You are on page 1of 23

Why Would Corporations Behave in Socially Responsible Ways?

An Institutional Theory
of Corporate Social Responsibility
Author(s): John L. Campbell
Source: The Academy of Management Review , Jul., 2007, Vol. 32, No. 3 (Jul., 2007), pp.
946-967
Published by: Academy of Management

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/20159343

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Academy of Management is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The Academy of Management Review

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
? Academy of Management Review
2007, Vol. 32, No. 3, 946-967.

WHY WOULD CORPORATIONS BEHAVE IN


SOCIALLY RESPONSIBLE WAYS? AN
INSTITUTIONAL THEORY OF CORPORATE
SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY
JOHN L. CAMPBELL
Dartmouth College and Copenhagen Business School

I offer an institutional theory of corporate social responsibility consisting of a se?es


of propositions specifying the conditions under which corporations are likely to
behave in socially responsible ways. I argue that the relationship between basic
economic conditions and corporate behavior is mediated by several institutional
conditions: public and private regulation, the presence of nongovernmental and other
independent organizations that monitor corporate behavior, institutionalized norms
regarding appropriate corporate behavior, associative behavior among corporations
themselves, and organized dialogues among corporations and their stakeholders.

Concerns about corporate social responsibil pendent variable only 15 percent of the time
ity have grown significantly during the last two (twenty-two studies). Moreover, they criticized
decades. Not only has the issue become com this literature for ignoring factors other than cor
monplace in the business press and among porate financial performance that might affect
business and political leaders (Buhr & Graf corporate social responsibility. As a result, they
str?m, 2004) but a body of academic literature called for more serious theoretical inquiry into
has also emerged around it (Margolis & Walsh, this matter (2003: 274-278). Others concur with
2003; Walsh, Weber, & Margolis, 2003). Neverthe this assessment (Maignan & Ralston, 2002: 512)
less, little theoretical attention has been paid to and complain, in particular, that we need to pay
understanding why or why not corporations act much more attention to the institutional mecha
in socially responsible ways (Rowley & Berman, nisms that may influence whether corporations
2000; Ullman, 1985). Indeed, much of the litera
act in socially responsible ways or not (Buhner,
ture on corporate social responsibility has been Rasheed, Rosenstein, & Yoshikawa, 1998: 148;
more descriptive or normative than positivist in Doh & Guay, 2006; Orlitzky, Schmidt, & Rynes,
tone (e.g., Harvard Business School Press, 2003). 2003; Walsh et al., 2003: 877). This paper helps to
Most of the theoretically oriented research on
fill this theoretical void by exploring a broad set
this subject has focused on investigating the of institutional conditions under which socially
connection between corporate social responsi
responsible corporate behavior is likely to occur.
bility and corporate financial performance
To some people the idea of corporations act
(Rowley & Berman, 2000; Walsh et al., 2003). And
ing in socially responsible ways would seem
most often the emphasis there has been on de
silly. If the raison d'?tre for corporations is to
termining the extent to which socially responsi
maximize profit and shareholder value as best
ble corporate behavior affects financial perfor
they can, then it stands to reason that corpora
mance?not the other way around. Margolis and tions will do whatever it takes to achieve this
Walsh (2003: 273-278) reviewed this literature
from 1972 to 2002 and found that socially respon
goal?perhaps even if that includes acting in
socially irresponsible ways if they believe that
sible corporate behavior was treated as the de
they can get away with it. Indeed, whole fields
of economic inquiry, such as the study of eco
I thank Michael Allen, Robert Bies, Eva Boxenbaum, S0ren nomic regulation (e.g., Demsetz, 1968; Stigler,
Christensen, Frank Dobbin, Heather Haveman, Neil Flig 1968) and transaction cost analysis (e.g., North,
stein, Renate Meyer, Ove K. Pedersen, Jesper Strandgaard
1990; Williamson, 1985), are based on these as
Pedersen, Marc Schneiberg, Marc Ventresca, Ann Westen
holz, Christine Wohlforth, and four anonymous AMR review sumptions. For instance, Williamson's (1985:
ers for comments on an earlier draft. Chapter 2) classic transaction cost analysis of
946
Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright
holder's express written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 947

the firm rests on the assumption that individu what conditions are corporations more likely to
als, and by extension the firms that they run, act in socially responsible ways than not?
will act opportunistically?by which he means In this paper I seek to answer this question. I
in self-interested ways and with guile?when do so by drawing on insights from two bodies of
ever possible and, therefore, are not fully trust literature not generally associated with the ac
worthy. ademic discussion of corporate social responsi
Moreover, an extensive body of literature on bility: the literature on institutional analysis in
comparative political economy argues that un sociology and the literature on comparative po
der competitive conditions the separation of cor litical economy in political science. Generally
porate ownership and control from direct pro speaking, what is important about these is that
ducers, consumers, and others creates all sorts they focus on how institutions constrain and en
of structural incentives and opportunities for able behavior.1
firms to benefit themselves at the expense of More specifically, in recent studies scholors
others, to free ride on (rather than contribute to) have argued that the tendency toward socially
collective or public goods, and in some cases to responsible corporate behavior varies across
subvert social welfare, such as by skimping on countries and that much more research is re
product quality and safety, engaging in toxic quired to understand why (Maignan & Ralston,
dumping, and so on, all in the pursuit of short 2002). The comparative political economy litera
term profits or share prices unless institutions ture is useful in this regard because it has a
are in place to mitigate such behavior (e.g., Al long tradition of examining how political and
bert, 1993; Crouch & Streeck, 1997; Dore, 2000; economic institutions vary cross-nationally and
Roe, 2003). And while business associations, affect economic activity. The institutional anal
state regulations, and other forms of economic ysis literature is useful because institutionalists
governance can help solve the problem, they understand that institutions beyond the market
also create opportunities for corporations to pur are often necessary to ensure that corporations
sue new collective forms of opportunistic or are responsive to the interests of social actors
predatory behavior, including the capture and beside themselves, particularly in today's in
subversion of regulatory authorities (e.g., Bern creasingly global economy (Scott, 2003: 346.). In
stein, 1955; Perrow, 2002; Schneiberg, 1999; other words, in both bodies of literature, re
Schneiberg & Bartley, 2001). searchers recognize that the way corporations
There are plenty of examples of firms that, in treat their stakeholders depends on the institu
the pursuit of profit, have exhibited all sorts of tions within which they operate (e.g., Fligstein &
socially irresponsible corporate behavior, such Freeland, 1995; Hall & Soskice, 2001). By stake
as deceiving customers, swindling investors, ex holder I mean individuals or groups with which
ploiting and even brutalizing employees, put the corporation interacts who have a stake or a
ting consumers at risk, poisoning the environ vested interest in it, such as employees, con
ment, cheating the government, and more sumers, suppliers, and local communities
(Vogel, 1992). However, many corporations do nof within which corporations operate (Carroll &
behave in socially irresponsible ways. In fact, Buckholtz, 2000: 21).2 Thus, insights from both
some corporations go to great lengths to do just bodies of literature can help move the analysis
the opposite, by giving to charities, supporting of corporate social responsibility in a more the
community activities, treating their workers and oretically oriented direction.
customers decently, abiding by the law, and The paper proceeds as follows. First, I briefly
generally maintaining standards of honesty and review the literature on corporate social respon
integrity. sibility to identify some important clues that
All of this raises an interesting question for will help focus discussion on the institutional
scholars. Given the incentives for maximizing conditions under which corporations are more or
profit and shareholder value, let alone acting
opportunistically, why would a corporation ever
1 For overviews of both bodies of literature, see Campbell
act in socially responsible ways, even at the (2004: Chapter 1).
most minimal level? Put in slightly different 2 Defining who the most important stakeholders are is a
terms, given the wide range of corporate behav complex conceptual issue that has been addressed else
iors?both good and bad?noted above, under where (e.g., Mitchell, Agle, & Wood, 1997).

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
948 Academy of Management Review July

less likely to act in socially responsible ways. Maggio & Powell, 1983; Fligstein & Freeland,
Second, I provide a definition of socially respon 1995). I leave it to others to consider the deter
sible corporate behavior that identifies a behav minants of socially responsible corporate be
ioral threshold below which corporations no havior that may be operating inside the corpo
longer behave in socially responsible ways. ration, such as the corporation's culture,
This is a slightly unconventional definition com structure, leadership, and managerial compen
pared to those typically found in the literature sation schemes. A systematic treatment of these
on corporate social responsibility, because it fo firm-level factors is beyond the scope of this
cuses on the minimum behavioral standard be paper (but see Aguilera & Jackson, 2003, and
low which corporate behavior becomes socially Mitchell et al., 1997). Hence, I am not making the
irresponsible. By taking this definition as my overly deterministic claim that institutions are
starting point, I help to fill an important blind solely responsible for corporate social responsi
spot in the literature. Third, I explore some of the bility.
conditions under which corporations may be
more or less likely to engage in socially respon INSTITUTIONS AND THE LITERATURE ON
sible behavior as defined in this paper. To begin CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY
with, I argue that basic economic factors, includ
ing the general financial condition of the firm, The literature on corporate social responsibil
the health of the economy, and the level of com ity is vast and has been reviewed in detail else
petition corporations face, are all likely to affect where (e.g., Margolis & Walsh, 2003; Orlitzky et
the degree to which corporations act in socially al., 2003).3 The discussion that follows is in
responsible ways. However, the relationships tended simply to indicate where research on
between economic conditions and socially re this subject provides hints as to how an institu
sponsible corporate behavior are mediated by tionally focused approach to the subject might
several institutional factors: public and private be developed. As noted above, most of the liter
regulation, the presence of nongovernmental ature on corporate social responsibility does not
and other independent organizations that mon explore whether institutional conditions affect
itor corporate behavior, institutionalized norms the tendency for firms to behave in socially re
regarding appropriate corporate behavior, asso sponsible ways. For example, Waddock and
ciative behavior among corporations them Graves (1997) found through regression analysis
selves, and organized dialogues among corpo that an increase in corporate financial perfor
rations and their stakeholders. mance was associated positively with an in
As a result, this paper makes two important crease in corporate social responsibility. Their
contributions to the literature on corporate so analysis is among the best of its kind, particu
cial responsibility. On the one hand, it focuses larly insofar as they constructed a sophisticated
on an important aspect of corporate behavior multidimensional measure of corporate social
that has received very little attention in this responsibility. However, the only independent
literature?that is, the threshold between so variables included in their analysis, beside
cially responsible and irresponsible behavior. measures of corporate financial performance,
On the other hand, it helps to move this litera were firm size, management's risk tolerance,
ture in a more theoretically oriented direction by and type of industry. In this regard, their work is
offering an institutional theory of the determi typical of much research in this field. Most stud
nants of socially responsible corporate behav ies of the determinants of corporate social re
ior. sponsibility have examined the effects of vari
I focus on the institutional determinants of ous aspects of corporate financial performance
corporate social responsibility because firms but not much else (e.g., Brown & Perry, 1994; Fry,
are embedded in a broad set of political and
economic institutions that affect their behavior
(e.g., Campbell, Hollingsworth, & Lindberg, 1991;
3 Much of it concerns whether corporations ought to en
Fligstein, 1990, 2001b; Roe 1991, 1994). These in
gage in socially responsible behavior?a subject that is not
clude forces operating outside the corporation at directly related to this paper (e.g., Friedman, 1970; Jensen,
the macro- and interorganizational or field level 2002; Levitt, 1958; Porter & Kramer, 2003; Prahalad & Ham
within which the corporation maneuvers (Di mond, 2003).

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 949

Keim, & Meiners, 1982; McGuire, Sundgren, & cultural, and other institutions may have been
Schneeweis, 1988). responsible. For example, variation in these in
However, there are a few exceptions. First, stitutions may mediate the degree to which
some of the research on corporate philanthropy stakeholders can influence managers. However,
investigates whether tax law?specifically, the the authors did not explore the institutional im
ability to deduct charitable contributions? plications of their findings. There is a more gen
affects philanthropic giving by firms. Whether it eral body of literature on corporate governance
does or not is in dispute (e.g., Clotfelter, 1985; that has done a better job in arguing that legal,
Navarro, 1988). But the important point is that tax financial, property rights, and other institutions
law is an important property rights institution vary cross-nationally and, therefore, affect the
that may affect corporate behavior (Campbell, degree to which stakeholders can influence cor
2004: 131-132). Hence, this stream of research porate managers (e.g., Aguilera & Jackson, 2003;
suggests that property rights and, by implica Dore, 2000; Roe, 2003). But this literature focuses
tion, other forms of state regulation may affect less on corporate social responsibility per se
the degree to which corporations behave in so than on corporate governance broadly con
cially responsible ways. strued, including, for example, factors that affect
Second, Galaskiewicz (1991) showed that cor the proclivity of managers to take a short- or
porations tend to act in socially responsible long-term view of corporate decision making
ways if normative or cultural institutions are in and investment; to favor upgrading employee
place that create the proper set of incentives for skills or not; and to finance operations through
such behavior. For instance, when corporations bond and equity markets, bank loans, or re
or their managers belonged to business or pro tained earnings.
fessional associations dedicated to charitable Fourth, several scholars have developed what
giving, these corporations were more likely to has become known as stakeholder theory, which
engage in philanthropy. Why? Because mem examines whether and why corporations attend
bership in such organizations instilled in mem to the interests of stakeholders along with their
bers an ethic of enlightened self-interest as they own immediate corporate interests (e.g., Allen,
participated in seminars about the virtues and 1992; Freeman, 1984; Mitchell et al, 1997). Stake
benefits of corporate giving, as they learned of holder theory is closely related to the issue of
such behavior from their counterparts in other corporate social responsibility to the extent that
cities, and as they were exposed to peer pres stakeholder theorists define appropriate and in
sure to behave in these socially responsible appropriate corporate behavior in terms of how
ways. corporations act vis-?-vis their stakeholders
Third, a few researchers have studied corpo (Driver & Thompson, 2002: 117). However, most
rate social responsibility in a comparative stakeholder theory is not well-suited to our pur
cross-national context that has important insti poses because it neglects the question that mo
tutional implications. A case in point is Maig tivates this paper: What are the conditions un
nan and Ralston's (2002) study of firms in France, der which corporations are likely to act in
the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, and the socially responsible ways? Instead, most of the
United States. They examined public commit stakeholder literature focuses on four other is
ments to socially responsible behavior (posted sues (Donaldson & Preston, 1995). It describes
on corporate web sites) of 100 firms in each what the corporation is and who its stakehold
country and found that firms reported three mo ers are. It argues that stakeholders have legiti
tivations for behaving in socially responsible mate interests in corporate activity. It recom
ways: (1) managers valued such behavior in its mends attitudes, structures, and practices that
own right, (2) managers believed that this be constitute stakeholder management. It identi
havior enhanced the financial performance of fies the relationship between stakeholder man
their firms, and (3) stakeholders?notably, com agement and the achievement of various corpo
munity groups, customers, and regulators? rate performance goals, such as profitability,
pressured firms to behave in socially responsi stability, and growth. As such, scholars have
ble ways. The fact that they found systematic argued that stakeholder theory has failed to at
differences in responses across the four coun tend to the social and economic imperatives that
tries suggests that nationally specific political, often confront organizations in contradictory

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
950 Academy of Management Review July

ways (Margolis & Walsh, 2003: 280). These are might include, for instance, measures of how the
precisely the sorts of imperatives on which I corporation treats its employees with respect to
dwell here?imperatives that encourage firms to wages, benefits, and levels of workplace safety;
act in socially responsible ways or not. how it treats its customers with respect to prod
In sum, all of this literature points toward, but uct quality, truth in advertising, and pricing;
in most cases does not systematically develop, how it treats its suppliers with respect to its
an institutional analysis of corporate social re willingness to uphold contracts and honor more
sponsibility. I draw on this work where appro informal commitments; how it treats the govern
priate, as well as the literature on institutional ment with respect to operating within the law
analysis and comparative political economy, to and not trying to subvert it; and how it treats the
develop a set of testable propositions about how community with respect to making charitable
regulatory, normative, associative, stakeholder, contributions, ensuring not to foul the environ
and other institutions affect corporate social re ment, and so forth.
sponsibility. But first we need to be clear about Furthermore, what passes as socially respon
the meaning of socially responsible corporate sible corporate behavior shifts historically. Dur
behavior. ing the Industrial Revolution, reducing the stan
dard factory working day from fourteen to ten
hours may have been considered socially re
WHAT IS SOCIALLY RESPONSIBLE sponsible. But today anything more than eight
CORPORATE BEHAVIOR? hours would probably seem unacceptable in ad
vanced capitalist countries, at least unless hefty
Defining socially responsible corporate be overtime wages were paid.
havior is not a straightforward exercise (e.g., Finally, we need to distinguish between the
Maignan & Ralston, 2002: 498; Roberts, 2003; rhetoric of socially responsible corporate be
Rowley & Berman, 2000). This is because several havior and substantive action. That is, corpo
issues are at stake. To begin with, what consti rations may pay lip service in corporate re
tutes socially responsible behavior may vary ports, advertising, web sites, and elsewhere to
according to our point of view. On the one hand, the idea that they act in socially responsible
we might adopt a more or less objective criteria ways. But their rhetoric may diverge from their
of acceptable behavior against which firms can substantive behavior insofar as they take the
be judged as being socially responsible or not. issue seriously and dedicate significant re
For instance, we might define socially responsi sources to it (Roberts, 2003; Weaver, Trevi?o, &
ble behavior as that which provides the corpo Cochran, 1999). This should not be surprising.
ration's employees with a decent living wage After all, organizations often engage in sym
relative to local costs of living as determined by bolic and rhetorical framing in order to man
some independent organization, such as the age their public image (Hirsch, 1986; Meyer &
United Nations. Or we might define socially re Rowan, 1977). My concern in subsequent sec
sponsible behavior as that which does not ruin tions of this paper is with the substantive
the local environment and jeopardize the com rather than the symbolic or rhetorical aspects
munity's health as measured against interna of corporate social responsibility.
tionally accepted standards of environmental The point is that socially responsible corpo
quality or health. On the other hand, we might rate behavior may mean different things in dif
use more subjective criteria and adopt the per ferent places to different people and at different
spective of the stakeholders who interact with a times, so we must be careful in how we use the
corporation. In this case we can argue that cor concept and how we define it. And care is re
porate behavior is socially responsible as long quired in measuring the degree to which corpo
as it meets these actors' expectations regarding rations are actually behaving in socially re
appropriate and acceptable corporate behavior, sponsible ways or simply making hollow claims
however they choose to define it. to that effect. Finally, caution is warranted be
There are also several dimensions that we cause the concept itself is a fairly new one in the
might use to identify important aspects of so world and because its different local meanings,
cially responsible corporate behavior (Rowley & which are only now beginning to diffuse inter
Berman, 2000; Waddock & Graves, 1997). These nationally, have not yet congealed in a single

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 951

commonly accepted definition (Boxenbaum, insofar as it assumes that, in the absence of


2004).4 institutional constraints in the environment that
I view corporations as acting in socially re mitigate such behavior, firms will have interests
sponsible ways if they do two things. First, they and incentives that may cause them to behave
must not knowingly do anything that could in socially irresponsible ways as I have defined
harm their stakeholders?notably, their inves them. In other words, in the absence of these
tors, employees, customers, suppliers, or the lo institutions, firms will be more likely to behave
cal community within which they operate. Sec irresponsibly than they would if such institu
ond, if corporations do cause harm to their tions were present.
stakeholders, they must then rectify it whenever By focusing on the threshold between irre
the harm is discovered and brought to their at sponsible and minimally responsible corporate
tention. Rectification could be done voluntarily behavior, my definition differs from the conven
or in response to some sort of encouragement, tional definition that other researchers use.
such as moral suasion, normative pressure, le Many of them define corporate social responsi
gal threats, regulatory rulings, court orders, and bility as actions taken by a firm that are in
the like. This is a definition that sets a minimum tended to further social welfare beyond the di
behavioral standard with respect to the corpora rect economic, technical, and legal interests of
tion's relationship to its stakeholders, below the firm (e.g., Davis, 1973; McWilliams & Siegel,
which corporate behavior becomes socially irre 2001). I do not deny that this conventional defi
sponsible. Unless noted otherwise, this is the nition is useful in that it draws our attention to
definition that I will use throughout the rest of important issues that are worth studying (e.g.,
this paper.5 Harvard Business School Press, 2003), but my
This definition fits squarely with the insights concern in this paper is only with the conditions
of comparative political economists, institution under which corporations meet the minimum
alists, and others noted earlier who have em level of socially responsible behavior as I have
phasized the problems of opportunism, moral defined it. Why?
hazard, and the erosion of public or collective The issue of doing harm (intentionally or not)
goods (e.g., North, 1990; Ostrom, 1990; Streeck, largely has been ignored in the literature on
1997). My definition draws from this literature corporate social responsibility (but see Bartley,
2003; Grant, 1997; Grant & Downey, 1996). In fact,
no mention is made of the issue in three recent
4 Differences in definitions are not just a matter of aca comprehensive reviews of the literature (Margo
demic concern. The clash over different local definitions of
lis & Walsh, 2003; Orlitzky et al., 2003; Walsh et
corporate social responsibility can have serious practical
consequences in the real world. As is well known, the Nike
al., 2003). To put this in slightly different terms,
Corporation was embroiled in a major scandal by paying we can array examples of socially responsible
workers in its Southeast Asian athletic footwear plants corporate behavior along a continuum ranging
wages that were quite low but still in accordance with the from minimally responsible behavior, as I have
local customs there. Elsewhere, Nike paid substantially defined it, to increasingly more responsible be
higher wages?but again, wages that were in accordance
haviors, as others have defined them. Granted,
with local customs in these other places. The scandal
erupted amidst charges that Nike was operating according it might be difficult for everyone to agree on
to a double standard (Martin, 2003: 96). which specific instances of corporate social re
5 Some people might argue that, for some corporations, sponsibility fit where along this continuum. But
the very nature of the business they are in may be deemed the point is that virtually all of the literature on
socially irresponsible. That is, some people might distin corporate social responsibility has neglected
guish between firms whose business may be inherently
irresponsible?perhaps weapons manufacturing?and firms
the minimum end of the continuum, focusing
instead on behaviors located toward the other
whose business may be responsible but whose practices
may not. An extreme example of the latter would be the end. This is both surprising and important,
German firm LG. Farben, whose basic business, chemical given the fact that some firms may score quite
manufacturing, was all right but whose particular business high on corporate social responsibility by con
practices at one time were not?that is, the deliberate man
ventional definitions but very low by my defini
ufacturing and sale during the Second World War of Zyclon
B, a poison gas, to the Nazis for purposes of genocide. This tion. For instance, a firm may do lots of public
paper is not concerned with whether the basic nature of a service work and contribute heavily to charities
business itself is socially responsible. but systematically foul the environment, steal

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
952 Academy of Management Review July

from its employees' pension fund, or discrimi interests in corporate social responsibility as it
nate against women in the workplace. As a re is conventionally defined (Friedman, 1970;
sult, there is a blind spot in this literature that Jensen, 2002; Levitt, 1958). Many students of eco
requires attention, which this paper helps to fill. nomic regulation, transaction cost analysis, and
comparative political economy also accept this
UNDER WHAT CONDITIONS DO FIRMS ACT behavioral assumption but take an even stron
IN SOCIALLY RESPONSIBLY WAYS? ger position regarding its implications. They
maintain that the imperative of profit and share
Now let us get to the heart of the matter. Why holder value maximization may cause corpora
do some corporations act in socially responsible tions to act in ways that do not even meet the
ways while others do not? Is socially responsi minimum threshold of socially responsible be
ble corporate behavior purely voluntary and de havior as I have defined it.
pendent on having honorable people in charge, Two arguments flow from this. First, much of
or is there something more to it? Put in slightly the extant literature on corporate social respon
different terms, under what conditions are firms sibility suggests that firms whose financial per
more likely to act in socially responsible ways? formance is weak are less likely to engage in
This is a question that pushes us quickly into socially responsible corporate behavior, con
the fields of institutional analysis and compar ventionally defined, than firms whose financial
ative political economy, because one way to an performance is strong (e.g., Margolis & Walsh
swer the question is to compare variation in 2001; Orlitzky et al., 2003). Why? Because firms
corporate behavior across different institutional that are less profitable have fewer resources to
environments and countries. spare for socially responsible activities than
To facilitate such a research agenda, I offer firms that are more profitable?an argument
several propositions about the factors that may that is often referred to as slack resource theory
affect the degree to which corporations act in (Waddock & Graves 1997). It follows, then, that
socially responsible ways. I begin with a brief firms whose financial performance is so weak
discussion of some basic economic conditions that they risk suffering serious losses and jeop
that may affect corporate behavior. I do so be ardizing shareholder value may be less inclined
cause it is important to recognize that institu to meet even the minimum threshold of socially
tions, the focus of this paper, are not the only responsible behavior as I define it than firms
factors that may affect corporate behavior. Eco whose financial situation is stronger. This as
nomics certainly matter too. However, my over sumes, of course, that managers think that act
riding argument is that variation in socially re ing in socially irresponsible ways will improve
sponsible corporate behavior is probably their firm's financial situation and that they can
associated with variation in institutions and the get away with it. That is, managers act opportu
sticks and carrots they provide to constrain and nistically (i.e., with self-interest and guile). Sim
enable behavior. In a nutshell, my argument is ilarly, if firms are operating in an economic cli
that economic conditions affect the degree to mate where, for instance, inflation is high,
which corporations act in socially responsible productivity growth is low, consumer confidence
ways but that this relationship is mediated by a is weak, and, in short, it appears that it will be
variety of institutional factors. relatively difficult for firms to turn a healthy
profit in the near term, they will be less likely to
Economic Conditions behave in socially responsible ways than would
otherwise be the case.
To review briefly, I assume that the impera
tive of maximizing profit and shareholder value Proposition J: Corporations will be
is the root cause that may prevent corporations less likely to act in socially responsi
from acting in socially responsible ways. This ble ways when they are experiencing
assumption is widely held. Proponents of the relatively weak financial perfor
so-called contractarian view of the firm argue mance and when they are operating
that interests in maximizing profit and value lie in a relatively unhealthy economic
at the heart of the modern corporation and that environment where the possibility for
these interests ought to take precedence over near-term profitability is limited.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 953

Second, if this proposition is true, then it fol Friedman, 1962: 128). Although not all econo
lows that the odds that firms will act in socially mists agree that state regulation is the best way
responsible ways will also be associated with to handle the problems associated with monop
the level of competition they face. To begin with, oly conditions, virtually all agree that monop
in situations where competition is so extremely oly, if left unchecked, will likely result in irre
intense that profit margins are narrow enough sponsible corporate behavior because of the fact
to put shareholder value and firm survival at that firms will operate opportunistically if they
risk, the incentive to cut corners and save money believe they can get away with it (e.g., William
wherever possible will cause corporations to act son, 1985: Chapter 13).
in socially irresponsible ways insofar as they
Proposition 2: Corporations will be
believe that this will help them turn a profit and
less likely to act in socially responsi
survive. Indeed, business history is brimming
ble ways if there is either too much or
with examples of how periods of very intense
too little competition. That is, the rela
competition caused firms to do all sorts of so
tionship between competition and so
cially irresponsible things in order to survive,
cially responsible corporate behavior
including compromising product safety and will be curvilinear.
quality, sweating labor, and cheating customers
(Kolko, 1963; McCraw, 1984; Schneiberg, 1999; One caveat is in order. Competition is a com
Weinstein, 1968). plex phenomenon. Corporations can deal with it
However, under normal competitive condi in a variety of ways in order to obtain competi
tions, where at least a modest profit is assured tive advantage over their rivals. One way is to
and firm survival per se is not at stake, firms are act in socially irresponsible ways, as I have just
less likely to engage in socially irresponsible indicated. But firms can also seek to deprive
practices. Why? The imperative to behave irre their rivals of competitive advantage in other
sponsibly has lessened, and, as a result, man ways. For instance, in the area of international
agers become more concerned with preserving trade, corporations that face competition from
the reputation of their firms for the sake of con lower-cost imports may try to have regulatory
tinued business success. After all, if the reputa and other institutional obstacles created that
tion of a firm is compromised, it often becomes improve their competitive position relative to
more difficult for the firm to continue doing busi foreign producers, such as tariffs, import sur
ness with its customers and suppliers. When charges, and product safety or environmental
customers and suppliers no longer trust a firm, requirements. Of course, low-cost foreign pro
they take their business elsewhere, and the ducers often resist. Indeed, international trade
firm's profitability may be compromised (Mac disputes and the political struggles that sur
Caulay, 1963). round the creation of transnational market
Finally, at the other extreme, in situations zones, such as NAFTA, the European Union, and
where competition is virtually nil (e.g., monop Mercosur, have often involved disputes of this
oly or monopsony), firms may have little interest kind (Duina, 2006). The point is that corporations
in acting in socially responsible ways because do not necessarily have to resort to socially ir
things like corporate reputation or customer loy responsible behavior in order to cope with com
alty will not likely affect sales, profitability, or petitive pressures, at least where international
survival very much. This is because, under such commerce is concerned.
conditions, customers and suppliers have few if However, conflicts of this sort may still be
any alternatives. For instance, monopoly condi related to issues of corporate social responsibil
tions can lead to severe price gouging?a so ity. Struggles for international competitive ad
cially irresponsible corporate behavior in terms vantage, which by most accounts have in
of its effects on customers. This is one reason creased as economic activity became more
many economists have argued that, barring out globalized during the late twentieth century,
right government ownership, the state should have led corporations and others to press na
regulate corporations under monopoly condi tional governments to adopt a range of neolib
tions in order to mitigate some of the market eral policies: reductions in taxes, welfare expen
failures and negative externalities that concern ditures, and business regulations (e.g.,
students of corporate social responsibility (e.g., Campbell & Pedersen, 2001). Many people have

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
954 Academy of Management Review July

complained that these policies have contributed move investments and production from one reg
to increased economic inequality, environmen ulatory regime to another has increased. Many
tal degradation, and other socioeconomic ills people believe that because national govern
(e.g., Gilpin, 2000; Wade & Veneroso, 1998a,b). ments do not want to lose local investment, pro
These are the sorts of problems that people often duction, jobs, and tax revenues, they are forced
attribute to the irresponsible behavior of corpo to ease business regulations (e.g., McKenzie &
rations and that cause people to beseech corpo Lee, 1991; Ohmae, 1990, 1995)?regulations that
rations to act in more socially responsible ways. help militate against socially irresponsible cor
porate behavior.6 Indeed, the threat of capital
Institutional Conditions disinvestment has long been an important con
cern for regulators at subnational levels of gov
Remember that researchers have called for ernment, at least in the United States, that has
greater attention to the factors that moderate the mitigated the imposition and enforcement of
relationship between economic conditions, such more stringent corporate regulations (e.g., Cren
as corporate financial performance, and socially son, 1971).
responsible corporate behavior. Toward that Of course, it is not just the presence of regu
end, let us now turn to a discussion of institu lations per se that matters but also the capacity
tional factors. of the state to monitor corporate behavior and
To begin with, consider the most obvious in enforce these regulations when necessary. We
stitutional explanation of socially responsible should not assume that states will always do
corporate behavior?one that focuses on the this effectively. Many researchers have argued
state's regulatory sanctions. The importance of that corporations may not only resist the impo
regulations is clear if we take an historical view. sition of regulations in the first place but may
Meat packers in the United States, for instance, also seek to control or otherwise capture regu
operated during the early twentieth century lators in ways that bend them toward the will of
with much less concern for food safety and qual the corporations they are supposed to oversee
ity than they did after the Department of Agri (Bernstein, 1955; Kolko, 1963; Vogel, 1989; Wein
culture moved to regulate the industry. Indeed, stein, 1968). As such, much hinges on the insti
their earlier behavior was so irresponsible that tutional design and configuration of regulation
it provided a notorious source of inspiration for and the balance of political forces surrounding
muckraking journalists of the day. And work it.

place safety in the packing plants has improved Institutionalists and comparative political
considerably since the Occupational Safety and economists have long recognized this (e.g.,
Health Administration began supervising shop Campbell, 1988: Chapters 5 & 8; Kelman, 1981;
floor practices (Portz, 1991). Similarly, it has been Vogel, 1986). For example, air pollution regula
widely reported that government deregulation tions were devised and deployed in Sweden and
during the 1980s and 1990s created an environ the United States during the late 1960s and early
ment where U.S. corporations began to take 1970s, but in very different ways and with very
more liberties and act in more socially irrespon different outcomes. In Sweden the process in
sible ways than they would have otherwise. For volved extensive and inclusive consultation and
example, observers have argued that the sav negotiation with business, environmentalists,
ings and loan crisis, the Enron debacle, the U.S. scientists, government agencies, and political
accounting frauds, and other corporate scandals parties. The result was a set of practical regula
of the 1990s can all be attributed in large part to tions that did not exceed the available technol
financial deregulation (Stiglitz, 2003). And Italy's ogies and that took seriously economic as well
feeble stock market regulation has been blamed as environmental consequences. Business and
in part for the Parmalat scandal (Economist, the other parties to negotiation were satisfied,
2004).
Whether the scandals of the 1990s are indica
6 The general argument about the drive toward deregula
tive of a more systemic turn away from corpo
tion, lost tax revenue, and the like that is alleged to stem
rate social responsibility is a matter of consid from increased globalization is hotly debated. For dissent
erable speculation. Particularly in an era of ing views, see, for example, Hirst and Thompson (1996),
increased globalization, the capacity for firms to Gilpin (2000), and Campbell (2003, 2004: Chapter 5).

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 955

and implementation turned out to be quite effec by industrial associations whose job, in part, is
tive. In the United States, however, the process to ensure that their members act in socially re
was much less inclusive with respect to busi sponsible ways. For instance, the dairy industry
ness, more contentious, and the regulations that in many European countries adopted this sort of
were passed were rather impractical because self-regulation approach, based largely on net
they set standards that were nearly impossible works of dairy cooperatives, to maintain certain
to achieve given the available technologies. levels of quality in milk, butter, cheese, and
Hence, corporations fought implementation at other products (O'Rourke, 2006; Streeck &
every turn, in part because they did not feel they Schmitter, 1985b). Recently, this sort of activity
had been given an adequate voice in the pro has taken on a global dimension. New organi
cess. In the end, regulation was much less effec zations, such as Transparency International,
tive than it was in Sweden (Lundqvist, 1980). which is supported by sixty-four corporations
The fact that the creation and enforcement of from the United States and other countries, have
effective state regulations turn in part on the been created to help reduce corrupt business
capacity of external actors, such as environmen practices around the world (Porter & Kramer,
talists, unions, consumers, and other stakehold 2003: 40).
ers, to participate in and monitor these regula Comparative political economists and institu
tory processes is something that has received tionalists have shown that self-regulation by in
some attention from institutionalists in organi dustry association is often linked to the state.
zation studies (e.g., Troast, Hoffman, Riley, & Sometimes this sort of activity is encouraged
Bazerman, 2002). For instance, research suggests and authorized by the state so that the state can
that government statutes are most effective in displace on to these private associations what
facilitating socially responsible corporate envi would otherwise be its own regulatory respon
ronmental behavior if they afford citizens access sibilities (Streeck & Schmitter, 1985a). This polit
to information about toxic emissions, legal ical move has become more prevalent insofar as
standing in court to sue suspected polluters, and states respond to globalization pressures by
sufficient resources to support both of these ac pursuing neoliberal reforms and passing wel
tivities (Grant, 1997; Grant & Downey, 1996). I fare and regulatory functions on to the private
will return to the issue of monitoring by stake sector (Bartley, 2003: 434; Maignan & Ralston
holders later. But keeping all of this in mind, 2002: 510). Sometimes industry moves toward
another proposition follows. self-regulation out of a concern that to do other
wise would eventually result in state regulatory
Proposition 3: Corporations will be
intervention. That is, astute members of industry
more likely to act in socially responsi
realize that it is better to control the regulatory
ble ways if there are strong and well
process themselves than to be forced by the
enforced state regulations in place to
state to succumb to a process and a set of stan
ensure such behavior, particularly if
dards over which they would have little control
the process by which these regula
(Kolko, 1963; Schneiberg, 1999; Streeck & Schmit
tions and enforcement capacities
ter 1985a; Weinstein, 1968). Finally, sometimes
were developed was based on negoti
self-regulation emerges because corporations
ation and consensus building among
fear that state regulation is insufficient to pro
corporations, government, and the
other relevant stakeholders. tect the industry from itself. This happened after
the accident at the Three Mile Island nuclear
It is important to understand that regulation is reactor in 1979. Electric utility companies that
not always the responsibility of the state. Often, owned and operated nuclear facilities through
industries establish their own regulatory mech out the United States recognized that the acci
anisms to ensure fair practices, product quality, dent might have been prevented had the federal
workplace safety, and the like by setting stan government taken a tougher regulatory position
dards to which their members are expected to in the first place. Fearing that another accident
adhere. In fact, sometimes the most effective might ruin the commercial nuclear power indus
means of facilitating increased corporate social try forever, they took matters into their own
responsibility is through corporate peer pres hands and organized a system of self-regulation
sure (Martin, 2003: 98). This is often undertaken designed to set standards, monitor performance,

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
956 Academy of Management Review July

and punish utilities whose behavior failed to litically how effective self-regulation is in en
meet the new industry standards (Campbell, suring that corporations behave in socially
1989). responsible ways. For example, Schneiberg and
As is true for state regulation, effective indus Bart ley (2001) studied the fire insurance industry
trial self-regulation can also be undermined by in early twentieth century America from an in
the very corporations it is designed to oversee. stitutionalist perspective. During this period, the
For instance, there are plenty of examples of industry was regulated by industrial associa
corporations violating cartel agreements (Chan tions. Insurers pooled data on losses, coordi
dler, 1977: Chapter 10) or refusing to abide by nated rates, and set industry standards. How
industrial benchmarks and standards for qual ever, in addition to problems of internal
ity or performance that have been set by indus enforcement and defection from their collective
trial associations (Schneiberg, 1999). Recent agreements, these associations also faced
scandals in the U.S. accounting industry?an mounting political opposition from consumers
industry that has long set its own standards of over rate discrimination, price fixing, and in
acceptable business practice?is another exam competent or unfair claims adjustments. Some
ple of industrial self-regulation gone awry. times this helped improve industry self-regula
Moreover, some instances of industrial self tion. But, in the long run, it led to the
regulation have been devised not only to evade development of various kinds of state interven
state regulation and other forms of external con tion and, ultimately, insurance regulation by
trol but also to facilitate predatory and opportu state governments.
nistic rather than socially responsible corporate I will return to monitoring shortly. For now, the
behavior. Price-fixing cartels are a case in point. important lesson, which parallels the discussion
This is another reason, according to political about state regulation, is that much depends on
economists, the relationship between industrial how self-regulation is organized, the balance of
self-regulation and the state is important. With political forces involved, and how self-regula
out enough support from the state, self-regula tion intersects with the state and its legal insti
tion often fails (Karkkainen, Fung, & Sabel, 2000: tutions.
697). Notably, in the United States the self
Proposition 4: Corporations will be
regulatory association agreements into which
more likely to act in socially responsi
firms have entered have not always been up
ble ways if there is a system of well
held by the courts when associations sued mem
organized and effective industrial
bers who had violated the terms of these agree
self-regulation in place to ensure such
ments (Chandler, 1977; Lindberg & Campbell,
1991). In countries that are more amenable to behavior, particularly if it is based on
the perceived threat of state interven
associative governance and that have property tion or broader industrial crisis and if
rights in place that are more supportive of col
the state provides support for this form
lective business activity, such as the United
of industrial governance.
Kingdom and Germany (Djelic, 1998; Dobbin,
1994), I suspect that the courts are more likely to I have mentioned that the effectiveness of
back up industrial self-regulation. And to the state regulation and industrial self-regulation
extent that self-regulation in the nuclear power may be affected by stakeholder monitoring. In
industry improved plant operation and safety, it deed, scholars of stakeholder theory, corporate
was due in part to the fact that the utility asso governance, and corporate social responsibility
ciation interfaced with the federal government's have intimated that the monitoring of corporate
Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NRC). The performance by stakeholders is an important
NRC now often adopts as law the industry's factor that increases the likelihood corporations
beefed-up standards of conduct, or at least offi will behave in socially responsible ways (Agui
cially acknowledges industrial best practices as lera & Jackson, 2003; Allen, 1992; Driver &
the association defines them (Karkkainen et al., Thompson, 2002; Mitchell et al., 1997).
2000). For example, institutionalists have shown
As is true with respect to state regulation, the that as economic activity has become increas
capacity of various stakeholders to monitor in ingly global, and especially as corporations en
dustrial self-regulation also helps determine po gage in truly multinational operations, a variety

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 957

of nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) have corporate behavior (Doh & Guay, 2006; Teegen,
emerged in an effort to establish codes of con Doh, & Vachani, 2004).
duct and monitor the behavior of corporations. Similarly, social movement organizations
When necessary, NGOs pressure corporations to have emerged around issues of corporate social
behave in more socially responsible ways. Some responsibility and have used tactics resembling
international NGOs have been around for a long those of NGOs (Smith, 2005). For instance, Scan
time, such as the International Labor Organiza dinavian consumer groups long pressed for
tion, the World Wildlife Federation, and the more environmentally friendly paper products
World Health Organization, but their numbers like disposable diapers and toilet tissue. This
are growing (Boli & Thomas, 1999). For instance, pressure helped spur local producers to improve
the International Corporate Governance Net their practices, such as by using unbleached
work was formed by major institutional inves rather than bleached pulp in these products
tors, including TIAA-CREF and the California (Martin, 2003). Social movement campaigns
Public Employees Retirement System, to pro have also targeted specific companies in order
mote improved standards of corporate gover to pressure them to act in more socially respon
nance and disclosure, especially in developing sible ways, as was the case, for example, when
countries (Porter & Kramer, 2003: 41). activists mobilized against key members of both
NGO tactics vary, from appealing directly to the apparel industry for unfair labor practices
the corporations themselves, organizing demon and the timber industry for deforestation (Bart
strations against them, pressuring local govern ley, 2003). Of course, corporate shareholders
ments to force corporations to improve their be have recently mobilized to press corporate
havior, and mobilizing media campaigns to boards to act in more socially responsible ways.
bring public attention to certain alarming corpo Institutional investors and financial intermedi
rate practices (Keck & Sikkink, 1998). Whether or aries, like pension funds and mutual funds,
not they are successful in these efforts depends have become important economic actors control
in part on the political institutions through ling billions of dollars in investments. They
which they operate?institutions that vary con have also come to play an increasingly impor
siderably across countries. In the United States tant role in monitoring corporate behavior and,
NGOs confront a federalist political structure, in some cases, pressing corporations to act in
weak political parties, and a separation of pow environmentally and socially responsible ways
ers among the three branches of government, so (Armour, Deakin, & Konzelmann, 2003). Such
the opportunities for influencing public policy shareholder activism has been described as a
are quite diffuse. In Europe, both at the national new kind of social movement that may affect the
and European Union level, NGOs face more cen degree to which corporations act in socially re
tralized political structures that often grant for sponsible ways (Davis & McAdam, 2000; Davis &
mal standing to interest groups, so NGOs more Thompson, 1994; Maignan & Ralston, 2002: 498).
often enjoy direct access to the policy-making Particularly as economic activity becomes more
process.7 But regardless of the institutional set globalized and, thus, more difficult for national
ting, the success of NGOs also hinges on governments to regulate, the capacity of social
whether they are captured by certain constitu movements, activists, institutional investors,
ents at the expense of others. In any case, NGOs and others to monitor and challenge corporate
have developed an increasing presence in the behavior becomes more important in ensuring
institutional field within which corporations op that corporations act in socially responsible
erate and have worked for socially responsible ways (e.g., Fung, O'Rourke, & Sabel, 2001).
Finally, the press also plays an important role
in that it monitors and reports on corporate be
7 Insofar as this sort of NGO activity is similar to that of havior in ways that discipline corporations by
conventional social movements, research on the determi subjecting them to the constant threat of public
nants of corporate social responsibility would benefit from exposure. Indeed, the press has long been a
incorporating insights from the social movements literature,
watchdog of sorts, keeping both the public and
as well as comparative political economy, regarding how
political opportunity structures affect the degree to which government officials informed about corporate
movement organizations are able to achieve their goals (e.g., activity. But in some countries this role has in
Kitschelt, 1986; McAdam, McCarthy, & Zald, 1996). creased in recent years, to the point where cor

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
958 Academy of Management Review July

porations have dedicated more resources to views on which business models were accept
managing media relations and monitoring the able or not was related in part to the models that
media to appraise the performance of their own received the most attention in the academic and
subsidiaries. As such, the media has increas business press.
ingly played an important role in corporate gov The underlying idea is that managers seek to
ernance (Kjaer & Langer, 2004). act in ways that are deemed appropriate by
All of this is consistent with research that other managers and significant actors in their
shows that ensuring responsible corporate be environment. Institutionalists like these are
havior requires that outsiders?not just state keen on the importance of normative institutions
agencies?are sufficiently strong and well (see also Scott, 2001: Chapter 3). It follows that
organized to provide a counterbalance to corpo these sorts of institutionalized norms may affect
rate power (Schneiberg & Bartley, 2001: 133-141; the degree to which firms operate in socially
see also Schneiberg, 1999, and Schneiberg & responsible ways. Indeed, recognizing this is
Soule, 2005). probably one reason why publications like the
Harvard Business Review have recently run ar
Proposition 5: Corporations wiiJ be
ticles advocating socially responsible corporate
more likely to act in socially responsi
behavior (Harvard Business School Press, 2003)
ble ways if there are private, indepen
and why business schools in Europe and the
dent organizations, including NGOs,
United States have incorporated courses on
social movement organizations, insti
business ethics into their curriculum (Vogel,
tutional investors, and the press, in
1992).
their environment who monitor their
At least one study of corporate social respon
behavior and, when necessary, mobi
sibility has made precisely this point. As noted
lize to change it.
earlier, Galaskiewicz's (1991) research on corpo
So far, my argument has been that institutions rate philanthropy in Minneapolis-St. Paul
and organizations influence corporations by showed that business leaders developed and
constraining their behavior?that is, by discour institutionalized norms that encouraged chari
aging them through rules and negative sanc table giving. The impetus came initially from a
tions or punishments from acting in socially ir conference of local business leaders in 1976,
responsible ways. We know, however, that where a professor from the Harvard Business
institutions can enable as well as constrain ac School lectured on communitarian ideology and
tion (Campbell, 2004: Chapter 3). Institutions can warned that the business community needed to
entice actors to behave in certain ways through come to grips with it. This led to additional con
the use of more positive incentives, rewards, ferences and seminars and, eventually, to the
and other mechanisms. creation of the Minnesota Project on Corporate
The literature on institutional analysis, com Responsibility (MPCR), whose goal was largely
parative political economy, and corporate gov educational. MPCR offered a core curriculum for
ernance has stressed that the cognitive frames, executives that focused on the fundamentals of
mindsets, conceptions of control, or world views corporate responsibility, public-private partner
of corporate managers are important determi ships, international business responsibilities,
nants of how managers run their firms (e.g., and the like. Galaskiewicz found that managers
Aguilera & Jackson, 2003; Dore, 1983; Hall & Sos from local firms that had participated in MPCR
kice, 2001; Whitley, 2004). Scholars emphasize tended to embrace an ethic of enlightened self
that managers often learn these mental con interest and social responsibility. Although he fo
structs by absorbing the messages that are cused on a form of corporate social responsibility
transmitted to them at business schools and that fits the conventional definition better than it
through the professional publications they pay does mine, his basic argument that normative in
close attention to (e.g., the business press, trade stitutions matter holds, regardless of how we de
journals). Fligstein (1990), for example, found fine socially responsible corporate behavior.8
that corporate executives' approaches to man
aging their firms depended in part on the sorts
of training they received in business schools. 8 Of course, once key firms begin to behave in socially
And Guillen (1994) showed that managerial responsible ways, others may follow suit, not so much be

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbeil 959

Institutionalists and some comparative politi ing and health care reform during the 1990s than
cal economists have long recognized that nor firms that were more isolated. This was because
mative institutions vary significantly across firms that were more connected developed a
countries in ways that affect corporate behavior more sophisticated understanding of how gov
(e.g., Dobbin, 1994; Dore, 1983). Indeed, the rela ernment intervention for these sorts of policies
tionship between normative institutions and could improve the overall well-being of their
corporate social responsibility is perhaps most workers, their workers' human capital, and,
noticeable in comparative studies. Japan, for ex thus, corporate performance in the long run. In
ample, long has been known for the fact that its particular, business associations played an im
corporations typically hire employees for life portant role in educating their members on
and, if economic circumstances dictate, will these issues (Martin, 2000). Similarly, Danish
shed labor by reassigning employees to jobs in business associations played a key role during
other closely held firms (Dore, 1983, 2000; West the 1990s in educating their members about the
ney, 2001). The implicit commitment to employee importance of working with labor unions and
security has been under strain recently owing to state officials to fashion labor market and social
the Japanese recession, but many firms are still policies that helped retrain workers, improve
reluctant to engage in mass layoffs for fear of
their skills, support workers during periods of
public criticism. In other words, the normative
unemployment, and help them find new jobs
status of employees as stakeholders in Japanese (Martin, 2005, 2006). Business associations like
society is well-recognized and deeply embed the Chamber of Commerce, as well as local as
ded in business culture. This is not the case in
other countries with different normative stan sociations, have been influential in encouraging
social responsibility in business of various sorts
dards, such as the United States, where mass
(Galaskiewicz, 1991: 305). In all of these cases,
layoffs are not uncommon (Buhner et al., 1998).
business associations were responsible for in
Proposition 6: Corporations will be stitutionalizing a normative climate that facili
more likely to act in socially responsi tated socially responsible corporate behavior
ble ways if they operate in an environ among their members.
ment where normative calls for such Of course, nationally organized business as
behavior are institutionalized in, for sociations also played an important role during
example, important business publica the early twentieth century in helping to edu
tions, business school curricula, and cate their members about the long-term benefits
other educational venues in which of better industrial relations systems, better
corporate managers participate. worker compensation programs, fairer trade
Researchers have argued that when firms be practices, and the like. This was not entirely
long to trade or employer associations and in altruistic insofar as some of this was designed
teract on a more systematic and frequent basis to dampen public concerns about business con
with their peers, they are more likely to develop duct, which farsighted business leaders feared
a relatively long-term view of their interests that might create political problems later. But re
may supercede their short-term views. In the gardless of their motives, this sort of activity did
United States, for instance, firms that belonged cultivate a certain normative environment that
to trade associations and relatively dense inter was conducive to corporate social responsibil
corporate networks that facilitated communica ity. It is important to note, however, that this was
tion among firms were more likely to support not uniformly true for all such organizations
proposals for federal interventions like job train (Schneiberg, 1999). While some of them, such as
the National Civic Federation, were very much
at the forefront in proposing relatively progres
cause they necessarily subscribe to the normative principles sive ideas among their members as well as in
that condone such behavior but because firms often mimic
the halls of Congress, others?notably, the Na
what other firms in their environments do in order to curry tional Association of Manufacturers?were more
legitimacy from them (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). There are at
least a few hints of this sort of mimetic behavior with regard reluctant and in some cases vehemently op
to corporate social responsibility (e.g., Margolis & Walsh, posed the efforts of their more progressive coun
2003: 286; Orlitzky et al., 2003: 426). terparts (Kolko, 1963; Weinstein, 1968).

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
960 Academy of Management Review July

Proposition 7: Corporations will be governance are particularly helpful in this re


more likely to act in socially responsi gard because they have paid much attention to
ble ways if they belong to trade or these institutions and how they vary cross
employer associations, but only if nationally (e.g., Aguilera & Jackson, 2003; Roe,
these associations are organized in 2003).
ways that promote socially responsi Consider first institutions that provide em
ble behavior. ployees with a voice in corporate decision mak
ing. In some countries workers are guaranteed
Communication and education also affect cor by law a voice in corporate decision making. For
porate behavior in other ways. Comparative po instance, in Germany federal statutes guaran
litical economists have written a lot about the tee unions seats on corporate boards of directors
economic benefits associated with interfirm col and rights to participate in a wide range of
laboration and cooperation (Best, 1990; Piore & corporate decision-making activities (Streeck,
Sabel, 1984). But when communication extends 1997). Legislatively mandated works councils
beyond corporations themselves to encompass are another example that many Western Euro
workers, local community leaders, government, pean countries have adopted by law. Works
and others, it appears that corporations begin to councils are representative bodies elected by
better appreciate the concerns of these other employees (regardless of union membership) in
actors and, in turn, take their concerns into ac a workplace that enjoy institutionalized rights of
count when it comes to making corporate policy. access to important corporate information, as
Corporations act in more socially responsible well as rights of codetermination. Codetermina
ways as a result. This is because patterns of tion is shared decision making about matters
interaction affect how actors perceive and de unrelated to wages and benefits, such as the
fine their situations (e.g., Fligstein, 2001a; Os organization of production on the shop floor, the
trom, 1990: Chapter 5; Piore, 1995). development of job classifications, the introduc
For instance, in the United States the state of tion of new technologies, hiring and firing, plant
Pennsylvania suffered a severe economic de closings, and more (Rogers & Streeck, 1994). Sim
cline during the 1970s and early 1980s as its ilarly, in Japan labor law reinforces the notion of
steel manufacturers experienced significant fi the firm as a consensual community where em
nancial losses because of an increase in foreign ployees' interests must be well-represented,
competition. Initially, manufacturers and unions such as in decisions to employ workers on short
locked horns in what each side perceived to be a term contracts rather than the typical life-time
zero-sum game involving issues like wages, employment basis that has governed many Jap
benefits, and especially factory closings. As anese firms for decades (Dore, 2000: 102-104).
long as this confrontational mentality persisted, Of course, representation rights can also be
things continued to stagnate. But then state of established through legally binding collective
ficials encouraged the steel corporations, bargaining agreements between unions and
unions, and representatives from the local com corporations. Needless to say, much of this de
munities to brainstorm collectively for solutions pends on the organizational strength of unions,
to the problem of local industrial decline. This which also varies widely across countries and
effort eventually resulted in more inclusive in depends on the legal and regulatory supports
teractions, greater appreciation for the concerns that the state provides for unions, the degree to
of each other, less hostility, the formation of a which collective bargaining is centralized na
new collective identity, and a variety of innova tionally, and other features of national labor law
tive programs for resurrecting the local econ (Western, 1997). However, the European Union
omy. Part of this caused the steel producers to has passed directives that oblige employers in
act in more socially responsible ways toward all member countries?regardless of the
their workers and toward the communities strength of unions?to enter into processes of
within which they operated (Sabel, 1993). information and consultation with employee
Legal institutions are particularly important representatives at critical moments, such as
in facilitating this sort of dialogue between cor when firms become insolvent or managers try to
porations and stakeholders. The literature on sell the firm to another corporation (Armour et
stakeholders and the literature on corporate al., 2003).

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 961

The German case is worth closer scrutiny be localities; and, in consultation with local actors,
cause it reveals an interesting dynamic uses these data to reformulate and refine per
whereby legal institutions helped transform cor formance standards, desirable targets, and the
porate managers' perceptions of their interests preferred means of achieving them. In turn, the
in ways that benefited employees and others. communities work with the new standards, re
The West German state passed codetermination port back to central government for further revi
legislation shortly after the Second World War. sion, and so on in an iterative process. So,
This meant that workers were systematically through an ongoing dialogue between corpora
involved in corporate decision making. Initially, tions and stakeholders at the community level,
managers were concerned that this would jeop and between the communities and central au
ardize short-term profitability, as well as their thorities, standards, targets, and measures be
managerial prerogatives. However, they came come benchmarks against which the local firms
to realize that these new forms of institutional can then evaluate and regulate their own per
ized dialogue with workers provided benefits formance in cooperation with other actors.
that enhanced the long-term competitiveness of Through this sort of institutionalized practical
their firms. Among other things, this dialogue deliberation, the interests of ordinarily antago
facilitated collaborative problem solving and nistic parties (i.e., corporations and stakehold
flexible labor-management relations on the ers) are often redefined, much as occurred in the
shop floor, which helped firms effectively adjust Pennsylvania and German cases noted earlier,
to shifting market demands and new production and actors?including corporate managers?
technologies. In some cases this enabled firms begin to expand what they believe to be feasible
to reorient production through flexible special environmentally responsible practices. Re
ization in ways that avoided firing workers or search shows that under these new perfor
closing plants. Thus, as a result of a change in mance-based, discursive, rolling-rule regimes,
their institutionalized interactions with labor, firms are more likely to behave in socially re
the mindset of managers shifted, and workers sponsible ways (Karkkainen et al., 2000: 691?
and local communities as well as firms bene 692). This sort of legally sanctioned, dialogue
fited (Streeck, 1997). In other words, firms were based regulation is often viewed as a way to
more inclined to act in socially responsible overcome the inadequacies of conventional in
ways. Managers still defend this institutional dustrial regulation, particularly as globalization
ized dialogue, even under the increased pres undermines the traditional means that govern
sures of global competition (Thelen, 2000). ments have to regulate how corporations treat
Legal institutions have also facilitated delib the environment and their workers (Fagotto &
eration, discourse, and dialogue between corpo Fung, 2003; Fung, 2003).
rations and community stakeholders in ways Of course, legal institutions also determine
that improve corporate social responsibility. the degree to which corporate managers engage
This is particularly evident in the area of indus in dialogue with investors. In Germany and Ja
trial regulation. For example, in the area of en pan, for example, corporate managers share au
vironmental regulation, Sabel and his col thority with large financial intermediaries, par
leagues (Dorf & Sabel, 1998; Karkkainen et al., ticularly banks, which hold concentrated blocks
2000; Sabel, Fung, & Karkkainen, 2000) have ex of stock, thereby making managers highly ac
amined cases in the United States where firms, countable to shareholders. Much dialogue and
local governments, local representatives of fed interaction with representatives of these inter
eral agencies, community members, and others mediaries result. Notably, in Japan managers
have been granted legal authority by central often meet monthly with intermediary represen
government statutes to establish local environ tatives. But in the United States stock ownership
mental performance targets. These local actors is much more diffuse, it is unusual for share
enjoy political autonomy to collectively estab holders to own large concentrated blocks of
lish, monitor, and assess initial performance stock, and financial intermediaries do not con
standards and to adjust practice when neces sult regularly with corporate managers. As a
sary in their communities. Later, a central gov result, U.S. managers typically have much more
ernment agency collects information on all of decision-making autonomy and much less ac
this from each locality; disseminates it across countability to investors.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
962 Academy of Management Review July

Why do these countries differ like this? For act in socially responsible ways the more they
much of the twentieth century, legislation in the encounter strong state regulation, collective in
United States kept banks relatively small by dustrial self-regulation, NGOs and other inde
banning them from operating nationally, enter pendent organizations that monitor them, and a
ing commerce, affiliating with investment banks normative institutional environment that en
or equity mutual funds, and coordinating stock courages socially responsible behavior. More
holdings with other intermediaries. The law was over, socially responsible corporate behavior is
much different in Germany and Japan. As a re more likely to occur to the extent that firms be
sult of these legal differences, managers are long to industrial or employee associations and
much less obliged to engage in dialogue with engage in institutionalized dialogue with stake
their investors in the United States than in these holders.
other countries (Buhner et al., 1998; Roe 1991, Several issues remain. First, it is important to
1993, 2003). This does not mean that investors or recognize that the institutional terrain within
other stakeholders are completely powerless in which corporations operate is not static. Instead,
the United States. Given the United States' com there are dynamic pressures that ebb and flow,
mon law tradition, U.S. stockholders enjoy much causing this terrain to shift over time. This is
stronger voting rights than they do in many Eu certainly true, for example, with respect to insti
ropean countries with civil law traditions. And tutions that facilitate the sort of dialogue that
creditors in the United States also enjoy greater may result in more socially responsible corpo
legal protections against managers than in rate behavior. Bartley (2003) showed that, in re
many European countries (LaPorta, Lopez-de sponse to increased globalization and a desire
Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1998). But voting to move toward neoliberalism, some govern
rights and legal protections do not necessarily ments off-loaded some of their regulatory re
provide for the sort of dialogue and communica sponsibilities to the private sector. Concerned
tion that tends to facilitate the consensus-based about the implications of such a move, social
corporate decision making that occurs in other movements, unions, NGOs, and other stakehold
countries. ers countered by pressing corporations to act in
more responsible ways when it came to caring
Proposition 8: Corporations will be for the environment and treating their workers
more likely to act in socially responsi decently. According to Bartley, the result was
ble ways if they are engaged in insti the emergence of institutionalized dialogues
tutionalized dialogue with unions, among state actors, corporations, activists,
employees, community groups, inves NGOs, unions, institutional investors, and other
tors, and other stakeholders. stakeholders over how best to ensure against
socially irresponsible corporate behavior. In
CONCLUSION several important cases this discourse resulted
in standards of corporate conduct, certification
To summarize briefly, I have argued that eco procedures, monitoring mechanisms, and infor
nomic conditions?specifically, the relative mal public shaming techniques to ensure that
health of corporations and the economy and the corporations behaved responsibly. Often this
level of competition to which corporations are activity was supported with resources from
exposed?affect the probability that corpora states and NGOs.
tions will act in socially responsible ways. This dialogue was truly transnational and
Weak corporate financial performance and an emergent. However, institutions promoting such
unhealthy economy reduce this probability, dialogue over corporate social responsibility
while the level of competition has a more com are also in flux at the subnational level, such as
plex, curvilinear effect, where moderate levels in the United States, where, during the late
of competition tend to elicit more socially re 1980s, several state governments adopted legis
sponsible behavior but either high or low levels lation authorizing boards of directors to con
of competition tend to elicit less socially respon sider the interests of all corporate stakehold
sible behavior. However, a variety of institu ers?not just shareholders (Allen, 1992: 276-277).
tional conditions mediate these basic economic The point is that the pressures of globalization,
relationships. Corporations are more likely to stakeholder activism, political decision making,

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 963

and other forces discussed in this paper will Finally, some suggest that the best way to get
continue to conspire in ways that may change firms to behave in socially responsible ways is
institutions and, therefore, the tendency for cor to convince their managers that it is either the
porations to act in socially responsible ways or right thing to do ethically or is in their self
not. interest (Handy, 2003; Kaku, 2003; Prahalad &
Second, how does my argument about the ne Hammond, 2003). Appeals such a these may
cessity for institutions square with the realities help, but institutions are critical, especially if
that corporations face in an age of increasing we are concerned with ensuring that corpora
economic globalization? Put in slightly different tions actually behave in socially responsible
terms, in order to cope with the pressures of ways, rather than just pay rhetorical lip service
globalization, we hear frequently that govern to the issue. Indeed, if substantively responsible
ments must adopt neoliberal policies, notably corporate behavior improves corporate and, in
deregulation, which are premised on the belief turn, national economic performance and com
that institutional constraints on corporations petitiveness, as seems to have occurred in Scan
tend to undermine competition, market effi dinavia, then policy makers and others?
ciency, and, ultimately, economic performance. including firms themselves?would be wise to
Is my argument about the need for institutions to facilitate the creation and continued nurturing
facilitate socially responsible corporate behav of the sorts of institutions discussed here.
ior incompatible with the rise of a more globally
oriented economic environment and more in
tense international competition? No. In fact, con
REFERENCES
trary to the neoliberal argument, these sorts of
institutions may actually enhance economic Aguilera, R. V., & Jackson, G. 2003. The cross-national diver
sity of corporate governance: Dimensions and determi
performance. For example, evidence in the eco
nants. Academy of Management Review, 28: 447-465.
nomics literature suggests that when corpora
tions treat their workers fairly, such as by pro Albert, M. 1993. Capitalism vs. capitalism. New York: Four
Walls Eight Windows.
viding them with a decent living wage, and
engage in other forms of social justice, national Allen, W. T. 1992. Our schizophrenic conception of the busi
ness corporation. Cardozo Law Review, 14: 261-281.
economic growth and development improve
Armour, J., Deakin, S., & Konzelmann, S. J. 2003. Shareholder
(Kapstein, 1999: 10; see also Putnam & Goss,
primacy and the trajectory of UK corporate governance.
2002: 5-7, and Zak & Knack, 2001). Indeed, the British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41: 531-555.
World Economic Forum (2003) recently ranked
Bartley, T. 2003. Certifying forests and factories: States, so
three Scandinavian countries?Finland, Swe
cial movements, and the rise of private regulation in the
den, and Denmark?among the four most com apparel and forest products fields. Politics and Society
petitive economies in the world. It also ranked 31: 433-464.
them very high in terms of the strong ethical Bernstein, M. H. 1955. Regulating business by independent
behavior of their national corporations. All three commission. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
are very open economies and, therefore, highly Best, M. 1990. The new competition: Institutions of industrial
susceptible to the economic pressures of global restructuring. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
ization, and all three have the sorts of institu Press.
tions that I have argued will facilitate socially Boli, J., & Thomas, G. M. 1999. INGOs and the organization of
responsible corporate behavior.9 world culture. In J. Boli & G. M. Thomas (Eds.), Construct
ing world culture: International nongovernmental orga
nizations since 1875: 13-49. Stanford, CA: Stanford Uni
versity Press.
9 These Scandinavian countries have much state regula Boxenbaum, E. 2004. Institutional innovation processes: A
tion, self-regulation, corporatist bargaining?including hybridization of institutional logics. Paper presented at
well-organized business associations?and other mecha the annual meeting of the Academy of Management,
nisms for institutionalized dialogue among firms and their New Orleans.
stakeholders (e.g., Campbell & Hall, 2006; Hall & Soskice,
2001; Katzenstein, 1985; Lazonick & O'Sullivan, 1996). So far, Brown, B., & Perry, S. 1994. Removing the financial perfor
these institutions have persisted despite increased global mance halo from Fortune's "most admired" companies.
Academy of Management Journal, 37: 1347-1359.
ization (Armour et al., 2003; Fligstein, 2001b: Chapter 9; Flig
stein & Freeland, 1995; Guillen, 2000; O'Sullivan, 2003; Buhner, R., Rasheed, A., Rosenstein, J., & Yoshikawa, T. 1998.
Swank, 2002). Research on corporate governance: A comparison of

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
964 Academy of Management Review July

Germany, Japan, and United States. Advances in Inter organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48:
national Comparative Management, 12: 121-155. 147-160.

Buhr, H., & Grafstr?m, M. 2004. "Corporate social responsibil Djelic, M.-L. 1998. Exporting the American model: The post
ity" edited in the business press. Paper presented at the war transformation of European business. New York: Ox
conference on Corporate Social Responsibility in the Era ford University Press.
of the Transforming Welfare State, Florence, Italy. Dobbin, F. 1994. Forging industrial policy. New York: Cam
Campbell, J. L. 1988. Collapse of an industry: Nuclear power bridge University Press.
and the contradictions of U.S. policy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Doh, J. P., & Guay, T. R. 2006. Corporate social responsibility,
University Press. public policy, and NGO activism in Europe and the
Campbell, J. L. 1989. Corporations, collective organization, United States: An institutional-stakeholder perspective.
and the state: Industry response to the accident at Three Journal of Management Studies, 43: 47-73.
Mile Island. Social Science Quarterly, 70: 650-666. Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. E. 1995. The stakeholder theory of
Campbell, J. L. 2003. States, politics, and globalization: Why the corporation: Concepts, evidence, and implications.
institutions still matter. In T. V. Paul, G. J. Ikenberry, & Academy of Management Review, 20: 65-91.
J. A. Hall (Eds.), The nation-state in question: 234-259. Dore, R. 1983. Goodwill and the spirit of market capitalism.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. British Journal of Sociology, 34: 459-482.
Campbell, J. L. 2004. Institutional change and globalization. Dore, R. 2000. Stock market capitalism, welfare capitalism:
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Japan and Germany versus the Anglo-Saxons. New York:
Campbell, J. L., & Hall, J. A. 2006. The state of Denmark. In J. L. Oxford University Press.
Campbell, J. A. Hall, & O. K. Pedersen (Eds.), National Dorf, M. C, & Sabel, C. F. 1998. A constitution of democratic
identity and the varieites of capitalism: The Danish ex experimentalism. Columbia Law Review, 98: 267-473.
perience: 3-49. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University
Press. Driver, C, & Thompson, G. 2002. Corporate governance and
democracy: The stakeholder debate revisited. Journal of
Campbell, J. L., Hollingsworth, J. R., & Lindberg, L. N. (Eds.). Management and Governance, 6: 111-130.
1991. Governance of the American economy. New York:
Duina, F. 2006. The social construction of free trade: The
Cambridge University Press.
European Union, NAFTA, and Mercosur. Princeton, NJ:
Campbell, J. L., & Pedersen, O. K., 2001. The rise of neoliber Princeton University Press.
alism and institutional analysis. In J. L. Campbell &
O. K. Pedersen (Eds.), The rise of neoliberalism and in Economist. 2004. European corporate governance: Turning
sour. January 3: 8-9.
stitutional analysis: 1-24. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni
versity Press. Fagotto, E., & Fung, A. 2003. Improving workplace hazard
communication, issues in Science and Technology, Win
Carroll, A. B., & Buckholtz, A. K. 2000. Business and society:
ter: 63-68.
Ethics and stakeholder management. Cincinnati: South
western Publishing. Fligstein, N. 1990. The transformation of corporate control.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A. D. 1977. The visible hand: The managerial rev
olution in American business. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Fligstein, N. 2001a. Social skills and the theory of fields.
Press of Harvard University Press. Sociological Theory, 19: 105-125.
Clotfelter, C. T. 1985. Federal tax policy and charitable giv Fligstein, N. 2001b. The architecture of markets. Princeton, NJ:
ing. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Princeton University Press.

Crenson, M. A. 1971. The un-politics of air pollution. Balti Fligstein, N., & Freeland, R. 1995. Theoretical and compara
more: Johns Hopkins University Press. tive perspectives on corporate organization. Annual Re
Crouch, C, & Streeck, W. (Eds.). 1997. PoJificaJ economy of view of Sociology, 21: 21-43.

modern capitalism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Freeman, R. E. 1984. Strategic management: A stakeholder
approach. Marshfield, MA: Pitman.
Davis, G. F., & McAdam, D. 2000. Corporations, classes, and
social movements after managerialism. Research in Or Friedman, M. 1962. Capitalism and freedom. Chicago: Uni
ganizational Behavior, 22: 195-238. versity of Chicago Press.

Davis, G. F., & Thompson, T. A. 1994. A social movement Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of business is to
perspective on corporate control. Administrative Sci increase profits. New York Times Magazine, September
ence Quarterly, 39: 141-173. 13: 32-33, 122, 124, 126.

Davis, K. 1973. The case for and against business assump Fry, L. W., Keim, G. D., & Meiners, R. E. 1982. Corporate
tion of social responsibilities. Academy of Management contributions: Altruistic or for-profit? Academy of Man
Journal, 16: 312-323. agement Journal, 25: 94-106.

Demsetz, H. 1968. Why regulate utilities? Journal of Law and Fung, A. 2003. Deliberative democracy and international la
Economics, 11: 55-66. bor standards. Governance, 16(1): 51-71.

DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Fung, A., O'Rourke, D., & Sabel, C. 2001. Can we put an end
Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in to sweatshops? Boston: Beacon Press.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 965

Galaskiewicz, J. 1991. Making corporate actors accountable: comparative study of occupational safety and health
Institution-building in Minneapolis-St. Paul. In W. W. policy. Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technol
Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism ogy Press.
in organizational analysis: 293-310. Chicago: University
Kitschelt, H. 1986. Political opportunity structures and polit
of Chicago Press.
ical protest: Anti-nuclear movements in four democra
Gilpin, R. 2000. The challenge of global capitalism. Prince cies. British Journal of Political Science, 16: 57-85.
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Kjaer, P., & Langer, R. 2004. Infused with news value: Man
Grant, D. S. 1997. Allowing citizen participation in environ agement, managerial knowledge and the institutional
mental regulation: An empirical analysis of the effects ization of business news. Unpublished manuscript, De
of right-to-sue and right-to-know provisions on indus partment of Organization and Industrial Sociology,
try's toxic emissions. Social Science Quarterly, 78: 859 Copenhagen Business School.
874.
Kolko, G. 1963. The triumph of conservatism. Chicago: Quad
Grant, D. S., & Downey, L. 1996. Regulation through informa rangle.
tion: An empirical analysis of the effects of state
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W.
sponsored right-to-know programs on industrial toxic
1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106:
pollution. Policy Studies Review, 14(3/4): 339-352. 1113-1155.
Guillen, M. 1994. Models of management: Work, authority
Lazonick, W., & O'Sullivan, M. 1996. Organization, finance
and organization in comparative perspective. Chicago:
and international competition. Industrial and Corporate
University of Chicago Press.
Change, 5: 1-48.
Guillen, M. 2000. Corporate governance and globalization: Is
Levitt, T. 1958. The dangers of social responsibility. Harvard
there convergence across countries? Advances in Inter
Business Review, 36(5): 41-50.
national Comparative Management, 13: 175-204.
Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. 2001. An introduction to varieties of Lindberg, L. N., & Campbell, J. L. 1991. The state and the
organization of economic activity. In J. L. Campbell, J. R.
capitalism. In P. A. Hall & D. Soskice (Eds.), Varieties of
Hollingsworth, & L. N. Lindberg (Eds.), Governance of the
capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative
American economy: 356-397. New York: Cambridge Uni
advantage: 1-70. New York: Oxford University Press.
versity Press.
Handy, C. 2003. What's a business for? In Harvard Business
Lundqvist, L. 1980. The hare and the tortoise: Clean air poli
Review on corporate social responsibility: 65-82. Boston:
cies in the United States and Sweden. Ann Arbor: Uni
Harvard Business School Press.
versity of Michigan Press.
Harvard Business School Press. 2003. Harvard Business Re
MacCaulay, S. 1963. Non-contractual relations in business: A
view on corporate social responsibility. Boston: Harvard
Business School Press. preliminary study. American Sociological Review, 28:
55-67.
Hirsch, P. M. 1986. From ambushes to golden parachutes:
Corporate takeovers as an instance of cultural framing
Maignan, I. & Ralston, D. A. 2002. Corporate social responsi
and institutional integration. American Journal of Soci bility in Europe and the U.S.: Insights from businesses'
ology, 91: 800-837.
self-presentations. Journal of International Business
Studies, 33: 497-514.
Hirst, P., & Thompson, G. 1996. Globalization in question.
Cambridge: Polity Press. Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. 2001. People and profits? The
search for a link between a company's social and finan
Jensen, M. 2002. Value maximization, stakeholder theory, cial performance. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum As
and the corporate objective function. Business Ethics sociates.
Quarterly, 12: 235-256.
Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. 2003. Misery loves companies:
Kaku, R. 2003. The path of Kyosei. In Harvard Business Re Rethinking social initiatives by business. Administra
view on corporate social responsibility: 105-130. Boston: tive Science Quarterly, 48: 268-305.
Harvard Business School Press.
Martin, C. J. 2000. Stuck in neutral: Business and the politics
Kapstein, E. B. 1999. Sharing the wealth: Workers and the of human capital investment. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
world economy. New York: Norton.
University Press.
Karkkainen, B., Fung, A., & Sabel, C. 2000. After backyard Martin, C. J. 2005. Corporatism from the firm perspective.
environmentalism: Toward a performance-based re British Journal of Political Science, 35: 127-148.
gime of environmental regulation. American Behavioral
Scientist, 44: 690-709. Martin, C. J. 2006. Corporatism in the post-industrial age:
Employers and social policy in the little land of Den
Katzenstein, P. J. 1985. Small states in world markets. Ithaca,
mark. In J. L. Campbell, J. A. Hall, & O. K. Pedersen (Eds.),
NY: Cornell University Press.
National identity and the varieties of capitalism: The
Keck, M., & Sikkink, K. 1998. Activists beyond borders: Advo Danish experience: 271-294. Montreal: McGill-Queen's
cacy networks in international politics. Ithaca, NY: Cor University Press.
nell University Press.
Martin, R. L. 2003. The virtue matrix: Calculating the return
Kelman, S. 1981. Regulating America, regulating Sweden: A on corporate responsibility. In Harvard Business Review

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
966 Academy of Management Review July

on corporate social responsibility: 83-104. Boston: Har tage of corporate philanthropy. In Harvard Business Re
vard Business School Press. view on corporate social responsibility: 27-64. Boston:
Harvard Business School Press.
McAdam, D., McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.). 1996. Com
parative perspectives on social movements. New York: Portz, J. 1991. Economic governance and the American meat
Cambridge University Press. packing industry. In J. L. Campbell, J. R. Hollingsworth, &
McCraw, T. 1984. Prophets of regulation. Cambridge, MA: L. N. Lindberg (Eds.), Governance of the American econ
Harvard University Press. omy: 259-293. New York: Cambridge University Press.

McGuire, J. B., Sundgren, A., & Schneeweis, T. 1988. Corpo Prahalad, C. K., & Hammond, A. 2003. Serving the world's
rate social responsibility and firm financial perfor poor, profitably. In Harvard Business Review on corpo
mance. Academy of Management Journal, 31: 854-872. rate social responsibility: 1-26. Boston: Harvard Business
School Press.
McKenzie, R. B., & Lee, D. R. 1991. Quicksilver capital. New
York: Free Press. Putnam, R. D., & Goss, K. A. 2002. Introduction. In R. D.
Putnam (Ed.), Democracies in flux: The evolution of so
McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. 2001. Corporate social respon
cial capital in contemporary society: 3-20. New York:
sibility: A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of
Oxford University Press.
Management Review, 26: 117-127.
Roberts, J. 2003. The manufacture of corporate social respon
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organiza
sibility: Constructing corporate sensibility. Organiza
tions: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. Ameri
tion, 10: 249-265.
can Journal of Sociology, 83: 340-363.
Roe, M. J. 1991. A political theory of American corporate
Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. 1997. Toward a theory
finance. Columbia Law Review, 91: 10-67.
of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the
principle of who and what really counts. Academy of Roe, M. J. 1993. Some differences in corporate structure in
Management Review, 22: 853-886. Germany, Japan, and the United States. Yale Law Jour
nal, 102: 1927-2003.
Navarro, P. 1988. Why do corporations give to charity? Jour
nal of Business, 61(1): 65-93. Roe, M. J. 1994. Strong managers, weak owners: The political
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and eco roots of American corporate finance. Princeton, NJ:
nomic performance. New York: Cambridge University Princeton University Press.
Press. Roe, M. J. 2003. Political determinants of corporate gover
Ohmae, K. 1995. The end of the nation state. New York: Free nance: Political context, corporate impact. New York:
Press. Oxford University Press.

Ohmae, K. 1990. The borderless world: Power and strategy in Rogers, J., & Streeck, W. 1994. Workplace representation
the interlinked economy. New York: Harper Collins. overseas: The works councils story. In R. B. Freeman
(Ed.), Working under different rules: 97-156. New York:
Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F. L., & Rynes, S. L. 2003. Corporate
Russell Sage Foundation.
social and financial performance: A meta-analysis. Or
ganization Studies, 24: 403-441. Rowley, T., & Shawn, B. 2000. A brand new brand of corporate
social performance. Business and Society, 39: 397-418.
O'Rourke, K. 2006. Late nineteenth century Denmark in an
Irish mirror: Towards a comparative history. In J. L. Sabel, C. 1993. Studied trust: Building new forms of cooper
Campbell, J. A. Hall, & O. K. Pedersen (Eds.), National ation in a volatile economy. In R. Swedberg (Ed.), Explo
identity and the varieites of capitalism: The Danish ex rations in economic sociology: 104-144. New York: Rus
perience: 159-196. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University sell Sage Foundation.
Press.
Sabel, C, Fung, A., & Karkkainen, B. 2000. Beyond backyard
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of environmentalism. Boston: Beacon Press.
institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge
Schneiberg, M. 1999. Political and institutional conditions for
University Press.
governance by association: Private order and price con
O'Sullivan, M. 2003. The political economy of comparative trols in American fire insurance. Politics and Society,
corporate governance. Review of International Political 27(1): 67-103.
Economy, 10(1): 23-72.
Schneiberg, M., & Bartley, T. 2001. Regulating American in
Perrow, C. 2002. Organizing America: Wealth, power, and the dustries: Markets, politics, and the institutional determi
origins of corporate capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton nants of fire insurance regulation. American Journal of
University Press. Sociology, 107: 101-146.
Piore, M. J. 1995. Beyond individualism: How social demands Schneiberg, M., & Soule, S. 2005. Measuring institutional
of the new identity groups challenge American political effects in federated, multi-level systems. In G. F. Davis,
and economic life. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University D. McAdam, W. R. Scott, & M. N. Zald (Eds.), Social
Press.
movements and organization theory: 122-160. New York:
Piore, M. J., & Sabel, C. F. 1984. The second industrial divide. Cambridge University Press.
New York: Basic Books.
Scott, W. R. 2001. Institutions and organizations (2nd ed.).
Porter, M. E., & Kramer, M. R. 2003. The competitive advan Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2007 Campbell 967

Scott, W. R. 2003. Organizations: Rational, natural, and open U.S. firms. Academy of Management Review, 10: 540
systems (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall. 557.

Smith, J. 2005. Globalization and transnational social move Vogel, D. 1986. National styles of regulation: Environmental
ment organizations. In G. F. Davis, D. McAdam, W. R. policy in Great Britain and the United States. Ithaca, NY:
Scott, & M. N. Zald (Eds.), Social movements and organi Cornell University Press.
zation theory: 226-248. New York: Cambridge University
Press. Vogel, D. 1989. Fluctuating fortunes: The political power of
business in America. New York: Basic Books.
Stigler, G. J. 1968. The organization of industry. Home wood,
IL: Irwin. Vogel, D. 1992. The globalization of business ethics: Why
America remains distinctive. California Management
Stiglitz, J. E. 2003. The roaring nineties: A new history of the Review, 35(1): 30-49.
world's most prosperous decade. New York: Norton.
Wade, R., & Veneroso, F. 1998a. The Asian crisis: The high
Streeck, W. 1997. Beneficial constraints: On the economic debt model versus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF com
limits of rational voluntarism. In J. R. Hollingsworth & plex. New Left Review, 228: 3-24.
R. Boyer (Eds.), Contemporary capitalism: The embed
Wade, R., & Veneroso, F. 1998b. The gathering world slump
dedness of institutions: 197-219. New York: Cambridge
and the battle over capital controls. New Left Review,
University Press.
231: 13-42.
Streeck, W., & Schmitter, P. 1985a. Community, market,
state?and associations? The prospective contribution Waddock, S. A., & Graves, S. B. 1997. The corporate social
of interest governance to social order. In W. Streeck & performance-financial performance link. Strategic Man
agement Journal, 18: 303-319.
P. Schmitter (Eds.), Private interest government: Beyond
market and state: 1-29. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Walsh, J. P., Weber, K., & Margolis, J. D. 2003. Social issues
Streeck, W., & Schmitter, P. (Eds.). 1985b. Private interest and management: Our lost cause found. Journal of Man
agement, 29: 859-881.
government: Beyond market and state. Beverly Hills, CA:
Sage. Weaver, G. R., Trevi?o, L. K., & Cochran, P. L. 1999. Integrated
Swank, D. 2002. Global capital, political institutions and and decoupled corporate social performance: Manage
policy change in developed welfare states. New York: ment commitment, external pressures, and corporate
Cambridge University Press. ethics practices. Academy of Management Journal, 42:
539-552.
Teegen, H., Doh, J. P., & Vachani, S. 2004. The importance of
non-governmental organizations (NGOs) in global gov Weinstein, J. 1968. The corporate ideal in the liberal state.
ernance and value creation: An international business Boston: Beacon Press.
research agenda. Journal of International Business Stud Western, B. 1997. Between class and market. Princeton, NJ:
ies, 35: 463-483. Princeton University Press.
Thelen, K. 2000. Why German employers cannot bring them Westney, D. E. 2001. Japanese enterprise faces the twenty
selves to dismantle the German model. In T. Iversen, first century. In P. DiMaggio (Ed.), The twenty-first
J. Pontousson, & D. Soskice (Eds.), Unions, employers and centuryfirm: 105-144. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
central banks: 138-169. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Press.
Whitley, R. 2004. The social construction of organizations
Troast, J. G., Hoffman, A. J., Riley, H. C, & Bazerman, M. H. and markets: The comparative analysis of business rec
2002. Institutions as barriers and enablers to negotiated ipes. In F. Dobbin (Ed.), The new economic sociology:
agreements: Institutional entrepreneurship and the 162-187. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Plum Creek Habitat Conservation Plan. In A. J. Hoffman
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capital
& M. J. Ventresca (Eds.), Organizations, policy, and the
ism. New York: Free Press.
natural environment: 235-261. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press. World Economic Forum. 2003. Global competitiveness report,
2003-2004. Davos, Switzerland: World Economic Forum.
Ullman, A. H. 1985. Data in search of a theory: A critical
examination of the relationships among social perfor Zak, P. J., & Knack, S. 2001. Trust and growth. Economic
mance, social disclosure, and economic performance of Journal, 111:295-321.

John L. Campbell Qohn.L.Campbell@Dartmouth.Edu) is the Class of 1925 Professor,


Department of Sociology, Dartmouth College, and professor of political economy,
Copenhagen Business School. He received his Ph.D. from the University of Wisconsin
Madison. He is currently studying the relationship among the size, cultural composi
tion, and socioeconomic performance of advanced capitalist economies.

This content downloaded from


13.234.89.89 on Tue, 23 Apr 2024 11:13:38 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like