You are on page 1of 63

Part III

Applications & Extensions


• Investments / choices over
time (Ch 16)

• Uncertainty (Ch 17)

• Externalities & public goods


(Ch 18)

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-1


Chapter 16

Interest Rates,
Investments, and
Capital Markets
Topics
• Comparing money today to money in the
future.
• Choices over time.
• Exhaustible resources.(will not be covered)
• Capital markets, interest rates, and
investments.
→ Intertemporal economic decisions: choices
now have costs & benefits in future

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-3


Introductory Definitions

• Stock - a quantity or value that is


measured independently of time.
• Flow - a quantity or value that is measured
per unit of time.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-4


Interest Rates

• Interest rate - the percentage more that


must be repaid to borrow money for a fixed
period of time.

• Time value of money: money today is worth


more than money in the future.
– Why?
– Not just because of inflation!

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-5


Interest rates
• Assume that you are owed R1000. Would you
prefer to be repaid the R1000 today or receive it
in a year’s time? Why?

• People tend to have positive time preferences


for money. In other words, a Rand received
today is preferred to a Rand received at
some future date.
• Opportunity cost
• Risk
• Inflation

• Interest charges paid by borrowers compensate


lenders for the time value of money.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-6


• In reality, at any point in time there are many
interest rates in an economy. Why?

• Interest rates vary due to:

• Borrow or saving
• Short-term or long-term transaction
• Source of transaction, e.g. bank / credit
card / moneylender
• The creditworthiness of the borrower.
• Etc.

• To simplify, assume that there is a single


interest rate (i).
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-7
Discount Rate

• Even when faced with the same interest


rate, responses of people differ: some
borrow, some save.

• Discount rate - a rate reflecting the


relative value an individual places on future
consumption compared to current
consumption.

• The higher the personal discount rate, the


more an individual values present over
future consumption.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-8


Discount Rate cont’d
• If your discount rate is nearly zero
– you would gladly lend money in exchange for a
positive interest rate.

• If your discount rate is high


– you would be willing to borrow at a lower interest
rate.

• If d > i, person will borrow (i.e. forego future


consumption to increase current consumption)

• If d < i, person will save (i.e. forego current


consumption to increase future consumption)
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-9
When you save money, you expect to have more in the
bank at the end of the year than you deposited at the
beginning …
… and when you borrow money you are expected to
pay back more than you initially borrowed.
• How much more depends on the interest rate (i).
• E.g. if i = 4% per annum on savings, then for each
Rand you invest at the beginning of the year, you will
have R1x(1+i) = R1x(1+0.04) = R1.04 after 1 year.

• If you leave your R100 in the bank indefinitely and the


interest rate remains constant, you will receive a
payment of R4 each year.
– So you can convert your R100 stock into a flow of
R4-a-year payments forever.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-10


Compounding cont’d
• But if you leave both your R100 and your R4
interest in the bank, the bank must pay you
interest on R104 at end of the second year.
• The bank owes you interest of R4 on your original
deposit of R100, and interest of R4 × 0.04 = R0.16
on your interest from the first year, for a total of
R4.16.
• So after 2 years, the account will have a balance of
R104x(1+0.04) = R108.16.
• Note that in year 2 you earn interest on the initial
deposit plus interest on the first year’s interest
income. This is referred to as compounding interest
over time.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-11


Compounding cont’d

• Thus, at the end of Year 1, your account


contains
$104.00  $100  1.04  $100 1.041

• By the end of Year 2, you have


2
$108.16  $104  1.04  $100 1.04

• At the end of Year 3, your account has


3
$112.49  $108.16  1.04  $100  1.04

• And extending to t years…


Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-12
Assuming that interest is calculated on an annual
basis, the value of 1 Rand invested now at an
interest rate of i% per year for a period of t years is:

Future Value = R1(1 + i)t

Where, i = annual interest rate


t = no of years.
(1+i)t = compound factor

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-13


Frequency of Compounding

• To get the highest return on your savings


account, you need to check both the interest
rate and the frequency of compounding.

• Many banks pay interest more frequently


than once a year.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-14


Frequency of Compounding
(cont.)
• If a bank’s annual interest rate is i = 4%,
but it pays interest two times a year,
– The bank pays you half a year’s interest,
i/2 = 2%, after six months.
– For every Rand in your account, the bank pays
you (1 + i/2) = R1.02 after six months.
• At the end of the year,
– the bank owes you (1 + i/2) × (1 + i/2) =
(1 + i/2)2 = (1.02)2 = R1.0404, which is your
original R1 plus 4.04c in interest.
And extending this…

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-15


If interest is calculated more frequently (n times per year),
then the value of 1 Rand invested now at an interest rate of
i% per year for a period of t years is:

Future Value = R1*(1 + i/n)tn

Where, i = annual interest rate


t = number of years.
n = number of conversion periods per year
(1+i/n)tn = compound factor

See Table 16.1 for examples of such calculations

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-16


Table 16.1 Interest and the
Frequency of Compounding

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-17


Using Interest Rates to Connect
the Present and Future
• Present value (PV) - the value of the
money you put in the bank today.
• Future value (FV) - the present value
plus interest.
• If you deposit PV dollars in the bank today
and allow the interest to compound for t
years, how much money will you have at the
end?

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-18


Using Interest Rates to Connect the
Present and Future
• If we know the present value (PV) of an
investment, we can compute its future value
(FV) after t years using the following formula:

t
FV  PV (1  i)
where:
i = interest rate per year
t = no. of years
(1 + i)t = compound factor

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-19


PV & FV cont’d
t
FV  PV (1  i)

So e.g. R1 in the bank for 50 years, at 1%


compounded annually = R1.64
• at 4% = R7.11
• at 10% = 117.39
• at 20% = R9100.44!

See Table 16.2 for more examples of such


calculations.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-20


Table 16.2 future value, FV, to which $1
grows by the end of year t at various
interest rates, i, compounded annually, $

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-21


Present Value

• If we want to have FV = R100 at the end of


a year and the interest rate is i = 4%, then:
PV × 1.04 = R100.
• Dividing both sides of this expression by
1.04,
PV = R100/1.04 = R96.15
• R96.15 is needed in the bank today to have
R100 next year.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-23


• General formula for computing present values
from future values i.e. relating money t periods
in the future to money today:

FV -t
PV  t
= FV (1 + i)
(1 + i)

where:
(1 + i)-t = discount factor

• E.g. using a discount rate of 4% per annum, the


present value of a promise of R1000 in 1 year’s
time is:

R1000x(1+0.04)-1 = R1000x0.96154 = R961.54

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-24


Table 16.3 present value, PV, of a payment
of $1 at the end of year t at various interest
rates, i, compounded annually, $

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-25


Figure 16.1 PV of $1 in the future
$1
i = 0%
90¢
If i = 0%, a promise of 1$ 10 years from now has a PV
80¢ of 1$
Present value of 1 $

70¢
If i = 5%, a promise of 1$ 10 years from now has a
60¢
PV of 61.4 cents

50¢ If i = 10%, a promise of 1$ 10 years from now has


a PV of 38.6 cents
40¢
If i = 20%, a promise of 1$ 10 years from
30¢ now has a PV of 16.15 cents
20¢

10¢ i = 20% i = 10% i = 5%

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
t, Years
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-26
Stream of Payments

• Sometimes we need to deal with payments


per period, which are flow measures, rather
than a present value or future value, which
are stock measures.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-27


Payments for a finite number of
years
• Suppose that you agree to pay $10 at the
end of each year for three years to repay
a debt.
• If the interest rate is 10%, the present
value of this series of payments is:

$10 $10 $10


PV   2  3  $24.87
1.1 1.1 1.1

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-28


Payments for a finite number of
years cont’d

 Add up the present value of each


payment to determine the PV of a series
of future payments.

 If P1 = P2 = … = PT = f, then the stream


of payments is an annuity.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-29


Payments for a Finite Number of
Years (cont’d)
• If you make a future payment of f per
year for t years at an interest rate of i,
the present value (stock) of this flow of
payments (annuity) is
 1 1 1 
PV  f    t 
 1  i  1  i  1  i  
1 2

PV = f [(1 + i)-1 + (1 + i)-2 + . . . + (1 + i)-t]


PV = f [USPVi,t] (uniform series PV)
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-30
Table 16.4 Present Value, PV, of a Flow of
$10 a Year for t Years at Various Interest
Rates, i, Compounded Annually, $

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-31


 Example: A soccer coach is offered R1 million per year
(paid at the end of the year) for a period of three years to
coach a team. What is the present value of his contract?
Assume a discount rate of 12% per annum.

Payment Nominal Present Value


Value

1 R1 million R1m*(1+0.12)-1 = R0.893m

2 R1 million R1m*(1+0.12)-2 = R0.797m

3 R1 million R1m*(1+0.12)-3 = R0.712m

Total R3 million R2.402m

PV = R1million * [USPV12%, 3 Years]


= R1million * [(1+0.12)-1 + (1+0.12)-2 + (1+0.12)-3]
= R1million * [2.4018] = R2.4018 million
Solved Problem 16.1
 Melody Toyota advertises that it will sell you a Corolla for
$14,000 or lease it to you. To lease it, you must make a
down payment of $1,650 and agree to pay $1,800 at the
end of each of the next two years. After the last lease
payment, you may buy the car for $12,000. If you plan to
keep the car until it falls apart (at least a decade) and the
interest rate is 10%, which approach has a lower present
value of costs?
Option 1: Purchase Option 2: Lease
t Payment PV t Payment PV
0 $14000 $14000 0 $1650 $1650
1 1 $1800 $1636
2 2 $1800 + $11405
$12000
Total $14000 Total $14691
Payments forever (perpetuity)

• If you put PV dollars into a bank account


earning an interest rate of i,
– you can get an interest or future
payment of f = i × PV at the end of the
year.
• To get a payment of f each year forever,
you’d have to put in the bank:
f
PV 
i
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-35
Future value of payments over
time
• Suppose that you want to know how much
you’ll have in your savings account, FV, at
some future time if you save f each year.

• At the end of t years, the account has:

FV = f [1 + (1 + i)1 + (1 + i)2 + . . . + (1 + i) t − 1]

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-36


Inflation and Discounting

• Nominal prices - actual prices that are not


adjusted for inflation – rise over time.
• Real prices - constant prices that are
independent of inflation.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-37


Adjusting for Inflation
• Suppose that the annual rate of inflation is γ
(“gamma”). If the current price of a good if
f, then its price one year from now will be:
~
f  f (1   )

~
• Therefore, if γ = 10%, a nominal f
payment
~
of f one year from today has a real value
(measured in today’s Rands) of:
~ 1
~
1
~
f  f (1   )  f (1  0.10)  0.909 f
Nominal & real rates of interest
• Without inflation, R1 one year from today has a PV
of R1/(1 + i) today.

• With an inflation rate of γ, R1 one year from today


has a PV of R1/[(1 + i)(1 + γ)].

• E.g. if i = 5% and γ = 10%, R100 one year from today


is worth R100/[(1.05 )× (1.1)] = R86.58 today.

Likewise, R100 today is worth


R100×(1.05)×(1.1) = R115.50 nominal Rands
one year from today.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-39


Nominal & real int rates cont’d
~
• Banks pay a nominal interest rate, i , rather
than a real one.

• If they’re going to get people whose real


discount rate is i to save, banks’ nominal
interest rate must be such that
~
(1  i )  (1  i )(1   )  1  i  i  
• Therefore, the nominal rate is
~
i  i  i  
~
i  i   if  and i are low
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-40
Nominal & real int rates cont’d
• Rearranging the previous equation, we see
that: ~
i
i
1 

• Therefore, to obtain the real present value of


a payment one year from now we use:
~ ~
f f f
PV    ~
1  i (1   )(1  i ) (1  i )
Choices over Time
• Often decisions made by consumers and
firms involve comparisons over time.

• One way to make a choice involving time is


to pick the option with the highest present
value.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-42


Investing

• A firm makes an investment if the expected


return from the investment is greater than
the opportunity cost.

• The opportunity cost is the best alternative


use of its money, which is what it would
earn in the next best use of the money.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-43


Net Present Value Approach

• A firm has to decide whether to buy a truck


for $20,000.

A firm should make an investment only if


the present value of the expected return
exceeds the present value of the costs.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-44


NPV Approach (cont.)
• If
R = the present value of the expected returns to an
investment and
C = the present value of the costs of the
investment,
the firm should make the investment if R > C.

• A firm should make an investment only if the net


present value is positive:

NPV = R − C > 0.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-45


NPV Approach (cont.)
• The initial year is t = 0, the firm’s revenue in year
t is Rt, and its cost in year t is Ct.
• If the last year in which either revenue or cost is
nonzero is T, the net present value rule holds
that the firm should invest if
NPV  R  C
 R1 R2 RT 
  R0    ...  T 
1  i  1  i  1  i  
1 2

 C1 C2 CT 
 C0    ...  T 
 0.
1  i  1  i  1  i  
1 2


Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-46


NPV Approach (cont.)
• Alternatively we could examine whether the
present value of the cash flow in each year
πt = Rt − Ct is positive.
R1  C1 R2  C2 RT  CT
NPV   R0  C0     ... 
1  i  1  i  1  i 
1 2 T

1 2 T
 0    ...   0.
1  i  1  i  1  i 
1 2 T

Note: The discount rate, i, used in NPV calculations


should reflect the firm’s opportunity cost of capital.
If NPV > 0, then the investment is more profitable
than the opportunity cost.
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-47
Solved Problem 16.2

Peter Guber and Joe Lacob bought the Golden State


Warriors basketball team for $450 million in 2010.
Forbes magazine estimates the team’s net income for
2009 was $11.9 million.
If the new owners believed that they would continue
to earn this annual profit (after adjusting for
inflation), f = $11.9 million, forever, was this
investment more lucrative than putting the $450
million in a savings account that pays a real interest
rate of i = 2%? At i = 3%?

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-48


Solved Problem 16.2: Answer

Determine the net present value of the team.


Given a real interest rate of 2%:
PV of the stream of income = $11.9m/0.02 = $595m;
PV of the cost = the purchase price of $450m
NPV = $595m - $450m = $145m > 0 .

However, for interest rate 3%:


PV of income stream = $11.9m/0.03 = $397m
NPV = $397m - $450m = -$53 million < 0 .

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-49


Internal Rate of Return Approach

• Internal rate of return (irr) - the


discount rate that results in a net present
value of an investment of zero
• i.e. the discount rate (rate of return) at
which a firm is indifferent between making
an investment or not.
1 2 T
NPV   0    ...  0
1  irr 1  irr 2
1  irr 
T

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-50


Internal Rate of Return
Approach (cont.)

• The investment’s rate of return is found


by rearranging the previous equation
and replacing i with irr:

f
PV 
i
f
irr  .
PV
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-51
Internal Rate of Return
Approach (cont.)
• If the firm is borrowing money to make the
investment, it pays for the firm to borrow to
make the investment if the internal rate of
return on that investment exceeds that of the
next best alternative: irr > i.

• If the firm is investing equity capital to make the


investment, it pays for the firm to use equity
capital only if the internal rate of return on
that investment exceeds that of the next best
alternative: irr > i.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-52


IRR - example

• A new solar geyser will cost you R10000.


You estimate that it will save you R1000 a
year, forever. What is the irr on this
investment? Should you buy the panel?

• Irr = f/PV = 1000 / 10000 = 10%

• Buy it? If the market interest rate is < 10%

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-53


Solved Problem 16.3

• Peter Guber and Joe Lacob can buy the


Golden State Warriors basketball team for
$450 million, and they expect an annual real
flow of payments (profits) of f = $11.9
million forever. Using the internal rate of
return approach, should they buy the team
if the real interest rate is 2%?

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-54


Solved Problem 16.3: Answer

• Determine the internal rate of return to this


investment and compare it to the interest
rate. Calculate that the internal rate of
return from buying the Warriors is

f $11 .9million
irr    2.6%
PV $450million
• Because this irr, 2.6%, is greater than the
real interest rate, 2%, they buy the team .

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-55


Rate of Return on Bonds
• Bond - a piece of paper issued by a
government or a corporation that promises
to repay the borrower with a payment
stream (fixed regular payment amount).
• Face value – the amount borrowed.
• Maturity date – when the borrower will
redeem the bond by repaying face value.
• Perpetuities – bonds with no maturity date
(the face value is never returned).
• If nominal interest rates rise, bond
prices fall (to keep the rate of return in line
with market rates).

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-56


Capital Markets, Interest Rates,
and Investments
• The intersection of supply of and demand for
loanable funds determines the equilibrium
price or interest rate and the equilibrium
quantity of funds in this capital market.
• DD: for investment funds from indivs, firms,
and govt;
• SS: savings from indivs & firms
• ‘Shift variables’ can change eqm as usual… 

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-57


Figure 16.4 Capital Market
Equilibrium

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-58


Solved Problem 16.4

• Suppose the government needs to borrow


money to pay for fighting a war in a foreign
land. Show that increased borrowing by the
government—an increase in the
government’s demand for money at any
given interest rate—raises the equilibrium
interest rate, which discourages or crowds
out private investment.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-59


Solved Problem 16.4: Answer

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-60


Human capital investment decision
(or, should you attend university?
Decision: invest in education to increase productivity
& future earnings?
e.g. decision to attend university
 
Assume: want to max lifetime earnings.
Simplify – choose:
• start work straight after matric, work from 18 – 70
(benefits = income)
• start university straight after matric, graduate in 4
years, work from 22-70
(benefits = income after 22;
costs = tuition fees + foregone earnings
i.e. opportunity cost).
Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-61
Challenge solution: should you
go to college?

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-62


Human capital cont’d
The figure (Challenge Solution) shows costs &
benefits for ‘average’ USA high school diplomate vs
college (= university) graduate at each age.

NPV is positive (PV benefits of college > PV costs) for


discount rates < 10.42% in USA.
 
Note PV depends on discount rate applied: Table
(average irr to univ education = 10.42% in USA)

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-63


Challenge solution should you
go to college? (Cont.)

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-64


Human capital cont’d

South Africa: no comparable study BUT there is


evidence of high returns to university education in
terms of employability:
• graduates find jobs much faster (Moleke, 2005)
• & are less likely to be unemployed (Broekhuizen &
van der Berg 2013)
– see Returns to studying on moodle fyi.

Copyright ©2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. All rights reserved. 16-65

You might also like