1-s2.0-S0038012123002124-main-Incentives For Local Government Expenditures

You might also like

You are on page 1of 9

Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Socio-Economic Planning Sciences


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/seps

Incentives for local government expenditures on people’s livelihood: the


role of high-speed rail
Xia Meng a, Tao Ding a, Haisen Wang b, c, *
a
School of Economics and Management, China University of Geosciences, Wuhan, 430074, China
b
Economics and Management School, Wuhan University, Wuhan, 430072, China
c
Research Center of Yangtze River Economic Belt Development, Wuhan University, Wuhan, 430072, China

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Can high-speed rail (HSR) lines create effective incentives for local governments to supply public goods for
High-speed rail people’s livelihood? This paper builds a time-varying difference-in-differences (TVDID) model and uses
Market access 2002–2018 Chinese data. The empirical results show that HSR enhances the fiscal responsiveness of local gov­
Human capital
ernments and creates effective incentives for local governments’ expenditures on education and medical/health
Government capacity
Basic public services
care; however, this “HSR effect” does not significantly influence expenditures on social security or employment.
The mechanism analysis shows that HSR has a significant amplification effect on interregional competition,
specifically in terms of market access and human capital agglomeration. Notably, the opening of HSR lines forms
a new “incentive-constraint” mechanism for local governments to supply public services for people’s livelihood
from both the supply and demand sides, and the fiscal and administrative capacities of local governments can
strengthen the influence of HSR lines on the supply of public goods for people’s livelihood.

1. Introduction effect” [5], and improved the efficiency of population flow between
cities with stations [6]. Thus, China is further meeting residents’ de­
Improving the quality and level of the public service supply by local mand for basic public services across regions, breaking the regional
governments and realizing basic public service equity are the core boundaries and spatial dimensions of people’s access to basic public
propositions for social governance by local governments in China. Since services, and effectively improving the accessibility of basic public
the reform and opening up, China’s economic development has made services.
remarkable achievements, and basic public services for people’s liveli­ The construction of high-speed rail brings about rapid flow and ex­
hood have comprehensively improved. However, there is still a struc­ change of resources such as people, finance and technology, which can
tural imbalance in the allocation of resources for education, medical and reduce the cost of factor flow and improve the rate of factor flow [7,8]. It
health care, and social security between urban and rural areas, showing is conducive to improving the efficiency of resource allocation across
obvious spatial dimensions and differences and, in the supply and equity regions and achieving national efficiency goals and regional equality
of basic public services, becoming a challenge for governance by local goals in a coordinated manner, with significant network and structural
governments. In recent years, China has continued to expand household effects. HSR lines improve the accessibility of cities, strengthen the
registration system reform, and liberalized and relaxed various types of connection between cities that serve as transportation hubs, and accel­
requirements for urban household registration. In doing so, China has erate regional market integration, which enables the sharing and
effectively facilitated social mobility, enhanced the incentives for resi­ diffusion of basic public service resources within the same network,
dents to seek high-quality basic public services [1], and raised residents’ generates positive spillover effects, and enhances overall welfare,
expectations of improved welfare levels. In particular, the rapid devel­ demonstrating a network effect. Furthermore, Institutional constraints
opment of high-speed rail (HSR) in China in recent years has greatly such as the household registration and land systems and government
changed the pattern of relative locations between cities [2,3], effectively intervention and control have resulted in the artificial market segmen­
shortened the spatial and temporal distance of travel, strengthened the tation [9]. However, HSR breaks regional administrative divisions and
linkages between cities [4], generated a significant “traffic creation market segmentation, reduces transaction costs and time costs, and

* Corresponding author.Economics and Management School, Wuhan University, Wuhan, 430072, China
E-mail address: hswang@whu.edu.cn (H. Wang).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2023.101700
Received 20 June 2023; Accepted 10 August 2023
Available online 11 August 2023
0038-0121/© 2023 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

changes the direction of interregional factor mobility and residents’ breaks the regional division of regional basic public service resources
location preferences for basic public service choices, leading to the and creates new commuters [5,6] and demanders of basic public ser­
divergence of individual benefits and costs from social benefits and costs vices. The opening of HSR lines has a significant “spatiotemporal
and resulting in a structural effect. At the factor competition level, the convergence” effect, providing a new channel for “cross-border” resi­
opening of HSR lines promotes market integration, strengthens regional dents to access basic public service resources such as regional education
competition effects and learning spillover effects [10], intensifies and medical care [13]. To a certain extent, improvements in the trans­
interregional competition based on mobility factors, and creates effec­ portation environment enhance the advantages of regional public ser­
tive incentives for livelihood expenditures by local governments. At the vice resources, which in turn promote the reselection of residential areas
public service demand level, the opening of HSR lines promotes the by different groups based on their needs for public service resources,
agglomeration, selection, and sorting effects of residents’ demand for causing changes in the spatial pattern of residents’ demand for basic
basic public services [11], which leads to a mismatch between the public services [14,15]. Specifically, for cities with high levels of basic
supply and demand of basic public service resources allocated on the public services and large populations, the radial connection and transfer
basis of rigid administrative divisions and thus generates constraints on effect of HSR creates more public service demanders, and in the short
local governments’ livelihood expenditures. The differences in the social term, urban public service resources are likely to be in short supply due
governance capacity of local governments, especially differences in the to excessive demand, which in turn causes a “congestion” of public
fiscal and administrative capacities of local governments, cause signif­ services and a decrease in utility. In contrast, cities with low levels of
icant heterogeneity in the responses of local governments to the com­ basic public services and small populations have difficulty scaling public
bined effects of these two types of capacity, resulting in a structural service resources due to the transfer effect of HSR. However, some re­
imbalance and a loss of efficiency in the supply of public service re­ searchers have shown that over time, the opening of HSR lines leads to
sources. Under conditions of regional openness, what is the influence of an increase in the spatial density of populations living in central cities
the opening of HSR lines on the fiscal behaviour of local governments? Is and the development of employment opportunities and economic ac­
the opening of HSR lines conducive to the formation of new incentives tivities along more scattered paths, creating decentralized economic
for livelihood expenditures by local governments? spaces and new development corridors [16]. The allocation of basic
To answer these questions, this study constructs a complete frame­ public service resources among cities needs to follow this trend.
work to explore the influence of the opening of HSR lines on the fiscal Accordingly, this paper proposes hypothesis 1: the opening of HSR
responsiveness of local governments and the corresponding mechanism lines will help increase local government expenditures on public goods
(fiscal responsiveness is the extent to which residents’ public goods for people’s livelihood.
preferences and needs respond to government public expenditure de­ Under a system of fiscal decentralization, there are fiscal competition
cisions) to provide an important reference for optimizing the spatial and promotion incentives among local governments, making production
allocation and equity of basic public services in new development stages. expenditures more likely and thus resulting in insufficient livelihood
Compared with previous studies, this study makes the following con­ expenditures. Due to the differences in development stages and the types
tributions. First, on the basis of the allocation of public resources based of government responsibility in various regions [17], there are signifi­
on rigid administrative divisions, this study introduces HSR as an cant regional disparities in the allocation of basic public service re­
exogenous shock factor to analyse the influence of the opening of HSR sources [1]. From the perspective of the transportation infrastructure
lines on local governments’ livelihood expenditures and responsiveness, itself, HSR allows basic public services in various regions to coexist in a
providing a new perspective for local governments to strengthen and spatial network, with significant externalities and income redistribution
optimize the supply of public services and to promote basic public ser­ effects. The mechanism of the influence of HSR on local governments’
vice equity. Second, this study analyses the amplification effect of the livelihood expenditures is mainly reflected in the incentive mechanism
opening of HSR lines on regional competition. The opening of HSR lines formed by competition among local governments and the constraint
promotes interregional competition, with market access and human mechanism formed by population flow. The opening of HSR lines is
capital agglomeration as important mediating mechanisms. Local gov­ conducive to enhancing local spatial advantages, effectively increasing
ernments use more competitive strategies for livelihood expenditures, the capacity of other modes of transportation, reducing transaction
and the fiscal and administrative capacities of local governments are costs, narrowing the price gap between regions, significantly improving
important factors affecting expenditure intensity, providing new in­ market access, increasing the scale of trade [18], accelerating the
centives for improving the fiscal responsiveness of local governments. interregional mobility and spatial reallocation of factors such as finan­
Third, based on the “HSR effect,” a policy balance for the social gover­ cial capital and human capital, expanding the degree of economic
nance of local governments is proposed to achieve a balance between integration [19], and promoting spatial spillovers and competition ef­
enhancing urban competitiveness and meeting residents’ basic public fects. Furthermore, improvements in urban accessibility enhance the
service needs, providing a new path for enhancing the governance ca­ efficiency of population flow, which may generate employment, hous­
pacity and level of local governments. ing, and innovation corridors, accelerate market integration and the
spatial transfer of residents’ demand for basic public services, increase
2. Literature review the demand density of cities that serve as transportation hubs, and form
a rigid constraint on local governments’ livelihood expenditures.
New economic geography theory states that the spatial agglomera­ The opening of HSR lines enhances the competitiveness of cities and
tion of economic activities promotes the development of cities and the further intensifies interregional competition, but the incentive-
flow of public service resources to central regions. In a heterogeneous constraints generated for different cities are different, resulting in
space, there is a large gap between the level of economic development different competition effects [20] and substantially affecting the stra­
and the supply capacity of basic public services, with the emergence of tegic behaviour of local governments’ livelihood expenditures.
certain regional boundaries. The “spatial devouring” effect and spatial Increasing public expenditures is an important strategy for governments
correlation effect of the HSR network greatly reduce the regional to compete for the tax base of working capital and human capital, and
boundaries of basic public services in different regions and amplify the governments choose the appropriate combination of fiscal revenue and
influence and range of central cities. In the process of spatial agglom­ expenditures based on factors such as the preferences of the public to
eration and the diffusion of basic public service resources, trans­ retain and attract tax-paying residents and enterprises. Dziuda et al. [21]
portation infrastructure is both a prerequisite for spatial agglomeration argue that with the changing socioeconomic environment, the social
and a condition for the spatial diffusion of advantageous regions [12]. costs arising from the insufficient supply of public goods for people’s
According to transport creation theory, the “transfer effect” of HSR livelihood increase continuously, and the combination of capital and

2
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

highly skilled labour is changing the competition mode of government above analysis ignores the key institutional feature of the government’s
expenditures from low taxes and public inputs that favour material ability to implement policies. Bellofatto and Besfamille [1] incorporate
capital to low taxes and goods for people’s livelihood that balance ma­ the administrative and fiscal capacities of local governments into their
terial and human capital inputs. However, some studies have also noted analytical framework to investigate the optimal degree of fiscal decen­
that competition among local governments distorts the structure of local tralization under different local government capacities and the condi­
government expenditures, with an increase in production expenditures tions for achieving the effective provision of local public services. China
and a decrease in livelihood expenditures. Wang et al. [22] point out employs a government-led governance model. The governance behav­
that the competition among regions to attract investment projects iour of local governments directly determines the economic and social
indeed leads to the rapid development of developing economies, but the development of the areas under their jurisdiction [35], and the differ­
excessive use of incentives by local governments to attract foreign in­ ences in the capacity of local governments form a new constraint on the
vestment results in a serious lack of livelihood public services. Zodrow supply of public goods for people’s livelihood. Currently, there are sig­
and Mieszkowski [23] use a game model of tax competition to show that, nificant differences in the degree of fiscal decentralization and fiscal
assuming the local public goods budget comes from the capital tax imbalance among different cities in China as well as differences in social
revenue within a jurisdiction, local tax competition leads to a sharp governance capacity, such as the lack of government responsibility [17]
decrease in local fiscal revenue and an inadequate supply of public and the selectivity of a vertical co-response to central policies. Despite
goods. Keen and Marchand [24] also argue that tax competition among the influence of China’s economic transition and its objective institu­
local governments leads to a systematic distortion of the expenditure tional conditions, the differences in the subjective and objective factors
structure. That is, in the entire public expenditure structure, public input of local governments are still important causes of the heterogeneity in
expenditures into the enterprise production function increase, and the quality and level of basic public service provision.
public goods expenditures into the household utility function decrease. Therefore, this paper proposes hypothesis 3: the administrative ca­
Furthermore, the higher the level of competition within local govern­ pacity and financial capacity of local governments can regulate the
ment is, the greater the likelihood of the formation of a structure with a relationship between HSR and local government expenditures on public
bias towards production expenditures. The interregional “fiscal goods. Fig. 1 shows the path of the influence of the opening of HSR lines
competition mechanism” and the “scale competition effect” intensify on the bias of local governments’ livelihood expenditures.
intergovernmental competition, leading to an imbalance in the inter­
regional public goods supply structure and triggering the free-riding 3. Research design
behaviour of neighbouring regions and the implementation of substi­
tution strategies for fiscal expenditures [25]. Although the market 3.1. Econometric model setting
environment from segmentation to integration is conducive to the for­
mation of regional spillover benefits of livelihood expenditures, do the To evaluate the influence of the opening of HSR lines on local gov­
incentives for and constraints on the opening of HSR lines with respect ernments’ livelihood expenditures, this study treats the opening of HSR
to the supply of goods for people’s livelihood go beyond the influence of lines as a quasi-natural experiment and uses a time-varying difference-
a “fiscal competition mechanism” and the “scale competition effect”? Do in-differences (TVDID) model for analysis. This model establishes dif­
local governments positively respond to the livelihood needs (e.g., ed­ ferences with respect to time and group to remove common trends and
ucation and health care) of “HSR migrants”? Currently, effective individual heterogeneity and to allow for the presence of confounding
empirical research and countermeasures are lacking. Overall, there is factors that do not change over time. It reveals the net influence by
still no consensus on the net influence of the opening of HSR lines on comparing the changes of two groups across the same period; thus, the
local governments’ livelihood expenditures. key to this model is distinguishing between the treatment and control
Therefore, this paper proposes hypothesis 2: competition among groups. The control group can present counterfactual results with
local governments has a mediating role, which is embodied in the respect to the treatment group. The following baseline model is set:
competition over market access and human capital. ∑
Systematic research and empirical evidence are needed to under­ Epgit = β0 + β1 Hsrit + βXit + μt + vi + εit (1)
stand the differences in the responsiveness of local governments to the
opening of HSR lines. With China’s fiscal decentralization system as the Where i represents the city; t represents the year; Epg is the dependent
basis, numerous studies have analysed the causes of and incentives for variable, including Total, Education, Security and Medical); Hsrit is the
the “absence” of local fiscal expenditures on people’s livelihood [26] as core independent variable, with Hsrit = 1 when an HSR line was opened
well as the environment and mode of government behaviour [17] from in city i in year t and Hsrit = 0 otherwise; X is the control variable at the
the perspectives of fiscal competition, transfer payments [27], and city level; μt represents year fixed effects; vi represents individual fixed
promotion incentives [28,29]. Some studies have also noted the exter­ effects, which are used to control for the influence of omitted variables
nalities and spatial spillover effects of transportation infrastructure such that do not vary by year and city; and ε is the random error term.
as HSR, but research on the causes of the differences in the influence of
the opening of HSR lines on local fiscal responsiveness has not been 3.2. Variable
adequately conducted. There are differences in the influence of the
opening of HSR lines on local governments with different levels of 3.2.1. Explained variable (Epg)
economic development, financial resources, and social governance ca­ Fiscal expenditure is an important indicator that reflects the incre­
pabilities. That is, some local governments positively respond to the mental fiscal responsiveness of a city. This study uses Epg to represent
spatial transfer of the demand for public services from HSR, and other the government’s preference for public goods expenditure on people’s
local governments have imbalances in their fiscal expenditure structure, livelihood, including total expenditure bias (Total) and structural bias
showing varying degrees of distortion [30,31]. The reason may be that (Education, Security and Medical). Total is the total bias towards liveli­
when providing local basic public services, local governments often face hood expenditures, which is expressed as the ratio of the proportion of
a “vertical fiscal imbalance,” which can be compensated for by transfer the total livelihood expenditures of a city to the proportion of the total
payments provided by the central government or circumvented by national livelihood expenditures. Taking Total as an example, the
decentralizing taxation power to local governments [1]. In practice, calculation formula is as follows:
both paths generate different negative externalities, which have been
analysed in numerous studies based on different degrees of fiscal
decentralization [32,33]. Bardhan and Mookherjee [34] argue that the

3
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

Fig. 1. The path of the influence of HSR on the bias towards expenditures on livelihood public goods.

/( / ) 3.2.3. Mediating variables


∑ ∑ (2)
n n
Totalit = (publicit /financeit ) publicit financeit
i=1 i=1
3.2.3.1. Market access (Mk). In international trade models, a reduction
Among them, public represents the sum of education expenditures, in trade costs leads to an increase in the actual income level in the
medical and health care and family planning expenditures, and social trading region and is an important aspect of factor competition in
security and employment expenditures in a city; thus, public represents various regions. The reduction in trade costs caused by the opening of
the total financial expenditures of the city. The denominator represents HSR lines can effectively reflect the influence of HSR on the welfare of
the proportion of the total national people’s livelihood expenditures in residents and reflect the responsiveness of local governments to factor
the national fiscal expenditures. The formula measures the deviation competition. This study uses market access (Mk) as a proxy variable.
between the proportion of urban people’s livelihood expenditures and Drawing lessons from the research of Donaldson and Hornbeck [36], the
the average national people’s livelihood expenditures; the larger the market access caused by HSR is measured. That is, assuming that the
value is, the more the local government tends to spend on public goods trade cost will have an impact on a city’s market size, under the premise
for people’s livelihood. Education, Security and Medical are the govern­ that the geographic distance between two cities is maintained, the
ment’s preference for spending on public goods such as education, social impact value is θ. The calculation formula is as follows:
security and employment, and medical and health care and family ∑
Mkit = κ−ij ε gdpj (3)
planning, respectively. Salinas and Solé-Ollé [26] show that there is a j
monotonic relationship between local fiscal responsiveness and the fis­
cal expenditure structure. Therefore, this study uses the ratios of the Mk represents the market access of a city, and κ represents the trans­
proportions of a city’s expenditures on education (Education), medical portation cost between city i and city j. This article sets the HSR speed to
and health care and family planning (Medical), and social security and 250 km/h, and the operating cost is 0.43 yuan/km. Based on the
employment (Security) to the proportions of the corresponding national straight-line distance matrix between cities and the HSR fare cost, the
average expenditures. The calculation formula is the same as that for distance matrix and cost matrix are constructed to calculate the trans­
Total. portation cost. ε measures a city’s trade potential and is directly pro­
portional to the city’s comparative advantage. The larger its value is, the
3.2.2. Core explanatory variable (Hsr) more trade the city can attract. Therefore, different assignments will
The subjects of this study are prefecture-level cities and above. The result in different levels of market access. Related studies involving ε did
cities where HSR stations have been established since 2008 were ob­ not give an authoritative degree of assignment, but Donaldson and
tained from the China Railway Yearbook and the China Railway Cor­ Hornbeck [36] modelled that the reasonable range of ε was between
poration website, and the cities that have stations for intercity HSR and 3.37 and 13.18. In existing studies, ε was often assigned a value of 3.6 or
non-intercity HSR were obtained from the framework of the “eight 4 [18]. Accordingly, this paper also assigns a value of 3.6 for ε and uses
north-south and eight west-east” main corridors identified in the Me­ the market access level calculated when ε = 4 as a robustness test. Mk is
dium- and Long-Term Railway Network Plan (with adjustment in 2016). inversely proportional to transportation costs and directly proportional
Intercity HSR refers to HSR lines planned and constructed within to market size. Therefore, the larger the calculated market access is, the
neighbouring cities or city clusters. It is designed based on both the lower the trade transaction cost caused by HSR.
“Code for the Design of Intercity Railways” and “Code for the Design of
High-Speed Railways.” It has shorter operating routes and operating 3.2.3.2. Human capital (Hci). Although some studies use the number of
shifts. Moreover, the operating speed is not less than 250 km/h, high school graduates to measure the level of human capital at the
generally with only 2–5 neighbouring cities at close distances. The first regional level, Morkutė and Koster [37] note that the human capital
intercity HSR identified in this article began on December 16, 2007, and externalities associated with an increase in the educational attainment
the Beijing-Tianjin intercity train opened on June 8, 2008. Non-intercity of high school students are far from those of college graduates and that
HSR refers to the design based solely on the “Code for the Design of the human capital externalities are derived from the agglomeration of
High-Speed Railways.” It has a larger service range, longer operating highly skilled labour. Therefore, drawing on the studies of Diamond
lines, and longer distances between stations. In this study, because the [38] and Liang and Lu [39], the logarithm of the number of college
speed of the Qinhuangdao-Shenyang Passenger Line, which opened in students plus one is used to characterize the level of urban human
2003, is lower than 200 km/h, the cities along this line are not consid­ capital.
ered cities with HSR. The opening of HSR lines identified in this study
began with the opening of the Hefei-Nanjing Section of the Nanjing- 3.2.4. Moderating variables (local government capacity (Ability))
Chengdu Line on April 18, 2008. Based on the study of Loayza et al. [40], administrative capacity is

4
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

often used to measure the efficiency of plan implementation and is ∑Sit Sit
therefore expressed as the ratio of the actual fiscal expenditures of a city Potenit = + (8)
d dii
to its budgetary fiscal expenditures. A higher ratio suggests a higher =j ij
i∕

efficiency of plan implementation by the government and a higher


administrative capacity. The level of fiscal capacity is characterized by Where Poten is the market potential of a city; S is the market size of a
the degree of revenue effort of a city. This paper constructs the following city, expressed in terms of regional GDP; dij is the linear distance from
model to calculate the degree of revenue effort: the geometric centre of city i to that of city j; and dii is the intracity
distance, which is taken as 2/3 of the radius of the urban area, with
finance∗it = τ0 + τ1 pcgdpit + τ2 fdiit + τ3 densityit + τ4 ind2it + τ5 ind3it reference to Harris [41], i.e., dii = 2(area/π )1/2 /3, with area being the
+ τ6 urbanit + εit (4) land area of the administrative region of a city.

In the formula above, finance∗ represents the expected fiscal revenue, 3.3. Data sources and description
and finance represents the actual fiscal revenue, expressed as the pro­
portion of a city’s fiscal revenue to GDP. First, the formula above is used The data used in this study are divided into the following three main
to calculate finance∗ , and then, revenue effort is calculated (revenue = categories. (1) The variable data at the provincial and municipal levels
finance/finance∗ ). pcgdp represents the per capita GDP of a city; fdi were derived from the China City Statistical Yearbook and China Pop­
represents the openness of a city; density represents the population ulation Statistics Yearbook for the years 2002–2018. Due to adjustments
density of a city, expressed as the logarithm of the population per square in city administrative divisions or the absence of data for some cities,
kilometre; ind2 represents the proportion of the secondary industry, considerable data were missing for some key continuous variables.
expressed as the proportion of the urban secondary industry in GDP; Therefore, the data were first supplemented using the China Statistical
ind3 represents the proportion of the tertiary industry, expressed as the Yearbook for Regional Economy from 2002 to 2018, and then, the
proportion of the urban tertiary industry in GDP; and urban represents remaining missing data were imputed with the data from the year before
the urbanization rate, expressed as the proportion of the urban non- and after. (2) HSR data were mainly obtained from the China Railway
agricultural population to the total population. Specifically, the 33% Yearbook and the China Railway Corporation website (http://news.gaot
quantile of administrative capacity and 66% quantile of fiscal capacity ie.cn). (3) The vector data for the selected minimum spanning tree were
are used for definitional purposes. When both the administrative ca­ calculated from elevation data with an accuracy of 90 m; these data were
pacity and fiscal capacity of the local government are greater than or derived from the Chinese Geospatial Data Cloud (https://www.gscloud.
equal to the 66% quantile, a city is defined as a high-capacity city, with cn) using radar image data provided in each longitude and latitude grid.
Ability = 1; otherwise, a city is defined as a low-capacity city, with The radar image data are primarily divided into two types of data, i.e.,
Ability = 0. SRTM1 (30-m data) and SRTM3 (90-m data), which include the height
data for 3600 × 3600 and 1200 × 1200 sampling points, respectively. In
3.2.5. Other control variables this study, the 90-m data points are calculated from nine 30-m data
To more comprehensively examine the influence of HSR on urban points and then processed to obtain the minimum spanning tree data.
livelihood expenditures, in addition to controlling for the mediating The specific calculation steps are as follows: first, ArcGIS software is
variables, we set control variables that may influence local government used to mosaic and crop the elevation data to obtain an elevation map,
fiscal expenditures: (1) the GDP growth rate (Gdpr); (2) city openness extract the hydrological data, slope data, and undulation data of all cells
(Fdi), which is expressed as the proportion of the total amount of direct from the map and merge them. Second, the slope cost and undulation
use of foreign capital by each city deflated by the annual end-of-period cost are reassigned based on the three data sets and the three data layers:
exchange rate in the GDP of the city; (3) the urbanization level (Ur), the slope data and undulation cost data are divided into deciles, the
which is the proportion of the urban non-agricultural population to the smallest data are divided into 1, and the largest data are divided into 10.
total population; (4) road mileage (Road), which is expressed as the Finally, the unbalanced panel data of a total of 272 cities are selected as
actual road mileage in a city; (5) population size (Size), which is the research samples; a statistical description of the data is provided in
expressed as the logarithm of the year-end total population in a city; and Table 1.
(6) the degree of urban decentralization (Fd). The following calculation
formulas are constructed: 4. Empirical results and analysis
RDit
Fd = (5) 4.1. Analysis of the baseline regression results
EDit

LRit The results of the event study method show that the parallel trend is
RDit = ∑n (6)
LRit + ηgdp
it i=1 CRit
valid (The result is not shown in this paper due to space limitation), this
study uses a propensity score matching (PSM) TVDID regression. Spe­
LEit cifically, this paper uses K nearest neighbor matching method (one-to-
EDit = ∑n (7)
LEit + ηpeople
it i=1 CEit
five matching) to match, the estimation method for the HSR dummy is
logit. After the PSM of the treatment and control groups, 722 samples
Where RD is revenue decentralization; LR is local general public budget that were not within the common range of values were excluded, and the
revenue; CR is central general public budget revenue; ηgdp is the pro­ remaining samples were used for regression. Table 2 provides the results
portion of the GDP of city i in the national GDP; ED is expenditure of the baseline regression. Column (1) shows the influence of the
decentralization; LE is local general public budget expenditures; ηpeople is opening of HSR lines on the total bias towards urban livelihood ex­
the proportion of the population of city i to the total population of the penditures. The regression coefficients are significantly positive, indi­
country; CE is central general public budget expenditure, and Fd is the cating that the opening of HSR lines enhances the responsiveness of local
degree of urban fiscal decentralization, which is the ratio of revenue government fiscal expenditures, as reflected in the substantial increase
decentralization to expenditure decentralization. in the proportion of local government expenditures on people’s liveli­
(7) Urban market potential (Poten) is calculated as follows based on hood. Columns (2)–(4) provide the regression results for the influence of
Harris [41]: HSR on the government’s preference for spending on public goods such
as education, social security and employment, and medical and health
care and family planning, respectively. The coefficients are all

5
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

Table 1
Descriptive statistics.
Variable Meaning Observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum

Total Bias towards livelihood expenditures 4340 1.789 1.389 0.516 21.820
Education Bias towards education expenditures 4340 1.864 1.468 0.541 24.720
Security Bias towards social security and employment expenditures 4340 1.440 1.375 0.085 14.704
Medical Bias towards medical and health care expenditure 4340 2.375 1.849 0.522 29.290
Hsr Opening of HSR lines 4340 0.263 0.441 0.000 1.000
Gdpr GDP growth rate 4340 0.019 0.046 − 0.073 0.308
Fd Decentralization 4340 0.370 0.114 0.086 0.718
Poten Market potential 4340 0.203 0.204 0.017 1.159
Fdi Openness 4340 0.021 0.023 0.000 0.123
Ur Urbanization level 4340 0.720 0.343 0.111 1.044
Hci Human capital 4340 10.207 1.534 0.000 13.898
Mk Market access 4340 − 19.497 2.037 − 26.538 − 11.441
Road Road mileage 4340 8.989 0.765 5.357 11.144
Size Population size 4340 5.848 0.674 2.923 9.315
Ability Government capacity 4340 0.343 0.475 0.000 1.000

promote bias towards expenditures on people’s livelihood? To answer


Table 2
this question, this study tests the mediating effect from the perspective
Baseline regression results.
of factor competition.
(1) (2) (3) (4) Under China’s system of fiscal decentralization and its structure of
Total Education Security Medical multilevel government, there is a competition mechanism in the relative
Hsr 0.205*** 0.269*** 0.054 0.256*** performance evaluation of local governments, that is, the “promotion
(3.74) (4.61) (1.09) (3.49) tournament” mechanism through which local governments compete for
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes tax revenue and expenditures to compete for a mobile tax base. The
Year/Individual Yes Yes Yes Yes existence of significant strategic interactions between local governments
fixed effects
in terms of expenditure policies has been confirmed by the literature
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618
R-squared 0.247 0.177 0.399 0.193 [45]. Competition among local governments tends to strategically
r2_a 0.179 0.103 0.345 0.120 respond to the expenditure behaviour of other local governments, which
F 40.300*** 26.370*** 81.720*** 29.340*** in turn affects local livelihood expenditures. The spillover of public
Note: ***, **, and × indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, goods and the noncooperative supply among local governments can also
respectively. The same applies below. cause the supply of public goods to deviate from the optimal level. The
competition among regions is further reflected in the competition be­
significantly positive, except for the bias towards social security and tween local governments for financial capital and human capital.
employment expenditures Hsr, which is statistically nonsignificant. The Accordingly, this study further identifies the mechanisms of the influ­
results indicate that, compared with the local governments of cities ence of HSR on the bias of local governments’ livelihood expenditures,
without HSR stations, those of cities with HSR stations effectively in­ with market access (Mk) and human capital (Hci) as proxy variables for
crease the bias towards expenditures on education and medical and the former and the latter, respectively.
health care. The direct promoting effect of the opening of HSR lines on
local governments’ livelihood expenditures is mainly reflected in the 5.1.1. Market access mechanism
substantial increase in the proportion of expenditures on education and Column (1) of Table 3 reports the results of the regression of HSR for
medical and health care. market access, and the coefficient estimate of Hsr for market access (Mk)
is significant; columns (2)–(5) show the regression results when both Mk
and Hsr are included. Although the regression coefficients of the former
4.2. Robustness tests
are small, the coefficients of Mk and Hsr are both significant except those
for regression (4). Therefore, the Sobel test is not required, indicating
This paper primarily conducted robustness tests from four aspects:
that the influence of HSR on the total and structural bias towards live­
first, testing the gradient effects of the opening of HSR lines grade in
lihood expenditure is closely related to market access. Based on the
different cities on urban livelihood expenditures; second, testing the
calculation equation of Mk, the new market access is calculated by
gradient effects of different HSR lines coverage numbers on urban
replacing ε with 4, and the results show that the mediating mechanism
livelihood expenditures; third, addressing endogeneity issues [42,43];
still holds after incorporation into the model. Market access due to HSR
and finally, conducting a placebo test. Limited to length, the relevant
has a positive effect on local fiscal responsiveness. Market access is a
results are placed in the appendix.
measure of the extent to which the goods, labour services, and capital of
a country or region participate in market competition. With the rapid
5. Further analysis
development of trade liberalization and information technology, it has
become easier to acquire basic information in the process of trade ex­
5.1. Test of the mediating effects
change between two regions. The truly decisive factor is the familiarity
with each other’s markets, supply and demand networks, and informa­
To enhance the attraction of mobile resource factors, local govern­
tion on inbound goods, and such “soft information” is accessed from the
ments can compete by reducing the cost of resource use or by providing
oral communication between entrepreneurs and relies on face-to-face
different types and scales of public goods [25]. The rapid development
dissemination [46]. HSR provides a good medium for this information
of HSR has effectively reduced the cost of domestic trade and promoted
access. The opening of HSR lines improves the accessibility of cities,
the integration of domestic markets [44], accelerated the mobility and
reduces fixed trade costs, and enhances the economic, information, la­
spatial reallocation of factors such as financial capital and human cap­
bour, and technology flows between cities [20], These positive changes
ital, and resulted in a significant “multiplier effect.” Will the opening of
enable enterprises to obtain lower-priced or higher-quality factors in
HSR lines intensify the competition among governments and thus

6
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

Table 3
Test of the influence mechanism of market access.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Mk Total Education Security Medical

Hsr 0.056** (2.15) 0.212*** (3.85) 0.276*** (4.73) 0.058 (1.17) 0.262*** (3.57)
Mk 0.111*** (3.01) 0.153*** (3.91) 0.014 (0.43) 0.180*** (3.65)
Z value / / / /
Does the mediating effect hold? Yes Yes No Yes
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year/Individual fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618 3618
R-squared 0.802 0.243 0.172 0.398 0.191
r2_a 0.784 0.176 0.098 0.344 0.118
F 537.700*** 41.080*** 26.480*** 84.440*** 30.110***

areas with better accessibility, which influences the location choice of 5.1.2.2. Human capital structure. To further explain the influence
enterprises and the formation of industrial agglomeration and promotes mechanism of the difference in human capital structure in the promotion
competition in interregional factor and product markets. Market size of livelihood expenditures by HSR, this study introduces four new in­
expansion stimulates new growth points of service consumption de­ dicators, namely, Edu1 to Edu4, which represent the number of em­
mand, increases the sales radius of enterprises, and expands the distance ployees with an elementary school education or below, a middle school
of goods accessibility. To attract an inflow of the mobile tax base, local education, a high school education, and a college education or above,
governments enhance their competitive advantage through the expen­ respectively, in a city. The number of employees with different educa­
diture competition strategy and thereby increase the proportion of tional levels in each city is calculated based on data on the educational
livelihood expenditures. level of employees in each province to indicate the distribution of em­
ployees with different educational levels. Table 5 provides the regres­
5.1.2. Human capital mechanism sion results for the influence mechanism of the human capital structure.
Hsr is statistically nonsignificant for human capital with an elementary
5.1.2.1. Total human capital. Table 4 reports the results of the regres­ school education or below, and the Z value for the Sobel test is less than
sion with human capital as a mediating variable. The coefficient esti­ 0.97. However, Hsr has significant explanatory power for human capital
mates of Hsr for Hci are significant. In regressions (2), (3), and (5), the with the other three educational levels and, in particular, promotes a
regression coefficients of Hci and Hsr for both the total and structural significant increase in the number of employees with a college education
bias of livelihood expenditures have explanatory power and are signif­ or above. After adding the indicators for both the opening of HSR lines
icant at the 1% level; thus, the Sobel test is not required. Therefore, and the human capital structure, the regression results show that there is
human capital is an important channel through which the opening of no mediating effect on the number of employees with an elementary
HSR lines influences the bias of governments’ livelihood expenditures. school education or below and that there is a significant mediating effect
That is, the opening of HSR lines accelerates the flow of human capital on each of the other three human capital indicators. The results indicate
between cities, which in turn enhances the incentives of local govern­ that after the opening of HSR lines, cities gain competitive advantages
ments to supply livelihood public goods. The opening of HSR lines by increasing livelihood expenditures to promote the agglomeration of
shortens the accessibility distance of human capital in search of jobs and human capital, especially that of highly skilled human capital with a
reduces the cost of mobility, thereby improving the efficiency with college education or above. The reason is that the agglomeration of
which human capital is matched with jobs and reducing the structural highly skilled human capital in a city is closely related not only to the
unemployment caused by the mismatch between labour skills and industrial structure, job opportunities, and income level of the city but
market demand in the unemployment process as well as the frictional also to the quality and level of basic public services such as education
unemployment caused by the failure to connect workers with market and medical and health care in the city.
demand, a lack of mobility, and information mismatches. Human capital
mobility helps cities achieve an initial accumulation of human capital. In
the development process, due to the externalities of human capital [47], 5.2. Test of the moderating mechanisms of local government capacity
the flow of highly educated talent to areas with good accessibility ac­
celerates, forming a virtuous cycle of “inflow-optimization-re-inflow,” Based on the variable Ability, this study investigates the heteroge­
further amplifying the effect of the opening of HSR lines on human neous influence of the opening of HSR lines on the bias towards liveli­
capital. hood expenditures in cities with different government capacities. The
relevant results are reported in Table 6. When the multiplicative

Table 4
Test of the influence mechanism of human capital.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Hci Total Education Security Medical

Hsr 0.057* (1.83) 0.211*** (3.84) 0.276*** (4.73) 0.054 (1.10) 0.266*** (3.61)
Hci 0.126*** (4.09) 0.153*** (4.66) 0.074*** (2.67) 0.122*** (2.97)
Z value / / / /
Does the mediating effect hold? Yes Yes No Yes
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year/Individual fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618 3618
R-squared 0.348 0.245 0.173 0.399 0.190
r2_a 0.290 0.178 0.099 0.346 0.117
F 70.880*** 41.470*** 26.780*** 84.880*** 29.900***

7
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

Table 5 financial capital and human capital, it is difficult for local governments
Test of the influence mechanism of the human capital structure. to allocate expenditures on goods for people’s livelihood that match the
Step 1 (1) (2) (3) (4) demand, thus leading to a decrease in government responsiveness via
livelihood expenditures induced by HSR. For governments with a strong
Edu1 Edu2 Edu3 Edu4
capacity, administrative and fiscal capacities are related to the efficiency
Hsr − 0.008 0.021** 0.048*** 0.068*** of these governments in acquiring resources and using them effectively,
(− 1.48) (2.51) (5.30) (3.03)
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes
which is reflected in the strong social governance capacity of the cities
Year/ Yes Yes Yes Yes and can amplify the incentive effect of HSR on the supply of public goods
Individual by local governments.
fixed
effects
6. Conclusions
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618
R-squared 0.998 0.996 0.995 0.970
r2_a 0.998 0.995 0.994 0.967 Based on a quasi-natural experiment involving the opening of HSR
F 74469.740*** 29686.620*** 24937.660*** 4317.450*** lines, this study tests the influence of the opening of HSR lines on the
Step 2 Total Total Total Total bias of local governments’ livelihood expenditures and the corre­
Hsr 0.216*** 0.213*** 0.197*** 0.201***
(3.93) (3.87) (3.57) (3.66)
sponding mechanisms in multiple dimensions using a TVDID model as
Edu1 − 0.196 well as 2002–2018 Chinese city data and geographic information data.
(− 1.09) The main conclusions are as follows. First, the opening of HSR lines
Edu2 0.233** effectively enhances local governments’ bias towards livelihood ex­
(2.07)
penditures, and the responsiveness of local governments increases with
Edu3 0.441***
(4.22) the increase in the number of HSR lines in cities. This “HSR effect” is
Edu4 0.254*** reflected in both the total amount and structure of livelihood expendi­
(5.98) tures. Second, the opening of HSR lines accelerates the spatial reallo­
Z value Z = 0.17 Z = 1.36 Z = 1.36 Z = 1.78 cation of resource factors, which has a significant amplification effect on
Does the No Yes Yes Yes
mediating
the competition among local governments, accelerating the agglomer­
effect ation of capital and factors in large cities through market access and
hold? human capital and providing an important transmission mechanism for
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes local governments’ livelihood expenditures. Third, from the perspective
Year/ Yes Yes Yes Yes
of social governance capacity, the opening of HSR lines has a more
Individual
fixed significant incentive effect on local governments’ livelihood expendi­
effects tures in cities with stronger administrative and fiscal capacities.
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618 Therefore, local governments should pay full attention to the spillover
R-squared 0.242 0.242 0.245 0.249 effect of HSR lines, shift from comparative advantage to competitive
r2_a 0.174 0.175 0.178 0.182
F 40.680*** 40.830*** 41.520*** 42.430***
advantage, promote the shift of basic public services from a regional
territorial supply to a regionally linked and coordinated supply, opti­
mize the allocation pattern of basic public services among cities, and
enhance their governance capacity and levels.
Table 6
Test of the moderating mechanism of local government capacity.
Funding
(1) (2) (3) (4)

Total Education Security Medical The financial support from the Major Program of National Fund of
Hsr 0.142** 0.184*** 0.027 (0.50) 0.183** Philosophy and Social Science of China(No. 18ZDA040).
(2.34) (2.86) (2.26)
Ability 0.140** 0.123* 0.138*** 0.216*** Credit author statement
(2.35) (1.94) (2.59) (2.71)
Hsr_Ability 0.199** 0.271*** 0.068 (0.94) 0.235**
(2.48) (3.18) (2.19)
Xia Meng: Methodology, Software, Writing - original draft, Funding
Covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes acquisition. Tao Ding: Software, Supervision, Writing - review & editing.
Year/Individual Yes Yes Yes Yes Haisen Wang: Conceptualization, Data curation, Supervision, Writing -
fixed effects review & editing.
Observations 3618 3618 3618 3618
R-squared 0.251 0.181 0.402 0.197
r2_a 0.183 0.107 0.348 0.124 Declaration of competing interest
F 39.680*** 26.190*** 79.550*** 28.990***
None.

interaction term of local government capacity and the opening of HSR Data availability
lines is added, the estimate of its coefficient is significantly positive at
the 1% level (except for social security and employment expenditures), Data will be made available on request.
indicating that the higher the administrative and fiscal capacities are,
the more pronounced the total bias towards increases in livelihood ex­ Acknowledgements
penditures after the opening of HSR lines. The contribution of the
opening of HSR lines to the total and structural expenditures on goods We would like to thank the editor and the anonymous referees for
for people’s livelihood (except social security and employment expen­ their highly constructive suggestions.
ditures) gradually decreases with the decrease in local government ca­
pacity, a result that is consistent with that of the heterogeneity test by Appendix A. Supplementary data
city size discussed in the previous section. In areas with weak admin­
istrative and fiscal capacities, even if the opening of HSR lines attracts Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi.

8
X. Meng et al. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 89 (2023) 101700

org/10.1016/j.seps.2023.101700. [24] Keen M, Marchand M. Fiscal competition and the pattern of public spending. J Publ
Econ 1997;66(1):33–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(97)00035-2.
[25] Fuhrmann M. When do leaders free-ride? Business experience and contributions to
References collective defense. Am J Polit Sci 2020;64(2):416–31. https://doi.org/10.1111/
ajps.12502.
[1] Bellofatto AA, Besfamille M. Regional state capacity and the optimal degree of [26] Salinas P, Solé-Ollé A. Partial fiscal decentralization reforms and educational
fiscal decentralization. J Publ Econ 2018;159:225–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. outcomes: a difference-in-differences analysis for Spain. J Urban Econ 2018;107:
jpubeco.2017.12.010. 31–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2018.08.003.
[2] Chang Z, Diao M, Jing K, Li W. High-speed rail and industrial movement: evidence [27] Li T, Du T. Vertical fiscal imbalance, transfer payments, and fiscal sustainability of
from China’s greater bay area. Transport Pol 2021;112:22–31. https://doi.org/ local governments in China. Int Rev Econ Finance 2021;74:392–404. https://doi.
10.1016/j.tranpol.2021.08.013. org/10.1016/j.iref.2021.03.019.
[3] Wang Y, Ni P. Economic growth spillover and spatial optimization of high-speed [28] Zhou LA. Governing China’s local officials: an analysis of promotion tournament
railway. China Ind Econ 2016;2:21–36. https://doi.org/10.19581/j.cnki. model. Econ Res J 2007;7:36–50.
ciejournal.2016.02.003. [29] Zhou L, Tao J. Bureaucratic promotion competition and border effect: evidence
[4] Fan X, Xu Y. Does high-speed railway promote urban innovation? Evidence from from economic development in China’s border regions. J Financ Res 2011;3:15–26.
China. Soc Econ Plann Sci 2023;86:101464. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. [30] Goodspeed TJ. Decentralization and intra-country transfers in the great recession:
seps.2022.101464. the case of the European Union. Reg Stud 2020;54(7):931–41. https://doi.org/
[5] Vickrey WS. Congestion theory and transport investment. Am Econ Rev 1969;59 10.1080/00343404.2019.1666207.
(2):251–60. [31] Hickey R, Lozej M, Smyth D. Financing government investment and its implications
[6] Mohring H. Optimization and scale economies in urban bus transportation. Am for public capital: a small open economy perspective. Econ Modell 2020;93:
Econ Rev 1972;62(4):591–604. 620–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.08.006.
[7] Yang X, Zhang H, Li Y. High-speed railway, factor flow and enterprise innovation [32] Brueckner JK. Partial fiscal decentralization. Reg Sci Urban Econ 2009;39(1):
efficiency: an empirical analysis on micro data. Soc Econ Plann Sci 2022;82: 23–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2008.06.001.
101305. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2022.101305. [33] Qian Y, Roland G. Federalism and the soft budget constraint. Am Econ Rev 1998;88
[8] Meng X, Ding T, Liu W. Research on the effect and mechanism of the opening of (5):1143–62. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.149988.
high-speed rail on city-level air quality. Pol J Environ Stud 2023;32(2):1287–300. [34] Bardhan P, Mookherjee D. Decentralisation and accountability in infrastructure
https://doi.org/10.15244/pjoes/156826. delivery in developing countries. Econ J 2006;116(508):101–27. https://doi.org/
[9] Yang G, Ding Z, Wu M, Gao M, Yue Z, Wang H. Can digital finance reduce carbon 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2006.01049.x.
emission intensity? a perspective based on factor allocation distortions: evidence [35] Ronaghi M, Reed M, Saghaian S. The impact of economic factors and governance
from Chinese cities. Environ Sci Pollut Res 2023;30:38832–52. https://doi.org/ on greenhouse gas emission. Environ Econ Pol Stud 2020;22(2):153–72. https://
10.1007/s11356-022-24748-1. doi.org/10.1007/s10018-019-00250-w.
[10] Huang Y, Jiang C, Wang K, Xiao Y, Zhang A. Public-private partnership in high- [36] Donaldson D, Hornbeck R. Railroads and American economic growth: a “market
speed rail financing: case of uncertain regional economic spillovers in China. access” approach. Q J Econ 2016;131(2):799–858. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/
Transport Pol 2021;106:64–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2021.03.016. qjw002.
[11] Duranton G, Puga D. The economics of urban density. J Econ Perspect 2020;34(3): [37] Morkutė G, Koster S. Human capital as a location factor: an empirical investigation
3–26. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.34.3.3. of relocating firms and their labour force in The Netherlands. Pap Reg Sci 2018;97
[12] Shao S, Tian Z, Yang L. High speed rail and urban service industry agglomeration: (3):595–616. https://doi.org/10.1111/pirs.12257.
evidence from China’s Yangtze River Delta region. J Transport Geogr 2017;64: [38] Diamond R. The determinants and welfare implications of US workers’ diverging
174–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2017.08.019. location choices by skill: 1980-2000. Am Econ Rev 2016;106(3):479–524. https://
[13] Ren X, Chen Z, Wang F, Dan T, Wang W, Guo X, Liu C. Impact of high-speed rail on doi.org/10.1257/aer.20131706.
social equity in China: evidence from a mode choice survey. Transp. Res. Pt A- [39] Liang W, Lu M. Growth led by human capital in big cities: exploring
Policy Pract. 2020;138:422–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2020.05.018. complementarities and spatial agglomeration of the workforce with various skills.
[14] Cascetta E, Papola A, Pagliara F, Marzano V. Analysis of mobility impacts of the China Econ Rev 2019;57:101113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2017.09.012.
high speed Rome–Naples rail link using withinday dynamic mode service choice [40] Loayza NV, Rigolini J, Calvo-González O. More than you can handle:
models. J Transport Geogr 2011;19(4):635–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. decentralization and spending ability of Peruvian municipalities. Econ Polit 2014;
jtrangeo.2010.07.001. 26(1):56–78. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecpo.12026.
[15] Dong Y, Zhu Y. Can high-speed rail construction reshape the layout of China’s [41] Harris CD. The, market as a factor in the localization of industry in the United
economic space: based on the perspective of regional heterogeneity of States. Ann Assoc Am Geogr 1954;44(4):315–48. https://doi.org/10.1080/
employment, wage and economic growth. China Ind Econ 2016;10:92–108. 00045605409352140.
https://doi.org/10.19581/j.cnki.ciejournal.2016.10.007. [42] Faber B. Trade integration, market size, and industrialization: evidence from
[16] Nakagawa D, Hatoko M. Reevaluation of Japanese high-speed rail construction: China’s national trunk highway system. Rev Econ Stud 2014;81(3):1046–70.
recent situation of the north corridor Shinkansen and its way to completion. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdu010.
Transport Pol 2007;14(2):150–64. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. [43] Chen S, Chen T. Air pollution and public health: evidence from sulfur dioxide
tranpol.2006.11.004. emission of coal-fired power stations in China. Econ Res J 2014;8:158–83.
[17] Lü W, Wang W. Unbalanced development, public services and government [44] Qin Y. ‘No county left behind?’ The distributional impact of high-speed rail
responsibility: an analysis based on government preference and government upgrades in China. J Econ Geogr 2017;17(3):489–520. https://doi.org/10.1093/
efficiency. Soc Sci China 2008;29(4):63–80. https://doi.org/10.1080/ jeg/lbw013.
02529200802500342. [45] Pao HT, Fu HC. Competition and stability analyses among emissions, energy, and
[18] Donaldson D. Railroads of the Raj: estimating the impact of transportation economy: application for Mexico. Energy 2015;82:98–107. https://doi.org/
infrastructure. Am Econ Rev 2018;108(4–5):899–934. https://doi.org/10.1257/ 10.1016/j.energy.2014.12.076.
aer.20101199. [46] Loughran T. The impact of firm location on equity issuance. Financ Manag 2008;37
[19] Tang Y, Yu F, Lin F, Zhang M. China’s high-speed railway, trade cost and firm (1):1–21. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1755-053X.2008.00004.x.
export. Econ Res J 2019;54(7):158–73. [47] Lu M. Urban, regional and national development: the present and future of spatial
[20] Shao ZZ, Ma ZJ, Sheu JB, Gao HO. Evaluation of large-scale transnational high- political economics. Chin Econ Q 2017;16(4):1499–532. https://doi.org/
speed railway construction priority in the belt and road region. Transp. Res. Pt E- 10.13821/j.cnki.ceq.2017.03.11.
Logist. Transp. Rev. 2018;117:40–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2017.07.007.
[21] Dziuda W, Gitmez AA, Shadmehr M. The difficulty of easy projects. Am. Econ. Rev.
Xia Meng, female, PhD. School of Economics and Management, China University of
Insights 2021;3(3):285–302. https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20200311.
Geosciences. Main research directions: public economy.
[22] Wang H, Yang G, Ouyang X, Tan Z. Does environmental information disclosure
promote the supply of environmental public goods? Evidence based on a dynamic
spatial panel Durbin model. Environ Impact Assess Rev 2022;93:106725. https:// Tao Ding, male, Master. School of Economics and Management, China University of
doi.org/10.1016/j.eiar.2021.106725. Geosciences. Main research directions: regional economy and industrial economy.
[23] Zodrow GR, Mieszkowski P. Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the
underprovision of local public goods. J Urban Econ 1986;19(3):356–70. https:// Haisen Wang, male, PhD. Economics and Management School, Wuhan University. Main
doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)90048-3. research directions: regional economy and industrial economy.

You might also like