when actors' conduct impacts countries and concludes that low quality of accounting is predisposed to
upon the rights or interests of others (Keay & Loughrey, 2015). In the a climate of corruption. In similar vein, Riahi-Belkaoui (2004) uses a
case of firms, executives, who manage companies as agents, should be cross-country longitudinal dataset covering the period 1985–1998 and
accountable to shareholders (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). This is because observes that corruption creates a climate conducive to low quality
executives have considerable power over, and control of, the affairs of accounting. Recently, Lourenço, Rathke, Santana, and Branco (2018)
the company (Fama & Jensen, 1983). For example, they are in charge of employ data from 33 emerging markets, concluding that country per-
the capital provided by shareholders as well as of any profits that firms ceived corruption is related to higher incentives for firms to manipulate
generate. It is, therefore, necessary that executives account for their earnings.
actions given the level of power and control they have over the prin- Moreover, extant work in international accounting argues that the
cipals' resources. strength of accounting quality is principally influenced by critical en-
But managerial accountability to shareholders is not ubiquitous, vironmental factors such as economic forces, social forces, legal system,
varying across countries due to different corporate governance systems culture and political system (Doupnik & Salter, 1995; Nobes, 1998). The
(Aguilera & Jackson, 2003). For example, the Anglo-American model of legal system, for example, is a typical formal institution and the per-
corporate governance emphasizes shareholder supremacy (Hansmann ception of its strengths or weaknesses as well as its outcomes speak to
& Kraakman, 2001). Going by the logic of shareholder-value max- the levels of government integrity (Rothstein & Teorell, 2008) with
imization, with emphasis on the individual interest of the shareholder, potential impact on firms' accounting practices. La Porta, Lopez-de-
managerial accountability should be expected to be higher in Anglo- Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) observed that when a nation's legal
American models of governance than in stakeholder models of Japan system is relatively underdeveloped or if the legal code is enforced
and Germany (Chizema & Shinozawa, 2012). unevenly, respect for the law declines and economic transactions are
We argue that beyond the logic drawn on diverse corporate gov- generally disorderly and inefficient.
ernance systems, government integrity potentially determines the ex- However, there is a plethora of studies suggesting that enforcement
tent to which firms in a given country context exercise managerial ac- mechanisms alone are not a sufficient condition to deliver effective fi-
countability on shareholders. We further argue that in national nancial reporting at a country level (Brown et al., 2014), calling for
environments where government integrity is low, laws and regulations attention to contextual issues in accounting (Mazzi, Slack, &
may not be effectively implemented thus failing to provide direction on Tsalavoutas, 2018). We argue that government integrity is an important
how corporate leaders should behave. In such contexts where govern- and relevant contextual factor in this regard. Indeed, government in-
ment corruption is pervasive (Rodriguez et al., 2005) corporate leaders tegrity is often seen in light of how the government discloses its actions
may lose confidence in the word and action (Simons, 2002) of gov- to the public (Devas & Grant, 2003). Consistent with our main argu-
ernment authorities. Here, the failure of government officials to account ment in this paper, government integrity is likely to drive corporate
for their actions to the citizens may be taken as an example by corpo- leadership in its policy and action on corporate accountability and
rate leaders as they deal with shareholders and the board. Thus, the disclosure. Managers might, therefore, be unable or unwilling to
lack of government accountability, most likely through levels of gov- commit their firms to credible external verification of their income
ernment integrity, may suggest that corporate leaders may in turn fail disclosures if the necessary infrastructure for such verification is not
to be accountable to shareholders and to the board of directors. Khatri, available.
Tsang, and Begley (2006) found that, in the aftermath of the Asian fi-
Hypothesis 2. Government integrity will positively impact
nancial crisis, corruption was endemic and that it led to weak corporate
accountability and disclosure as measured in auditing and accounting
governance practices, with no regard for shareholders' interests. In
reports.
contrast, Du, Li, Lin, and Wang (2018) found that government integrity
is positively related to efficient corporate investment, a practice bound
to benefit shareholders. Government integrity and protection of minority shareholders
We, therefore, hypothesize that:
The contextual effect of government integrity may also influence
Hypothesis 1. Government integrity will positively impact on
corporate leadership on how minority shareholders are protected across
managerial accountability to shareholders and the board.
countries. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2002) show that

4
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

most firms outside the US are controlled by large shareholders who can GDP accounted for by the respective sector (Global Competitiveness
extract private benefits from the corporations they control. A number of Report, 2017–2018). Moreover, the companies from which the re-
recent papers model this extraction of private benefits (Shleifer & spondents are randomly selected, represent a good geographical cov-
Wolfenzon, 2002; Doidge, Karolyi, & Stulz, 2007; Stulz, 2005). erage within a country. The survey is administered in a variety of for-
Moreover, studying emerging markets, Young, Peng, Ahlstrom, mats, including face-to-face or telephone interviews with business
Bruton, and Jiang (2008) argue that principal-principal agency pro- executives, mailed paper forms and online surveys. This survey, con-
blems, that is conflicts between large and small shareholders, exist in ducted by WEF, is a reputable source of timely and vital information
these economies because they typically do not have an effective and related to the business environment in which business executives op-
predictable rule of law which, in turn, creates a ‘weak governance’ erate in several countries. It is widely used in academic research (Van
environment (Dharwadkar, George, & Brandes, 2000, p. 650; Mitton, de Walle, 2006; Yang & Huang, 1990). The data from the survey gives a
2002, p. 215). comparative qualitative picture of the economic and business en-
Exploitation of minority shareholders by large owners, including vironment of each country as provided by a representative group of
family control, is therefore more severe in corrupt countries, that is, business executives.
where government institutions lack integrity (Schleifer & Vishny, 1993; The three measures used in this study are based on executives' re-
Zingales, 1994). Consistent with this view, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, sponses on the following questions: 1) ManAcc: In your country, to
Shleifer, and Vishny (1999) find that French civil law countries, which what extent is management accountable to investors and boards of di-
they claim to be relatively more corrupt, tend to have particularly poor rectors? [1 = not at all; 7 = to a great extent]. 2) AuditRep: In your
protection of minority shareholders. In other words, the lack of gov- country, how strong are financial auditing and reporting standards?
ernment integrity is manifested in poor protection of minority share- [1 = extremely weak; 7 = extremely strong]. 3) MinIntrst: In your
holders as large owners either have no control from the authorities or country, to what extent are the interests of minority shareholders pro-
bribe government officials to avoid any restrictions to their actions and tected by the legal system? [1 = not protected at all; 7 = fully pro-
choices (La Porta et al., 1999; Ufere et al., 2012; Young et al., 2008). tected]. We compute a fourth measure, Corporate Governance Index
Based on these arguments, drawn on extant literature, we hypothesize (CGI), as the average of the three WEF measures explained above.
that governments that lack integrity, in other words, that are more Given that several business executives provided responses to the
corrupt, have less impact on the protection of minority shareholders. questions above, over a period of four years, we need to establish
whether these responses are both reliable (interrater reliability-IRR)
Hypothesis 3. Government integrity will positively impact on the
and in agreement (interrater agreement-IRA). The presence of both
protection of minority interests.
reliability and agreement would justify our decision to aggregate yearly
The fourth hypothesis is a summary of the preceding ones, ag- survey scores into single variables.
gregating the three corporate governance outcomes. It is drawn on the Using STATA, we estimated ICCs, based on the one-way random
central view that government integrity potentially dictates how cor- effects. We report ICC estimates, the F-static and significance levels for
porate leadership behaves in determining the overall health of cor- the four dependent variables. First, the aggregation was justifiable for
porations in a country. Thus, high levels of government integrity or the managerial accountability to shareholders and the board: F(92,
state of a country's freedom from corruption translates into better 279) = 27.75; p > 0.01; ICC(1) = 0.87; ICC(2) = 0.96. Second, the
corporate governance by firms hence: aggregation for audit and accounting reporting was supported: F(92,
279) = 70.65; p > 0.01; ICC(1) = 0.95; ICC(2) = 0.99. Third, the ag-
Hypothesis 4. Government integrity will positively impact on overall
gregation for the variable on minority interests protection was justified:
corporate governance practices.
F(92, 279) = 62.61; p > 0.01; ICC(1) = 0.94; ICC(2) = 0.98. The ag-
gregation for the fourth variable, CGI, was also justifiable: F(92,
Field study methodology 186) = 7.34; p > 0.01; ICC(1) = 0.68; ICC(2) = 0.86.
These ICC estimates (both for ICC1 and ICC2) are high suggesting
Data and measures the suitability of aggregating yearly survey scores into single variables.
Because the ICC(1) index simultaneously measures IRR and IRA,
Our study examines the potential impact of government integrity on LeBreton and Senter (2008) claim that high values may only be ob-
national corporate governance practices. To achieve our objectives, we tained when there is both absolute consensus and relative consistency
source data from a sample of 93 countries that were selected on the in judges' ratings.
basis of available data on all the study's variables for the period
2011–2018. Independent variable

Dependent variables For this study, we employ government integrity (GovInt) as the in-
dependent variable. The score for GovInt is derived from Transparency
The dependent variables are about corporate governance practices International's Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) for 2011 and is a
namely, managerial accountability to shareholders and the board measure of how corrupt public sectors are seen to be in countries
(ManAcc), strength of audit and accounting reports (AuditRep) and (Fredriksson & Svensson, 2003). According to Transparency Interna-
protection of minority interests (MinIntrst). tional, the index captures the informed views of analysts, business-
Data for the dependent variables are drawn from the Global people and experts in countries around the world. The CPI is based on a
Competitiveness Reports of the World Economic Forum (WEF) for the 10-point scale in which a score of 10 indicates very little corruption,
years 2011 through 2018, for the 93 countries in our sample. The WEF thus high level of government integrity (Fredriksson et al., 2007), and a
draws its data from carrying out annual Executive Opinion Surveys of score of 0 indicates a very corrupt government. In scoring freedom from
business executives who are randomly sampled from a large list of corruption, the Index converts the raw CPI data to a scale of 0 to 100 by
potential respondents from micro companies, small and medium-sized multiplying the CPI score by 10. For example, if a country's raw CPI
enterprises and large companies. data score is 3.5, its overall freedom from corruption score is 35.
The companies represent various sectors including agriculture,
manufacturing industry, non-manufacturing industry (e.g., mining and Control variables
quarrying, electricity, gas and water supply, construction) and services.
The number of firms from each sector is in proportion to the share of We use the logarithm of the five-year (2012–2016) growth rate of

5
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

gross domestic product per capita as the basis of our measurement for regressors in our model. We provide the rationale for each of the in-
level of economic development (GDP). We collect data for this variable struments we use in this study. We use legal origin as an instrumental
from the World Bank Development Indicators, published on their variable for government integrity. In previous studies, legal origins
website. have been used as instrumental variables for corruption (e.g.,
We also use the logarithm of foreign direct investment inflows (FDI). Fredriksson & Svensson, 2003; Pellegrini & Gerlagh, 2004). The vari-
The rationale for this control variable is that foreign direct investment able is a categorical variable indicating whether a country has French,
influences the corporate governance of companies in the target country English, Scandinavian, German or Socialist legal origin. The justifica-
as governance practices are diffused from the country of origin. tion for using legal origins as an instrument is its relationship with
Moreover, previous studies have shown that countries with higher institutional efficiency as well as with the level of government inter-
foreign equity inflows have a higher degree of protection of shareholder vention. La Porta et al. (1999) argue that more interventionist gov-
rights (Guillén & Capron, 2016). To control for this competitive kind of ernments and less efficient bureaucracies should have higher levels of
adoption, we included the logarithm of the average annual inflows of corruption, and hence lower levels of government integrity. For ex-
foreign direct investment for the years 2009 through 2016. Data on ample, countries founded on English common law focus less on gov-
foreign direct investment inflows was collected from the UNCTAD. ernment intervention and place more emphasis on the protection of
In addition, we employ a cultural dimension, the extent to which a individual rights and should therefore have lower levels of corruption.
given society is considered to be individualistic or collectivist La Porta et al. (1999) also argue that legal origins are exogenous to
(Hofstede, 1983), as a third control variable (Individualism). Corporate economic variables or institutions because they are mainly determined
governance practices such as the use of independent directors on boards by historical factors (La Porta et al., 1999).
have their origin in countries that score highly on the cultural dimen- For the endogenous variable (GDP), we use four instrumental vari-
sion of individualism. Examples include the US and the UK, and in such ables. Two of these are on fractionalization: linguistic and religious.
countries the purpose of corporate governance practices is to maximize Linguistic and religious fractionalization measures are based on the
value for the individual investor and not for the collective of other probability that two randomly drawn individuals (from a country) are
stakeholders (Aguilera & Jackson, 2003). not from the same linguistic and religious group respectively. These
fractionalization variables, drawn from Alesina, Devleeschauer,
Model specification Easterly, Kurlat, and Wacziarg (2003), refer to the situation in the late
1980s and early 1990s. Scholars argue that highly fragmented countries
Using STATA, we conducted the following estimation. Given the on the basis of both language and religion are more likely to have poor
linear regression: Y = β0 + β1X1 + … + β1Xn + ε, where Xi are en- economic development. For example, studies by Mauro (1995) and
dogenous variables - government integrity (GovInt), economic devel- Easterly and Levine (1997) offer econometric evidence showing that
opment (GDP), foreign direct investment inflows (FDI) and in- greater levels of linguistic fractionalization hinder economic perfor-
dividualism, we first regress Xi on Z1 and Xi−1 to obtain Xi mance. The fact that the data on fractionalization variables were col-
lected in the 1980s–1990s and the fact that the fragmentation of so-
Xi = y0 + y1 Z1 + …+ yn Zn + v (1) cieties on the basis of language and religion cannot be changed by the
dynamics of corporate governance in recent years, suggest that the
where Zi represents instrumental variables. We then plug in the fitted
averaged instrumental variables are exogenous.
values of Xi derived from Eq. (1) into the original linear regression
We use an exogenous geographical feature of countries (latitude) as
equation to estimate Eq. (2):
a second instrument for economic development. Latitude, the distance
Y (corpgov ) = 0 + 1 X1 + …+ 1 Xn + , (2) from the equator measured in absolute degrees, affects climate and,
therefore, aspects of agricultural productivity and disease. Previous
where Y(corpgov) is represented by dependent variables (managerial studies have shown that countries closer to the equator are less devel-
accountability to shareholders and the board, auditing and financial oped. Latitude has, therefore, considerable explanatory power for the
reporting, protection of minority investors) and ν is a composite error log of per capita GDP (Barro & McCleary, 2003), suggesting a positive
term, correlated with X1 … Xn . relationship between latitude and economic development. Latitude is
As pointed out above, our regressors are potentially endogenous, completely exogenous and can be used as an appropriate instrument as
that is they may be systematically related to unobserved causes of the it can be changed neither by economic development nor by any level of
dependent variable, in this case, corporate governance variables. shock from a disturbance.
Violations of this sort commonly occur when factors related to in- We also employ the situation of whether a country is landlocked
dependent variables, that predict outcome, are dropped in estimation or (landlock) or not as an instrumental variable for economic development.
when the independent variables themselves are measured with error Collier (2008) argues that the landlocked status is one of the four key
(Wooldridge, 2002). Of course, two-way causation is yet another con- factors preventing the poorest countries from growing and ripping the
dition but not the only concern. For example, in the context of our benefits of globalization. Moreover, gravity models point to a strong
study, it is plausible that government integrity could determine cor- negative effect of landlockedness on bilateral trade (Coulibaly &
porate governance practices as we hypothesize in this paper. However, Fontagne, 2006; Limao & Venables, 2001). As such trading costs are
the reverse is also likely to be the case as corporate governance prac- higher in landlocked countries thus constraining economic develop-
tices such as the quality of auditing and accounting reporting could ment. The fact that a country is landlocked cannot be affected by eco-
deter corrupt practices by government authorities. Moreover, within nomic development, making it a good instrumental variable.
our model, government integrity could be a predictor of economic de- The third endogenous variable, foreign direct investment (FDI), is
velopment. We thus used the 2SLS estimator, an instrumental variable instrumented by two measures of size: log population and log area.
(IV) method which is useful to purge coefficients of endogeneity bias First, large populations provide a large market for products and services
(Baum, Schaffer, & Stillman, 2011) due to common methods, mea- offered by multinational enterprises, have a large and cheaper labor
surement error or simultaneity (Antonakis, Bendahan, Jacquart, & force and a vast skills base (Billington, 1999). Large land area is likely
Lalive, 2010). to accommodate more foreign firms seeking to establish greenfield in-
vestment and potentially home to more resources that foreign firms
Instrumental variables seek to exploit. Foreign direct investment does not impact on country
population, but the reverse, we argue, is true. Land area is finite,
We identified instrumental variables for the four endogenous making a good instrumental variable for foreign direct investment. We

6
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

source data on population and land area from the World Bank Database. the set of dependent variables are high. All other correlations are
It is important for our model to justify the exogeneity of our in- modest.
struments (population and area). While area is a geographical “hard” As explained above, we tested our hypothesis using ivregress of
characteristic of a country and is unlikely to be influenced by other STATA to obtain 2SLS estimates. As suggested by several scholars (e.g.,
variables, the situation is not as straightforward for the population. For Antonakis et al., 2010; Larcker & Rusticus, 2010), we report both the
example, one could argue that population variable is not exogenous OLS (see Table 2) and the 2SLS results (see Table 3). First, Table 3
because it depends on FDI, that is, richer countries attract larger shows OLS results.
numbers of migrants and, therefore, these countries are likely to have From our OLS results, as shown in Table 2, the coefficients for the
higher FDI. Studies have found that FDI and migration often move in effect of government integrity on managerial accountability to share-
the same direction (e.g., Clemens & Williamson, 2000; Groznik, 2003; holders and the board (β = 0.02, p = 0.000), auditing and accounting
Lucas, 1990), however, several of these papers consider correlation reporting (β = 0.02, p = 0.000), protection of minority interest
rather than causality. Kim (2006), for example, investigated the link (β = 0.03, p = 0.000) and on the overall corporate governance index
between migration, trade and FDI for the United States and concluded (β = 0.02, p = 0.000) are as predicted.
that FDI and trade are substitutes, but both are led by migration, sug- Table 3 shows results for 2SLS tests. Joint tests including all en-
gesting that migration was an exogenous variable. Kugler and Rapoport dogenous regressors and their respective instruments provide a better
(2005) distinguished between skills and unskilled labor movements and explanation for the state of variables and for the suitability of their
argued that skilled migrants positively influence FDI, but only in the instruments. Starting with the instruments for the variable, government
long run. In order to further test the exogeneity of the population in- integrity, the coefficients on legal origins are significant and positive, as
strument, we collected data on immigration for 93 countries in our shown in Table 3, Model 1. Specifically, relative to the Socialist legal
sample from the UN dataset2 as well as data on FDI for the same origin (dropped in the estimation), the coefficients for the rest of the
countries from the UNCTAD World Investment Report.3 Considering legal origins are positive and significant: British (β = 11.22,
that the data on immigration was very fragmented after 2015, we p = 0.063), French (β = 8.97, p = 0.014), German (β = 22.97,
captured data for the relative change in FDI from 2011 to 2015 as well p = 0.000), and Scandinavian (β = 25.93, p = 0.001).
as for the relative change in immigration for the same period in 79 Coefficients of two instrumental variables used for the endogenous
countries in our dataset. We found that FDI decreased from 2011 to variable economic development are significant, as shown in Table 3,
2015 in 47 out of 79 countries. In 36 of these countries, migration also Model 2. Specifically, linguistic fractionalization (β = −0.73,
decreased and in 11 of them FDI increased. In 32 out of 79 countries p = 0.001) is negative and significant and as expected, latitude is po-
FDI increased from 2011 to 2015 and in 26 out of 32 countries, mi- sitive and significant (β = 0.01, p = 0.030). From the two instrumental
gration declined whereas in 6 of them it increased. Fisher's exact test variables used for foreign direct investment (FDI), the size of a country's
comparing countries with increased and decreased migration levels population is positive and significant (β = 0.10, p = 0.025).
showed no statistically significant difference (Fisher's exact test Finally, as stated earlier, we considered whether the dominant
p = 0.782). This provides additional support for our assumption of country language allows pronoun drop or not, where languages that
exogeneity of the population variable. allow pronoun drop are collectivist. The coefficient for the instrumental
For the fourth endogenous variable (individualism) we use a dummy variable, pronoundrop (β = −0.20.49, p = 0.000) is positive and sig-
variable of whether a country's primary language permits speakers to nificant (as shown in Table 3, Model 4), suggesting that countries
drop a personal pronoun (pronoundrop) when it is used as the subject of whose languages drop the pronoun ‘I' are not individualistic.
a sentence. In some languages, for example Spanish, pronoun drop is We also carried out post-estimation tests to ascertain the strength of
permitted. For example, the English sentence “I speak” may be trans- the first stage statistics, at equation level. The results, as shown in
lated into Spanish either as “Yo ablo” or simply as “Ablo” (Davis & Table 3, show that that the employed instrumental variables are strong:
Abdurazokzoda, 2016). In contrast, pronoun drop is not permitted in Model 1 [F(11, 81) = 18.71, p = 0.000], Model 2 [F(11, 81) = 24.07,
other languages such as English, as the pronoun “I” is required to make p = 0.000], Model 3 [F(11, 81) = 18.85, p = 0.000], Model 4 [F(11,
sense of the sentence. In such languages, the use of “I” signals that the 81) = 19.62, p = 0.000].
person is highlighted as a figure against the speech context and its We also used Reg3 of Stata to determine the strength of instruments
absence reduces the prominence of the speaker's person. As such the used for each of the endogenous variables: [F(4, 89) = 6.56, p = 0.000]
emphasis on the pronominal subject, especially I or you, in languages in for the instruments of GovInt, [F(4, 89) = 13.10, p = 0.000] for GDP,
which pronoun drop is not permitted is expected to be associated with [F(2, 91) = 8.23, p = 0.000] for FDI and [F(1, 92) = 42.22, p = 0.000]
cultural individualism (Davis & Abdurazokzoda, 2016; Kashima & for individualism.
Kashima, 1998). In contrast, the greater contextualization of the subject We turn to results for the full models or joint tests, that is, in the
in languages that permit pronoun drop is expected to be associated with second stage of the 2SLS shown in Table 3. First, contrasting the results
more collectivist cultures. of the second-stage regression with OLS estimation, the Wu-Hausman
Data on pronoun drop is based on an authoritative source of lin- test, for the full models, rejects the null that there is no endogeneity
guistic information, the World Atlas of Language Structures (WALS) and problem with OLS estimation for Model 5 [χ2(4) = 5.26, p = 0.001],
has been used in previous studies (e.g., Davis & Abdurazokzoda, 2016; Model 6 [χ2(4) = 5.27, p = 0.001], Model 7 [χ2(4) = 6.60,
Kashima & Kashima, 1998). p = 0.000] and Model 8 [χ2(4) = 7.08, p = 0.000]. These results
suggest that all the regressors are endogenous, suggesting that 2SLS
estimation is preferred to the OLS estimation.
Results of the field study Second, we examined the exclusion restriction (over-identification
restriction) of the 2SLS model to ensure that the excluded instruments
Tables 1a and 1b show the correlations, means and standard de- from the equation do not correlate with the disturbance of the depen-
viations of the variables used in this study, including dependent, in- dent variable. The null hypothesis for the overidentification test is that
dependent, control and instrumental. As expected, correlations among the instruments are exogenous, in other words, uncorrelated with the
error term. Thus, if the test statistic is insignificant, we fail to reject the
2
See https://www.un.org/en/development/desa/population/migration/ null hypothesis. The over-identification Sargan test results are as fol-
data/index.asp for more detail. lows: for Model 5 [χ2(6) = 5.64, p = 0.582], Model 6 [χ2(6) = 5.74,
3
See https://unctad.org/en/pages/PublicationWebflyer.aspx?publicationid p = 0.570], Model 7 [χ2(6) = 12.36, p = 0.089] and Model 8
=2460 for more detail. [χ2(6) = 7.25, p = 0.404]. These results indicate that the model

7
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 1a
Field study means, standard deviations and correlations (part 1).
Variable Mean SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

1 ManAcc 4.94 0.63


2 AuditRep 4.92 0.78 0.89⁎⁎⁎
3 MinIntrst 4.33 0.73 0.83⁎⁎⁎ 0.90⁎⁎⁎
4 CGI 4.73 0.68 0.94⁎⁎⁎ 0.97⁎⁎⁎ 0.95⁎⁎⁎
5 GovInt 50.25 20.99 0.77⁎⁎⁎ 0.78⁎⁎⁎ 0.75⁎⁎⁎ 0.80⁎⁎⁎
6 GDP 9.23 1.36 0.62⁎⁎⁎ 0.70⁎⁎⁎ 0.57⁎⁎⁎ 0.66⁎⁎⁎ 0.79⁎⁎⁎
7 FDI 2.88 0.24 −0.40⁎⁎ −0.38⁎⁎ −0.31⁎⁎ −0.38⁎⁎ −0.41⁎⁎⁎ −0.35⁎⁎⁎
8 Individualism 39.84 22.40 0.57⁎⁎⁎ 0.57⁎⁎⁎ 0.50⁎⁎ 0.57⁎⁎⁎ 0.63⁎⁎⁎ 0.60⁎⁎⁎ −0.36⁎⁎⁎
9 legor_uk 0.32 0.47 0.12 0.11 0.26⁎⁎ 0.17 −0.08 −0.21⁎ 0.10 0.01
10 legor_fr 0.44 0.50 −0.27⁎⁎ −0.32⁎ −0.34⁎⁎ −0.33⁎⁎ −0.26⁎⁎ −0.11 0.06 −0.25⁎⁎ −0.61⁎⁎⁎
11 legor_ge 0.17 0.38 0.01 0.12 −0.04 0.04 0.22 0.24⁎⁎ −0.07 0.16 −0.31⁎⁎
12 legor_sc 0.05 0.23 0.36⁎⁎⁎ 0.32⁎⁎ 0.37⁎⁎ 0.36⁎⁎⁎ 0.39⁎⁎⁎ 0.31⁎⁎ −0.24⁎⁎ 0.29⁎⁎ −0.16
13 legor_so 0.01 0.10 −0.11 −0.12 −0.20 −0.15 −0.06 −0.04 0.06 −0.07 −0.07
14 Ling-fractional 0.33 0.20 0.03 −0.06 0.06 0.01 −0.19⁎ −0.43⁎⁎ 0.10 −0.08 0.38⁎⁎⁎
15 Relig-fractional 0.43 0.24 −0.12 0.14 0.14 0.14 0.03 −0.08 −0.07 0.14 0.39⁎⁎⁎
16 Latitude 24.43 26.66 0.12⁎ 0.12 0.05 0.10 0.36⁎⁎⁎ 0.45⁎⁎⁎ −0.19⁎ 0.40⁎⁎⁎ −0.36⁎⁎⁎
17 Landlock 0.11 0.31 0.05 0.08 0.02 0.05 −0.02 −0.08 −0.06 0.15 −0.02
18 LnArea 12.20 2.04 −0.10 −0.21⁎ −0.11 −0.15 −0.20 −0.24⁎ 0.28⁎⁎ 0.04 0.08
19 LnPopul 7.21 0.70 −0.27⁎⁎ −0.32⁎⁎ −0.21 −0.28⁎⁎ −0.32⁎⁎ −0.36⁎⁎⁎ 0.39⁎⁎⁎ −0.10 0.14
20 pronoundrop 0.70 0.45 −0.59⁎⁎ 0.45⁎⁎ −0.46⁎ −0.51⁎⁎ −0.52⁎⁎ −0.41⁎⁎ 0.32⁎⁎ −0.56⁎⁎⁎ −0.14

Notes: N = 93.
⁎⁎⁎
p < 0.001.
⁎⁎
p < 0.01.

p < 0.05.

Table 1b
Field study means, standard deviations and correlations (part 2).
Variable Mean SD 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19

1 ManAcc 4.94 0.63


2 AuditRep 4.92 0.78
3 MinIntrst 4.33 0.73
4 CGI 4.73 0.68
5 GovInt 50.25 20.99
6 GDP 9.23 1.36
7 FDI 2.88 0.24
8 Individualism 39.84 22.40
9 legor_uk 0.32 0.47
10 legor_fr 0.44 0.50
11 legor_ge 0.17 0.38 −0.40⁎⁎⁎
12 legor_sc 0.05 0.23 −0.21⁎ −0.11
13 legor_so 0.01 0.10 −0.09 −0.05 −0.02
14 Ling-fractional 0.33 0.20 −0.13⁎ −0.15 −0.18⁎ −0.12
15 Relig-fractional 0.43 0.24 −0.40⁎⁎ 0.20 −0.20 −0.18 0.36⁎⁎⁎
16 Latitude 24.43 26.66 −0.10 0.36⁎⁎⁎ 0.33⁎⁎ 0.08 −0.28⁎⁎ −0.27⁎⁎
17 Landlock 0.11 0.31 −0.17 0.30⁎⁎ −0.08 −0.04 0.17 0.21 0.01
18 LnArea 12.20 2.04 0.04 −0.13 −0.01 −0.03 0.19⁎ 0.05 −0.23⁎⁎ −0.11
19 LnPopul 7.21 0.70 0.09 −0.13 −0.24 −0.05 0.19⁎ 0.03 −0.14 −0.13 0.37⁎⁎⁎
20 pronoundrop 0.70 0.45 0.25⁎⁎ 0.05 −0.37⁎⁎⁎ 0.07 −0.07 −0.23⁎ −0.25⁎⁎ −0.00 −0.02 0.13

Notes: N = 93.
⁎⁎⁎
p < 0.001.
⁎⁎
p < 0.01.

p < 0.05.

constraints were tenable, suggesting that the instruments are jointly There is support for this hypothesis in our results as shown in Model 5
exogenous.4 (β = 0.03, p = 0.004).
Our central hypothesis is that corporate leadership in a given con- In Hypothesis 2, we proposed that government integrity, as a con-
text of government integrity will positively impact on national corpo- textual leadership factor, will positively impact on auditing and ac-
rate governance practices. Compared to the OLS estimates, discussed counting reports. As predicted, government integrity has a positive and
above, coefficients from 2SLS trend in the same direction, however, significant impact on auditing and accounting reports as shown in
they are larger. For example, in Hypothesis 1, we proposed that gov- Model 6 (β = 0.04, p = 0.003).
ernment integrity, as a contextual leadership factor, will positively In Hypothesis 3, we proposed that government integrity, as a con-
impact on managerial accountability to shareholders and the board. textual leadership factor, will positively impact on the protection of
minority interests. As we predicted, government integrity has a positive
and significant impact on the protection of minority interests as shown
4 in Model 7 (β = 0.05, p = 0.000).
Note that Model 7 returns probability of 0.089. However, this suggests that
test results are only marginally significant at 10% level when we use protection In Hypothesis 4, we proposed that government integrity, as a con-
of minority investors as a dependent variable. textual leadership factor, will positively impact on overall corporate

8
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 2 significant coefficient as an indication of the causal effect of the context


OLS results of the effects of government integrity on corporate governance. of government integrity on leaders' corporate governance practices.
Model 1 2 3 4 Another finding worth mentioning is that from one of the control
variables, specifically, the economic development. This is because from
ManAcc AudRep MinIntst CGIndex 2SLS results, the impact of economic development on managerial ac-
countability to shareholders and the board, on protection of minority
Constant 4.49 ⁎⁎⁎
3.38⁎⁎⁎
3.20⁎⁎⁎
3.69⁎⁎⁎
(0.69) (0.83) (0.84) (0.71) investors and on the overall corporate governance index suggest that
GovInt 0.02⁎⁎⁎ 0.02⁎⁎⁎ 0.03⁎⁎⁎ 0.02⁎⁎⁎ when countries are doing well economically, less attention is given to
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) corporate governance. This probably explains why corporate govern-
GDP −0.03⁎ 0.23⁎⁎ −0.09 0.03 ance is considered to be cyclical as calls for improved corporate gov-
(0.11) (0.14) (0.14) (0.12)
ernance tend to take place when performance by firms and countries is
FDI −0.21+ −0.17 0.01 −0.12
(0.19) (0.23) (0.24) (0.20) poor or following corporate scandals (Clarke, 2017).
Individualism 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Adj R2 0.60 0.61 0.55 0.64 Laboratory study: experimental design and hypotheses
F-statistic 35.41⁎⁎⁎ 37.29⁎⁎⁎ 29.25⁎⁎⁎ 41.29⁎⁎⁎
Our field study suggests that, at the macro level, government in-
Notes: N = 93. Robust standard errors in parentheses.
+ tegrity impacts on corporate governance decisions. Yet, further ex-
Significant at 0.10 level.
ploration is needed to clearly show the link between the macro level

Significant at 0.05 level.
⁎⁎
Significant at 0.01 level. contextual impact of government integrity on the leader's decision
⁎⁎⁎
Significant at 0.001 level. making or choices at the micro level. To achieve this, we utilize the
methodology of laboratory experiments. Specifically, we design a series
governance practices. As we predicted, government integrity has a of experimental treatments, where we vary the social norm about cor-
positive and significant impact on corporate governance index as shown porate governance (corporate governance norm variable), the level of
in Model 8 (β = 0.04, p = 0.001).5 corruption in the state (government integrity variable), the strength of
law enforcement mechanisms (law enforcement variable), as well as the
level of profit which could be achieved from corporate activity (profit
Discussion of field results level variable). In our design, each variable may take only 2 values,
therefore, we have 16 treatment variations in total.
The results of the field study offer support to the tested hypotheses. In each variation, participants are assigned to groups of 3 people
The results suggest that countries with higher levels of government each. A randomization process assigns the CEO role to one of the par-
integrity, characterized by less corruption, are perceived to have better ticipants and the roles of employees to 2 of the participants.6 Each
corporate governance practices. First, and specifically, we found a group of participants is asked to perform a simple experimental task. In
significant causal relationship such that higher levels of government this experimental task, the group receives an endowment of £9. The
integrity positively impact on managerial accountability to share- CEO then has an opportunity to invest the money into a risky business
holders and the board. This finding points to the exemplary guidance activity or to keep the endowment. If the CEO decides to keep the en-
that good national governance provides to corporate leaders either dowment, each group participant receives £3. The group has an op-
through the presence of effective formal institutions of the government portunity to earn more money if the CEO decides to invest in a risky
(North, 1990) or simply by way of conforming to what may be seen as business activity. The exact amount of money at stake is determined by
normal national behavior (Scott, 2001). the value of the profit level variable. To maximize the number of ob-
Second, we found a significant causal relationship such that higher servations, we use a strategy method, asking all participants to make
levels of government integrity positively impact on the strength of audit their decisions “as if” they played the role of the CEO. After all decisions
and accounting reports. This finding helps to explain the heterogeneity are made, the computer program determines the CEO in each group and
of auditing and accounting reporting across the world even in instances calculates the payoff for each player.
where countries adopted similar international accounting standards. Half of the variations (8 of 16) represent our baseline in the sense
Thus, while countries may be using similar accounting standards (e.g. that we do not use the corporate governance norm in those variations.
International Accounting Standards-IAS), however, the quality of their In the other half of variations (8 of 16), the norm (e.g., Bendahan,
application differs as a function of contextual factors, where govern- Zehnder, Pralong, & Antonakis, 2015) is first elicited and informed to
ment integrity is one of them. Previous studies have noted a variety of the participants. To elicit the norm, we used the following two ques-
contextual factors including legal, social and economic factors and at- tions:
tention has not been given to the causal impact of government integrity.
Third, we found a significant and causal relationship such that (1) Do you think it is acceptable for a CEO not to pay taxes? Yes No
higher levels of government integrity positively impact on the protec- (2) Do you think it is acceptable for a CEO to pay bribes? Yes No
tion of minority investors. This finding is consistent with earlier re-
search on the determinants of minority shareholders' protection (La In each experimental session, in variations where the norm was
Porta et al., 1999). More importantly, our findings provide an ex- used, participants answered these two questions and results from their
planation on the condition that allows exploitation of minority in- responses (total percentage of “Yes” and “No” answers in an experi-
vestors by majority shareholders beyond that made on emerging mar- mental session) were reported to all the participants. In other words, in
kets (Young et al., 2008). The three findings discussed above are these variations, we imposed a demand effect (Welsh & Ordonez, 2014)
summarized in our fourth hypothesis that similarly yields a positive and which enhanced the corporate governance norm (henceforth, the norm-
enhancing demand effect) (e.g., Bendahan et al., 2015). This norm-
5
We conducted a robustness check to ascertain the effect of regions in our
6
estimations. The countries in the sample were classified under the following Because we are primarily interested in the link between corporate govern-
regions: Africa, Asia, Middle East, South America, North America, Eastern ance, government integrity and leaders' decision making, for simplicity, we
Europe and Rest of Europe. Results from these tests (not included) are not concentrate on a case when leaders are appointed (exogenous assignment of
significantly different from those reported in Table 3. CEOs) rather than voted (endogenous assignment of CEOs).

9
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 3
2SLS results of the effect of government integrity on corporate governance.
Model 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Shea's R2

1st stage 1st stage 1st stage 1st stage 2nd stage 2nd stage 2nd stage 2nd stage

GovInt GDP FDI Individual ManAcc AudRep MinIntst CGIndex

Constant 91.56⁎⁎⁎ 5.46⁎⁎⁎ 2.15⁎⁎⁎ 32.71 9.32⁎⁎⁎ 8.73⁎ 7.75⁎ 8.60⁎⁎


(20.06) (0.56) (0.25) (23.70) (2.92) (3.50) (3.47) (3.08)
GovInt 0.03⁎⁎ 0.04⁎⁎ 0.05⁎⁎⁎ 0.04⁎⁎⁎ 0.154
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
GDP −0.75⁎⁎ −0.63⁎ −1.04⁎⁎⁎ −0.81⁎⁎ 0.285
(0.27) (0.33) (0.32) (0.29)
FDI −1.18 −1.16 −0.65 −0.99 0.087
(0.84) (1.01) (1.00) (0.89)
Individualism 0.01 −0.00 0.00 0.00 0.270
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (−0.01)
+
Legor_uk 11.22 0.53 ⁎⁎⁎
−0.08 14.85 ⁎

(5.94) (0.19) (0.06) (6.17)


Legor_fr 8.97⁎ 0.52⁎⁎⁎ −0.013+ 10.98⁎
(3.56) (0.11) (0.07) (4.58)
Legor_ge 22.97⁎⁎⁎ 0.73⁎⁎⁎ −0.10 11.14+
(5.92) (0.17) (0.06) (6.38)
Legor_sc 25.94⁎⁎⁎ 0.48⁎⁎ −0.19⁎⁎ 12.95+
(7.16) (0.18) (0.06) (7.43)
Lingui-fractional −6.96 −0.73⁎⁎⁎ 0.03 −9.91
(6.92) (0.21) (0.08) (8.14)
Relig-fractional −3.32 −0.01 −0.10 9.67
(9.40) (0.28) (0.09) (9.82)
Latitude 0.04 0.01⁎ −0.00 0.29⁎
(0.11) (0.00) (0.00) (0.12)
Landlock −5.67 −0.19 −0.01 10.92⁎
(4.84) (0.17) (0.06) (5.00)
LnArea −0.64 0.02 0.01 2.59+
(1.89) (0.04) (0.01) (1.47)
LnPopul −4.01 −0.26⁎ 0.10⁎ −4.37
(4.33) (0.11) (0.04) (3.91)
pronoundrop −20.17⁎⁎⁎ −0.47⁎⁎ 0.12⁎⁎⁎ −20.49⁎⁎⁎
(5.08) (0.15) (0.04) (5.88)
R2 0.44 0.52 0.25 0.45 0.33 0.37 0.29 0.36
Hausman χ2(4) 5.26 5.27 6.60 7.08
p = 0.001 p = 0.001 p = 0.000 p = 0.000
Sargan χ2(7) 5.64 p = 0.582 5.74 12.36 7.25
p = 0.570 p = 0.089 p = 0.404
F-stat (F(11, 81)) 18.94⁎⁎⁎ 24.07⁎⁎⁎ 18.85⁎⁎⁎ 19.62⁎⁎⁎

Notes: N = 93. Robust standard errors in parentheses.


+
Significant at 0.10 level.

Significant at 0.05 level.
⁎⁎
Significant at 0.01 level.
⁎⁎⁎
Significant at 0.001 level.

enhancing demand effect allows us to test whether and to what extent whether participants played in the Rich condition or in the Poor con-
the behavior of the study participants depends on what the social norm dition. In the Rich condition, investment of £9 in a risky business ac-
suggests as “acceptable” or the “right” course of action. It intends to tivity yielded £46 with a probability of 2/3 and £9 with a probability of
mimic socially admissible practices, giving us an opportunity to test 1/3. In the Poor condition, investment of £9 in a risky business activity
whether corporate decision making is affected by norms that are im- yielded £19 with a probability of 2/3 and £9 with a probability of 1/3.7
posed by society. In the treatment variations with norm, in order to give In both conditions, if the group earns £9, the group payoff is reported to
participants an opportunity to express their thoughts about the social all participants and split equally (£3 each). In the Rich condition, if the
norm for corporate governance in a less structured way, we also asked group earns £46, the CEO has the following action space:
them an additional question:
(i) The CEO may report the entire profit to the group and pay full tax
(3) Please, provide 3 keywords (adjectives) which, in your opinion, describe in which case:
a “good” CEO. • The CEO receives £40 before taxes are paid and £16 after taxes
are paid (the amount of tax is £24 which is then split between the
The outcome of this question was not displayed to participants. We employees);
used participants' answers to this question to understand the com-
monality and divergence of views among participants about desirable 7
Probabilities of 1/3 and 2/3 were used to minimize the effect of human
CEO traits that impact on our measure of the corporate governance
probability weighting. According to Tversky and Kahneman (1992), humans
norm and we analyzed these answers separately.
tend to overestimate small probabilities and underestimate large probabilities,
As explained above, in variations with and without the norm, we
in other words, they have an inverse S-shaped probability weighting function.
also varied the profit level variable, the law enforcement variable, and This inverse S-shaped probability weighting function crosses the 45-degree line
the government integrity variable. The profit level variable determined at 1/3 (the point where probability weighting is minimal).

10
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

• Employees receive £3 each before taxes are paid and £15 after that CEOs should be honest, then they are more likely to behave
the taxes are paid (each employee receives additional £12 of honestly and if the norm suggests that it is acceptable for CEOs to be
redistributed wealth). dishonest, then they are more likely to behave dishonestly.
(ii) Alternatively, the CEO may report partial profit and cheat on taxes
Hypothesis 6. Government integrity impacts on corporate leaders'
in which case:

behavior such that in a Transparent government context, CEOs are
The CEO receives £40;

more likely to behave honestly, whereas in a Corrupt government
Employees receive £3 each.
context they are more likely to behave dishonestly.
In the Poor condition, if the group earns £19, the CEO has the fol- Hypothesis 7. Law enforcement impacts on corporate leaders' behavior
lowing action space: such that in a High law enforcement context, CEOs are more likely to
behave honestly, whereas in a Low law enforcement context they are
(i) The CEO may report the entire profit to the group and pay full tax more likely to behave dishonestly.
in which case:

Hypothesis 8. The size of corporate profits impacts on corporate
The CEO receives £13 before taxes are paid and £7 after taxes are
leaders' behavior such that in a Poor condition, CEOs are more likely
paid (the amount of tax is £6 which is then split between the
to behave honestly, while in a Rich condition they are more likely to
employees);

behave dishonestly.
Employees receive £3 each before taxes are paid and £6 after
taxes are paid (each employee receives additional £3 of redis-
tributed wealth). Experimental results
(ii) Report partial profit and cheat on taxes in which case:
• The CEO receives £13; As explained above, we conducted 16 variations of the experiment
• Employees receive £3 each. (summarized in Fig. 1). Overall, 576 individuals took part in our ex-
periment: 36 people (2 sessions 18 people each) participated in each
For simplicity, we assume that the CEO can either be completely experimental treatment variation. All experimental participants were
honest or completely dishonest, a condition for our integrity task de- students at the University of Warwick. Participants of all races, ethnic
scribed above. Therefore, in both the Rich condition and the Poor origins, genders, ages, income groups and different university majors
condition, the CEO can either behave honestly (by selecting options (i) were invited to take part in the experiment. Overall, of 576 partici-
or dishonestly (by choosing options (ii)). In other words, our experi- pants, 47% were female and 53% were male. Across all variations, the
mental task closely mimics a corporate responsibility dilemma in which a percentage of female participants ranged between 42% and 55%
CEO can either pay or evade taxes and, in some experimental varia- (Kruskal-Wallis equality-of-populations test revealed no statistically
tions, can either pay on not pay bribes. significant difference across variations according to the gender com-
A law enforcement mechanism is tested using two conditions: Low position (χ2 = 3.44, p = 0.99, df10 = 15). The average age of partici-
enforcement and High enforcement. In the Low enforcement condition, pants was 21 years and the standard deviation is 1.07 (Kruskal-Wallis
the integrity of the CEO is controlled 1/3 of the time, while in the High equality-of-populations test revealed no statistically significant differ-
enforcement condition, the integrity of the CEO is controlled 2/3 of the ence across variations according to the age composition (χ2 = 10.38,
time.8 When the integrity of the CEO is controlled, the CEO is fined his p = 0.80, df = 15). Experiments were conducted in the laboratory
or her entire payoff if he or she behaves dishonestly, in which case the using the z-Tree software (Fischbacher, 2007). Slightly over 1/2 of
payoff of the CEO is divided equally between the remaining two par- participants (54%) were native speakers of English. The number of
ticipants in the group. There is no implication from law enforcement native speakers was similar across all 16 variations (Kruskal-Wallis test
when the CEO behaves honestly. χ2 = 7.58, p = 0.94, df = 15).
The level of government integrity is tested using two conditions: Irrespective of the context, in all the 8 variations where we used the
Corrupt government and Transparent government. If the government is norm-enhancing demand effect, over 94% of participants (on average,
Transparent, then the law enforcement mechanism is applied as de- 98% across all 8 variations) said that it was not acceptable for the CEO
scribed above. If the government is corrupt, the CEO has an opportunity to evade taxes (results of the Kruskal-Wallis test of the equity of po-
to completely avoid controls (checks) if he or she pays ¼ of his or her pulations suggests that there is no statistical difference across 8 varia-
payoff as a bribe (£10 in the Rich condition and £3 in the Poor con- tions with the norm-enhancing demand effect according to this variable
dition9). We assume that if the CEO decides to hide the profit and pay (Kruskal-Wallis test χ2 = 6.29, p = 0.51, df = 7) and over 97% of
the bribe, he or she would not be checked and would avoid the fine with participants (on average, 99% across 8 variations) said that it was not
a probability of 100%. Yet, in this case, in the Rich condition the CEO acceptable to pay bribes (results of the Kruskal-Wallis test also did not
will receive £30 and in the Poor condition, the CEO will receive £10. reveal statistically significant differences across treatments χ2 = 6.02,
Because in the experimental task only 2 out of 3 situations could p = 0.54, df = 7). In other words, in all the 8 variations with the norm-
result in a higher outcome of the investment for the group and lead to enhancing demand effect, the corporate governance norm commu-
“dishonest” behavior or “cheating” (i.e., in our design, tax evasion), we nicated to all participants was that the majority of participants believed
used the strategy method (e.g., Fischbacher, Gächter, & Quercia, 2012) that it was not acceptable for the CEO not to pay taxes and that it was
to elicit decision reactions of the CEOs and then applied those decisions not acceptable for the CEO to pay bribes. Therefore, in each variation
when randomization procedure selected the higher outcome of the two with the norm-enhancing demand effect, participants received a nudge
with a probability of 2/3. which suggested that leaders' integrity is important and that leaders
Our experimental design allows us to test the following hypotheses: should behave honestly.
Hypothesis 5. The endogenous social corporate governance norm To explore the impact of this norm on leaders' decision making in
impacts on corporate leaders' behavior such that if the norm suggests our experiment, we calculated the total number of times when CEOs
decided to hide the profit and evade taxes across all 16 treatment
variations. In other words, we calculated the number of times when
8
As explained above, we use probabilities of 1/3 and 2/3 to avoid potential CEOs “cheated” or decided to behave dishonestly. Results of these
effects of probability weighting (see Tversky & Kahneman, 1992).
9
In the Poor condition, ¼ of the dishonest CEO payoff is equal to £13/
10
4 = £3.25. For simplicity, we round this amount to £3. df stands for degrees of freedom.

11
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Fig. 1. Experimental treatment variations.


Notes: No norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was not used; Norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was used.

calculations are presented in Fig. 2. As pointed out earlier, in our ex- Fig. 2 shows that in variations with the norm-enhancing demand
periment, “cheating” refers to the decision to hide part of a CEO's payoff effect cheating is a lot less frequent than in variations without the norm-
and evade taxes, which could be observed in all treatment variations. enhancing demand effect. Specifically, in variations without the norm-
Decisions to resort to bribery are considered separately for variations enhancing demand effect, 95 out of 288 decisions (33%) were dis-
where the government integrity is set to be low (Corrupt government honest, whereas in variations with the norm-enhancing demand effect,
conditions). only 56 out of 288 decisions (19%) were dishonest. The difference
As all participants decided to invest in a risky business activity ra- between these two conditions is highly statistically significant (Fisher's
ther than share the £9 equally among all group members, when we exact test p = 0.001).
asked them to make decisions as if they were CEOs using the strategy Government integrity is also a significant determinant of leaders'
method, we had 36 observations in each experimental variation. Each decision making. Specifically, in variations with a Transparent gov-
bar in Fig. 2 presents the frequency of cheating (number of times when ernment, 34 of 288 (12%) of decisions are dishonest, while in variations
CEOs decided to cheat relative to the total number of decisions made) in with a Corrupt government, 117 of 288 (41%) of decisions are dis-
a particular variation of the experiment. honest. The difference between decisions made in Transparent condi-
According to Fig. 2, the corporate governance norm is correlated tions and those made in Corrupt conditions is highly statistically sig-
with leaders' propensity to behave honestly. In all variations with the nificant (Fisher's exact test p = 0.001).
norm-enhancing demand effect, the norm was “positive” in the sense In our experiment, CEOs tend to cheat more in Low enforcement
that the overwhelming majority of participants believed that the in- (105 of 288 cases, 36%) than in High enforcement variations (46 of 288
tegrity of CEOs' was important and that CEOs should behave honestly. cases, 16%). This difference is highly statistically significant (Fisher's
We, therefore, did not have an opportunity to test the reverse norm. exact test p = 0.001). They also cheat more in variations with Rich (96

12
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Rich Corrupt Rich Transparent Poor Corrupt Poor Transparent

0.83

0.58

0.53
0.44

0.33
0.25

0.22

0.22
0.17
0.14

0.11

0.11
0.08

0.08
0.06

0.03
LOW ENFORCEMENT HIGH ENFORCEMENT LOW ENFORCEMENT HIGH ENFORCEMENT
NO NORM NORM

Fig. 2. Experimental Summary statistics: cheating frequency by treatment variation.


Notes: Cheating frequency is shown on the vertical axis.
No norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was not used;
Norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was used.

of 288 cases, 33%) rather than Poor (55 of 288 cases, 19%) incentive 25%) and with the norm-enhancing demand effect (6 cheating cases,
conditions (Fisher's exact test p = 0.001). 17%) the difference in CEO behavior is not statistically significant
At first sight, it may seem that Hypotheses 5–8 are confirmed, (Fisher's exact test = 0.280). In Rich, Transparent government, High
however, the picture is different when comparisons of individual var- enforcement variation without the norm-enhancing demand effect,
iations are made. We first consider experimental variations where all CEOs tend to cheat exactly the same number of times (4 cases, 11%) as
treatment variables, apart from the norm, are held the same. Specifi- in Rich, Transparent government, High enforcement variation with the
cally, in the Rich, Corrupt government, Low enforcement conditions, norm-enhancing demand effect (4 cases, 11%). Similarly, in Poor,
the variation with norm has a count of 30 (83%) dishonest decisions, Transparent government, Low enforcement variations without (5 cases,
whereas in the variation without the norm the count is 19 (53%). This 14%) and with (3 cases, 8%) the norm-enhancing demand effect the
difference is significant according to the Fisher's exact test (p = 0.005). frequency of cheating is very similar (Fisher's exact test = 0.36). We
Similar results are observed for Rich, Corrupt government, High en- obtain the same result in Poor, Transparent government, High en-
forcement conditions, where the cheating count is 16 (44%) for “No forcement variations without (2 cases, 5%) and with (1 case, 3%) the
norm” variation and 8 (22%) for the “With Norm” variation (Fisher's norm-enhancing demand effect (Fisher's exact test, p = 0.500).
exact test, p = 0.040). This result is also observed in variations with Therefore, Hypothesis 5 is only partially confirmed as social norm
Poor, Corrupt government conditions. Specifically, cheating is more about corporate governance is an important determinant of leaders'
prevalent in Poor, Corrupt government, Low enforcement variation decisions only in variations with a Corrupt government condition (in
without the norm-enhancing demand effect (21 cases of cheating, variations with the norm-enhancing demand effect cheating frequency
58%), than in Poor, Corrupt government, Low enforcement variation is lower than that in variations without the norm-enhancing demand
with the norm-enhancing demand effect (12 cases of cheating, 33%). effect), whereas in variations with a Transparent government condition
This difference is statistically significant (Fisher's exact test, p = 0.029). the level of cheating is low in all variations and the impact of the norm-
In the variation with Poor, Corrupt government, High enforcement and enhancing demand effect is not statistically significant.
without the norm-enhancing demand effect, CEOs cheated 8 times Similar results are obtained for Low and High enforcement condi-
(22%); whereas in the variation with Poor, Corrupt government, High tions. When government integrity is low (Corrupt government),
enforcement and the norm-enhancing demand effect, CEOs cheated cheating is observed more frequently in the Low enforcement condition
only 3 times (8%). This difference is marginally statistically sig- rather than High enforcement condition. Yet, when the government is
nificant11 (Fisher's exact test, p = 0.094). Transparent, the level of cheating is low in all variations. Specifically,
While the difference between “No norm” and “With norm” condi- in Rich, No norm variations and when the government is Corrupt, High
tions is statistically significant in all treatment variations with a Corrupt enforcement (30 cases, 83%) is associated with lower frequency of
government, when we consider variations with a Transparent govern- cheating than Low enforcement (16 cases, 44%). Similarly, in Rich,
ment, we do not observe results that are statistically significant. With norm variations when the government is Corrupt, High enforce-
Specifically, in Rich, Transparent government, Low enforcement var- ment (8 cases, 22%) is associated with lower frequency of cheating than
iations without the norm-enhancing demand effect (9 cheating cases, Low enforcement (19 cases, 53%). Results of Fisher's exact test show
high statistical significance in variations without (p = 0.001) and with
(p = 0.007) the norm-enhancing demand effect. In Poor, Corrupt, No
11
It is significant at 10% rather than 5% level. norm variations, CEOs cheat less in High enforcement (8 cases, 22%)

13
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 4
Mean values and correlation matrix for experimental variables presented in Tables 5a–5c.
Mean SD Norm Enforcement Rich-Poor Corruption Gender Age Native speaker Experience Major

Norm 0.50 0.50 1


Enforcement 0.50 0.50 0 1
Rich-Poor 0.50 0.50 0 0 1
Corruption 0.50 0.50 0 0 0 1
Gender 0.47 0.50 −0.02 0.00 0.00 −0.04 1
Age 21.04 1.07 0.10 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.05 1
Native speaker 0.54 0.50 0.02 −0.00 −0.04 0.03 −0.01 −0.07 1
Income 1.53 1.42 0.06 −0.08 0.01 0.09⁎ −0.06 0.03 −0.02 1
Experience 0.80 0.71 −0.04 0.01 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.00 −0.04 1
Major 0.54 0.50 −0.03 −0.03 0.02 −0.00 −0.00 0.04 0.04 0.00 −0.03

Notes: Norm (Norm = 1; No norm = 0); Enforcement (High = 1, Low = 0); Rich-Poor (Rich = 1, Poor = 0); Corruption (Corrupt state = 1; Transparent state = 0);
Gender (Female = 1; Male = 0); Age (age in years); Native speaker dummy (1 = native speaker of English, 0 = otherwise); Income (the higher, the more the annual
income is); Experience (the higher the more experience participants have in taking part in experiments); Major (Economics or Business = 1, Other = 0).

Significant at 0.05 level.

variation compared to the Low enforcement (21 cases, 58%) variation that government integrity is the most important determinant of the
(Fisher's exact test = 0.002). Similarly, in Poor, Corrupt, With norm propensity to cheat among CEOs in our experiment.
variations, CEOs cheat less in High enforcement (3 cases, 8%) variation Recall that in 8 out of 16 variations, government integrity is low
than in the Low enforcement (12 cases, 33%) variation (Fisher's exact (Corrupt condition) and CEOs may avoid checks by paying a bribe.
test, p = 0.009). However, when the state is Transparent, differences Table 6 provides summary statistics on the frequency of bribes in each
between Low and High enforcement are not statistically significant. In variation with a Corrupt government condition. Table 6 shows that the
these conditions, CEOs in Rich, No Norm variations resort to cheating effect of the corporate governance norm goes in the same direction for
less in High enforcement (4 cases, 11%) compared to Low enforcement the effect for bribing decisions and for cheating decisions. Specifically,
(9 cases, 25%) variations. However, this difference is not statistically in the No Norm variations, overall, CEOs resort to bribing in 50 out of
significant (Fisher's exact test p = 0.110). A similar result is obtained 75 cases, whereas in Norm variations they use bribing in 26 out of 42
for the variations With Norm where the frequency of cheating is 17% (6 cases.
cases) in the Low enforcement condition and 11% (4 cases) in the High We conducted a clustered12 probit regression, with bribery as a
enforcement condition (Fisher's exact test p = 0.37). In variations with dependent variable and treatment variables (corporate governance
Transparent government, No norm, Poor variations, CEOs cheat in 5 norm, enforcement mechanism, and Rich-Poor revenue size). Even
(14%) and 2 (5%) cases in Low and High enforcement, respectively though the sample size for bribing decisions is relatively small (there
(Fisher's exact test p = 0.21). In variations with a Transparent gov- are 117 observations from the Corrupt government variations when
ernment, With norm, Poor variations, CEOs cheat in 3 (8%) and 1 (3%) CEOs cheated and, therefore, had an opportunity to resort to bribing),
cases in Low and High enforcement, respectively (Fisher's exact test we found that the only significant treatment variable is Rich-Poor
p = 0.31). Therefore, Hypothesis 7 is only partially confirmed as the condition. Specifically, bribery was more common in the Rich rather
enforcement mechanism matters only in variations with a Corrupt than in the Poor condition (coefficient β = 0.33; robust SE = 0.17, z
government. statistic = 1.95, and p = 0.051). Other treatment variables are not
Overall, our findings suggest that government integrity is a very statistically significant for bribing decisions.
important determinant of CEO decisions. The effects associated with Additionally, we also analyzed text data from question (3) about the
corporate governance norms and enforcement mechanisms are a lot desirable characteristics of the CEO in order to better understand the
stronger in variations with a Corrupt government compared to one with corporate governance norm. The analysis of textual information pro-
a Transparent government. vided by the participants reveals that credible, sincere, and truthful are
Table 4 provides correlation analysis and Tables 5a–5c reports a among the most common characteristics of a “good” CEO as described
series of comparisons between variations with a Corrupt and a Trans- by the experimental participants. Fig. 3 presents the word cloud ana-
parent government. Interestingly, in all comparisons, with the only lysis mapping characteristics which were mentioned twice or more by
exception of high enforcement variations with the norm-enhancing participants. The larger the font of the trait, the more it was mentioned
demand effect (Fisher exact test probabilities for all comparisons by participants. Overall, Fig. 3 shows that characteristics associated
are > 0.1), cheating is more frequent in a Corrupt government condi- with integrity are very common. Specifically, participants mentioned
tion than in a Transparent government condition (Fisher exact test “credible” 53 times (most frequent), sincere – 41 times, reliable – 30
probabilities for all comparisons are lower than 0.05). Fig. 2 also shows times, and truthful – 25 times.
that the lowest frequency of cheating is associated with a Transparent
government, High enforcement variation with the norm-enhancing
demand effect. The highest level of cheating is associated with No Discussion of laboratory results
norm, Corrupt government, Low enforcement variation.
We also conduct a series of OLS and probit regressions (unclustered Our experimental results confirm the link between corporate gov-
as well as clustered by experimental variation). Results of these re- ernance, decision making by leaders and government integrity. In fact,
gressions are reported in Tables 5a–5c. Tables 5a–5c show that the results from a series of Fisher's exact tests suggest that government
norm-enhancing demand effect and high enforcement are associated integrity is a better determinant of how leaders make decisions and
with lower cheating propensity, whereas low government integrity choices than corporate governance norms and enforcement mechan-
(Corrupt government) as well as high business profit (Rich condition) isms. Specifically, making social norms more transparent, through
are associated with a high frequency of cheating. None of the personal creating a demand effect, potentially leads to higher corporate
characteristics have a significant effect on CEOs decisions. Importantly,
the regression coefficients for government integrity are higher than the 12
Observations were clustered by experimental treatment variation (8 var-
regression coefficients for any other treatment variables, confirming iations where Corrupt government condition was implemented).

14
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 5a
Results of the OLS and probit regressions using all experimental data.
Dependent variable is “Cheating” (1 = decision to hide profit by the CEO; 0 - otherwise).
Independent variable OLS Probit

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3


Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust
SE) SE)

Norm (Norm = 1; No norm = 0) −0.14⁎⁎⁎ −0.13⁎⁎⁎ −0.13⁎⁎⁎ −0.50⁎⁎⁎ −0.50⁎⁎⁎ −0.50⁎⁎⁎


(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.13) (0.13) (0.09)
Enforcement (High = 1, Low = 0) −0.20⁎⁎⁎ −0.20⁎⁎⁎ −0.20⁎⁎⁎ −0.76⁎⁎⁎ −0.76⁎⁎⁎ −0.76⁎⁎⁎
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.13) (0.13) (0.08)
Rich-Poor (Rich = 1, Poor = 0) 0.14⁎⁎⁎ 0.14⁎⁎⁎ 0.14⁎⁎⁎ 0.55⁎⁎⁎ 0.56⁎⁎⁎ 0.56⁎⁎⁎
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.13) (0.13) (0.08)
Corruption (Corrupt state = 1; Transparent state = 0) 0.29⁎⁎⁎ 0.29⁎⁎⁎ 0.29⁎⁎⁎ 1.05⁎⁎⁎ 1.06⁎⁎⁎ 1.06⁎⁎⁎
(0.03) (0.03) (0.04) (0.13) (0.13) (0.10)
Gender (Female = 1; Male = 0) – −0.04 −0.04 – −0.12 −0.12
(0.03) (0.04) (0.13) (0.15)
Age (age in years) – −0.02 −0.02 – −0.11 −0.11
(0.02) (0.01) (0.06) (0.05)
Native speaker dummy (1 = native speaker of English, – 0.02 0.02 – 0.09 0.09
0 = otherwise) (0.03) (0.03) (0.13) (0.14)
Income (the higher, the more the annual income is) – −0.00 −0.00 – 0.00 0.00
(0.01) (0.01) (0.04) (0.05)
Experience (the higher the more experience participants – 0.01 0.01 – 0.01 0.01
have in taking part in experiments) (0.02) (0.02) (0.09) (0.09)
Major (Economics or Business = 1, Other = 0) – 0.03 0.03 – 0.12 0.12
(0.03) (0.03) (0.13) (0.13)
Clustered by – – 32 experimental – – 32 experimental
sessions sessions
Constant 0.22 ⁎⁎⁎
0.69 0.69 −0.96⁎⁎⁎
1.15 1.15
(0.04) (0.33) (0.30) (0.14) (1.21) (1.11)
Number of observations 576 576 576 576 576 576
R2 for OLS/pseudo R2 for probit 0.21 0.22 0.22 0.20 0.21 0.21

Notes: No norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was not used; Norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was used.
⁎⁎⁎
Significant at 0.001 level.

Table 5b
Results of the OLS and probit regressions using data without the norm-enforcing demand effect.
Dependent variable is “Cheating” (1 = decision to hide profit by the CEO; 0 - otherwise).
Independent variable OLS Probit

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3


Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust
SE) SE)

Enforcement (High = 1, Low = 0) −0.24⁎⁎⁎ −0.24⁎⁎⁎ −0.24⁎⁎⁎ −0.84⁎⁎⁎ −0.84⁎⁎⁎ −0.84⁎⁎⁎


(0.05) (0.05) (0.04) (0.18) (0.18) (0.09)
Rich-Poor (Rich = 1, Poor = 0) 0.16⁎⁎⁎ 0.16⁎⁎⁎ 0.16⁎⁎⁎ 0.57⁎⁎⁎ 0.58⁎⁎⁎ 0.58⁎⁎⁎
(0.05) (0.05) (0.04) (0.17) (0.18) (0.11)
Corruption (Corrupt state = 1; Transparent state = 0) 0.38⁎⁎⁎ 0.38⁎⁎⁎ 0.38⁎⁎⁎ 1.26⁎⁎⁎ 1.28⁎⁎⁎ 1.28⁎⁎⁎
(0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.18) (0.18) (0.12)
Gender (Female = 1; Male = 0) – −0.08 −0.08 – −0.25 −0.25
(0.05) (0.05) (0.17) (0.19)
Age (age in years) – −0.01 −0.01 – −0.05 −0.05
(0.02) (0.02) (0.08) (0.08)
Native speaker dummy (1 = native speaker of English, – 0.06 0.06 – 0.21 0.21
0 = otherwise) (0.04) (0.05) (0.18) (0.19)
Income (the higher, the more the annual income is) – −0.01 −0.01 – −0.01 −0.01
(0.01) (0.01) (0.06) (0.07)
Experience (the higher the more experience participants – 0.01 0.01 – 0.04 0.04
have in taking part in experiments) (0.03) (0.04) (0.12) (0.15)
Major (Economics or Business = 1, Other = 0) – 0.01 0.01 – 0.01 0.01
(0.05) (0.04) (0.18) (0.13)
Clustered by – – 16 experimental – – 16 experimental
sessions sessions
Constant 0.18⁎⁎⁎ 0.37 0.37 −1.07⁎⁎⁎ −0.16 −0.15
(0.05) (0.47) (0.43) (0.18) (1.65) (1.55)
Number of observations 288 288 288 288 288 288
R2 for OLS/pseudo R2 for probit 0.26 0.27 0.27 0.22 0.24 0.24

Notes: In this analysis only data from sessions without the demand effect were used (No norm variations).
⁎⁎⁎
Significant at 0.001 level.

15
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Table 5c
Results of the OLS and probit regressions using data with the norm-enforcing demand effect.
Dependent variable is “Cheating” (1 = decision to hide profit by the CEO; 0 - otherwise).
Independent variable OLS Probit

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 1 Model 2 Model 3


Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (SE) Coefficient (robust
SE) SE)

Enforcement (High = 1, Low = 0) −0.17⁎⁎⁎ −0.16⁎⁎⁎ −0.16⁎⁎⁎ −0.69⁎⁎⁎ −0.70⁎⁎⁎ −0.70⁎⁎⁎


(0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.19) (0.19) (0.09)
Rich-Poor (Rich = 1, Poor = 0) 0.13⁎⁎ 0.12⁎⁎ 0.12⁎⁎ 0.54⁎⁎ 0.56⁎⁎ 0.53⁎⁎⁎
(0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.19) (0.19) (0.10)
Corruption (Corrupt state = 1; Transparent state = 0) 0.19⁎⁎⁎ 0.19⁎⁎⁎ 0.19⁎⁎⁎ 0.80⁎⁎⁎ 0.81⁎⁎⁎ 0.81⁎⁎⁎
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.19) (0.20) (0.15)
Gender (Female = 1; Male = 0) – −0.00 −0.00 – −0.03 −0.03
(0.04) (0.04) (0.19) (0.24)
Age (age in years) – −0.04 −0.04 – −0.17 −0.17
(0.02) (0.02) (0.09) (0.08)
Native speaker dummy (1 = native speaker of English, – 0.00 0.00 – 0.03 0.03
0 = otherwise) (0.04) (0.02) (0.19) (0.20)
Income (the higher, the more the annual income is) – 0.00 −0.01 – 0.03 0.03
(0.02) (0.01) (0.07) (0.06)
Experience (the higher the more experience participants – 0.00 0.00 – −0.02 −0.01
have in taking part in experiments) (0.03) (0.02) (0.14) (0.09)
Major (Economics or Business = 1, Other = 0) – 0.04 0.04 – 0.17 0.17
(0.04) (0.05) (0.19) (0.23)
Clustered by – – 16 experimental – – 16 experimental
sessions sessions
Constant 012⁎⁎ 0.94⁎ 0.94⁎ −1.33⁎⁎⁎ 2.16 2.16
(0.04) (0.46) (0.43) (0.20) (1.85) (1.56)
Number of observations 288 288 288 288 288 288
R2 for OLS/pseudo R2 for probit 0.13 0.14 0.14 0.14 0.16 0.16

Notes: In this analysis only data from sessions with the demand effect were used (Norm variations).
⁎⁎⁎
Significant at 0.001 level.
⁎⁎
Significant at 0.01 level.

Table 6 governance norms may offer a better way to make leaders' decisions
Experimental summary statistics: Bribery frequency in Corrupt condition. more honest.
Rich Poor

No norm Low enforcement 20 of 30 11 of 21


General discussion
(67%) (52%)
High enforcement 12 of 16 7 of 8 A central argument in this study is that leadership is embedded in
(75%) (88%) the context (Johns, 2006). As such leaders' choices and actions are in-
Norm Low enforcement 14 of 19 6 of 12
fluenced and shaped by institutions that define the context (Oc, 2018).
(74%) (50%)
High enforcement 5 of 8 1 of 3 Drawing on the arguments and literatures on leadership and integrity,
(63%) (33%) we thus sought to establish the relationship between government in-
tegrity and the effectiveness of certain corporate governance practices
Notes: Bribery is only possible in the Corrupt condition. across countries. The assumption is that corporate governance practices
No norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was not used; are the result of corporate leaders' choices pursuant of the situational or
Norm = demand effect enhancing endogenous social norm was used.
contextual factors, including the level of corruption in their countries.
Using the two-stage least squares method, a statistical technique
responsibility in a Corrupt government condition, whereas in a
that takes care of endogeneity in econometric models, the field study
Transparent government condition the level of tax evasion is low irre-
provides externally valid evidence that government integrity de-
spective of norm, enforcement strength as well as other contextual
termines the extent to which certain corporate governance practices are
variables (e.g., Rich versus Poor condition in terms of the payoff size).
applied. The experimental study, focusing on the individual leader,
Perhaps the most interesting result of our experiment is the impact
supports the overarching finding in the first study, imposing more
of the social norm of corporate governance in a Corrupt government
structure and providing clarity on the leaders' decision-making me-
condition. This result suggests that making a “positive” social norm
chanisms under conditions of varying, endogenous, and contextual
transparent increases CEO integrity. In other words, a simple reminder
norms. Indeed, results from the experimental study show that CEOs are
about social norms in corrupt environments might make a lot of posi-
more likely to cheat in a corrupt environment than in a transparent one.
tive difference, encouraging more responsible corporate behavior. This
Beyond the use of an appropriate statistical approach in 2SLS,
result is particularly important because, in practice, many states spend
alongside an experimental study, this paper contributes to the literature
large amounts of money on developing anti-corruption measures. These
on contextual leadership, providing better understanding of the link
measures often take the form of either a carrot (e.g., increasing size of
between government integrity and corporate governance practices.
salaries of decision makers in order to discourage tax evasion and
Indeed, by bringing together literatures on government integrity, a
bribery) or a stick (e.g., increasing punishment for those who engage in
domain of political and policy studies, and corporate governance, a
tax evasion and bribery). Our experimental findings show that such
domain of management and accounting and finance, this study provides
carrot-and-stick measures may not help improve leaders' integrity. In
a multidisciplinary view of contextual leadership.
fact, campaigns which communicate positive social corporate
Moreover, findings from this study provide answers to some of the

16
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Fig. 3. A word cloud analysis of the “good” CEO traits.


Notes: most commonly mentioned characteristics of “good” CEO are shown in bolder and larger font.

questions that have dominated the corporate governance literature for higher in countries with low levels of government integrity. In such
some time. For example, some studies have attributed the failure or countries, companies may need to incur more agency costs by ap-
success of corporate leadership to firm and CEO characteristics pointing more independent directors and making use of well-designed
(Hambrick & Mason, 1984) as well as a range of corporate governance managerial incentives that help align the interests of management with
mechanisms, without taking into consideration the effect of govern- those of shareholders (Shleifer & Wolfenzon, 2002).
ment integrity that vary across countries, on corporate leadership. As
such, our study expands understanding of how governments differ and Limitations and the possibility for further research
how they matter in the leadership of firms. Essentially, the study
highlights the effect of corruption on corporate leadership. Notwithstanding the relevance and timeliness of this study, we
In instances where cross-country studies have been carried out, the identify some limitations and suggest avenues for further research.
focus has been on the variety of corporate governance models (Aguilera Although, we believe that we have captured some of the key variables
& Jackson, 2003), with emphasis on the respective effectiveness of such in corporate governance, future studies could test the effect of gov-
models (Hansmann & Kraakman, 2001; Yoshikawa & Rasheed, 2009). ernment integrity on other governance variables such as the use of
In such studies, scholars have often attributed the failure of corporate board committees, independent directors and the emerging theme of
governance systems to the quality of the institutional environment such board diversity. Such studies could use interviews to gather more and
as the country's laws and regulations, without going beyond the level of direct information on corporate leaders' decision-making mechanisms
policy implementation to examine why such institutions are effective in across countries with varying levels of government integrity. Moreover,
some countries and not in others. By arguing for government integrity, studies could focus on the behavior and decision-making mechanisms of
a hypothesis confirmed by our findings from both field and experi- CEOs in several countries with varying approaches on anti-corruption
mental studies, this research provides an important determinant to, and practices. We also acknowledge that the survey items we used for our
indeed a potential element that leads to heterogeneity in, the success of dependent variables were not worded to directly source information on
corporate governance practices across countries. company practices but on national business norms. However, the use of
Indeed, our study, through a combination of field and experimental the laboratory experiment made up for this potential weakness.
studies, not only provides a comprehensive analysis of corporate deci-
sion making observed at the national level, but shows too the behavior Conclusion
of the individual leader under different contextual and norm conditions.
In addition, our study has implications for investors. For example, The present study finds that government integrity has a positive
using knowledge of a country's level of government integrity, minority effect on corporate governance practices and choices made by corporate
investors may be able to determine the probability of exploitation they leaders. Beyond the question of corporate governance choices made by
are likely to suffer from majority shareholders or from self-interested corporate leaders, this study has unveiled what appears to be weak-
executives (Fama & Jensen, 1983). In cases where government integrity nesses on current anti-corruption practices within the business en-
is low, minority investors may have to consider mechanisms that allow vironment. Consequently, two important lessons are discernible from
their voices to be heard either by pooling their resources together, this study. First, from the field study, our findings demonstrate that
engaging more with legal advisors or making use of proxy voting. governments need to get it right first before expecting corporate citi-
Moreover, investors, in general, may need to take more attention on zenry to do the right thing. Second, from the experimental study, it is
how CEOs make decisions and how firms report their financial reports clear that in contexts where government integrity is low, the nature of
in countries that have low levels of government integrity and low levels the problem lies at the heart of what is right, ethical and acceptable, on
of enforcement. the one hand; and what is mandated by the law, on the other. This gap
Finally, the fact that managerial accountability to both shareholders may be bridged by instilling acceptable social norms in corporate lea-
and the board is better in countries with higher levels of government ders.
integrity has implications for corporate governance practice. The logic According to Axelrod (1986), a norm exists in a given social setting
of this observation is that the need for monitoring should, therefore, be to the extent that individuals usually act in a certain way and are often

17
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

punished when seen not to be acting this way. The problem, of course, Routledge.
is that in contexts characterized with high levels of corruption perva- Clemens, M., & Williamson, J. (2000). Where did British foreign capital go? Fundamentals,
failures, and the Lucas paradox: 1870–1913. NBER working paper no. 8028.
siveness (Rodriguez et al., 2005) there may not be norms to talk about Collier, P. (2008). The bottom billion - Why the poorest countries are failing and what can be
as irresponsible actions go unpunished. This raises the question of the done about it. New York: Oxford University Press.
origin of norms or put differently, what is the content of behavior that Coulibaly, S., & Fontagne, L. (2006). South-south trade: Geography matters. Journal of
African Economies, 15(2), 313–341.
might later turn into a norm? Moreover, how can norms be sustained Currie, G., Lockett, A., & Suhomlinova, O. (2009). Leadership and institutional change in
and maintained? An evolutionary approach to norms (Axelrod, 1986) the public sector: The case of secondary schools in England. The Leadership Quarterly,
suggests that norms, that are often a reflection of underlying interests 20, 604–616.
Davis, G. F. (2005). New directions in corporate governance. Annual Review of Sociology,
and resulting political struggles in a society, originate from the domi- 31, 143–162.
nant actors in society who have the power, through punishments, to Davis, L. S., & Abdurazokzoda, F. (2016). Language, culture and institutions: Evidence
promote a certain type of behavior. As such, norms often precede laws from a new linguistic dataset. Journal of Comparative Economics, 44, 541–561.
Devas, N., & Grant, U. (2003). Local government decision-making - Citizen participation
but are then supported, maintained and extended by laws (Miyashita,
and local accountability: Some evidence from Kenya and Uganda. Public
2007). Therefore, to the extent that those with power to change societal Administration and Development, 23, 307–316.
norms do not have the interest or motive to do so, contexts that lack Dharwadkar, R., George, G., & Brandes, P. (2000). Privatization in emerging economies:
government integrity may be difficult to change with the effect that An agency theory perspective. Academy of Management Review, 25, 650–669.
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional iso-
corporate leaders may continue to make bad corporate governance morphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological
choices and decisions. Review, 48, 147–160.
Doidge, C., Karolyi, A. G., & Stulz, R. M. (2004). Why are foreign firms listed in the U.S.
worth more? Journal of Financial Economics, 71, 205–238.
Appendix A. Supplementary data Doidge, C., Karolyi, A. G., & Stulz, R. M. (2007). Why do countries matter so much for
corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 86(1), 1–39.
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https:// Doupnik, T., & Salter, S. (1995). External environment, culture, and accounting practice:
A preliminary test of a general model of international accounting development.
doi.org/10.1016/j.leaqua.2019.07.001. International Journal of Accounting, 30(1), 189–202.
Du, J., Li, W., Lin, B., & Wang, Y. (2018). Government integrity and corporate investment
References efficiency. China Journal of Accounting Research. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cjar.2017.
03.002 (forthcoming).
Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2004). Private benefits of control: An international comparison.
Ashforth, B. E., & Anand, V. (2003). The normalization of corruption. Research in Journal of Finance, 59, 537–600.
Organizational Behavior, 25, 1–52. Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (1997). Africa's growth tragedy: Policies and ethnic divisions,
Aguilera, R. V., & Jackson, G. (2003). The cross-national diversity of corporate govern- The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1203–1250.n.
ance: Dimensions and determinants. Academy of Management Review, 28, 447–465. Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law
Alesina, A., Devleeschauer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). and Economics, 26, 301–325.
Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8(2), 155–194. Fijnaut, C. J. C. F. (2002). Corruption, integrity and law enforcement. In C. J. C. F.
Antonakis, J., Bendahan, S., Jacquart, P., & Lalive, R. (2010). On making causal claims: A Fijnaut, & L. Huberts (Eds.). Corruption, integrity and law enforcement (pp. 3–37). Den
review and recommendations. The Leadership Quarterly, 21(6), 1086–1120. Haag: Kluwer Law International.
Axelrod, R. (1986). An evolutionary approach to norms. The American Political Science Finkelstein, S., & Hambrick, D. (1996). Strategic leadership: Top executives and their effects
Review, 80, 1095–1111. on organizations. St. Paul, Minneapolis: West Publishing Company.
Ayman, R., & Adams, S. (2012). Contingencies, context, situations, and leadership. In D. Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments.
V. Day, & J. Antonakis (Eds.). The nature of leadership (pp. 218–256). Thousand Oaks, Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.
CA: Sage. Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Quercia, S. (2012). The behavioral validity of the strategy
Ball, R., & Shivakumar, L. (2005). Earnings quality in U.K. private firms. Journal of method in public good experiments. Journal of Economic Psychology, 33(4), 897–913.
Accounting and Economics, 39, 83–128. Fredriksson, P. G., Neumayer, E., & Ujhelyi, G. (2007). Kyoto Protocol cooperation: Does
Bamberger, P. (2008). Beyond contextualization: Using context theories to narrow the government corruption facilitate environmental lobbying? Public Choice, 133,
micro-macro gap in management research. Academy of Management Journal, 51, 231–251.
839–846. Fredriksson, P. G., & Svensson, J. (2003). Political instability, corruption and policy
Barro, R. J., & McCleary, R. M. (2003). Religion and economic growth. American formation: The case of environmental policy. Journal of Public Economics, 87(7–8),
Sociological Review, 68, 760–781. 1383–1405.
Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., & Stillman, S. (2011). Using Stata for applied research: Groznik, P. (2003). Immigration and international financial flows. Indiana University working
Reviewing its capabilities. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25(2), 380–394. paper.
Bendahan, S., Zehnder, C., Pralong, F. P., & Antonakis, J. (2015). Leader corruption de- Guillén, M. F., & Capron, L. (2016). State capacity, minority shareholder protections, and
pends on power and testosterone. The Leadership Quarterly, 26(2), 101–122. stock market development. Administrative Science Quarterly, 61(1), 125–160.
Billington, N. (1999). The location of foreign direct investment: An empirical analysis. Hambrick, D. C., & Mason, P. A. (1984). Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection
Applied Economics, 31(1), 65–76. of its top managers. Academy of Management Review, 9, 193–206.
Brown, P. (2011). International Financial Reporting Standards: What are the benefits? Hansmann, H., & Kraakman, R. (2001). The end of history for corporate law. Georgetown
Accounting and Business Research, 41(3), 269–285. Law Journal, 89, 439–468.
Brown, P., Preiato, J., & Tarca, A. (2014). Measuring country differences in enforcement Hedstrom, P., & Swedberg, R. (1998). Social mechanisms. An analytical approach to social
of accounting standards: an audit and enforcement proxy. Journal of Business Finance theory. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ Press.
and Accounting, 41, 1–52. Hedstrom, P., & Ylikoski, P. (2010). Causal mechanisms in the social sciences. Annual
Bullough, A., Kroeck, K. G., Newbury, W., Kundu, S. K., & Lowe, K. B. (2012). Women's Review of Sociology, 36, 49–67.
political leadership participation around the world: An institutional analysis. The Hiller, N. J., & Hambrick, D. C. (2005). Conceptualizing executive hubris: The role of
Leadership Quarterly, 23, 398–411. (hyper) core self-evaluations in strategic decision making. Strategic Management
Burgstahler, D., Hail, L., & Leuz, C. (2006). The importance of reporting incentives: Journal, 26, 297–319.
Earnings management in European private and public firms. The Accounting Review, Hofstede, G. (1983). National cultures in four dimensions: A research-based theory of
81, 983–1016. cultural differences among nations. International Studies of Management and
Campbell, J. L. (2007). Why would corporations behave in socially responsible ways? An Organization, 13, 46–74.
institutional theory of corporate social responsibility. Academy of Management Review, Hogan, R., & Kaiser, R. B. (2005). What we know about leadership. Review of General
29, 345–361. Psychology, 9, 169–180.
Chizema, A. (2008). Institutions and voluntary compliance: The disclosure of individual House, R. J., & Aditya, R. N. (1997). The social scientific study of leadership: Quo vadis?
executive pay in Germany. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 16(4), Journal of Management, 23(3), 409–473.
359–374. The global competitiveness report (2017–2018). The executive opinion survey: The voice
Chizema, A., Kamuriwo, D. S., & Shinozawa, Y. (2015). Women on corporate boards of the business community. http://www3.weforum.org/docs/GCR2017-2018/
around the world: Triggers and barriers. The Leadership Quarterly, 26(6), 1051–1065. 04Backmatter/TheGlobalCompetitivenessReport2017%E2%80%932018AppendixC.
Chizema, A., & Kim, J. (2010). Outside directors on Korean boards: Governance and in- pdf, Accessed date: 10 July 2018.
stitutions. Journal of Management Studies, 47(1), 109–129. Huberts, L., Lasthuizen, K., & Peeters, C. (2006). Measuring corruption: Exploring the
Chizema, A., Liu, X., Lu, J., & Gao, L. (2015). Politically connected directors and top iceberg. In C. Sampford, A. Shacklock, C. Connors, & F. Galtung (Eds.). Measuring
executive compensation in Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 36, 890–906. corruption (pp. 265–293). Hampshire, UK: Ashgate Publishing.
Chizema, A., & Shinozawa, Y. (2012). The ‘company with committees’: Change or con- Ioannou, I., & Serafeim, G. (2012). What drives corporate social performance? The role of
tinuity in Japanese corporate governance. Journal of Management Studies, 49(1), nation-level institutions. Journal of International Business Studies, 43, 834–864.
77–101. Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs
Clarke, T. (2017). International corporate governance: A comparative approach. London: and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

18
A. Chizema and G. Pogrebna The Leadership Quarterly 30 (2019) 101303

Johns, G. (2006). The essential impact of context on organizational behavior. Academy of technology start-up and established firms. Journal of Management, 35(2), 348–368.
Management Review, 31, 386–408. Picur, R. D. (2004). Quality of accounting, earnings opacity and corruption. Review of
Kashima, E. S., & Kashima, Y. (1998). Culture and language: The case of cultural di- Accounting and Finance, 3(1), 103–114.
mensions and personal pronoun use. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 2(9), Porter, L. W., & McLaughlin, G. B. (2006). Leadership and the organizational context: Like
461–487. the weather. The Leadership Quarterly, 17, 559–573.
Keay, A., & Loughrey, J. (2015). The framework for board accountability in corporate Riahi-Belkaoui, A. (2004). Effects of corruption on earnings opacity internationally.
governance. Legal Studies: The Journal of The Society and Legal Scholars, 35(2), Advances in International Accounting, 17, 73–84.
252–279. Rodriguez, P., Uhlenbruck, K., & Eden, L. (2005). Government corruption and the entry
Keig, D. L., Brouthers, L. E., & Marshall, V. B. (2015). Formal and informal corruption strategies of multinationals. Academy of Management Review, 30, 383–396.
environments and MNE social irresponsibility. Journal of Management Studies, 52, Rohr, J. (1989). Ethics for bureaucrats: An essay on law and values (2nd ed.). New York:
89–115. Marcel Dekker.
Khatri, N., Tsang, E., & Begley, T. (2006). Cronyism: A cross-cultural analysis. Journal of Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975). The economics of corruption. Journal of Public Economics, 4,
International Business Studies, 37, 61–81. 187–203.
Kim, C.-U. (2006). Immigration, FDI, and international trade. University of Oregon working Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2008). What is quality of government? A theory of impartial
paper. government institutions. Governance: An International Journal of Policy,
Kugler, M., & Rapoport, H. (2005). Skilled emigration, business networks, and foreign direct Administration, and Institutions, 21(2), 165–190.
investment. CESifo working paper no. 1455. Rousseau, D. M., & Fried, Y. (2001). Location, location, location: Contextualizing orga-
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Government ownership of banks. nizational research. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 22, 1–13.
Journal of Finance, 57, 265–301. Schleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 599–617
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. (August).
Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155 (b). Scott, W. R. (2001). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of gov- Scott, W. R. (2008). Institutions and organizations: Ideas and interests (3rd ed.). Thousand
ernment. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15, 222–279. Oaks, CA: Sage.
Larcker, D. F., & Rusticus, T. O. (2010). On the use of instrumental variables in accounting Shleifer, A., & Wolfenzon, D. (2002). Investor protection and equity markets. Journal of
research. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 49, 186–205. Financial Economics, 66(1), 3–27.
LeBreton, J. M., & Senter, J. L. (2008). Answers to 20 questions about interrater reliability Simons, T. L. (2002). Behavioral integrity: The perceived alignment between managers'
and interrater agreement. Organizational Research Methods, 11, 815–852. words and deeds as a research focus. Organization Science, 13, 18–35.
Licht, A. N., Goldschmidt, C., & Schwartz, S. H. (2005). Culture, law, and corporate Steffens, N. K., Haslam, S. A., & Peters, K.. Identity economics meets identity leadership:
governance. International Review of Law and Economics, 25, 229–255. Exploring the consequences of elevated CEO pay. (2018). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Limao, N., & Venables, A. J. (2001). Infrastructure, geographical disadvantage, transport leaqua.2018.10.001 in press.
costs, and trade. The World Bank Economic Review, 15(3), 451–479. Stoker, J. I., Garretsen, H., & Soudis, D. (2019). Tightening the leash after a threat: A
Lord, R. G., Day, D. V., Zaccaro, S. J., Avolio, B. J., & Eagly, A. H. (2017). Leadership in multi-level event study on leadership behavior following the financial crisis. The
applied psychology: Three waves of theory and research. Journal of Applied Leadership Quarterly, 30(2), 199–214.
Psychology, 102(3), 434–451. Stulz, R. M. (2005). The limits of financial globalization. Journal of Finance, 60(4),
Lourenço, I. C., Rathke, A., Santana, V., & Branco, M. C. (2018). Corruption and earnings 1595–1638.
management in developed and emerging countries. Corporate Governance, 18(1), Suchman, M. C. (1995). Managing legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches.
35–51. Academy of Management Review, 20, 571–610.
Lucas RE Jr (1990) Why doesn't capital flow from rich to poor countries. The American Tan, J. (2009). Institutional structure and firm social performance in transitional
Economic Review 80(2): 92–96. economies: Evidence of multinational corporations in China. Journal of Business
Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), Ethics, 86, 171–189.
681–712. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative re-
Mazzi, F., Slack, R., & Tsalavoutas, I. (2018). The effect of corruption and culture on presentation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297–323.
mandatory disclosure compliance: Goodwill reporting in Europe. Journal of Ufere, N., Perelli, S., Boland, R., & Carlsson, B. (2012). Merchants of corruption: How
International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 31, 52–73. entrepreneurs manufacture and supply bribes. World Development, (12), 2440–2453.
Minichilli, A., Zattoni, A., Nielsen, S., & Huse, M. (2012). Board task performance: An Uhlenbruck, K., Rodriguez, P., Doh, J., & Eden, L. (2006). The impact of corruption on
exploration of micro- and macro-level determinants of board effectiveness. Journal of entry strategy: Evidence from telecommunication projects in emerging economies.
Organizational Behavior, 33(2), 193–215. Organization Science, 17, 402–414.
Mitton, T. (2002). A cross-firm analysis of the impact of corporate governance on the East UNCTAD (2017). FDI Inflows Database. http://unctad.org/en/Pages/DIAE/FDI
Asian financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics, 64, 215–241. %20Statistics/Interactive-database.aspx, Accessed date: 11 November 2017.
Miyashita, A. (2007). Where do norms come from? Foundations of Japan's postwar pa- Van de Walle, S. (2006). The state of the world's bureaucracies. Journal of Comparative
cifism. International Relations of The Asia-Pacific, 7, 99–120. Policy Analysis, 8, 437–448.
Montefiore, A. (1999). Integrity: A philosopher's introduction. In A. Montefiore, & D. Welsh, D. T., & Ordonez, L. D. (2014). Conscience without cognition: The effects of
Vines (Eds.). Integrity in the public and private domains (pp. 1). London: Routledge. subconscious priming on ethical behavior. Academy of Management Journal, 57(3),
Ng, D. (2006). The impact of corruption on financial markets. Managerial Finance, 32, 723–742.
822–832. Wooldridge, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Massachusetts:
Nobes, C. W. (1998). Towards a general model of the reasons for international differences MIT Press.
in financial reporting. Abacus, 34(2), 162–187. World Bank (2016). Market capitalisation of listed domestic companies (% of GDP). ac-
North, D. C. (1990). Institution, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: cessed at: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/CM.MKT.LCAP.GD.ZS.
Cambridge University Press. World Economic Forum. Global Competitive Index. (2017). Accessed at http://reports.
Nwabuzor, A. (2005). Corruption and development: New initiatives in economic openness weforum.org/global-competitiveness-index-2016-2017/ (22nd Dec 2017).
and strengthened rule of law. Journal of Business Ethics, 59, 121–138. Yang, C. H., & Huang, Y. J. (1990). Do intellectual property rights matter to Taiwan's
Oc, B. (2018). Contextual leadership: A systematic review of how contextual factors shape exports? A dynamic panel approach. Pacific Economic Review, 14, 555–578.
leadership and its outcomes. The Leadership Quarterly, 29(1), 218–235. Yoshikawa, T., & Rasheed, A. A. (2009). Convergence of corporate governance: Critical
OECD (2013). Recommendation of the Council on Public Integrity. Paris: OECD. review and future directions. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(3),
O'Reilly, C. A., III, Doerr, B., & Chatman, J. A. (2018). “See You in Court”: How CEO 388–404.
narcissism increases firms' vulnerability to lawsuits. The Leadership Quarterly, 29(3), Young, M. N., Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G. D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). Corporate
365–378. governance in emerging economies: A review of the principal–principal perspective.
Osborn, R. N., Hunt, J. G., & Jauch, L. R. (2002). Toward a contextual theory of lea- Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), 196–220.
dership. The Leadership Quarterly, 13, 797–837. Zingales, L. (1994). The value of the voting right: A study of the Milan stock exchange
Pellegrini, L., & Gerlagh, R. (2004). Corruptions effect on growth and its transmission experience. The Review of Financial Studies, 7, 125–148.
channels. KYKLOS, 429–456. Zizzo, D. J. (2010). Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments. Experimental
Peterson, S. J., Walumbwa, F. O., Byron, K., & Myrowitz, J. (2009). CEO positive psy- Economics, 13(1), 75–98.
chological traits, transformational leadership, and firm performance in high-

19

You might also like