You are on page 1of 6

Int. J.

Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472

Project procurement and disposal decisions:


An inventory management model
Keith A. Willoughby*
Department of Management, Bucknell University, Lewisburg, PA 17837, USA

Abstract

In this paper, we develop a two-stage mathematical model to examine an important inventory management problem
within a large-scale project context. Speci"cally, we analyze the procurement and disposal of an important, expensive
item (e.g. pipeline). There is uncertainty surrounding total requirements of this item during a project. Surplus stock
on-hand at the conclusion of the project may be disposed for revenue. However, it may be retained to satisfy requirements
during a subsequent project. The time between projects follows a discrete probability distribution. The key decision
variables involve the procurement quantity in the initial project as well as the best disposal quantity (should a surplus
exist) at the conclusion of the project.  2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Excess stock disposal; Stochastic inventory models; Large-scale projects

1. Introduction problems, mid-stream engineering design changes


(even project cancellation), environmental condi-
`Except in the midst of a battle"eld, nowhere tions (e.g. unpredictable project `windowsa in
must men coordinate the movement of other remote, harsh climates) and labour disruptions,
men and all materials in the midst of such chaos among others, contribute to the extreme di$culty
and with such limited certainty of present facts in e!ectively managing project inventories.
and future occurrences as in a huge construction This paper examines critical inventory manage-
projecta. ment decisions encountered in large-scale projects.
Speci"cally, we develop a mathematical model to
(Blake Construction Co. v. C.J. Oakley Co. [1], emphasis analyze the procurement and disposal of an impor-
added)
tant, expensive item (e.g. pipeline). Due to the
Clearly, inventory management within large- inherent uncertainty of subsurface work, total
scale projects is subject to a tremendous amount of requirements of this item during construction are
uncertainty. Delays in vendor shipments, quality not known with certainty.
Surplus units on-hand after project completion
may be salvaged (disposed for revenue), or retained
* Corresponding author. Tel.: #1-570-524-2939 (Res), #1- to satisfy requirements during a subsequent project
570-577-1751 (work); fax: #1-570-577-1338. (retention may prove especially bene"cial if pro-
E-mail address: kwilloug@bucknell.edu (K.A. Willoughby). curement prices in the subsequent project increase

0925-5273/01/$ - see front matter  2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 9 2 5 - 5 2 7 3 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 1 4 6 - 8
468 K.A. Willoughby / Int. J. Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472

signi"cantly, and the cost of holding stock is not costs, disposal values, shortage penalties and hold-
prohibitive). The time until the next project is ing costs, he was able to determine optimal policies
modelled as a random variable following a discrete for an entire planning horizon. Teisberg [5] de-
probability distribution. Although one could incor- veloped a multi-period, stochastic dynamic pro-
porate continuous probability distributions to rep- gramming tool to guide the ongoing acquisitions
resent inter-project time, our selection of a discrete and disposals (releases) of the United States stra-
distribution is practitioner-motivated. Representa- tegic petroleum reserve. For each entering stockpile
tive parameter values in our study were obtained size and each possible oil market state, and using
via interviews with materials management and the present value of all relevant costs, he was able
logistics personnel. We felt it was more reasonable to determine optimal stockpile acquisition or re-
to elicit discrete data from these practitioners (i.e. lease rates for a speci"c time period.
a certain likelihood of a subsequent project occur- Several models have been developed to examine
ring within a speci"c time interval), rather than the disposal of excess stock, given that an organiza-
querying them for continuous inter-project distri- tion is currently in a surplus inventory situation.
butions. In essence, a greater understanding (and A few of the more signi"cant contributions will be
appreciation) of model development may lead to cited. Simpson [6] was an early contributor to the
improved prospects of model implementation. excess stock literature. Basing his analysis on
The vital decision variables include the appropri- inventories held at Naval supply stores, he found
ate quantity to procure at the beginning of the an economic retention quantity by developing
initial project and the proper amount to dispose, in a tradeo! between storage and obsolescence costs
the event of on-hand surplus, after construction versus the expenses of repurchasing the material in
completion. The procurement and disposal quant- the future (if and when required). Tersine and
ities are to be selected so as to provide lowest Toelle [7] generated relationships for the economic
overall costs. We note here that we are not taking time supply of an item, under the existence or
into account the total costs associated with a sec- non-existence of present value and in#ation consid-
ond (and any additional) project(s). We are only erations. Incorporating stochastic (Poisson) de-
concerned with how the presence of various cost mand, Rosen"eld [8] developed optimal quantities
and revenue values a!ect initial project procure- for excess stock disposal. He applied his methodo-
ment and subsequent disposal decisions. logy to an actual distributor of durable goods faced
Silver [2,3] conducted a survey of senior inven- with excessive amounts of slow-moving items. The
tory management personnel involved in large-scale model showed that substantial savings could be
oil and gas projects in the Province of Alberta earned by the judicious disposal of surplus stock.
(Canada). Critical decision areas faced by these Some researchers have examined various inven-
professionals involved coping with uncertainty tory management issues within a project manage-
surrounding total project requirements, and the ment context. In particular, Smith-Daniels and
disposal of project surplus. Hence, there would Smith-Daniels [9] examined the performance
appear to be a practitioner-oriented motivation for of several heuristics for determining lot sizes in
a systematic method to analyze the procurement projects. Inventory management was especially
and disposal problem. To the best of our know- complex in projects due to uncertainty surrounding
ledge, no previous attempt has been made to jointly the quantity and timing of requirements, as well as
investigate procurement and disposal decisions in the `lumpya nature of those requirements.
a project context. The format of this paper is as follows. Section 2,
Only a handful of articles have jointly considered by analyzing the inter-project period costs, deter-
procurement (acquisition) and disposal decisions in mines optimal disposal quantities at the conclusion
any context, let alone within a project environment. of the initial project. Section 3 then develops
Fukuda [4] examined ordering and disposal expressions for initial project costs. Numerical
policies in a multiechelon, multiperiod inventory examples are provided in both sections 2 and 3.
situation. Considering such factors as ordering Conclusions are included in the "nal section.
K.A. Willoughby / Int. J. Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472 469

2. Inter-project analysis and, for t )t )t ,


G\ M G
p
We shall introduce the development of our f (t )" G .
model by analyzing inter-project period costs. The R  t !t
G G\
following notation is required:
Evaluation of (2) gives
t time interval i associated with the subsequent
G h(1!exp(t ))!v exp(t ). (3)
project (i"1, 2, 2, n)   
p probability of the subsequent project begin- Since we are dealing with a discrete probability
G
ning within time interval (t , t ] distribution, we may rewrite (1) as
G\ G
Common probability rules maintain that each

L RG p
p is non-negative and that the sum of the respective R(t ) G dt
G  t !t 
probabilities over all time intervals is equal to one. G RG\ G G\
We assume that the subsequent project is equally which is
likely to occur any time within the time interval


(t , t ] and that t "0. L p RG
G\ G M G R(t ) dt . (4)
Surplus stock may be retained after completion t !t  
G G G\ RG\
of the initial project to satisfy subsequent project
requirements. Maintaining available on-hand Substituting (3) into (4) gives


stock, then, means that those speci"c units will not L p RG
need to be procured during the future project. This G [h(1!exp(!t ))
t !t 
represents a cost savings. However, one must pay G G G\ R G\

holding charges to carry these units in inventory. !v exp(!t )] dt . (5)


  
We shall use continuous discounting (see Gurnani
[10]) in determining these holding costs. Let us Evaluation of the integral in (5) gives
introduce some further notation:

RG RG
ht  (h exp(!t )#v exp(!t )) dt
h out-of-pocket inventory carrying charges ($     
RG\ R G\
per unit of inventory per unit time)
 continuous discount rate (i.e. a cost of x in- which can be expressed as
curred at time t has a present value of h(t !t )
x exp(!t)) G G\

 
v unit procurement cost in the subsequent pro- h#v
Q ! Q [exp(!t )-exp(t )]. (6)
ject (due to varying market conditions, this  G\ G
future unit procurement cost may be greater
than, the same as or less than the unit cost in Thus, the expected present value of the inter-
the initial project) project period costs per surplus unit retained
h h/ (EIPC) becomes

  
L p h#v
The present value of the inter-project costs may EIPC" G h(t !t )! 
t !t G G\ 
be modelled as G G G\ (7)


R [exp(!t )!exp(!t )]).

f (t )[R(t )] dt , (1) G\ G
R    Note that the unit inter-project period costs are

where t represents the largest t value under linear with respect to the quantity of retained stock.
 G In essence, they are independent of the on-hand
consideration and
surplus after initial project completion (assuming


R that all units retained are needed in the subsequent
R(t )" h exp(!z) dz!v exp(!t ) (2)
   project, a rather reasonable assumption).

470 K.A. Willoughby / Int. J. Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472

Disposing surplus stock upon completion of the on-hand stock, the EPV*(I) values are either:
initial project generates immediate revenues. The
E EIPC*I, if W*"0 (all surplus stock is retained),
following notation is used:
E !g*I, if =*"I (all surplus stock is disposed)
g unit salvage value for surplus stock dis-
As a numerical example, assume the following
posal
values:
w disposal quantity (W* represents the op-
p : 0.60 t : 1.0
timal disposal quantity)  
p : 0.30 t : 2.0
I on-hand surplus stock after completion  
p : 0.10 t : 3.5
of the initial project (but before any  
h: $13 per unit of inventory per year
disposal decision)
: 0.10
EPV*(I) expected present value of completing
v : $100
the initial project with I units of inven- Q
tory on-hand, and proceeding in an op- Using (7), we determine that EIPC"!78.22.
timal fashion from thereon (with respect Consequently, one would need to obtain a unit
to disposal decisions) salvage value of more than $78.22 in order to make
disposal attractive. Since the unit acquisition cost is
Since we have constant marginal inter-project
$100, this indicates that (given the parameter values
period costs and disposal revenues, the determina-
under consideration) the retention of excess stock is
tion of optimal disposal quantities upon comple-
quite bene"cial. Decision-makers in our inventory
tion of the initial project is quite straightforward.
management context would rarely observe a sal-
We simply compare the associated costs and
vage value in excess of 3/4 of the unit acquisition
revenues in the following fashion:
cost!
E If EIPC#g)0 (this implies that EIPC)!g),
then =*"0. No surplus stock is disposed
(equivalently, all units are retained) since the 3. Initial project analysis
bene"t (cost reduction) of retention is higher
than the bene"t of disposal. We shall now model those costs incurred during
E If EIPC#g'0 (this implies that EIPC'!g), the initial project. Without loss of generality, we
then =*"I. All surplus stock is disposed assume that on-hand inventory at the beginning of
(equivalently, no units are retained) since the this project is zero. The following notation is
bene"t (cost reduction) of retention is less than required:
the bene"t of disposal.
Q initial project procurement quantity
The disposal choice after the initial project is, ETC(Q) expected total discounted costs (initial
essentially, an `all-or-nothinga decision. We either project costs plus costs relating to post-
dispose everything on-hand, or retain all of it to project disposal decisions) as a func-
satisfy future project requirements. One could sug- tion of the initial project procurement
gest that, if one were indi!erent between surplus quantity
stock retention or disposal (i.e. EIPC"!g), then
The best procurement quantity, Q*, is the one
it could be attractive to dispose a portion of the
that minimizes ETC(Q).
on-hand surplus. However, in this extreme case,
As mentioned earlier, there exists uncertainty
observe that total costs would be equivalent under
surrounding total requirements during the initial
any disposal strategy. The key "nding is that an
project. We shall model this uncertainty with a dis-
organization could never be better o! by disposing
crete probability distribution. Speci"cally, let
a portion of the on-hand surplus.
The EPV*(I) values are quite important to our D total requirements in the initial project

analysis, for they `linka the two stages of our P (D ) probability of observing a speci"c re-
" 
model. Since disposal decisions are independent of quirements value
K.A. Willoughby / Int. J. Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472 471

The following additional notation will be re- Although we explicitly recognize holding costs
quired to determine ETC(Q): prior to a stockout, we shall ignore any carrying
charges incurred subsequent to the receipt of ex-
v unit procurement cost in the initial pro-
 pedited stock. In all likelihood, the relatively large
ject stockout penalties would dominate these holding
T duration of initial project (in years) costs.
B "xed cost per stockout occasion
 To determine the present value of stockout
B penalty (expressed as a fraction of the
 penalties, these costs must be discounted from the
unit value) per unit short moment at which they occur. The B stockout

The respective cost components of ETC(Q) will penalty is given as
now be described. Since procurement costs occur at

 
the beginning of the initial project, there is no need Q¹
B P (D )exp ! (11)
to discount them. Quite simply, they are  "  D
" / 
Qv . (8) while the B stockout penalty is
 
For any procurement quantity Q, we have the
 
Q¹
following expression for carrying charges: (1#B )v (D !Q)P (D )exp ! . (12)
   "  D
" / 

 
2 D
h P (D ) Q!  t exp!(t) dt, In the previous section, we derived the expres-
"  ¹
" W/  sion for EPV*(I). We note here that the quantity of
which is evaluated as on-hand surplus at the conclusion of the initial


Q project, I, is equivalent to maxQ!D , 0. For
h P (D ) (1!exp(!¹)) 
"   D *Q, one begins the inter-project period with

" W/ (9) zero units of stock on-hand. Since no disposal

   
D ¹ 1 1 revenue or holding charges will be incurred, there
#  exp(!¹) # ! .
¹    are no discounted inter-project period costs.
However, for D (Q, these discounted costs are
We also recognize any carrying charges incurred 
prior to the occurrence of a stockout. Since a stock-
out, should it occur, would happen at time Q¹/D , exp(!¹) EPVH(Q!D )P (D ). (13)
  " 
these carrying charges are expressed as " /

  
/2" D Combining expressions (8)}(13) yields our math-
h P (D ) Q!  t exp(!t) dt,
"  ¹ ematical model for determining the expected total
" /  discounted costs as a function of the procurement
which becomes quantity in the initial project. We note here that the

  
Q Q¹ "nal model is of a news-vendor type. In other
h P (D ) 1!exp !
"   D words, a one-time decision procurement decision is
" /  made in order to minimize both initial project and

    
D Q¹ Q¹ 1 1
#  exp ! # ! . inter-project costs.
¹ D D   Let us expand on the numerical example present-
 
This expression can be simpli"ed to yield ed earlier. In particular, let:
v : $100 (same value as the unit acquisition cost in

the subsequent project)
h P (D )
"  T : 1 year
" / D : 200 P : 0.10
 
     
Q D Q¹ 1 1 D : 300 P : 0.20
; #  exp ! ! . (10)  
 ¹ D   D : 400 P : 0.40
  
472 K.A. Willoughby / Int. J. Production Economics 71 (2001) 467}472

D : 500 P : 0.20 could extend this to the case of multiple procure-


 
D : 600 P : 0.10 ment opportunities during the project.
 
B : $3000

B : 0.5
 Acknowledgements
We "nd that Q*"400 units and that
The research leading to this paper was partially
ETC(400)"$46,157.96. Moreover, we note that
supported by the Natural Sciences and Engineering
(due to the EIPC value found in Section 2) any
Research Council of Canada under Grant No.
on-hand stock after the conclusion of the initial
A1485 and by the Carma Chair at the University of
project will be retained to satisfy usage during the
Calgary.
subsequent project. The disposal of surplus stock is
not warranted.
References

[1] Blake Construction Co. v. C.J. Oakley Co., 431 A.2d 569
4. Conclusions (D.C. 1981). Transactions of the American Association of
Cost Engineers, 1993. C.11.1.
This paper has developed a mathematical deci- [2] E.A. Silver, Policy and procedural issues in procurement
sion-making tool to assist practitioners in manag- and logistics for large-scale projects in the oil and gas
ing project inventories. There is considerable industry, Project Management Journal 18 (1) (1987) 57}62.
[3] E.A. Silver, Materials management in large-scale construc-
opportunity for further exploration in this vital tion projects: Some concerns and research issues, Engineer-
decision-making area. A possible extension would ing Costs and Production Economics 15 (1989) 223}229.
be to model an important, expensive item (e.g. [4] Y. Fukuda, Optimal disposal policies, Naval Research
compressors, valves, electrical control devices) that Logistics Quarterly 8 (1961) 221}227.
is required during the initial project, but also [5] T.J. Teisberg, A dynamic programming model of the U.S.
strategic petroleum reserve, Bell Journal of Economics 12
has operational usage (as a spare part) during the (1981) 526}546.
ongoing operations of the constructed facility. In [6] J. Simpson, A formula for decisions on retention or dis-
this case, retaining surplus stock after project con- posal of excess stock, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly
struction could help to satisfy both subsequent 2 (1955) 145}155.
project requirements and ongoing operational [7] R.J. Tersine, R.A. Toelle, Optimum stock levels for excess
inventory items, Journal of Operations Management
usage. High unit costs may be incurred to replenish 4 (1984) 245}258.
small lots of this item to satisfy ongoing usage [8] D.B. Rosen"eld, Disposal of excess inventory, Operations
(there would be no `quantity discountsa), so reten- Research 37 (1989) 404}409.
tion of surplus stock after the initial project may [9] D.E. Smith-Daniels, V.L. Smith-Daniels, Finding lot sizes
become more attractive. for materials used in projects, Production and Inventory
Management Journal 27 (1986) 61}71.
We have considered a situation in which there [10] C. Gurnani, Economic analysis of inventory systems, In-
existed only a single procurement opportunity at ternational Journal of Production Research 21 (1983)
the beginning of the initial project. Obviously, one 261}277.

You might also like