You are on page 1of 47

Chapter 13

Market Structure and


Competition
Chapter Thirteen Overview
• Describing and Measuring Market Structure
• Oligopoly with Homogeneous Products
• Dominant Firm Markets
• Oligopoly with Horizontally Differentiated Products
• Monopolistic Competition

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• The Cournot Equilibrium and the Inverse Elasticity Pricing
Rule

2
Market Structures: Four Key Dimensions

1. The number of sellers

2. The number of buyers

3. Entry conditions

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


4. The degree of product differentiation

3
Product Differentiation
• Product differentiation between • "Superiority" is when one product is
two or more products exists viewed as unambiguously better
when the products possess than another so that, at the same
price, all consumers would buy the
attributes that, in the minds of
better product
consumers, set the products
– Vertical product differentiation
apart from one another and • "Substitutability" is when, at the
make them less than perfect same price, some consumers would

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


substitutes prefer the characteristics of product
• Examples: Pepsi is sweeter than A while other consumers would
Coke, brand name batteries last prefer the characteristics of B
longer than "generic" batteries – Horizontal product differentiation
4
Types of Market Structures

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Oligopoly Assumptions
• Many buyers and few sellers
• Each firm faces downward-sloping demand because each
is a large producer compared to the total market size
• There is no one dominant model of oligopoly

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


6
Cournot Oligopoly
• Augustin Cournot developed • In a Cournot game, each firm
the first theory of oligopoly sets its output (quantity) taking
• Assumptions as given the output level of its
– Firms set outputs (quantities)
competitor(s), to maximize
profits
– Homogeneous products
• Price adjusts according to
– Simultaneous
demand

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– Non-cooperative
• Firm's guess about its rival's
output determines its residual
demand
7
Simultaneously vs. Non-cooperatively
• Firms act simultaneously if each firm makes its strategic
decision at the same time, without prior observation of the
other firm's decision
• Firms act non-cooperatively if they set strategy
independently, without colluding with the other firm in any
way

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


8
Residual Demand
• The relationship between the
price charged by firm I and the
demand firm I faces is firm is
residual demand
• In other words, the residual
demand of firm I is the market
demand minus the amount of

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


demand fulfilled by other firms
in the market: Q1 = Q - Q2

9
Profit Maximization
• Each firm acts as a monopolist on its
residual demand curve, equating MR r
to MC
• MRr = p + q1(p/q) = MC
• Best response function:
– The point where (residual) marginal
revenue equals marginal cost gives the
best response of firm I to its rival's actions

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– For every possible output of the rival(s),
we can determine firm i's best response
– The sum of all these points makes up the
best response (reaction) function of firm I

10
Equilibrium
• Equilibrium: No firm has an incentive to • What is the equation of firm 1's
deviate in equilibrium reaction function?
– Each firm is maximizing profits given its
• Firm 1's residual demand:
rival's output
• P = 100 - Q1 - Q2 • P = (100 - Q2) - Q1
• MC = AC = 10 • MRr = 100 - Q2 - 2Q1
• What is firm 1's profit-maximizing output • MRr = MC  100 - Q2 - 2Q1 = 10
when firm 2 produces 50?

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• Firm 1's residual demand: • Q1r = 45 - Q2/2 firm 1's reaction
– P = (100 - 50) - Q1 function
– MR50 = 50 - 2Q1 • Similarly, one can compute that
– MR50 = MC  50 - 2Q1 = 10 • Q2r = 45 - Q1/2
11
Calculate the Cournot Equilibrium
• Q1 = 45 - (45 - Q1/2)/2
• Q1* = 30
• Q2* = 30
• P* = 40
• 1* = 2* = 30(30) = 900

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


12
The Bertrand Model of Oligopoly
• In a Bertrand oligopoly, each • Firms set price
firm sets its price, taking as • Homogeneous product
given the price(s) set by other • Simultaneous
firm(s), so as to maximize
profits • Non-cooperative
• The resulting total output
determines the market price

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


13
Setting Price
• Homogeneity implies that consumers will buy from the low-
price seller
• Further, each firm realizes that the demand that it faces
depends both on its own price and on the price set by other
firms
• Specifically, any firm charging a higher price than its rivals

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


will sell no output
• Any firm charging a lower price than its rivals will obtain the
entire market demand
14
Residual Demand Curve – Price Setting
• Assume firm always meets its
residual demand
– No capacity constraints
• Assume that marginal cost is
constant at c per unit
• Hence, any price at least equal

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


to c ensures non-negative
profits

15
Best Response Function
• Each firm's profit maximizing • Two firms
response to the other firm's • Bertrand competitors
price is to undercut
• Firm 1's best response function
– As long as P > MC
is P1 = P2 - e
• Definition: the firm's profit
• Firm 2's best response function
maximizing action as a
is P2 = P1 - e
function of the action by the

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


rival firm is the firm's best
response (or reaction) function

16
Equilibrium
• If we assume no capacity • Firms price at marginal cost
constraints and that all firms • Firms make zero profits
have the same constant average • The number of firms is irrelevant to
and marginal cost of c then: the price level when more than one
• For each firm's response to be a firm is present
best response to the other's each – Two firms is enough to replicate the
firm must undercut the other perfectly competitive outcome

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– As long as P> MC • Essentially, the assumption of no
capacity constraints combined with
• Where does this stop?
a constant average and marginal
– P = MC (!) cost takes the place of free entry
17
Stackelberg Oligopoly
• Stackelberg model of oligopoly is a
situation in which one firm acts as a
quantity leader, choosing its quantity first,
with all other firms acting as followers
– Call the first mover the “leader” and the
second mover the “follower”
• The second firm is in the same situation
as a Cournot firm
– It takes the leader’s output as given and

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


maximizes profits accordingly, using its
residual demand
• The second firm’s behavior can, then, be
summarized by a Cournot reaction
function
18
Dominant Firm Markets
• A single company with an
overwhelming market share (a
dominant firm) competes against
many small producers
(competitive fringe), each of
whom has a small market share
• Limit pricing – a strategy whereby

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


the dominant firm keeps its price
below the level that maximizes its
current profit in order to reduce
the rate of expansion by the fringe
19
Bertrand Competition – Assumptions
• Firms set price*
• Differentiated product
• Simultaneous
• Non-cooperative

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• *Differentiation means that lowering price below your rivals' will
not result in capturing the entire market, nor will raising price
mean losing the entire market so that residual demand
decreases smoothly
20
Bertrand Competition – Example
• Q1 = 100 - 2P1 + P2 "Coke's demand"
• Q2 = 100 - 2P2 + P1 "Pepsi's demand"
• MC1 = MC2 = 5
• What is firm 1's residual demand when
• Firm 2's price is $10? $0?

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• Q1(10) = 100 - 2P1 + 10 = 110 - 2P1
• Q1(0) = 100 - 2P1 + 0 = 100 - 2P1
21
Bertrand Competition – Example Continued

• Each firm maximizes profits


based on its residual demand
by setting MR (based on
residual demand) = MC
• Pepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and
$10 for D10

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


22
Bertrand Competition – Example
Continued

23

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Bertrand Competition – Example
Continued

24

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Bertrand Competition – Key Concepts
• MR1(10) = 55 - Q1(10) = 5 • Solving for firm 1's reaction
function for any arbitrary price by
• Q1(10) = 50 firm 2
• P1(10) = 30 – P1 = 50 - Q1/2 + P2/2
• Therefore, firm 1's best – MR = 50 - Q1 + P2/2
response to a price of $10 by – MR = MC => Q1 = 45 + P2/2
firm 2 is a price of $30 • And, using the demand curve, we

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


have:
– P1 = 50 + P2/2 - 45/2 - P2/4 or
– P1 = 27.5 + P2/4 the reaction function

25
Equilibrium and Reaction Functions

26

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Equilibrium and Reaction Functions
Continued

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


27
Equilibrium
• Equilibrium occurs when all • Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2, continued
firms simultaneously choose • P1 = 27.5 + P2/4
their best response to each • P2 = 27.5 + P1/4
others' actions • Solving these two equations in two
unknowns.
• Graphically, this amounts to
– P1* = P2* = 110/3
the point where the best • Plugging these prices into demand, we
response functions cross

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


have:
• Q1* = Q2* = 190/3
• 1* = 2* = 2005.55
•  = 4011.10
28
Equilibrium Continued
• Profits are positive in equilibrium • Only if the number of firms
since both prices are above approaches infinity would price
marginal cost! approach marginal cost
• Even if we have no capacity • Prices need not be equal in
constraints, and constant marginal
equilibrium if firms not identical
cost, a firm cannot capture all
demand by cutting price – Marginal costs differ implies that
prices differ

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• This blunts price-cutting incentives
and means that the firms' own • The reaction functions slope
behavior does not mimic free upward: "aggression =>
entry aggression"
29
Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly Equilibriums

• P > MC for Cournot competitors, but P < PM


• If the firms were to act as a monopolist (perfectly collude), they
would set market MR equal to MC:
– P = 100 - Q
– MC = AC = 10
• MR = MC => 100 - 2Q = 10 => QM = 45

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– PM = 55
– M= 45(45) = 2025
– c = 1800
30
Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly Equilibriums
Continued

• A perfectly collusive industry considers that an increase in output by one firm


depresses the profits of the other firm(s) in the industry
• A Cournot competitor considers the effect of the increase in output on its own
profits only
• Therefore, Cournot competitors "overproduce" relative to the collusive
(monopoly) point
• Further, this problem gets "worse" as the number of competitors grows because
the market share of each individual firm falls, increasing the difference between

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


the private gain from increasing production and the profit destruction effect on
rivals
• Therefore, the more concentrated the industry in the Cournot case, the higher
the price-cost margin
31
Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly Equilibriums
Continued

• Homogeneous product Bertrand resulted in zero profits, whereas


the Cournot case resulted in positive profits
• The best response functions in the Cournot model slope
downward
– In other words, the more aggressive a rival (in terms of output), the
more passive the Cournot firm's response

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• The best response functions in the Bertrand model slope upward
– In other words, the more aggressive a rival (in terms of price) the more
aggressive the Bertrand firm's response

32
Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly Equilibriums
Continued

• Cournot
– Suppose firm j raises its output…the price at which firm i can sell
output falls
– This means that the incentive to increase output falls as the output of
the competitor rises
• Bertrand

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– Suppose firm j raises price the price at which firm i can sell output
rises
– So long as firm's price is less than firm's, the incentive to increase
price will depend on the (market) marginal revenue
33
Monopolistic Competition
• Market structure
– Many buyers
– Many sellers
– Free entry and exit
– (Horizontal) product differentiation
• When firms have horizontally differentiated products, they each face

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


downward-sloping demand for their product because a small
change in price will not cause all buyers to switch to another firm's
product
• Example: restaurants, local markets for doctors
34
Monopolistic Competition – Short Run
1. Each firm is small each takes the observed "market price"
as given in its production decisions
2. Since market price may not stay given, the firm's perceived
demand may differ from its actual demand
3. if all firms' prices fall the same amount, no customers
switch supplier, but the total market consumption grows

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


4. If only one firm's price falls, it steals customers from other
firms as well as increases total market consumption

35
Perceived vs. Actual Demand

36

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Perceived vs. Actual Demand Continued

37

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Market Equilibrium
• Each firm maximizes profit taking the average market
price as given

• Each firm can sell the quantity it desires at the actual


average market price that prevails

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


38
Short Run Equilibrium

39

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Short Run Equilibrium Continued

40

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Short Run Monopolistically Competitive
Equilibrium
• MC = $15 A. What is the equation of d40? What is
the equation of D?
• N = 100 – d40: Qd = 100 - 2P + 40 = 140 - 2P
• Q = 100 - 2P + PA – D: Note that P = PA so that
– QD = 100 - P
• Where: PA is the average
B. Show that d40 and D intersect at P =
market price N is the number
40
of firms
– P = 40 => Qd = 140 - 80 = 60

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– QD = 100 - 40 = 60
C. For any given average price, PA,
find a typical firm's profit maximizing
quantity
41
Inverse Perceived Demand
• P = 50 - (1/2)Q + (1/2)PA
• MR = 50 - Q + (1/2)PA
• MR = MC => 50 - Q + (1/2)PA = 15
• Qe = 35 + (1/2)PA
• Pe = 50 - (1/2)Qe + (1/2)PA

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


• Pe = 32.5 + (1/4)PA

42
Short Run Monopolistically Competitive
Equilibrium
• What is the short run equilibrium price in this industry?
• In equilibrium, Qe = QD at PA so that
– 100 - PA = 35 + (1/2)PA
– PA = 43.33
– Qe = 56.66

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– QD = 56.66

43
Monopolistic Competition in the Long Run
• At the short run equilibrium
P > AC so that each firm may make
positive profit
• Entry shifts d and D left until average
industry price equals average cost
• This is long run equilibrium is
represented graphically by:
– MR = MC for each firm

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


– D = d at the average market price
– d and AC are tangent at average market
price

44
Summary
1. Market structures are characterized by the number of
buyers, the number of sellers, the degree of product
differentiation and the entry conditions
2. Product differentiation alone or a small number of
competitors alone is not enough to destroy the long run
zero profit result of perfect competition

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


3. Monopolistic competition assumes that there are many
buyers, many sellers, differentiated products and free
entry in the long run
45
Summary Continued
4. Sellers face downward-sloping demand but are price takers (i.e. they do
not perceive that their change in price will affect the average price level)
– Profits may be positive in the short run but free entry drives profits to zero in the
long run
5. Bertrand and Cournot competition assume that there are many buyers,
few sellers, and homogeneous or differentiated products
– Firms compete in price in Bertrand oligopoly and in quantity in Cournot oligopoly

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


6. Bertrand and Cournot competitors take into account their strategic
interdependence by means of constructing a best response schedule:
each firm maximizes profits given the rival's strategy

46
Summary Continued
7. Equilibrium in such a setting requires that all firms be on their best
response functions
8. If the products are homogeneous, the Bertrand equilibrium results in
zero profits
– By changing the strategic variable from price to quantity, we obtain much higher
prices (and profits)
– Further, the results are sensitive to the assumption of simultaneous moves

Copyright (c) 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.


9. This result can be traced to the slope of the reaction functions: upwards
in the case of Bertrand and downwards in the case of Cournot
– These slopes imply that "aggressivity" results in a "passive" response in the
Cournot case and an "aggressive" response in the Bertrand case
47

You might also like