You are on page 1of 60

When Does Funding Research by Smaller Firms Bear Fruit?

:
Evidence from the SBIR Program*

by

Joshua S. Gans and Scott Stern**

First Draft: April 2, 1999


This Version: November 8, 1999

COMMENTS WELCOME!

*
The cooperation and assistance of the firms that contributed data used in this study is greatly appreciated.
Josh Lerner, Scott Wallsten, Scott Shane, seminar participants at MIT, the FTC and the NBER, and
especially Iain Cockburn, provided thoughtful suggestions and advice. David Hsu provided outstanding
research assistance. We also gratefully acknowledge funding for this research by the MIT Center for
Innovation in Product Development under NSF Cooperative Agreement # EEC-9529140. Any remaining
errors or omissions are our responsibility.
**
Melbourne Business School, University of Melbourne, and MIT Sloan School & NBER, respectively.
All correspondence to Scott Stern, Sloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge (MA), 02142;
mailto:sstern@mit.edu. The latest version of this paper is available at
http://www.mbs.unimelb.edu.au/jgans/research.htm.
When Does Funding Research in Smaller Firms Bear Fruit?:
Evidence from the SBIR Program

Abstract
This paper evaluates whether the relative concentration of funding for small, research-
oriented firms in some important high-tech industries is related to the differences across
industries in the appropriability regime facing small firms. We explore this hypothesis by
analyzing the performance of projects funded by the Small Business Innovation Research
(SBIR) program, a Federal subsidy that provides R&D funds for small businesses. By
design, the cost of R&D capital is (approximately) equalized for firms funded by the
SBIR. As a result, we neutralize capital market imperfections as a direct source of
variation in our sample. In contrast, the SBIR does not affect sector-level differences in
the appropriability regime or in the underlying level of technological opportunity. The
main contribution of this paper results from exploiting this difference to evaluate the
salience of capital market imperfections, the appropriability regime facing small firms,
and the overall level of technology opportunity. Specifically, if the SBIR fund projects on
the margin (as it should under an optimal subsidy regime), then a cross-sectional
comparison identifies the relative importance of capital versus product market
imperfections across markets. Our principal empirical result is that project-level
performance is highest for those technologies that are in industrial segments that attract
high rates of venture capital investment. As well, there is weak but positive evidence that
performance is related to the overall level of scientific opportunity. We interpret these
findings as suggesting that an important difference between industrial sectors is the
degree of appropriability for research-oriented small businesses; variation in the
appropriability regime helps explain the concentrated nature of venture capital activity in
the economy.
I. Introduction

Since Arrow (1962), economists have been aware that competitive markets may

fail to provide the socially optimal level of R&D investment. Innovation is beset by

uncertainty, imperfect monitoring and imperfect property rights; the combination of these

factors leads many to conclude that the realized level of R&D investment by private firms

is too low (Bush, 1945; Griliches, 1992; Romer, 1990). In this context, special attention

is paid to the role of the small, research-oriented firm. While many suggest that these

firms have organizational advantages enhancing their research productivity (Schumpeter,

1934; Foster, 1986; Acs and Audretsch, 1996), others highlight that smaller, start-up

firms may be particularly susceptible to the constraints identified by Arrow (Holmstrom,

1989; Teece, 1986; Kamien and Schwartz, 1982; Himmelberg and Petersen, 1994).

Specifically, smaller firms may both have difficulty raising capital for R&D projects and

be less well positioned to extract the social value of their innovations in the marketplace.

Perhaps in part because of the salience of these constraints, private financing of

small firm research is quite concentrated in a small number of industrial sectors.

Historically, areas such as biotechnology and software development have attracted a

disproportionate share of financing, particularly when compared with industries such as

industrial equipment, transportation or environmental technologies (while all of these

sectors experience high rates of innovation, the composition of funding and performance

differs across sectors). Concentrated financing of entrepreneurial activity suggests that

venture financiers have somehow overcome the capital market imperfections and

appropriability constraints in a small number of distinct market and technological


2

environments. Put another way, understanding why small firm research is financed in

only a few sectors involves discerning how the funded sectors differ in terms of the

salience of agency and/or appropriability. By undertaking such an exercise, this paper

enhances understanding of how agency and appropriability affect innovation incentives

as well as providing policy guidance in terms of how to better encourage small firm

formation and innovation.

The paper evaluates the variation across sectors in the performance of projects

funded by the Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program, a Federal subsidy

that provides R&D funds for small businesses. By design, the SBIR program effectively

equalizes the type of capital market imperfections that theoretically raise the costs of

capital to small firm R&D. As a result, the salience of capital market imperfections is

(roughly) equalized across our sample. In contrast, the SBIR does not affect sector-level

differences in the appropriability regime or in the underlying level of technological

opportunity. The main contribution of this paper arises from exploiting this difference to

evaluate how sectors differ in terms of capital market imperfections, the appropriability

regime facing small firms, and the overall level of technological opportunity.

We construct a theoretical model demonstrating that, if the SBIR funds projects

that would not have been funded in the absence of a subsidy, then a cross-sectional

comparison identifies the relative importance of capital versus product market

imperfections across industries. The intuition is straightforward. Private financiers will be

deterred from funding innovations with relatively high ex post returns in those industries

where capital market imperfections are particularly binding. If projects are funded on the

margin, then one would expect that grants provided to firms in capital-constrained
3

industries would tend to perform most highly. On the other hand, grantee performance

will be highest in those sectors that have the ability to earn the highest returns even in the

absence of the subsidy. If differences across sectors are driven by differences in the

appropriablity regime, this will manifest itself as a positive correlation between

performance and the stock of private venture capital fundraising, conditional on the level

of technological opportunity. Alternatively, if the key correlation is between performance

and technological opportunity itself, this may suggest that the critical differences in

funding across sectors simply result from variation in technological opportunity.

Using a novel dataset constructed from a survey by the authors of SBIR funded

projects, our principal empirical finding is that project-level performance is highest for

those technologies that are in industrial segments that attract high rates of venture capital

investment. As well, there is weak, but positive, evidence that performance is related to

the overall level of scientific opportunity. We interpret these findings as suggesting that

an important difference between industrial sectors is the degree of appropriability for

research-oriented small businesses, and this variation helps explain the relative

concentration of venture capital activity in some industrial segments.

By examining performance differences across subsidized projects, this paper

differs from most prior treatments that have attempted to evaluate intersectoral

differences in the environment for small-firm R&D. By and large, such studies have

analyzed samples that are subject to an important selectivity – they have indeed been

funded by the private sector (Mansfield, 1995; Griliches, 1998; Hall, 1988; 1993;

Himmelberg and Petersen, 1994). As such, it is difficult to isolate the differences in

capital market imperfections from more downstream issues such as the appropriablity
4

regime. As well, our approach differs from prior work on the SBIR (in particular Lerner

(1996) and Wallsten (1997)). Both of these prior studies seek to identify the incremental

benefits of an SBIR grant relative to privately funded research; in contrast, we examine

the differences across funded firms in order to understand how different segments differ

in terms of the environment for innovation for smaller firms.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we review the

theoretical and empirical literature on the constraints facing small research-oriented firms

in capital and product markets. Section III then describes the SBIR program and the

features that allow it to provide an experiment to control for capital market imperfections

across sectors. Section IV presents a model that captures the essence of capital and

product market imperfections and we use this as a basis to formulate testable hypotheses

about the determinants of venture capital funding levels across industries. Section V

presents an overview of our dataset while in Section VI we present our main empirical

results and tests for the robustness of these. A final section concludes.

II. The Concentrated Nature of R&D and Venture Capital


Expenditures: An Economic Puzzle?

Among the most distinctive facts about the innovative process is the concentrated

nature of formal R&D investment across the economy and the even further concentrated

nature of venture capital finance or small-firm R&D financing. Consider first the

concentration of privately funded R&D expenditure. Figure 1A presents the Lorenz

distribution of R&D funding relative to value added across the manufacturing sector of
5

the U.S. economy. 1 Relative to the distribution of aggregate economic activity (even

confined to the manufacturing sector), a small share of sectors (such as the

pharmaceutical, computer equipment, and transportation industries) account for most of

privately financed R&D.2

This relative concentration of innovative investment is even more pronounced

when one examines the venture capital financing or the financing of R&D in small and

medium-sized firms. Using data drawn from Kortum and Lerner (1999), Figure 1B

compares the relative distribution of venture financing by industrial segment relative to

the (already concentrated) privately financed R&D investment. Though there are

substantial difficulties in uniquely assigning venture capital investments into specific

SIC-oriented sectors (a concern which we address directly in our empirical work), Figure

1B suggests that, even among R&D-intensive sectors, a very small number receive a very

high share of the overall funds from venture capital sources.3 This latter finding about the

concentrated nature of investment by small firms suggests that differences across sectors

are not merely driven by difference in raw technological opportunity (which would be

reflected in the aggregate R&D distribution) but depend on the ability of small firms to

both finance risky but potentially valuable innovation investments and their ability to

translate their technological success into economic returns.

1
All data are drawn from the 1992 NSF Science and Engineering Indicators and are presented in terms of
R & Dj
their rank of .
VALUE ADDED j
2
Indeed, the Gini coefficient of inequality is over .6, a relatively high rate of inequality across sectors in
terms of their R&D expenditures.
3
Indeed, while economists have relatively ignored the consequences of this observation, its validity is a
widely accepted and well-documented feature of the venture finance industry (REFS,
www.ventureone.com). As well, one could replicate our result by shifting the analysis away from venture
capital in particular and towards the somewhat more comparable concept of small-to-medium sized R&D
investment (tabulations available from the authors).
6

Although prior research has acknowledged that these distributions are in fact

skewed (Griliches, 1986; Hall, 1992; Kortum and Lerner, 1999), few attempts have been

made to distinguish the different potential drivers of the heterogeneity across sectors.

Specifically, while there exist studies which examine a single hypothesis and exploit

variation across sectors to evaluate its relative importance (e.g., Cockburn and Griliches,

1988; Himmelstein, 1993), there has been little systematic analysis of the full set of

potential drivers of this observed heterogeneity across sectors in terms of the intensity of

the innovative or entrepreneurial process. In particular, our analysis will consider three

broad sources of non-mutually-exclusive differences among sectors which may

contribute to differences in terms of their R&D investment levels: the salience of capital

market imperfections, the degree of appropriability, and the level of technological

opportunity. Each of these potential sources has the potential to create variance in the

environment across different industrial sectors that manifests itself in terms of differences

in R&D investment. Accordingly, we review each of these areas informally before

turning to an equilibrium analysis of how each shapes industry-level R&D funding and

how evaluation of government-subsidized research may provide insight into the relative

salience of these different forces.

Level of Technological Opportunity

Perhaps the simplest explanation for differences across sectors is fundamental

differences in the level of technological opportunity or demand across sectors

(Schmookler, 1967; Rosenberg, 1974). Indeed, to the extent that most studies of the

determinants of R&D investment focus on the activities of established incumbent firms


7

within given sectors, the opportunity hypothesis is perhaps a persuasive baseline

hypothesis for considering the sources of differences across sectors.

Salience of Capital Market Imperfections

From a theoretical perspective, research on the salience of capital market

imperfections in shaping R&D investment has focused on the presence of information

asymmetries between financier and research firm and the consequential incompleteness

of financial contracts (Kamien and Schwartz, 198*). One strand of this literature focuses

on the potential conflict between equity or debt finance and the incentives of small

research firms to expend non- or partly contractible effort in innovative activity.

Holmstrom (1989) notes the difficulty in measuring either the inputs or outputs of

research firms while Aghion and Tirole (1994) extend this to demonstrate the adverse

incentive consequences of in-house R&D and of equity participation by third party

financiers such as venture capitalists.

Related to this are concerns that innovators themselves may be able to hold-up

financiers. Anand and Galetovic (1999) examine the potential concerns of corporate and

venture capitalists in having multi-project research firms realize the returns from financed

innovations in opportunistic ways. Hellmann (1998a) notes that innovators may have

incentives that are not purely commercial and hence, may not act in ways that maximize

investor returns. These effects can make finance contracts infeasible or require excessive

control and monitoring by financiers thereby diluting the innovation incentives of small

firms.
8

A final strand of the literature concerns the ability of financiers to identify

potentially successful projects ex ante. The adverse selection literature goes all the way

back to Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) and their analysis of the difficulties of using debt

contracts to identify good projects. Ownership arrangements and other forms of corporate

governance can mitigate these issues. However, the potential for small firm

overstatement of the potential feasibility of their proposed research remains (see

Hubbard, 1998).

Degree of Appropriability

Finally, there may be differences across sectors in terms of the ability of

innovators to appropriate the economic returns from the innovative process. Innovation

involves spillovers (Bush, 1949; Nelson, 1959) and the pricing of indivisibilities is

imperfect (Arrow, 1962; Romer, 1990) so that private investors can never appropriate the

full social returns on any sunk R&D costs. These challenges face all private research

activity. Indeed, the role of appropriability in shaping both the mode of

commercialization and the incentives for R&D investment is the central focus of the

work by Teece (1987) and others.

There is also a specific set of constraints that face research-oriented start-ups.

Schumpeter (1942) noted that the competitive process dissipates innovative rents

favoring monopoly over entry (see also Gilbert and Newbery, 1982). However, even

when these firms are looking to license or otherwise sell their innovations to product

market incumbents, there are important challenges. As noted earlier, such licensing

contracts can rarely be agreed upon ex ante. Either the output of innovative activity is
9

hard to specify (Aghion and Tirole, 1994) or it is difficult to identify good projects ex

ante (Anton and Yao, 1994). The result of this is that, even when intellectual property

rights are relatively secure, small firms may only appropriate a fraction of the private

returns from innovation. Only when they pose a sufficient competitive threat to existing

incumbents or play multiple incumbents off against on another, can they improve their

bargaining position (Teece, 1987; Gans and Stern, 1998).

Furthermore, there are transactions costs associated with the exchange of ideas ex

post. Potential purchasers of tacit knowledge or innovations with weak property rights

can expropriate small firm innovators deterring them from seeking profitable partnerships

(Anton and Yao, 1994). This is fundamental because it is rarely the case the innovations

can be sold without revealing their nature to potential buyers (Arrow, 1962).4 This means

that small research firms may face costly product market entry as the only feasible

commercialization route, thereby, reducing their returns further (Gans and Stern, 1998).

III. A Simple Model of Sector-Level Variation in Innovative


Expenditure

In this section, we integrate the insights of the previous two sections and develop

a simple model of the impact of an R&D subsidy focused on small mostly research-

oriented firms. We demonstrate that, if capital market imperfections are important

constraints on small firm research financing, the average performance of SBIR grantees

is likely to be negatively associated with observed levels of venture capital funding. This

4
Anton and Yao (1994) demonstrate that the presence of multiple incumbents or low entry barriers can
mitigate this exp ropriation problem. In these cases, the small research firm can credibly threaten to destroy
the potential for an exclusive licensing arrangement in order to avoid expropriation and improve their
potential license fee (see also Rasmusen, 1988).
10

is because the funding mechanism identifies high potential performers only in industries

where those are not otherwise likely to be funded. Alternatively, a positive association

between average performance and venture capital funding will be indicative of the

relative importance of appropriability as explaining differences across industries in terms

of small firm research financing.

Either way, this discussion will highlight the fact that we need to control for

differences across industries in appropriability and technological opportunity when

attempting to examine the importance of capital market imperfections in constraining

small firm research activity.

Players, Payoffs and Choice Variables

Our focus here is on the provision of capital to a research unit (RU) that engages

in innovative activity. That capital is considered a critical input for innovative activity.

We suppose that a project requires a unit of capital. 5 This capital may be provided by a

venture capitalist (VC) or by a subsidy from the government. The primary difference

between the two sources is that the former requires, while the latter does not strictly use,

potential private returns in selecting projects to fund. We will consider the VC capital

source first and discuss the role of a government subsidy later. It is assumed that the

VC’s capital contribution is contractible and that VC financing is competitive.

Having received the requisite capital for the project, the probability that a

commercializable innovation is generated is p. This probability may be endogenous

depending on the ability (type) or effort of the RU.

5
This unit is the minimum level of capital required for a project. The unit assumption is a normalization;
essentially all our return variables are in per unit of capital terms for notational ease.
11

An innovation, if generated, has a social value of V of which the RU (and their

equity partners) can only appropriate a fraction, γ (< 1). We denote the RU’s returns by v

= γV. As discussed earlier (in Section II), previous research has identified many potential

determinants of γ including the degree of product market competition and the ease of

entry to it, the strength of intellectual property rights, and transactions costs involved in

selling ideas. Each of these represents a potential imperfection at the product, rather than

capital, market level affecting the private returns to innovation.

While our discussion of the model here will focus on an individual project with

social return, V, we expect that these returns will vary among projects. For our exposition

here we will assume that a given project is drawn from an industry-level distribution that

is uniform over the space [ 0,V ] . The parameter, V , is, therefore, a measure of the level

of technological opportunity in an industry. Hence, one would expect average

performance to be higher in industries with larger V .

Determining VC Funding

The social cost of the total level of industry funding, F, is assumed to be 1


2
F2;

that is, it is increasingly difficult to attract capital. For a given project, the marginal

private cost of capital is F + θ, where θ is the difference between the private and social

marginal cost of capital. We assume that θ > 0 capturing the potential for capital market

imperfections. This marginal cost determines the supply of industry funding for small

firm research. This model is admittedly a reduced form. In the appendix, we provide

three alternative models of why, in this context, the private cost of capital may be greater

than the social cost.


12

On the demand-side, the expected private return from a project is pv. The total

industry demand for these projects – that is, the number of projects funded, F – is

determined by the distribution of project value in the industry. That is, if for F projects

are funded, the marginal project has social value V determined by F = V − V . The

expected marginal private return when F projects are funded is, therefore,

pγ V = pγ (V − F ) . This is the (inverse) demand for funding of RUs in the industry.

Figure 2 graphically depicts the supply and demand for RU funding in an

industry. In equilibrium, the level of industry funding is:

F= 1
2 ( pγ V −θ ) (1)

Notice that F is increasing in V and γ but falling in θ. That is, an increase in V or γ

shifts the demand and hence F, upwards, while an increase in θ, shifts supply upwards

and reduces F. Thus, industries with greater appropriability, technological opportunity

and lower capital costs, will see more funding than other industries. However, other

things being equal, the marginal project funded will have a higher expected value in

industries that have higher capital costs as well as greater degrees of appropriability and

technological opportunity.
13

Figure 2: Equilibrium Industry Funding

pγ V F+θ

Expected
Project
Value

pγ (V − F )

0 Total Funding
F

Notice that a project will be undertaken only if pv ≥ F + θ . This differs from the

social criteria for project desirability: pV ≥ F . Consequently, the level of private

investment in R&D may be less than the socially desirable level both because of

difficulties in appropriability through the product market (γ < 1) and a greater private cost

of capital.

The Effect of a Capital Subsidy

Our empirical goal is to determine the broad explanation of differences in

observed VC funding across industries. Above we derived that, for industry i,

Fi = f (Vi ,γ i ,θ i ) . That is the random variable, Fi, is a function of the industry levels of

technological opportunity ( Vi ), appropriability (γi) and capital market imperfections (θi).

Each of these variables determines either the demand or supply of funds to the industry.

Therefore, to discover which of these might account for variations in industry VC


14

funding, we need to determine whether different inter-industry funding levels are

consistent with movements along the demand or supply curve.

The key issue with this empirical exercise is that, while the quantity variable (F)

is readily observable, there are difficulties in determining the price variable (the expected

profitability of the marginal project) in a way that is comparable across industries. We

propose that SBIR program recipients provide a means of identifying the marginal

project. The SBIR program provides capital grants that effectively equalize the type of

capital market imperfections modeled here. Specifically, these grants do not require

equity participation by third parties or any reference to the private returns from capital

investment. As such, the effect of the SBIR program is to (roughly) equalize any

differences in capital market imperfections across grantees in different industries. The

private cost of capital is simply irrelevant in terms of the direct objectives of the subsidy

program. Hence, SBIR recipients include those that would not otherwise meet private

funding criteria.

It is the SBIR funding mechanism that assists in identifying marginal projects. A

laudable goal of any government subsidy program is to encourage economic activity

where it does not currently exist. For the financing of small firm investment, this goal

could be realised if the projects that were selected were the most promising projects that

missed out on private funding. In our model, these projects would be those that just failed

to attract funding. For industry i, the marginal project would be characterized by the

condition:

pγ iVi + θ i
vi = .
2p
15

If this project is granted a subsidy, this condition characterizes the private return it would

realize. Observe that this private return is increasing in the degree of capital market

imperfection (θi), the space of technological opportunities ( Vi ), and the level of

appropriability (γi). Importantly, given its role in determining the supply of funds,

changes in θi move Fi and v i in opposite directions. Hence, if differences in capital market

perfections were an important driving force in the concentration of VC funding, we

would expect observed Fi and v i to be negatively correlated.

The following proposition characterizes the correlation between vi and Fi across

industries.

Proposition 1. cov[vi ,Fi ] < 0 if and only if the variance of θi exceeds the variance of
pγ iVi .

PROOF: Recall that, from (1), Fi = 1


2 ( pγ V −θ ) . Then:
i i i

 pγ V + θ i   pγ iVi +θ i 
cov[ F , vi ] = E  12 ( pγ iVi − θ i ) i i  − E  2 ( pγ iVi −θ i )  E 
1
 <0
 2p   2p 

1
4p
( 

2


 ) (
p2 E  (γ iVi )  − E θi2  <
1
4p
p2 E γ iVi  − E [θi ]
2
) 2

⇒ p ( E ( γ V )  − E γ V  ) < E θ  − E [θ ]


2 2 2
2 2
 i i
 i i i i

Intuitively, variations in θi move the supply curve while variations pγ iVi move the

demand curve. Thus if the variance of θi exceeded that for pγ iVi , one would observe

‘price’ and ‘quantity’ variables across industries tracking the demand curve. As this is

downward sloping those variables would be negatively correlated. On the other hand, if

the opposite were true and θi varied relatively little across industries, observed pairs

would track the supply curve that is upward sloping. Hence, the variables would be

positively correlated.
16

In summary, by looking to the SBIR program for information regarding the

returns of marginal projects (v i), we can use the correlation between this and observed

VC funding (Fi) to determine the relative strengths of capital market imperfections and

product market variables in accounting for differing levels of VC funding across

industries.

Funding Mechanism

In proposing the above empirical test of the relative salience of capital and

product market imperfections in determining the level of VC funding we have postulated

a marginal funding mechanism for selecting SBIR recipients. It may be objected that the

SBIR could use other mechanisms for allocating funds. In particular, projects may be

selected to ensure political success of the program. Consequently, the SBIR may cherry

pick the best possible project rather than projects that would otherwise not receive private

funding (Wallsten, 1997).

If cherry picking is the selection mechanism, then if the main source of variation

across industries is in the capital market imperfection (θi) then the level of industry VC

funding is unlikely to explain the average performance of grant recipients. While the

grant alleviates the capital market imperfection, it equalizes its expected effect on

individual grant recipients, as those recipients are not selected on the basis of V alone.

This is in contrast to the marginal rule that implicitly considers θ when it searchers for

projects that are not likely to be funded by the VC. Under cherry picking, projects that

might otherwise by funded, are selected for a government subsidy. Hence, the concerns
17

that subsidy programs, such as the SBIR, may not be allocating resources to where they

are currently scarce (Wallsten, 1997).

Nonetheless, grantees in industries with greater technological opportunity ( Vi ) or

higher product market appropriability (γi), will perform better under a cherry picking rule.

Hence, if either of these were the main source of structural variation across industries,

this would still be reflected in a positive correlation between industry-average grantee

performance and the level of industry VC funding. Otherwise that correlation would be

close to zero.

IV. The SBIR Program and R&D Investment by Small Firms

This paper uses Proposition One in order to evaluate how an evaluation of the

performance of government-subsidized small R&D-intensive firms may inform us about

the relative salience of different forces which determine the funding and intensity of

small-firm research-oriented innovation across industries and technology segments. To

do so, we exploit data about projects funded by the Federal government’s SBIR, the

largest individual source of R&D financing for small to medium-sized firms in the United

States. SBIR funding provides a unique and informative source of variation in the

funding of small, research-oriented firms. Specifically, from the perspective of funded

firms, the SBIR program (roughly) equalizes the cost of capital for R&D regardless of

industrial sector, while keeping the nature of downstream appropriability and

technological opportunity constant in specific industries and technology sectors. We

exploit this variation to evaluate the relative importance of capital market imperfections,

product market imperfections, and technological opportunity in determining differences


18

in the level and composition of R&D investment across industries and technological

sectors. Such a test depends, of course, on drawing a precise mapping between the

institutional details of the SBIR program and the assumed economic consequence of the

program. We, therefore, first briefly review the SBIR program, highlighting the potential

economic effects of the subsidy program.

The SBIR Program, first authorized in 1982, requires that all Federal agencies

who support a minimal level of R&D activity are required to set aside a certain

percentage of their funds for extramural grants to fund R&D projects by small business.6

The principal legislative goals of the program are to:

(a) increase the rate of commercialization of innovations derived from Federal

research,

(b) enhance the ‘competitiveness’ of small firms in technology-intensive

industries; and

(c) enhance the participation of small firms as well as women and minority-

owned businesses in the Federal contracting process (GAO, 1995).

From a political perspective, the program’s support seems to derive in part from (ever-

increasing) political demand to focus R&D expenditures towards more near-term

development projects and to areas which have a clear relationship to medium-term

economic growth (Cohen and Noll, 1993). Combined with political rhetoric which simply

assumes that research-oriented start-up firms are the engine of long-term economic

growth, and that such firms face a particularly severe “funding gap” arising from the

6
This percentage has varied over time starting at X in 1990 and reaching a stable level of Y in 1997. For
the purposes of the program, a small business is defined as an US-owned firm with less than 500
employees. Further details of the SBIR are discussed extensively in GAO (1995), Wallsten (1995, 1997),
and Lerner (1999).
19

unwillingness of investors to shoulder the risks of early-stage financing, the SBIR has

been a popular program whose scope has been consistently expanded since its inception

(REFS). Indeed, the SBIR is now the single largest source of early–stage R&D financing

for small firms in the United States with 1997 expenditures of over $1 billion.

Despite its political support, the program has been somewhat controversial. In

part, this is because neither the legislative nor regulatory rules governing the program

mandate the program fund projects on the margin (which would determine performance

according to the first part of Proposition One): indeed, as dramatically highlighted by

Wallsten (1997), the program’s funding guidelines seem to focus on funding the most

attractive grant applications from either a technical or commercialization perspective

(thus suggesting that performance may reflect the “cherry-picking” regime).7 Perhaps as a

consequence of this selectivity, there is some evidence that firms funded by the program

do tend to have an accelerated rate of growth compared to similar firms (Lerner, 1999).

However, Lerner emphasizes that this “boost” to firm-level growth seems to be localized

according to the location or technology focus of the firm, a contention which we explore

in much further detail in our empirical work.

Indeed, the main focus of this prior research is on the assessment of the marginal

contribution of SBIR funding (and government venture capital more generally). Towards

this goal, each of these analyses is framed in terms of the counterfactual of the expected

behavior or performance of these firms, in the absence of the subsidy program. Indeed,

both Lerner (1999) and Wallsten (1997) focus their results around the comparison of a

7
An additional critique is that a small number of firms have been able to win a disproportionate share of
overall grants. While the absolute importance of these so-called “SBIR mills” is limited, the potential for
regulatory capture by these firms has led to interest in limits on the total number of grants for which a
20

group of SBIR-funded firms and a “matched sample” of firms who are observationally

similar ex ante but who do not receive SBIR funding. For example, Wallsten concludes

that SBIR award winners do not necessarily grow faster than other firms (in terms of

employment growth) by comparing a group of SBIR award winners with a group of firms

who had applied for but been rejected in the SBIR grant applications. Lerner also

examines both SBIR grantees and a comparison group in a regression analysis. Once

again his focus is on the incremental differences at the firm level associated with

receiving an SBIR award. He concludes that the awardees do tend to grow faster though

this effect is mostly localized around firms in locations that also fund venture capital.

This paper refocuses analysis of the program away from program assessment.

Instead, our analysis exploits three central features of SBIR funding:

(1) the wide dispersion of these funds across industries and technology segments;

(2) the program’s ability to alleviate capital market imperfections in the funding

of research; and

(3) the program’s inability to directly impact the nature of appropriability or

technology opportunity in a given field or technology area.

We use these features together to pose and analyze our empirical test which compares the

behavior and performance of SBIR grantees across industrial areas and technology

segments.

First, because the program is administered through a variety of Federal agencies

(Agriculture, Defense, HHS, etc.) whose missions span the scope of the economy’s

activities, the expenditures of the SBIR program are much more widely dispersed (across

single firm might be eligible (GAO, 1995). While we do not specifically address mini-mills per se, we do
demonstrate that our results are robust to their inclusion or exclusion.
21

industries and technological areas) than privately funded R&D. This wedge between

SBIR expenditures and private funding is particularly salient if one focuses on investment

or R&D expenditures specifically for small (or venture-backed) firms. In other words, a

specific if unintended contribution of the SBIR program is to expand the supply of capital

to research-oriented, smaller firms to a set of industries and technologies which, for one

reason or another, do not currently attract such funds.

The second element of the program that we utilize is that, as a “hands-off”

subsidy, the SBIR program substantially alleviates the salience of capital market

imperfections. In contrast to the tradeoff that emerges between the provision of incentives

and the taking of equity in the analysis of private investment in a research-oriented

organization, the SBIR does not extract equity (or debt) from the grantee. In fact, quite

the opposite. The incentives to perform the research are preserved and incentives to divert

the fruits of research away from equity holders are minimized. Of course, SBIR funds do

not completely alleviate capital market issues or incentive problems – we only claim (or

need to claim) that the SBIR program reduces the salience of capital market

imperfections relative to the provision of private venture capital.

Finally, as a hands-off subsidy, SBIR grants cannot alleviate product market

imperfections or the lack of technological opportunity in a given field. If intellectual

property rights are weak in a given area prior to the SBIR grant, there is nothing in the

funding of that research which will overcome this general bias. Indeed, while venture

capitalist funding may provide non-pecuniary value to the firm through the experience of

the managers in translating research results or novel ideas into appropriable technologies
22

or business models, the SBIR granting process is focused on funding technology

development per se and contributes essentially no additional commercialization services.8

The remainder of this paper is devoted to exposing and exploring the economic

test embedded in these three features of the SBIR. By being more diverse than privately

funded investment, data from grantees provides information about the differences in the

returns structure across industries where there is currently venture capital funding and

also where such funding is more rare. Differences among SBIR grantees across industrial

areas may reflect the differential impact of reducing the salience of capital market

imperfections. For example, if capital market imperfections are particularly strong in a

given industry, then the provision of public funds may hold particularly high marginal

productivity there. Alternatively, perhaps capital market imperfections are somewhat

similar across sectors, but sectors differ substantially in terms of their appropriability

regime (or overall technological opportunity). In this case, the subsidy will be most

productive (in terms of project performance) in those sectors that already offer a

favorable appropriability (or technological opportunity) environment. As such, in contrast

to the earlier hypothesis, project performance should be highest in those sectors that

already are funded by venture capitalists. In evaluating the performance of the SBIR

program, we are examining a interesting empirical context where we observe an

equalizing shift in the capital constraint, holding the appropriability regime constant. We

can examine this more carefully by first describing the data we have gathered for this

study before turning to our empirical results.

8
In recent years, there has been legislation encouraging the funding of consultants for grantees to assist in
the commercialization process. By all accounts, such efforts or activities are very rare empirically and pale
compared to the involvement of venture capital management.
23

V. Data

This paper presents results from a novel dataset of 100 projects funded by the

SBIR since 1990. The data were gathered via a field-based proprietary survey conducted

by the authors. This project-level data was then supplemented with public data on each

firm’s patenting behavior, SBIR grant history, and covariates related to the industry,

business segment, and scientific underpinning associated with each project. In this

section, we first review our procedure and the elements of our survey (highlighting the

sample selection and data gathering process) and then review the summary statistics for

the sample (Table 1 includes the definitions of all the variables used in the analysis;

Table 2 provides means and standard deviations).

Survey Data Sources and Sample Selection Method

The data is drawn from several sources; most importantly a survey conducted

between December and February 1999 (see Appendix B for a copy). Along with a similar

survey of the commercialization histories of venture-backed firms, the data from this

survey are being used to study a variety of phenomena associated with the incentives,

strategies, and performance of research-oriented start-ups and, in particular, on the impact

of the Federal SBIR subsidy on each of these issues.

The sample is drawn from a list (compiled by the Small Business Administration)

of the (approximately) 200 largest historical beneficiaries of SBIR grants. For survey

participants, we requested information about their most successful project funded by the

SBIR (for most firms, there was only one (or at most two) SBIR-funded projects which

the firm considered technologically successful). By focusing on the projects for each firm
24

that overcame the substantial technological hurdles associated with innovation, the data

provide information about the relative economic returns of projects in different industries

that are at least successful in a technical sense.

Approximately 50% of the surveys were conducted over the telephone. The

remainder was completed through fax and regular mail (many surveys required follow-up

telephone conversations to clarify ambiguities or to fill in missing data fields). The

overall response rate to the survey was approximately 50%. While sample selection was

not ideal, the degree of non-response seemed correlated with the level of effort devoted to

identifying the individual at the firm who could answer the questions on the survey. Only

a minority of non-responders reported either that no SBIR-funded project was

commercialized successfully or that their non-response was based on concerns relating to

secrecy or confidentiality (all respondents were ensured that their individual responses

would be kept confidential).

The surveys provide information both about the company who received the SBIR

grant as well as the details of the SBIR-funded project. The first part of the survey

gathers information about the size and background of the workforce (e.g., share of

workforce with a Ph.D.) as well as some information about the criteria used to promote

scientists and engineers. Second, the survey asks about the financial structure of the firm

(e.g., share of the firm’s equity owned by venture capitalists or by top management) as

well as the rules used to fund research and development activities (as well as other

investment activities such as advertising). Data is also gathered about the internal

authority structure of the firm (the composition of the board of directors) and the firm’s

overall strategy and perception of its competitive advantage.


25

Firm-level information is complemented with detailed information about the

commercialization history of the SBIR-funded project. These questions include

information about the nature of the technology and the underlying innovation (e.g.,

product or process innovation, development of novel system, the intellectual property and

appropriability environment) as well as information about the product development

strategy of the firm (e.g., time from conception of the new product to market

introduction, upgrades and modifications since product introduction). Further, we break

out the revenues associated with the project into several different categories,

distinguishing direct product market sales from licensing revenue and the sale of

intellectual property assets (e.g., patent exchanges and the like). For both product market

sales and licensing revenue, the survey gathers information about the current-year

revenue (which seemed to be much more reliable, consistent and complete for most

firms) and the total revenues accruing to this product since its commercial introduction.

Finally, the survey gathers information about the nature of the licensing (if it occurs) as

well as the structure of decision-making associated with choosing how to commercialize

the technology.

From this survey, we construct both project-specific and firm-specific variables

(see Table 1 for definitions). First, we define the project-level variables. We define

performance in terms of the aggregate annual revenues from product sales, licensing, and

intellectual property exchanges (REVENUE 98).9 For each project, we identify the

number of PATENTS awarded since the grant as well as the project-level SBIR AWARD

SIZE (from the USPTO and the Small Business Administration, respectively). In

9
All of the qualitative results are robust to using the data on total project revenues (indeed, they are highly
correlated). However, this would further reduce the number of usable surveys by approximately one-third.
26

addition, we identify all firms who receive at least some of their overall revenues not

through direct product market sales but through licensing arrangements or intellectual

property sales. We denote these firms COOPERATORS insofar as nearly all of these

firms are involved in cooperative contracting with more established product market

incumbents; it is useful to note that this cooperative behavior is in lieu of competition

with the same firms who have arranged to “buy out” the SBIR awardees’ product market

position (Anton and Yao, 1995; Gans and Stern, 1998). We also include several dummy

variables, which denote the technology, product and customer base types of each project

(UPGRADE, MADE-TO-ORDER, NOVEL SYSTEM, and LARGE CUSTOMER

BASE). Finally, we calculate one measure of overall product development efficiency

(TIME-TO-MARKET) that is simply the overall time from initial product conception to

the first sale of this product to any customer (either directly or through licensing).

As well, we include several firm-specific variables that describe the more general

financial and organizational structure of the firm. In terms of the measurement of

performance, a portion of our analysis is organized around the determinants of current

firm size (EMPLOYMENT 98). We use the initial value of this measure as a key control

in most of our empirical analysis (BASELINE EMPLOYEES), in order to control for the

initial size of the firm. As well, the analysis examines variables related to financial

structure, VC EQUITY SHARE and INSIDER EQUITY SHARE. The difference

between these is while the first confirms the potential importance of the “certification”

hypothesis (SBIR grants lead to VC funding which leads to overall performance), the

latter allows us to capture the pure associated between performance and maintaining a
27

closely held organization. Similarly, FOUNDER CEO proxies for the overall

entrepreneurial culture and authority structure of the firm.

Sources and Definitions of Industry and Segment-Level Variables

A critical element of the analysis is the relationship of project-level performance

to measures of private and public investments in the industries, technology segments or

scientific areas associated with each project. Specifically, we want to distinguish three

concepts: overall investment in businesses or R&D by small firms, aggregate private

R&D in the project’s industrial area, and the scientific and engineering opportunities

present in the technological areas inherent in the project.

To capture the first, we assigned each project to one of eleven technology

segments identified by Venture One (see Figure 3A). For each segment, we measure the

VC FUNDING STOCK as the (undiscounted) sum of venture investing in that segment

between 1985 – 1992. We also present results for the VC CAPITAL FLOW, which are

composed exclusively of the 1992 disbursements. We also assign each project (firm) to a

single three-digit SIC; the NSF Science and Engineering Indicators provides data for each

SIC on SIC-LEVEL R&D EXPENDITURES, SIC SALES, and SIC-LEVEL SMALL

FIRM R&D EXPENDITURES. Finally, we measure the project’s association with

scientific or engineering opportunity by constructing a SCIENCE STOCK for each

project. First, we assigned each project to one or more scientific and engineering fields

(out of a total of 14). In contrast to the mutually exclusive nature of the prior variables,

the science base of each project can be composed from multiple sources. For each area

(e.g., physics or chemical engineering), we computed the (discounted) Federal Funding


28

stock in that area (equal to 1990 FUNDING + .8 1988 FUNDING + .6 1986 FUNDING).

Each project’s SCIENCE STOCK is simply the sum of the individual field-level stocks

for fields associated with that project.

In addition, we attempt to provide additional controls for the environmental

heterogeneity among firms by including a number of variables from the survey that

capture, at least to some degree, the firm’s perception of the appropriability environment

relevant for the project under consideration. Specifically, we include several variables

that relate to the relative importance of differences source of intellectual property

(PATENTS, SECRECY, SPEED TO MARKET), each of which is measured as a 5-point

Likert scale variable. As well, we include several assessments of the degree of

importance associated with the control of different complementary assets

(MANUFACTURING, DISTRIBUTION, BRANDING, SERVICING). As with the IP

measures, each is a five-point Likert Scale measure as reported in the survey.

Summary Statistics

Out of a total 100 responses, 74 were fully usable for the empirical work reported

here.10 However, for most of the analysis, we exclude the small number of observations

(3) that were clearly so-called SBIR “mills”; these organizations have a much more

diverse research portfolio from the rest of the sample and also have a different

relationship with funding agencies. This leaves us with 71 total observations for the

majority of our analysis.

10
Most of the non-responses were because of non-reporting of all 1998 revenues (e.g., sales reported but
not licensing revenue. We have checked our results including all results, even those for whom the data was
incomplete; the qualitative results are unchanged.
29

Among these 71, the average project reports approximately 6.5 million dollars in

revenue, compared with an average award size of 1.5 million (but note the high standard

deviations associated with each). As well, these organizations seem to be highly

productive in a technical sense. On average, each has been issued over 9 patents that were

applied for since the first SBIR grant associated with the specific project here (all chosen

projects have their first funding date after 1990). In addition, almost a third of the sample

earns at least some its revenue through cooperative licensing or IP exchanges (most often

with product market incumbents). As well, the average commercialization length of

projects is a little over four years, though some outliers in part drive this (from

biotechnology and the like). Finally, at the firm level, while most of these organizations

are quite small at inception (35 employees on average), they tend to experience

substantial growth over time (the average firm has nearly 90 employees by 1998).11

As suggested earlier, the principal empirical exercise of this paper will be to relate

project-level performance measures (REVENUE 98 and EMPLOYMENT 98) to

segment-level measures of private investment activity and the technological environment.

Figure 3 presents the distributions of the three principal measures we use to capture these

effects: 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK, SCIENCE STOCK, and SIC-LEVEL R&D

EXPENDITURES. Each of these measures provides a distinct way of capturing the

degree of environmental heterogeneity facing different SBIR-funded projects in terms of

the level of technological opportunity and realized private investment activity. Whereas

the VC FUNDING STOCK (Figure 3A) measures the skewed distribution of

11
As well, in terms of the internal organization and finance of the firms, over 50% of equity is retained by
insiders; perhaps surprisingly, while 25% of the sample had attracted some form of VC or “angel”
financing, the equity share of these investors is quite small (the average level of equity held by these
outside investors across the full sample is less than 7%). In addition, in nearly 60% of the firms, the CEO is
30

entrepreneurial activity and is divided into several segments which do not precisely map

into the traditional SIC classification, Figure 3B and 3C measure differences in

investment in alternative scientific and engineering fields upon which many of these

innovations draw and differences across sectors ni terms of aggregate R&D expenditures,

respectively. Whereas SCIENCE STOCK and R&D EXPENDITURES will tend to be

sensitive to differences across sectors in terms of technological opportunity, only VC

FUNDING STOCK will be sensitive to the differences across sectors in terms of the

degree of appropriability or the salience of capital market constraints facing small

research-oriented firms. Consistent with the SIC-level motivating statistics we presented

in Table II, Figure 3 highlights both the skewed nature of both venture financing and

R&D funding (e.g., telecommunications, medical care technologies, and software make

up over 60% of the aggregate 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK).

In terms of their overall summary statistics, while the VC FUNDING STOCK is

measured as the cumulative investment in given areas over 8 years, one can see that the

aggregate average level of SCIENCE STOCK and R&D EXPENDITURES are

considerably higher, particularly given that SCIENCE STOCK depends on the

summation across three years of investment and R&D EXPENDITURES is measured

from a single cross-section. As well, the Appropriability Mechanism measures (control

vraiables for the environment) are each Likert measures; not surprisingly, the mean of

each varies from a little above 3 to just over 4. With these summary statistics in mind, we

can turn the heart of our empirical analysis, to which we now turn.

one of the original founders of the firm. Finally, the firms are reasonably concentrated
geographically(nearly half the companies are located in either California or Massachusetts).
31

VI. Empirical Results

We now turn to our evaluation of the principal hypotheses of this paper (recall

Proposition 1). Specifically, we are concerned with the degree of variation across sectors

in technological opportunity (V(V )), the degree of appropriability (V(γ)), and the

relative salience of capital constraints (V(θ)). Our empirical test provides evidence about

the relative salience of these factors in explaining the large differences in R&D funding

for small firms across industries that we highlighted in Section II. Specifically, we test for

the relationship between project-level performance and the level of private investment in

each project’s industry or technological segment, controlling for project-specific or firm-

specific factors that also may affect performance. In Tables 3-5, we present our main

finding from this analysis: controlling for project-level, firm-level and other

environmental characteristics, revenue is increasing in the level of venture capital funding

for small firms in a given technology segment and, more tentatively, in the science stock

associated with a given technology. In contrast, performance is not statistically related to

overall R&D investment in a given area or the overall size of an industrial segment.

These basic findings are robust to several quite stringent tests of robustness, including the

inclusion of additional controls for appropriability, project-level and firm-level factors, as

well as variation in the measurement of the level of financing for small research-oriented

firms (some of these results are presented in Appendix C). As well, in Table 6, we show

that there is also a positive relationship between an alternative measure of performance

(EMPLOYMENT 98) and the industry-specific level of venture financing.


32

The Performance of SBIR-funded Development Projects

We begin in Tables 3 with the relationship between L REVENUE 98 and each of

the alternative measures of private investment and technological opportunity. The most

striking result is that, whereas SCIENCE STOCK, SIC R&D EXPENDITURES, and SIC

SIZE are uncorrelated with project-level performance, 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK is

both statistically significant and quantitatively important: doubling the level of venture

funding in an industrial segment is associated with over a 50% increase in measured

revenue (see (3-1)). As well, in (3-5), we demonstrate that our principal result

concerning the VC FUNDING STOCK is robust to the inclusion of the alternative

measures of the segment-level environment (which remain themselves insignificant and

lower in magnitude). When considering these results, it is useful to recall that, relative to

the VC FUNDING STOCK measure, SCIENCE STOCK and SIC R&D

EXPENDITURES are more closely associated with variation in technological

opportunity than the variation in the structural parameters associated with appropriability

or capital market imperfection impacting small, entrepreneurial firms. While we defer our

overall interpretation of this result until our conclusions, it is useful to note that, under the

logic of Proposition 1, this result suggests that there is a salient difference across

industrial segments in terms of their appropriability environment (i.e., V(γ) > 0), even

after incorporating some more direct measures which would capture variation in

technological opportunity (V(V )).

Table 4 extends this analysis of the determinants of REVENUE 98 by focusing on

the robustness of the VC FUNDING STOCK result to the inclusion of various project-

level, firm-level, or alternative environmental controls. In (4-1), we include the simplest


33

“control,” the level of initial employment at each firm. In some sense, this very simple

measure should capture some degree of the heterogeneity among firms in terms of their

initial conditions in terms of generating products associated with a given level of

revenue; however, its inclusion does not impact our main result at all. We then extend our

analysis is (4-2) and (4-3) by including a number of alternative control variables,

associated with the firm’s perception of the appropriability environment and project-level

controls, respectively. At one level, the results from this analysis are interesting in their

own right: while revenues are increasing in the technological quality and product

development efficiency of the project (PATENTS, UPGRADE and TIME TO MARKET

respectively) and whether firms “cooperate” with more established firms (note this could

be in part the result of the selectivity of projects which are attractive for licensing),

revenues are relatively unrelated to the Likert measures of the appropriability

environment facing individual firms. However, the more important finding from Table 4

is that the coefficient associated with VC FUNDING STOCK remains roughly the same

magnitude and statistically significant, despite the large number of control variables

included and given the relatively small number of observations in the sample. Indeed, in

(4-4), we include all of the control measures simultaneously with no impact on the

underlying result regarding the VC FUNDING STOCK variable. Once again, given the

logic of Proposition 1, these results suggest that there exists an important source of

variation across sectors in terms of the degree of appropriability facing small firms, and

that such differences are reflected in the ability of subsidized firms to earn returns on

their innovations in specific industrial segments.


34

In Table 5, we turn back to the more general comparison between the VC

FUNDING STOCK variable and measures which more closely correspond to

technological opportunity (SCIENCE STOCK and SIC R&D EXPENDITURES).

Specifically, in (5-1) and (5-2), we regress REVENUE 98 on each of the alternative

measures (SCIENCE STOCK and SIC R&D EXPENDITURES, respectively), including

all of the controls considered in Table 4. Interestingly, with these controls in place, the

magnitude of the coefficient associated with SCIENCE STOCK increases substantially

and is statistically significant (SIC R&D EXPENDITURES remains both relatively small

and statistically insignificant). However, when, in (5-3), we include all of these variables

together, the principal result associated with VC FUNDING STOCK remains robust, as

does the SCIENCE STOCK result. In other words, even after we control simultaneously

for various project-level controls as well as measures associated with technological

opportunity and aggregate R&D expenditures, the highest performing SBIR-funded

projects tend to be associated with those industrial segments with high rates of venture

capital funding.12 While such a result may be interesting in terms of SBIR evaluation per

se, perhaps its more important implication is that such covariation is only possible when

differences across sectors are powerfully shaped by differences in the appropriability

conditions facing small, entrepreneurially oriented firms.

12
Appendix Tables A-1 and A-2 further establish the robustness of the VC FUNDING result. In A-1, we
include additional firm-level covariates, including measures of the financial organization of the firm, as
well as additional environmental covariates associated with the geographic location of the firm. As before,
while the SCIENCE STOCK variable is only significant in some specifications, the VC FUNDING
STOCK remains significant at a similar magnitude. Finally, in A-2, we consider alternative sample
selection schemes such as mandating that we only include projects whose 98 REVENUES are greater than
the size of their SBIR grant or including the SBIR “mills” in the analysis. As before, our main qualitative
result is confirmed: project-level revenues are strongly associated with segment-specific level of venture
financing.
35

Finally, in Table 6, we compare our results regarding REVENUE 98 to an

alternative analysis focused on the determinants of firm-level employment

(EMPLOYMENT 98). In some sense, this analysis is more directly comparable to the

analysis pursued by Lerner (1999), in that Table 6 focuses on the determinants of firm-

level performance among SBIR-funded firms. The analysis is straightforward and echoes

our earlier finding: while employment growth seems to be relatively unrelated to

environmental measures associated with SCIENCE STOCK or SIC R&D

EXPENDITURES, there is a quantitatively important and statistically significant

relationship between EMPLOYMENT 98 and VC FUNDING STOCK, even after

controlling for BASELINE EMPLOYMENT (as well, this result is relatively robust to

the inclusion of various controls, similar to the earlier analysis). In conjunction with our

earlier findings regarding REVENUE 98, Table 6 provides additional evidence that there

is a robust positive relationship between the performance of SBIR-funded projects and

segment-specific levels of venture activity, a result which can be tied to the potential

presence of differences across sectors in the appropriability environment facing small

research-oriented firms.

VII. Conclusions and Interpretation

Before turning to our interpretations, we emphasize the fragile nature of our

results. The sample is small and based on an imperfect survey. Even with this limitation,

however, several generalizations are possible. First and most importantly, our results

suggest a very specific interpretation of the extreme concentration of venture capital

financing in a small number of technology segments. Rather than simply being a


36

“herding” response to a diffuse sense of technological opportunity, such financing

behavior seems to reflect that the economy offers small “pockets” where the

appropriability regime facing small, research-oriented start-ups is particularly favorable.

Understanding how such pockets emerge seems to be a promising area for further study.

More broadly, our results can be tied to policy. While recent policy activity has

focused on overcoming the “funding gap” for small, research-oriented firms, our results

suggest that benefits might arise from turning attention to strengthening the

appropriability regime facing small firms.

Finally, we return to our contention that our results are suggestive but not the final

word. Beyond the small sample size, we can imagine that a more conclusive approach to

this type of research would be to more carefully integrate the earlier approaches of

Lerner, Wallsten and others (which compared the incremental benefits of SBIR grants)

with the intra-grantee analysis presented here. Such a dataset would allow for more

careful distinction between variation resulting from overall technological conditions, the

fact of being an SBIR grantee, and policy-sensitive issues such as the appropriability

regime facing small firms.


37

Appendix A: Sources of Capital Market Imperfections

In Section III, we considered the effect of a capital subsidy. We argued that a


capital subsidy effectively eliminates problems caused by capital market imperfections or
at least equalizes them for grant recipients across industries. It is, therefore, important to
consider in more detail the reasons why θ > 0 . We consider three alternative models
based on moral hazard, adverse selection and expropriation. In each the capital market
imperfection will arise when a particular parameter, φ, is positive. We will demonstrate
that θ = 0 whenever the parameter φ is zero.

(a) Moral Hazard

Suppose that the RU employs effort in innovative activity and that this can
influence the likelihood of generating a successful innovation. We assume that this effort
has a contractible and a non-contractible component. Using only contractible effort, the
probability of generating a successful innovation is pL. We normalize the cost of this
effort to 0. However, by expending non-contractible effort for a marginal cost of 1, the
RU can raise this innovation probability to pH > pL.
We make two simplifying assumptions. First, we assume that research and capital
provision to the RU is socially desirable for some projects, i.e., p HV > F + 1 . Second, we
assume that there exists F beyond which it is never worthwhile providing capital to the
RU if it is not expected to expend a high level of effort in innovative activity, i.e.,
p Lγ V = F . The former assumption raises the possibility that some socially desirable
projects may go unfunded because of a lack of appropriability. The latter assumption,
however, means that the VC may not fund some privately profitable projects. This is
essentially because of a capital market imperfection that dilutes the role of VC-equity
when RU effort is non-contractible.
Turning to the determinants of VC funding let α denote the level of equity the RU
retains in its own firm. This level of equity (and any capital forthcoming from the VC) is
determined prior to the RU engaging in any innovative activity. The minimum level of
equity the RU can have and still expend a high level of effort ex post is given by the α
that just satisfies the RU’s incentive constraint:
1
pH αv − 1 ≥ pL v ⇒ α ≥ .
v ( pH − pL )

Given the competitive nature of VC capital markets, VC capital will be forthcoming for
the project so long as it is still profitable at this minimum RU-equity level.
p H (1 − α ) v ≥ F
38

Substituting for α, we can re-write the participation constraint for the VC as:
pH v −1 ≥ F +φ ,

where φ = pL /( pH − pL ) . Notice that, in this model, θ = φ ; meaning that the private cost
of capital exceeds the social cost of capital whenever, φ > 0.

(b) Adverse Selection

In the previous model, the capital market imperfection arose because of the
detrimental effect of VC equity on the incentives of the RU to expend non-contractible
effort in innovative activity. Here we consider an alternative model where the probability
of a successful innovation depends on the RU’s ‘type’ that is private information to the
RU. We suppose that there are two types of RU’s. RU’s with high ability generate a
successful innovation with probability pH while for those with lower ability this
probability is reduced to pL. There is no non-contractible RU effort. It is assumed that a
given RU is a high type with probability 1-φ and this is commonly known. The potential
value of the project, v, is, however, known. Finally, we maintain the assumption of the
previous section that p HV > K and p Lγ V < K .
Recall that the VC market is competitive, so RUs can demand the maximum level
of equity for a given project, v. However, as they cannot signal their type, the maximum
RU equity that either the high or low type can demand is:
( (1 − φ ) pH + φ p L ) (1 − α ) v = F
F
⇒ α =1 −
( (1 − φ ) pH + φ p L ) v
This means that the lowest value project that can be funded in an industry is determined
by the v that results in α = 0; i.e., v = (1−φ ) pKH +φ pL . This implies that the total level of VC
funding in the industry will be:
 F 
F =  V − 
 ( pH − φ ( p H − p L ) ) γ 

Notice that this is decreasing in φ implying that the inability of VCs to distinguish good
RUs from bad results in a lower level of VC funding in the industry. Thus, for this model,
θ = (1φ−(φp) HpH+ −pφL )pL . This equals 0 if φ = 0.
39

(c) Expropriation

Our final model of capital market perfections is based on the potential for
expropriation of ideas by a VC. When an RU approaches a given VC for funding they
must reveal their potential idea. In some situations an RU will provide inputs that are
required for that idea to become commercially viable. In other situations, however, the
RU does not add any value in this sense. If property rights over the idea are weak (as they
may be prior to any patents or copyright), then a VC may expropriate the idea and refuse
to let the RU share in any returns. This is a fundamental difficulty in any trade in ideas
(Arrow, 1962; and Anton and Yao, 1994) and it constrains RU appropriability in at every
stage of innovation.
We suppose that, provided a unit of capital is expended, the idea becomes
commercializable with probability, p, and the potential return, v, is common knowledge.
However, it is possible that the VC simply expropriate the full private return v if
approached by the RU. Anticipating this, the RU may not develop the idea of approach
the RU (although here there is no incentive for the RU not to bring the idea to a VC13 ).
However, as Anton and Yao (1994) demonstrate, a capital constrained RU may have
some alternative means of raising capital. This is certainly the case here given our
assumption of a competitive VC market. If one VC were to expropriate the idea, the idea
may be financed by another VC.
To see this, recall that product market appropriation (γ) depends in part on the
degree of competition an innovation faces. That is, are there products that are close
substitutes? If the RU were to turn to another VC, it may be able to reduce product
market appropriation to (1 − φ )γ ; even though it would not receive any ex post rents itself
in this eventuality. Fearing the RU’s competitive threat from disclosure to others, the
initial VC may not expropriate the RU; instead giving the RU some equity in the venture.
This means that RU-equity will be determined through a bilateral negotiation
between themselves and the first VC they approach. This equity is, therefore, not
determined competitively but through a bilateral monopoly (Williamson, 19??).
Essentially, both the RU and VC can use the threat of disclosure to others or
expropriation to bind themselves to reach agreement.
Following disclosure of the idea to the VC, the two parties negotiate over the
equity level given to the RU. Assuming Nash bargaining with equal bargaining power
this yields:
p (1 − α )γ V − F − ( p (1 − φ )γ V − F ) = pαγ V
⇒ α = 12 φ

A project with social value, V, will be funded if and only if the VC’s participation
constraints (expecting this level of equity) are satisfied. This participation constraint is

13
One could imagine that the RU has some sunk expenditures prior to bringing an idea to a VC that would
be lost in the face of expropriation. This could be added to the model here but it would not alter the basic
insight below about the high private cost of capital; it would merely complicated the cost of capital
function.
40

pγ V ≥ 2
2 −φ F . Consequently, the private cost of capital for this model is given by
φ
θ= 2 −φ F and it clearly exceeds 0 for φ ∈ (0,2] .
41

Figure 1A. Concentration of Private R&D Expenditures


vs. Value-added
(Lorenz curve, millions of 1992 dollars)

Gini Coefficient = 0.604


1.000

0.900

0.800

0.700

0.600

0.500

0.400

0.300

0.200

0.100

0.000
0.000 0.100 0.200 0.300 0.400 0.500 0.600 0.700 0.800 0.900 1.000
Cumulative % Value-added
42

Figure 1B. Concentration of VC Disbursement


vs. Private R&D Expenditures
(Lorenz curve, millions of 1992 dollars)

1 Gini Coefficient = 0.560

0.9

0.8

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

Cumulative % private R&D expenditures


43

3A. VC Funding Stock, 1992

14000

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

2000

Industrial Segment

3B. R&D Expenditures, 1993

16000

14000

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

2000

0
metal prod. industrial prod. electric. equip. instruments biotech transportation
Industrial Segment
(Note: R&D expenditures unreported for software & business services)

3C. Science Stock, 1990


8000

7000

6000

5000

4000

3000

2000

1000

Academic Discipline
44

4A. Performance by VC Stock


VC Funding Stock 1992 Revenue 1998
14000 18.00

16.00
12000
1992 VC Funding Stock ($M)

14.00
10000

1998 Revenue ($M)


12.00
8000 10.00

6000 8.00

6.00
4000
4.00
2000
2.00

0 0.00
y

/IT
erg

gy

ter
s
tion

s
ts
En

tor

ice
olo

pu
s

uc
rta

ice

uc

ev
hn

m
rod
po

nd
erv

lD

Co
tec
ns

lP

ico

ica
sS

Bio
Tra

tria

ed
es

Se
us

M
sin

Ind
Bu

Industrial Segment
45

4B. Performance by R&D Expenditures

R&D Expenditures ($M) Revenue 1998


16000 12.00

14000
1993 R&D Expenditures ($M) 10.00
12000

1998 Revenues ($M)


8.00
10000

8000 6.00

6000
4.00
4000
2.00
2000

0 0.00

h
d.

ts

tec

n
pro

en
uip

tio
.
rod

bio
m

rta
eq
tal

lp

tru

po
me

tria

ic.

ins

ns
ctr
us

tra
ele
ind

Industrial Segment
(Note: R&D expenditures unreported for software & business services)
46

TABLE 1
VARIABLES * & DEFINITIONS

VARIABLE DEFINITION SOURCE


PROJECT-LEVEL PERFORMANCE
REVENUE 98 Total 1998 Revenues from Project MIT Survey
EMPOYMENT 98 Total Employees in 1998 MIT Survey
PROJECT- AND FIRM-LEVEL CONTROL VARIABLES
PATENTS Patents awarded since SBIR grant USPTO
COOPERATOR Dummy = 1 if Project Revenues include MIT Survey
licensing revenues, intellectual property sales, or
merger and acquisition, 0 else
UPGRADE Dummy = 1 if Project Technology has been MIT Survey
“substantially upgraded” since market
introduction or prototype, 0 else
TIME-TO-MARKET Months From Conception of Intial Project Idea MIT Survey
Until Product Market Introduction
MADE-TO-ORDER Dummy = 1 if Firm Sells “Made-to-order” MIT Survey
Technologies, 0 else
SBIR AWARD SIZE SBIR Grant Awards Related to Project MIT Survey
Technology (both Phase I and Phase II included)
BASELINE Total Employees in Firm at Start of Project MIT Survey
EMPLOYEES
INDUSTRY OR SEGMENT-LEVEL VARIABLES
1992 VC FUNDING Total (undiscounted) stock of venture capital MIT Survey; Venture
STOCK investment in technology segment most closely One
associated with project
SCIENCE STOCK Total (discounted) stock of Federal expenditures MIT Survey;
on scientific and engineering areas closely related NSF S&E Indicators
to project technology. See text for details.
NB: Stock is linear in all areas related to project
technology
SIC-LEVEL R&D 1993 R&D Expenditures in Project 3-digit SIC MIT Survey;
EXPENDITURES Corptech Directory;
NSF S&E Indicators
SIC SIZE 1993 Total SIC Sales NSF S&E Indicators
APPROPRIABILITY VARIABLES
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Patents for Appropriating Returns
PATENT FOR
APPROPRIABILITY
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Secrecy for Appropriating Returns
SECRECY FOR
APPROPRIABILITY
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of being First to Market to
BEING FIRST TO Appropriate Returns
MARKET FOR
APPROPRIABILITY
47

COMPLEMENTARY ASSET VARIABLES


LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of the MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Control over Manufacturing in
MANUFACTURING Earning Returns from the Project
AS A COMPLEM.
ASSET
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of the MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Control over Distribution Channels
DISTRIBUTION AS in Earning Returns from the Project
A COMPLEM.
ASSET
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of the MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Control over Branding Resources
BRANDING AS A in Earning Returns from the Project
COMPLEMENTARY
ASSET
LIKERT OF 5-Point Managerial Likert Scale Rating of the MIT Survey
IMPORTANCE OF Importance of Control over Servicing Resources
SERVICING AS A in Earning Returns from the Project
COMPLEMENTARY
ASSET
*
The natural logarithm of a variable, X, will be denoted L X
48

TABLE 2
MEANS & STANDARD DEVIATIONS

VARIABLE MEAN STD. DEVIATION


PROJECT-LEVEL PERFORMANCE
REVENUE 98 6.453 13.145
EMPLOYMENT 98 87.784 97.973
PROJECT- AND FIRM-LEVEL CONTROL VARIABLES
PATENTS 8.928 13.104
COOPERATOR 0.351 0.481
UPGRADE 0.838 0.371
TIME-TO-MARKET 45.000 42.142
MADE-TO-ORDER 0.622 0.488
SBIR AWARD SIZE 1.745 1.458
BASELINE EMPLOYEES 35.554 45.477
INDUSTRY OR SEGMENT-LEVEL VARIABLES
1992 VC FUNDING STOCK 2361.752 1380.537
SCIENCE STOCK 7129.043 4336.470
SIC-LEVEL R&D EXPENDITURES 4564.783 3014.836
SIC SIZE 62722.370 38679.860
APPROPRIABILITY MECHANISM VARIABLES
LIKERT PATENT 3.617 1.344
LIKERT SECRECY 3.723 1.363
LIKERT SPEED 3.655 1.261
LIKERT MANUFACTURING 4.191 1.056
LIKERT DISTRIBUTION 3.490 1.214
LIKERT BRANDING 3.191 1.313
LIKERT SERVICING 3.426 1.229
49

TABLE 3
PROJECT-LEVEL PERFORMANCE EQUATIONS
(NO PROJECT-LEVEL CONTROLS)

Dependent Variable = L REVENUE 98


N= 71 observations, excludes “mills”
(3-1) (3-2) (3-3) (3-4) (3-5)
VC STOCK SCI STOCK SIC R&D SIC SIZE Combination
only only only only Model
L 1992 VC FUNDING 0.567 0.586
STOCK (0.255) (0.265)
L SCIENCE STOCK 0.383 0.281
(0.267) (0.271)
L SIC-LEVEL R&D 0.463 0.278
EXPENDITURES (0.347) (0.347)
L SIC SIZE 0.251 0.400
(0.504) (0.507)
Constant -3.680 -2.703 -3.220 -2.112 -12.975
(1.931) (2.308) (2.931) (5.605) (6.700)
R-Squared 0.067 0.029 0.041 0.020 0.125
Adjusted R-Squared 0.054 0.015 0.013 -0.009 0.058
50

TABLE 4
PROJECT-LEVEL PERFORMANCE
AS A FUNCTION OF VC

Dependent Variable = L REVENUE 98


N= 71 observations, excludes “mills”
(4-1) (4-2) (4-3) (4-4)
Control for Initial (4-1) with Likert (4-1) with Project- Combination
Firm Size Appropriability and level Controls Model
Complementary Asset
Controls

L 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK 0.537 0.574 0.550 0.510


(0.265) (0.286) (0.258) (0.747)

BASELINE EMPLOYEES 0.125 0.096 0.117 0.135


(0.152) (0.175) (0.143) (0.169)
LIKERT SERVICING -0.249 -0.094
(0.248) (0.237)
LIKERT DISTRIBUTION -0.150 0.028
(0.262) (0.237)
LIKERT BRANDING 0.039 -0.141
(0.260) (0.258)
LIKERT MANUFACTURING 0.446 0.266
(0.352) (0.344)
LIKERT PATENT 0.060 0.182
(0.222) (0.215)
LIKERT SECRECY 0.034 0.069
(0.249) (0.242)
LIKERT SPEED 0.348 0.200
(0.299) (0.287)
PATENTS 0.037 0.030
(0.015) (0.017)
COOPERATOR 0.836 0.711
(0.380) (0.428)
UPGRADE 1.007 0.961
(0.499) (0.551)
TIME-TO-MARKET -0.008 -0.006
(0.004) (0.005)
MADE-TO-ORDER 0.430 0.387
(0.415) (0.485)
L SBIR AWARD SIZE -0.213 -0.286
(0.165) (0.176)
Constant -3.763 -6.221 -5.730 -7.717
(1.953) (2.830) (2.353) (3.439)
R-Squared 0.081 0.181 0.347 0.411
Adjusted R-Squared 0.040 0.012 0.225 0.176
51

TABLE 5
ALTERNATIVE INDUSTRY-LEVEL
CORRELATES OF SBIR PERFORMANCE

Dependent Variable = L REVENUE 98


N= 71 observations, excludes “mills”
(5-1) (5-2) (5-3)
Science Stock and Industry-level Combination
Opportunity Expenditures and Model
Measures Opportunity
Measures

L SCIENCE STOCK 0.603 0.655


(0.279) (0.295)
L SIC-LEVEL R&D EXPENDITURES 0.178 -0.079
(0.360) (0.348)
L 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK 0.613
(0.278)

FIRM-LEVEL CONTROLS YES YES YES


PROJECT-LEVEL CONTROLS YES YES YES
COMPL. ASSET CONTROLS YES YES YES
APPROPRIABILITY REGIME YES YES YES
CONTROLS
Constant -7.605 -4.493 -12.656
(3.245) (3.746) (4.445)
R-Squared 0.420 0.374 0.474
Adjusted R-Squared 0.188 0.106 0.217
52

TABLE 6
FIRM EMPLOYMENT EQUATIONS
(NO PROJECT-LEVEL CONTROLS)

Dependent Variable = L EMPLOYMENT 98


N= 71 observations, excludes “mills”
(6-1) (6-2) (6-3) (6-4) (6-5)
VC STOCK SCI STOCK SIC R&D SIC SIZE Combination
only only only only Model

BASELINE EMPLOYMENT 0.324 0.377 0.364 0.373 0.339


(0.010) (0.010) (0.102) (0.100) (0.103)
L 1992 VC FUNDING 0.334 0.380
STOCK (0.174) (0.182)
L SCIENCE STOCK 0.156 0.128
(0.178) (0.183)
L SIC-LEVEL R&D 0.047 -0.065
EXPENDITURES (0.235) (0.236)
L SIC SIZE 0.306 0.421
(0.338) (0.344)
Constant 0.377 1.394 2.379 -0.661 -5.252
(1.279) (1.591) (1.965) (3.792) (4.523)
R-Squared 0.217 0.184 0.175 0.184 0.244
Adjusted R-Squared 0.182 0.147 0.125 0.135 0.160
53

TABLE A-1
EQUITY & GEOGRAPHY CONTROLS

Dependent Variable = L REVENUE 98


N= 71 observations, excludes “mills”
(A1-1) (A1-2) (A1-3)
Control for VC Control for Exploring
EQUITY SHARE Management and Geographic Effects
Employee Equity
Share

L SCIENCE STOCK 0.532 0.615 0.689


(0.328) (0.315) (0.304)
L SIC-LEVEL R&D EXPENDITURES -0.090 -0.086 0.004
(0.352) (0.347) (0.369)
L 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK 0.606 0.512 0.636
(0.283) (0.285) (0.284)

VC EQUITY SHARE -0.012


(0.014)
INSIDER EQUITY SHARE -0.010
(0.007)
LOCATED IN NY 1.560
(1.035)
LOCATED IN CA 0.251
(0.502)
LOCATED IN MA 0.050
(0.653)

FIRM-LEVEL CONTROLS YES YES YES

PROJECT-LEVEL CONTROLS YES YES YES


COMPL. ASSET CONTROLS YES YES YES
APPROPRIABILITY REGIME YES YES YES
CONTROLS
Constant -11.111 -10.529 -13.022
(5.254) (5.198) (4.476)
R-Squared 0.486 0.501 0.502
Adjusted R-Squared 0.200 0.224 0.208
54

TABLE A-2
VARYING THE SAMPLE & THE VC MEASURE

Dependent Variable = L REVENUE 98

(A2-1) (A2-2) (A2-3)


Excludes “mills” Includes “mills” in Excludes
and imposes the sample
product revenue
threshold for
”mills” and
inclusion in the
sample imposes product
N=43 N=74 revenue threshold

for inclusion in the

sample

N=71

L SCIENCE STOCK 0.739 0.670 0.626


(0.502) (0.288) (0.299)
L SIC-LEVEL R&D EXPENDITURES -0.053 -0.010 -0.084
(0.504) (0.349) (0.357)
L 1992 VC FUNDING STOCK 1.242 0.567 0.440
(0.520) (0.268) (0.253)

BASELINE EMPLOYEES 0.028 0.228 0.244


(0.308) (0.170) (0.176)
PATENTS 0.021 0.030 0.031
(0.021) (0.017) (0.018)
PROJECT-LEVEL CONTROLS YES YES YES
COMPL. ASSET CONTROLS YES YES YES
APPROPRIABILITY REGIME YES YES YES
CONTROLS
Constant -16.940 -13.168 -10.159
(7.144) (4.446) (4.161)
R-Squared 0.546 0.463 0.455
Adjusted R-Squared 0.003 0.216 0.189
55

References

Aghion, P. and J. Tirole (1994), “The Management of Innovation,” Quarterly Journal of


Economics, 109 (4), pp.1185-1210.

Anand, B. and A. Galetovic (1999), “Weak Property Rights and Hold-up in R&D,”
Working Paper, No.99-007, Harvard Business School.

Anton, J.J. and D.A. Yao (1994), “Expropriation and Inventions: Appropriable Rents in
the Absence of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 84 (1), pp.190-
209.
Arrow, K.J. (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,”
in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton University Press:
Princeton, pp.609-625.

Bush, V. (1945), Science: The Endless Frontier, US GPO.

Cockburn, I. and Z. Griliches (1988). “Industry Effects and Appropriability Measures in


the Stock Market's Valuation of R&D and Patents,” American Economic Review.
78 (2). p 419-23.
Cockburn, I. and R. Henderson (1994), “Racing to Invest? The Dynamics of Competition
in Ethical Drug Discovery,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3
(3), pp.481-519.

Cohen, W. and D. Levinthal (1990), “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on


Learning and Innovation,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), pp. 128-152.

Cohen, L. and R. Noll (1993), The Technology Pork Barrel, Brooking Institution:
Washington (DC).

Crepon, B., Duguet, E. and J. Mairesse (1998). “Research, Innovation and Productivity:
An Econometric Analysis at the Firm Level,” Economics of Innovation & New
Technology. 7 (2) p 115-58.
General Accounting Office (1995), Federal Research: Interim Report on the Small
Business Innovation Research Program.
Gans, J.S. and S. Stern (1998), “Incumbency and R&D Incentives: Licensing the Gale of
Creative Destruction,” mimeo., MIT.

Gans, J.S. and S. Stern (1999), “Models of Corporate and Venture Capital,” mimeo.,
Melbourne.
56

Geroski, P.A. (1994). Market Structure, Corporate Performance and Innovative Activity..
Oxford University Press.

Geroski, P., Machin, S. and J. Van Reenen (1993). “The Profitability of Innovating
Firms,” Rand Journal of Economics 24 (2). p 198-211.
Gilbert, R. and D. Newbery (1982), “Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence of
Monopoly,” American Economic Review, 72 (3), pp.514-526.
Gompers, P.A. and J. Lerner (1999). “What Drives Venture Capital Fundraising?,”
NBER WP.
Griliches, Z (1986). “Productivity, R&D, and the Basic Research at the Firm Level in the
1970's” American Economic Review. 76 (1). p 141-54.
Griliches, Z. (1998). R&D and Productivity. University of Chicago Press.

Griliches, Z., Hall, B.H. and A. Pakes (1991). “R&D, Patents, and Market Value
Revisited: Is There a Second (Technological Opportunity) Factor?,” Economics
of Innovation & New Technology. 1 (3). p 183-201.

Hall, B.H. (1992). “Investment and Research and Development at the Firm Level: Does
the Source of Financing Matter?,” NBER WP 4096.

Hall, Bronwyn H. (1988). “The Effect of Takeover Activity on Corporate Research and
Development.. Corporate takeovers: Causes and consequences.” Auerbach, Alan
J., ed, NBER Project Report series, University of Chicago Press. p 69-96.
Hall, B.H. and J. van Reenen (1999). “How Effective are Fiscal Incentives for R&D? A
Review of the Evidence,” NBER WP ***.
Hao, K.Y. and A.B. Jaffe (1993). “Effect of Liquidity on Firms' R&D Spending,”
Economics of Innovation & New Technology. 2 (4) p 275-82.
Hellmann, T. (1998a), “The Allocation of Control Rights in Venture Capital Contracts,”
RAND Journal of Economics, 29 (1), pp.57-76.

Hellmann, T. (1998b), “A Theory of Corporate Venture Investing,” mimeo., Stanford.


Hellmann, T. and M. Puri (1998), “The Interaction Between Product Market and
Financing Strategy: The Role of Venture Capital,” mimeo., Stanford.
Henderson, R. (1993), “Underinvestment and Incompetence as Responses to Radical
Innovation: Evidence from the Photolithographic Alignment Equipment
Industry,” RAND Journal of Economics, 24 (2), pp.248-270.
Himmelberg, C.P. and B. Petersen (1994). “R&D and Internal Finance: A Panel Study of
Small Firms in High-Tech Industries,” Review of Economics & Statistics. Vol. 76
(1). p 38-51.
57

Holmstrom, B. (1989), “Agency Costs and Innovation,” Journal of Economic Behavior


and Organization, 12 (2), pp.305-327.

Hubbard, R.G. (1998), “Capital-Market Imperfections and Investment,” Journal of


Economic Literature, 36 (1), pp.192-225.
Kortum, S. and J. Lerner (1998), “Does Venture Capital Spur Innovation,” Working
Paper No.6846, NBER.
Klenow, P.J. (1996). “Industry Innovation: Where and Why,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy. 44 (0). p 125-50.
Klette, T. J., Moen, J. and Z. Griliches (1999). “Do Subsidies to Commercial R&D
Reduce Market Failures? Microeconomic Evaluation Studies,” NBER WP
Lerner, J. (1996), “The Government as Venture Capitalist: The Long-Run Impact of the
SBIR Program,” Working Paper, No. 5753, NBER.
Lerner, J. (1997), “An Empirical Analysis of a Technology Race,” RAND Journal of
Economics, 28 (3), pp.228-247.

Lerner, J. and R. Merges (1997), “The Control of Technology Alliances: An Empirical


Analysis of the Biotechnology Industry,” NBER Working Paper No. 6014.

Launjouw, J. (1994), “Economic Consequences of a Changing Litigation Environment:


The Case of Patents,” NBER Working Paper No. 4835.

Levin, R., et. al. (1987). “Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and
Development,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, pp. 783-831.
Mansfield, Edwin (1995). Innovation, technology and the economy: Selected essays of
Edwin Mansfield. Economists of the Twentieth Century series. Elgar (UK).
Nelson, R.R. (1959), “The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research,” Journal of
Political Economy, pp.297-306.
Rasmusen, E. (1988), “Entry for Buyout,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 36 (3),
pp.281-299.
Reinganum, J.F. (1983), “Uncertain Innovation and the Persistence of Monopoly,”
American Economic Review, 73 (4), pp.741-748.
Reinganum, J.F. (1989), “On the Timing of Innovation,” in R. Schmalansee and R. Willig
(eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol.1, Elsevier, pp. 849-908.

Romer, P. (1990), “Endogenous Technological Change,” Journal of Political Economy,


Schumpeter, J.A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Harper: New York.

Stiglitz, J.E. and A. Weiss (1981), “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect
Information,” American Economic Review, 71 (3), pp.393-410.
58

Teece, D.J. (1987), “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for


Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy,” in D.J. Teece (ed.), The
Competitive Challenge: Strategies for Industrial Innovation and Renewal,
Ballinger: Cambridge (MA), pp.185-220.

Wallsten, S.J. (1997), “The Small Business Innovation Research Program: Encouraging
Technological Innovation and Commercialization in Small Firms?” mimeo.,
Stanford.

You might also like