You are on page 1of 14

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/sced

Innovation strategies, process and product innovations and growth:


Firm-level evidence from Brazil
Micheline Goedhuys a , Reinhilde Veugelers b,c,d,e,∗
a
UNU-MERIT (United Nations University, Maastricht Economic and Social Research and Training Centre on Innovation and New Technologies) and
Maastricht University, The Netherlands
b
University of Leuven, Belgium
c
ECOOM, Belgium
d
Bruegel, Bruxelles, Belgium
e
CEPR, London, United Kingdom

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Using World Bank ICS 2000–2002 data from Brazilian manufacturing firms, this paper
Received January 2010 identifies innovation strategies of firms – in particular internal development (“technol-
Received in revised form January 2011
ogy make”) and external acquisition (“technology buy)” – and their effect on successful
Accepted January 2011
process and product innovations. It subsequently explores the importance of process and
Available online 12 February 2011
product innovations for firm growth. Successful process and product innovations occur
mostly through “technology buy” (mostly through the purchase of machinery and equip-
JEL classification:
ment), either alone or in combination with a “technology make” strategy. The option of
O12
O31 only relying on internal development is less successful. The results on firm growth indicate
O54 that innovative performance is an important driver for firm growth. It is particularly the
combination of product and process innovations that significantly improves firm growth.
Keywords: Both innovation and growth performance are supported by access to finance. Skills of work-
“Make” and “buy” innovation strategies force and management matter, but not necessarily tertiary education levels. The impact of
Process and product innovations
international linkages on innovative and growth performance is mixed.
Firm growth
Brazil
© 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction for growth and the adoption of new technologies are heavy
regulatory burden, the quality of institutions, severe finan-
Technological progress is at the heart of development. cial constraints and macro-economic uncertainty (Bastos
But the innovation processes that underlie technological and Nasir, 2004; Dollar et al., 2003; Eifert et al., 2005).
progress in developing countries have very different char- In addition, technology diffusion depends on the extent
acteristics from that in developed countries. Innovation to which firms are exposed to foreign and new vintage
in these countries largely occurs through the absorption, technologies – through trade, FDI and migration of human
adaptation and mastery of already elsewhere developed capital – and on the firms’ ability to absorb and adapt
technologies, often sourced from abroad, rather than the the technologies to which they are exposed. A number of
invention of entirely new technologies. studies on innovation activities of firms in particular indus-
Clearly there is a huge heterogeneity across develop- tries in Latin America and elsewhere in the developing
ing countries and firms in the importance of innovation for world (e.g. Bell and Pavitt, 1995) stress the importance of
growth. Among the factors identified as potential barriers investment in domestic capabilities to generate and man-
age change in technology. These capabilities encompass
specialised resources such as skilled labour.
∗ Corresponding author at: KULeuven, MSI, Naamsestraat 69, B-3000 To shed more light on the link between adoption of new
Leuven, Belgium. Tel.: +32 16326908. technologies, innovation and firm growth, this paper anal-
E-mail address: reinhilde.veugelers@econ.kuleuven.be (R. Veugelers). yses micro-evidence from a sample of manufacturing firms

0954-349X/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2011.01.004
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 517

from Brazil. In recent years, Brazil has been able to play an absorption and exploitation of knowledge, independently
increasingly important role in international trade, produc- of where it is created.
tion and innovation. While this pattern of emerging success Spillovers from technology elsewhere developed, have
has given rise to a significant amount of research docu- been identified as particularly important drivers in endoge-
menting the performance of the economy at the aggregate, nous growth models (a.o. Grossman and Helpman, 1991).
the micro-evidence on the factors that underlie Brazil- However, knowledge does not spill over easily and cost-
ian firms’ success remains less abundant, especially when lessly, but rather depends on countries’ ability to effectively
it comes to studies on larger samples, including various absorb new technologies (Lall, 1992). Accessed knowl-
industries, and controlling for the variety of factors that edge needs to be combined with a sufficiently developed
can influence firm performance. “absorptive capacity” (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989) or
This paper, using firm level data from the World Bank’s “social capability” (Abramovitz, 1986) in order to deliver
Investment Climate Survey (ICS) collected in Brazil in growth. Absorptive capabilities depend on many factors,
2003, contributes to the literature on innovation and including the extent to which a country has a technologi-
development in several ways. Taking a micro-econometric cally literate workforce and a highly skilled elite; promotes
perspective, the paper investigates in more detail not only an investment climate that encourages investment and
how the interplay between external technology sourc- permits the creation and expansion of firms using higher-
ing (a “technology buy” strategy) and internal technology technology processes and products; permits access to
development (a “technology make” strategy) affects inno- capital; and has adequate public sector institutions to pro-
vation outcomes, but also how the successful introduction mote the diffusion of critical technologies where private
of new products and processes in turn drives firm growth. demand or market forces are inadequate (World Bank,
Both the innovation and the growth analysis also con- 2008).
sider the importance of other framework conditions like A second set of factors explaining technological progress
access to finance, skills, ICT, (international) openness and is own indigenous innovative capacity, which becomes
competition. Our focus on Brazil allows analysing the increasingly important as a country progresses closer to
case of a middle-income country in fast development, the technology frontier (Hoekman et al., 2005). First, own
where innovation strategies are becoming increasingly R&D complements the adoption of existing technology
more important for sustaining growth, particularly the because it is a component of absorptive capacity. Foreign
interaction between “technology buy” and “technology technologies frequently need to be modified so that they
make” and the interaction between product and process are suitable for domestic circumstances. Countries tend to
innovations. Also on the role of foreign technologies, trade acquire technology more readily when domestic firms have
and FDI, Brazil is an interesting case. Although it has opened R&D capabilities and when public research laboratories and
up to the global economy, it still carries the reminders of universities have relatively close ties to industry. But, at
a closed economy set-up, relying on its own large internal higher levels of development, own R&D increasingly may
market. Our study takes on board many of these influences also start to substitute adoption of existing technologies,
to study what drives or impedes Brazilian manufacturing allowing generation of new technologies, particularly in
firms to introduce new products and processes successfully these areas where the country has developed comparative
and grow. strengths.
Before we present our results in Section 5, we first Empirical macro-analysis confirms the importance of
briefly review several strands of the literature (Section 2), innovation for catching-up (Nelson, 1993; Kim, 1997).
discuss the specifics of Brazil (Section 3) and introduce our Fagerberg et al. (2007) and Fagerberg and Srholec (2008)
data (Section 4). for a large cross-section of countries find significant effects
of technological capacity (both creation and absorption)
2. Literature review to be significantly related to growth. But although a well
functioning innovation system seems critical for develop-
Several strands of the literature are relevant for under- ment, they also confirm the importance of the quality of a
standing the link between innovation and firm growth in country’s institutions.
developing countries: the macro-economic literature on For catching-up countries, international transfer of
innovation and growth, the literature on FDI, technology technology, through trade (exports and imports) or FDI,
spillovers and growth, and the micro-literature explaining is an important source for growth. Many endogenous
firm growth. growth models have emphasized technology spillovers
It is widely recognised in the macro-economic liter- from the North to the South as a vehicle for productivity
ature that R&D and innovation are a major driver of growth of the South (e.g. Grossman and Helpman, 1991;
economic growth. Since the classic “Solow residual” paper Coe et al., 1997). However, the empirical evidence on the
(Solow, 1956), it has been recognised that rates of fac- effects of international technology transfer is less clearcut
tor accumulation do not account for the major part of (Hoekman and Smarzynska Javorcik, 2006). Although ear-
economic growth. The endogenous growth literature (see lier studies based on industry level cross-sectional data
Romer, 1994; Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Aghion and found statistically significant horizontal spillover effects
Howitt, 1998) identifies innovation efforts as a major in developing countries (Blömstrom and Persson, 1983;
engine of growth. In these models, the rate of growth of Blömstrom, 1986; Kokko, 1994), more recent studies using
a country is determined by its initial level of development, panel data sets, correcting for firm or sector specific fixed
the creation of new knowledge within the country and the effects, find no positive within-industry spillover effects
518 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

for developing countries (e.g. Görg and Greenaway, 2003). process innovation, which in turn are explained by R&D and
Using macro data, no or little support is found for open- other innovation expenditures.1 For instance, Chudnovsky
ness to trade and foreign direct investment to matter for et al. (2006) find in-house R&D and technology acquisition
innovation and growth (Fagerberg and Srholec, 2008). expenditures to enhance the probability of product and/or
One explanation for the difficulty to find evidence process innovations, which in turn attain higher productiv-
of positive spillovers from openness is the confound- ity levels than non-innovators. The impact of innovation
ing impact of competitive effects from open markets on firm growth is studied by Benavente and Lauterbach
(Markusen and Venables, 1999). In addition, the poten- (2008) for Chile. They find product innovations to stimu-
tial benefits from FDI may not materialize, as multinational late employment growth, but find no relationship between
firms may protect their core know-how from dissipating to process innovation and growth. Equally interesting is the
local rivals (Veugelers and Cassiman, 2004). An additional paper by Almeida and Fernandes (2008) who analyse inno-
critical factor to exploit spillovers is the technological capa- vation and international exposure, based on firm data from
bility of indigeneous firms (Blomström and Kokko, 1998; 43 developing countries, and find importing and exporting
Blalock and Gertler, 2009). Most of the empirical studies on firms, but not foreign owned firms, to be more innovative;
developing countries have failed to find robust evidence of they do not measure the further impact on firm perfor-
positive knowledge spillovers from multinational invest- mance. Raffo et al. (2008) equally do not find a positive
ment, accounted for by the lack of absorptive capacity in effect of foreign ownership on innovativeness, but a signif-
these host countries (e.g. Aitken and Harrison, 1999; Narula icant positive one on productivity.
and Dunning, 2000). Overall, the literature paints a complex relationship
The literature explaining firm growth has shown between technology development (technology make) and
that growth is largely a stochastic process where many the acquisition and absorption of externally developed
unidentified and unobservable (firm-specific) factors are (foreign) technologies (technology buy) and growth. At
responsible for the growth performance of firms. However, the macro-level, R&D and innovation seem important for
since the seminal work of Jovanovic (1982) firm growth is development, but are no panacea for success. Depending
seen as a learning process: firms discover their true effi- on the initial country conditions, flanking conditions such
ciency levels and adjust their size accordingly, with more as education, finance, quality of institutions, governance
efficient firms growing into a larger size. This learning pro- and openness, need to be factored in. At the firm level, link-
cess is most apparent shortly after entry, which explains ing innovation strategies and growth requires taking into
why small and young firms grow faster. Pakes and Ericson account the conditions for effective technology creation
(1998), building further on Jovanovic (1982), developed an and absorption.
‘active’ learning model, in which the efficiency level can
be actively raised by firm-specific investments in innova- 3. The case of Brazil
tion activities and R&D, thereby opening up the growth
perspectives of firms. As our analysis uses 2000–2002 firm level evidence from
Several authors (e.g. Katz, 1987; Enos, 1992; Lall, 1992; Brazil, this section characterizes the country specific set-
Bell and Pavitt, 1995; Kim, 1997) have integrated these ting of the data, particularly with respect to its innovation
ideas with the literature on technology for catching up position, its development process and the framework con-
firms in developing countries, using an evolutionary per- ditions for innovation and growth.
spective of economic change (Nelson and Winter, 1982). With the largest population in Latin America and the
These authors underscore the importance of investment Caribbean, Brazil has reached in the past few years impor-
in domestic capabilities to generate and manage change tant economic, social and environmental advances (OECD,
in technology. In the absence of domestic technological 2006). The country has expanded beyond agricultural com-
capabilities – specialised resources and skilled labour – effi- modities and low value-added manufacturing, to become
ciency gains and firm growth will not automatically follow a global competitor with a significant group of firms
from the acquisition of foreign technology and know-how being inserted in international markets via medium and
embodied in machinery (Bell and Pavitt, 1995). Firm level high-tech goods (De Negri and Turchi, 2007). Through
technological change is understood as a continuous pro- joint ventures with multinational corporations (MNCs), the
cess, to absorb or create technical knowledge, determined country also has developed information and communica-
partly through the acquisition of external inputs – through tions technology (ICT) and software industries that serve
FDI, licenses, know-how and technical service agreements, domestic and regional markets. However, in other high-
capital goods imports – and partly through accumulating tech, high-growth sectors, Brazil is falling behind global
skills and knowledge – by training human capital through competitors, particularly Asian.
formal education, on the job training, experience and in Brazil has made great strides in developing its own inno-
house R&D efforts to manage technological change. vation system. Brazil is Latin America’s largest and most
Recently a number of empirical studies emerged innovative economy, with about 1% of its GDP going to R&D
analysing innovation in developing country firms, its deter- in 2000–2003 (Lugones and Suarez, 2007, p. 156). However,
minants as well as its impact on other firm performance
indicators (see Raffo et al., 2008 for an overview). Using
mainly innovation survey data, these studies follow Crépon 1
Examples from Latin America include the analysis of countries such
et al. (1998) or variations thereof, explaining firm perfor- as Argentina (Chudnovsky et al., 2006), Chile (Benavente, 2006), Mexico
mance, mostly productivity, as a function of product and/or (Pérez et al., 2005) and Argentina, Brazil and Mexico (Raffo et al., 2008).
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 519

most of Brazil’s R&D is coming from the public sector, with Overall, the recent fast development of Brazil provides
the private sector R&D expenditure as share of revenue and an interesting case to examine the interplay between dif-
numbers of R&D workers being still low2 (Peirano, 2007) fusion (buy) and creation (make) of new technologies, as
and advancing on a specialisation path that requires little centrepiece for sustaining growth, with many of the flank-
investment in R&D. ing conditions for an innovation-growth nexus critical.
A first barrier to effective R&D and innovation per- Our analysis examines the relationship between the
formance in Brazil is a shortage of skills, especially in technology make and buy strategies on the one hand and
the fields of natural and exact sciences and engineering, the innovation and growth performance on the other hand,
needed for the technological development of technology together with its flanking conditions, at the level of individ-
intensive industries (Lugones and Suarez, 2007). Most of ual firms operating in manufacturing sectors in Brazil. More
the recent expansion in the number of higher education specifically, we examine
degrees awarded is accounted for by private institutions,
where quality concerns are present. • which innovation strategies are most conducive to a
A second barrier is access to finance. Despite macroe-
firm’s successful introduction of new products and
conomic stabilisation since the mid nineties, the cost of
processes: technology make, technology buy or a combi-
capital still remains high in Brazil thwarting the innova-
nation of both strategies? We expect for Brazilian firms
tion efforts of small and medium sized firms (Prochnik
the technology buy option to be particularly important,
and Dias de Araujo, 2007). The government has instituted
especially when combined with a technology make strat-
several financial incentives (De Brito Cruz and de Mello,
egy to improve absorptive capacity;
2006). Many are targeted at specific industries, such as • how important successful product and/or process inno-
aerospace and IT, concentrated in specific regions. During
vations are for firm growth;
the economic recessions and crises of the 1990s, funding • the impact, as framework conditions in the innovative
for science and technology programmes was severely cut
and growth performance, of human capital as a crucial
(Cassiolato et al., 2003). The funding for innovation that was
component of absorptive capacity, financial constraints
available to firms was directed to purchase capital equip-
and international exposure.
ment rather than for R&D.
Another factor limiting the innovation potential is
ICT usage. The Brazilian telecommunications equipment 4. Data and methodology
industry was initially a protected “infant industry” in
Brazil. Trade barriers were erected to allow the industry 4.1. Data
room to grow. Government-sponsored R&D efforts in com-
munications hardware and software helped to create an Difficulties related to data availability and the mea-
indigenous sector that was capable of serving the local surement of innovation typically hamper firm level
market. Nevertheless, the use of ICT technologies is less econometric analysis of the link between innovation and
widespread in Brazil than in countries with comparable growth for developing countries. To analyse the link
development (Szapiro, 2003). between technology creation and adoption, innovation and
With its history of import substitution, various sectors firm growth, we use the World Bank’s Investment Climate
of the Brazilian economy remain sheltered from inter- Survey (ICS) data collected in Brazil in 2003. The survey col-
national competitive pressure (OECD, 2006). While the lected data for the periods 2000, 2001 and 2002,3 through
country has lowered barriers that were left over from its intensive interviews with owners and managers of firms.
previous import substitution policies, it has moved to pro- The data collection is part of a larger programme coor-
tect and foster those technology sectors that thrived under dinated by the World Bank that implements Investment
the barriers. This has included regulations on joint ventures Climate Surveys in many countries using a harmonised
with multinational corporations and technology licensing master questionnaire. The objective of the ICS is to obtain
agreements – meant to support innovative capacity build- firm level data that allow analysing the conditions for
ing within Brazil. investment and enterprise growth in the country. As such,
Despite these limitations and based on observations the many aspects of the business environment that influ-
from innovation surveys, Arbix and De Negri (reported in ence the investment decisions and performance of the
De Negri and Turchi (2007)) find strong indications that firms were tackled, in a number of sub-questionnaires. A
the opening up of the economy since the mid nineties set of questions was asked on the history of the firm, the
has gradually led to a more entrepreneurial stance, that background of the entrepreneur and manager, the acquisi-
has improved global competitiveness of Brazilian indus- tion and status of equipment and technology, the firm’s
try. They find innovative and product differentiating firms human resource management, innovation activities, and
to combine product and process innovation more often institutional constraints to growth and investment. The
than firms producing standardised goods; and they actively survey provides more information on a wider variety of
search information required for innovation abroad through factors affecting technological innovation and firm perfor-
FDI and alliances.

3
Additionally, the sales value was also asked for the year 1997,
2
80% of Brazilian researchers carry out their activities within public which permits investigating sales growth over a longer period of time:
institutions (universities or research centres). 1997–2002.
520 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

mance than the Brazilian Innovation Survey 1998–2000,4 Table 1


Composition of the sample.
which was restricted to a more limited and focused set of
questions on innovation. Small Medium Large All firms
The ICS dataset allows the construction of innovative 10–29 30–99 100+
workers workers
strategies, along both a “make” and a “buy” option. The
innovation outcome of the firms can be assessed through Food 15 33 72 120
self-reported success in introducing new processes as well Textiles 21 27 54 102
Clothing 95 203 126 424
as products. The growth performance of the firms is based Leather 26 78 56 160
on the self-reported sales data by the respondents for the Chemicals 12 32 34 78
years 2000–2002. Machinery 43 61 74 178
In addition, the dataset allows for a rich set of control- Electronics 12 39 23 74
Auto-parts 16 42 68 126
ling factors. Beyond the typical firm size and age variables,
Furniture 76 136 89 301
as well as sector and regional classification, the dataset Total 316 651 596 1563
also allows identifying the catching-up position of the
firm in the technology space (technology leading or lag-
ging); the human capital of the firm (both its work force
growth. Table A1 in Appendix A provides a description of
as its management), which can be characterized by sec-
all the variables used in the analysis.
ondary and tertiary education levels; the use of ICT; the
financial constraints firms face in doing business; and
4.2.1. Innovation strategies: make and/or buy
the exposure to international technology and competition,
We first identify firms’ innovation strategies, on both
investigated through multiple channels: foreign owner-
the “make” and “buy” dimension. In the questionnaire,
ship, exports, imports of components, competition from
firms were asked about their major ways of acquiring
imports.
new technology. Firms could report up to three important
The main disadvantage of the dataset is the self-
strategies. As observed in many other developing countries
reported character of the data, leading to a possible
and in line with expectations, firms reported that the most
subjective bias and the restriction to a cross-section dimen-
important channel for new technology acquisition was
sion only, prohibiting constructing the dataset as a panel.
by investing in machinery and equipment that embodied
The ICS data set of Brazil contains information on 1642
newer vintage technology, followed by in-house develop-
manufacturing firms, which represent a random sample,
ment of new technology.7 Hiring of key personnel came
stratified on the basis of size, sector and location. The firms
in third position. Other less frequently mentioned chan-
are selected from nine manufacturing sectors.5 Within the
nels as major ways of acquiring new technology consisted
selected sectors, the sample gives a fair representation of
of sourcing from a parent company, licensing technology
the total population with respect to the size and location
from other firms, developing technology in collaboration
dimension.6 More detailed information on the sample and
with clients or suppliers, or universities, or from trade fairs,
sampling procedure can be found in World Bank (2005).
exhibitions and study tours.
Due to missing values for some of the key variables, the
We concentrate on the two major innovation strategies,
number of firms used in our analysis is reduced to 1563,
capturing the most frequently used channels: developing
distributed over the different size classes and sectors as
technology within the firm, i.e. the MAKE option versus
shown in Table 1.
the technology acquisition or BUY option. For the BUY
option, we include acquiring new technology embodied in
4.2. Methodology
new machinery, in key personnel as well as licensing-in
technology.8
Using the ICS information, we investigate the firm,
We construct different exclusive categories for the
industry and regional characteristics that can explain a
firm’s innovation strategy (I): firms that only report in-
firm’s innovation performance and its impact on firm
house development of technology (MakeOnly); firms that
only do external technology acquisition embodied in
4
This survey was coordinated by the Brazilian Geographic and Statis- machinery and key personnel (BuyOnly); and firms that
tical Institute (IBGE), and gathers information from 10,328 firms. Access report both own development activities and embodied
to the data for research is restricted, in contrast to the World Bank ICS technology acquisition as important channels for tech-
data, which are more accessible. Summary tables are available on the IBGE
nology acquisition (Make&Buy). The reference category is
website, results of the survey data are discussed in De Negri and Turchi
(2007).
5
Food industries (CNAE code 150), textiles (CNAE 170), clothing
7
(CNAE 180), leather products (CNAE 190), chemical products (CNAE 240), This was also observed in the Brazilian Innovation Survey 1998–2000:
machinery (CNAE 290), electronics (CNAE 320), auto-parts (CNAE 344), acquisition of machinery and equipment accounts for half of innovation
and furniture (CNAE 361). The CNAE (Classificação Nacional de Atividades expenditures, followed by R&D, accounting for 25% of expenditures. These
Econômicas) is the Brazilian national classification which is closely linked proportions differ from developed economies, where R&D is relatively
to the ISIC (International Standard Industrial Classification) revisions 3 more important, e.g. Germany, 55%; The Netherlands, 74% (Peirano, 2007).
8
and 3.1, at least up to the 2-digit level. We checked the robustness of our analysis to alternative composi-
6
A majority of firms is from São Paulo and Minas Gerais, but in total 13 tions of the BUY strategy. Most notably, we also concentrated the BUY
states are covered by the sample. These are Rio de Janeiro, Santa Catarina, strategy on the buying of equipment only, which is the most commonly
Rio Grande do Sul, Paraná, Goiás, Mato Grosso, Ceará, Paraíba, Maranhão, chosen BUY option. Most results (unless otherwise stated) are robust to
Bahia, Amazonas. the composition of the BUY strategy.
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 521

firms that have no innovation strategy of developing tech- As a robustness test, we also estimate a multinomial
nology nor buying technology (NoMake&Buy).9 logit, where we compare the impact of the various
innovation strategies on different exclusive categories of
4.2.2. Innovative performance: introducing new products combined product and process innovation outcomes: pro-
and/or processes cess only innovation (PROCONLY), product only innovation
Having identified a firm’s innovative strategy, we then (PRODONLY) and combined product and process innova-
link the technology “make” or “buy” strategy to the out- tion (PPI), versus no innovation outcomes, which is the base
come of the innovation process: the successful introduction case.
of a new production processes that substantially changed Compared to the bivariate probit model, the multi-
the way the main product is produced (PROCESS) and/or the nomial logit allows coefficients to vary across exclusive
successful introduction of new products (PRODUCT), both combinations of innovative performance. The multinomial
over the period 1998–2002.10 logit model can therefore reveal the drivers that affect the
Successful innovation – both the successful introduc- joint successful implementation of product and process
tion of new products and processes – is modelled following innovations. The disadvantage of the multinomial logit is
a bi-probit model, which relates the probability of being a that it requires an Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives
successful innovator to the characteristics of the firm (X) assumption.11 It also requires that the number of cate-
and the underlying innovation strategies (I). Our main vari- gories may not be too large and that there is sufficient
ables of interest are the set of innovation strategies (I): variation in each category. In our dataset a large majority
MakeOnly, BuyOnly, Make&Buy, with NoMake&Buy being of our observations is in the combined product and pro-
the reference category. cess category, leaving the exclusive outcomes only sparsely
Our set of other independent firm characteristics populated. The data further indicated that the category of
includes the typical size, age, sector and regional dum- product only innovators was very similar to the category
mies. In addition, other flanking variables that are likely of combined product and process innovators. We there-
to influence innovative performance are included in the fore had to merge both categories. Our final multinomial
equation. These are the technology position of the firm in logit specification thus includes three mutually exclusive
its market (T), the absorptive capacity in the firm (AC), for- categories: the process only innovators (PROCONLY), the
eign linkages and exposure (F), competitive pressure (C) product innovators, irrespective of whether or not this is
and financial constraints (FIN). They are measured through combined with process innovations (PRODONLY + PPI), and
various proxies, shown in Table A1 in Appendix A. the non-innovators, the latter being the reference group.
We thus estimate the following bi-variate probit model We estimate the following multinomial model of innova-
explaining successful process and product innovations
jointly, using the same set of variables as regressors.:

PRODUCT∗i = ˛Xi + ˇIi + Ti + ıACi + εFi + Ci + FINi + 1i


PRODUCTi = 1 if PRODUCT∗i ≥ 0; PRODUCTi = 0 if PRODUCT∗i < 0
∗ (1)
PROCESSi = ˛Xi + ˇIi + Ti + ıACi + εFi + Ci + FINi + 2i
PROCESSi = 1 if PROCESS∗i ≥ 0; PROCESSi = 0 if PROCESS∗i < 0

The launching of new products may often be combined


with the introduction of new production processes, leav-
ing product and process innovations as complementary tion performance outcomes:
(see also Miravete and Pernias (2006) for evidence on com-

plementarity between product and process innovations eZ j

for developed countries). The bi-variate probit regression


Prob(Y = j) = 3 iı
, j ∈ {None(1), PROCONLY(2),
k=1
eZ k
allows taking into account the correlation between PRO-
CESS and PRODUCT explicitly: PRODONLY + PPI(3)} (2)

E[1 ] = E[2 ] = 0, Var[1 ] = Var[2 ] = 1, Cov[1 , 2 ] =  where Zi


is a vector of firm characteristics, comprising
beyond the innovation strategies I also (X, T, AC, F, C, and
FIN).
9
These firms may still be acquiring technology but from less explicit
innovation strategies than the ones included in the MAKE and BUY cat- 4.2.3. Growth performance
egory, such as through sourcing information from or collaboration with Having analyzed the innovative strategies and innova-
clients, suppliers, universities, trade fairs, exhibitions and study tours. tion performance of firms in a first step, the analysis will in
10
Note that the available information on process and product inno-
a second step assess the relationship between innovation
vations is in terms of successful introductions. Strictly speaking, the
information can therefore only be interpreted as an innovation outcome
variable, not as a innovation strategy choice for process versus prod-
11
uct innovation. Two recent papers (Srholec and Verspagen, 2008; Bodas The multinomial logit has the potential weakness inherent in the fact
Freitas et al., 2008) propose, though in a different context, an alternative that choices between any two alternatives are assumed to be made inde-
definition of firm strategies which address the nature of innovation output pendently of the remaining alternatives. This is problematic whenever
itself (product and process). In this case, product and process innovation some of the available alternatives are rather close substitutes in which
choices would be the strategies to influence performance, rather than the case the merger of the substitutes is the most sensible solution (Kmenta,
make and/or buy strategies. 1997, p. 259).
522 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

and firm performance. We use as measure of firm perfor- firm fixed effects. Our data set does however not permit a
mance, self-reported average annual sales growth over the panel data structure.
period 2000–2002.12 We thus use a two step procedure in an attempt to
In line with the literature on firm growth using a learn- improve our estimation while correcting for the potential
ing perspective (Evans, 1987; Sleuwaegen and Goedhuys, biases due to endogeneity and unobserved heterogene-
2002), the basic empirical model for the growth equation is ity. The two-step procedure uses the predicted values of
a general growth function relating firm growth (g) to firm the innovative performance as instrument in the growth
size (S) and firm age (A): regression (3), derived from the estimations (1) and (2).
More specifically, we include in the growth specifica-
St 
g= = g(St , A) tion the predicted values PRODUCT and PROCESS from the
St
biprobit estimation or the predicted exclusive categories
where St and St are the size of a firm in end period t – here (PROCONLY, PRODONL + PPI, and NOPPI) either derived from
2002 – and in beginning of period t – 2000 – respectively, the bivariate estimation (1) or alternatively from the multi-
and A is the age of the firm in 2003. nomial logit estimation (2).13
This functional relationship is augmented with addi- As an alternative, we also report the results where we
tional variables that are expected to be related to growth. relate firm growth directly to the innovation strategies (I:
Our major variables of interest are the various innovative MakeOnly, BuyOnly, Make&Buy, and NoMake&Buy), bypass-
performance indicators (IP). In addition, we add access to ing the innovative performance outcomes.
finance (FIN), foreign linkages (F) and absorptive capacity
(AC) which are affecting growth, as flanking conditions. 5. The empirical analysis
We approximate the growth function g through a sec-
ond order logarithmic expansion of a generalised function Before we present the results from the econometric
relating growth to size and age and we add the growth analysis of firms’ innovative performance and growth in
shifting variables. The resulting estimating equation cor- Section 5.2, we first show some descriptive statistics on
responds to the following form: firm’s innovative strategies, innovative performance and
growth in Section 5.1.
log(St  ) − log(St )
d
5.1. Descriptive statistics
= a0 + a1 log(St ) + a2 [log(St )]2 + a3 log(A) + a4 [log(A)]2
Table 2 summarizes the information about the firm’s
+a5 log(St ) × log(A) + aI IP + a8 FIN + a9 F + a10 AC (3)
innovation activities, more particularly who BUYs and/or
where d stands for the number of years over which growth MAKEs. The most frequently observed innovation strat-
is measured and a are coefficient vectors. egy is the combination of Make&Buy (44%). The exclusive
In line with this model, our dependent variable corre- use of external acquisition embodied in new machinery,
sponds to an average annual sales growth rate over the key personnel or through licensing (BUYonly) is the sec-
period 2000–2002. The explanatory variables are as defined ond most frequently observed observation (34%). The total
in Table A1 in Appendix A and include beyond innovative proportion of sample firms that acquire technology exter-
performance, the OVERDRAFT variable to consider finan- nally (BUY) therefore sums up to 78%.14 Somewhat less
cial constraints (FIN); MNE and EXPORT for international but still more than half of the sample firms (56%) relies on
linkages (F) and GMHIGH for the quality of human capital internal development (MAKE). However, only 12% have a
(AC). MakeOnly strategy. 10% of the sample firms report noMake-
Our major variable of interest is the effect on sales orBuy activities. These are firms that have no innovation
growth of innovative performance, either through the PRO- strategy or resort to other less frequently observed and
CESS and PRODUCT dummy or the exclusive categories more informal ways for acquiring technology (such as trade
(PROCONLY, PRODONLY + PPI, and NOPPI). fairs, exhibitions, contacts and cooperation with consul-
Simply including the innovative performance in the tants, universities, clients, suppliers).
growth equation may result in their coefficients being Table 2 also shows the innovative performance of the
biased, because of endogeneity: faster growing firms may different innovative strategies. For process innovations,
have a larger incentive and capacity to introduce new two third of all firms report having successfully introduced
innovations. Unfortunately our dataset does not allow a new processes in the observed period. Companies without
sufficient lagging of the innovative performance variable an innovation strategy are clearly less likely to introduce
or forwarding of the growth results. Furthermore, unob- new processes (29%). Interesting to observe is the perfor-
served firm-specific effects in the innovation performance mance of the MakeOnly strategy, which is less effective as
regression can cause the coefficient of the innovation vari- compared to an innovation strategy that uses embodied
ables in the growth regression to be biased, if they also
enter the growth error term, as an unobserved explanatory
13
factor for growth as well. Panel data would allow including If we would use a perspective that interprets product and process
innovations as innovation strategy choices, rather than innovation out-
come variables, cf supra, our two-step procedure, can then be read as
showing the impact of these strategies on growth performance, with the
12
Alternatively we also check robustness of our results using a longer strategy choice being endogeneized to correct for potential biases.
14
time period for growth over the 1997–2002 period. This is consistent with the IBGE Brazilian innovation survey.
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 523

Table 2
Frequency of occurrence of innovation strategies.

Total Frequency of Process New-product Sales growth


occurrence innovators innovators 2000–2002

No make/no buy 10% 29% 34% -1.8%


Make only 12% 60% 65% 1.7%
Buy only 34% 71% 69% 5.5%
Make and buy 44% 73% 71% 6.9%
X2 67.7*** 31.6***
100% 66% 66% 5.2%
***
Significance of X2 test at the 1%.

Table 3 innovations.16 These companies also report the highest


Innovative performance and sales growth 2000–2002.
sales growth over the considered period (6.6%), well above
Frequency of Sales growth the growth performance of firms that introduce only prod-
occurrence 2000–2002 (%) uct innovations (4.1%) or only process innovations (4.3%),
No new product/no 222 (14%) 2.5 and significantly higher than the sample average growth
process rate of 5.2%. This is suggestive of complementarity between
innovation product and process innovations. Firms who failed to intro-
Product and 788 (50%) 6.6
process
duce new innovations (either product or process) have
innovators significantly lower sales growth (2.5%). Similarly, firms
Product only 267 (17%) 4.1 without innovation strategies (NoMake&Buy) have a lower
innovators sales performance (see Table 2).
Process only 286 (18%) 4.3
This first descriptive view of the data suggests first
innovators
Process innovators 1074 (69%) 6.0 the importance of embodied technology acquisition as an
Product innovators 1055 (68%) 6.0 innovation activity (BUY), with support for complement-
Total 1563 5.2 ing technology acquisition with in-house development
(MAKE) in a Make&Buy innovation strategy; second,
innovative strategies are positively related to innova-
technology acquisition, exclusively or in combination with tive performance, especially for process innovation, where
internal development. There is some evidence in favor of the BUY option (exclusively or in combination with
complementarity between Make and Buy, since the highest MAKE) proves particularly favorable; third, innovative
success rate is observed for the Make&Buy strategy (73%). performance is positively associated with higher sales
But this is only slightly higher than the performance of the performance, particularly the combined product–process
BuyOnly strategy (71%). innovations.
On average, 66% of all companies report having success- The next sections will examine in a multivariate analy-
fully introduced new products in the observed period.15 sis which factors are significant drivers of innovative and
The lowest frequency is again observed among the growth performance.
NoMake&Buy category, where 34% of firms report to have
introduced new products. Again, the highest frequency of
5.2. Multivariate analysis results on innovative
successful product innovations is among the firms in the
performance
Make&Buy category, though the disparity with the other
categories is smaller than for process innovation.
In this section, we analyse the determinants of product
The successful introduction of product and process
and process innovations, as indicators of innovative perfor-
innovations is highly correlated. Table 3 reports the fre-
mance. In Section 5.3, we analyse their impact on the sales
quency of occurrence of the exclusive categories of firms:
growth of firms.
product innovators alone (PRODONLY), process innova-
Table 4 reports the results on innovative performance.
tors alone (PROCONLY), combined product and process
Columns (1) and (2) contain the bi-probit results on pro-
innovators (PPI) or none of both (NOPPI). Half of the
cess, respectively, product innovation. The marginal effects
firms (50%) introduce simultaneously product and process
of the explanatory variables are reported, which for the
dummy variables represents the change in the probability
resulting from a change of the binary variable from 0 to 1.
15
There was also information on whether firms had significantly
Columns (3) and (4) contain the results of the multinomial
improved products during the same period. If we define product innovat-
ing firms as those that introduced new or significantly improved products,
logit estimation, in marginal effects.
almost all companies – 94% – report themselves as product innovators, The bi-probit estimations reveal a strong and sig-
with very little difference between the different innovation strategies, nificant effect of innovative strategies on innovative
with the exception of the NoMake&NoBuy strategy, which “only” has
three quarters of these firms being able to introduce new or significantly
improved products. The high frequency of reporting introductions of
16
improved products makes this variable not useful for analysis. This is why Other Brazilian evidence, using the Brazilian innovation survey, found
we concentrate the remainder of the analysis on innovative performance process innovations to be the most common and relevant form of innova-
on process and new product innovations only. tions (De Negri et al., 2008).
524 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

Table 4
Results of the bi-probit and multinomial logit analyses explaining process and product innovation.

Bi-probit Multinomial

PRODUCT(1) PROCESS(2) PROCONLY(3) PRODUCT (=PRODONLY + PPI)(4)

LTL00 0.009 0.010 −0.010 0.009


(0.014) (0.013) (0.012) (0.014)
LFIRMAGE 0.013 −0.030 0.005 0.013
(0.022) (0.021) (0.019) (0.022)
MAKEONLY 0.116** 0.139*** 0.033 0.038
(0.047) (0.043) (0.058) (0.060)
BUYONLY 0.184*** 0.249*** 0.026 0.105**
(0.044) (0.040) (0.049) (0.052)
MAKEANDBUY 0.203*** 0.295*** 0.024 0.135***
(0.046) (0.044) (0.046) (0.052)
TECHLEADER 0.061** 0.112*** 0.006 0.058**
(0.029) (0.028) (0.025) (0.028)
TECHLAGGARD −0.000 −0.072** −0.009 0.002
(0.034) (0.036) (0.028) (0.034)
OVERDRAF 0.084*** 0.060** −0.046* 0.080***
(0.030) (0.030) (0.025) (0.029)
LFHIGH 0.275* −0.044 −0.190 0.265*
(0.050) (0.136) (0.131) (0.151)
LFSEC 0.110* 0.117* −0.043 0.107*
(0.063) (0.063) (0.051) (0.061)
GMHIGH 0.010 −0.067** −0.042* 0.009
(0.027) (0.027) (0.022) (0.027)
LTOTEXPER −0.026 0.025 0.005 −0.026
(0.024) (0.023) (0.020) (0.024)
ICT 0.102** 0.087* −0.016 0.100**
(0.051) (0.051) (0.039) (0.051)
TRAINING 0.030 0.094*** 0.031 0.028
(0.029) (0.030) (0.022) (0.028)
FORFIRMEXPER −0.004 −0.078 0.023 −0.005
(0.050) (0.051) (0.044) (0.050)
MNE −0.088 −0.065 −0.037 −0.085
(0.077) (0.072) (0.059) (0.082)
EXPORT 0.048 −0.000 −0.049 0.040
(0.033) (0.033) (0.026) (0.032)
FOREIGNSUPPLIER 0.038 0.048* −0.007 0.034
(0.026) (0.026) (0.021) (0.025)
COMPIMP 0.054 0.034 −0.021 0.053
(0.038) (0.038) (0.031) (0.036)
COMPPRESSPF 0.101** 0.028 −0.060* 0.094**
(0.041) (0.042) (0.032) (0.039)
COMPPRESSPD −0.037 −0.001 0.002 −0.037
(0.029) (0.028) (0.023) (0.028)
# observations 1563 1563 1563 1563

Marginal effects reported. Standard errors in parentheses; the estimation includes eight sector dummies and 12 geographical location dummies.
*
Significant at 10%.
**
Significant at 5%.
***
Significant at 1%.

performance. All innovative strategies, MakeOnly, BuyOnly nology embodied in equipment only. It compares well to
and Make&Buy, have significantly positive coefficients, a the findings of Peirano (2007) who concludes on the basis
result which appears robust across alternative specifica- of the Brazilian innovation survey that the acquisition of
tions. The marginal effects indicate a lower performance machinery and equipment predominates the innovation
of the MakeOnly strategy as compared to the BuyOnly and activities and finds the absorption of technology to prevail
Make&Buy strategy. The combination of Make&Buy has the over the creation of new knowledge, especially for process
highest effect on the probability that the firm is a success- innovations.
ful product or process innovator. This can be interpreted as Technology leading firms have a significantly higher
evidence in favor of complementarity, but the difference likelihood of successfully introducing new processes and
with the BuyOnly strategy is only minimal. Overall the data products (+11% and +6%, respectively), while technology
seems to suggest that for Brazilian manufacturing firms, it lagging firms have a significantly lower likelihood of intro-
is particularly the BUY strategy that is most associated with ducing process innovations (−7%). As this variable reflects
innovative performance, particularly for being successful in subjective self-reporting, correlated with innovativeness,
introducing process innovations. This result is robust to a we also checked the estimation without these variables on
more narrow definition for BUY, confined to buying tech- technology position. The results for the other determin-
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 525

ing variables, especially the innovation strategy variables, statistically significant. These favorable results are driven
remain unaffected and robust to the specification with or by the majority of cases who combine product and process
without technology position. innovations.18 For the category of process innovations only,
Financial constraints are a significant factor in the inno- there is no significant relationship with any type of innova-
vation process. Companies that are less financially con- tion strategy.19 The significance of the innovation strategy
strained, having overdraft facilities, are more likely to be variables in the bivariate probit results for PROCESS (col-
successful innovators. The effect from financial constraints umn (1)) therefore seems to come from those firms that
is stronger for product innovation (+8% against +6% for pro- combine their process innovations with product innova-
cess innovation). This is also found by Prochnik and Dias de tions. On the other determining factors, the multinomial
Araujo (2007) on the Brazilian innovation survey data. results confirm the importance of financial constraints,
On the different measures for absorptive capacity, the human capital formation and competition from foreign
results suggest that their effect depends on the type of firms for successful product innovations. In the category
innovation. For process innovation it is not the propor- of firms with only process innovations, we find a much
tion of employees with tertiary education that matters, more weaker profile of firms, as there are significantly more
but rather the share of secondary education workers and firms which are financially constrained, with lower skilled
even more significantly the provision of formal training managers and confined to local sales.
to them. This is reminiscent of the problems in Brazil’s
higher education system associated with being able to sup- 5.3. Multivariate analysis results on growth performance
ply quality skills in particularly sciences and engineering. A
general manager with graduate or postgraduate education Table 5 presents our results on sales growth. Our major
even adds negatively to innovative process performance. variable of interest is the effect of innovative performance
Product innovation on the contrary, appears to be more on sales growth. Simply including the PROCESS and PROD-
high-skill intensive, with larger shares of highly educated UCT dummy in the growth equation, as done in column (1),
employees (secondary, but also tertiary), raising the prob- or the exclusive categories, PRODONLY, PROCONLY, PPI, as
ability of being a product innovator. Raising the proportion done in column (2), may result in their coefficients being
of tertiary educated workers from zero to 20 for instance badly estimated, because of endogeneity and unobserved
increases the probability that the firm is a product innova- heterogeneity. As explained in the previous section, we
tor by 5%.17 The use of ICT (as measured through e-mail use a two step procedure in an attempt to improve our
connection) also adds to the probability of successfully estimation. The two-step procedure uses the predicted val-
introducing new products to the market (+10%), as well as ues of the innovative performance as instrument in the
new process innovations (+9%). growth regression. Column (3) uses the bivariate estima-
The variables on international linkages, as well as tions reported in columns (1) and (2) of Table 4, to construct
on competition, are weak in explaining innovative per- predicted values for PB PROCESS and PB PRODUCT or pre-
formance, in various alternative specifications. Only dicted values for PB PRODONLY, PB PROCONLY and PB PPI in
competitive pressure from foreign firms has a positive column (4). Column (5) of Table 5 reports the results as
and significant effect on the likelihood that firms develop derived from the multinomial logit presented in Table 4,
new products, raising it by 10%. Having foreign owner- columns (3) and (4) on the predicted exclusive categories:
ship (MNE) or foreign sales (DIRECTEXPORT), or facing process innovators alone (PM PROCONLY), product and/or
competition from imports, seems unrelated to innovative process innovators (PM PRODONLY/PPI) or none of both.
performance. Sourcing inputs from a foreign supplier raises Finally, we estimate a reduced form version of the model
the likelihood that a firm introduces new production pro- explaining growth directly by the innovation strategies:
cesses, but the effect is only significant at the 10% level. MakeOnly, BuyOnly and Make&Buy (column (6)).
This weak effect of global market forces may be specific for The results on growth performance confirm the signif-
Brazil, suggestive of the fact that still an important share icance of negative firm size and age effects as predicted
of firms remains sheltered from global market influences from the learning models. Small firms grow significantly
reminiscent of Brazil’s past industrialisation policies. The faster in Brazil than larger firms, but with significant evi-
findings are in contrast with those for other countries, such dence of non-linearity in the size effect, as indicated by the
as Almeida and Fernandes (2008). squared term. Also younger firms grow significantly faster,
The multinomial logit results confirm the significant especially the very youngest, but no significant interaction
and strong impact from having a technology BUY strat- effect between size and age prevails.
egy on the probability for successful product innovations, Our main variable of interest in the growth equa-
most typically combined with process innovations. Espe- tion is the innovation performance of the company. Do
cially the Make&Buy strategy gives the highest return, firms that introduce successfully new product and pro-
although the difference with the BuyOnly strategy is not

18
In the (not-reported) multinomial logit results for the 4 exclusive cat-
17
The mean proportion of workers with higher education is 0.08, with a egories, disentangling PRODONLY from PPI, the marginal effects results
standard deviation of 0.09, making this example coincide with the effect for the PPI category on the innovation strategy are even stronger in favor
about one standard deviation more and less than the mean proportion of the BUY strategy, particularly the Make&Buy option.
19
of high skilled workers. For secondary education, the mean proportion The insignificance of the marginal effects for the innovation strategy
among the labour force equals 0.23, SD 0.20. The effect here is a 2% variables in the PROCONLY category also holds in the multinomial logit
increase. results for the 4 exclusive categories, disentangling PRODONLY from PPI.
526 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

Table 5
Innovation and firm sales growth (2000–2002).

Effect of Effect of Predicted Predicted Predicted Reduced form


product and product and values from values from values from estimation
process process inno.; biprobit biprobit; multinomial;
innovation exclusive exclusive exclusive
categories categories categories
Dependent (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
variable: sales
growth 2000–2002

LSSAL −0.181*** −0.181*** −0.183*** −0.184*** −0.180*** −0.175***


(0.042) (0.042) (0.042) (0.042) (0.042) (0.042)
SLSSAL 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.004*** 0.005***
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
LFIRMAGE −0.314*** −0.314*** −0.320*** −0.320*** −0.323*** −0.316***
(0.069) (0.069) (0.068) (0.068) (0.068) (0.069)
SLAGE 0.030*** 0.029*** 0.030*** 0.030*** 0.029*** 0.030***
(0.010) (0.010) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.010)
SALES00AGE 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.007 0.006
(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)
PRODUCT 0.057
(0.036)
PROCESS 0.021
(0.014)
PRODONLY 0.018
(0.023)
PROCONLY 0.019
(0.022)
PPI 0.041**
(0.019)
PB PRODUCT 0.357***
(0.111)
PB PROCESS 0.014
(0.083)
PB PRODONLY 0.279
(0.180)
PB PROCONLY −0.071
(0.176)
PB PPI 0.348***
(0.077)
PM PROCONLY 0.035
(0.135)
PM PPI + PRODONLY 0.339***
(0.061)
MAKEONLY 0.044
(0.029)
BUYONLY 0.060**
(0.026)
MAKE&BUY 0.078***
(0.025)
OVERDRAF 0.065*** 0.065*** 0.034** 0.034** 0.038** 0.068***
(0.015) (0.015) (0.016) (0.016) (0.017) (0.015)
GMHIGH 0.030** 0.031** 0.020 0.020 0.022 0.029**
(0.014) (0.014) (0.015) (0.015) (0.015) (0.014)
MNE 0.057 0.058 0.075** 0.076** 0.072* 0.059
(0.037) (0.037) (0.037) (0.037) (0.037) (0.037)
EXPORT 0.047** 0.046** 0.034* 0.033* 0.037* 0.047**
(0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019)
CONSTANT 1.837*** 1.881*** 1.768*** 1.818*** 1.752*** 1.795***
(0.300) (0.300) (0.297) (0.311) (0.300) (0.300)
# observations 1503 1503 1503 1503 1503 1503
R-squared 0.14 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.15 0.14

The estimation includes eight sector dummies and 12 geographical location dummies. Standard errors in parentheses.
*
Significant at 10%.
**
Significant at 5%.
***
Significant at 1%.
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 527

cess innovations also reap the benefits of this in terms development, where the interplay between diffusion (buy)
of larger sales growth? When we separately include PRO- and creation (make) of new technologies, shapes innova-
CESS and PRODUCT in the growth equation, the results (not tion and growth performance. With a large internal market
reported) are positive and significant for each of them. But and mixed legacy of protectionism and international open-
when including product and process innovation jointly as ness, it is also a specific case to analyse the importance of
explanatory variables (column (1)), none of the innova- international linkages for innovation and growth.
tion performance variables show up as being significantly There are a number of interesting findings that appear
related to sales growth. The high occurrence of firms doing to be robust across specifications. First, like in many
both product and process innovation is responsible for this developing countries, also in Brazil, innovation strategies
effect, and requires the investigation of exclusive inno- involve mostly technology acquisition, by acquiring know-
vation categories: process innovators alone (PROCONLY), how embodied in machinery and equipment, exclusively
product innovators alone (PRODONLY), combined product but also substantially, in combination with own internal
and process innovators (PPI) with none of both the refer- development. Secondly, innovative strategies contribute
ence category (column (2)). Only those firms that combine significantly to being able to introduce successfully new
successful product innovations with process innovations innovations. For both process and product innovation the
realize a significantly higher sales growth, supportive of technology buy strategy is dominant, with some weak evi-
the complementarity between both types of innovations. dence on complementarities for firms combining make and
These results are confirmed in the two-step estima- buy strategies. The option of relying on internal develop-
tions: only the bivariately predicted PRODUCT innovations, ment only is clearly less effective. The positive link between
rather than the PROCESS innovations, are significantly an innovation make and/or buy strategy and innovative
related to sales growth (column (3)). This is due to the performance, only holds for product innovations, either
firms combining product and process innovations as the exclusively or in combination with process innovations.
results using the bivariate predictions to construct exclu- None of the innovative strategies are of significant effect
sive categories, indicate (column (4)). Also the multinomial for firms which are only involved in process innovations.
predictions support the lack of effects on sales growth What is needed in terms of human capital is also surpris-
from introducing only process innovations, reminiscent of ing: a large share of workers with secondary education is
the cost cutting/restructuring story behind pure process very important for process innovations. It does not require
innovations. Only the introduction of product innovations, a tertiary skilled workforce to be a successful process
exclusively, but mostly done in combination with pro- innovator in Brazil. Product innovation is more high-skill
cess innovations, translates into significantly higher sales intensive, needing higher shares of highly (university) edu-
growth (column (5)). cated workers, a highly educated management and ICT
When directly relating the innovation strategies to usage for communicating with the market. This suggests
firm’s growth, rather than the innovation performance that product innovation, in comparison to process inno-
(column (6)), we find that the technology BUY strategy is vation, is a more complex process with multiple inputs
significantly related to firm growth, particularly, although requiring more advanced knowledge inputs and absorptive
not significantly more, when combined with a technology capacity.
MAKE strategy. An innovation strategy of MakeOnly fails to Product innovation also translates into superior sales
significantly translate in higher sales growth. This is not so growth rates. This is particularly so when it is combined
surprising, as both the BuyOnly and Make&Buy strategies with process innovation. Process innovation alone without
were found to positively effect the successful introduction the introduction of new products runs the risk of being
of product innovations, particularly the combined prod- ineffective to boost higher growth. It is indeed possible
uct and process innovations (see Table 4) and the latter that the benefits of more cost efficient production are only
were found to translate into higher sales growth (columns reaped after an initial period of restructuring, beyond what
(1)–(5) in Table 5). we can measure with our data set. Alternative measures,
With respect to other flanking conditions for growth, such as productivity, productivity growth, or profitability,
the results confirm the strong, significant and robust effect may capture the beneficial influence of process innovation
of short term credit constraints on growth. Also prior more rapidly.
exporting experience is systematically and robustly related Another robust factor driving innovative and growth
to higher growth rates. Other variables on foreign linkages performance is access to finance. This supports policy inter-
and absorptive capacity are not consistently significant ventions to alleviate the financial constraints, by improving
across specifications. financial market functioning and/or providing financial
incentives.
6. Conclusions Finally, our results on international linkages are some-
what mixed. International openness is important for
Using data from the World Bank’s Investment Climate stimulating innovative and growth performance, but this
Survey (ICS) data collected in Brazil in 2003 for manufac- openness works particularly through competition and
turing sectors, this paper tries to contribute to the literature access to markets, but not necessarily as a mechanism for
on technological progress and development by bringing technology absorption improving innovative performance.
on board a micro-econometric perspective on the factors Again this can be related to the specifics of the Brazilian
determining innovative performance and firm growth. Our case, which has for a long time protected local champions
focus on Brazil allows analysing the case of a country in fast in its policies.
528 M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529

Appendix A.

Table A1
Definition of variables.

Sales growth 2000–2002 Average annual sales growth over the period 2000–2002, calculated by
(ln(sales2002) − ln(sales2000))/2
PROCESS =1 if the firm successful introduced new technology that has substantially
changed the way the main product is produced, in 1998–2002
PRODUCT =1 if the firm successfully developed a major new product line in 1998–2002
Firm characteristics (X)
LFIRMAGE Age of the firm, in logarithmic terms 2.68 (0.80)
LTL00 Size of the firm, measured by number of employees in 2000, in log 3.91 (1.15)
Innovation strategy (I)
MAKEONLY =1 if firm reports ‘in-house development’ as major way of acquiring new 0.12
technology, not ‘embodied in machinery, hiring key personnel, licensing’
BUYONLY =1 if firm reports ‘new technology embodied in machinery’, the ‘hiring of key 0.34
personnel’ or ‘licensing of technology’ as major ways of acquiring new
technology; not ‘developed in-house’
MAKEANDBUY =1 if firm reports both ‘in-house development’ and ‘embodied in machinery’ or 0.46
‘hiring key personnel’ or ‘licensing’ as major ways of acquiring new technology
The technology position of the firm in its market (T)
TECHLEADER =1 if the firm reports that his technology is more advanced than that of its 0.24
main competitors
TECHLAGGARD =1 if the firm reports that his technology is less advanced than that of its main 0.15
competitors
Absorptive capacity (AC), as measured through various proxies
LFHIGH Proportion of the labour force with higher education [0,1] 0.08 (0.09)
LFSEC Proportion of the labour force with secondary education as highest level 0.23 (0.20)
attained [0,1]
GMHIGH =1 if the firm has a general manager with a graduate or postgraduate degree or 0.51
diploma of tertiary college
LTOTEXPER Total number of years of experience of the manager working in this industry, 2.46 (0.69)
in log terms
ICT =1 if the firm uses a email to interact with clients and suppliers 0.92
TRAINING =1 if the firm offers formal training to its employees 0.67
Foreign linkages (F)
FORFIRMEXPER =1 if the manager has previously acquired working experience in the same 0.08
industry, in a foreign firm
MNE =1 if the firm‘s principal shareholder is a foreign company 0.04
EXPORT =1 if the firm is a direct exported prior to 2000 0.27
FOREIGNSUPPLIER =1 if the firm sources its main supply or inputs from foreign owned firms 0.40
Competition (C)
COMPIMP =1 if for the firm’s main product the main competitor is an imported product 0.13
COMPPRESSPF =1 if firm reports that the most important influence/pressure to develop new 0.09
products are foreign competitors
COMPPRESSPD =1 if firm reports that the most important influence/pressure to develop new 0.24
products are domestic competitors
Financial constraints (FIN)
OVERDRAFT =1 if the firm has an overdraft facility with a formal bank 0.74

References Blalock, G., Gertler, P., 2009. How firm capabilities affect who benefits from
foreign technology. Journal of Development Economics 90, 192–199.
Abramovitz, M., 1986. Catching up, forging ahead and falling behind. Jour- Blömstrom, M., 1986. Foreign investment and productive efficiency: the
nal of Economic History 46 (2), 386–406. case of Mexico. Journal of Industrial Economics 37, 315–328.
Aghion, P., Howitt, P., 1998. Endogenous Growth Theory. MIT Press, Cam- Blomström, M., Kokko, A., 1998. Multinational corporations and spillovers.
bridge, MA, 694 pp. Journal of Economic Surveys 12 (3), 247–277.
Aitken, B., Harrison, A., 1999. Do domestic firms benefit from foreign direct Blömstrom, M., Persson, H., 1983. FDI and spillover efficiency in under-
investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic Review developed economy: evidence from Mexico. World Development 11,
89 (3), 605–618. 493–501.
Almeida, R., Fernandes, A.M., 2008. Openness and technological inno- Bodas Freitas, A.M., Clausen, T., Fontana, R., Verspagen, B., 2008. For-
vations in developing countries: evidence from firm-level surveys. mal and informal external linkages and firms’ innovative strategies. A
Journal of Development Studies 44, 701–727. cross-country comparison, UNU-MERIT Working Paper 2008-065.
Bastos, F., Nasir, J., 2004. Productivity and the investment climate: what Cassiolato, J., Lastres, H., Maciel, M.L., 2003. Systems of Innovation and
matters most? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3335. Development. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd, Cheltenham, UK.
Bell, M., Pavitt, K., 1995. The development of technological capabilities. In: Chudnovsky, D., López, A., Pupato, G., 2006. Innovation and productivity
Haque, I. (Ed.), Trade, Technology and International Competitiveness. in developing countries: a study of Argentine manufacturing firms’
World Bank, Washington, DC. behaviour (1992–2001). Research Policy 35, 266–288.
Benavente, J.M., 2006. The role of research and innovation in promoting Coe, D., Helpman, E., Hoffmaister, A., 1997. North-south R&D spillovers.
productivity in Chile. In: Hall, B., Mairesse, J. (Guest Eds.), Empirical The Economic Journal 107, 134–149.
Studies of Innovation in the Knowledge Driven Economy. Economics Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces
of Innovation and New Technologies 15, 301–315. of R&D. Economic Journal 99, 569–596.
M. Goedhuys, R. Veugelers / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2012) 516–529 529

Crépon, B., Duguet, E., Mairesse, J., 1998. Research, innovation and pro- Markusen, J.R., Venables, A.J., 1999. Foreign direct investment as a catalyst
ductivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of for industrial development. European Economic Review 43, 335–356.
Innovation and New Technology 7, 115–158. Miravete, E., Pernias, J., 2006. Innovation complementarity and scale of
De Brito Cruz, C., de Mello, L., 2006. Boosting innovation performance in production. Journal of Industrial Economics 54, 1–29.
Brazil. OECD Economic Department Working Paper 532. Narula, R., Dunning, J., 2000. Industrial development, globalisation and
De Negri, J., Turchi, L.M. (Eds.), 2007. Technological Innovation in Brazilian multinational enterprises: new realities for developing countries.
and Argentine Firms. IPEA, Brasilia. Oxford Development Studies 28 (2).
De Negri, F., Araujo, B.C., De Negri, J.A., 2008. Channels of international Nelson, R. (Ed.), 1993. National Systems of Innovation: A Comparative
technology transfer in Brazilian industrial firms. In: Paper Presented Study. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
at the Second MEIDE Conference , Beijing. Nelson, R., Winter, S.G., 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.
Dollar, D., Hallward-Driemeier, M., Menigstae, T., 2003. Investment Cli- Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
mate and Firm Performance in Developing Countries. Mimeo the OECD, 2006. Economic Surveys: Brazil, vol. 18.
World Bank Development Research Group, 42 pp. Pakes, A., Ericson, R., 1998. Empirical implications of alternative models
Eifert, B., Gelb, A., Ramachandran, V., 2005. Business environment and of firm dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory 79, 1–45.
comparative advantage in Africa: evidence from the investment cli- Peirano, F., 2007. Technological change in the manufacturing sectors of
mate data. Center for Global Development, Working Paper 56. Argentina and Brazil: an analysis based on innovation surveys 2007.
Enos, J., 1992. The Creation of Technological Capabilities in Developing In: De Negri, J., Turchi, L.M. (Eds.), Technological Innovation in Brazil-
Countries. Pinter, London. ian and Argentine Firms. IPEA, Brasilia.
Evans, D.E., 1987. The relationship between firm growth, size and age: Pérez, P., Dutrénit, G., Barceinas, F., 2005. Actividad Innovadora y
estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Eco- Desempeño Económico: un análisis econométrico del caso mexicano.
nomics 35, 567–582. In: Albornoz, M., Ratto, D. (Eds.), Indicadores de Ciencia y Tecnología
Fagerberg, J., Srholec, M., 2008. National innovation systems, capabilities en Iberoamerica. Agenda. , pp. 299–318.
and economic development. Research Policy 37, 1417–1435. Prochnik, V., Dias de Araujo, R., 2007. A comparison of the technological
Fagerberg, J., Srholec, M., Knell, M., 2007. The competitiveness of nations: strategies of the less productive Argentine and Brazilian firms. In: De
why some countries prosper, while others fall behind. World Devel- Negri, J., Turchi, L.M. (Eds.), Technological Innovation in Brazilian and
opment 35 (10), 1595–1620. Argentine Firms. IPEA, Brasilia.
Görg, H., Greenaway, D., 2003. Much ado about nothing? Do domestic Raffo, J., Lhuillery, S., Miotti, L., 2008. Northern and southern innovativ-
firms really benefit from FDI? Mimeo. ity: a comparison across European and Latin American countries. The
Grossman, G., Helpman, E., 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global European Journal of Development Research 20, 219–239.
Economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Romer, P., 1994. The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of Economic
Hoekman, B., Smarzynska Javorcik, B. (Eds.), 2006. Global Integration and Perspectives 8, 3–22.
Technology Transfer. Palgrave Mac Millan, New York. Sleuwaegen, L., Goedhuys, M., 2002. Growth of firms in developing coun-
Hoekman, B.K., Maskus, K., Saggi, K., 2005. Transfer of technology to devel- tries, evidence from Côte d’Ivoire. Journal of Development Economics
oping countries: unilateral and multilateral policy options. World 68, 117–135.
Development 33 (10), 1587–1602. Solow, R., 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quar-
Jovanovic, B., 1982. Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica terly Journal of Economics 70 (1), 65–94.
50, 649–670. Srholec, M., Verspagen, B., 2008. The voyage of the beagle in innovation
Katz, J. (Ed.), 1987. Technology Generation in Latin America. MacMillan, systems land. Explorations on sectors, innovation, heterogeneity and
London. selection, TIK Working Paper on Innovation Studies 20080220. Uni-
Kim, L., 1997. Imitation to Innovation: The Dynamics of Korea’s Techno- versity of Oslo.
logical Learning. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge. Szapiro, M., 2003. Downgrading local capabilities in IT: the telecom inno-
Kmenta, J., 1997. Elements of Econometrics. The University of Michigan vation system in Campinas. In: Cassiolato, J., Lastres, H., Maciel, M.L.
Press, 786 pp. (Eds.), Systems of Innovation and Development. Edward Elgar Pub-
Kokko, A., 1994. Technology, market characteristics and spillovers. Journal lishing Ltd, Cheltenham, UK.
of Development Economics 43, 279–293. Veugelers, R., Cassiman, B., 2004. Foreign subsidiaries as channel of inter-
Lall, S., 1992. Technological capabilities and industrialisation. World national technology diffusion: some direct firm level evidence from
Development 20, 165–186. Belgium. European Economic Review 48, 455–476.
Lugones, G., Suarez, D., 2007. National innovation systems in Brazil and World Bank, 2005. Brazil Investment Climate Assessment, vol. II. Mimeo,
Argentina: key variables and available evidence. In: De Negri, J., Turchi, The World Bank, Washington, DC, 278 pp.
L.M. (Eds.), Technological Innovation in Brazilian and Argentine Firms. World Bank, 2008. Global Economic Prospects 2008, Technology Diffusion
IPEA, Brasilia. in the Developing World. The World Bank, Washington, DC, 201 pp.

You might also like