You are on page 1of 14

Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars

ISSN: 0007-4810 (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rcra19

From peasants to petty commodity production in


Southeast Asia

Joel S. Kahn

To cite this article: Joel S. Kahn (1982) From peasants to petty commodity
production in Southeast Asia, Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars, 14:1, 3-15, DOI:
10.1080/14672715.1982.10412633

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/14672715.1982.10412633

Published online: 05 Jul 2019.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 505

View related articles

Citing articles: 1 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rcra20
From Peasants to Petty Commodity Production
in Southeast Asia

by Joel S. Kahn
This paper represents a preliminary attempt to deal way, of the "commoditization" of production. It is argued
with transformations of the peasant economy in specific that one of the most significant changes in the peasant
regions of Southeast Asia. I shall argue that the change is economy has been not so much in the productive organiza-
not simply the result of the incorporation of peasants within tion of enterprises themselves, as in the ways in which the
a world economy, but one that considerably predates the productive cycle is renewed. This change can best be seen
modern period. Nor can the change be viewed as part of a as the integration of local productive systems within circuits
transition to capitalist forms of production. On the con- of reproduction organized acording to the principles of
trary the forms of production which have emerged differ in commodity circulation.
significant ways from those that developed in the capitalist The market integration of peasant production in the
core as merchant capital and feudal landed property gave region is not a recent phenomenon~in some regions this
way to industrial capital and capitalist relations of produc- can be traced back certainly to the earliest period of Euro-
tion. Accordingly, it would be unwise to assume that the pean mercantile domination, and most probably much ear-
existing situation represents some step in a necessary trans- lier. Even involvement in world commodity markets con-
ition which will mirror changes that took place in Britain in siderably pre-dates the coming of Portuguese and other
the 18th and 19th centuries. 1 As a consequence there is a European merchants to those areas that were at one time
need for forms of economic and political analysis not easily involved in the trade which linked the Persian Gulf and
derivable from Marxist theories of the capitalist mode of Canton. It can, however, be argued that the consequences
production, or from theories 2 of the "articulation" of of this kind of market penetration, stimulated by merchant
modes of production in which the modes subordinated to capital and the drive to monopoly, were rather different for
capital are deduced directly from the functional prerequis- both the short and long-term dynamics of peasant enter-
ites of capitalism conceived as an abstract, global structure. prises in the region than the situation described here. For in
The process of change that I am concerned with is the earlier periods it seems likely that while peasants pro-
manifest in the increasing extent to which small-scale peas- duced for regional and even overseas markets, participa-
ant enterprises have become dependent on the world tion in these commodity circuits was not dependent upon
market for their reproduction. Looked at from the point of markets (whether regional or international) in land, labor
view of the peasant enterprise itself, the change can be and/or means of production. Instead such fators were al-
viewed as a process of market penetration or, put another located largely through non-market mechanisms. Access to
land, for example, was obtained through membership in
kin groups, local communities and/or guaranteed through
households, communal labor exchanges and through the
institutions of marriage.
1. Thus, for example, the line of the Latin American Communist Parties The significant transformation, then, has not been the
so effectively criticized by Frank among others that Latin America must change from a "natural" subsistence economy to an econ-
first pass through a capitalist stage before becoming socialistmthe argu-
ment that you first need a bourgeois revolution before a socialist one is of omy dominated by the market principle, but rather the
course not restricted to Latin Americamis premised on a unilinear view of change is marked by market penetration of the reproduc-
economic development of the sort I mean when I talk about changes tive circuits of peasant enterprises. Before examining the
mirroring those that took place in Britain. However, such a teleological causes and implications of this transformation, I shall illus-
notion of evolution could also be attributed to Frank and other of the
trate the change by means of examples from my own re-
dependency writers, a point made in a slightly different way by Taylor
recently. J. Taylor, From Modernization to Modes of Production (Basing- search. 3 The first example comes from the period of Dutch
stoke: MacMillan, 1979).
2. Such a functionalist view is, I would argue, implicit in a wide range of
recent theories. See for example the following: E. Laclau, "Feudalism and
Capitalism in Latin America," New Left Review, No. 67, 1971; C. Meillas-
soux, Femmes, greniers et capitaux, Paris: Maspero, 1975; and K. Ver- 3. Research in West Sumatra, Indonesia was carried out from 1970 to
gopoulos, "Capitalism and Peasant Productivity, "The Journal of Peasant 1972, under the auspices of the Indonesian Academy of Sciences and with
Studies, Vol. 5, No. 4, 1974. a grant from the London-Cornell Project for Southeast Asian Studies.
~ , , 3 ~ 0 miles
,,o
"., 6 " SbOkm

5*N ~ o ..~" _ ,

. 0 ~ "" 'g I
"~',,~ :" , . ,.~ , , t0 ~ . ~ ~ / ~ 9
% _* " ~ " N ~ ~ . ~ / / ~ j *,~ KALIMANTAN ,, . Sl0,/

O* ~,_!~W'E~TI"~:RIAU~ =_
d:IJ,,SUMATR~ . . . . . . .% t.~'~ ,,
Pontianak~LKALIM/V/~I~AN. ~ ' ' ' , -
'f" ,.._/ \
(--,
( ,
/
t I ...... ~
~ , ."
~:~_,
... 11 "~ -
(~\Padang j DJAMBI \ " ' ' ' " ~,~ A, ~I:.N I HAL t ~ ' b. ~ ~ I" == 9 o, Ir u x
ko- '~- i . . . . . ...o,_.}< ~,--~ ""." (,,kALIMANTAN ~ . . g '/" : /~,~.,-~.,,.~-I" ~ r ~ l ~ c2) ~..,.aX~, I~ ~_...,.
-~ L-.~ . . . .=" r - - ~ . ~ L _,.9 ~ --,,,i t ,-,.,.,,,
o u u /....
n !, ~ u t . a" w~,~
~ ; V---~ mALUKu " ~ .' ~ ~ "--,~

}' "N~ SOUTH f " Ba~masin~L~ : %SOUTHk Q~tE~.~~",~"n-(S"b/ect'~ .


- k,~SUMATRA I t ! 9 , "~o A m b o n "~*o . ~ x--L dispute!

~ - T , ' T ~ ~ , _ , JAVA 7 ~ ~ : "~' d~ ;


" - ~ . ~ n d u n g ~ ,'~ WEST NUSA ~ EAST NUSA .... ~_ ~;
WEST ~ ~ S u r a E ~ g ~ t TENGG.ARA ; T ENG G ~ A o r ff ) ,."

"BALI~ .," /'mcd/~----#""

,0~ I l I
First-level administrative regions of Indonesia, 1960. Map provided by Joel S. Kahn.

m e r c a n t i l e domination in the East Indies, and the second changing forms of surplus extraction, and indeed the shift
a n d third from field research carried out in the 1970s. f r o m C o m p a n y to State control, there is an overall con-
tinuity in the region from the early seventeenth to the late
Coffee Cultivation in 19th Century Sumatra n i n e t e e n t h century. T h r o u g h o u t this period surplus was
e x t r a c t e d from Indonesian peasants through the mecha-
D i r e c t E u r o p e a n involvement in the Indonesian econ-
nisms of m e r c h a n t capital, with any changes due largely to
o m y can be traced to early Portuguese attempts to m a k e
a t t e m p t s by m e r c h a n t capital to overcome its own con-
profits on the Asian spice and p e p p e r trade. Here, how-
t r a d i c t o r y tendencies. T h e apparently isolated and tradi-
ever, I shall examine the long term effects of Dutch mer-
tional societies of nineteenth century Indonesia are explic-
c h a n t m o n o p o l y in West Sumatra.
able only in terms of this long-term historical process,
If any overall generalization could be m a d e about
r a t h e r than as the result of cultural lag. s These processes
social and economic change for this period it would concern
e n c o u r a g e d the emergence of peasant enterprises that pro-
the continual changes in the nature of colonial accumula-
d u c e d crops such as coffee and sugar for world markets but
tion from a system based at the outset on external trade
which w e r e nonetheless r e p r o d u c e d through local commu-
m o n o p o l y to one based in the nineteenth century on forced
nal a n d kinship s t r u c t u r e s - - t h e m s e l v e s preserved or even
labor and forced deliveries. 4 In spite, however, of the
c r e a t e d by C o m p a n y and colonial rule.
It is clear that in the earliest years after its formation in
1602 the U n i t e d Netherlands East India C o m p a n y
(V. O . C . ) had an interest only in mercantile exploitation of
an a l r e a d y existing commodity circuit. Neither E u r o p e a n
Research in Malaysia was carried out from 1975 to 1976, partially funded
by the British S.S.R.C. and jointly sponsored by the Department of
National Unity and Dr. Kahar Bador of the Universiti Malaya. I have
discussed many of the ideas in this paper with a number of colleagues and
have benefited from their comments, criticisms and insights into the
nature of small production. I would particularly like to thank John Gled- H. Kroeskamp, De Westkust en Minangkabau (Utrecht: Fa. Schotanusen
hill, Steve Nugent, Nukhet Sirman, Ken Young and Maila Stivens in this Jens, 1931); W.J.A. de Leeuw, Het Painansch Contract (Amsterdam: H.J.
regard. Paris, 1926); B.H. Parels, "Bevolkings Kofficultuur," in C.J. van Hall and
4. This discussion is not intended as an original contribution to Indone- C. van de Koppel (eds.), De Landbouw in de Indische Archipel (The Hague:
sian history. Rather it is based on an interpretation based on existing W. van Hoeve, 1944); D. Pies, De Koffij-Cultuur op Sumatra's Westkust
published sources. Of particular importance for this analysisor the follow- (Batavia: Ogilvie and Company, 1978); B. Schrieke, Indonesian Sociologi-
ing: J. Furnivall, Netherland India: A Study of Plural Economy (Cambridge: cal Studies (The Hague: W. van Hoeve, 1955); and S.P. Sen, "Indian
Cambridge Univ. Press, 1949); J.S. Bastin, The British in West Sumatra, Textiles in the Sout-East Asian Trade in the Seventeenth Century,"
1685-1825 (Kuala Lumpur: Univ. of Malaya Press, 1965); C. Dobbins, Journal of Southeast Asian History, Vol. 1, No. 2, 1962.
"The Exercise of Authority in Minangkabau in the Late 18th Century," in 5. Swift's explanation on the Minangkabau economy refers to cultural
A. Reid and L. Castles (eds.), Pre-Colonial State Systems in Southeast Asia obstacles to cooperation and obviously implies a "cultural-lag" type exp-
(Kuala Lumpur: Monographs of the Malaysian Branch of the Royal lanation. M. Swift, "Minangkabau and Modernization," in I. Hogbin and
Asiatic Society, 1975), No. 6, and "Economic Change in Managkabau as a L.Hiatt, eds., Anthropology in Oceania (Sydney: Angus and Robertson,
Factor in the Rise of the Padri Movement," Indonesia, Vol. 7, No.2, 1977; 1971).
colonization and territorial control, nor the sale of Dutch
manufactures held any interest for merchants whose sole
9.- _ ....
aim was to obtain something for nothing in the Asia trade.
Fulfilling this aim meant obtaining a monopoly on the trade
in certain indigenously-produced commodities such as ii
I
spices, pepper, gold and cloth. ,"" Ulung

Perhaps the main initial attraction in western Sumatra


was the gold mined under royal monopoly in the Minang- Lubuk Slkapmg i
x
Bonlol \
kabau highlands, and, in the sixteenth century, traded by Sasak \
\
the Acehnese, who had taken control of the western coastal Y~Payakumbuh
%
%
districts. After an extended period of struggle against the 9 Sungat Puar %
%
Acehnese, other Asian traders, and French and British Batu Sangkar \

merchants, the V.O.C. was able to take the lion's share of Par~ama~
\
the trade, and to enforce their monopoly through a series of unlung

"contracts" made by representatives of the V.O.C. with


PADANG
local rulers. Teluk B3yur
The V.O.C. ideal was to obtain both pepper and gold /
/
in exchange for Indian cloth, already in demand through- Paman /s
/
out the region, although clearly cash was also used. Ac- I N D / A N
/
/

cumulation depended on fixed rates of exchange for pepper /


/
/

and gold being written into the contracts and backed up, 0 C E A N
" • B a~lSelasa
a / /

when necessary, by naval and military force. Profits could \ ~'


be realized in different ways, but a favored system was to Muara SakaJ
Indrapura I

reproduce the commodity circuit in the India-Indonesia - Malor roads


\ ~ an /!
West Sumatra border
exchange. Given favorable exchange rates, the .Z,sian trade 0 50 miles L I"I
would generate a surplus of pepper and spices which, when
sold on the Amsterdam market, represented pure profit.
Historical circumstances, however, gradually under-
mined accumulation based solely on trade monopoly and
even in the seventeenth century the Company was moving Major towns and roads of West Sumatra. The Minang-
towards control of production itself. This change was due in kabau highlands comprise the mountainous areas around
part to attempts by the Netherlands to reduce the flow of the towns ofBukit Tinggi, Batu Sangkar, and Payakumbuh.
precious metals eastwards, the danger of price fluctuations
on the home market and continuing competition at the
three points of the circuit from Asian and other European
ued to return home with large fortunes made in the East,
merchants. Equally significant, although the nature of the
the V.O.C. had been a losing concern as early as the
data makes it difficult to investigate, must have been the
eighteenth century. By the early 1780s the Company was
fact that, while monopoly demands on the one hand an
increasing peasant output of certain commodities for the no longer able to raise money on the open market and by
world market, its very reproduction depends on the other the time of the Batavian Republic, the V.O.C. was dis-
hand on the restricted commercialization of the peasant banded, all its possessions and debts falling to the Nether-
economy. Particularly striking in this respect were early lands government.
V. O.C. moves to prevent the development of an indigen-
ous cloth industry and later attempts by a colonial govern- The Culture System
ment interested in coffee exports to discourage the cultiva- The period from 1800 to 1830 is significant both from
tion of rice for sale. Thus by reinforcing the monopoly the the point of view of colonial policy and for its implications
V.O.C. was at the same time undercutting its ability to for the peasant economy. In spite of proposals to abandon
extract commodities for export. mercantile exploitation of the colony, the Dutch govern-
Monopoly brought territorial control with it as a neces- ment and the colonial bureaucracy resisted the demands of
sary byproduct, and, coupled with that, came tribute, tax the Dutch bourgeoisie who wished to encourage free trade,
farming and forced cultivation, all of which became signi- private investment and impose a money tax on the peasan-
ficant features of V.O.C. policy. In Sumatra the V.O.C. try. It was in this struggle between the "conservatives" and
demanded tribute of rulers who were thought to have bro- the "liberals" that the Culture System based on forced
ken their contracts, and it imposed a treaty on the Minang- labor and forced deliveries was born. The victory of the
kabau King which allowed it to collect taxes in the coastal conservatives, however temporary, and the continuity of
region. Elsewhere, whole villages were let out to Company policies are indications of the fact that mercantilism did not
officials and Chinese entrepreneurs in exchange for an die with the V.O.C. For Dutch colonialism in nineteenth
annual payment of rent. century Indonesia, at least up to the passage of the Agra-
While the V.O.C. attempted to overcome these con- rian Land Law of 1870, was not capitalist in the strict sense
tradictions by making more direct demands on peasant of the term since it was based on commercial monopoly
cultivators, and while individual Company officials contin- rather than free trade and private investment.
T h e r e are a n u m b e r of studies of the Culture System in Schrieke (1955) for example describes the almost ridicul-
english 6 and hence its broad outlines should be well known. ous lengths to which the government in West Sumatra went
I shall therefore restrict the discussion to its operation in to discourage the trade in rice.~l The rules of adat, or
West S u m a t r a and its implications for the nature of peasant c u s t o m a r y law as it is usually translated, were also trans-
e c o n o m i c organization in the region. f o r m e d in function if not content by the colonial authorities
By intervening in the Padri W a r s , ~ a struggle be- in some regions. Through a process of selection and codifi-
t w e e n Islamic Fundamentalists and supporters of a d a t cation familiar to students of colonial history elsewhere,
( c u s t o m a r y law) and the royal l i n e a g e m t h e Dutch estab- D u t c h judicial authorities turned a fluid system of custom-
lished a military presence in the Minangkabau highlands. ary practices into a rigid legal code. There is evidence for
O n e of the first acts of the government, after Dutch forts o t h e r parts of Indonesia that this policy actually strength-
were built in the highlands, was to send a commissioner e n e d the subsistence community by increasing the extent to
from Batavia to investigate ways of increasing coffee pro- which all villagers had access to land for subsistence cul-
duction, which had been exported from the early 1800s tivation. ~2 N o n - m a r k e t levelling mechanisms prevented
u n d e r colonial monopoly. As a result of his recommenda- the e m e r g e n c e of an internal market. 13
tions, a law was passed in 1847 bringing in a system of In short while no doubt there was considerable varia-
forced deliveries along the lines of the system developed tion in the nature of peasant enterprise, most factors
earlier in western Java. U n d e r the new law it was up to local favored the emergence of enterprises of a particular type in
officials, appointed by the government, to see that every which households cultivated some coffee to be sold to
able-bodied man with access to land cultivated a certain g o v e r n m e n t warehouses and other products for direct
n u m b e r of coffee trees. The cooperation of local officials h o u s e h o l d consumption using family labor and locally-
was secured by granting them a percentage of the revenues supplied raw materials on land distributed through the
on coffee grown in their areas of jurisdiction. Small ware- n e t w o r k of a d a t relations. What limited cash income there
houses were built in most market towns, and the grower was must in most cases have been negligible, and this was
was expected to deliver the coffee to the government at p r o b a b l y largely used to purchase a few consumption goods
these points. In 1862 cultivation was made legally com- such as salt and textiles supplied by those same warehouses
pulsory and in 1879 the percentage offered to local officials to which the coffee was delivered.
was raised. 7 Peasants were paid a price for the coffee which
was set by the colonial government at a level sufficiently Blacksmithing in Sungai Puar, 1970-1972
low to yield profits in the trade rather than in the produc-
The contrast between coffee cultivation in the nine-
tion process. All indications are that prices paid to produc-
t e e n t h century and the production of steel t o o l s w a x e s ,
ers were extremely low, often too low even to cover the
hoes, p a r a n g (machetes), sickles and k n i v e s m i n the modern
cost of transport.
highland n a g a r i (village) of Sungai Puar at first sight ap-
A n examination of colonial policy in the region sug-
pears to be slight; and yet, as we shall see, the differences are
gests a close relation between the economic aims (securing
significant. Since I have discussed this case in more detail
a m o n o p o l y on the coffee trade, increasing cultivation and
elsewhere, 14 1 shall present only a brief overview here.
pegging prices substantially below world market prices)
Sungai Puar is a Minangkabau n a g a r i with a resident
and the b r o a d e r social aims of the colonial power. Hence,
p o p u l a t i o n of just over 9000 in 1971. In the village section
for example, the preservation of what was assumed to be
of Limo Suku is found the "industry" for which the vililage
the " t r a d i t i o n a l " structure of isolated villages~subsis-
is best known. Here smiths forge and finish steel tools
tence orientation, universal access to land through local
which they sell mostly in the nearby market town of Bukit
kinship groupings, absence of production for the market,
Tinggi, the main point of distribution for markets through-
e t c . ~ w e n t hand in hand with the attempt to secure a
out the province and indeed throughout the island of
m o n o p o l y in coffee, s Here, however, we are concerned to
Sumatra. Smithing is the main occupation of male resi-
examine the implications of this specific colonial context
dents, yet a large proportion of Sungai Puar men and
for peasant enterprises in the region. While there is some
w o m e n product or trade in some commodity for sale in
d i s a g r e e m e n t on this issue 9, it seems that the tendency of
local markets.
these policies would have been to strengthen subsistence
p r o d u c t i o n to the detriment of commodity production with
the i m p o r t a n t exception of course of coffee cultivation. ~0

II | 11. Schrieke, 1955.


12. See A.D.A. de Kat Angelino, Colonial Policy (The Hague: Martinus
Nijhoff, 1931), p. 6.
6. See Furnivall, 1949, and C. Geertz, Agricultural Involution (Berkeley:
Univ. of California Press (1963). 13. Here I am referring specifically to Schrieke's finding (Schrieke, 1955)
that in spite of attempts by Sumatran villagers to grow rice as a cash crop
7. W.F.Huitema, De Bevolkingsko.ff~ecultuur on Sumatra (Wageningen:H. for the internal market after the lifting of commercial restrictions, and in
Veen en Zonen, 1935),p. 59. spite of an initial rise in rice prices, rice prices fell rapidly, not because of
8. J.S. Kahn, " 'Tradition,' Matriliny and Change among the Minang- the huge volume of rice surpluses being sold, but because of a relative
kabau of Indonesia," Bijdragen, No. 132, 1976. oversupply composed of small rice surpluses. Such a relative oversupply
9. See F. von Benda-Beckmann, Propert)' in Social Continuity (The Hague: was caused by the widescale persistence of what can loosely be termed
Martinus Nijhoff, 1979). "subsistence production," i.e. non-market, internal distribution of rice.
10. Currently Mr. K. Young is writing up the results of archival research See also Geertz, 1963; J. Scott, Ttle Moral Economy of the Peasant (New
into, among other things, the economic background of the 1908 tax Haven: Yale Univ. Press, 1976).
rebellions. This important work should further our understanding of the 14. J.S. Kahn, Minangkabau Social Formations." Indonesian Peasants and the
effects of forced deliveries on the 19th century peasant economy. World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 1980).
Smithing is in fact carried out within a number of cles or from the unfinished section of the Padang-Pakan
different kinds of enterprise, the three most significant of Baru railway. Other costs include expenditures for certain
which were, at the time of my research, individual produc- tools, anvils, paint, and polishing grit used in the process of
tion, production by owner of enterprise with from two to finishing forged steel ware. The only "capital" costs met
three wage workers, and kin-based production. As the outside the market involve the reproduction of certain
figures in the table show individual production was the pre- items of fixed capital, including some of the hammers used
dominant form, while kin-based production was very little in forging, the small thatched hut within which forging
favored. takes place, and the land on which the hut stands. The first
two are produced by the smiths themselves, while the huts
are built on housing plots classified as the ancestral land of
the smith's own lineage (or that of the spouse).
I have pointed out that labor costs are not monetized,
and yet to some extent this is an oversimplication. Firstly,
Table
there are, as the table demonstrates, a number of enterprises
E c o n o m i c Relations in Smithing which employ wage labor. Here, however, there is no
Breakdown by "class" of total working population developed wage form. Rather the "return to labor" (re-
(residents and migrants) venues minus money costs) is divided equally among the
workers in a forging unit, with an extra share "for the
Productive Role Number o f Smiths Percent of Smiths forge." This extra share is intended to cover fixed capital
expenditure, but because this is relatively small, the re-
Owner-worker employing maining proportion of the extra share is retained by the
3-4 workers 24 4.7 " e m p l o y e r " as a kind of disguised profit. Even when smith-
Owner-worker employing ing units were amalgamated within larger enterprises con-
1-2 workers 111 21.7 trolled by individual entrepreneurs in the late 1950s ~5, this
mode of calculation was employed. The system comes
Independent Producer 180 35.2 closer to piece-work payment than wages in that workers
Wage worker 117 22.9 are rewarded according to the volume of output rather than
W o r k e r with close
kinsman 46 9.0
Other 34 6.6
While monopoly demands on the one hand an increas-
ing peasant output of certain commodities for the
i world market, its very reproduction depends on the
other hand on the restricted commercialization of the
Smithing is carried out entirely with the aim of earning peasant economy.
a cash income. Like coffee cultivation in the nineteenth
century, moreover, smithing is dominated by very small-
scale enterprises, with self-employment predominating.
This suggests that, as in the 19th century, most such en-
terprises obtained labor without the existence of a labor the duration of labor. Thus even when labor costs are
market, and that, with some exceptions, there were no essentially monetized, payment according to labor time
monetized labor costs for production. (the main capitalist mode) is absent.
However, there is a major difference between smith- It would, however, be misleading to speak of an ab-
ing in the early 1970s and the case described above, since sence of labor costs even for self-employed smiths. Most
while monetized labor costs remain minimal, other mone- smiths have worked at other occupations during their
tary costs are incurred by the producer. In other words both lifetimes, and the high rates of temporary migration, as
are cases of a commercialized peasantry, producing com- well as the interchange among different local cash-earnings
modities for a market (in one case a world market, in activities, leads to some notion of an acceptable return to
another largely regional). Yet in the former the market- labor in commodity production and distribution. As we
oriented peasant enterprises are reproduced largely shall see there is some difference between this situation and
through non-market mechanisms, while in the latter an one in which labor input can be treated as though it were
important proportion of productive inputs are supplied totally free of monetary cost.
through the market mechanism. While smithing, unlike coffee production, has been
In the case of smithing, an average of about a half of all effectively integrated within the circuit of commodity rela-
revenues brought in from the sale of steelware must be used tions, such is not the case for the village economy as a
by the owner/worker to purchase raw materials. The main
raw material costs are expenditures on coal and scrap steel.
Coal is brought into the village by a small number of traders
who purchase it at the Ombilin coal mines in Sawah Lunto. 15. J.S. Kahn, "Economic Scale and the Cycle of Petty Commodity
A n o t h e r group of merchants buys scrap steel in surround- Production in West Sumatra," in M. Bloch (ed.), Marxist Analyses and
Social Anthropology (London: Malahy, 1975),
ing market towns which comes either from scrapped vehi-
whole. About 60 percent of households in the village have
access to some irrigated land on which rice is cultivated
largely for household consumption typically with house-
hold labor (more female labor than male). While rice .. ~("5......
farmers have to make some monetary expenditures even if
they cultivate the land themselves (primarily for tools), the N ' " .......... ? , ....... \) ......
main productive inputs are supplied outside the market.
Land is inherited in the female line, and while some trans-
fers may take place through a system of pawning there are
strict social obstacles to the development of a land market.
Labor is, as we have seen, supplied by a woman with the / , ....
help of other family members, and even when land is i.,^11 u t 9 Ell i, ~ , c,s ^1~ ( .L~, KELANT&N tl -

cultivated by tenants, rent is always paid in kind. In Sungai


Puar irrigated land is in short supply, and very few house-
holds are self-sufficient in rice. On average households can
meet about 20 percent of their annual rice needs through
subsistence cultivation, although the subsistence ratio is
higher in other parts of West Sumatra. Thus while the
various forms of commodity production in the village~
smithing, carpentry, sewing, matmaking, petty trading,
e t c . ~ a r e heavily dependent upon the market for the re-
production of enterprises, there are still areas of the peas-
ant economy that remain isolated from the circuit of com-
modity circulation. This serves to distinguish the economy POLITICAL DIVISIONS -"<"~ ~,:~, .~.~ =,."~,"
of Sungai Puar from the case described below.

Rice Cultivation in Negeri Sembilan, 1975-1976


0 I0 ZO $0 40 ~0

Like the Sungai Puar villagers, peasants in the cul-


turally-related area in Malaysia known as Negeri Sembilan Map 1
expend a considerable proportion of their effort in the
production of commodities for the market. The principle Map of West Malaysian peninsula showing Rembau and
form of local commodity production is rubber tapping. Tampin in southern Negeri Sembilan.
Coagulated latex sheets are then sold to shopkeepers. As in
the case of blacksmithing, the predominant productive role Source: Ginsburg & Roberts, Malaya (Seattle." Univ. of Washington, 1958.
is that of owner tapper, although a smaller proportion of
villagers sharetap on land owned by someone else. Rubber
cultivation is, like smithing, closely integrated within com- technological changes in rice cultivation. Techniques sup-
modity circuits. Tools, land, seedlings and coagulation plied during the "Green Revolution" have spread rela-
equipment are all purchased either directly or through tively rapidly, and local rice farmers increasingly employ
various government credit schemes, although some tap chemical fertilizers, herbicides and pesticides or hire a
trees on ancestral land. The replanting of rubber holdings, tractor to plough the fields prior to transplanting. In the
for example, has taken place largely through government years since the adoption of new techniques, there has been
loans which are then repaid over a period of years. little change, however, in the relatively egalitarian pattern
The main difference is in rice cultivation. Villagers in of land distribution and the relatively low rates of tenancy.
R e m b a u and Tampin districts, like those in Sungai Puar, The new techniques do not appear to have had any favor-
cultivate rice on irrigated land for household subsistence. In able effect on household output, but their use nonetheless
Rembau over 90 percent of such land is classified as pusako * marks an important change. For example, while in the past
although in the region as a whole it may now be possible to output was a factor of labor supply, the volume of house-
speak of the emergence of a land market. Up to about 1960, hold demand and the size of holdings, now the success of
rice cultivation in the area conformed in many ways to what rice cultivation depends largely on the use of the new
Jackson has termed the "traditional pattern" in the inland inputs. And of course what is most significant about these
valleys region of West Malaysia, namely, irrigation by new inputs is that they cost money, which makes access to
means of brushwood dams or waterwheels, hand prepara- cash, rather than access to labor and land, the most im-
tion of the soil with a hoe, the use of dry nursuries, harvest- portant feature of a successful household. ~7
ing with the tuai (a small knife) and threshing by stamping
(menghirik). 16 Today, however, there have been important

II II
16. J.C. Jackson, "Rice Cultivation in West Malaysia," Journal of the
Royal Asiatic Society (Malayan Branch), No. 45, 1972.
* Pusako: Ancestral land, i.e. land which is acquired through inheri- 17. J.S. Kahn, "The Social Context of Technological Change in Four
tance and not purchase. Malayan Villages," forthcoming in Man.
Hence while the commodity-producing sector of the
Negeri Sembilan peasant economy is in many ways similar
to that of West Sumatra, the main difference is that in this
case even when goods are produced for household con-
sumption and not sale, their production depends on the
market supply of productive inputs. In other words even
so-called subsistence production has become integrated
Marxist Literary
within reproductive circuits governed by the commodity
form.
The cases outlined above demonstrate differing rela-
Thought in
tions between peasant enterprises and the circulation of
commodities. In all the cases a proportion of total individual
or household output is sold on the market to be consumed
China
locally (steelware) or overseas (coffee, rubber). The differ- The Influence of Ch'ii Ch'iu-pai
ences therefore are not between "traditional" subsistence- by Paul G. Pickowicz
oriented peasants and market-oriented producers. Rather, Marxist aesthetic thought has dominated Chinese
the most striking difference is the degree and nature of literary life for half a century, but little is known
market penetration of production. In nineteenth century about how this distinctive Western school of
Sumatra productive inputs were supplied almost entirely thought came to be accepted. Pickowicz remedies
outside the market through community and kin-based the situation, tracing the evolution of Chinese
Marxist literary thought by focusing on Ch'i~
mechanisms of appropriation. There is no evidence of a
Ch'iu-pai, China's most important Marxist literary
market in means of production, land or labor. Craftsmen intellectual of the twenties and thirties. $25.00
and women in the 1970s, however, not only produce com-
At bookstores
modities for sale, but productive units are also substantially
reproduced through commodity relations, while the cultiva- University of California Press
tion of rice for household consumption was reproduced Berkeley 94720
outside the commodity circuit. Finally in Negeri Sembilan
rubber tapping and rice cultivation are closely integrated
within a commodity circuit that involves land and, most
importantly, the means of production. Moreover in this last
case the commmodity circuit that penetrates peasant pro-
duction is at the same time a world commodity circuit scale production from the wider world system and/or the
involving capitalist firms and multinational enterprises. long-term dynamics of the capitalist mode of production all
Finally, however, it should be noted that in spite of too frequently explain the emergence and rationality of
increased market penetration, there is, in none of these petty production simply as a response to the abstract needs
cases, a highly developed labor market, at least within the of capitalism itself. ~8Short- and long-term trends in regions
peasant economy itself. The main differences in the nature in which petty production predominates, or in which indi-
of labor supply is that only with the system of forced de- vidual production units make a significant contribution to
liveries is labor relatively immobile across different bran- regional or sectoral output are then deduced in teleological
ches of production. This suggests that the process of dif- fashion from secular trends which have occurred elsewhere
ferentiation which leads to capitalist relations of produc- (such as differentiation) or from the functional prerequis-
tion in peasant agriculture, which has been extensively ites of capitalist reproduction, or as residual or marginal
described for other parts of the world-economy, is not an phenomena that exist only "by default." In all such global
inevitable consequence of market penetration on the periph- attempts to deal with the emergence, reproduction and
ery. Indeed on closer examination the differentiation thesis possible development of petty production there is a
appears to rest on the conflation of three quite different tendency to lose sight of the real historical processes
processes: the commoditization of output, of the means of through which petty production is (sometimes) subsumed
production, and of labor power. As these cases demon- by capital: the specificities of petty production itself (as
strate these three processes are not necessarily causally opposed together productive forms which would be equally
interlinked. beneficial to capital); the possible contradictions between
different fractions of capital and between petty production
The Implications of Input Commoditization and capitalist production; and the extreme generality of the
for a Theory of Petty Production notion of petty production itself. 19
If one wished to summarize the result of decent de- y ii ~l ,

bates, particularly among Marxists, over concepts like


peasantry, informal sector, family labor farms and the like, 18. See for example J. Ennew et al, " 'Peasantry' as an Economic Cate-
it could be stated that such notions have been found want- gory," The Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4, 1977; M. Harrison,
"The Peasant Mode of Production in the Work of A.V. Chayanov," The
ing because they are imprecise, they are inductive abstrac- Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4, 1977; H. Bernstein, "Concepts for
tions that permit no deductive conclusions about concrete the Analysis of Contemporary Peasantries," The Journal of Peasant
cases, and that they give a misleading impression of a static Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4, 1979.
and self-contained isolation of small producers. On the 19. S.A. Mann and J.M. Dickson, "Obstacles to the Development of a
other hand many studies which begin a theory of small- Capitalist Agriculture," The Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 5, No. 4, 1978.
In an a t t e m p t to o v e r c o m e the theoretical and empirical c o n f o r m to this m o d e l . Secondly, the notion of h o u s e h o l d
p r o b l e m s i n h e r e n t in transitional, functional and "by- is u n l i k e l y to be anything m o r e than a superficial descrip-
d e f a u l t " e x p l a n a t i o n s of petty production, 2~ I p r o p o s e to t i o n of a l a b o r process. T o say that the basic unit of produc-
a n a l y z e the n a t u r e and forms of petty p r o d u c t i o n itself tion is the h o u s e h o l d is in fact to say very little, since it
b e f o r e t u r n i n g to the b r o a d e r analysis of the long-term p r e s u m e s a given social division of labor based on sex and
t r e n d d e s c r i b e d above. a g e a l r e a d y d e f i n e d outside the h o u s e h o l d altogether. Gi-
T h e r e are two obvious starting points for such an v e n this fact, i.e. that the very f o r m of the h o u s e h o l d as
analysis. T h e first is the notion of h o u s e h o l d production, o r g a n i z e r of the labor process is d e t e r m i n e d by o t h e r struc-
d e r i v e d at least in part from the w o r k of C h a y a n o v and the t u r e s , it is not surprising that different " h o u s e h o l d - b a s e d
" O r g a n i z a t i o n of P r o d u c t i o n School. ,,2~ While C h a y a n o v ' s e c o n o m i e s " will differ radically f r o m the situation analyzed
w o r k has b e e n s u b j e c t e d to n u m e r o u s criticisms, p e r h a p s by C h a y a n o v .
t h e m a i n p r o b l e m with the concept of h o u s e h o l d produc- T h e i m p o r t a n c e of C h a y a n o v ' s w o r k then lies not so
t i o n lies in t h o s e m i s g u i d e d a t t e m p t s to generalize Chay- m u c h in a w h o l e s a l e application of the h o u s e h o l d m o d e l to
a n o v ' s findings to all cases in which " t h e h o u s e h o l d " is the all s i t u a t i o n s w h e r e t h e r e is no m a r k e t in labor p o w e r as in
basic unit of p r o d u c t i o n , zz or to give to the h o u s e h o l d a t h e kinds of insights his w o r k provides into the b e h a v i o r of
t h e o r e t i c a l status which it does not deserve. This leads to small e n t e r p r i s e s at least partially r e p r o d u c e d outside the
t w o m a i n difficulties. Firstly, C h a y a n o v ' s analysis of the circuit of c o m m o d i t y relations. 23
s h o r t - t e r m d y n a m i c s of p e a s a n t p r o d u c t i o n in Russia de- T h e s e c o n d obvious starting point for a t h e o r y of small
p e n d s o n a set of historically specific circumstances. It is p r o d u c t i o n is M a r x ' s discussion of petty c o m m o d i t y pro-
o v e r l y optimistic to expect all h o u s e h o l d p r o d u c t i o n to d u c t i o n in the pages of Capital. A l t h o u g h it is i m p o r t a n t to
distinguish a p r o p e r t y f o r m c h a r a c t e r i z e d by individual
o w n e r s h i p a n d possession of the m e a n s of p r o d u c t i o n from
capitalist private p r o p e r t y , M a r x ' s d e m o n s t r a t i o n d e p e n d s
o n a series of a s s u m p t i o n s m o r e p r o b l e m a t i c from our point
The authors argue that petty commodity production will be predominant of view, since for him the discussion is only a logical step in
in agriculture when there is a relatively high production time/labor time an a r g u m e n t a b o u t the capitalist m o d e of production. T h e
ratio. The problem with such an argument is that this is not really an use of v a l u e analysis, for e x a m p l e , is m a d e possible only
explanation since as they show themselves when capitalism penetrates
agriculture it reduces this ratio. Moreover, based as it is solely on an b e c a u s e M a r x can a s s u m e that c o m m o d i t i e s e x c h a n g e at
explanation of capitalist tendencies, it does not demonstrate why it should v a l u e m m e a s u r e d as h o m o g e n e o u s , abstract, socially-nec-
be that petty commodity producers are able to operate under such e s s a r y l a b o r t i m e - - a n a s s u m p t i o n valid only w h e n labor
conditions. p o w e r is a c o m m o d i t y , and h e n c e only u n d e r capitalist
20. See J. Gledhill, "Towns, Haciendas and Yeoman," Bulletin of Latin p r o d u c t i o n . T h e idea of a petty commodity mode o f produc-
American Resarch, Vol. 1, No. 1, 1981, who gives a critique of these three
different approaches. tion in which labor p o w e r is not a c o m m o d i t y and yet in
21. Aleksandr Vasil'evich Chayanov was the major spokesman for what w h i c h c o m m o d i t i e s are a s s u m e d to e x c h a n g e at value is,
was termed the "neo-populist" tradition in the analysis of the Russian t h e r e f o r e , c o n t r a d i c t o r y (unless we a s s u m e that the mobil-
peasantry. The characterization of the tradition, which can be attributed ity of l a b o r p r o d u c e s a n a l o g o u s results). 14
as much to its critics, stems from their apparent defense of the viability of This p a p e r is not the place for an e x t e n d e d theoretical
the peasant farm in the context of debates over the colle6tivisation of discussion of t h e s e issues. H e r e we n e e d only recognize
Russian agriculture. Chayanov and other members of the tradition ar-
gued, on the basis of a mass of statistical data termed the zemstvo statis- t h a t the c o n c e p t s of h o u s e h o l d p r o d u c t i o n on the one hand
tics, that the Family Labor Farm was the predominant form of agricultural a n d p e t t y c o m m o d i t y p r o d u c t i o n on the o t h e r are not
productive unit, that the behavior of an economy dominated by such units n e c e s s a r i l y i n c o m p a t i b l e b e c a u s e they serve to address two
was not analyzable using the tools provided by national economics, and-that distinctive p h e n o m e n a . T h e use and d e v e l o p m e n t of Chay-
a proper theory of the Russian peasant economy should be based on a a n o v ' s w o r k in the context of p e r i p h e r a l peasantries is m o s t
different theory that reorganized the qualitative differences between dif-
ferent types of economy. The specificity of the Family Labor Farm is fruitful for the analysis of the n o n - m a r k e t r e p r o d u c t i o n of
derived from the absence of wage costs, since labor is supplied not through e n t e r p r i s e s . C h a y a n o v ' s discussion of the d e t e r m i n a n t s of
a labor market but through the family tie. Chayanov's point is that the
absence of one of the basic categories of capitalistic calculation of profita-
bility (which explains enterprise organization) is of no use for the analysis I I I
| ,,,
_ |

of peasant economy.
This initial analysis leads Chayanov to develop certain specific analyses
based on a series of assumptions about the conditions within which such an 23. W. Kula, for example, has been able to produce a convincing analysis
economy operates with which we shall not be concerned here. His views of the short- and long-term dynamics of Polish feudalism by examining the
lead him into both political and theoretical conflicts, the main objection to prevailing forms of economic calculation. Here feudal enterprises were
his work coming from those who argued that far from being a significant linked into regional and international output markets while at the same
category in Russian agriculture, the Family Labor Farm was not the main time land, labor and the means of production were distributed to en-
form of economic organization and that class differentiation of the terprises in such a way as to be treated as costless by feudal lords. W. Kula,
peasantry in the 19th century had been leading to capitalist agriculture. An Economic Theory of the Feudal System (London: New Left Books, 1976).
These critiques were based largely on the alternative analyses suggested Recently H. Friedman has proposed a similar typology of small enter-
by Lenin in his The Development of Capitalism in Russia. For further prises by distinguishing between what she terms peasant and petty com-
discussions see A.V. Chayanov, The Theory of Peasant Economy, ed. and modity production. The latter is distinguished from the former again in
introduced by D. Thorner, B. Kerblay and R. Smith (Homewood, Il- terms of the degree to which the enterprises are reproduced through
linois, 1966); B. Kerblay, "Chayanov and the Theory of Peasantry," in T. commodity relations. H. Friedman, "Household Production and the Na-
Shanin (ed.), Peasants and Peasant Societies (Harmondsworth: Penguin, tional Economy," The Journal of Peasant Studies, Vol. 7, No. 2, 1980.
1966); and Harrison, 1977. 24. J.S. Kahn, Minangkabau Social Formations: Indonesian Peasants and the
22. M. Sahlins, Stone Age Economics (Chicago: Aldine, 1974). World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 1980).

10
labor intensification, for example, are at least partly de- output prices, competition with technically more efficient
signed to show how labor is allocated in the absence of a forms of production, etc.--could lead not just to increased
labor market. 25 The negative-supply response* of (some) levels of labor intensity, but to a superexploitation of all
peasant producers noted first by members of the "Organi- other productive inputs supplied outside the market and
zation of Production School" can only be the consequence hence not valorized in production, in particular land. In-
of the relative immobility of peasant labor from the branch deed there is evidence that the forced deliveries of coffee
of production experiencing deteriorating profits into other did produce overexploitation of land and all its conse-
branches in which the price structure is more favorable. quences, such that when commercial restrictions were
The concept of petty commodity production, on the lifted, land suitable for cash crop production had to be
other hand, draws our attention to situations in which at sought outside the region where coffee had been grown in
least constant capital is valorized and, hence, in which the 19th century. 28
the allocation of land and the means of production is de-
termined by the market price. Bernstein's discussion of
what he calls the "simple commodity squeeze," for exam-
ple, is directed to a situation in which labor inputs must be
intensified because the market price of productive inputs The use of blanket terms like peasant, small producer,
has risen faster than the market price of output. 26 My own household production and the like all lead to a mis-
discussion of the cycle of petty commodity production, leading conflation of rather different forms of petty
similarly, is based on the changing relation between money production.
costs and money returns and its effect on the organization
of production. 27
In short while the concepts are not mutually exclu-
s i v e ~ b o t h being designed to deal with enterprises in which
labor costs are not m o n e t i z e d ~ t h e y do have quite differ- As enterprises become more reliant on the commodity
ent aims. This should therefore direct our attention to the market for their reproduction, however, and raw materials
kinds of differences between small, commodity-producing and other means of production acquire a monetary cost,
enterprises. While the sharp dichotomy between peasants the situation is rather different. Firstly, opportunities for
and petty commodity producers suggested by Friedman such superexploitation are decreased. Secondly, self-ex-
may be unhelpful, it is nonetheless important to recognize ploitation (or intensification of labor) increasingly be-
that the use of blanket terms like peasant, small producer, comes the only alternative--hence suggesting that labor
household production and the like all lead to a misleading intensification may be even greater as we approach the
conflation of rather different forms of petty production. petty commodity end of the spectrum. Thirdly, when input
The cases briefly outlined in the first section of this paper commoditization results in increased labor mobility, peas-
can be taken for the time being as formal types of petty ants may move into less and less productive (because of low
production. I want now to suggest more precisely how they levels of fixed capital costs) branches of production.
might differ. Fourthly, the potential causes of self-exploitation them-
selves actually increase, since added to the other causes we
Self-exploitation now have the deleterious effects of rising input prices.
The first difference concerns the meaning of self- t

"Supply Response"
exploitation This term, usually taken to mean the increased
intensification of labor inputs (beyond the limits which a A second, although related, difference between the
capitalist enterprise would entertain under similar condi- different types of enterprise concerns the problem of sup-
tions), in fact could be taken to refer to a broader range of ply response. We have pointed out that some writers have
phenomena, i.e. the superexploitation of all productive suggested that, due to a subsistence ethic, peasant produc-
inputs. ers respond "perversely" to price fluctuations. Higher out-
It can be seen that, in the case of nineteenth century put prices are then expected to lead to a decrease in the
Sumatra, factors which typically increased levels of self- volume of output, while lowering of output prices produces
exploitation~rising consumer/worker ratios, declining the opposite effect. The typology proposed here suggests
that this negative supply response is not universal in peas-
ant economies, but that it may occur under certain cir-
cumstances. Specifically, increased production in the face
of falling prices is likely to take place only when labor is
* Negative supply response" an inverse relationship between price relatively immobile. When labor mobility exists, falling
changes and fluctuation in the volume of putput. prices can be expected to produce a drop in both enterprise
25. Kula's case study of glass production on Polish feudal estates is
designed to show how the use of raw materials (in this case timber) differs ,,
I !11 II II II III , ,

when no market price can be assigned to them.


2,~. This is a process in many ways similar to the destruction of feudal
26. II. l~crn',f~'in. "'Notes~n ('~pital ~lntl Peasantry.'" Rr~'iew of A/rit'an estates in Poland described by Kula, for much the same reasons, and
Politi~'al l:~-m.nv. N~ II) 1"}'77
_ . . J : ,
presumably also for what has all too frequently been attributed to natural
27. K :,1,n. I~)75. disaster more recently in places like the Sahel.

11
and aggregate production as peasants switch to branches of sible or possible only with extremely high rates of labor
production in which the "return to labor" is more favor- intensity. The differences between a situation of labor im-
able. Indeed it is precisely under such circumstances that mobility, and one of labor mobility, however limited, are
we may expect a social average return to labor to develop, considerable. Firstly, the mobility of small producers is
as described above. The converse--i.e, rising prices result- based on, and in turn accentuates, the tendency for deci-
ing in falling o u t p u t - - c a n be assumed to take place only if sions to be arrived at through a comparison of different
peasant producers are already achieving desired subsis- rates of (money) profitability on the one hand, and dif-
tence levels, something which is increasingly rare in con- ferent rates of return to labor input on the other. Other
temporary Southeast Asia. things being equal, for example, we might expect peasants
In any case there is certainly evidence from Southeast to move from branches in which the return to labor is below
Asia and elsewhere to show that under certain conditions the social average and into those in which it is equal to or
peasants do indeed strive to expand output, expand mone- higher than the socially average return to labor. Of course
tary incomes beyond levels required for simple reproduc- as long as labor power is not fully commoditized, other
tion, and invest in monetary inputs that serve to increase factors will enter into calculation, and strict labor-time
productivity. The literature on Malaysia and Indonesia, accounting may well not develop. Nevertheless, since indi-
with its continuous emphasis on obstacles to growth, sub- vidual petty commodity producers experience the drudgery
sistence ethics and the like needs to be counterbalanced by of labor inputs directly, something analogous to the wage as
further research into the conditions that favor such devel- an historically-determined and relatively standardized
opments. level around which "returns to labor" in different branches
of production tend to vary will emerge. To the extent that
Profitability such a social average has emerged we might expect the
A further difference concerns the way peasant pro- exchange value of peasant-produced commodities to be
ducers compare the "profitability" of different economic proportional to the labor time involved in their production,
activities. In Negeri Sembilan, for example, the evidence which in turn further constrains petty commodity produc-
suggests that the commoditization of inputs in rice cultiva- ers to produce in terms of socially-necessary labor time.
tion has led to a gradual decline in aggregate rice outputs This situation is very different from one in which the rela-
precisely because different kinds of comparisons than pre- tive unimportance of monetary costs of production has not
viously existed are now possible between the (money) cost caused qualitatively distinct and concrete forms of labor to
of rice cultivation and the price of purchased rice on the one merge into a single, abstract, homogeneous category of
hand, and the money costs of other forms of production labor.
(such as rubber tapping) or even wage labor. 29 Mobility of small producers has the other implication,
This leads to a consideration of a phenomenon that has already mentioned, that decisions will increasingly be
been mentioned in passing several times in this argument, based on a comparison of money rates of profitability
and that concerns the mobility of labor in an economy in across different branches of production. Again, other
which petty commodity production is a significant form of things being equal we might expect small producers to
enterprise. A basic assumption in much of the writings 3~on engage in activities which require the minimum of cash
peasants is that peasants are for one reason or another expenditures. Moreover since market penetration of pro-
rather severely restricted in the kinds of economic activities duction has already been assumed to have occurred, small
they can undertake and even in the places they can under- producers can be expected to favor a high t u r n o v e r ~ h e n c e
take them. Hence work on the moral economy of the favoring branches with relatively higher ratios of circula-
p e a s a n t r y - - t h e tendency for there to be an inverse correla- ting capital to fixed capital, rather than vice versa.
tion between price and output, subsistence-orientations I have so far considered the shorter term implications
of input commoditization for small-scale peasant enter-
and the like--frequently takes it for granted that peasants
are not free: for example, they may not move out of one prises. I have suggested that the distinction between peas-
kind of production, in which there has been a deterioration ant production and petty commodity production is signifi-
cant from the point of view of the nature and determinants
in output prices, and into another branch where conditions
are more favorable. It is precisely this immobility of peas- of self-exploitation, the response of small producers to
ant labor which, as we have seen, prevents an analysis of price fluctuations, the kinds of comparisons made between
peasant commodity exchange in terms of value. different alternatives, and the determination of prices and
ratios between fixed and circulating capital in small produc-
However, the commoditization of productive inputs is
tion. In the final section of the paper I want to turn to an
one of the factors which breaks down the obstacles to
mobility, although it can only be said to be one of the examination of the historical process of input commoditiza-
tion itself.
preconditions for this mobility to develop. Equally impor-
tant are the constraints set by wider economic forces, in-
cluding the presence of more technologically advanced Some Hypotheses Concerning the Causes
enterprises which make peasant competition either impos- of Market Penetration
The three cases discussed above, while they cannot be
. I I IlL
taken to represent stages in some necessary evolutionary
sequence, do nonetheless suggest that the most significant
29. Kahn, forthcoming. process of economic transformation is that described as
30. See Scott, 1976. the penetration of peasant production by the circuit of
12
national and international commodity relations. Having in West Sumatra, it was designed to replace forced de-
pointed to the significant implications of this process it is liveries. Where there was a relatively low level of market
necessary to account for it. What follows is in no way penetration, the imposition of the tax, not surprisingly,
intended to constitute such an explanation. Rather I shall forced peasants to produce cash crops for the world rather
instead attempt to set out a proposal for further research. than the internal market. In Sumatra, for example, the
An historical explanation of the phenomenon as it has initial response to the tax in some villages was the produc-
occurred in specific cases is necessary for reasons outlined tion of marketable rice surpluses. However, villagers quite
above. We have criticized the differentiation thesis pre- quickly turned to more profitable world cash crops such as
cisely for treating the commoditization of production as rubber, tea, coconuts and coffee when they discovered that
though it were some inevitable evolutionary process on the even small rice surpluses produced a glut in the market.
world capitalist periphery. A proper understanding must Production of cash crops for the world market at the
therefore avoid confusing the qualititatively different kinds same time did create some opportunities for further spe-
of input markets that underlie the differentiation thesis. cialization. In order to meet the tax burden some peasants
R a t h e r it seems better to assume that market penetration is could produce commodities such as steelware, textiles, and
a consequence of particular economic and political strug- fruit and vegetables for the internal market which devel-
gles both within the peasantry and between peasants and oped in part as a result of the changing division of labor in
other classes in concrete social formations. As Marx shows Sumatra. 31
so clearly for the development of capitalist production, the Thus the imposition of a money tax explains on the one
commoditization of labor power is not a natural but an hand the increased market orientation of peasant enter-
historical development, the end result of a process of pro- prises and, on the other, a qualititave change in the way
letarianization whereby producers are deprived of/separ- enterprises are reproduced. The tax becomes a money cost
ated from the means of production. Only when the direct of production, like rent, and serves to redefine the condi-
producer has no alternative is he/she compelled to sell tions under which peasant calculation is made. The reor-
labor power as a commodity. ientation and the consequent change in the social division
Similarly it would seem best to assume that peasants of labor may also explain some degree of market penetra-
are likely to resist the market penetration of production. tion of production, since new economic activities may re-
Firstly, increased monetary costs of production serve to quire non-traditional inputs which can only be purchased
undermine the (money) rate of profitability of commodity on the market.
production. Secondly, market penetration takes place only
when peasants are no longer able to reproduce themselves
outside the market. Hence a land market will not develop
simply as a result of the introduction of the "market princi-
ple" but when, for example, the communal structures of Thus the imposition of a money tax explains on the one
land distribution have been sufficiently undermined to hand the increased market orientation of peasant en-
threaten the reproduction of existing agricultural pro- terprises and, on the other, a qualitative change in the
duction. way enterprises are reproduced. The tax becomes a
This proposition can be illustrated for Sumatran coffee money cost of production, like rent, and serves to
producers in the nineteenth century. Whether these peas- redefine the conditions under which peasant calcula-
ants were concerned to maximize cash revenues or whether tion is made.
they were interested only in simple reproduction, it is likely
that they would have little interest in expanding their cash
costs. The "profitability" of coffee cultivation was a result,
not of high coffee prices, but of negligible money costs.
A n y increase in these money costs would quickly under- However, while a tax may increase commercialization
mine socially-defined profit levels. Put another way, the of production beyond the level of production, a head tax is
colonial government was able to extract a surplus in the not on its own a sufficient explanation for a long term
coffee trade, based on paying very low prices to producers, process of market penetration, since the compulsion to pay
when the land, labor and means of production employed in a tax of this kind does not necessarily undermine the ability
coffee cultivation were locked away from the market. In of peasants to reproduce their productive activities outside
this case the necessarily high rates of exploitation of these the market. A land tax, such as that levied in by the British
inputs could be ensured only through the use of direct in Malaya, on the other hand, may have longer term effects
political pressure. As long as they had a choice, therefore, on the viability of subsistence reproduction since it may, if
we can expect that these peasants would have operated it is proportional to land area, lead to fragmentation of
with a minimum of cash outlays. holdings. Nonetheless, set levels of money taxation are, it
Any increase in the market penetration of peasant would seem, at best a partial explanation for the long term
production, therefore, could have only been the result of
force in the broad sense. Hence the first significant change
was marked not by the natural evolution of the market
mechanism in Southeast Asia, but by the imposition of a
31. Kahn, 1980; O. Oki, "Textiles in West Sumatra," in F. van Androoij
money tax by colonial governments. Indeed it is not par- (eds.), Between People and Statistics (The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff,
et al
ticularly surprising that the imposition of the money tax 1980); M. Singaribum, Kinship, Descent, andAlliance among the Karo Batak
was strenuously resisted by rural cultivators even when, as (Berkeley and Los Angeles: Univ. of California Press, 1975).
13
process described above. Rather, taxation would produce behind the population growth mechanism make it suspect.
enterprises somewhere in between the peasant--petty Specifically, it fails to explain particular demographic trends
commodity production extremes, without implying any in specific historical periods. Secondly Geertz has outlined
necessary further process of input commoditization. one way in which population growth leads to intensification
And yet, as we have seen, the market penetration of of land use, labor inputs and non-market mechanisms of
peasant enterprises in the region has considerably in- resource distribution. To rely on population growth to
creased, even in the last twenty years. A full explanation explain the opposite tendency thus requires an explanation
for this continuing transformation of peasant enterprises in for relative population surplus and a specification of the
the region is not possible at this stage. Therefore, in conclu- conditions under which that leads to increased market
sion, I propose only to examine some of the possible expla- penetration.
nations as a means of stimulating further discussion. 4) An account of why market penetration has occurred
1) The first thing to note is that market reproduction is in increasingly in this century is implied in writings which
the interests of capitalism. It has become apparent in recent stress the increased divergence between price and output
years that while profit levels in peripheral peasant agricul- fluctuations brought by reliance on producing for world
ture are rather low, small producers are able both to pro- rather than local markets. Scott, for example, explains the
duce much needed commodities at relatively low prices 32 breakdown of "moral economy" and traditional redistribu-
while at the same time forming a profitable market for tional systems in Southeast Asia as being due at least in part
agricultural inputs supplied by multinational corporations. to the shift from internal to external markets. 35 The conse-
As C. Payer has recently pointed out, there is an inevitable quence has been that price fluctuations in the latter, being
clash of interests between "self-provisioning" peasantries extra-locally determined, do not make up for annual varia-
and the interests of capital. 33 Payer focuses in particular on tion in output to the same extent that they would if prices
the way policies advocated by the World Bank have served were locally-determined.
to undermine self-reproducing peasants who are forced to Increased world market penetration of production
subsitute for traditional techniques through the mechanism would, by this theory, be due to the turn-of-the-century
of indebtedness. As a result, they become dependent on shift in Indonesia and Malaysia to the cultivation of world
firms supplying agricultural chemicals, for instance, the cash crops, and consequent fluctuations in price and output
market for which is rapidly shrinking in the core countries. serving to dispossess at least some small producers of access
This process is clearly important, and the means by to the means of production, producing the cycle of debt and
which such techniques have been introduced during the further penetration as described above. This hypothesis
Green Revolution needs closer examination in Southeast too deserves further investigation to see whether the
Asia. And yet such an explanation is at best incomplete, rhythm of market penetration can be related to the dif-
since it fails to explain precisely how peasants with an ferent stages of commodity penetration. However, such a
interest in minimizing cash expenditures are placed in a general explanation would have difficulty acounting for the
position of reliance on such inputs. lack of differentiation between proletarians and employers
of wage labor. In other words it would probably be insuffi-
2) One explanation offered is that peasants have become cient to explain the specific pattern of commoditization
increasingly impoverished by world price fluctuations and, that has taken place in particular regions.
as a result, are forced into debt. Failure to repay the debt
locks them into a vicious circle of asset-stripping, increased 5) In some areas in Southeast Asia, full petty commodity
reliance on the market for the purchase of means of pro- production has been the result of colonial policies which
duction which leads in turn to increased indebtedness. aimed to ensure an adequate labor supply to plantation
There is no doubt that this has occurred in Southeast agriculture both through land grabbing and immigration
Asia, 34 and yet again the explanation is insufficient since it policies. The resultant absolute and relative surplus popu-
fails to account for the occurrence of such impoverishment lations would by these means become proletarianized.
in some places and not others, and more significantly from Economic cycles and technological change, on the other
our point of view, why it occurs in some periods and not hand, would have the effect in certain periods of denying
others. wage employment, and the unemployed would then be
forced into production and trade using means of produc-
3) A similar explanation is embodied in the thesis that it is tion purchased on the market. However, while this de-
population expansion and land fragmentation that makes velopment has clearly been a significant process in the
peasants particularly susceptible to the cycle of indebted- creation of a peripheral lumpenproletariat, entirely depen-
ness. Again this has clearly taken place, and yet theories on dent on the market for its reproduction, it has not been a
population growth also leave a number of things unex- sufficiently general process in the region to be the sole
plained. Firstly, of course, the Malthusian assumptions explanation for the developments described above.
6) Another important factor in decreasing local forms of
reproduction has been the import of cheap manufactured
goods from the capitalist core. It would here be particularly
32. G. Lee, "Commodity Production and Reproduction amongst the
Malayan Peasantry," Journal of Contemporao' Asia, Vol. 3, No. 4, 1973.
33. C. Payer, "The World Bank and the Small Farmer," Monthly Review,
Vol. 32 No. 2, 1980.
34. See G. Myrdal, Asian Drama (New York): 1968). 35. Scott, 1976.
14
interesting to compare Indonesia, which has traditionally reproductive mechanisms (to acquire more land, more
had tighter restrictions on imports, with Malaya which has labor, new technologies, etc.).
had freer p o l i c i e s ~ a difference partly traceable to differ- These are some of the factors which might contribute
ences between Dutch and British colonial policies. It is, to the significant transformation in the Southeast Asian
however, by no means evident that tight import controls peasant economy described above. What should perhaps
have not in fact led to a transformation of petty commodity
be noted is that the penetration of commodity relations
production rather than a reinforcing of the individual pat-
may be due on the one hand to a deterioration in the
tern of production encompassed by that term. 36
conditions of peasant enterprises or, on the other hand, to
7) Finally, it cannot be assumed that under all circum- attempts by peasants to improve these conditions. Neither
stances peasant producers are interested only in simple is there a simple answer to the question of whether the
reproduction. Under certain conditions peasants in South- causes are internal or external to the peasant economy.
east Asia behave more like petty capitalists, expanding External pressures to commoditize must be met by inter-
production in order to increase money revenues and invest- nal conditions which force such commoditization on peas-
ment. While research is needed in Southeast Asia into the ants whose main interests may lie in minimizing cash
historical conditions under which this occurs, it seems that expenditures.
increasing output will imply greater monetary costs of pro- What is now required is more detailed research into
duction in order to overcome given limits in communal specific processes of change, combined with better histori-
cal work on Southeast Asian peasants which does not re-
i
i
ii i iiii
i i
i i iii
I ii ii
IIII IIIII
- iiii
II
i i
II ill ill
I , , . . . . . . . . . .
duce them all to a timeless and unchanging mass, but links
transformations in their lives to the wider historical and
36. Kahn, 1975. social processes of which they are a p a r t . ' ~

INTERNATIONAL R E V I E W O F E C O N O M I C S A N D BUSINESS

RIVISTA I N T E R N A Z I O N A L E DI S C I E N Z E
ECONOMICHE E COMMERCIALI
Direzione 9 Amministrazione: 20136 MI L A N O
Via P. Teulit, I - Telefono (02) 8399031

Vol. XXVIII J u l y - A u g m t 1981 N. ? 4


L ' e c o n o m i a liapponesr 9 I'ltalta
B O L T H O , A N D R E A : Italian and J a p a n r Postwar Growth--Ymme Similarities and Difference=
A R! K I, S O I C H I R O : J a p a n ' s Economy at the Croa4uroads--Analysis o f Conditions for Her
Survival
H A L L I D A Y , JON: The Specificity of Japan's Re-integration into the World Capitalist Economy
after 1945
I M A Z A T O . H I R O K I : The Japanese E c o n o m y in the 1980s
T A K A G i , TADAO: Labour Market and Salary Structure: A Compariaon between Japan and
Italy
ISHIMINE. T O M O T A K A : Japan's Economic Cooperation in Latin America
LOMBARDO, ANTONIO: Japan's and Italy's Political Systems--Developmental and
Comparative Perspectives
S T A M M A T I , GAETANO: Italy and Japan in the New Oil and Monetary Crisis
TU FARELLI, NICOLA: The Current International Situation and National Restrain~ of Italy Connexions presents the
and Japan
FODELLA, G I A N N I : Narrowing the Gap among Pure Rr Applied Re,earth and
world from a woman's
Technological Diffusion: The Japanr162Experience perspective 9
BOOK REVIEWS
. . . . . .

The International R e v i e w o f Economics and Busine.~.~~is a monthly published since 1954. The majority
of the articles are in English with English resumes for tho~ printed in a different language. In the =NEWS
~
riod 1971-1981 the International Review has published 84 c ~ y ~ on Japanese economy. Among iU
st-known authors are: A. Boitho, R, P. Dorr G. Gregory, K, Haitani, J. Halliday, R. tT~ia, 9
K. Kojima, F. Maraini, T. N a k a m u r a , N. Namiki, P. Sylos Labini, K. Taira, S. Tsr t | . Wagatsuma.
Annual subxcripti,n $50.00. IVhoh' colh'ction available. 9 INTERVIEWS

translated from the


im i lllllllll llll I l l / I/II l I l II I llllm international feminist
press.
Moving?
SUBSCRIBE N O W !
Moving is costly. For you. And occasionally for Annual sub'S 10
us. If you change your address but do not tell us, CONNEXIONS/PTS
the Post Office throws away your copy of the 4228 Telegraph Ave.
Bulletin... and then charges us! Oakland, CA. 94609
(415) 654-6"/25
Give us a b r e a k . Tell us before you move.
mlmllmmmmmmllummmmmmmlllmmll m
15

You might also like