You are on page 1of 310

Managing Forest Ecosystems

Annika Kangas
Mikko Kurttila
Teppo Hujala
Kyle Eyvindson
Jyrki Kangas

Decision Support
for Forest
Management
Second Edition
Managing Forest Ecosystems

Volume 30

Series Editors
Klaus von Gadow, Georg-August-University, Gottingen, Germany
Timo Pukkala, University of Joensuu, Joensuu, Finland
Margarida Tome, Instituto Superior de Agronoma, Lisbon, Portugal
Aims & Scope
Well-managed forests and woodlands are a renewable resource, producing essential
raw material with minimum waste and energy use. Rich in habitat and species
diversity, forests may contribute to increased ecosystem stability. They can absorb
the effects of unwanted deposition and other disturbances and protect neighbouring
ecosystems by maintaining stable nutrient and energy cycles and by preventing soil
degradation and erosion. They provide much-needed recreation and their continued
existence contributes to stabilizing rural communities.
Forests are managed for timber production and species, habitat and process
conservation. A subtle shift from multiple-use management to ecosystems man-
agement is being observed and the new ecological perspective of multi-functional
forest management is based on the principles of ecosystem diversity, stability and
elasticity, and the dynamic equilibrium of primary and secondary production.
Making full use of new technology is one of the challenges facing forest
management today. Resource information must be obtained with a limited budget.
This requires better timing of resource assessment activities and improved use of
multiple data sources. Sound ecosystems management, like any other management
activity, relies on effective forecasting and operational control.
The aim of the book series Managing Forest Ecosystems is to present state-of-
the-art research results relating to the practice of forest management. Contributions
are solicited from prominent authors. Each reference book, monograph or pro-
ceedings volume will be focused to deal with a specific context. Typical issues of
the series are: resource assessment techniques, evaluating sustainability for even-
aged and uneven-aged forests, multi-objective management, predicting forest
development, optimizing forest management, biodiversity management and moni-
toring, risk assessment and economic analysis.

More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/6247


Annika Kangas Mikko Kurttila Teppo Hujala
Kyle Eyvindson Jyrki Kangas

Decision Support for Forest


Management
Second Edition
Annika Kangas Mikko Kurttila
Economics and Society Bio-based Business and Industry
Natural Resources Institute Natural Resources Institute
Finland (Luke) Finland (Luke)
Joensuu, Finland Joensuu, Finland

Teppo Hujala Kyle Eyvindson


Bio-based Business and Industry Department of Forest Sciences
Natural Resources Institute University of Helsinki
Finland (Luke) Helsinki, Finland
Helsinki, Finland

Jyrki Kangas
School of Forest Sciences
University of Eastern Finland
Joensuu, Finland

ISSN 1568-1319 ISSN 2352-3956 (electronic)


Managing Forest Ecosystems
ISBN 978-3-319-23521-9 ISBN 978-3-319-23522-6 (eBook)
DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6

Library of Congress Control Number: 2015950347

Springer Cham Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London


Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of
the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations,
recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission
or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or
dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt
from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this
book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the
authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained
herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made.

Printed on acid-free paper

Springer International Publishing AG Switzerland is part of Springer ScienceBusiness Media


(www.springer.com)
Preface

This book has been developed to serve as a textbook of decision support methods
for students and as a handbook for practical foresters and researchers. It is based on
the research we have carried out, lectures we have given over the past years and also
on our experiences in real-life planning and decision-making processes. We have
set out to present the methods used in enough details and with examples so that they
can be adopted from this book. For researchers who need additional details,
references are given to more advanced scientific papers and books.
In this book, theories of decision-making and the methods used for forestry
decision support are presented. The book covers the basics of classical utility theory
and its fuzzy counterparts, exact and heuristic optimisation methods, deterministic and
stochastic methods and modern multi-criteria decision support tools. The use of each
method is illustrated with examples. In addition to decision aid methods, we present
the basic theory of participatory planning. Both hard and soft methods suitable for
participatory or group decision analysis are presented, such as problem structuring
methods and voting. The criticism towards decision theory is also covered.
In this second edition, we have given special emphasis on the practical aspects of
multi-criteria decision analysis, namely, in selecting the set of criteria and creating
the alternatives for sustainable forest management. We have included descriptions
of different types of real-life participatory planning situations and described how
different decision support tools can be used in them. Furthermore, we have intro-
duced more advanced problem formulations and examples of linear programming
and goal programming and introduced stochastic programming as well as new
local-level heuristic optimisation methods. We hope the new edition can serve as
a handbook in many different planning problems in the future.

Joensuu, Finland Annika Kangas


Joensuu, Finland Mikko Kurttila
Helsinki, Finland Teppo Hujala
Helsinki, Finland Kyle Eyvindson
Joensuu, Finland Jyrki Kangas

v
Acknowledgements

We wish to give our warmest thanks to our many co-authors and collaborators, who
have with their own work helped us in writing this book. We specifically wish to
thank Dr. Juha Lappi for his many comments and corrections to different parts of
the new edition.

vii
Contents

Part I Concepts and Definitions


1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1 What Is Planning? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.2 The Phases of Decision-Making . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.3 Classification of Planning Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
2 Forest Management Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
2.1 Forest Management as a Planning Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
2.2 Stand-Level Forest Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
2.3 Development of Sustainable Forest Management
Planning Approaches . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.3.1 Concept of Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.3.2 Fully Regulated Forestry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.3.3 Development of Optimisation Approaches . . . . . . . . . 16
2.3.4 Development of Multi-criteria Approaches . . . . . . . . . 17
2.3.5 Need for Participatory Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

Part II Discrete Problems


3 Single-Criterion Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
3.1 Decisions Under Risk and Uncertainty . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
3.2 Measuring Utility and Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.2.1 Estimating a Utility Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.2.2 Risk Attitude . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
3.2.3 Estimating a Value Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

ix
x Contents

4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37


4.1 Decision Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
4.1.1 Objectives and Decision Criteria . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
4.1.2 Selecting the Set of Criteria . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
4.1.3 Designing Alternatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
4.1.4 Indifference, Preference and Trade-Off . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
4.1.5 Dominance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
4.2.1 Function Forms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
4.2.2 Basis for Estimating the Weights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
4.2.3 SMART . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
4.2.4 TOPSIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
4.2.5 Cautionary Note of Weighting Methods . . . . . . . . . . . 58
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
4.3.1 Decision Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
4.3.2 Phases of AHP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
4.3.3 Uncertainty in AHP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
4.4 ANP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
4.5 Even Swaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
4.6 AWOT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
5.1 Nature of Uncertainty . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
5.2.1 Membership Functions and Fuzzy Numbers . . . . . . . . 82
5.2.2 Fuzzy Goals in Decision-Making . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87
5.2.3 Fuzzy Additive Weighting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
5.3 Outranking Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
5.3.1 Outline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
5.3.2 PROMETHEE Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.3.3 ELECTRE Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.3.4 Other Outranking Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.1 Stochastic Multi-criteria Acceptability
Analysis (SMAA) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.2 SMAA-O . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
5.4.3 Pairwise Probabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120

Part III Continuous Problems


6 Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
6.1 Linear Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
6.1.1 Primal Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
6.1.2 Dual Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
Contents xi

6.2 Forest Planning with LP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137


6.2.1 Formulating a Problem in an Estate Level . . . . . . . . . . 137
6.2.2 Even-Flow and End-Inventory Constraints . . . . . . . . . 139
6.2.3 Production Possibility Frontier . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
6.3 Goal Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
6.3.1 Soft Constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
6.3.2 Balancing Different Goals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
6.4 General Forest Planning Problem Formulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
6.5 Integer Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
6.6 Hierarchical Forest Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160
6.7 Spatial Goals and Constraints in Linear Programming . . . . . . . 161
6.7.1 Adjacency Constraints and Green-Up Constraints . . . . 161
6.7.2 Spatial Goals Suitable for Linear Programming . . . . . . 164
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
7 Heuristic Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
7.1 Principles of Heuristic Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
7.1.1 Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
7.1.2 Objective Function Forms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170
7.2 HERO . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171
7.3 Metaheuristic Methods Using Local Improvements . . . . . . . . . 173
7.3.1 Simulated Annealing and Threshold Accepting . . . . . . 173
7.3.2 Tabu Search . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
7.3.3 Defining the Parameters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176
7.3.4 Defining the Neighbourhood . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177
7.4 Population-Based Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178
7.4.1 Genetic Algorithms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178
7.4.2 Other Population-Based Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
7.5 Local/Global Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
7.5.1 Cellular Automaton . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
7.5.2 Reduced-Cost Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 186
7.6 Combining Optimisation Techniques . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
8 Uncertainty in Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
8.1 Stochastic Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
8.1.1 Effect of Uncertainty on Optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
8.1.2 Basics of Stochastic Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
8.1.3 Modelling Forest Planning Problems
with Stochastic Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200
8.1.4 Value of Information and Stochastic Solution . . . . . . . 203
8.1.5 Two-Stage Stochastic Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 204
8.2 Robust Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
8.3 Chance-Constrained Programming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
xii Contents

8.4 Robust Portfolio Modelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210


8.4.1 Principles of the Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210
8.4.2 Use of RPM in Forest Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 211
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214

Part IV Cases with Several Decision Makers


9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning . . . . . . . . . . . 219
9.1 Decision-Makers and Stakeholders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 219
9.2 Designing the Appropriate Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221
9.3 Facilitation and Different Facilitator Roles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226
9.4 Success of the Participation Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 229
10 Voting Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233
10.1 Social Choice Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233
10.1.1 Outline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233
10.1.2 Evaluation Criteria for Voting Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . 234
10.2 Positional Voting Schemes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235
10.2.1 Plurality Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235
10.2.2 Approval Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235
10.2.3 Borda Count . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 237
10.3 Pairwise Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 238
10.4 Fuzzy Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 240
10.5 Probability Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 242
10.6 Multi-criteria Approval . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 242
10.6.1 Original Method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 242
10.6.2 Fuzzy MA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 245
10.6.3 Multi-criteria Approval Voting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 248
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 249
11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 253
11.1 Participatory Planning Case Types . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 253
11.1.1 Participation in Public Urban Forests . . . . . . . . . . . . . 253
11.1.2 Regional Forest Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 254
11.1.3 Preparation of Policy Programmes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 256
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 258
11.2.1 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 258
11.2.2 Strategic Options Development
and Analysis (SODA) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 260
11.2.3 Soft Systems Methodology (SSM) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 263
11.2.4 Strategic Choice Approach (SCA) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 270
11.3 Tools for Eliciting the Public Preferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273
11.3.1 Surveys . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273
11.3.2 Public Hearings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274
11.3.3 Location-Specific Preferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274
Contents xiii

11.4 Decision Support for Group Decision-Making . . . . . . . . . . . . . 275


11.4.1 Combined Use of MCA Methods in Group Settings . . . . 275
11.4.2 Utilising GDSS Software for Distributed
Group Negotiation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 281

Part V Behavioral Viewpoints


12 Behavioural Aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289
12.1 Criticism Towards Decision Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289
12.1.1 Outline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289
12.1.2 Satisficing or Maximising? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 291
12.1.3 Rules or Rational Behaviour? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 292
12.2 Image Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 292
12.3 Biases and Distortions in Decision Support Situations . . . . . . . 295
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 300
13 Final Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 301
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 306
Part I
Concepts and Definitions
Chapter 1
Introduction

Abstract In this chapter, decision, decision support, decision-making and plan-


ning are defined. We describe what planning means, why planning is needed and
what are the aims of planning as a process. We describe the phases decision
situations typically involve. We describe the different views for studying
decision-making, i.e. the descriptive view, which studies decisions as people
make them, and normative view, which studies the ways that may help in making
better decisions. We present the different dimensions of decision situations (under
certainty/under uncertainty, single goal/multiple goals, discrete/continuous, single
decision-maker/multiple decision-makers or stakeholders). Finally, we briefly pre-
sent classes of methods potentially useful for decision support for these situations
such as mathematical optimisation, heuristics, multi-criteria decision-making and
group decision-making.

1.1 What Is Planning?

Decision means choosing from at least two distinct alternatives. Most decisions we
face every day may be easy, like picking a meal from a restaurant menu. In most of
the decisions, we need to consider several viewpoints (criteria). For instance, in the
decision about the meal, it can be considered from the points of view of price, taste,
energy content and healthiness. Usually in simple decisions, we balance the differ-
ent criteria without giving it a conscious thought. Everyday decision-making is a
mix of careful judgement and intuitive selection, in other words the slow and fast
processes of reasoning (Kahneman 2011).
Sometimes the problems that people face in their lives (both professional and
private) are so complex or otherwise hard to tackle, however, that some kind of
decision support is needed. Decision support means that we formally model the
decision. It means that we explicitly account for the multiple criteria in important
decisions and systematically explore the effects of different choices on these
criteria. It means that the subjective values of decision-makers are made explicit
and the evaluation of the possible choices is made transparent (Belton and Stewart
2002).
Decision-making, on the other hand, can be defined to include the whole
decision process from problem identification to choosing the best alternative

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 3


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_1
4 1 Introduction

(e.g. Kangas 1992). The decision process starts from the discovery of a decision
problem, meaning the decision-maker (DM) either realises that he/she has alterna-
tive options available and needs to choose the best or realises that the current
situation is not satisfactory and some action needs to be taken. In the first case, the
DM needs to think of the values based on which to make the choice, and in the
latter, the DM needs to define suitable actions based on his/her values. The actual
choice is just the last phase of the decision process.
Planning, on the other hand, can be defined as the process of thinking about and
organising the activities required in order to achieve a desired goal. Planning
involves the creation and maintenance of a plan. Thus, planning is very closely
related to the decision process, and the plan can be seen as the guide to the final
decision.
The choice of the best action is not the only decision type. Also ranking or
sorting type of problems can be seen as decision problems (Ishizaka and Nemery
2013). The sorting problem can be, for instance, such that the alternative options are
sorted to groups of acceptable and not acceptable, for instance, when selecting
a candidate to vote for parliament or choosing research projects to be funded. The
ranking problem means that the candidates are ranked from best to worst, for
instance, when selecting the best candidate for a post in an organisation. Another
type of a decision problem is a design problem (Keeney 1992). It means that a
creative new alternative option is sought for.
In economic theory, it is usually assumed that people act rationally. A rational
decision-maker chooses an alternative which in his/her opinion maximises the
utility (Etzioni 1986, von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). For this, one has to
have a perfect knowledge of the consequences of different decision alternatives, the
goals and objectives of the decision-maker and the preferences of the decision-
maker among them. There is evidence that people are not necessarily rational
(e.g. Simon 1957, Kahneman 2011). Or, even if they would want to make the
best choice, they do not necessarily have enough information for being able to
behave fully rationally.
Therefore, decision-making can be considered from at least two points of view:
one can analyse how the decisions should be made in order to obtain best results
(prescriptive approach) or one can analyse how people actually do decisions
without help (descriptive approach) (e.g. von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986).
The first approach is normative; it aims at designing and promoting methods that
can be used to aid people in their decisions. The second approach represents
behavioural research, usually based on experiments on how people actually make
decisions under different conditions. In the behavioural studies, people have been
found to have many different biases (see, e.g., Kahneman et al. 1991). For instance,
people tend to remember the results of their past decisions as better than they
actually are or to pay attention only to the information that confirms their
pre-assumptions, to name but a few. People have also been found to behave more
business-like and unethically in decisions when they have been prompted with
money just before the decision (e.g. Kouchaki et al. 2013).
1.2 The Phases of Decision-Making 5

The decision support methods are usually based on an assumption that decisions
are made rationally. This is not a problem in decision aid: it can realistically be
assumed that decisions actually were better if people were instructed to act ratio-
nally and advised how to avoid common fallacies in their decision-making. Seem-
ingly, there is a conflict between the rational decision-making and emotions
(Menzel 2013), as well as between rational decision-making and cooperation
(Biel and Thgersen 2006). Emotions may be seen as non-analytical information
concerning the situation, so that they may reflect some important viewpoint in the
decision problem (Menzel 2013). To use them in decision analysis would require
making the non-analytical analytical. Cooperation, on the other hand, could be seen
as a social norm that affects our decision-making (Biel and Thgersen 2006). Social
norms can be interpreted as constraints in the decision-making situation. On the
other hand, social network around the decision-maker may be regarded as an
information resource, thus a potentially useful source of decision support. Decision
aid methods aim at helping people to improve the decisions they make, not
mimicking human decision-making. However, if the assumption of rational behav-
iour is used to predict what people will actually do in future decisions, the
deviations from the rationality assumption may introduce misleading conclusions.
The planning situation can be characterised with three dimensions: the material
world, the social world and the personal world (Mingers and Brocklesby 1997,
Fig. 1.1). The material world dictates what is possible in a planning situation, the
production possibility border. The personal world dictates what we wish for and
what our values are. The decisions are not carried out in a void. The social world
dictates what is acceptable to the society surrounding us, i.e. the social norms. The
effects of all these elements are involved in decision-making, with different
emphasis in different situations.

1.2 The Phases of Decision-Making

The basis of decision-making can be divided into three elements: alternatives,


information and preferences (Bradshaw and Boose 1990). The basis has to be
solid with respect to all elements so that one is able to choose the best alternative.
Keeney (1982) divided the decision analysis into four phases which all are neces-
sary parts of the modelling of decision-making:
1. Structuring a decision problem
2. Defining the consequences of decision alternatives
3. Eliciting out the preferences of the decision-maker
4. Evaluating and comparing the decision alternatives
Generally, in decision-making processes, decision-makers are assumed to rank a
set of decision alternatives and choose the best according to their preferences. To be
able to rank, they select the criteria that are relevant to the current problem and that
are of significance in their choice (e.g. Bouyssou et al. 2001). The criteria used in
6 1 Introduction

The material world


Moulds Our social world
Objectivity
Intersubjectivity
We observe Reproduces
We participate in

Acting
Languaging

Constraints
Enables
& constraints

Appreciates Emoting Expresses

My personal world
Subjectivity
We experience

Fig. 1.1 Three dimensions of problem situation (Modified from Mingers and Brocklesby 1997)

ranking are standards or measures that can be used in judging if one alternative is
more desirable than another (Belton and Stewart 2002). Each alternative needs to be
evaluated with respect to each criterion.
Belton and Stewart (2002, Fig. 1.2), on the other hand, divided the decision aid
process to three phases, namely, problem structuring, model building and using the
model to inform and challenge thinking. This definition emphasises using decision
aid as a help in thinking, not as a method providing ready-made solutions.
According to Keeney (1992), decision-makers should focus on values and on
creating creative new alternatives based on their values, rather than ranking existing
alternatives. He argues that creating the alternatives is the most crucial phase of all
in the decision-making process, and it is not dealt with at all in the traditional
decision science. Both these perspectives reflect the current view of decision
analysis. Some of the older ideas and definitions have been strongly criticised for
treating decision-makers as machines (e.g. French 1989 p. 143). The contemporary
decision aid science emphasises the meaningfulness of the decision support in
shaping how courses of action are manoeuvred.
In practical planning and decision-making processes, different kinds of
approaches, definitions and phases, and combinations of them, may be applied.
There is no universal truth on how a decision process should be performed or
modelled, although researchers often tend to favour their own schools ideas in
all kinds of cases.
1.3 Classification of Planning Problems 7

Identification
of the problem
Problem
Values
structuring

Goals
Stakeholders

Constrains Model
building
Alternatives
External
environment
Uncertainties Specifying
alternatives Using model
Key issues
issues Eliciting
to inform and
values
challenge thinking

Synthesis of
Synthesisof
Defining information Sensitivity
criteria analysis
Developing
an action plan
Challenging Robustness
intuition analysis

Creatingnew
alternatives

Fig. 1.2 The process of MCDA (Belton and Stewart 2002)

1.3 Classification of Planning Problems

The decision situations can be classified in many ways, depending on the charac-
teristics of the problem. The decisions can be made either under certainty or
uncertainty, and the problem could be either a single-criterion or multi-criteria
problem. In addition, the problem can be either discrete (i.e. the number of possible
alternatives is limited) or continuous (i.e. there is an infinite number of possible
alternatives) and include either one or several decision-makers. In the case of forest
management problems, the characterisation may also include spatial and temporal
scales, i.e. geographical coverage and time horizon, and whether the problem is
spatial or nonspatial and which type(s) of goods and services of forests it considers
(e.g. Eriksson and Borges 2014).
If the problem is a single-criterion problem under certainty, the problem is,
theoretically taken, straightforward to solve. If the alternatives are discrete, the best
is chosen by evaluating all the alternatives with respect to the single criterion. In a
continuous case, all alternatives cannot be enumerated, and the best options need to
be searched for using numerical optimisation methods. For instance, the case could
be such that the decision-maker needs to allocate the resources (e.g. money and
land) to competing forms of production (e.g. what tree species to plant) in order to
get the best profit. In such cases, the decision aid methods typically used are
mathematical optimisation methods. These methods produce exact optimal solu-
tions to modelled decision problems. The most commonly applied of these methods
8 1 Introduction

is linear programming LP (see, e.g., Dantzig 1963; Dykstra 1984; Taha 1987;
Hillier and Lieberman 2001). There are also many modifications of this basic
approach, such as integer programming and goal programming.
In many cases, the real problems are too complicated for these exact methods.
Then, the problem either is simplified so that it can be solved with exact methods or
the solution is searched using heuristic methods (e.g. Glover 1989, Glover
et al. 1995 and Reeves 1993). These methods can produce a good solution with
fairly simple calculations, but they cannot guarantee an optimal solution. The
benefit in these methods is that the true decision problems can often be described
better than with exact methods. It may be more useful to get a good solution to a real
problem than an exact solution to a simplified one. Various heuristic optimisation
methods are particularly useful in spatial forest planning problems where, for
example, constrained clusterings of harvestings or habitat networks with connec-
tivity and adjacency goals are formed and thus flexibility to the problem formula-
tion is needed.
If the decision has to be made under uncertainty, also the discrete single-
criterion case is of interest. Modern utility-theoretic studies can be considered to
begin with the works of Ramsey (1930) and von Neumann and Morgestern (1947)
dealing with the unidimensional case under risk. Also Bayesian decision analysis
can be used for single-criterion decision-making under uncertainty (Smith 2010). In
a continuous case, the uncertainties can be dealt with using stochastic programming
(Birge and Louveaux 1997; King and Wallace 2012).
In a multidimensional case under certainty, the problem is to define the trade-
offs between the criteria. In a decision situation, a trade-off means the relative value
of one unit of an attribute for the decision-maker in comparison to one unit of the
other attribute. Such trade-offs reflect the relative importance of the criteria for the
decision-maker, and thus, they are subjective, i.e. there are no correct trade-off
values that all decision-makers should use (Keeney and Raiffa 1976). These trade-
offs may depend, besides the values of the decision-maker, also on the initial wealth
of the decision-maker (von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). The most challenging
problems are those with multiple dimensions including uncertainty. There may be
uncertainty in all parameters of decision analysis; for instance, the future conse-
quences of different actions or the preferences of the decision-maker with respect to
different criteria may be uncertain. Depending on whether the decision problem is
discrete or continuous, different methods are available, for instance, stochastic
multi-criteria acceptability analysis (SMAA) for discrete cases and stochastic
goal programming for continuous cases.
As the name suggests, multi-criteria decision support [MCDS or MCDA (MCD
aid) or MCDM (MCD making)] methods have been developed to enable analysis of
multi-criteria decision situations. They are typically used for dealing with planning
situations in which one needs to holistically evaluate different decision alternatives
and in which evaluation is hindered by the multiplicity of decision criteria that are
difficult to compare and by conflicting interests. For more fundamental descriptions
of MCDS, readers are referred to Keeney and Raiffa (1976), von Winterfeldt and
Edwards (1986), French (1989), Bouyssou et al. (2001), Vincke (1992), Belton and
References 9

Stewart (2002) or Ishizaka and Nemery (2013). Optimisation methods can also be
used in cases where there are an infinite number of possible actions and several
criteria (Steuer 1986; Miettinen 1999). The simplest way is just to use one variable
as objective and the others as constraints and vary the constraint values in order to
see how the increasing of the decided level of one criterion affects the others.
Another complication is that there may be several decision-makers or other
stakeholders involved. In such cases, the problems may be messy: it is not clear
what are the alternatives among which to choose from or what are the criteria with
respect to which the alternatives should be compared because the stakeholders may
have a different view on the problem at hand. The case becomes even more
complex when acknowledging the different attitudes to risks among the multiple
decision-makers. For such situations, there exist several problem structuring
methods (Mingers and Brocklesby 1997). When the problem has been well defined,
many of the MCDS methods can be utilised for group decision-making (see Kilgour
and Eden 2010). In some cases, the stakeholders may have to use the decision
support tool like there were only one decision-maker; other tools such as those
designed to apply the analytic hierarchy process (AHP, Saaty 1980) method can be
used to aggregate the preferences of a number of stakeholders even if they did not
include the same criteria in their models. Some tools, such as voting, are specifi-
cally designed for aggregating the preferences of several decision-makers into a
social choice.

References

Belton, V., & Stewart, T. J. (2002). Multiple criteria decision analysis: An integrated approach.
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.
Biel, A., & Thgersen, J. (2006). Activation of social norms in social dilemmas: A review of the
evidence and reflections on the implications for environmental behaviour. Journal of Economic
Psychology, 28(2007), 93112.
Birge, J. R., & Louveaux, F. (1997). Introduction to stochastic programming. New York: Springer.
421 p.
Bouyssou, D., Jacquet-Lagrez, E., Perny, P., Slowinski, R., Vanderpooten, D., & Vincke, P. (Eds.).
(2001). Aiding decisions with multiple criteria. Essays in honour of Bernard Roy. Dordrecht:
Kluwer Academic Publishers. 274 p.
Bradshaw, J. M., & Boose, J. H. (1990). Decision analysis techniques for knowledge acquisition:
Combining information and preferences using Aquinas and Axotl. International Journal of
Man-Machine Studies, 32, 121186.
Dantzig, G. B. (1963). Linear programming and extensions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
630 p.
Dykstra, D. P. (1984). Mathematical programming for natural resource management. New York:
McGraw-Hill Book Company. 318 p.
Eriksson, L. O., & Borges, J. G. (2014). Computerized decision support tools to address forest
management planning problems: History and approach for assessing the state of art world-wide
In J. G. Borges, E.-M. Nordstr om, J. Garcia-Gonzalo, T. Hujala, & A. Trasobares (Eds.),
Computer-based tools for supporting forest management. The experience and the expertise
10 1 Introduction

world-wide (pp. 315). Umea: Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences. Arbetsrapport/


or skoglig resurshushallning och geomatik 1.
Sveriges lantbruksuniversitet, Institutionen f
Etzioni, A. (1986). The case for a multiple-utility conception. Economics and Philosophy, 2,
159183.
French, S. (1989). Readings in decision analysis. London: Chapman and Hall. 210 p.
Glover, F. (1989). Tabu search Part I. ORSA Journal of Computing, 1, 190206.
Glover, F., Kelly, P., & Laguna, M. (1995). Genetic algorithms and tabu search: Hybrids for
optimization. Computers in Operations Research, 22, 111134.
Hillier, F. S., & Lieberman, G. J. (2001). Introduction to operations research (7th ed.). New York:
McGraw Hill. 1214 p.
Ishizaka, A., & Nemery, P. (2013). Multi-criteria decision analysis. Methods and software.
Chichester: Wiley. 296 p.
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. 499 p.
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss
aversion, and status quo bias. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193206.
Kangas, J. (1992). Metsik on uudistamisketjun valinta monitavoitteiseen hy oty teoriaan perus
tuva paatosanalyysimalli. Summary: Choosing the regeneration chain in a forest stand, A
decision-model based on multi-attribute utility theory. Joensuun yli opiston luonnontieteelli
sia julkaisuja 24. 230 p.
Keeney, R. L. (1982). Decision analysis: An overview. Operations Research, 30, 803838.
Keeney, R. L. (1992). Value-focused thinking. A path to creative decision making. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press. 416 p.
Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and value
tradeoffs. New York: Wiley, 569 p.
Kilgour, D. M., & Eden, C. (Eds.). (2010). Handbook of group decision and negotiation (Advances
in group decision and negotiation, Vol. 4). Dordrecht: Springer. 477 p.
King, A. J., & Wallace, S. W. (2012). Modelling with stochastic programming. New York:
Springer. 173 p.
Kouchaki, M., Smith-Crowe, K., Brief, A. P., & Sousa, C. (2013). Seeing green: Mere exposure to
money triggers a business decision frame and unethical outcomes. Organizational Behavior
and Human Decision Processes, 121, 5361.
Menzel, S. (2013). Are emotions to blame? The impact of non-analytical information
processing on decision-making and implications for fostering sustainability. Ecological Eco-
nomics, 96, 7178.
Miettinen, K. (1999). Nonlinear multiobjective optimization. Boston: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Mingers, J., & Brocklesby, J. (1997). Multimethodology: Towards a framework for mixing
methodologies. Omega, International Journal of Management Science, 5, 489509.
Ramsey, F. P. (1930). The foundations of maths and other logical essays. New York: Humanities
Press. 280 p.
Reeves, C. R. (Ed.). (1993). Modern heuristic techniques for combinatorial problems. Oxford:
Blackwell Scientific Publications. 320 p.
Saaty, T. L. (1980). The analytic hierarchy process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man: Social and national. New York: Wiley. 247 p.
Smith, J. Q. (2010). Bayesian decision analysis. Principles and practise (p. 338). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Steuer, R. E. (1986). Multiple criteria optimization: Theory, computation, and application.
New York: Wiley. 532 p.
Taha, H. A. (1987). Operation research. New York: Macmillan Publishing Company. 876 p.
Vincke, P. (1992). Multi-Criteria decision aid. New York: Wiley.
von Neumann, J., & Morgestern, O. (1947). Theory of games and economic behaviour. New York:
Wiley. 641 p.
von Winterfeldt, D., & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision analysis and behavioral research. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chapter 2
Forest Management Planning

Abstract Forest management planning is a rather unique planning situation. In this


chapter, we describe the special features of forest planning. Forest owners and
managers need to take decisions which can deal with a variety of spatial and
temporal scales, from one stand and short time period up to the national level and
very long time horizons. Forest management decisions also have an impact on
many ecosystem services. Therefore, decision-making must be able to ensure the
economic, ecological and social sustainability of forestry. In this chapter, we
present a historical outline of developing a methodology for forest planning and
the evolving definitions of sustainable forestry. Moreover, we present the require-
ments that the contemporary understanding of sustainable forest management sets
to the development of forest planning methodology.

2.1 Forest Management as a Planning Problem

Forest management planning is a tool of central importance in forestry-related


decision-making. The aim in forest planning is to provide support for forestry
decision-making so that such mix of inputs to and outputs from the forests is
found that best fulfils the goals set for the management of the forest area under
planning. The goals can be related to ecological, economic and social variables and
at the background is the aim for sustainable use of forests. In practice, forests should
produce reasonable incomes while at the same time promoting conservation and
recreational considerations. As a result, practically all forests are being used
simultaneously for multiple purposes (e.g. Kangas 1992; Davis et al. 2001).
Forest decision-making often includes numerous decision-makers or other stake-
holders. They could be owners of the forests, local inhabitants, people connected
with tourism and recreation services, private persons or officials concerned with
nature conservation or personnel of forestry enterprises. Each of them can have
different objectives concerning the use of forests and other natural resources.
Forest planning problems are typically described so that several different and
feasible treatment schedules are created for each stand. For instance, harvests with
two different rotation times produce two different schedules for one stand. Each
schedule may include several treatments with a different timing. It may be that the
schedule for one stand includes one or two thinnings before the final harvest and

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 11


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_2
12 2 Forest Management Planning

planting after it. Also an alternative of having no treatments at all is typically


simulated for stands. The development of the stand is then predicted with respect to
all relevant criteria to the decision-making situation at hand. The predictions are
typically based on forest simulators including growth and yield models for forest.
With different combinations of standwise treatment schedules, a huge number of
different production programmes for the whole forest area under consideration
could be obtained. Among these programmes, those that are efficient with respect
to the criteria involved are worth further investigations. This means that
programmes that are worse than another programme with respect to at least one
criterion but not better than it with respect to any criterion (i.e. is dominated by this
other plan) could be excluded from the analysis. Normally, the end result of forest
planning is a management plan, which recommends the optimal production
programme for the forest area, with predictions of the consequences of
implementing the plan.
Briefly, the main phases in a forest planning process are:
(i) Forest data acquisition and assessing the present state of the forests
(ii) Clarifying the criteria and preferences of the decision-maker(s) regarding the
use of forests and, in participatory planning, clarifying the criteria and pref-
erences of other interested parties
(iii) Generating alternative treatment schedules for forest stands within the plan-
ning area and predicting their consequences
(iv) Producing efficient production programmes for the forest area
(v) Choosing the best production programme from among those deemed to be
efficient with respect to the criteria and preferences as clarified in phase (ii)
These phases do not necessarily proceed in this order, and they can be applied
iteratively, interactively and/or simultaneously.
Forest planning can be strategic, tactical or operational. In strategic planning, the
basic idea is to define what is wanted from the forest and, in tactical planning, to
define how these goals are obtained. In forest context, strategic planning typically
means time horizons from 20 years upwards. Long horizons are especially needed
when assessing the sustainability of alternative decisions. Strategic plans are
usually prepared to cover fairly large areas, from forest estate level in private
forests to regional or national level in the forestry of big organisations. Also
national-level forest programmes can be seen as strategic plans. For practical
reasons, strategic planning calculations are usually not very detailed, and (clusters
of) sample plots can be used instead of spatially explicit stands in planning
calculations.
In tactical forest planning, on the other hand, the time horizon is typically 5
20 years. The number of alternative forest plans, each consisting of a combination
of forest stand-level treatment schedules, can be considerable and practically
infinite. It also means that the resulting plans are detailed, typically including
standwise recommendations. In operational planning, carrying out these standwise
recommendations is planned in great detail. In practice, the strategic and tactical
planning are often integrated so that both strategic and tactical solutions are
2.2 Stand-Level Forest Planning 13

produced at the same time. Planning is continuous work, and whenever the planning
environment or needs of decision-maker(s) change, the plan is updated.

2.2 Stand-Level Forest Planning

In addition to forest area-level planning, it is possible to make plans in the stand


level also. In single stands, planning has been concentrated in defining an optimal
rotation time (e.g. Gregory 1972, Johansson and Lofgren 1985, Buongiorno and
Gilles 2003). There are several criteria for selecting the rotation time. The simplest
of them is to select the rotation, which maximises the mean annual increment
(MAI) of the forest stand (rotation of maximum sustained yield). This is achieved
by harvesting the stand when MAI is equal to the current volume increment. The
most famous rotation calculation method is, however, the Faustmann formula
(1849). In this formula, the value of land is maximised over infinite number of
rotations (the rotation of maximum land rent). In continuous form, the formula is
(Viitala 2002)

X
1
pV ueru  c
Max L pV ueru  ceiru 2:1
fug
i0
1  eru

where p is the price of timber (no assortments assumed), V(u) is the volume at the
end of rotation time u (only clear-cut assumed), r is the interest rate and c defines
the costs of regeneration (no other costs assumed). This rotation time is the
economically optimal rotation for any given stand. In continuous form, the optimi-
sation problem can be analytically solved, and general results, i.e. cutting rules, can
be produced. In this form, however, thinnings cannot be included. In a discrete
form, thinnings can be included, but the problem can no more be analytically
solved. The discrete form is (Viitala 2002)

X
u
Ri  Ci 1 r ui
i0
Max L 2:2
fug 1 r t  1

where R denotes the revenues and C costs in year i.


The stand-level calculations are typically considered as a single-criterion prob-
lem, i.e. only the incomes from future harvests are included. It is possible, however,
also to include other criteria, such as amenities into the problem. In this case, the
amenity value of the forest stand is just expressed in the monetary units like the
incomes, and the multi-criteria problem can be solved as a single-criterion problem
(Hartman 1976). Another possibility is to model the utility of a forest owner (see
Chap. 4) consisting of many criteria and maximise that rather than the Faustmann
formula (e.g. Pukkala and Miina 1997). In that problem formulation, also the
14 2 Forest Management Planning

uncertainties were introduced. In recent years, the uncertainties have been also
included into the traditional Faustmann formula calculations (e.g. Valsta 1992,
Alvarez and Koskela 2007).

2.3 Development of Sustainable Forest Management


Planning Approaches

2.3.1 Concept of Sustainability

The concept of sustainability came to wider interest among decision-makers,


researchers and the general public in the 1980s, when the Brundtland Commission
defined sustainable development as development that meets the needs of the
present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own
needs (United Nations General Assembly 1987; Adams 2006). Later on, sustain-
ability has been defined to contain three pillars: economic, environmental and
social (United Nations General Assembly 2005; Adams 2006). These can be
presented as a Venn diagram (Adams 2006, Fig. 2.1). Sometimes cultural sustain-
ability has been distinguished as the fourth pillar but more common has been to
consider it as part of social or sociocultural sustainability (see Rantala
et al. 2012 and Myllyviita et al. 2014).
In forest management, the principles of sustainability stem from a much earlier
era. Already in 1713, Hans Carl von Carlowitz presented the sustainability princi-
ples in his book Sylvicultura Oeconomica: Wird derhalben die grosste Kunst,
Wissenschafft, Flei und Einrichtung hiesiger Lande darinnen beruhen, wir eine
sothane Conservation und Andbau des Holzes anzustellen, da eine continuerliche,
bestandige und nachhaltende Nutzung gebe; weiln es eine unentbehrliche Sache ist,
ohne welche das Land in seinem Esse nicht bleiben mag (Therefore it is highly
essential to combine research, hard work and planning, that aims at protection and
planting of forests in our country [Electorate of Saxony/Kurfurstentum Sachsen],
that makes a continuous, and sustainable use of our forests possible; all this is
necessary to ensure the future of our country) (von Carlowitz 1713 p. 105106,
Hamberger 2013 p. 216).
In the beginning, sustainability was defined mainly from timber production point
of view. Yet, even in those days, sustainability had many competing definitions
(Lihtonen 1959). It could be considered from static (sustainability of forest state) or
dynamic (sustainability of forest growth and harvested yield) point of view (Speidel
1972). Forestry could be defined as sustainable if the forest land was kept in timber
production (Heyer 1841) or if the periodic harvest levels were kept at the same level
(Hartig 1795) or if the periodic incomes from the forests were kept at the same level
(Ostwald 1931), to name but a few.
To achieve sustainable forest management in those early days, one approach was
to define the optimal rotation age using forest rent approach or land rent approach
2.3 Development of Sustainable Forest Management Planning Approaches 15

Fig. 2.1 The three components of sustainability (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sustainability)

and calculate the harvest levels using principles of fully regulated forestry
(Sect. 2.3.2). Later, the sustainability was striven for using linear optimisation
and imposing constraints of non-declining or even flow of timber or incomes
(e.g. Sample 2004, Sect. 2.3.3). In recent years, the sustainable forest management
(SFM) has required that forestry is not only ecologically sound but also econom-
ically viable and socially responsible (Aplet et al. 1993). An official definition of
SFM was developed by the Ministerial Conference on the Protection of Forests in
Europe (MCPFE), defining sustainable forest management as:
The stewardship and use of forests and forest lands in a way, and at a rate, that maintains
their biodiversity, productivity, regeneration capacity, vitality and their potential to fulfill,
now and in the future, relevant ecological, economic and social functions, at local, national,
and global levels, and that does not cause damage to other ecosystems.

The definition of SFM thus requires that several different aspects need to be
covered in decision-making, thus leading to multi-criteria decision-making
(Sect. 2.3.4). It also means that concerns of many interested parties need to be
taken into account in decision-making, leading to a participatory planning approach
(Sect. 2.3.5). Under the SFM umbrella, topics such as legality and certification are
also important (http://www.fao.org/sustainable-forest-management/toolbox/mod
ules/en/). These issues are not dealt with in this book as they fall out of the main
topics of this book, but in this book, we concentrate on the possibilities to enhance
sustainability through decision support.

2.3.2 Fully Regulated Forestry

The earliest formal forest management planning methods for large areas were based
on the concept of fully regulated even-aged forests (e.g. Kilkki 1989, Davis
et al. 2001, Bettinger et al. 2009). Fully regulated forest is an ideal state of forests.
16 2 Forest Management Planning

It means that a forest area has a steady-state structure and conditions and a stable
flow of outcomes. The growth is equal to annual harvest, and harvest is the same
each year. The area harvested each year can be calculated simply by dividing the
total area A by the selected rotation time R. Thus, it ensures a sustainable yield,
which has been an important objective of forestry.
Real forests, however, do not fulfil the requirements of fully regulated forests.
Yet, in forest-related decision-making, fundamental decisions are how large an area
and how much volume to cut. Traditional methods of forest planning provide two
different types of methods: those based on area control and those based on volume
control (Recknagel 1917; Davis et al. 2001 p. 528).
Area control method is the simplest way to regulate the harvests. If a constant
area A/R is harvested each year, the forests are fully regulated after R years. On the
other hand, the harvested volume may vary a lot between years. This method
assumes a constant site quality, but it is also possible to utilise different rotation
times for different site types.
The oldest documented volume control method is the Austrian formula, first
published already in 1788 (Speidel 1972),
  
Ct I V c  V f =a 2:3

where Ct is the annual cut, I is the annual increment of forests, Vc is the current
volume of the growing stock, Vr is the volume of the desired state (i.e. fully
regulated forest) and a is the adjustment time. This means that the harvest is the
growth of the area, corrected so that the volume of fully regulated forests is
achieved after the adjustment period a. This method ensures a constant harvest
level in short term. Yet, the method does not necessarily ensure the fully regulated
condition on longer term (Davis et al. 2001 p. 545).
Later on, these methods were developed to more advanced cutting budget
methods, which enable controlling both area and volume at the same time
(e.g. Lihtonen 1959, Kuusela and Nyyssonen 1962, Davis 1966).

2.3.3 Development of Optimisation Approaches

The next phase for large area planning was the introduction of linear programming
and complex models that were developed to predict forest development under
different scenarios (e.g. Duerr et al. 1979, Clutter et al. 1983, Kilkki 1989). The
first applications of linear programming to forest planning were published in the
1960s (e.g. Curtis 1962, Kilkki 1968). In the next decades, forest planning models
based on linear programming were developed in many countries, for instance, the
FORPLAN model in the USA (Johnson 1986; Johnson et al. 1986; see also Iverson
and Alston 1986) and MELA model in Finland (Siitonen 1983, 1994). Also models
based on simulation were generated in many countries, i.e. models that were not
2.3 Development of Sustainable Forest Management Planning Approaches 17

used to find an optimal solution but more to make ifthen calculations of different
cutting scenarios. Such models were, for instance, HUGIN in Sweden (Hagglund
1981) and AVVIRK in Norway (e.g. Eid and Hobbelstad 2000). Now linear
programming is in use in most European countries (http://forestdss.org/CoP/, Bor-
ges et al. 2014).
Linear programming was used to enhance sustainable harvests through even-
flow constraints. In the USA, this principle was even stated in law: the National
Forest Management Act of 1976 declared that timber sale quantities on each forest
shall be limited to a quantity equal to or less than a quantity which can be removed
from such forest annually in perpetuity on a sustained-yield basis (McQuillan
1986). This rigid constraint was much criticised. For instance, Lenard (1981)
argued that the nation would get more both wilderness and timber if the constraints
were removed and forests were treated more efficiently. The non-declining even-
flow constraint may even lead to a declining yield in subsequent forest plans, when
applied to forests that are not fully regulated but consist mainly of old forests
(McQuillan 1986). Thus, the forest planning required more flexibility even when
sustainability was striven for.
The approaches based on LP were not regarded as sufficient with respect to
ecological considerations (e.g. Shugart and Gilbert 1987). Therefore, multi-criteria
decision analysis was needed. Besides the -constraint approach (Miettinen 1999),
multiple criteria can be accounted for if, instead of ordinary LP, goal programming
or compromise programming is used. The spatial dimensions and non-linearities
cause problems for all these LP-based formulations. For instance, the planners
might want to avoid large clear-cut areas and thus restrict the cuttings of adjacent
stands or to reduce the fragmentation in the forest area or to aggregate the harvested
stands so as to reduce harvesting or road maintenance costs. To alleviate these
problems, methods for spatial and heuristic optimisation were adopted to the
forestry calculations (e.g. Bettinger et al. 2002, Pukkala 2002).
In recent years, also stochastic optimisation has been introduced to forest
planners toolbox (e.g. Kangas et al. 2014). It will be important, for instance,
when the uncertain impacts of climate change are accounted for in planning
calculations and more profound science-based decision support is required for
forest management decisions (see Yousefpour et al. 2012 and Lindner et al. 2014).

2.3.4 Development of Multi-criteria Approaches

No optimisation method, however, can answer the question of how to value the
different criteria in planning. This is because the values are inherently subjective.
The criteria are often contradictory and need to be carefully weighted in order to
find the best solution. This is the essence of multi-criteria approaches. Early studies
on multi-criteria analysis in forest planning include those of Mendoza and Spouse
(1989) and Kangas (1992), for instance. To deal with the criteria valuation
18 2 Forest Management Planning

problems, multi-criteria decision methods have been adopted in forestry decision-


making (Pukkala 2002; Kangas and Kangas 2005).
Today, multiple criteria decision aid receives continuously more popularity both
in research and in practice. For instance, in their review, Diaz-Balteiro and Romero
(2008) found over 200 published applications of multi-criteria analysis in forestry,
including both optimisation approaches such as goal programming and methods
suitable for discrete cases such as the multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT) and
analytic hierarchy process (AHP). The applications included harvest scheduling,
biodiversity and sustainability as well as forest industry-related topics.
The multi-criteria approach has also been a popular means to enhance sustain-
ability through criteria and indicators approach (see Myllyviita et al. 2011). It
means that the sustainability is defined using principles of the multi-criteria
approach so that it is possible to measure the sustainability of forestry in different
areas (e.g. Prabhu et al. 1999).

2.3.5 Need for Participatory Planning

Participatory planning approach has also gained attention in forestry decision-


making in recent years. In many cases, the managers are required to engage the
stakeholders in the decision-making. In USDA Forest Service, for instance, a forest
plan where public participation was used, in the form of meetings, workshops,
tours, periodic newsletters, media releases and a series of planning booklets, was
already produced in 1987 (Ginger 2014). It can also be seen as an essential part of
sustainable forest management, and in certain urban forests, participatory approach
is a routine continuous operation before forest management takes place.
It is typical that, if a planning problem includes multiple criteria, it often also
includes several decision-makers or stakeholders (Mendoza and Martins 2006).
One early example of participatory planning using multi-criteria decision aid was
published by Kangas (1994). It is also typical that the planning cases including
stakeholders are more or less messy, i.e. the stakeholders may have an entirely
different view of what kind of actions are desirable than the managers. Thus, a
proper problem structuring phase to sort out this kind of problems is recommended
in the planning process, rather than making the stakeholders to select the best of
predefined alternatives using predefined criteria (Mendoza and Martins 2006). For
example, in the planning of Finnish state-owned forests, the stakeholders take part
in formulating the alternatives and also in formulating the decision criteria
(Hiltunen et al. 2008).
LP-based systems are typically used to predict the consequences of the different
actions. The problem in this approach may be that the system simply is not able to
include all relevant values of stakeholders (Ginger 2014). It may also be seen as a
black box by the participants, and they do not understand how the results have been
achieved.
References 19

There are also many examples of community forests and urban areas where
public participation is an essential part of the process. In such cases, it is especially
important that the stakeholders understand the methods that are used to inquire their
wishes as they are ordinary people rather than method experts or forestry pro-
fessionals. The methods used in participatory planning to capture stakeholders
place specific wishes in urban forests include, for instance, participatory GIS
(De Meo et al. 2013; Ginger 2014). It may be easier to define important areas
with certain properties and what areas could be devoted to a given activity, rather
than give abstract preferences.
However, even if the methods may be difficult to understand for ordinary people,
LP and MCDM methods have an important role in forest decision-making. They
just need to be used in a way that all relevant values of stakeholders can be included
in the analyses in a comprehensible and transparent way.

References

Adams, W. M. (2006). The future of sustainability: Re-thinking environment and development in


the twenty-first century. Report of the IUCN Renowned Thinkers Meeting, 2931 January
2006.
Alvarez, L. H. R., & Koskela, E. (2007). The forest rotation problem with stochastic harvest and
amenity value. Natural Resource Modeling, 20, 477509.
Aplet, G., Johnson, N., Olson, J., & Sample, V. A. (1993). Defining sustainable forestry.
Washington, DC: Island Press. 328 p. ISBN 1-55963-234-8.
Bettinger, P., Graetz, D., Boston, K., Sessions, J., & Chung, W. (2002). Eight heuristic planning
techniques applied to three increasingly difficult wildlife planning problems. Silva Fennica, 36,
561584.
Bettinger, P., Boston, K., Siry, J., & Grebner, D. L. (2009). Forest management and planning.
London: Academic. 360 p.
Borges, J. G., Nordstrom, E.-M., Garcia-Gonzalo, J., Hujala, T., & Trasobares, A. (Eds.). (2014).
Computer-based tools for supporting forest management. The experience and the expertise
world-wide. Umea: Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences. 499 p. ISBN 978-91-576-
9236-8.
Buongiorno, J., & Gilles, J. K. (2003). Decision methods for forest resource management. Boston:
Academic. 439 p.
Clutter, J. L., Fortson, J. C., Pienaar, L. V., Brister, G. H., & Bailey, R. L. (1983). Timber
management: A quantitative approach. New York: Wiley. 333 p.
Curtis, F. H. (1962). Linear programming of the management of a forest property. Journal of
Forestry, 60, 611616.
Davis, K. P. (1966). Forest management: Regulation and valuation (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw
Hill. 519 p.
Davis, L.-S., Johnson, K. N., Bettinger, P. S., & Howard, T. E. (2001). Forest management To
sustain ecological, economic and social values (4th ed.). Boston: McGraw Hill. 804 p.
De Meo, I., Ferretti, F., Frattegiani, M., Lora, C., & Paletto, A. (2013). Public participation GIS to
support a bottom-up approach in forest landscape planning. iForest, 6, 347352.
Diaz-Balteiro, L., & Romero, C. (2008). Making forestry decisions with multiple criteria: A
review and an assessment. Forest Ecology and Management, 255, 32223241.
Duerr, W. A., Teeguarden, D. E., Christiansen, N. B., & Guttenberg, S. (1979). Forest resource
management. Philadelphia, PA: W.B. Saunders Company. 612 p.
20 2 Forest Management Planning

Eid, T., & Hobbelstad, K. (2000). AVVIRK-2000 A large-scale forestry scenario model for long-
term investment, income and harvest analyses. Scandinadian Journal of Forest Research, 15,
472482.
Faustmann, M. (1849). Berechnung des Wertes welchen Waldboden, sowie noch nicht haubare
Holzbestande fur die Waldwirtschaft besitzen. Allgemeine Forst- und jagdzeitung, 25,
441455.
Ginger, C. (2014). Integrating knowledge, interests and values through modelling in participatory
processes: Dimensions of legitimacy. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management,
57, 643659.
Gregory, G. R. (1972). Resource economics for foresters. New York: Wiley. 477 p.
Hagglund, B. (1981). Forecasting growth and yield in established forests An outline and analysis
of the outcome of a subproject within the HUGIN project (Rep 31). Department of Forest
Survey, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences. Umea.
Hamberger, J. (Hrsg.). (2013). Hans Carl von Carlowitz. Sylvicultura oeconomica oder
Hauwirthliche Nachricht und Naturm aige Anweisung zur Wilden Baum-Zucht. Munchen:
Oekom, 640 p. ISBN-13: 978-3-86581-411-1
Hartig, G. L. (1795). Anweisun zur Taxation der Forste, oder zu Bestimmung des Holzertrags der
W alder. Gieen: Heyer.
Hartman, R. (1976). The harvesting decision when a standing forest has value. Economic Inquiry,
14(52), 58.
Heyer, C. (1841). Die Waldertrags-Regelung. Gieen: Verlag von B. C. Ferber.
Hiltunen, V., Kangas, J., & Pykalainen, J. (2008). Voting methods in strategic forest planning
Experiences from Metsahallitus. Forest Policy and Economics, 10, 117127.
Iverson, D. C., & Alston, R. M. (1986). The genesis of FORPLAN: A historical and analytical
review of Forest Service planning models (Gen. tech. rep. INT-214). Ogden: USDA Forest
Service, Intermountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 37 p.
Johansson, P.-O., & L ofgren, K.-G. (1985). The economics of forestry and natural resources.
Oxford: Basil Blackwell. 292 p.
Johnson, K. N. (1986). FORPLAN version 1: An overview. Washington, DC: USDA Forest
Service, Land Management Planning Section. 85 p.
Johnson, K. N., Stuart, T. W., & Crim, S. A. (1986). FORPLAN version 2: An overview.
Washington, DC: USDA Forest Service, Land Management Planning Section. 110 p.
Kangas, J. (1992). Metsikon uudistamisketjun valinta monitavoitteiseen hyotyteoriaan perustuva
paat
osanalyysimalli. Summary: Choosing the regeneration chain in a forest stand, A decision-
model based on multi-attribute utility theory (Joensuun yliopiston luonnontieteellisia
julkaisuja, Vol. 24). Joensuu: University of Joensuu. 230 p.
Kangas, J. (1994). An approach to public participation in strategic forest management planning.
Forest Ecology and Management, 70, 7588.
Kangas, J., & Kangas, A. (2005). Multiple criteria decision support in forest management
Fundamentals of the approach, methods applied, and experiences gained. Forest Ecology
and Management, 207, 133143.
Kangas, A., Hartikainen, M., & Miettinen, K. (2014). Simultaneous optimization of harvest
schedule and measurement strategy. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29, 224233.
Kilkki, P. (1968). Tulotavoitteeseen perustuva hakkuulaskelma. Acta Forestalia Fennica, 91, 54 p.
Kilkki, P. (1989). Timber management planning (Silva Carelica, Vol. 5, pp. 1160). Joensuun
yliopisto. Metsatieteellinen tiedekunta: Joensuu.
Kuusela, K., & Nyyssonen, A. (1962). Tavoitehakkuulaskelma. Acta Forestalia Fennica, 74. 34 p.
Lenard, T. M. (1981). Wasting our national forests. How to get less timber and less wilderness at
the same time. AEI Journal of Government and Society. Regulation, July/August, 2938.
Lihtonen, V. (1959). Mets atalouden suunnittelu ja j
arjestely. Porvoo: WSOY. 355 p.
Lindner, M., Fitzgerald, J. B., Zimmermann, N. E., Reyer, C., Delzon, S., van der Maaten, E.,
Schelhaas, M.-J., Lasch, P., Eggers, J., van der Maaten-Theunissen, M., Suckow, F., Psomas,
A., Poulter, B., & Hanewinkel, M. (2014). Climate change and European forests: What do we
know, what are the uncertainties, and what are the implications for forest management?
Journal of Environmental Management, 146, 6983.
References 21

McQuillan, A. G. (1986). The declining even flow effect Non sequitur of National Forest
Planning. Forest Science, 32, 960972.
Mendoza, G. A., & Martins, H. (2006). Multi-criteria decision analysis in natural resource
management: A critical review of methods and new modelling paradigms. Forest Ecology
and Management, 230, 122.
Mendoza, G. A., & Spouse, W. (1989). Forest planning and decision making under fuzzy
environments: An overview and illustration. Forest Science, 35, 481502.
Miettinen, K. (1999). Nonlinear multiobjective optimization. Boston: Kluwer Academic.
Myllyviita, T., Hujala, T., Kangas, A., & Leskinen, P. (2011). Decision support in assessing the
sustainable use of forests and other natural resources A comparative review. The Open Forest
Science Journal, 4(1), 2441.
Myllyviita, T., Lahtinen, K., Hujala, T., Leskinen, L. A., Sikanen, L., & Leskinen, P. (2014).
Identifying and rating cultural sustainability indicators: A case study of wood-based bioenergy
systems in eastern Finland. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 16(2), 287304.
Ostwald, E. (1931). Grundlinien einer Waldrententheorie, d.h. einer in Anhalt an das relative
Waldrenten-Maximum entwickelten forstlichen Reinertragstheorie. Riga: W.F. Hacker.
Prabhu, R., Colfer, C. J. P., & Dudley, R. G. (1999). Guidelines for developing, testing and
selecting criteria and indicators for sustainable forest management. A C&I developers
reference. Jakarta: CIFOR. 183 p.
Pukkala, T. (Ed.). (2002). Multi-objective forest planning (Managing forest ecosystems, Vol. 6).
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. 207 p.
Pukkala, T., & Miina, J. (1997). A method for stochastic multiobjective optimization of stand
management. Forest Ecology and Management, 98, 189203.
Rantala, M., Hujala, T., & Kurttila, M. (2012). Measuring and monitoring socio-cultural sustain-
ability in the action of forest biodiversity cooperation networks. Silva Fennica, 46(3), 441459.
Recknagel, A. B. (1917). Theory and practise of working plans (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley.
Sample, V. A. (2004). Sustainability in forestry: Origins, evolution and prospects. Discussion
paper 604. Pinchot Institute for Conservation. 43 p. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/
download?doi10.1.1.182.1386&reprep1&typepdf
Shugart, H. H., & Gilbert, B. J. (1987). An ecological evaluation of FORPLAN in national forest
planning. In T. W. Hoekstra, A. A. Dyer, & D. C. LeMaster (Eds.), FORPLAN: An evaluation
of a forest planning tool (Gen tech. rep. RM-140, pp. 105121). Fort Collins: USDA Forest
Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station.
Siitonen, M. (1983). A long-term forestry planning system based on data from the Finnish national
forest inventory. Proceedings of the IUFRO subject group 4.02 meeting in Finland. University
of Helsinki, Department of Forest Mensuration and Management (Research notes 17, pp.
195207), 59 September 1983.
Siitonen, M. (1994). The MELA system as a forestry modelling framework. Lestnictvi-Forestry,
41, 173178.
Speidel, G. (1972). Planung im Forstbetrieb. Hamburg: Verlag Paul Parey. 267 p.
United Nations General Assembly. (1987). Report of the World Commission on Environment and
Development: Our Common Future. Transmitted to the General Assembly as an Annex to
document A/42/427 Development and International Co-operation: Environment.
United Nations General Assembly. (2005). 2005 World Summit Outcome, Resolution A/60/1,
adopted by the General Assembly on 15 Sept 2005.
Valsta, L. (1992). A scenario approach to stochastic anticipatory optimization in stand manage-
ment. Forest Science, 38, 430447.
Viitala, E.-J. (2002). Mets an optimaalinen kiertoaika: L ahestymistavat ja niiden talousteor-
eettinen perusta. Research notes of Finnish Forest Research Institute. Report 848. 128 p.
von Carlowitz H. C. (1713). Sylvicultura oeconomica, oder hauwirthliche Nachricht und
Naturm aige Anweisung zur wilden Baum-Zucht. Leipzig: Verlegts Johann Friedrich Braun.
Yousefpour, R., Jacobsen, J. B., Thorsen, B. J., Meilby, H., Hanewinkel, M., & Oehler, K. (2012).
A review of decision-making approaches to handle uncertainty and risk in adaptive forest
management under climate change. Annals of Forest Science, 69(1), 115.
Part II
Discrete Problems
Chapter 3
Single-Criterion Problems

Abstract Single-goal problems are the simplest class of decision problems. In this
chapter, utility function and value function concepts are presented for the single-
goal case, as well as the differences between these two approaches. We describe
how normalisation of forest information can also be interpreted as a value function.
We describe the concept of uncertainty and risk and the classical criteria of
decision-making under risk or uncertainty. We also describe risk attitude and its
relation to the utility function. We then describe and present comprehensible
examples on how a single-variable utility function or value function is estimated
and interpreted.

3.1 Decisions Under Risk and Uncertainty

From the viewpoint of decision theory, the decision problems including uncertainty
can be presented according to a decision table

2 1 2 : : m 3
d1 c11 c12 : : c1m
d2 6 c21 c22 : : c2m 7
6 7 3:1
: 6 : : : : : 7
6 7
: 4 : : : : : 5
dn cn1 cn2 : : cnm

The components of a decision table are the decision alternatives (di, i 1,. . .,n), the
states of nature (j, j 1,. . .,m) and the consequences (cij, i 1,. . ., n, j 1,. . .,m).
The consequence of an action is determined by the action and by a number of
external factors which are beyond the control of the decision-maker. A state of
nature is a particular set of values that these external factors might assume.
If the state of nature that will actually occur and the consequences associated
with the decision alternatives are known, a decision is made under certainty. Under
risk and uncertainty, the state of nature that would prevail is not known with
certainty. Under risk, the probability of each state of nature occurring and, corre-
spondingly, the probability distribution of consequences are known; otherwise, the
decision is made under uncertainty. The probabilities of the states of nature are

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 25


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_3
26 3 Single-Criterion Problems

rarely known, but it is often possible to estimate these probabilities. If objective


probabilities cannot be determined, subjective ones may be used, for example,
based on expertise. This being the case, risk management methods can be applied
also to support decision-making under uncertainty. Therefore, the distinction
between risk and uncertainty is not always clear. In addition to the future states
of nature, uncertainty may be related to other elements of the decision-making as
well. These sources of uncertainty are dealt with in later chapters.
Different decision-makers can take different attitudes towards risk and uncer-
tainty, which may lead to different priority orders among decision alternatives.
People can strive for good profits, although their probability is not great (risk-
seeking person), or settle with lower profits that have great probability if there is
risk of large losses (risk-averse person). Decision-maker can also be risk neutral.
Maximisation of expected utility is a risk-neutral decision strategy for
supporting risky choices (e.g. von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). Assume a
problem where there are m possible consequences of a decision di, ci1, ci2, . . ., cim
that have probabilities of realisation p1, p2, . . ., pm. Then, the expected utility from
decision di is

X
m  
Eudi p1 uci1 p2 uci2 . . . pm ucim p j u ci j : 3:2
j1

For decision support under uncertainty, several different decision strategies or


rules have been developed (see, e.g., Miller and Starr 1969; Lee and Moore 1975
and Cook and Russell 1981). For example, according to maximin or Wald criterion,
alternatives are ranked according to the worst possible consequences (risk-avoiding
behaviour), and the alternative with the best worst-case consequence is chosen.
According to maximax criterion, alternatives are ranked according to the best
possible consequences (risk-taking behaviour), and the alternative with the best
best-case consequence is chosen. Hurwicz criterion is a combination of these two
categorical rules; the alternative with the greatest weighted mean of the worst and
the best possible outcomes is chosen. Here, the weights for the worst and the best
possible outcomes reflect the attitude towards risk; e.g. for a risk-neutral decision-
maker the weights are equal.
A more general criterion, which produces the above-mentioned criteria as
special cases, has been developed by Kangas (1992, 1994). In this approach, the
decision-maker determines the importance of three priority measures in decision-
making: (i) the worst possible outcome, (ii) the expected outcome and (iii) the best
possible outcome associated with the decision alternative. The alternatives can then
be ranked based on the weighted average of these three outcomes. Then, if the
weight of the worst outcome, bw, is one, one speaks of the maximin criterion.
Correspondingly, if the weight of the best outcome, bb, is 1, an alternative is chosen
according to the maximax criterion. If the weight of the expected outcome, be, is
1, an alternative is selected from a risk-neutral decision-makers point of view.
3.2 Measuring Utility and Value 27

If bb > be > bw the decision-maker can be classified as a risk seeker. In general, if


bb is greater than bw, one can speak about risk-seeking behaviour. Correspondingly,
if bb < be < bw, or, more generally, if bb < bw, the decision-maker can be classified
as a risk avoider. The decision strategy can be changed flexibly by weighting the
coefficients using different weighting schemes. Sensitivity analysis can be made,
for example, of the meaning of the attitude towards risk in the choice of the
forest plan.

3.2 Measuring Utility and Value

3.2.1 Estimating a Utility Function

All methods for estimating utility (or value) functions are based on certain axioms.
Eilon (1982) presented three basic axioms that are needed in estimation:
Connectivity
The decision-maker is able to say from two alternative outcomes A and B, if he/she
prefers A to B, B to A or if he/she is indifferent between these outcomes.
Transitivity
If the decision-maker prefers outcome A to B and outcome B to C, then he/she also
prefers outcome A to C
Comparability
If the decision-maker has three outcomes, A, B and C, and he/she prefers A to B and
B to C, he/she can choose a coefficient x such that utility of xA (1  x) C B.
The first of these axioms may be violated, if the decision-maker cannot make
his/her mind. In practical work, it has often been noted that axioms 2 and 3 may not
hold (e.g. Eilon 1982; Knowles 1984; Bell and Farquhar 1986). Furthermore, the
last axiom only makes sense if the outcomes that are compared are quantitative,
such as money.
Estimating the utility function at single-criterion case is typically based on
indifference methods (von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986, p. 217). In practice it
means that the decision-maker needs to match two outcomes or pairs of outcomes to
meet indifference relation. In essence, it means estimating the utility function based
on the comparability axiom above.
As the utility is relative, the utility of two consequences can be arbitrarily
assigned, and the rest of the utilities are assessed relative to these (Keeney and
Raiffa 1976, p. 140). It is assumed that the most preferred consequence is defined as
c* and the least preferred as c0. The utilities provided by these consequences can be
scaled to u(c*) 1 and u(c0) 0, respectively. In the next stage, the consequence ci
is compared to a lottery, where the consequence is c* with probability and c0 with
probability (1  ), defined with (c*, , c0). The decision-maker is required to state,
which is the probability with which he/she is indifferent between the certain
28 3 Single-Criterion Problems

consequence ci and the lottery. Because of the indifference, the utility u(ci) must be
equal to the expected utility of the lottery. It follows that
   
uci u c* 1  u c0 1 1  0 : 3:3

When several such comparisons are made, the utility function can be fitted to the
expressed probabilities. This approach is called variable probability method (von
Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). The other possibility is to use a constant proba-
bility, say 0.5, and to change the consequence ci to such amount that the utility it
provides would be indifferent with the lottery. This approach is called variable
certainty equivalent method.
The well-known von NeumannMorgenstern utility function was already based
on such comparisons. In their approach, risk attitudes are dealt with implicitly; form
of the utility function is said to describe the decision-makers attitude towards risk
(von Neumann and Morgenstern 1947).

3.2.2 Risk Attitude

In many cases, the certainty equivalent ci, which gives the same utility as the
lottery, is actually larger or smaller than the expected payoff of the lottery. For
instance, the decision-maker may say that 80 is the certainty equivalent for lottery
(200, 0.5, 0). Then, the difference between the expected payoff and certainty
equivalent, 10080, is the risk premium. This is the amount a risk-avert deci-
sion-maker is willing to give up in order to avoid uncertain lottery. If the risk
premium is negative, the decision-maker is a risk seeker.
The utility function of a risk-neutral person is according to this theory linear, that
of risk avoider concave and that of risk seeker convex. This result has, however,
been criticised, since a concave utility function can also be reasoned based on an
assumption of decreasing marginal utility (e.g. Sarin 1982; Sheng 1989; Kangas
1992). The estimation of NeumannMorgenstern-type utility function is also con-
sidered to be too complicated for practical decision-making processes (Leung 1978;
Kirkwood and Sarin 1985; Butler and Loomes 1988). Therefore, risk is not
accounted for in most real applications.

Example 3.1: Certainty equivalent method


Assume a game with the best possible outcome is a gain of 10,000 and the
worst outcome a loss of 10,000 . The decision-maker is asked what amount
of money obtained for certain is indifferent (i.e. giving the same utility) as
game (10,000, 0.5, 10,000). If the DM answers 2000, the risk premium is
(02000) 2000, which means that the decision-maker is risk avoider.
The next question is, what certain outcome is indifferent to game
(10,000, 0.5, 2000) and game (2000, 0.5, 10,000). If the answers
were, for instance, 6400 and 3200, next games to be analysed are

(continued)
3.2 Measuring Utility and Value 29

Example 3.1 (continued)


(10,000, 0.5, 6400), (6400, 0.5, 2000), (2000, 0.5, 3200) and (3200,
0.5, 10,000). When the answers to these games are obtained, and u
(10,000) 0 and u(10,000) 1, utility of 2000 is calculated with u
(2000) 0.5 0 0.5 1.0 0.5. The rest of the utilities can be calculated
in the same way. Finally, the utility function can be fitted to the obtained data
(Table 3.1) and the utility of income can be drawn (Fig. 3.1). The function in
Example 3.1 is concave, which describes a risk avoider according to the the-
ory of von Neumann and Morgenstern (1947).

Table 3.1 The obtained Income Utility


utility data
10,000 0
8400 0.125
6400 0.25
4400 0.375
2000 0.5
400 0.625
3200 0.75
6000 0.875
10,000 1

Fig. 3.1 Utility function


30 3 Single-Criterion Problems

3.2.3 Estimating a Value Function

Single-criterion value functions or utility functions for no-risk situations are


formed based on comparisons between alternatives, but without lotteries. There
exist several methods for estimating a value function, of which only a few are
presented in this book.
One possibility is to utilise the natural scale with which the performance of
alternatives is measured, for instance, money, and scale it to range 01. The most
popular scaling approach is the maximum score-based approach

vi ci =maxc; 3:4

i.e. the criterion values ci are divided with the maximum value among alternatives.
The best alternative is assumed to have value of one. Rest of the alternatives are
relative to that and zero value is only given to an alternative also having zero value
in the natural scale. Then, the values follow a ratio scale. Another possibility is to
scale the natural scale values with score range procedure

vi ci  minc=maxc  minc; 3:5

The best alternative is assumed to have a value of one also in this case and the worst
the value of zero. In this case, if min(c) > 0, the alternatives do not follow a ratio
scale but an interval scale. In ratio scale, it is meaningful to compare the ratios
between values and in interval scale only the differences. In interval scale ratio
comparisons simply do not make sense: all the alternatives are infinitely better,
when compared to the worst alternative. Interval scale can be interpreted as local
scale, the length of which depends on the specific planning situation
(e.g. Kainulainen et al. 2007). If min(c) 0, these cases are equal.
The scaled scores obtained with (3.4) and (3.5) are often interpreted as value
function. Such interpretation is quite common in practical decision support tools, as
it is not necessary to ask decision-makers any questions to form this kind of value
function. Another interpretation is that the different variables and measurement
scales are just normalised to the same scale (Ishizaka and Nemery 2013).
If the scaled values are interpreted as a value function, it means that the analysis
is based on an assumption of a linear value function. The value function may,
however, be assumed to follow a certain type of non-linear function. In such a case,
the decision-maker can choose the shape from a few predefined ones
(e.g. exponential function or piecewise linear function). Then, at least one point
between the best and worst cases needs to be evaluated to be able to estimate such a
function.
A group of methods useful for estimating value function are the so-called
direct rating methods. In these methods, the decision-maker is assumed to be
able to rank the alternatives from best to worst. The best alternative and/or the
worst alternative are given some arbitrary number of points, for instance,
3.2 Measuring Utility and Value 31

100 points for the best alternative and 0 for the worst alternative. The decision-
maker is then asked to give the rest of the alternatives points, related to the best
and worst alternatives (von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986, p. 229). These points
are then scaled to 01 interval.

Example 3.2
Assume five alternatives, which all produce different amounts of incomes. It
is assumed that the natural scale is in linear relationship with the value scale.
The alternatives are scaled from natural to value scale utilising both a ratio
scale and an interval scale. The alternatives and different versions of scaling
are presented in Table 3.2. In the Fig. 3.2, the interval scale is presented with
circles and ratio scale with black dots.

Table 3.2 Scaling from Alternative Income Ratio scale Interval scale
original scale to utility scale
1 250 1 1
2 124 0.496 0.427
3 76 0.304 0.209
4 55 0.22 0.114
5 30 0.12 0

Fig. 3.2 Scaled utilities


32 3 Single-Criterion Problems

Example 3.3
The decision-maker was first asked to rank the alternatives from best (1) to
worst (5). After that, the decision-maker was asked to give points between
0 and 100 to the three middle alternatives of Example 3.2. The obtained data
is presented in Table 3.3 and the resulting value function based on direct
rating is presented in Fig. 3.3.

Table 3.3 Points given to the Alternative Income Order Points Value
alternatives
1 250 1 100 1
2 124 2 60 0.6
3 76 3 35 0.35
4 55 4 20 0.2
5 30 5 0 0

Fig. 3.3 Value function obtained from direct rating

Methods based on indifference are also used for estimating value functions, not
only utility functions. In the case of value functions, decision-makers are not asked
to select a certain amount of money equal in utility to some lottery but for selecting
an outcome or difference in outcomes that is indifferent to another outcome or
difference in outcomes. One example of the indifference methods is the difference
3.2 Measuring Utility and Value 33

standard sequence method. In this approach, first a zero level x0 is defined, i.e. the
level which is least preferred. Then, a small but meaningful improvement z1 from
this level x0 to a better level x1 x0 z1 is selected. Then, the decision-maker is
asked which improvement z2 from level x1 to level x2 x1 z2 is equally preferred
to the improvement z1 from level x0. After that, the decision-maker is asked which
improvement z3 from level x2 is equally preferred to the improvement z2 from level
x1 and so on. Thus, the decision-maker has to compare changes, the utility of which
is assumed to depend on the level achieved so far. Since all these improvements
z1. . .zn are equally preferred, they can all be given the same amount of points, say
1. Then, the points at each level can be calculated, so that v(x0) 0, v(x1) 1, v
(xn) n, and the value function can be calculated by dividing the points at each
level by n.
If the change zi is smaller than the equally preferred change zi1, the value
function is concave and shows marginally decreasing value (von Winterfeldt and
Edwards, p. 233). Thus, a concave utility function can be due to decreasing
marginal value, not just the sign of risk aversion.

Example 3.4
The situation is the same as in the above examples. In this case the zero level
x0 is set to 0, and the first improvement step z1 is 30. Then the decision-
maker evaluates that a change 0 ! 30 is equally preferred to a change
30 ! 70, and a change 30 ! 70 is equally preferred to change 70 ! 120
and so on. All the equally preferred changes are given in Table 3.4 and the
resulting values in Table 3.5, and the obtained value function is presented in
Fig. 3.4.

Table 3.4 Indifferent i xi xi1 zi1 Points


changes
0 0 30 30 1
1 30 70 40 1
2 70 120 50 1
3 120 180 60 1
4 180 250 70 1

Table 3.5 Resulting values Income Points Value


0 0 0
30 1 0.20
70 2 0.40
120 3 0.60
180 4 0.80
250 5 1.00

(continued)
34 3 Single-Criterion Problems

Example 3.4 (continued)

Fig. 3.4 Utility function resulting from indifferent changes

References

Bell, D. E., & Farquhar, P. H. (1986). Perspectives on utility theory. Operations Research, 34,
179183.
Butler, D., & Loomes, G. (1988). Decision difficulty and imprecise preferences. Acta
Psychologica, 68, 183196.
Cook, T. M., & Russell, R. A. (1981). Introduction to management science. Upper Saddle River:
Englewood Cliffs, Prentice-Hall. 763 p.
Eilon, S. (1982). Control and utility. Omega, 10, 223231.
Ishizaka, A., & Nemery, P. (2013). Multi-criteria decision analysis. Methods and software.
Chichester: Wiley. 296 p.
Kainulainen, T., Leskinen, P., Korhonen, P. and Haara, A. 2007. A statistical approach to assess
interval scale preferences in discrete choice problems. Manuscript
Kangas, J. (1992). Summary: Choosing the regeneration chain in a forest stand: A decision model
based on multi-attribute utility theory. Joensuu: University of. Metsik on uudistamisketjun
valinta monitavoitteiseen hyotyteoriaan perustuva paat
osanalyysimalli.
Kangas, J. (1994). Incorporating risk attitude into comparison of reforestation alternatives. Scan-
dinavian Journal of Forest Research, 9, 297304.
Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and value
tradeoffs. New York: Wiley. 569 p.
References 35

Kirkwood, C. G., & Sarin, R. K. (1985). Ranking with partial information: A method and an
application. Operations Research, 33, 3848.
Knowles, G. J. (1984). Some econometric problems in the measurement of utility. American
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66, 505510.
Lee, S. M., & Moore, L. J. (1975). Introduction to decision science. New York: Petrocelli/Charter.
589 p.
Leung, P. (1978). Sensitivity analysis of the effect of variations in the form and parameters of a
multiattribute utility model: a survey. Behavioral Science, 23, 478485.
Miller, D. W., & Starr, M. K. (1969). Executive decisions and operations research. Englewood
Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. 607 p.
Sarin, R. K. (1982). Strength of preference and risky choice. Operations Research, 30, 982997.
Sheng, C. L. (1989). Some quantitative concepts of value and utility from a utilitarian point of
view. Theory and Decision, 26, 175195.
von Neumann, J., & Morgestern, O. (1947). Theory of games and economic behaviour. New York:
Wiley. 641 p.
von Winterfeldt, D., & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision analysis and behavioral research. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chapter 4
Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Abstract The essential part of multi-criteria decision analysis is structuring a


value tree (or a decision hierarchy). Important in this phase is to find the relevant
set of criteria and their potential sub-criteria. In this chapter, a definition for such a
good set of criteria is provided. It is also important to design good decision
alternatives. Therefore, hints on how to produce these alternatives are given.
Another important aspect in multi-criteria analyses is the trade-offs between the
criteria. These trade-offs can be inferred from the choices the decision-maker
makes, either from actual or stated choices. We present different multi-attribute
utility models and the interpretations of trade-offs these approaches imply. We
present different approaches such as MAUT-related methods and the analytic
hierarchy process (AHP)-related methods for estimating the trade-offs
(or parameters of the utility functions) from stated choices. We present how the
methods are applied for selecting the best alternative or ranking the alternatives in
multi-criteria problems. We discuss the differences between the approaches and
between the interpretations of the results.

4.1 Decision Model

4.1.1 Objectives and Decision Criteria

A crucial task in any multi-criteria decision analysis situation is to define the


objectives of the decision-making situation. The objectives are statements about
the desired state of a system (Malczewski 1999). The objectives should answer the
question of what the decision-maker wishes to achieve by the decision (Keeney
1992). Then a distinct set of decision attributes needs to be selected, which allows
the decision-maker to measure how well the objectives are met in each of the
alternatives. In a forest management context, such an objective may be the sustain-
able use of forests, and the attributes should then be measures that tell us how well
each of the decision alternatives performs with respect to sustainability. As sus-
tainability is a complex objective, it will require several measures or attributes to
describe the achievement.
In most cases the decision problem can be modelled using a so-called value tree.
The value tree indicates an overall goal that is measured by several objectives, and

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 37


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_4
38 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Overall goal

Decision Decision Decision


objective 1 objective 2 ... objective n

Decision ... Decision Decision ... Decision


attribute 1 attribute n attribute 1 attribute n

Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Alternative 3 ... Alternative n

Fig. 4.1 The decision hierarchy

each of them can have two or more lower-level objectives that define the higher-
level objective (Keeney 1992). The lower-level objectives are mutually exclusive
and provide an exhaustive description of the higher-level objective. The lowest
level of objectives is formed of the attributes. Often (but not always) the value tree
also includes the alternatives as the lowest level. The objectives, attributes and
alternatives can be formulated to a decision hierarchy (Fig. 4.1).
This terminology comes from the multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT), where
the utility (the overall objective) of the decision-maker is considered to consist of
several attributes (Keeney 1992). In many cases also the term multi-attribute value
theory (MAVT), is used. The difference between MAUT and MAVT is that the
value functions with respect to each criterion do not include the risk preferences of
the decision-maker but the utility function may do. Von Winterfeldt and Edwards
(1986, p. 215) think this difference is spurious, however. Utility function can be
interpreted as a broader class: a utility function is also a value function, while value
function is not necessarily a utility function.
In recent years, the term criteria has often been used instead of objectives and
attributes (e.g. Belton and Stewart 2002; Ishizaka and Nemery 2013). Malczewski
(1999, p. 85) defines multi-criteria decision-making as a broader class, which
includes both multi-attribute decision-making for discrete decision problems and
multi-objective decision-making for continuous problems. Multi-criteria analysis
can be seen as a broader class also in a discrete context, as many of the decision
support methods are not based on utility theory. For instance, in the analytic
hierarchy process (AHP) method (Saaty 2013, see Sect. 4.3), the term criteria is
used instead of attributes and overall goal instead of overall objectives, although it
also uses a form of a decision hierarchy. In this book, the term criterion is used for
higher-level objectives and sub-criterion for lower-level objectives. Attributes are
4.1 Decision Model 39

only used in the context of multi-attribute utility theory. The decision criteria are
denoted with cj, j 1,. . ., m where cij represents the performance of alternative
i with respect to criterion j.

4.1.2 Selecting the Set of Criteria

The criteria selected to the decision model are meant to measure the achievement of
the overall objectives. To be able to do that, the set of criteria (or attributes) need to
fulfil several properties. Keeney (1992) lists nine such properties. The set of criteria
needs to be essential, meaning that alternatives vary with respect to the criteria, so
that the choice of an alternative influences to the degree to which the objectives are
achieved. The set of criteria needs to be controllable, so that the available decision
alternatives have influence on the consequences measured with the criteria. For
instance, in a forest planning context the decision alternatives are typically different
harvest levels. In that case, criteria that cannot be influenced by harvest levels are
not controllable.
In addition, the set of criteria need to be complete, meaning that the decision
criteria need to cover all relevant aspects of the decision situation. They need to be
measurable, meaning that they define the objectives of the decision-maker pre-
cisely and specify the degree to which these objectives are achieved. It means that it
is possible for the DM to see the differences in the consequences of the alternatives
and give his/her preferences concerning these differences. The set of criteria need to
be operational, meaning that it is possible to obtain the required information on the
set of criteria with reasonable time and resources. In a forestry context, using
genetic-level diversity is not an operational criterion to describe biodiversity, and
neither is the species diversity. If all species are considered, they are simply too
difficult to measure in a real-life case. Instead, the tree species diversity may be an
operational criterion for describing biodiversity.
Furthermore, the set of criteria need to be decomposable, meaning that the
consequences relating to each criterion can be addressed independently of the
consequences related to other criteria. However, also the possible interrelationships
between criteria may be modelled, but it often makes the decision model compli-
cated and hard to understand. The set of criteria should be nonredundant, so that no
consequences are double counted, and concise, meaning that the number of criteria
needed for the analysis should be as small as possible. Finally, the set of criteria
should be understandable, the criteria need to be such that the decision-makers can
all interpret them in the same way.
In some cases there is a natural scale with which the level of criteria can be
measured, like euros, cubic metres, tons or hectares. For instance, the carbon
sequestration can be measured with the forested area or the growing stock proper-
ties. Such criteria can be called natural (Keeney 1992). Natural measurement scale
does not mean, however, that measuring the achievements is completely unambig-
uous. For instance, if the forested area is used to measure carbon sequestration, that
40 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

criterion fails to acknowledge the differences in stored carbon between different


types of forest or different age classes of forest. In that respect, biomass would be a
much better criterion, but unfortunately using that criterion is not always possible
because of the amount of information needed.
In some cases, natural criteria with natural scale do not exist. Then, it is often
possible to use so-called constructed criteria instead (Keeney 1992). For instance,
scenic beauty and recreational value of a forest area are examples of criteria that
could be measured using constructed scales. For instance, in Finland, these criteria
have been evaluated using school grades from 4 (fail) to 10 (excellent) (e.g. Pukkala
et al. 1988). Typically such constructed scales are designed for each specific
decision problem separately. However, in some cases it may be possible to model
the responses from a previously constructed scale assessment using natural criteria
as explanatory variables, for instance, modelling the assessed scenic beauty of a
stand with respect to the tree species, stand age, stand basal area and so on. In that
case, the constructed scale can be interpreted as an expert opinion of the criterion or
as a persons subjective view (e.g. Kangas et al. 1993a, b).
In some cases it is not possible to have either natural or constructed criterion for
a given objective. For instance, biodiversity or sustainability may be so complicated
a criterion that forming a measurement scale is very difficult. In such a case, a proxy
criterion may be used (Keeney 1992). Proxy criteria are assumed to indirectly
measure the level of achievement. For instance, concerning biodiversity, if it is
assumed that old-growth forest has higher biodiversity than commercial forests,
then the area of old-growth forests can be used as a proxy for biodiversity
(e.g. Kangas and Pukkala 1996; Karkkainen et al. 2014).

Example 4.1: Measuring Sustainability


Sustainability can be seen as an overall objective, and it can be measured
using suitable criteria. Prabhu et al. (1999) presented guidelines for formu-
lating a framework for sustainability (Fig. 4.2). The uppermost element,
principle, can be interpreted as the overall objective. Prabhu et al. (1999)
give as an example of a principle, for instance, that human well-being is
assured or that ecosystem integrity is maintained or enhanced. The overall
objective is defined with a set of criteria, but the criteria are not yet measures
of performance. As an example of a criterion for the latter principle, they give
processes that sustain or enhance genetic variation are perpetuated. The
indicator can be interpreted as a lower-level criterion. For the criterion above,
they presented as one indicator directional change in allele or genotype
frequencies. The lowest level in this hierarchy is the verifier, which is
supposed to be measurable in the field. An example of a verifier for the
indicator above is number of alleles in the population. However, even if
this verifier is in principle measurable, measuring it will be very costly.

(continued)
4.1 Decision Model 41

Example 4.1 (continued)

Fig. 4.2 Criteria and indicator approach for sustainability (Adopted from Prabhu
et al. 1999)

If the verifiers, indicators and criteria are given weights, it is possible to


assess if a given plan performs better with respect to sustainability than another.
The verifier can also have a threshold value, which makes it possible to give a
yesno answer to a question of a management plan being sustainable.

4.1.3 Designing Alternatives

In all decision situations, there are more than just one possible choice or alternative,
denoted as di, i 1,. . ., n. The alternatives are not self-evident however and need to
be carefully designed for each decision problem. According to Keeney (1992), the
alternatives can be either in the mind waiting to be found or can be constructed from
what is in the mind. Formulating the decision alternatives should be creative, and
most of all, it should be based on the objectives the decision-maker has. If the
42 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

decision alternatives are formulated before the objectives are specified, none of
them may actually be very good for the decision-maker.
Keeney (1992) proposes that alternatives for one decision-maker are created first
by thinking an alternative that is desirable with respect to first of the criteria and
then do the same with other criteria. After that the decision-maker should consider
alternatives that could be desirable with respect to a pair of criteria and go through
all pairs. The process is continued until finally the DM tries to formulate an
alternative that is desirable considering all the alternatives. Then the DM should
think if the generated alternatives could be combined to one. For instance, if
promoting reindeer herding requires specific types of harvests on one specific
area, and promoting tourism requires specific types of harvest in another area, the
alternatives promoting these aspects could be combined to one alternative. In a case
of several decision-makers or stakeholders, each of them may have their own
objectives, but the above-mentioned process can still be used.
Ideally the alternatives created are located on the efficient frontier, i.e. on the
Pareto front. In forestry, such alternatives can be formulated by maximising one
criterion value (e.g. incomes) with varying levels of constraints on the other criteria
(e.g. amount of protected area) using the -constraint method in LP (Miettinen
1999) (see Sect. 6.2.3 later in this book).
After designing the alternatives, their performance with respect to all of the
criteria needs to be assessed. In forest management planning this may be prob-
lematic because of the long planning horizons. Timber production-related
criteria can usually be predicted using growth and yield models. Other criteria
may be more challenging. Even if we were able to measure as a criterion for
biodiversity number of species in the forest area, we would also need to know the
effect of different alternative plans on it after, say, 100 years. This is a very
common reason why proxy criteria (related to timber production) or expert
judgement models as constructed criteria may be the only practical criterion
for a given objective.

4.1.4 Indifference, Preference and Trade-Off

The basis for decision-making is that given two objects, say A and B, people can
meaningfully say whether they prefer A to B or B to A or whether they are
indifferent (von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). Usually, it is assumed that people
can also state the strength of this preference. The strength could be expressed either
in ordinal terms or in cardinal terms. If the decision-maker can say that change from
A to B is preferable to change from B to C, then the judgement is ordinal. If the
decision-maker can say by how much, the judgement is cardinal.
It is simply not possible to independently maximise or minimise several criteria
at the same time: you cannot maximise the gross incomes while at the same time
4.1 Decision Model 43

minimising the costs or maximise the yield and minimise the risks (Keeney and
Raiffa 1976, p. 66).
Therefore, the big issue in multi-criteria decision-making is that of trade-offs:
how much is the decision-maker willing to give up in one criterion, in order to
improve the performance with respect to another criterion by some fixed amount.
For instance, the decision-maker needs to decide, how much more risk of beetle
outbreak he/she will tolerate in order to improve net incomes by 100, or how much
incomes is he/she willing to give up in order to reduce the risk by 10 %.
The trade-off decisions are about personal values, and thus, they require subjec-
tive judgement of the decision-maker. This means that there are no correct or wrong
answers to the value questions; people may have very different preference struc-
tures. The trade-off problem can be solved in two ways: (1) the decision-maker can
informally weight the trade-offs in his/her mind or (2) the decision-maker can
formalise his/her preferences to a multi-criteria utility function and use it to solve
the problem (Keeney and Raiffa 1976). Either way, the trade-offs are inevitable in
any multi-criteria decision.
Hwang and Masud (1979) and Miettinen (1999) suggest grouping the MCDM
methods in four classes dependent upon the role the DMs preferences play in the
solution process. The no-preference methods must be used if there is no preference
information available. A priori methods are used when the DM can give his/her
preferences which are then used to calculate the solution. A posteriori methods
require the DM to compare and select between a set of the Pareto optimal solutions.
The DM does not directly provide preference values, but rather the method used
extracts the preferences between alternatives from the choices made. Interactive
methods require the DM to actively participate in the decision-making process.
Interactive methods have been more often used in connection to the continuous
problems than to discrete problems (e.g. Zionts and Wallenius 1976, 1983).

4.1.5 Dominance

There are a few choice procedures that do not require a decision model in order to
make choices. One of these is dominance. We can say that alternative i dominates
alternative i0 , if

ci j  ci0 j , 8 j 1, . . . , m
ci j > ci0 j , for some j 1, . . . , m

It means that alternative i is at least as good as alternative i0 for all criteria j, and, in
addition, alternative i is strictly better than alternative i0 with respect to some
criterion j. If an alternative is dominated by some other alternatives, it can be left
out from the analysis: it can never be chosen as a best alternative, whatever the
44 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Fig. 4.3 Dominated alternatives are presented with black dots and non-dominated with circles.
The non-dominated alternatives form the efficient frontier of the problem

preference structure. If there is one alternative among the n alternatives that


dominates all other alternatives, the choice would then be easy. However, such is
the case only rarely. It may, however, be that some of the alternatives can be
eliminated before further analysis.
What is important in the non-dominated alternatives is that they form the
efficient frontier or the Pareto optimal set among the alternatives (Fig. 4.3).
One possible way of choosing among a set of alternatives, without considering
the trade-offs, is to utilise a lexicographic ordering (Keeney and Raiffa 1976). In
this method, the decision-maker first ranks the criteria with respect to their impor-
tance. Then, the most important criterion is c1 and the least important criterion is cm.
Then, alternative i is preferred to alternative i0 , denoted by i  i0 , if and only if

a ci1 > ci0 1 or


b ci j ci0 j , j 1, . . . , k and
cik1 > ci0 k1 , for some k 1, . . . , m  1

It means that the choice is made only based on the most important criterion. If there
are several alternatives that are equal with respect to that criterion, then the second
most important criterion is considered and so on.
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 45

4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions

4.2.1 Function Forms

In a case of multi-attribute utility function, it is assumed that there are m criteria,


and a sub-utility (or value) function is evaluated or can be evaluated for each of
these criteria. The task is now to aggregate these sub-utility functions to describe
the overall utility of the alternatives. This aggregation is done by weighting the
different criteria in the utility function with respect to their importances. The
relations between the weights of different criteria describe the trade-offs between
the criteria. If the scores with respect to the criteria are normalised to interval 0-1
rather than forming a utility function, the method is often referred to as a simple
weighting approach (Ishizaka and Nemery 2013).
The most applied multi-attribute utility function is the linear additive utility function

X
m
Ui a j c ji 4:1
j1

where Ui describes the overall utility of alternative i (or priority of alternative i) and
cij is the performance of the alternative i with respect to criterion j and aj is the
importance weight of criterion j. In this equation, it is assumed that the criteria
values cij are already in utility scale or are scaled to a utility scale with formula (3.4)
or (3.5), for instance.
Typically, it is required that

X
m
a j 1; 4:2
j1

Otherwise, the utility could always be increased by increasing the weights. The
trade-offs between criterion k and k0 can be calculated from the ratio of the weights
ak/ak0 . In general, the marginal rate of substitution between criteria k and k0 can be
calculated as a ratio of partial derivatives of the utility function as

U 0k ak
4:3
U 0k0 ak0

This means that the decision-maker is willing to give up units of criterion k0 in


order to increase the value of criterion k by one.
46 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.2
Assume a utility function with Uk 0.67c1k 0.33c2k, where c1 denotes units
of income and c2 the number of animals in some wildlife species. Then, the
decision-maker is willing to give up one animal in order to increase the
incomes with 0.67/0.33 2 units of money.

In the linear additive utility function, the trade-off between the criteria is constant.
It means that the willingness of the decision-maker to change one unit of criterion k0
to units of criterion k does not change, even if there is only a few units left of
criterion k0 or even if there is already plenty of criterion k. If a decreasing marginal
utility is assumed, this does not hold. In this case, a more general function, namely,
the additive utility function, needs to be used. It is of the form

X
m  
Ui a j u j ci j 4:4
j1

where uj(cij) is the sub-utility due to criterion j. It is described with the sub-utility
function for this criterion. In this function, the marginal rate of substitution is a
function of the current values of criteria j.
The additive utility models are compensatory at nature. In this respect, this utility
function differs from other forms of utility functions. It means that even if some criteria
assume their lowest possible levels, this can be compensated if some other criterion or
criteria assume very good values. The compensation is dictated by the marginal rate of
substitution. This approach also demands more information from the decision-maker
than the simple weighting approach, as the form of the utility function needs to be
defined by the decision-maker, and it may have a large effect of the results.

Example 4.3
Lets consider six non-dominant alternatives from Fig. 4.3. The overall utility
function is assumed to be

U i a1  0:00506  ci1 a2  1:55251  exp60:2556=ci2

and the resulting utilities are presented in Table 4.1. The weights of these two
criteria are assumed to be equal, i.e. 0.5, and the greatest overall utility is
observed for alternative 2, with 164 units of incomes and 80 animals. If the
number of animals was 1, this could be fully compensated with 309 units of
incomes, i.e. such an alternative would get the largest overall utility, 0.782.
On the other hand, if the incomes were 10 units, this could be compensated
with 2100 animals, giving overall utility 0.780. The marginal utility of
additional animals is very small, when the number of animals is high.

(continued)
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 47

Example 4.3 (continued)

Table 4.1 Overall utilities of Alternative Income Animals Overall utility


the alternatives
1 197 18 0.526
2 164 80 0.780
5 30 137 0.576
8 186 34 0.603
9 182 38 0.619
10 93 121 0.707

Table 4.2 Ratio of partial Animals Income Animals


derivatives
30 0.00253 0.00697 0.3628
80 0.00253 0.00344 0.7352
130 0.00253 0.00174 1.4531
180 0.00253 0.00103 2.4493
230 0.00253 0.00068 3.7184
280 0.00253 0.00048 5.2589
330 0.00253 0.00036 7.0704
380 0.00253 0.00028 9.1527
430 0.00253 0.00022 11.5057
480 0.00253 0.00018 14.1293
530 0.00253 0.00015 17.0234

The partial derivatives of these functions are a1  0.00506 with respect to


criterion c1, incomes, and a2  1. 55251  exp(60.2556/ci2)  (60.2556/ci22)
with respect to criterion c2, number of wildlife animals. Thus, the marginal
rate of substitution does not depend on incomes, but it depends on the number
of animals. When the number of wildlife animals varies from 30 to 530, the
marginal rate of substitution varies from 0.36 to 17.02 animals: the more
animals there are, the more the decision-maker is willing to give up for
additional units of incomes. The partial derivatives and the resulting are
presented in the Table 4.2.

In addition to these two utility functions, there exist a number of different


functions. One example is the multiplicative model (von Winterfeldt and Edwards
1986, p. 291)

Y
m   
1 aU i 1 a a j u j ci j 4:5
j1

which can also be presented in a form of an additive utility function with interaction
terms
48 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

X
m   m X
X m  
Ui a j u j ci j a ai a j ui ci j uk cik . . .
j1 j1 k> j

Y
m  
am1 a j u j ci j : 4:6
j1

In this function, the interaction between the sub-utility of different criteria is


presented using products of each pair of alternatives, products of each group of
three criteria and finally the product of all criteria. The interactions are dealt with
using one parameter, a, with a power of p1, where p is the number of terms in the
product. It means that for two-term interactions p 1 and for m-term interactions
p m1. This parameter must lie between 1 and 1. As the value of a increases,
the amount of interaction increases, for a 0, this formula simplifies to additive
utility function. In a two-dimensional case a can be calculated from (von
Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986)

1  a1  a2
a 4:7
a1 a2

It means that if a1 a2 1, a is 0, and if a1 a2 0, a is infinite.


Using this function, the degree of compensation cannot be calculated as neatly as
with the previous additive models. Furthermore, also the interpretation of the model
is more complicated, as the level of any one criterion affects to the utility obtained
from a fixed level of another criterion.

Example 4.4
Assume the criteria in Example 4.3 to have an interaction, i.e. the level of
incomes affects to the utility obtained from wildlife animals. Both criteria
have equal weight, 0.4, and thus the interaction term a 10:40:4
0:40:4 1:25.
The partial utilities are calculated with the same functions as in Example 4.3
and the resulting utilities are presented in Table 4.3. In this case, as the
alternative 2 has the most even distribution of the criteria, it is the best
alternative also with this utility model.

Table 4.3 Overall utilities Alternative Income Animals Overall utility


with interaction term
1 197 18 0.431
2 164 80 0.746
5 30 137 0.491
8 186 34 0.532
9 182 38 0.554
10 93 121 0.654
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 49

Since all the interactions are dealt with the same parameter, this function is fairly
inflexible. In principle, it would be possible to estimate separate interaction terms
for each interaction pair of criteria, but this would require a lot of data from
decision-makers: each parameter requires at least one observation in order to be
estimated, and the number of observations increases very quickly as m increases.
Another common utility function form is the conjunctive function

Y
m   
a
Ui u j ci j j 4:8
j1

This model is non-compensatory in nature. If the utility due to one of the criteria
assumes zero value, the overall utility is also zero. It favours alternatives having
fairly similar sub-utility values for all criteria (e.g. Tell 1976).
The weights aj have throughout the chapter been interpreted as importances of
the different criteria. However, this approach has also been criticised. For instance,
Keeney and Raiffa (1976) consider the weights to be simple rescaling method
which is necessary to match the units of one sub-utility function with another.
Since it is possible to obtain very different value functions from the same data for
any one criterion (e.g. formulas 3.4 and 3.5), this needs to be kept in mind. For
instance, when formula 3.4 is used, the weights can be interpreted to describe the
importance of change from 0 level in natural scale to the maximum level, and when
formula 3.5 is used, the same weights should describe the importance of change
from the minimum value at natural scale, i.e. 0 at utility scale, to the maximum
value at both natural and utility scale.

Example 4.5
In the data of Example 4.3, also a conjunctive utility function can be used.
The sub-utilities are calculated with the same functions as in Example 4.3.
The criteria are assumed to be equally important also in this example, and the
resulting utilities are presented in Table 4.4. In this case, as the alternative
2 has the most even distribution of the criteria, it is the best alternative also
with this utility model.

Table 4.4 Overall utility Alternative Income Animals Overall utility


assuming a conjunctive utility
1 197 18 0.233
function
2 164 80 0.779
5 30 137 0.390
8 186 34 0.498
9 182 38 0.541
10 93 121 0.666
50 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

4.2.2 Basis for Estimating the Weights

There exist a large number of methods that can be used for estimating the weights in
the utility function. Generally, they can be divided to two main categories: direct
and non-direct methods. In non-direct methods, the estimation may be based on
earlier, true decisions. These revealed preferences are commonly utilised for
evaluating non-market values. In direct methods, the estimation is based on direct
questions concerning the importances of criteria, or priorities of decision alterna-
tives with respect to criteria, in the decision situation at hand.
It has been claimed that the old decisions are the only reliable way to estimate
the true utility function. Such a utility function is true only with respect to the old
decisions, however. The preferences and situation of the decision-maker may have
totally changed after that old decision was made, and the model may not be at all
useful in a new decision situation. The estimated utility model may also be incorrect
for the old decision, if it was made based on imperfect information on the alterna-
tives. Therefore, studying the old decisions and the preferences implied by these
decisions are mainly useful in descriptive studies. When aiming at decision support,
direct methods can be assumed more useful.
Estimation may also be based on a combined use of the two approaches. For
example, they may be applied iteratively so that the first model is estimated on
grounds of data on the earlier decision situations, and then the estimated model is
further improved by asking the decision-maker about his or her preferences.
Direct estimation methods can be further divided to two groups, statistical and
subjective methods (Schoemaker and Waid 1982). In statistical methods, the
decision-makers are asked to holistically evaluate some decision alternatives, and
the utility function is estimated based on these values. In subjective methods, the
decision problem is divided to several criteria, and preferences are asked regarding
these criteria.
Different estimation methods for utility functions have been tested, for instance,
by Eckenrode (1965), Fishburn (1967), Tell (1976), Tell and Wallenius (1979),
Eliashberg (1980), Jacquet-Lagreze and Siskos (1981), Schoemaker and Waid
(1982), Horsky and Rao (1984) and Laskey and Fisher (1987). In this chapter,
only one group of subjective direct methods of estimation are presented, namely,
SMART. Later in the chapter, some additional techniques like the pairwise com-
parisons of analytic hierarchy process are presented. These can also be used for
estimating a utility function. However, many decision scientists do not necessarily
regard these methods as belonging to the family of MAUT, and therefore they are
dealt with separately.
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 51

4.2.3 SMART

SMART (simple multi-attribute rating technique) is a decision support method


developed at the close of the 1960s and early 1970s in the field of multi-attribute
utility theory (von Winterfeldt and Edwards 1986). In fact, several methods based
on direct evaluation are involved in the family of SMART methods, of which
various researchers have developed new versions over the years. Generally, in
SMART, additive models are applied.
Direct rating in SMART means, for example, that criteria are directly assigned
numerical values depicting their importance. The least important criterion is first
given 10 points and the points of other criteria are related to that. Then, the points
are summed, and the final weights are the points of each criterion, divided by the
sum.
pj
aj X
m 4:9
pi
i1

The same principles can, of course, also be used for estimating the value function
with respect to each criterion (Chap. 3).
When the importance of the individual criteria and the priorities of each of the
alternatives with respect to each of the criteria have been determined, the overall
utility of alternatives can be calculated. SMART methods have been applied in
natural resource management by Reynolds (2001) and Kajanus et al. (2004), for
instance.
SMARTS (SMART using SWING) and SMARTER are elaborated versions of
SMART (Edwards and Barron 1994). In SWING weighting, it is first assumed that
all criteria are their lowest possible values, e.g. at utility function value 0. Then it is
asked which criteria is most important to change from its minimum level to its
maximum level. This criterion is given 100 points. After that, the rest of the criteria
are evaluated relative to that criterion. This approach has the advantage that the
importance weights explicitly depend on the range of criteria values on the problem
at hand, while the former SMART weighting does not necessarily do.

Example 4.6
The case example presented next is applied throughout the book to illustrate
different MCDM tools. The data comes from a real-life case of strategic
planning in a 320.9 ha area in northern Finland, owned by the state and
managed by the Finnish state forest enterprise Metsahallitus. It has been used
in many planning studies. The data consists of three criteria and six

(continued)
52 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.6 (continued)

Fig. 4.4 The decision Utility


hierarchy in SMART
example
Timber production Scenic beauty

Net incomes Future value of


timber

alternatives (see Kangas et al. 1992). The problem was to assess the
priority of the forest plans generated for the area. The plans were to:
Continue natural growth with no cuttings (NAT)
Optimise scenic beauty index (SCEN)
Apply normal forestry guidelines (NORM)
Optimise game values (GAME)
Make modest regeneration (MREG)
Maximise income (INC)
The decision criteria in this problem were timber production, scenic beauty
and game management. Each criterion was further decomposed into several
sub-criteria. In order to keep the example as simple as possible, only timber
production and scenic beauty were applied as criteria. The timber production
was divided to two sub-criteria, namely, net incomes during the first 10 years
and stumpage value after 20 years. The decision hierarchy (or value tree) is
presented in Fig. 4.4.
Net incomes describe the timber-harvesting income during the first half of
the 20-year planning period, and stumpage value describes the monetary
value of the remaining trees at the end of the 20-year period. Scenic beauty
is an index describing scenic beauty after 20 years, calculated with MONSU
software (see Pukkala 2006). The data for the example is presented in
Table 4.5. From the alternatives, NAT means that there are no cuttings at
all. In SCEN and GAME alternatives, regeneration is carried out, but no
clear-cuts are allowed. In INC alternative, the area of clear-cutting is largest:
in MREG the regeneration area is only half of that, although most of the
regeneration is carried out with clear-cutting (Table 4.6).
In SMART analysis, exponential utility function (of the form aeb/x) was
assumed for net incomes and stumpage value and a linear utility function
(formula 3.5) for scenic beauty. The utility functions were calculated with
WebHIPRE program (http://hipre.aalto.fi/). The utility function values for
each alternative and each criterion are given in the Table 4.7 and Fig. 4.5.

(continued)
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 53

Example 4.6 (continued)

Table 4.5 Net incomes, stumpage values and scenic beauty index of the six alternative plans
Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index
NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 38.0 0.60 5.4
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

Table 4.6 Cutting schemes of the example alternatives


Regeneration 1st Per cent Regeneration 2nd Per cent
period (ha) clear-cut period (ha) clear-cut
NAT 0 0 0 0
SCEN 55.1 0 104.3 0
NORM 14.9 81 15.6 81
GAME 17.0 0 17.2 0
MREG 50.3 96 44.5 11
INC 109.6 68 87.2 29

Table 4.7 Sub-utility Net Stumpage Scenic


function values incomes value beauty
NAT 0.000 1.000 0.750
SCEN 0.631 0.546 1.000
NORM 0.360 0.954 0.625
GAME 0.319 0.959 0.750
MREG 0.740 0.893 0.375
INC 1.000 0.000 0.000

Next, the criteria were weighted. Since the criteria form a decision hierarchy,
the lowest-level criteria were first weighted. The least important criterion, stump-
age value, was given 10 points and the most important, net incomes, was given
30 points. Then, the weight of net incomes becomes 0.75 and that of stumpage
value 0.25. The higher-level criteria were compared in the same way: scenic
beauty was given 10 points and timber production was given 40 points, which
gave weights 0.2 for scenic beauty and 0.8 for timber production. Then, the global
weights of net incomes and stumpage value were calculated as 0.8  0.75 0.6
and 0.8  0.25 0.2. With these weights, the priorities of the alternatives could
be calculated. In Table 4.8 and Fig. 4.6, the priorities of each alternative with
respect to both higher-level criteria and the global priorities are shown.

(continued)
54 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.6 (continued)

Fig. 4.5 The sub-utility functions for each criterion in the SMART example

Table 4.8 Global and local utilities


Global utility Timber production Scenic beauty
NAT 0.350 0.200 0.150
SCEN 0.688 0.488 0.200
NORM 0.532 0.407 0.125
GAME 0.533 0.383 0.150
MREG 0.697 0.622 0.075
INC 0.600 0.600 0.000

(continued)
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 55

Example 4.6 (continued)

Fig. 4.6 The global utility of the alternatives and its composition of the sub-utilities in the
SMART example

It is also possible to use the importance ranks of the criteria to calculate the
weights aj for the alternatives. This approach is called SMARTER (simple multi-
attribute rating technique exploiting ranks). One possible approach for calculating
the weights from ranks are the so-called rank order centroid or ROC weights
(Edwards and Barron 1994)

X
m
a j 1=m 1=i; 4:10
i j

where the criteria are assumed to be arranged from the most important ( j 1) to the
least important ( j m). Von Winterfeldt and Edwards (1986, also Stillwell
et al. 1981) presented three other formulas that can be used for calculating weights
from importance ranks of criteria, namely, the rank reciprocal rule,

1=r j
aj X 4:11
1=r i
i

the ranksum rule


56 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

  Xm
aj m 1  rj = ri 4:12
i1

and the rank exponent rule

 z X
m
aj m 1  rj = r iz ; 4:13
i1

where z is estimated with


 z
aj m1rj
4:14
ai m 1  r i z

In the last formula, the decision-maker needs to give a preference ratio (4.14) for
one pair of weights, in order to calculate the rest of them. This ratio could, for
instance, be the weight ratio of the most and least important criteria.
All three of the formulas can be considered as ad hoc procedures (Stillwell
et al. 1981; Edwards and Barron 1994). Yet, they could be useful if the decision-
maker does not want to evaluate the strength of his/her preferences.

Example 4.7
In the example above, in the higher hierarchy level, there are two criteria.
In this case, the weights for these two criteria, calculated with the formulas
based on ranks, are in Table 4.9. Using ROC weighting, the global priorities
of the alternatives are presented in Table 4.10, SCEN alternative being the
most preferred one.

Table 4.9 Weights based on ranking


Rank reciprocal Rank sum Rank exponent with z 1.6 ROC
Timber production 0.67 0.67 0.75 0.75
Scenic beauty 0.33 0.33 0.25 0.25

Table 4.10 Global utilities Global utility


with ROC weighting
NAT 0.375
SCEN 0.707
NORM 0.538
GAME 0.547
MREG 0.677
INC 0.563
4.2 Multi-attribute Utility Functions 57

4.2.4 TOPSIS

One example of utility functions is a distance function (Tell 1976; Tell and
Wallenius 1979). TOPSIS is a decision support tool that is designed to work
based on distances to the ideal (having the best available score for each criterion)
and anti-ideal (having the worst available score for each criterion) solutions of the
problem (Ishizaka and Nemery 2013). First, all the criteria values are normalised to
01 scale, for instance, by dividing with the highest value of each criterion (Eq. 3.4)
or, if the criterion is to be minimised, with the lowest score of the criterion. The
sub-utility scores are then multiplied with the weights of the criteria. Then, the
distance to the ideal solution is calculated with
v
uX
u m  ideal 2
di t

a j v j  a j vi j 4:15
j1

and likewise, the distance d


i to the anti-ideal solution is calculated. This procedure
gives the Euclidean distance, but also other distance metrics could be used. Then,
the relative closeness of each alternative is calculated with

d
Ci i
4:16
d
i d
i

This closeness index varies between 0 and 1, the closer to 1 the closer the
alternative is to the ideal solution.

Example 4.8
When the results of the Example 4.6. were calculated with TOPSIS, the
original criterion values (Table 4.5) were normalized using (3.4), and multi-
plied with the weights. The weights in this example are the same as above:
0.60 for incomes, 0.2 for stumpage value and 0.2 for scenic beauty. The
resulting scores are given in Table 4.11. The distances to ideal and anti-ideal
solutions as well as the closeness index are given in Table 4.12. In this case,
the INC alternative was the best, and MREG the second best.
Table 4.11 Sub-utility Net Stumpage Scenic
function values (normalised incomes value beauty
with Eq. 3.4 and multiplied
NAT 0.000 0.200 0.193
with the criteria weights)
SCEN 0.249 0.079 0.200
NORM 0.119 0.169 0.189
GAME 0.103 0.172 0.193
MREG 0.320 0.144 0.182
INC 0.600 0.037 0.172

(continued)
58 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.8 (continued)


Table 4.12 The distance d d C
from the ideal and anti-ideal
solution and the closeness NAT 0.600 0.165 0.215
index SCEN 0.371 0.254 0.407
NORM 0.482 0.179 0.271
GAME 0.498 0.171 0.256
MREG 0.286 0.338 0.542
INC 0.166 0.600 0.784

4.2.5 Cautionary Note of Weighting Methods

One possible drawback in the methods that are based on weighting and (linear)
additive utility assumption is that some of the alternatives may never get selected,
even if they are not dominated by any of the other alternatives. Especially very clear
compromise alternatives are such that they may never get selected. In our previous
Example 4.5, the alternative NORM is exactly that sort of an alternative.
An example evaluation can be made using the sub-utilities from Table 4.7 and a
systematic set of weights for the three criteria. To provide a representation of the
decision space, a set of 66 different weights were used, where the sum of the criteria
weights equals one, and the criteria weights are allowed to take the value from 0 to
1 with 0.1 steps (66 different sets of weights). From this set of weights, the
alternative NORM is never selected (Fig. 4.7). It is still not dominated: for instance,
even if it is worse than NAT and GAME with respect to stumpage value and scenic
beauty, it is still better than either with respect to net incomes. Likewise, while it is
worse than SCEN with respect to net incomes and scenic beauty, it is still better
than it with respect to stumpage value, and while it is worse than MREG and INC
with respect to net incomes, it is still better than either with respect to the other two
criteria. In fact, NORM might seem as a perfect compromise from many points of
view. If the sub-utilities were obtained by dividing with the highest value for each
criterion (i.e. the sub-utilities are linear and ratio scale values), neither NORM nor
GAME would never be selected. Thus, non-linear sub-utility functions can change
the situation.
The distance-based TOPSIS approach has been also noted to behave like that.
In this kind of situations, other kinds of decision support might be advisable.
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 59

Fig. 4.7 The dependency of the best alternative on the weight of net incomes, when the weight of
stumpage value is fixed at 0.2 and the weight of scenic beauty decreases

4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process

4.3.1 Decision Problem

The analytic hierarchy process (AHP), originally developed by Saaty (1977, 1980,
1990), is a widely used MCDS method and perhaps the most popular in many
application fields, including natural resource management. Mendoza and Sprouse
(1989), Murray and von Gadow (1991) and Kangas (1992), among others, have
used AHP in forestry applications, and the number of applications is continuously
increasing (e.g. Raucher et al. 2000; Reynolds 2001; Vacik and Lexer 2001;
Kukrety et al. 2013; Dhami et al. 2014). AHP has also gained interest among
forestry practitioners. The Finnish state forest enterprise Metsahallitus, which
governs the vast majority of state-owned lands in Finland, has used AHP, or
more precisely the HIPRE software, in practical natural resource planning
(Pykalainen et al. 1999; Kangas et al. 2001a). For a review of AHP forestry
applications, readers are referred to Kangas (1999) and to Schmoldt et al. (2001)
for extensions and for AHP-related development.
Basically the AHP is a general theory of measurement based on some mathe-
matical and psychological principles. In the method, a hierarchical decision schema
is constructed by decomposing the decision problem in question into decision
60 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Fig. 4.8 The decision


hierarchy of the AHP
example

elements overall goal, criteria, sub-criteria and decision alternatives. The general
goal is at the top of the decision hierarchy, and decision alternatives constitute the
lowest level (Fig. 4.8).
The branches of the decision hierarchy are assumed to be independent of each
other. It means that the decision criteria are not supposed to measure the same
values from the decision-makers point of view. For instance, if scenic beauty
measures, for instance, the recreational value of the forest estate, but has no
intrinsic value besides that, it should not be included as a criterion of its own but
as a sub-criterion for recreational value. Defining the decision hierarchy is impor-
tant, as splitting the criteria in different ways has been noted to affect their weight in
the decision analysis (e.g. Poyhonen and Hamalainen 1998; Poyhonen et al. 2001).
This does not mean, however, that the decision criteria should not be correlated. On
the contrary, it often happens that, for instance, measures describing biodiversity
and recreation value may be correlated.
On the other hand, the independency means that the criteria should not have
interactions. It is possible that the incomes in the different alternatives also affect to
the importance of aesthetic or ecological values (e.g. Leskinen et al. 2003). In basic
AHP this is not allowed, but in regression AHP context (e.g. Leskinen and Kangas
2005a, b) and in ANP, such interactions can be accounted for.
The importances or preferences of decision elements are compared in a pairwise
manner with regard to each element above in the hierarchy. Based on these compar-
isons, an additive model on a ratio scale describing the preferences of the decision-
maker and priorities of decision alternatives with respect to the overall goals or criteria
is estimated. The model is called a priority function. The decision alternative which
produces the greatest global priority is considered the best and most satisfactory.
Differences in measurement scales and units do not present any difficulty when
the AHP is used, because the method is based on straight comparison between the
significance and preference of each pair of decision elements without using any
physical unit. Thus, AHP can deal with qualitative criteria as well as with those
which are quantitative.
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 61

4.3.2 Phases of AHP

The four basic steps involved in using the AHP to address decision problems are:
1. The decision hierarchy is constructed by decomposing the original decision
problem into a hierarchy of interrelated decision elements.
2. Pairwise comparisons are made at each level of the hierarchy. In making the
comparison, the question is, which of the two factors has a greater weight in
decision-making, and how much greater, or which of the two decision alterna-
tives is more preferred with regard to a certain decision criterion (or sub-
criterion).
3. Using the pairwise comparisons as input, the relative weights (importance/
preference) of elements at each level are computed using the eigenvalue method.
The resulting weights or priorities represent the decision-makers perception of
the relative importance or preference of the elements at each level of the
hierarchy.
4. The ratings for the decision alternatives are calculated based on the relative
weights of the decision elements.
Pairwise comparisons give the decision-maker a basis on which to reveal his
preferences by comparing two elements at a time. The importances or preferences
of decision elements are compared in a pairwise manner with regard to each
element above in the hierarchy. First, each of the alternatives from 1 to n is
compared to each other alternative with respect to first sub-criterion (or criterion
if no sub-criteria exist). These comparisons, with respect to one decision element,
form one comparison set. Then, each of the alternatives is compared to each other
alternative with respect to rest of the (sub-) criteria, one by one. After that, the
sub-criteria are compared pairwisely with respect to each criterion above them, and
finally, the criteria are compared in a pairwise manner with respect to the
overall goal.
In the standard method presented by Saaty (1977, 1980), the decision-maker has
the option of expressing preferences between the two elements as:
(i) Equal importance or preference of both elements
(ii) Weak importance or preference of one element over another
(iii) Essential or strong importance or preference of one element over another
(iv) Demonstrated importance or preference of one element over another
(v) Absolute importance or preference of one element over another
These preferences are then translated into numerical values of 1, 3, 5, 7 and
9, respectively, with 2, 4, 6 and 8 as intermediate values. Many other variations
of the scale have also been presented (see Leskinen 2001). It is also possible to carry
out comparisons by using a continuous scale, e.g. by making use of graphical bars in
the computer interface (e.g. Pukkala and Kangas 1993).
For estimating the priorities, the matrix of pairwise comparisons A is
constructed for each set of comparisons. The elements of the matrix, aij, describe
the comparison of alternative (or (sub-) criterion) i to j. The matrix is required to be
62 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

reciprocal, i.e. in the matrix the element aij 1/aji. It means that if alternative i is
twice as good as j, then j has to be half as good as i. Each alternative is then
indifferent with itself, i.e. when i j, aij 1.
If there were no inconsistencies in judgements, matrix A has unit rank since
every row is a constant multiple of the first row, and all the eigenvalues of the
matrix are zero except one. (Rank of a matrix is the number of mutually indepen-
dent rows in it.) Based on a consistent matrix A, relative weights can be determined
by solving the equation

Aw w; 4:17

where is the only nonzero eigenvalue of a consistent matrix A and w is its right
eigenvector. The solution w of this problem is any column of A. These solutions
differ only by a multiplicative constant. Thus, the same relative weights are got
based on any column of the matrix. In human decision-making, some inconsis-
tencies can be expected: peoples feelings and preferences are not always consis-
tent. Furthermore, as the largest value used in the comparison matrix is 9, and there
are only nine possible answers, in many cases it may be impossible to compare the
decision elements consistently using this scale.

Example 4.9
If the comparisons were such that decision-maker considers alternative 1 to be
twice as good as 2, alternative 2 three times as good as 3 and alternative 1 six
(23) times as good as alternative 3 (i.e. a12 2, a23 3 and a13 6), the
decision matrix is considered to be consistent. The matrix A would then be
2 3
1 1=2 1=6
42 1 1=3 5
6 3 1

In this case, the weights can be obtained simply by dividing each column with
the sum of its cell values, giving as weights
2 3
0:111
4 0:222 5
0:667

When A contains inconsistencies, the estimated weights can be obtained using


the eigenvector equation.

A  max Iq 0; 4:18
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 63

where max is the largest eigenvalue of matrix A, q its right eigenvector and I the
identity matrix. The right eigenvector, q, constitutes the estimation of relative
weights. It is the first principal component of the matrix of pairwise comparisons.
The first principal component of a matrix is a linear combination of the variables
(i.e. comparisons with respect to one decision element) that describes the largest
part of the variation in the matrix. It gives the relative weights to the compared
elements, which best fit to the made comparisons. If the matrix does not include any
inconsistencies, i.e. the judgements made by a decision-maker have been consis-
tent, q is an exact estimate of the priority vector.
Each eigenvector is scaled to sum to one to get the priorities. The form of a
priority function is the same as the form of an additive utility function without
interaction terms.
Global priorities of decision elements are calculated downwards from the top of
the hierarchy by multiplying the local priorities by the priority of their
corresponding decision element at the level above. Global priority of an element
is then used to weight the local priorities of elements at the level below and so on
down to the bottom level. Global priorities at each level sum up to one.
It has been shown that max of a reciprocal matrix A is always greater or equal to
n ( number of rows number of columns) (e.g. Saaty 1977). If the pairwise
comparisons do not include any inconsistencies, max n. The more consistent
the comparisons are, the closer the value of computed max is to n. Based on this
property, a consistency index, CI, has been constructed

CI max  n=n  1: 4:19

CI estimates the level of consistency with respect to the entire comparison process.
A consistency ratio, CR, also measures the coherence of the pairwise comparisons.
To estimate the CR, the average consistency index of randomly generated compar-
isons, ACI, has to be calculated (CR 100(CI/ACI)). ACI varies as a function of
the size of matrix (e.g. Saaty 1980). As a rule of thumb, a CR value of 0.1 or less is
considered to be acceptable. Otherwise, all or some of the comparisons must be
repeated in order to resolve the inconsistencies of pairwise comparisons.

Example 4.10
The problem of Example 4.6 is analysed using AHP. There are six decision
alternatives and three criteria. They form a decision hierarchy (Fig. 4.8). The
alternatives were compared pairwisely with respect to each criterion
(Table 4.13). The obtained CR results mean that the comparisons were a bit
too inconsistent for a good analysis, and it would be recommendable to make
some of them again. After comparing the alternatives, the criteria were
compared. First, the second-level criteria net incomes and value of timber
were compared to each other and then the higher-level criteria were compared
(Table 4.14).

(continued)
64 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.10 (continued)

Table 4.13 Pairwise comparisons


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
(a) With respect to net incomes
NAT 1/1 1/4 1/2 1/2 1/7 1/9
SCEN 4/1 1/1 2/1 2/1 1/3 1/5
NORM 2/1 1/2 1/1 1/1 1/4 1/7
GAME 2/1 1/2 1/1 1/1 1/5 1/7
MREG 7/1 3/1 4/1 5/1 1/1 1/2
INC 9/1 5/1 7/1 7/1 2/1 1/1
CR 0.099
(b) With respect to value of timber
NAT 1/1 6/1 3/1 3/1 4/1 8/1
SCEN 1/6 1/1 1/4 1/4 1/3 3/1
NORM 1/3 4/1 1/1 1/1 2/1 6/1
GAME 1/3 4/1 1/1 1/1 2/1 6/1
MREG 1/4 3/1 1/2 1/2 1/1 4/1
INC 1/8 1/3 1/6 1/6 1/4 1/1
CR 0.159
(c) With respect to scenic beauty
NAT 1/1 1/2 1/1 1/1 3/1 5/1
SCEN 2/1 1/1 3/1 5/1 5/1 6/1
NORM 1/1 1/3 1/1 1/1 2/1 4/1
GAME 1/1 1/5 1/1 1/1 2/1 4/1
MREG 1/3 1/5 1/2 1/2 1/1 3/1
INC 1/5 1/6 1/4 1/4 1/3 1/1
CR 0.146

Table 4.14 Pairwise Net incomes Value of timber


comparisons between the
Net incomes 1/1 3/1
criteria
Value of timber 1/3 1/1
CR 0.000
Timber production Scenic beauty
Timber production 1/1 4/1
Scenic beauty 1/4 1/1
CR 0.000

The priorities and the consistency rations were calculated with


WebHIPRE program (http://hipre.aalto.fi/). The priorities were first calcu-
lated at the level of sub-criteria and criteria (Table 4.15). Then, INC is the
best alternative with respect to net incomes, NAT with respect to stumpage

(continued)
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 65

Example 4.10 (continued)

Table 4.15 Local utilities Net Stumpage Scenic


with respect to different incomes value beauty
criteria
NAT 0.036 0.421 0.186
SCEN 0.113 0.057 0.382
NORM 0.064 0.188 0.155
GAME 0.061 0.188 0.155
MREG 0.272 0.114 0.081
INC 0.455 0.031 0.04

Table 4.16 Overall utility Overall Timber Scenic


and global utility with respect utility production beauty
to timber production criterion
NAT 0.143 0.106 0.037
and scenic beauty
SCEN 0.156 0.079 0.076
NORM 0.107 0.076 0.031
GAME 0.105 0.074 0.031
MREG 0.202 0.186 0.016
INC 0.287 0.279 0.008

value and SCEN with respect to scenic beauty. The local weight of net
incomes was 0.75 and that of stumpage value 0.25, and the local weights of
scenic beauty was 0.2 and that of timber production 0.8. Thus, the global
weight of net incomes was 0.80.75 0.6 and that of stumpage value
0.250.8 0.2. The global priorities of the alternatives with respect to criteria
were obtained by multiplying their priorities at the sub-criteria level with the
global weights of these criteria (Table 4.16, Fig. 4.9). Global priorities with
respect to timber production were obtained by adding together the global
priorities with respect to net incomes and stumpage value and the overall
priorities by adding the priorities of timber production and scenic beauty
together (Table 4.16). It can be noted that INC is the best alternative with
respect to timber production as a whole, since the weight of stumpage value is
quite low and also its overall priority was the best.
To illustrate the notion of inconsistency, the priorities of the alternatives
were calculated from each column in matrix 4.11 (Table 4.17). It means that
six different priority estimates were obtained. It can be noted that these
priority estimates have a lot of variations among them, for instance, the
priority of INC with respect to net incomes varies from 0.360 to 0.509
(0.455 in eigenvalue analysis, Table 4.15) and that of NAT from 0.024 to
0.053 (0.036 in eigenvalue analysis).

(continued)
66 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.10 (continued)

Fig. 4.9 The global utility of the alternatives and its composition of the sub-utilities in the
AHP example

Table 4.17 Priorities calculated by scaling each column of pairwise comparisons matrix
separately
1 2 3 4 5 6
NAT 0.040 0.024 0.032 0.030 0.036 0.053
SCEN 0.160 0.098 0.129 0.121 0.085 0.095
NORM 0.080 0.049 0.065 0.061 0.064 0.068
GAME 0.080 0.049 0.065 0.061 0.051 0.068
MREG 0.280 0.293 0.258 0.303 0.255 0.238
INC 0.360 0.488 0.452 0.424 0.509 0.477

4.3.3 Uncertainty in AHP

Many decision scientists have criticised the AHP method. Perhaps the two foremost
problems with the application of AHP have been that the original comparison scale
does not allow for the expression of any hesitation regarding a single comparison
and that the AHP itself does not provide tools for in-depth analyses of the compar-
isons, particularly of the uncertainty inherent in the data (e.g. De Jong 1984;
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 67

Crawford and Williams 1985; Alho et al. 1996). The only means to analyse the
uncertainty in AHP is to calculate the inconsistencies. Moreover, part of the
inconsistencies in the pairwise analysis may be due to the scale, not the answers
given by the people (Leskinen 2001).
In basic AHP the number of comparisons increases rapidly as the number of
alternatives and criteria increases. Large numbers of comparisons may be too costly
and tedious, especially for participatory planning problems. However, eigenvalue
technique requires a full comparison matrix in order to be carried out.
Finally, rank reversal occurring when using the AHP may cause problems
(e.g. Belton and Gear 1983). This means that if a new alternative is added to the
analysis, it is possible that the rank of the previously considered alternatives
changes, although the preferences do not change. Rank reversal means that, for
instance, if the preferences originally are so that A is preferred to B and B to C, after
including a new alternative D the situation may change so that B is preferred to A,
for instance. In some occasions, it may be that rank reversal occurs if the inverses of
the ratios are used, that is, if the direction of the preferences is changed (Ishizaka
and Nemery 2013). According to Leskinen and Kangas (2005a, b), rank reversal is
acceptable if it is due to inconsistencies (i.e. new alternatives give new information
concerning the preferences) but not acceptable if it is due to the method itself. Using
the geometric aggregation rule, the rank reversal problem can be avoided (Barzilai
and Golany 1994, Leskinen and Kangas 2005a, b). The problem of rank reversal
does not only apply to AHP but also, for instance, SMART, if the sub-utility
functions are calculated using the interval scale.
To alleviate these problems, different modifications of AHP have been devel-
oped. In these, the concept of decision hierarchy and the pairwise comparisons may
be similar to the basic AHP, but the techniques are different. The number of
comparisons can be reduced by the use of regression techniques for estimating
preferences instead of the eigenvalue technique (Alho et al. 1996, 2001; Leskinen
2001). That method is also called as geometric mean method or logarithmic least
squares method (Ishizaka and   Nemery 2013). The pairwise comparisons are
denoted with r i j vi =v j exp i j , where exp(ij) describes the uncertainty in each
pairwise comparison. Since all the values of items i, vi are positive, with no loss of
generality, it can be expressed as

vi exp i 4:20

where and i are parameters. Then, the ratio can, in turn, be expressed as
 
vi =v j exp i  j 4:21

and the model can be expressed as


 
log r i j yi j i  j i j 4:22
68 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Thus, expressing the values vi as exponents and using a logarithmic transformation


enables using a linear model. The parameters i, i 1, . . ., n1 are then estimated
using a standard regression tools. The parameter n related to the item n is assumed
to be zero for definiteness, i.e. otherwise that would be an infinite number of
solutions to this model. The minimum number of observations in regression
analysis is the number of parameters to be estimated, i.e. it would be enough to
include only one row or column from the pairwise matrix in the analysis. In that
case, however, it would not be possible to estimate the inconsistency involved. For
that, additional observations are needed.
In this model, the distribution of the error term, ij, describes the uncertainty of
the analysis. With this formulation, the error variance describes the inconsistency of
the comparisons: if the variance is 0, the comparisons are consistent and the higher
the variance, the more inconsistency there is.
The priorities of the alternatives that sum up to one are finally calculated as

expi
qi X
n 4:23
expi
i1

With this formula, the scale is transformed from logarithmic scale back to original
(value scale). The division by the sum of transformed values scales the sum of
priorities to one. Finally, if the weight for each criterion j is denoted by aj, the utility
of each alternative i can be calculated with geometric aggregation rule as
Y a XY a
Ui q j = i j qi jj :
j ij
4:24

Example 4.11
The pairwise comparisons of Example 4.10 with respect to net incomes were
analysed with regression AHP. The data used in the example are presented in
Table 4.18. The explanatory variables are just zeros and ones. They describe
which alternative has been compared to which, according to model 4.21.
Since the parameter for the last alternative is set to 0, INC is not included in
the data. The parameters were calculated using SAS, and the priorities of the
alternatives with respect to net incomes could be calculated Table 4.19.
The standard error of the model is 0.19 and R2 is 0.9863. They indicate that
the pairwise comparisons are not quite consistent, but the consistency is fairly
high. These comparisons were consistent enough also with respect to CR
criterion.

(continued)
4.3 Analytic Hierarchy Process 69

Example 4.11 (continued)

Table 4.18 Pairwise comparison data for a model


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG r y
1 1 0 0 0 0.25 1.38629
1 0 1 0 0 0.5 0.69315
1 0 0 1 0 0.5 0.69315
1 0 0 0 1 0.143 1.94491
1 0 0 0 0 0.111 2.19823
0 1 1 0 0 2.0 0.693147
0 1 0 1 0 2.0 0.693147
0 1 0 0 1 0.33 1.10866
0 1 0 0 0 0.2 1.60944
0 0 1 1 0 1.0 0
0 0 1 0 1 0.25 1.38629
0 0 1 0 0 0.143 1.94491
0 0 0 1 1 0.2 1.60944
0 0 0 1 0 0.143 1.94491
0 0 0 0 1 0.5 0.69315

Table 4.19 Estimated exp() q


priorities of alternatives
NAT 2.55106 0.077999 0.035316
SCEN 1.38936 0.249235 0.112846
NORM 1.95364 0.141757 0.064183
GAME 1.99083 0.136582 0.06184
MREG 0.50575 0.603053 0.273044
INC 0 1 0.45277
sum 2.208626 1

Another example of accounting for uncertain preferences in AHP framework is


interval AHP (Leskinen and Kangas 1998; see also Arbel 1989 and Salo and
Hamalainen 1992). In interval AHP, the decision-makers are asked the probability
that the preference lies in a certain interval or the interval the preference lies in with
a certain probability.
The regression approach to AHP can also be reformulated to Bayesian frame-
work (e.g. Alho and Kangas 1997; Basak 1998). Bayes theorem is then used to
derive the conditional distributions of the parameters. Then, it is easy to calculate
the probabilities that one plan is better than all the others, for example.
Yet another example of accounting for uncertainty in AHP context is the fuzzy
AHP. In fuzzy AHP, preference ratios of criteria or alternatives are described by
membership functions (e.g. Mendoza and Prabhu 2001).
70 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

4.4 ANP

The analytic network process (ANP) is an extension of the AHP (Saaty 2001) that
answers some of the development challenges of the basic AHP methodology.
Basically, the ANP is a general theory of ratio scale measurement of influence,
with a methodology that deals with dependence and feedback. The comparisons are
made using pairwise comparisons like in original AHP, but the relations between
the criteria are included in the comparisons. The main idea is to avoid the assump-
tion of independence among criteria of the standard AHP.
ANP model can be designed either using a so-called control hierarchy (i.e. a
hierarchy of subsystems with inner dependencies) or as a nonhierarchical network,
which includes both decision criteria and alternatives as clusters (e.g. Wolfslehner
et al. 2005). The clusters are connected with arrows that describe the flow of
influence. Thus, each criterion can have an interaction with other criteria (outer
dependence), and each sub-criterion can have interaction with other sub-criteria in
the same cluster (inner dependence).
A hypothetical example of ANP network is presented in Fig. 4.10. In the
example, decision criterion 1 influences to criteria 2, 3 and 6, and criterion 3 is
also influencing criterion 1. In addition, there is a feedback loop back to the
criterion itself. The influence means that instead of comparing sub-criteria of
criterion 2 in pairwise manner, the influence is accounted for. Thus it is asked,
for instance, With regard to (the influencing element) criterion 1, sub-criterion 1 is
how many times more important than sub-criterion 2?. For a forestry example
concerning criteria and indicators of sustainable management, readers are referred
to Wolfslehner et al. (2005).

Fig. 4.10 An example of ANP network


4.5 Even Swaps 71

The ANP utilises a so-called supermatrix calculation in order to deal with


interactions among the network of criteria and decision alternatives. Saaty (2001)
stated that, generally taken, the ANP is more objective and more likely to capture
what happens in the real world than the AHP. However, applying the ANP is much
more laborious and time-consuming, and the method itself is more complicated and
harder to understand and, thus, less pedagogical. Obviously the ANP has potential
application in forest management, where different kinds of interdependencies
between decision elements are usual.

4.5 Even Swaps

Even swaps, originally developed by Hammond et al. (1998a, b), is a method for
making trade-offs among criteria across a range of alternatives. The method is
based on direct comparison of the preferences of each pair of decision elements:
one criterion is valued in terms of another criterion. The criteria can be qualita-
tive as well as quantitative. The method goes on in four steps (Hammond
et al. 1998a, b):
Step 1. The consequence matrix is created. Each row represents an alternative and
each column a criterion. Each cell contains the consequence of the given
alternative with respect to the given criterion.
Step 2. Dominated alternatives are eliminated. For instance, if alternative A is better
than alternative B on one or more criteria, and no worse on all other criteria, then
alternative B can be eliminated. Also such alternatives that are practically
dominated (i.e. have only a slight advantage in one criterion and are dominated
in other criteria) can be removed.
Step 3. Criteria, which have equal rating for each alternative, can be ignored in
decision-making. Therefore, the criteria are made equivalent by making trade-
offs. This is carried out with the following steps (Kajanus et al. 2001):
Determining the change necessary to eliminate one criterion
Assessing what change in another criterion would compensate for the needed
change
Making the even swap in the consequence table by reducing the value of one
criterion while increasing the value of other
Cancelling out the now irrelevant criterion
Step 4. Steps 2 and 3 are repeated until there is only one criterion left. Then, the
dominant alternative is selected.
72 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.12
The original table of consequences is the same as in Example 4.6.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index


NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 38.0 0.60 5.4
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

From this table, the swaps are made in order to get either some alternatives
dominated or some criteria irrelevant. The example was carried out with a
SMART-SWAPS program (http://smart-swaps.aalto.fi, Mustajoki and
Hamalainen 2005, 2006). The SMART-SWAPS program actively proposes
swaps for the decision-maker, to make the analysis easier.
The first swap was to compensate a change 5.4 ! 5.5 in NORMs scenic
beauty with a decrease of incomes 38 ! 33. Thus, the value of one unit
increase in scenic beauty would be 5000. The resulting table shows that
NORM is now dominated by GAME and can be removed.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index


NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 33.0 0.60 5.5
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

The second swap was to compensate a change 4.9 ! 5.5 in INCs scenic
beauty with a decrease of incomes 191.7 ! 170.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index


NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 170.0 0.13 5.5

(continued)
4.5 Even Swaps 73

Example 4.12 (continued)


The next swap was to compensate a change 5.2 ! 5.5 in MREGs scenic
beauty with a decrease of incomes 102.3 ! 90

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index


NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 90.0 0.51 5.5
INC 170.0 0.13 5.5

And the next swap was to compensate a change 5.7 ! 5.5 in SCENs scenic
beauty with an increase of stumpage value 0.28 ! 0.38. Now, the SCEN
alternative is dominated and can be removed from the table. In addition,
scenic beauty is irrelevant and can be removed from the table.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million Scenic beauty index


NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.38 5.5
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 90.0 0.51 5.5
INC 170.0 0.13 5.5

The next swap was to compensate a change 0.61 ! 0.71 in GAMEs stumpage
value with a decrease of incomes 33 ! 28, resulting NAT being a dominated
alternative that can be removed.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million


NAT 0.0 0.71
GAME 28.0 0.71
MREG 90.0 0.51
INC 170.0 0.13

The next swap was to compensate a change 0.51 ! 0.71 in MREGs stumpage
value with a decrease of incomes 90 ! 80, resulting GAME being a dominated
alternative that can be removed.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million


GAME 28.0 0.71
MREG 80.0 0.71
INC 170.0 0.13

(continued)
74 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Example 4.12 (continued)


Then, the final swap was to compensate a change 0.13 ! 0.71 in INCs
stumpage value with a decrease of incomes 170 ! 145, resulting MREG
being a dominated alternative and INC the recommended one.

Net incomes, 1000 Stumpage value, million


MREG 80.0 0.71
INC 145.0 0.71

4.6 AWOT

In the so-called AWOT method (Kurttila et al. 2000; Pesonen et al. 2001a), the
analytic hierarchy process (AHP) and its eigenvalue calculation framework are
integrated with SWOT analysis. SWOT is a widely applied tool in strategic
decision support. In SWOT, the internal and external factors most important for
the enterprises future are grouped into four categories: strengths, weaknesses,
opportunities, and threats. By applying SWOT in a strategic planning process, the
aim usually is to develop and adopt a strategy resulting in a good fit between these
internal and external factors. When used properly, SWOT can provide a good basis
for strategy formulation. However, SWOT could be used more efficiently than
normally has been the case in its applications. The most crucial problem with
SWOT is that it includes no means of analytically determining the importance of
factors or of assessing the fit between SWOT factors and decision alternatives.
The aim in applying the hybrid method is to improve the quantitative informa-
tion basis of strategic planning processes. AHPs linking with SWOT yields
analytically determined priorities for the factors included in SWOT analysis and
makes them commensurable (Fig. 4.11). In addition, decision alternatives can be
evaluated with respect to each SWOT factor by applying the AHP. So, SWOT
provides the basic frame within which to perform an analysis of the decision
situation, and the AHP assists in carrying out SWOT more analytically and in
elaborating the analysis so that alternative strategic decisions can be prioritised.
The main phases of AWOT are as follows:
(1) The SWOT analysis is carried out. The relevant factors of the external and
internal environment are identified and included in SWOT analysis.
(2) Pairwise comparisons between the SWOT factors are carried out separately
within each SWOT group. When making the comparisons, the issue at stake is
which of the two factors compared is more important and how much more
important. With these comparisons as the input, the mutual priorities of the
factors are computed.
(3) The mutual importance of the SWOT groups is determined by applying
pairwise comparisons. There are several possibilities as how to do this. For
instance, it is possible to compare the groups as such or the most important
factors in each group pairwisely.
4.6 AWOT 75

Operational
environment

SWOT Strengths Weaknesses Opportunities Threats


group (S) (W) (O) (T)

SWOT
factors

Strategy
S1 S2 ... Sn
alternatives

Fig. 4.11 AWOT framework (Kurttila et al. 2000)

(4) The strategy alternatives are evaluated with respect to each SWOT factor by
using pairwise comparisons and the eigenvalue technique.
(5) Global priorities are calculated for the strategy alternatives.
In the earliest AWOT applications (Kurttila et al. 2000; Pesonen et al. 2001a),
only steps (1), (2) and (3), as listed above, were carried out in an early stage of a
strategic planning process. AWOT strengthens the decision basis also in the case
where the result is only the quantification and commensuration of SWOT factors.
However, the final goal of any strategic planning process as a whole is to develop
and propose a strategy resulting in a good fit between internal and external factors.
When steps (4) and (5) are included in the AWOT process, the initial SWOT
analysis might not always be applicable as such (Pesonen et al. 2001b).
The reason for this is that the SWOT factors could have been formulated so that
strategy alternatives cannot be evaluated with respect to them. This being the case,
SWOT factors need some value-focused modification and fine-tuning
(e.g. Leskinen et al. 2006). For AWOT, SWOT factors should be determined by
asking which are the internal and external factors of the operational environment
that should be taken into account in choosing the strategy for the enterprise. Then it
is possible to compare strategy alternatives with respect to strengths, weaknesses,
opportunities, and threats as listed in SWOT. To take an example of the pairwise
comparisons: which of the two strategy alternatives compared (when
implemented) makes it possible to better exploit a certain opportunity, and how
much better? According to the experiences of AWOT applications and tests, the
combined use of the AHP and SWOT analysis is a promising approach in
supporting strategic decision-making processes (Kurttila et al. 2000; Kangas
et al. 2001b; Pesonen et al. 2001a, b). Recently, also other multi-criteria analysis
methods have been combined with SWOT (Kajanus et al. 2012). This has
increased the number of use situations and the popularity of the hybrid method
in various application fields.
76 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

References

Alho, J., & Kangas, J. (1997). Analysing uncertainties in experts opinions of forest plan perfor-
mance. Forest Science, 43, 521528.
Alho, J., Kangas, J., & Kolehmainen, O. (1996). Uncertainty in the expert predictions of the
ecological consequences of forest plans. Applied Statistics, 45, 114.
Alho, J. M., Kolehmainen, O., & Leskinen, P. (2001). Regression methods for pairwise compar-
isons data. In D. L. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic
hierarchy process in natural resource and environmental decision making (pp. 235251).
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Arbel, A. (1989). Approximate articulation of preference and priority derivation. European
Journal of Operational Research, 43, 317326.
Barzilai, J., & Golany, B. (1994). AHP rank reversal, normalization and aggregation rules. INFOR,
32, 5764.
Basak, I. (1998). Probabilistic judgments specified partially in the Analytic Hierarchy Process.
European Journal of Operational Research, 108, 153164.
Belton, V., & Gear, T. (1983). On a short-coming of Saatys method of analytic hierarchies.
Omega, 11, 228230.
Belton, V., & Stewart, T. J. (2002). Multiple criteria decision analysis: An integrated approach.
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Crawford, G., & Williams, C. (1985). A note on the analysis of subjective judgment matrices.
Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 29, 387405.
De Jong, P. (1984). A statistical approach to Saatys scaling method for priorities. Journal of
Mathematical Psychology, 28, 467478.
Dhami, I., Deng, J., Burns, R. C., & Pierskalla, C. (2014). Identifying and mapping forest-based
ecotourism areas in West Virginia Incorporating visitors preferences. Tourism Management,
42, 165176.
Eckenrode, R. T. (1965). Weighting multiple criteria. Management Science, 12, 180192.
Edwards, W., & Barron, F. H. (1994). SMARTS and SMARTER: Improved simple methods for
multiattribute utility measurement. Organizational Behaviour and Human Decision Process,
60, 306325.
Eliashberg, J. (1980). Consumer preference judgments: An exposition with empirical applications.
Management Science, 26, 6077.
Fishburn, P. C. (1967). Methods of estimating additive utilities. Management Science, 13,
435453.
Hammond, J. S., Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1998a). Even swaps: A rational method for making
trade-offs. Harvard Business Review, MarchApril, pp. 111.
Hammond, J. S., Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1998b). Smart choices: A practical guide to making
better decisions. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Horsky, D., & Rao, M. R. (1984). Estimation of attribute weights from preference comparisons.
Management Science, 30, 801821.
Hwang, C.-L., & Masud, A. S. M. (1979). Multi objective decision making Methods and
applications. Berlin: Springer.
Ishizaka, A., & Nemery, P. (2013). Multi-criteria decision analysis. Methods and software.
Chichester: Wiley. 296 p.
Jacquet-Lagreze, E., & Siskos, J. (1981). Assessing a set of additive utility functions for
multicriteria decision-making, the UTA method. European Journal of Operational Research,
10, 151164.
Kajanus, M., Ahola, J., Kurttila, M., & Pesonen, M. (2001). Application of even swaps for strategy
selection in a rural enterprise. Management Decision, 39, 394402.
Kajanus, M., Kangas, J., & Kurttila, M. (2004). The use of value focused thinking and the AWOT
hybrid method in tourism management. Tourism Management, 25, 499506.
References 77

Kajanus, M., Leskinen, P., Kurttila, M., & Kangas, J. (2012). Making use of MCDS methods in
SWOT analysis Lessons learnt in strategic natural resources management. Forest Policy and
Economics, 20, 19.
Kangas, J. (1992). Multiple-use planning of forest resources by using the Analytic Hierarchy
Process. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 7, 259268.
Kangas, J., Karsikko, J., Laasonen, L., & Pukkala, T. (1993a). A method for estimating the
suitability function of wildlife habitat for forest planning on the basis of expertise. Silva
Fennica, 27, 259268.
Kangas, J., Laasonen, L., & Pukkala, T. (1993b). A method for estimating forest landowners
landscape preferences. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 8, 408417.
Kangas, J. (1999). The analytic hierarchy process (AHP): Standard version, forestry application
and advances. In F. Helles, P. Holten-Andersen, & L. Wichmann (Eds.), Multiple use of forests
and other natural resources (Forestry sciences, Vol. 61, pp. 96105). Dordrecht: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Kangas, J., & Pukkala, T. (1996). Operationalization of biological diversity as a decision objective
in tactical forest planning. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 26, 103111.
Kangas, J., Matero, J., & Pukkala, T. (1992). Analyyttisen hierarkiaprosessin kaytt o metsien
monikayton suunnitteluun tapaustutkimus. Mets antutkimuslaitoksen tiedonantoja, 412. 48 p.
Kangas, J., Laasonen, L., & Pukkala, T. (1993). A method for estimating forest landowners
landscape preferences. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 8, 408417.
Kangas, J., Kangas, A., Leskinen, P., & Pykalainen, J. (2001a). MCDM methods in strategic
planning of forestry on state-owned lands in Finland: Applications and experiences. Journal of
Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 10, 257271.
Kangas, J., Pesonen, M., Kurttila, M., & Kajanus, M. (2001b). AWOT: Integrating the AHP with
SWOT analysis. In: K. Dellman (Ed.), Proceedings of the sixth international symposium on the
analytic hierarchy process ISAHP 2001 (pp. 189199), August 24, 2001, Kursaal Bern,
Berne-Switzerland. Bern.
Karkkainen, L., Kurttila, M. Salminen, O., & Viiri, H. (2014). Effects of energy wood harvesting
on timber production potential and biological diversity in North Karelia, Finland. Forest
Science, (in press).
Keeney, R. L. (1992). Value-focused thinking. A path to creative decision making. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press. 416 p.
Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and value
tradeoffs. New York: Wiley. 569 p.
Kukrety, S., Jose, S., & Alavalapati, J. R. R. (2013). Exploring stakeholders perceptions with
Analytic Hierarchy Process A case study of Red Sanders (Pterocarpus santalinus L.)
restoration in India. Restoration Ecology, 21, 777784.
Kurttila, M., Pesonen, M., Kangas, J., & Kajanus, M. (2000). Utilizing the analytic hierarchy
process (AHP) in SWOT analysis A hybrid method and its application to a forestcertifica-
tion case. Forest Policy and Economics, 1, 4152.
Laskey, K. B., & Fischer, G. W. (1987). Estimating utility functions in the presence of response
error. Management Science, 33, 965980.
Leskinen, P. (2001). Statistical methods for measuring preferences. Publications in Social Sci-
ences 48, Doctoral thesis, University of Joensuu.
Leskinen, P., & Kangas, J. (1998). Analysing uncertainties of interval judgement data in multiple-
criteria evaluation of forest plans. Silva Fennica, 32, 363372.
Leskinen, P., & Kangas, J. (2005a). Multi-criteria natural resource management with preferentially
dependent decision criteria. Journal of Environmental Management, 77, 244251.
Leskinen, P., & Kangas, J. (2005b). Rank reversals in multi-criteria decision analysis with
statistical modelling of ratio scale pairwise comparisons. Journal of the Operational Research
Society, 56, 855861.
78 4 Multi-criteria Decision Problems

Leskinen, P., Kangas, J., & Pasanen, A.-M. (2003). Assessing ecological values with dependent
explanatory variables in multi-criteria forest ecosystem management. Ecological Modelling,
170, 112.
Leskinen, P., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2004). Rank-based modelling of preferences in multi-
criteria decision making. European Journal of Operational Research, 158, 721733.
Malczewski, J. (1999). GIS and multi-criteria decision analysis. New York: Wiley. 392 p.
Mendoza, G. A., & Prabhu, R. (2001). A fuzzy Analytic Hierarchy Process for assessing biodi-
versity conservation. In D. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.), The
analytic hierarchy process in natural resource and environmental decision making (Managing
forest ecosystems, Vol. 3, pp. 219235). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Mendoza, G. A., & Sprouce, W. (1989). Multiobjective programming for generating alternatives.
Forest Science, 33, 458468.
Miettinen, K. (1999). Nonlinear multiobjective optimization. New York: Springer.
Murray, D. M., & von Gadow, K. (1991). Prioritizing mountain catchment areas. Journal of
Environmental Management, 32, 357366.
Mustajoki, J., & Hamalainen, R. (2005). A preference programming approach to make the even
swaps method even easier. Decision Analysis, 2, 110123.
Mustajoki, J., & Hamalainen, R. (2006). Smart-Swaps Decision support for the PrOACT process
with the even swaps method. Manuscript.
Pesonen, M., Ahola, J., Kurttila, M., Kajanus, M., & Kangas, J. (2001a). Applying AWOT to
forest industry investment strategies: Case Study of a Finnish Company in North America. In
D. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic hierarchy process
in natural resource and environmental decision making (pp. 131148). Dordrecht: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Pesonen, M., Kurttila, M., Kangas, J., Kajanus, M., & Heinonen, P. (2001b). Assessing priorities
using AWOT among resource management strategies at Finnish Forest and Park Service.
Forest Science, 47, 534541.
Poyhonen, M., & Hamalainen, R. P. (1998). Notes on the weighting biases in value trees. Journal
of Behavioral Decision Making, 11, 139150.
Poyhonen, M., Vrolijk, H., & Hamalainen, R. P. (2001). Behavioral and procedural consequences
of structural variation in value trees. European Journal of Operational Research, 134,
216227.
Prabhu, R., Colfer, C. J. P., & Dudley, R. G. (1999). Guidelines for developing, testing and
selecting criteria and indicators for sustainable forest management. The Criteria and Indica-
tors Toolbox Series, vol. 1. Center for International Forestry Research, Bogor. 186 pp. http://
www.cifor.org/publications/pdf_files/Books/toolbox-1.pdf
Pukkala, T. (2006). Monsu-metsasuunnitteluohjelmisto. Versio 5. Ohjelmiston toiminta ja kaytt o.
Mimeograph. 53 p.
Pukkala, T., & Kangas, J. (1993). A heuristic optimization method for forest planning and decision
making. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 8, 560570.
Pukkala, T., Kellomaki, S., & Mustonen, E. (1988). Predicting the amenity of a tree stand.
Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 3, 533544.
Pykalainen, J., Kangas, J., & Loikkanen, T. (1999). Interactive decision analysis in participatory
strategic forest planning: Experiences from State owned boreal forests. Journal of Forest
Economics, 5, 341364.
Raucher, H. M., Lloyd, F. T., Loftis, D. L., & Twery, M. J. (2000). A practical decision-analysis
process for forest ecosystem management. Computers and Electronics in Agriculture, 27,
195226.
Reynolds, K. M. (2001). Prioritizing salmon habitat restoration with the AHP, SMART, and
uncertain data. In D. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. M. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic
hierarchy process in natural resources and environmental decision making (pp. 199218).
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
References 79

Saaty, T. L. (1977). A scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures. Journal of Mathe-
matical Psychology, 15, 234281.
Saaty, T. L. (1980). The analytic hierarchy process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Saaty, T. L. (1990). The analytic hierarchy process: Planning, priority setting, resource allocation
(2nd ed.). Pittsburgh: RWS Publications.
Saaty, T. L. (2001). Decision making with dependence and feedback. The analytic network process
(2nd ed.). Pittsburgh: RWS Publications.
Saaty, T. L. (2013). The modern science of multicriteria decision making and its practical
applications. The AHP/ANP Approach, 61(5), 11011118.
Salo, A. A., & Hamalainen, R. P. (1992). Preference assessment by imprecise ratio statements.
Operations Research, 40, 10531061.
Schmoldt, D., Kangas, J., Mendoza, G. A., & Pesonen, M. (Eds.). (2001). The analytic hierarchy
process in natural resource and environmental decision making. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Schoemaker, P. J., & Waid, C. C. (1982). An experimental comparison of different approaches to
determining weights in additive utility models. Management Science, 28, 182196.
Stillwell, W. G., Seaver, D. A., & Edwards, D. (1981). A comparison of weight approximation
techniques in multiattribute utility decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human
Performance, 28, 6277.
Tell, B. (1976). A comparative study of some multiple-criteria methods. The Economic Research
Institute at the Stockholm School of Economics. 203 p.
Tell, B., & Wallenius, J. (1979). A survey of multiple-criteria decision methods and applications:
Utility theory and mathematical programming. Liiketaloudellinen aikakauskirja, 28, 322.
Vacik, H., & Lexer, M. J. (2001). Application of a spatial decision support system in managing the
protection forests of Vienna for sustained yield of water resources. Forest Ecology and
Management, 143, 6576.
von Winterfeldt, D., & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision analysis and behavioral research. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wolfslehner, B., Vacik, H., & Lexer, M. J. (2005). Application of the analytic network process in
multi-criteria analysis of sustainable forest management. Forest Ecology and Management,
207, 157170.
Zionts, S., & Wallenius, J. (1976). An interactive programming method for solving the multiple
criteria problem. Management Science, 22, 652663.
Zionts, S., & Wallenius, J. (1983). An interactive multiple objective linear programming method
for a class of underlying nonlinear utility functions. Management Science, 29, 519529.
Chapter 5
Uncertainty in Multi-criteria
Decision-Making

Abstract All forest-related decisions include uncertainty. Uncertainty can be from


several different sources like inventory data, growth and yield models, prices of
timber or carbon, costs of operations and preferences of the forest owners. The
uncertainties can be described in different ways, using a stochastic approach or a
fuzzy approach, for instance. Many multi-criteria analysis methods are able to deal
with uncertainty, but in each method the assumptions concerning the uncertainties
are unique, and these differences may affect the results obtained. In this chapter, we
present methods based on fuzzy numbers and fuzzy weighting, outranking methods
based on fuzzy preference relations and stochastic multi-criteria acceptability
analysis based on probability distributions. We discuss the drawbacks and benefits
of these different approaches for forest management.

5.1 Nature of Uncertainty

Often, the word uncertainty has been equated with random variability (Ferson and
Ginzburg 1996). In decision-making, the uncertainty is traditionally connected to
the unknown or uncertain future states of nature: the consequences of alternative
actions are not known, which makes choices risky.
Probability theory demands that probabilities should fulfil the Kolmogorov
axioms. It means that the probability of each event has to be greater than or equal
to zero (i.e. negative probabilities are not allowed), that the probability of the entire
set of events has to be one (i.e. some event in the whole set of events will occur with
probability 1) and that the probability of an union of disjoint events is the sum of
their individual probabilities (e.g. Williams 1991). It also means that the probability
of a union of an event and its negation must add up to one.
Probabilities can be either objective or subjective. Objective probabilities can be
calculated for events that can be repeated infinitely many times, for instance, the
probabilities of obtaining heads or tails when tossing a coin. Subjective probabil-
ities describe beliefs of persons, for instance, someone may believe that a certain
sports team will win with 0.7 probability. The Bayesian probability theory may be
the best known example of utilising subjective probabilities (Carlin and Louis
2000).

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 81


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_5
82 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Additivity requirement in probability theory means that if the decision-maker


has no idea of the probability of some event, like whether there is life in Mars or not,
both alternatives (there is and there is not) need to be assigned a 0.5 probability.
Assigning so high a probability to either option may seem counterintuitive in the
case of complete ignorance. There exist theories, in which also nonadditive sub-
jective beliefs can be dealt with, for example, the possibility theory (Dubois and
Prade 1988) and the evidence theory (Schafer 1976; Klir and Harmanec 1997).
These theories were developed to deal with situations, where the classical or
Bayesian probability theory was deemed too normative. They are argued to be
suitable especially in cases where human opinions, judgement and decisions are
involved (Zimmermann 1985; Dubois and Prade 1988).
In decision analysis, people may be uncertain about their preferences. People do
not know, for instance, which alternative they prefer with respect to a certain
criterion, or they do not know exactly how much they prefer a certain alternative.
Furthermore, there may be uncertainty concerning the performances of the alterna-
tives with respect to the criteria. One way to reflect such uncertainty is to present the
uncertain preferences and/or performances using linguistic scales. For instance, the
criterion values with respect to some characteristics, like the recreational value of a
certain area, may be evaluated as low, medium or high. In another occasion,
one alternative may be slightly preferred, strongly preferred or extremely
preferred when compared to another alternative.
In decision analysis, all judgements, numerical or linguistic, need to be
transformed to numbers or logical rules in order to make a recommendation. In
different decision support tools, different approaches have been developed to
deal with these uncertainties (for a review see Kangas and Kangas 2004a). One
commonly used approach for dealing with linguistic uncertainty is to use the fuzzy
set approach (Zimmermann 1985).

5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory

5.2.1 Membership Functions and Fuzzy Numbers

Fuzzy set theory was first presented by Zadeh (1965). The basis of the fuzzy set
theory is a membership function (x), which describes the degree by which a
certain statement is true (Zimmermann 1985). For example, a statement a tree is
defoliated can be more or less true. If we had a crisp definition, like a tree is
defoliated if it has lost at least 50 % of its needles or leaves, the membership
function would only have values 0 and 1, and fuzzy sets would not be needed.
Otherwise, a membership function (Fig. 5.1) for a fuzzy set A~ could be, for
example,
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory 83

1.2

0.8
membership

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
-0.2
needle loss

Fig. 5.1 Example of a membership function


x  20
A~ x 0; x < 20 %; ; 20 %  x  60 % 1; x  60 % 5:1
60  20

where x is the percentage of needles lost (in this case), and A~ x 2 0; 1. The
membership function needs not to be linear. Then, the fuzzy set A~ is defined as
  
~ x, ~ x jx 2 X , where X is the set of possible values of x (0100 % in this
A A
case) (e.g. Niskanen 2003).
Fuzzy numbers can also be defined. Fuzzy numbers are such membership
functions, which are convex (Chen and Hwang 1992; Malczewski 1999). The
membership function should be piecewisely continuous, and given four real num-
bers, a  b  c  d,

M x 0, 8x  a:

M(x) is increasing in [a, b] and decreasing in [c, d].


M x 1, x 2 b; c:

M x 0, 8x  d:

The fuzzy numbers can be, for instance, triangular or trapezoidal in shape
(Fig. 5.2). The triangular and trapezoidal fuzzy numbers are presented based
on the numbers a, b, c and d above, i.e. fuzzy number M (a, b, c, d ). In triangular
form b c. These fuzzy numbers can also be presented as so-called L-R
fuzzy numbers M0 (b, c, (ba), (dc)) (b, c, , ), i.e. and describe the
84 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

1.2

0.8
membership

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
x

Fig. 5.2 Two examples of fuzzy numbers, triangular and trapezoidal

deviation from the peak values b and c to left and right, respectively (e.g. Chen
and Hwang, p. 89).
In order to utilise fuzzy numbers, they require arithmetic rules. For instance, the
sum of two trapezoidal fuzzy numbers M and N is (e.g. Chen and Hwang 1992,
p. 93, Mattila 2002)

M N a; b; c; d e; f ; g; h a e, b f , c g, d h 5:2

and their product is

M  N a; b; c; d  e; f ; g; h a  e, b  f , c  g, d  h: 5:3

A subtraction of two fuzzy numbers is

M  N a; b; c; d  e; f ; g; h a  h, b  g, c  f , d  e 5:4

and their division is

M=N a; b; c; d=e; f ; g; h a=h, b=g, c= f , d=e: 5:5

In products and divisions these formulas apply only if both fuzzy numbers are
positive, i.e. M x 0, 8x < 0. Otherwise, different formulas need to be applied.
Furthermore, rules based on which the fuzzy numbers can be ranked are needed.
Usually the first and foremost method for ranking fuzzy numbers is just to look at
the drawn curves and use intuition (Cheng 1999). If this fails, different rules can be
used. A number of such rules have been presented in the literature (see, e.g., Chen
and Hwang 1992; Chang et al. 2006). Since the fuzzy numbers can have
overlapping areas, their ranking is not self-evident, and different rules may give
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory 85
Membership value

Membership value
Utility Utility
Membership value

Membership value
Utility Utility

Fig. 5.3 In the upper left figure, ranking of the fuzzy numbers is obvious, but in the later three
examples it is not

different answers (Fig. 5.3). Moreover, one rule may not produce a clear ranking,
and therefore several rules may be needed.
One possible solution is to rank the numbers based on so-called -cut (Adamo
1980; Chen and Hwang 1992). It means that the decision-maker defines an accep-
tance threshold for the fuzzy number. Then, a line is drawn on the figure on that
level of membership value (Fig. 5.4), and the fuzzy number having greater maxi-
mum value at that level is deemed better. In Fig. 5.4, number M2 is better at the
-cut level 0.7. If the -cut level were smaller than 0.5, e.g. 0, M1 would be deemed
better. Thus, this rule may produce controversial results in some cases.
Many rules for ranking fuzzy numbers are based on so-called defuzzification,
i.e. calculating crisp measures from the fuzzy numbers. Many methods have been
proposed for defuzzification, but the most commonly used methods are
(e.g. Hellendoorn and Thomas 1993; Yager 1996; Rondeau et al. 1997) mean of
maximum (MOM)

bc
m1 5:6
2

and centre of area/gravity (COA)

d
xxdx
a
m2 : 5:7
d
xdx
a
86 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

1.1

0.9 M1 M2
Membership value
0.7

0.5

0.3

0.1

-0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Utility

Fig. 5.4 Ranking of fuzzy numbers M1 and M2 with -cut level 0.7

The MOM criterion can be criticised because it does not take into account the
divergence of the fuzzy number. The COA criterion is better in the sense that it
accounts for all the possible solutions, but it does not necessarily choose a solution
having the maximum membership value (Rondeau et al. 1997). They produce
similar results, however, in the case of symmetric fuzzy numbers. The difference
is notable only if the fuzzy numbers are more complicated.
It may be that neither of these criteria can produce a ranking for two fuzzy
numbers. Then, the divergence or spread (da) of the fuzzy numbers can be used in
ranking. From two fuzzy numbers otherwise similar, the fuzzy number with smaller
spread is considered better.

Example 5.1
The MOM criterion in the fuzzy numbers of Fig. 5.4 are 0.4 for M1 and 0.5
for M2. Thus, based on MOM, M2 is easily seen to be better. The COA
criterion for M2 is calculated as


0:4
0:7
x  0:3 0:7  x
x dx x dx
0:1 0:3
0:3 0:4 0:018 0:075 0:093
0:465

0:4
0:7 0:05 0:15 0:2
x  0:3 0:7  x
dx dx
0:1 0:3
0:3 0:4

and for M1 as

(continued)
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory 87

Example 5.1 (continued)



0:5
0:6
x  0:2 0:6  x
x dx x dx
0:3 0:1
0:2 0:5 0:059 0:026 0:085
0:425

0:5
0:6 0:15 0:05 0:2
x  0:2 0:6  x
dx dx
0:3 0:1
0:2 0:5

which would also give M2 as better.

5.2.2 Fuzzy Goals in Decision-Making

In decision-making, the membership function may describe degree of satisfaction


with respect to some goal (or some constraint). It can be given, for instance, with a
function
8
< x  0, x<a
a
A~ x i j x , a <x<b 5:8
:b a
1, x  b

where a is the lower border and b is the upper border for the satisfaction, i.e. the
satisfaction is zero when x < a and it reaches its maximum when x  b. The borders
a and b, defining the membership function, can be given by the decision-maker.
For decision-making, the different goals need first to be aggregated describing
the overall desirability of each alternative, and second, the alternatives need to be
ranked according to these aggregated values (Bellman and Zadeh 1970; Zimmer-
mann 1985). In a traditional way of fuzzy decision-making (e.g. Bellman and Zadeh
1970; Malczewski 1999; Ducey and Larson 1999; Kangas et al. 2006b), a logical
and operator would be used to make a combination. An intersection of two fuzzy
~ \B
sets, A ~ , is then defined as a minimum of their membership functions as
 
A~ x ^ B~ x Min A~ x, B~ x 5:9

Then, the recommendation would be the alternative, for which the minimum
satisfaction value is the largest (Bellman and Zadeh 1970). However, this procedure
allows for no compensation or trade-offs between the criteria in the sense of utility
theory (e.g. Dubois et al. 1996). The bad degree of satisfaction with respect to one
criterion cannot be compensated by a good satisfaction level on another. In fact, it
models soft constraints more than soft goals (Dubois et al. 1994).
The min aggregation is one example of the so-called t-norms, which all are
non-compensatory in nature (e.g. Eastman and Jiang 1996; Choi and Oh 2000).
88 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Another example of t-norms is the product aggregation, A ~ B


~ , which is simply the
product of the membership functions A~ x  B~ x (Zimmermann 1985, p. 29).
Another possibility for aggregating is the logical or procedure (from the
family of t-conorms). In this procedure, the union of two sets is described with
the maximum of their membership functions as
 
A~ x _ B~ x Max A~ x, B~ x : 5:10

This approach, on the other hand, could be too liberally compensating (e.g. Eastman
and Jiang 1996; Malczewski 1999). When at least one of the criteria reaches the
maximum level 1, the aggregation also gets value 1. Another aggregation method of
the same family is the algebraic sum A~ B ~ with aggregation
  
A~ x B~ x 1  1  A~ x 1  B~ x : 5:11

Unfortunately, neither and nor or types of aggregation behave in a way


needed in decision analysis. Therefore, aggregations that are in the middle of these
extremes have been searched for. One group of these is formed by different mean
operators, such as arithmetic average. In ordered weighted average (OWA), the
membership functions are weighted based on their ranks (Yager 1988). For
instance, the largest membership function value gets the largest weight and the
smallest the smallest weight and so on. This is used to define the degree of
compensation among the criteria, the so-called andness and orness of the
aggregation (see, e.g., Eastman and Jiang 1996; Despic and Simonovich 2000).
The larger weight is given to the largest membership function value, the greater the
orness and the larger the weight given to the smallest membership function value,
the greater the andness.
Another important aggregation method is the -norm (Zimmermann and Zysno
1980; Zimmermann 1985), in which the algebraic sum and product aggregation
methods are combined. The aggregation is
Y 1  Y 
~ i 1 1  i 5:12

where is a parameter [0,1] defined by the user defining the degree of andness
and orness. The larger this parameter, the greater the degree of andness is.
None of these aggregation methods acknowledges the possible differences in the
importances of the criteria, which is one of the basic concepts in decision analysis
and multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT). However, weighting the criteria is quite
possible also in fuzzy decision analysis. For instance, Bellman and Zadeh (1970)
proposed a weighted mean aggregation method
X
i i 5:13
X
with weights similar to traditional utility functions and scaling to one as i 1.
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory 89

In addition to this mean operator, weights can be applied also in other aggrega-
tion methods. For instance, Yager (1978) proposed using exponential weight in min
operator, so that important criteria would have weight greater than zero, making the
membership grade smaller, and less important criteria would have weights smaller
than zero, making the membership grade larger. Then, the minimum of membership
grades is more likely to be defined by the important objectives. The -norm can also
be weighted, giving (e.g. Despic and Simonovich 2000)
Y 1  Y 
~ i i 1 1  i i 5:14

In the following examples, the weights have been assumed to be non-fuzzy.

Example 5.2
The data used in the example is from Example 4.5 (Table 5.1). It is assumed
that for each criterion the full satisfaction is obtained, if the criterion value is
at least 95 % of the maximum value (parameter b in Eq. 5.8). The lower
border for satisfaction (parameter a in Eq. 5.8) was set to 20 % (38.34), 50 %
(0.355) and 80 % (5.56) of the maximum criterion value for net incomes,
stumpage value and scenic beauty, respectively. Then, the degrees of satis-
faction for each alternative and each criterion are in Table 5.2. With different
aggregation rules, the results are presented in Table 5.3.

Table 5.1 Data from Example 4.5


Stumpage value Scenic beauty
Alternative Net income, 1000 Million Index
NAT 0 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 38 0.6 5.4
GAME 33 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

Table 5.2 Degrees of satisfaction


Alternative Net income, 1000 Stumpage value Scenic beauty
NAT 0 1 1
SCEN 0.29 0 1
NORM 0 0.77 0.98
GAME 0 0.8 1
MREG 0.44 0.49 0.75
INC 1 0 0.4

(continued)
90 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.2 (continued)


Table 5.3 Results with different aggregation rules
Mean
Alternative Min Product Max Sum Mean weighted -norm 0.5
NAT 0 0.000 1 1 0.667 0.400 1.000
SCEN 0 0.000 1 1 0.430 0.374 1.000
NORM 0 0.000 0.98 1 0.583 0.350 0.998
GAME 0 0.000 1 1 0.600 0.360 1.000
MREG 0.44 0.162 0.75 0.93 0.560 0.512 1.366
INC 0 0.000 1 1 0.467 0.680 1.000
The mean rule selected the NAT alternative. In Example 4.5, incomes
were assumed to be the most important criterion, but when weights were not
used, its bad degree could be compensated by the good degrees of two other
criteria. If similar weights were used also in this example, namely, incomes
0.6, and stumpage value and scenic beauty weight 0.2 each, INC would be the
choice, when the original choice was MREG. This is because the satisfaction
level of net incomes is quite low for alternatives other than INC. It means that
the defined satisfaction level also emphasises the importance of the most
important criterion. The t-conorms max and sum could not select one best
alternative. The non-compensative t-norms min and product selected clearly a
compromise value, MREG.

Example 5.3
The same problem was then solved using the OWA analysis. For this, the
satisfaction levels were ordered from largest to smallest. Weight 0.1 was then
given to the largest value, 0.3 to the middle one and 0.6 to the smallest value.
It means that the andness level in this analysis is great, i.e. the minimum
levels of satisfaction are emphasised in the analysis. Then, again, MREG is
the selected alternative, as it is the only alternative having a satisfaction level
greater than zero for all criteria (Table 5.4).
Table 5.4 Results with Alternative Largest Middle Smallest OWA
OWA aggregation
NAT 1 1 0 0.400
SCEN 1 0.29 0 0.187
NORM 0.98 0.77 0 0.329
GAME 1 0.8 0 0.340
MREG 0.75 0.49 0.44 0.486
INC 1 0.4 0 0.220
5.2 Fuzzy Set Theory 91

When the degree of satisfaction is expressed as one number, it can be argued that
the information is no fuzzier than in classical MCDM methods (Hannan 1983).
Only the form of scaling the original scale to utility (or satisfaction) scale is
different; otherwise, the satisfaction levels could as well be interpreted as
sub-utility function values.

5.2.3 Fuzzy Additive Weighting

Fuzzy decision analysis can also be based on linguistic criterion values and fuzzy
weights. For such a situation, fuzzy additive weighting method has been proposed
(Bonissone 1982; Chen and Hwang 1992; Malczewski 1999, p. 230, Kangas
et al. 2007). The fuzzy utility is of form

X
m
Fi aj c
ij 5:15
j1

where a denotes the fuzzy weight and c the fuzzy criterion value. In this method,
both the weights and the criteria can be linguistic variables, i.e. variables that are
evaluated with vague terms, which are then presented using fuzzy numbers. For
instance, the criteria could be slightly important or highly important and one
criterion, for instance, the risks caused to environment could be presented with low
risk, medium risk and high risk. Many other procedures have also been
presented for utilising fuzzy numbers in decision analysis, but this method is the
simplest.

Example 5.4
In the data of the previous example, the criteria are assumed to be linguistic
variables having five levels, very low, low, medium, high and very high with
respect to each criterion. The criteria, on the other hand, were having impor-
tance evaluated using scales low, moderate and high. Then, if the linguistic
variables were given values as in Table 5.5, performances as in Table 5.6 and
importances as in Table 5.7, the fuzzy criteria values times the fuzzy impor-
tance weights can be calculated as fuzzy numbers (Table 5.8). The fuzzy
numbers representing the overall utility are obtained as a fuzzy number
calculated from the sum of these fuzzy numbers (Table 5.9). The
recommended alternative is selected based on the mean of maximum m1. In
this case, the selected alternative is the MREG alternative. The resulting
fuzzy numbers are also presented in Fig. 5.5.

(continued)
92 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.4 (continued)

Table 5.5 Example 4.5 with linguistic performance expressions


Alternative Net income Stumpage value Scenic beauty
Importance High Moderate Low
NAT VL VH M
SCEN M L H
NORM L H M
GAME L H M
MREG H M L
INC VH VL VL

Table 5.6 Performance Criteria values


values as fuzzy numbers
VL (0.05, 0.2, 0.2, 0.35)
L (0.2, 0.35, 0.35, 0.5)
M (0.35, 0.5, 0.5, 0.65)
H (0.5, 0.65, 0.65, 0.8)
VH (0.65, 0.8, 0.8, 0.95)

Table 5.7 Importances as Importances


fuzzy numbers
Low (0.1, 0.25, 0.25, 0.4)
Moderate (0.35, 0.5, 0.5, 0.65)
High (0.6, 0.75, 0.75, 0.9)

Table 5.8 Fuzzy criteria numbers multiplied by criterion weights


Alternative Net incomes Stumpage value Scenic beauty
NAT 0.03, 0.15, 0.15, 0.32 0.23, 0.40,0.40, 0.62 0.04, 0.13, 0.13, 0.26
SCEN 0.21, 0.38, 0.38, 0.59 0.07, 0.18, 0.18, 0.33 0.05. 0.16, 0.16, 0.32
NORM 0.12, 0.26, 0.26, 0.45 0.18, 0.33, 0.33, 0.52 0.04, 0.13, 0.13, 0.26
GAME 0.12, 0.26, 0.26, 0.45 0.18, 0.33, 0.33, 0.52 0.04, 0.13, 0.13, 0.26
MREG 0.3, 0.49, 0.49, 0.72 0.12, 0.25, 0.25, 0.42 0.02, 0.09, 0.09, 0.20
INC 0.39, 0.6, 0.6, 0.86 0.02, 0.10, 0.10, 0.23 0.01, 0.05, 0.05, 0.14

Table 5.9 Overall fuzzy Alternative Overall utility m1


utility
NAT 0.29, 0.68, 0.68, 1.19 0.68
SCEN 0.33, 0.71, 0.71, 1.23 0.71
NORM 0.33, 0.71, 0.71, 1.23 0.71
GAME 0.33, 0.71, 0.71, 1.23 0.71
MREG 0.44, 0.83, 0.83, 1.34 0.83
INC 0.41, 0.75, 0.75,1.22 0.75

(continued)
5.3 Outranking Methods 93

Example 5.4 (continued)

Fig. 5.5 The fuzzy numbers that describe the membership in relation to utility values

5.3 Outranking Methods

5.3.1 Outline

Outranking methods serve as one alternative for approaching complex choice


problems with multiple criteria. Outranking indicates the degree of dominance of
one alternative over another (e.g. Rogers and Bruen 1998b). The outranking
methods enable the utilisation of incomplete value information and, for example,
judgements on ordinal measurement scale (e.g. Rogers and Bruen 1998b). They
provide the (partial) preference ranking of the alternatives, not a cardinal measure
of the preference relations.
In outranking methods, strong assumptions concerning the true preference struc-
ture of the decision-maker are avoided (e.g. Vincke 1992, Bouyssou et al. 2001). It is
not necessary to assume that a utility function exists or that it can be described with
some certain function form. The question is whether there is enough information to
state that one alternative is at least as good as another. The outranking approach,
consequently, concentrates on comparing the alternatives in a pairwise manner.
94 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

In each case, the problem is formulated with a set of distinct alternatives ai, i 1,
. . ., n and a set of decision criteria gj, j 1, . . ., p so that gj(ai) represents the
performance of alternative i with respect to criteria j. These criteria may be ordinal
or even descriptive, on the contrary to most decision aid methods. The decision
problem is assumed not to be hierarchical like in AHP, for example. This, however,
is not a problem since all hierarchical problems can also be presented as flat ones,
i.e. use only the lowest-level criteria. Thus, similar decision problems can be
analysed using either AHP or outranking. The hierarchical presentation in the
former serves as a tool for designing the problem.
The outranking methods have been used, for example, for choosing the solid
waste management system (Hokkanen and Salminen 1997a, c), for locating the
waste treatment facility (Hokkanen and Salminen 1997b), for nuclear waste man-
agement (Briggs et al. 1990), for irrigation system evaluation (Raju and Pillai 1999)
and other environmental impact analysis (EIA) projects. In forestry, outranking has
been tested in a few cases (e.g. Kangas et al. 2001a, b).
The families of ELECTRE and PROMETHEE are the most widely known
outranking methods. The ELECTRE methods have originally been developed by
Bernard Roy (1968). Several versions of the ELECTRE method have been
presented for different situations: ELECTRE I and IS are designed for selection
problems, ELECTRE TRI for sorting problems and ELECTRE II, III and IV for
ranking problems (see Roy 1991, Yu 1992 and Rogers et al. 2000). In this book,
only the ELECTRE III method of this family is presented. The PROMETHEE
methods were developed in the 1980s (see Brans et al. 1986).
In PROMETHEE I and II and ELECTRE III outranking methods, the criteria are
treated as so-called pseudo-criteria (Brans et al. 1986, see e.g. Hokkanen and
Salminen 1997a, b, c). This means that a threshold model is applied to the original
criteria value. If the criteria values are sufficiently close to each other, they are
indifferent to the decision-maker, and if the difference between the criteria values is
sufficiently large, there is no doubt which alternative is better according to that
criterion. In between there is an area, in which the decision-maker is assumed to
hesitate between indifference and strict preference.
The uncertainty is dealt using pseudo-criteria (e.g. Vincke 1992). This means
that two thresholds, namely, indifference and preference thresholds, are defined.
The indifference threshold for criterion j, qj is a difference beneath which the
decision-maker is indifferent between two management alternatives ak and al, i.e.


ak Ial , g j ak  g j al  q j ; 5:16

where I denotes indifference and g j ak  g j al denotes the difference between


alternatives k and l with respect to criterion j. The preference threshold for criterion
j, pj is a difference above which the decision-maker strongly prefers management
alternative ak over al, i.e.

ak Pal , g j ak  g j al > p j ; 5:17


5.3 Outranking Methods 95

where P denotes preference. Between these two thresholds there is a zone where the
decision-maker hesitates between indifference and strong preference, i.e. the zone
of weak preference.

ak Qal , q j < g j ak  g j al  p j : 5:18

However, the zone of weak preference does not make sense if the criteria are
ordinal or descriptive. In such a case, the preference and indifference thresholds
could be set to zero. This means that if one alternative is considered better in an
ordinal scale, this alternative is strictly preferred.
The indifference threshold can be defined either with respect to the uncertainty
of the criteria values or as a threshold at which the differences become perceptible
to decision-makers (Rogers and Bruen 1998b). Maystre et al. (1994) defined the
indifference threshold as the minimum margin of uncertainty and the preference
threshold as the maximum margin of uncertainty with respect to different criteria.
Thus, the preference threshold implies that there is no doubt that a certain alterna-
tive is better than the other. However, there are no right values for the thresholds nor
the one-and-only right way to define them.

5.3.2 PROMETHEE Method

In PROMETHEE I and II, the outranking degree (ak,al), describing the credibility
of the outranking relation that alternative ak is better than alternative al, for each
pair of alternatives (ak,al) is calculated as

X
p
ak ; al w j F j ak ; al ; 5:19
j1

where Fj(ak,al) is the preference function and wj are the weights of the criteria. In
(5.19), it is assumed that the weights are scaled to add up to one. In outranking, the
weights are not interpreted as importances of the criteria in the same sense than in
MAUT or AHP but more like votes given to different criteria. The weights can be
obtained, for example, by giving scores from 1 to 7 to the criteria, with 1 given to
the least important criteria (Hokkanen and Salminen 1997a, b). However, the
weights could also be obtained from pairwise comparisons as in the AHP method.
In PROMETHEE outranking method, the threshold values are assumed to be
constant (see Salminen et al. 1998). The values of preference function Fj(ak,al) for a
pair of alternatives ak and al with respect to criteria j are calculated using thresholds
pj and qj as
96 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

8
> 1, if g j ak  g j al  p j
>
>
>
>
>
>
< 0, if g j ak  g j al  q j
F j ak ; al   : 5:20
>
>
>
> g a  g j al  q j
>
> j k
>
: , otherwise
pj  qj

This formula can be interpreted to give a fuzzy degree of preference of one


alternative over another.
In this formula, the linear threshold function is utilised (Fig. 5.6a). Six different
forms of the threshold function can be applied. Three of them can be derived from
the linear threshold function, by setting q 0, q p or q p 0. The two other
forms are the step function and the non-linear or Gaussian function (see Brans
et al. 1986). These, however, have a slightly different interpretation than the others.
The criteria and threshold values together constitute the pseudo-criteria.

F(d) F(d)
1
1

d d
-p -q q p -p p

F(d) F(d)

1
1
1/2

d
d -p -q q p
-q q
F(d)
1

d
--

Fig. 5.6 The preference F as a function of difference (d g j ak  g j al ) between alternatives


with respect to some criterion with different options
5.3 Outranking Methods 97

The outranking degrees are used to calculate for each alternative the leaving
flow
X  
ak ak , al =n  1; 5:21
l6k

the entering flow


X  
 ak al , ak = n  1 5:22
l6k

and the net flow

ak ak   ak : 5:23

In PROMETHEE I, the alternatives are ranked based on both the leaving and
entering flow. These rankings are then used to calculate a partial preorder, where
certain alternatives may remain incomparable. If one alternative is better than
another with respect to both negative and positive flow, then it is determined better.
In a case where one alternative is better according to positive flow and another with
respect to negative flow, these two alternatives are interpreted as incomparable.
In PROMETHEE II the net flow is used, which leads to complete ranking
(Hokkanen and Salminen 1997a, b). This ranking method utilises the cardinal
properties of the valuations, while PROMETHEE I uses the ordinal properties
(Bouyssou and Perny 1992, Bouyssou 1992).

Example 5.5
The data is the same as in Example 4.5 (see also Table 5.1). The values used
for the weights and preference and indifference thresholds are given in the
Table 5.10. It means that alternatives differing less than by 5000 are
considered as indifferent, but 20,000 means a clear preference difference.
Then, a matrix containing the preference function (F) values for each pair of
alternatives k and j, for the first criterion, namely, the net incomes, is
calculated (Table 5.11). In this case, the differences between the alternatives
were clear so that INC is clearly better than any other alternative, and MREG
is better than all the others except INC. Alternatives NORM and GAME are
indifferent.
Table 5.10 Weights and w q p
threshold values
Net incomes (1000 ) 0.6 5 20
Future timber value (million ) 0.2 0.05 0.2
Scenic value (index) 0.2 0.1 0.2

(continued)
98 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.5 (continued)


The same analysis is then done with respect to the future timber value
(Table 5.12) and with respect to scenic beauty (Table 5.13). With respect to
scenic beauty, the differences are again clear, but for stumpage value some of
the differences are in the weak preference zone. For instance, SCEN is weakly
preferred to INC. In that case, d 0.28  0.13, giving F (0.28  0.13  0.05)/
(0.2  0.05) 0.67. The credibility matrix is calculated as their weighted
average (Table 5.14). For instance, credibility for statement that INC outranks
NAT is calculated with 0.6  1.0 0.2  0.0 0.2  0.0 0.600. Finally, the
positive and negative flows are calculated from the credibility matrix
(Table 5.15). The alternatives are ranked here both according to net flows,
negative flows and positive flows into decreasing order. MREG alternative is
best with respect to net flow. Since INC and MREG cannot be separated based
on the positive flow, their rank is indetermined according to PROMETHEE I. In
this case, the ranking is fairly clear, but this is not the case generally.

Table 5.11 Preference function values with respect to net incomes


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
SCEN 1.0 0.0 1.0 1.0 0.0 0.0
NORM 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
GAME 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
MREG 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.0 0.0
INC 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.0

Table 5.12 With respect to future timber value


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.0 1.0 0.39 0.33 0.99 1.0
SCEN 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.67
NORM 0.0 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.27 1.0
GAME 0.0 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.33 1.0
MREG 0.0 1.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.0
INC 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Table 5.13 With respect to scenic beauty


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.0 0.0 1.0 0.0 1.0 1.0
SCEN 1.0 0.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0
NORM 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.0
GAME 0.0 0.0 1.0 0.0 1.0 1.0
MREG 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.0
INC 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

(continued)
5.3 Outranking Methods 99

Example 5.5 (continued)


Table 5.14 Credibility matrix
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.000 0.200 0.280 0.067 0.400 0.400
SCEN 0.800 0.000 0.800 0.800 0.200 0.333
NORM 0.600 0.200 0.000 0.000 0.053 0.400
GAME 0.600 0.200 0.200 0.000 0.267 0.400
MREG 0.600 0.800 0.600 0.600 0.000 0.400
INC 0.600 0.600 0.600 0.600 0.600 0.000

Table 5.15 Positive and Positive flow Negative flow Net flow
negative net flows
MREG 0.600 0.304 0.296
INC 0.600 0.387 0.213
SCEN 0.587 0.400 0.187
GAME 0.333 0.413 0.080
NORM 0.251 0.496 0.245
NAT 0.269 0.640 0.371

5.3.3 ELECTRE Method

The ELECTRE III method can be considered as a non-compensatory model


(Rogers and Bruen 1998a). It means that a really bad score of any alternative
with respect to any one criterion cannot necessarily be compensated for by good
scores in other criteria.
In ELECTRE III method, a concordance index C(ak,al) for each pair of alterna-
tives is computed, describing the strength of a claim that alternative ak is at least as
good as alternative al, utilising pseudo-criteria in a similar fashion as in
PROMETHEE method. The concordance index is calculated as

X
p
C ak ; al w j c j ak ; al ; 5:24
j1

where wj are the relative importance of the different criteria (scaled to add up to one
in the formula) and cj(ak,al) is the local concordance index, defined as
8
> 0, if g j al  g j ak  p j
>
>
>
>
>
>
< 1, if g j al  g j ak  q j
c j ak ; al   5:25
>
>
>
>  
>
>
p j g j a l g j a k
>
: , otherwise:
pj  qj
100 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

1,2 b not prefererred to a


1

0,8
b weakly prefererred to a
c(a,b)

0,6

0,4

0,2 b clearly prefererred to a


0
g(b)-g(a)
Fig. 5.7 Support of the local concordance index for claim that a is at least as good as b

In formula (5.25), constant threshold values are applied. However, in ELECTRE


III, the thresholds may be either constant or proportional to the criterion value, or
they could be expressed with a linear model as a function of the criterion value
(e.g. Rogers and Bruen 1998b).
The concordance index is interpreted a bit differently than the preference
relations F in PROMETHEE. Here, it is analysed if there is evidence against the
claim that alternative ak is at least as good as al, and if al is clearly preferred to ak, no
such evidence can be found. If the alternatives are indifferent, or gj(al)gj(ak) < 0,
then such evidence can be found (Fig. 5.7). In PROMETHEE, the evidence
supporting the claim that ak is better than al is searched for.
If the decision were based on the concordance indices of alternatives, weighted
with the importance of different criteria, the approach would basically be based on
an additive utility function similarly as in PROMETHEE method (see Salminen
et al. 1998). Then, the ratios of weights of different criteria would represent the
substitution rates between the different criteria. However, in ELECTRE III there is
also a so-called veto threshold vj, which is used to compute the discordance index
for the alternatives. The discordance index is used to model the degree of
incompensation between the criteria. This means that an alternative with a very
poor value of any one criterion cannot be chosen irrespective of the values of the
other criteria. It also means that the weights of the criteria cannot be interpreted as
substitution rates, but they represent votes for the criteria (Miettinen and Salminen
1999). The discordance index is defined for each criterion as
8
> 0, if g j al  g j ak  p j
>
>
>
>
>
>
< 1, if g j al  g j ak  v j
d j ak ; al   5:26
>
>
>
> g j al  g j ak  p j
>
>
>
: , otherwise:
vj  pj

The discordance indices of different criteria are not aggregated using the weights,
since one discordant criterion is sufficient to discard outranking. In environmental
5.3 Outranking Methods 101

planning the veto threshold is appropriate in a sense that some alternatives are not
found acceptable at all with respect to some criteria (Rogers and Bruen 1998b). The
closer the veto threshold vj is to the preference threshold pj, the more important the
criterion j can be considered (Roy 1991).
Finally, the degree of outranking is defined by S(ak,al) as
8
< Cak ; al , if J ak ; al
>
Y 1  d j ak ; al
Sak ; al Cak ; al , otherwise; 5:27
>
: 1  C a ; a
j2J a ;a k l
k l

where J(ak,al) is a set of criteria for which dj(ak,al) > C(ak,al) (Miettinen and
Salminen 1999).
In basic ELECTRE III method, a descending (Z1) and ascending (Z2) preorder is
constructed using the outranking degrees S. The final partial order Z Z1\Z2 is
constructed based on these two complete orders. The preorders Z1 and Z2 are
constructed using a descending and ascending distillation.
In descending distillation procedure, first the maximum credibility value is
searched for, max maxSak ; al . Then, a quality matrix is formed such that only
values that are sufficiently close to that are considered. Sufficiently close means
here S(ak,al) values that are greater than max  s, where s 0:3  0:15max
(Belton and Stewart 2002, p. 246). The quality matrix T(ak,al) is defined as

1, if Sak ; al >  s
T ak ; al 5:28
0, otherwise

Ranking is then based on the number of alternatives outranked by each alternative


minus the number of alternatives which outrank it, i.e. row sum minus the column sum
for each alternative. The set of alternatives having the largest qualification is the first
distillate D1. If this distillate contains only one alternative, the procedure is continued
in the set of alternatives A, excluding that one alternative, i.e. in group A\D1. If there
are more alternatives in D1, the distillation procedure is applied to alternatives inside
it. When the whole group of alternatives is distillated this way, the first preorder Z1 is
ready. Ascending distillation is carried out in the same way, except the alternatives
with the smallest qualification are searched for first (for details, see e.g. Maystre
et al. 1994; Buchanan et al. 1999; Rogers et al. 2000; Belton and Stewart 2002).
The two distillations are then combined to form a partial preorder. This is carried
out so that an alternative is ranked higher in the final order, if it is ranked higher in
both these distillations. If the alternatives are indifferent in both distillations, they
are deemed indifferent. In the obtained partial preorder, some alternatives may be
incomparable, i.e. their performance order cannot be determined. This is the case, if
one alternative is better with respect to one distillation but worse in another.
This possibility of incomparability was, at first, deemed an important quality of
ELECTRE method. However, it is quite inconvenient in practical decision aid
situations. A complete ranking may be obtained using, for example, the min
procedure (see Pirlot 1995). In the min procedure, the alternatives are ranked
102 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

according to the minimum outranking degree of each alternative. The alternative


having the highest minimum is ranked first, and so on (see Miettinen and Salminen
1999). The min procedure utilises the ordinal properties of the valuations (Pirlot
1995). Another possibility is to utilise the so-called median ranking (Roy
et al. 1986), where the incomparabilities are removed by comparing the ranks of
the two alternatives in the two distillations.
The PROMETHEE II method includes an indifference threshold and a prefer-
ence threshold, but not a veto threshold as ELECTRE III. Also the method by which
the alternatives are ranked differs, and thus, these methods may not always produce
similar results. However, given similar thresholds, and veto threshold high enough
in ELECTRE III, the outranking degrees produced with these methods are identical
(Salminen et al. 1998).
The outranking methods are often used for group decision-making situations. In
group decision-making, the analyst typically chooses the values for the thresholds,
and the decision-makers only choose the weights of the criteria. Usually, each
decision-maker gives his/her own weights, and in the analysis the median or mean
values for the weights are used (Roy 1991). However, it is also important to study
the effect of the extreme values to the weights in a sensitivity analysis.

Example 5.6
Example 5.5 is analysed again with ELECTRE III, using the min approach
for ranking the alternatives. In this example, the same weights and preference
and indifference thresholds are used as above. In addition, however, a veto
threshold for each criterion is added. The values for these parameters are
presented in the Table 5.16.
As the concordance index matrices c for each criterion are almost similar
to those of PROMETHEE (except that alternatives at least as good are
searched for, i.e. each alternative is at least as good as itself), only the
resulting concordance matrix C is presented (Table 5.17).

Table 5.16 Weights and the w q p v


threshold values
Net incomes 0.6 5 20 200
Future timber value 0.2 0.05 0.2 2
Scenic beauty 0.2 0.1 0.2 2

Table 5.17 Resulting concordance matrix


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1.000 0.200 0.400 0.400 0.400 0.400
SCEN 0.800 1.000 0.800 0.800 0.200 0.400
NORM 0.720 0.200 1.000 0.800 0.400 0.400
GAME 0.933 0.200 1.000 1.000 0.400 0.400
MREG 0.600 0.800 0.947 0.733 1.000 0.400
INC 0.600 0.667 0.600 0.600 0.600 1.000

(continued)
5.3 Outranking Methods 103

Example 5.6 (continued)


The discordance matrices are next calculated (Table 5.18). For instance,
the discordance of the claim that NAT is at least as good as INC with respect
to net incomes is (191.7-0-20)/(20020) 0.954, i.e. fairly high
(Table 5.18a). The other alternatives all have fairly high discordance with
the claim that they are at least as good as INC alternative with respect to net
incomes. When calculating the final degree of outranking for NAT over INC,
the concordance is reduced because of the discordance with respect to net
incomes, so that the final outranking degree is 0.4(10.954)/(10.4)
0.4  0.046/0.6 0.031. INC alternative also has some discordance with
respect to claims that it is at least as good as other alternatives with respect
to future timber value and scenic beauty. Since these discordances are smaller
than the concordances of the same claims, they do not affect. The final
outranking degree matrix S is presented in Table 5.19. When these outranking
degrees for each alternative are ranked from smallest to largest, it is clear that
the minimum outranking degree is the highest for INC alternative.

Table 5.18 Discordances with respect to (a), (b) and (c)


(a) Net incomes
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.000 0.331 0.100 0.072 0.457 0.954
SCEN 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.015 0.512
NORM 0.000 0.120 0.000 0.000 0.246 0.743
GAME 0.000 0.148 0.000 0.000 0.274 0.771
MREG 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.386
INC 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(b) The future timber value
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
SCEN 0.128 0.000 0.067 0.072 0.017 0.000
NORM 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
GAME 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
MREG 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
INC 0.211 0.000 0.150 0.156 0.100 0.000
(c) The scenic beauty
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
SCEN 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
NORM 0.000 0.111 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
GAME 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
MREG 0.056 0.167 0.000 0.056 0.000 0.000
INC 0.222 0.333 0.111 0.222 0.056 0.000

(continued)
104 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.6 (continued)


If the qualification matrix T is calculated from S, with the largest outranking
degree being 1, then s 0.15 so that only outranking degrees greater than 0.85
are counted. The resulting T matrix is presented in Table 5.20 and the row and
column sums, as well as qualifications, in Table 5.21. In the qualifications,
GAME alternative has the best qualification, and it would be the first alterna-
tive in the descending preorder. The rest of the alternatives would be included
in a similar analysis for defining the rest of the preorder.

Table 5.19 Final outranking matrix


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1.000 0.167 0.400 0.400 0.362 0.031
SCEN 0.800 1.000 0.800 0.800 0.200 0.326
NORM 0.720 0.200 1.000 0.800 0.400 0.171
GAME 0.933 0.200 1.000 1.000 0.400 0.153
MREG 0.600 0.800 0.947 0.733 1.000 0.400
INC 0.600 0.667 0.600 0.600 0.600 1.000

Table 5.20 Qualification matrix T


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1 0 0 0 0 0
SCEN 0 1 0 0 0 0
NORM 0 0 1 0 0 0
GAME 1 0 1 1 0 0
MREG 0 0 1 0 1 0
INC 0 0 0 0 0 1

Table 5.21 Row and column Row sum Column sum Q


sums and qualifications Q for
NAT 1 2 1
each alternative
SCEN 1 1 0
NORM 1 3 2
GAME 3 1 2
MREG 2 1 1
INC 1 1 0

5.3.4 Other Outranking Methods

There are a wide range of related methods, but those do not have as wide interna-
tional usage as the presented methods. For example, fuzzy PROMETHEE utilises
fuzzy numbers in describing the performance of the alternatives with respect to
certain criteria in addition to fuzzy relations (Goumas and Lygerou 2000). There are
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 105

also attempts to include the uncertainty in the performance values using probability
distributions (dAvignon and Vincke 1988).

5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis

5.4.1 Stochastic Multi-criteria Acceptability Analysis


(SMAA)

It is also possible to account for uncertainty in a probabilistic framework. The effect


in both the weights of the criteria and the performance of the alternatives with
respect to these criteria can be assumed stochastic. Then, it can be analysed with a
Monte Carlo analysis what is the probability that a certain alternative beats all the
other alternatives or that a certain alternative beats another alternative. The distri-
bution of utilities for each alternative with respect to all decision criteria simulta-
neously can be calculated by sampling the distribution of weights and the criteria
values and by calculating the utility obtained from each realisation (e.g. Alho and
Kangas 1997; Kangas et al. 2000, 2007). In these studies, the uncertainty involved
in criteria weights was estimated using regression AHP.
Even in a case the decision-makers cannot or do not wish to express their
preferences concerning different criteria, or even provide a preference order, it is
still possible to utilise some MCDS tools in decision support. In acceptability
analysis, instead of considering which alternative is preferred using certain weights,
the weights that support a certain alternative are considered. Charnetski and Soland
(1978) presented the comparative hypervolume criterion for cases where only
partial preference information is available. Bana e Costa (1986, 1988) presented
an acceptability index, which was computed as the proportion of volume of the
weight space that supports a certain alternative. Butler et al. (1997) simulated the
effect of different weights on the results of the utility analysis and Lahdelma
et al. (1998) introduced a stochastic version of acceptability analysis (SMAA),
where both the weights and the criterion values were assumed stochastic.
In the original SMAA method by Lahdelma et al. (1998), the weight space
analysis is performed based on an additive utility or value function. The SMAA-2
method by Lahdelma and Salminen (2001) generalised the analysis to a general
utility or value function. The SMAA-O method by Lahdelma et al. (2003) extends
SMAA-2 for treating mixed ordinal and cardinal criteria in a comparable manner. In
addition, the SMAA family includes, among others, the methods ref-SMAA, SMAA-
3 and SMAA-III. In ref-SMAA the analysis is based on ideal or reference points
instead of utility function (Lahdelma et al. 2005a). The SMAA-3 method (Lahdelma
and Salminen 2002) is based on pseudo-criteria as in the ELECTRE III decision aid,
and SMAA-III is a full SMAA version of ELECTRE III (Tervonen et al. 2007).
The SMAA analysis has been used for several real-life problems. Among them
are, for instance, planning the development of Helsinki harbour (Hokkanen
106 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

et al. 1999) and searching for technology for cleaning polluted soil (Hokkanen
et al. 2000) and for locating a waste treatment facility (Lahdelma et al. 2002). It has
been also used for prioritising forest alternatives (Kangas et al. 2003, 2006a).
The SMAA-2 method (Lahdelma and Salminen 2001) has been developed for
discrete stochastic multi-criteria decision-making problems with multiple decision-
makers. SMAA-2 applies inverse weight space analysis to describe for each
alternative what kind of preferences make it the most preferred one or place it on
any particular rank.
The decision problem is represented as a set of n alternatives {x1, x2, . . ., xn} to
be evaluated in terms of m criteria. The decision-makers preference structure is
represented by a real-valued utility or value function u(xi,w)

X
m  
Ui w j u j xi j : 5:29
j1

The criterion values xij are usually scaled to value scale using (3.5), i.e.

  xi j  minxi
u j xi j 5:30
maxxi  minxi

The value function maps the different alternatives to real values by using a weight
vector w to quantify decision-makers subjective preferences. SMAA-2 has been
developed for situations where neither criteria measurements nor weights are
precisely known.
Uncertain or imprecise criteria are represented by a matrix of stochastic vari-
ables ij with joint density function f() in the space X  Rnm. The observed
criterion values xij are thus assumed to be realised values of a stochastic variable
having a probability distribution. It is assumed that the observed values xij represent
the expected value of this distribution, and the uncertainty involved in the criterion
value is described with the variance of the distribution. The distribution could be,

for instance, a uniform distribution, giving all values within range


xi j  j , xi j j equally probable. More likely, the distribution could be a
normal distribution so that small deviations from the expected value are more
probable than large ones.
If the variation in each variable is described with a uniform or normal distribution
this way, it is assumed that the uncertainty in any one variable is not related to the
uncertainty in another variable. If the criterion values are based on same causal factors,
the uncertainties may be dependent. However, explanatory variables in production
models are often the same: for example, the site index, volume of the growing stock
and age of the forest can be used to predict other forest products such as berry yields.
The predicted berry crop might, for instance, be the bigger the larger the volume of the
stand. Therefore, the errors in basic forest variables affect them, and there may be
dependencies in the errors between different criteria measurements as well. In this
case, a multivariate normal distribution could be used (Kangas et al. 2006a).
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 107

Fig. 5.8 The feasible


weight space in a case of no
information on weights,
presented as a shaded
triangle with corner points
(1, 0, 0), (0, 1, 0) and
(0, 0, 1)

The decision-makers unknown or partially known preferences are represented


by a weight distribution with joint density function f(w) in the feasible weight space
W. This facilitates very flexible modelling of different kinds of preference infor-
mation. For example, the decision-makers can specify precise weights, a priority
order for the criteria, weight intervals, intervals for weight ratios or arbitrary linear
or non-linear constraints for weights. Total lack of preference information is
represented in Bayesian spirit by a uniform weight distribution in W, i.e. for
each criterion j each weight from range [0,1] is equally probable. This can be
expressed with a joint distribution function for the weights

f w 1=volW 5:31

where vol(W) is the volume of the weight space. The weight space can be defined
according to needs, but typically, the weights are non-negative and normalised, i.e.
n Xm o
W w 2 Rm w  0 and j1
w j 1 5:32

The feasible weight space is an n1 dimensional simplex in n dimensional space.


For instance, with 3 criteria, the weight space is a plane and with two criteria a line
(Fig. 5.8, Tervonen and Lahdelma 2007).
The value function is then used to map the stochastic criteria and weight
distributions into value distributions u(i,w). In practice, it means that the joint
distributions of criteria values and weights are sampled for a large number of times,
108 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Fig. 5.9 The feasible


weight space, when the
importance order of criteria
is C2 > C1 > C3

say K. From these, K different realisations of the problem are obtained. From the
variation between the K realisations, the value distribution is obtained. The distri-
bution is thus obtained numerically, and an analytic solution would not be easy to
calculate, as the weights need to be normalised.
Obtaining m weights adding up to one may seem a difficult task. It is not possible
to sample m weights and scale them to one by dividing with the sum of obtained
weights, since then it would never be possible to obtain high weight for any
criterion. The task is, however, easy (see also Lahdelma and Salminen 1998). For
obtaining the weights, m1 random numbers r are sampled from the uniform
distribution. These numbers are then ordered from smallest to largest and values
0 and 1 are included in the numbers as 0 < r1 < . . . < rm1 < 1. Then, m numbers
summing up to one are obtained from differences r10, r2r1,. . ., 1rm1.
If there is information concerning the priority order of weights, for instance, this
can be used to order the obtained weights accordingly (Fig. 5.9). The decision-
maker may be able to define a complete importance order, only the importance
order of two groups of criteria, etc.

Example 5.7
Assume three criteria, from which the first one is known to be the most
important, and the importance order of the two other criteria is undetermined.
This can be denoted with C1 > C2 ? C3. To obtain weights for these, two
random numbers from a uniform distribution are sampled. These values were
0.112 and 0.308. From these, the weights are 0.112, 0.3080.112 0.196 and
10.308 0.692. Since the first criterion was the most important, it was given
the largest weight, 0.692, and since the priority of the others was
undetermined, they were given values in the order of observation, 0.112 for
C2 and 0.196 for C3.
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 109

Example 5.8
Assume the data set of Example 4.5. It is assumed that all criteria values have
a uniform distribution so that net incomes variate 10 (1000), stumpage
value 0.2 (million ) and scenic beauty 0.1 units around the expected
values (observed values). Random values for each variable are sampled from
the uniform distributions with the given assumptions. These variables form
one realisation in the simulation. An example realisation is presented in the
Table 5.22 and the resulting sub-utilities are presented in Table 5.23.

Table 5.22 An example Net income Stumpage value Scenic beauty


realisation from the
10 0.2 0.1
simulation
NAT 2.360 0.550 5.519
SCEN 87.582 0.434 5.792
NORM 28.290 0.563 5.473
GAME 25.772 0.508 5.409
MREG 92.948 0.376 5.144
INC 182.042 0.044 4.868

Table 5.23 Sub-utilities Net income Stumpage value Scenic beauty


resulting from simulated
NAT 0.012 0.725 0.774
criterion values
SCEN 0.457 0.524 1.115
NORM 0.148 0.746 0.716
GAME 0.134 0.652 0.636
MREG 0.485 0.424 0.305
INC 0.950 0.148 0.040

Based on the value distributions, the rank of each alternative is defined as an


integer from the best rank (1) to the worst rank (n) by means of a ranking function
Xn
ranki; ; w 1 k1
uk ; w > ui ; w; 5:33

where (true) 1 and (false) 0. With a given realisation of weights w and


criteria value matrix , this formula computes the rank of alternative xk as one
plus the number of alternatives xk that are strictly better than xi. SMAA-2 is based
on analysing the stochastic sets of favourable rank weights
 
Wir w 2 W ranki; ; w r : 5:34

Any weight vector w 2 Wir results in such values for different alternatives that
alternative xi obtains rank r.
110 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

The first descriptive measure of SMAA-2 is the rank acceptability index bri ,
which measures the variety of different preferences that grant alternative xi rank r. It
is the share of all feasible weights Wri () that make the alternative acceptable for a
particular rank, and it is most conveniently expressed in percent. Then, its accept-
ability is calculated as the expected volume of Wir, proportional to total weight
space volume as (Lahdelma et al. 1998; Lahdelma and Salminen 2001; Miettinen
et al. 1999)
 
bir vol Wir =volW 5:35

Generally bri is computed numerically as a multidimensional integral over the


criteria distributions and the favourable rank weights using

bir f f w dw d: 5:36
X Wir

The most acceptable (best) alternatives are those with high acceptabilities for the
best ranks. Evidently, the rank acceptability indices are in the range [0,1] where
0 indicates that the alternative will never obtain a given rank and 1 indicates that it
will obtain the given rank always with any choice of weights (with the given
information concerning weights). For comparing how different varieties of weights
support each rank for each alternative, graphical examination of the rank accept-
ability indices is useful. Alternatives with high acceptabilities for the best ranks are
taken as candidates for the most acceptable solution. On the other hand, alternatives
with large acceptabilities for the worst ranks should be avoided when searching for
compromises even if they would have high acceptabilities also for fair ranks.
The first-rank acceptability index is called the acceptability index ai. The
acceptability index is particularly interesting, because it can be used for classifying
the alternatives into stochastically efficient ones (ai > 0) and inefficient or weakly
efficient ones (ai zero or near zero). The acceptability index not only identifies the
efficient alternatives but also measures the strength of the efficiency considering the
uncertainty in criteria and decision-makers preferences.
If the applied weight distribution is assumed to represent accurately the distri-
bution of multiple decision-makers (or other stakeholders) preferences, then the
acceptability index is the share of votes that an alternative would receive in a voting
situation. An alternative obtaining over 50 % acceptability (or some other qualified
majority) could then be chosen directly. In the general case, when the applied
weight distribution cannot be assumed to represent the different preferences accu-
rately, the acceptability indices should not be used for absolute ranking of the
alternatives. This is due to the fact that an alternative with low support for the first
rank may well be the preferred one with suitable preferences.
If there is information available concerning the preferences, but it is not used in
the analysis, the results may be highly misleading. For instance, in a simulation
study where true preferences were assumed to exist but not used in decision analysis
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 111

at all, the SMAA analysis did recommend the best alternative only in less than 50 %
of cases (Kangas 2006). If no information of the preferences is used, the SMAA
analysis implicitly makes the recommendations as if the criteria had equal impor-
tance to the decision-maker.
Often, it can be useful to calculate also cumulative acceptability of some
alternatives. Instead of analysing the acceptability for one given rank, it is analysed
what is the acceptability for at least a given rank k (k-best acceptability). For
instance, it can be analysed the probability that alternative i is at least third,
i.e. among the three most acceptable alternatives.
The holistic acceptability index can be computed for each alternative as a
weighted sum of the rank acceptabilities

X
n
aih r bir ; 5:37
r1

where suitable meta-weights (or rank weights) 1 1  2  . . .  n  0 are used


to emphasise the best ranks. The holistic acceptability index is thus in the interval
[0,1] and aims to provide a rough measure of the overall acceptability of the
alternatives. The meta-weights can be, for instance, centroid weights

X
n1
1 X n1
1
r = 5:38
ir
i i1
i

Different meta-weights produce slightly different results, however, and the choice
of the meta-weights is subjective. Different ways to choose the meta-weights are
discussed in Lahdelma and Salminen (2001). The holistic acceptability indices have
an important practical use: sorting the alternatives by their holistic acceptability
index brings similar alternatives close to each other and makes the rank acceptabil-
ity index graph and table much more descriptive.
The central weight vector wci is the expected centre of gravity (centroid) of the
favourable first-rank weights of an alternative. wci is computed numerically as a
multidimensional integral over the criteria distributions and the favourable first-
rank weights using

wi
c
f f w w dw d=ai : 5:39
X W 1i

In practice it means that a mean of weights is calculated from those realisations that
give a certain alternative the first rank. The central weight vector represents the
preferences of a hypothetical decision-maker supporting this alternative. Of course,
the actual preferences of the decision-makers may be more or less incompatible
with the central weight vectors. Still, presenting the central weights of different
alternatives to the decision-makers may help them to understand how different
weights correspond to different choices with the assumed preference model. This
112 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

information may also aid the decision-makers to elicit their preferences in terms of
weights.
The confidence factor pci is the probability for an alternative to obtain the first
rank when the central weight vector is chosen. The confidence factor is computed as
a multidimensional integral over the criteria distributions using

pi
c
f d: 5:40
2X:wic 2W1i

Confidence factors can similarly be calculated for any given weight vectors. The
confidence factors measure whether the criteria data are accurate enough to discern
the efficient alternatives. The confidence factor can also be used together with the
acceptability index for eliminating weakly efficient alternatives. If the acceptability
index is very low (near zero,
1/n) and the confidence factor is low (less than, say,
5 %), we can argue that such an alternative is very unlikely the most preferred by
any decision-maker. In contrast, a very high confidence factor (over 95 %) indicates
that with suitable preferences, the alternative is almost certainly the most
preferred one.
The correlation among errors may considerably affect the results in the SMAA
analysis. Generally, if there are positive correlations across the alternatives, within
each criterion, the risks are less profound than in the case of independent errors (see
Kangas et al. 2006a). This is because high correlations retain the performance order
of alternatives with respect to each criterion in the realisations. On the other hand,
high positive correlations of criteria within alternatives may increase the risks
involved in SMAA analysis. This is because the performance order of the alterna-
tives is likely to change in the realisations, if the errors are to the same direction
with respect to several criteria but to different directions across alternatives. These
arguments can also be proven mathematically (see Lahdelma et al. 2005b).

Example 5.9
The problem analysed in Example 4.5 is analysed again using SMAA-2. In
the first analysis, it was assumed that the importance order or criteria is not
known, denoted by C1 ? C2 ? C3. The criteria values were assumed to be
certain. Then, the rank acceptabilities are presented in Table 5.24 and
Fig. 5.10. The rank probabilities are very similar for three alternatives,
NAT, SCEN and INC, but NAT could be selected as the most probable
alternative. INC has also 65.8 % probability of being the worst alternative.
The central weight vectors describe what kind of preferences support these
alternatives (Table 5.25). The results show that if large weight were given to
incomes, INC would be the preferred alternative; if large weight were given
to scenery, SCEN would be the preferred alternative; and if large weight were
given to stumpage value, NAT would be the preferred alternative. If all

(continued)
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 113

Example 5.9 (continued)


Table 5.24 Rank acceptabilities and confidence factors assuming no information from
criteria importances
1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th 6th pci
NAT 42.1 10.3 18.0 1.3 7.8 20.6 100
SCEN 32.2 8.7 20.6 12.3 19.9 6.3 100
NORM 0.0 0.2 34.3 37.4 20.9 7.3 100
GAME 3.9 60.5 13.4 17.8 4.3 0.0 100
MREG 0.1 15.5 12.4 30.2 41.7 0.0 100
INC 21.6 4.8 1.4 1.0 5.3 65.8 100

Fig. 5.10 The rank acceptabilities of the six alternatives, when no information on the
importance of criteria is available

Table 5.25 Central Net incomes Stumpage value Scenic beauty


weight vector
NAT 0.176 0.558 0.265
assuming no
information from SCEN 0.290 0.138 0.571
alternatives NORM 0.491 0.502 0.007
GAME 0.427 0.369 0.204
MREG 0.499 0.465 0.036
INC 0.687 0.180 0.133

(continued)
114 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.9 (continued)


criteria had quite similar weights, GAME could be the best alternative. The
confidence factors are 100 % for each alternative, since the criteria values
were assumed to be certain.
In the second analysis, it was assumed that the first criterion, net incomes,
was the most important, and the priority order of stumpage value and scenic
beauty is not known, denoted by C1 > C2 ? C3. The rank acceptabilities for
given ranks are presented in Table 5.26 and Fig. 5.11. It means that alterna-
tives NAT and NORM are dominated and alternative MREG nearly domi-
nated when it comes to the first rank. If the alternative were chosen based on
the first-rank probability ai, INC would be the most preferred alternative.
Table 5.26 Rank acceptabilities and confidence factors assuming net incomes the most
important criterion
1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th 6th pci
NAT 0.0 4.9 8.8 2.6 21.9 61.8 0
SCEN 31.8 26.3 29.4 2.0 3.4 7.2 100
NORM 0.0 0.0 4.5 19.2 55.8 20.5 100
GAME 7.3 14.1 10.2 58.3 10.2 0.0 100
MREG 0.3 36.4 43.8 15.5 4.0 0.0 100
INC 60.6 18.3 3.4 2.4 4.8 10.5 100

Fig. 5.11 The rank acceptabilities of the six alternatives, when the most important
criterion is known

(continued)
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 115

Example 5.9 (continued)


The holistic acceptability index aih for the alternatives are presented in
Table 5.27. INC would be the most preferred one also with this score. The
cumulative ranks acceptability indices for the alternatives are presented in
Table 5.28 and Fig. 5.12. The INC alternative is better than the others in the
first two ranks, but if the alternative is required to get at least the third rank,
SCEN is slightly better.

Table 5.27 Holistic NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC


acceptability
aih 10.2 59.8 14.9 35.8 43.3 74.0

Table 5.28 Cumulative rank 1 2 3 4 5 6


acceptability index
NAT 0.0 4.9 13.7 16.3 38.2 100.0
SCEN 31.8 58.1 87.5 89.5 92.8 100.0
NORM 0.0 0.0 4.5 23.7 79.5 100.0
GAME 7.3 21.4 31.5 89.8 100.0 100.0
MREG 0.3 36.7 80.5 96.0 100.0 100.0
INC 60.6 78.9 82.3 84.7 89.5 100.0

Fig. 5.12 The cumulative acceptabilities (k-best acceptability)

(continued)
116 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.9 (continued)


The central weight vectors for the alternatives are given in Table 5.29.
Since NAT alternative was dominated, it has no central weight vector, i.e. it
cannot be the best if the net incomes are the most important criterion.
Instead, MREG and NORM have central weight vectors. It means that
also NORM has probability above zero being the best alternative, even
though it is less than 0.1 %. It can be seen that if scenic beauty is given
fairly large weight (although net incomes as most important has larger),
SCEN may be the best alternative and NORM or MREG if stumpage values
are given much weight.

Table 5.29 Central weight Net Stumpage Scenic


vectors assuming net incomes incomes value beauty
the most important criterion
NAT 0.000 0.000 0.000
SCEN 0.492 0.149 0.359
NORM 0.493 0.492 0.015
GAME 0.431 0.365 0.204
MREG 0.499 0.463 0.038
INC 0.696 0.151 0.154

5.4.2 SMAA-O

SMAA-O is a version of SMAA, which can utilise also ordinal information


concerning the performance of alternatives with respect to some criteria. Ordinal
data are converted into stochastic cardinal data by simulating such values (in the
[0,1] interval) to the ordinal criteria that preserve the given rankings (Miettinen
et al. 1999). It is assumed that the cardinal (ratio scale) utility values for a given
criterion exist, but only their order is known. Similar ideas have been earlier
presented by Rietveld and Ouwersloot (1992).
In practice, m2 random numbers are sampled from a uniform distribution and
ordered together with zero and one, in order to obtain one realisation of the possible
underlying cardinal criterion values. Although all values are random numbers
sampled from uniform distribution, the method includes implicit assumptions
concerning the distribution of ordinal values (see Leskinen et al. 2004). In this
method, the order is assumed to be correct, but using a statistical approach devia-
tions from the given order can be accepted with a certain probability.
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 117

Example 5.10
Assume that in the previous example the performance with respect to the
last criterion, scenic beauty, is expressed as ordinal value. The ranks are in
Table 5.30. It is also assumed that there is 10 % standard deviation in the
values of net incomes and stumpage value. In this case, the rank accept-
abilities and confidence factors are presented in Table 5.31 and Fig. 5.13.
When there is uncertainty in the criterion values, normally distributed for
the first two criteria, and about the underlying cardinal criterion values of
the ordinal criterion, the rank acceptabilities among the alternatives are
somewhat more even: none of the alternatives is dominated any more. The
confidence factors, on the other hand, are smaller. The INC alternative
would be selected with 99.4 % confidence using the central weight vector
for it, but NORM and GAME would only occasionally be best even with
these favourable weights.

Table 5.30 Rank values for Scenic beauty


scenic beauty criterion
NAT 2.
SCEN 1.
NORM 4.
GAME 3.
MREG 5.
INC 6.

Table 5.31 Rank probabilities and confidence factors


1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th 6th pci
NAT 5.3 8.5 11.0 13.8 15.6 45.8 48.4
SCEN 30.2 33.5 23.6 3.8 3.6 5.3 95.4
NORM 1.1 2.4 6.4 27.5 33.9 28.7 11.1
GAME 2.8 7.2 15.7 38.5 29.9 5.8 22.7
MREG 2.2 28.6 37.3 11.3 12.3 8.2 12.2
INC 58.3 19.9 5.9 5.1 4.7 6.1 99.4

(continued)
118 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Example 5.10 (continued)

Fig. 5.13 The rank acceptabilities of the six alternatives, when the scenic beauty is
expressed as an ordinal variable

5.4.3 Pairwise Probabilities

Another possibility to analyse the SMAA calculations is to calculate pairwise


winning probability for all pairs of alternatives k and l (Leskinen et al. 2006). It
describes the probability of alternative k beating another alternative l. It can be
calculated as the proportion of realisations where one alternative is better than
another, using the same realisations of the stochastic processes as for the original
rank acceptabilities. Then, if a certain alternative has 100 % winning probability
against another, it is dominant, and 50 % probability might indicate either a tie
between the alternatives or conflicting criterion values for equally important
criteria.
For analysing the pairwise winning probabilities, a rule that is widely accepted
within social choice theory can be found, namely, the Condorcet criterion
(e.g. Bouyssou et al. 2000). The Condorcet winner is the candidate that in pairwise
election gets the majority of votes against all other candidates. In the SMAA
analogy, the Condorcet winner is the alternative which has more than 50 %
5.4 Probabilistic Uncertainty in Decision Analysis 119

probability of winning against all other alternatives. Condorcet loser, on the other
hand, has less than 50 % probability of winning against all alternatives.
A measure obtained from voting theory which may give good insight into the
problem is the Copeland score (e.g. Bouyssou et al. 2000). The Copeland score is
calculated so that an alternative that gets a majority in a pairwise election scores one
point and the alternative that loses the pairwise election loses one point.

X
n 
1, if pak ; al  0:5
Copelandk r kl , r kl 5:41
1, otherwise
l1
k 6 l

where p(ak,al) is the probability of alternative k beating alternative l and n is the


number of alternatives. Then, the maximum score is (n1) for a Condorcet winner
and minimum score is -(n1) for a Condorcet loser. This rule always finds the
Condorcet winner, if it exists.
In some cases the elections may result in a situation where there is no Condorcet
winner, for instance, there may be ties. In this case, another rule called Simpson
score is useful (e.g. Martin et al. 1996). Simpson score is the minimum number of
votes in pairwise elections a certain alternative gets against all other alternatives. In
the SMAA context, it would be the minimum of pairwise winning probabilities for
one alternative

Simpsonk min pak ; al , l 1, . . . , n k 6 l: 5:42

If a Condorcet winner exists, Simpsons score is larger than 50 %. If no alternative


wins against all others in pairwise competitions, Simpsons score chooses an
alternative against which there is not a large majority.
From pairwise probabilities it is also possible to calculate a holistic index. The
positive outranking index (POI) is calculated as the mean of the observed pairwise
probabilities of alternative k beating each of the other alternatives l

1 X n  
POIk p ak , a l : 5:43
n1
l1
k 6 l

This index has a clear interpretation: indices more than 50 % indicate alternative
above average, and less than 50 % indicate an alternative below average. It also
does not require arbitrary weights and the score only improves if an alternative has
positive probability to win. In this approach, losing to some alternatives can be
compensated, if the alternative beats the others by large enough an amount. This
approach resembles the positive flow in PROMETHEE method (e.g. Vincke 1992).
The positive outranking index could also be calculated by counting only those
probabilities that are over 50 %, giving a second version of positive outranking
index (POI II)
120 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making


1 X n   1, if pak ; al  0:5
POI IIk r kl p ak , al , r kl 5:44
n1 0, otherwise:
l1
k 6 l

Then, the index would both penalise losing to another alternative quite hard (but not
as much as Copeland score) and also take into account the amount by which it wins.

Example 5.11
In the problem above assuming net incomes as the most important criterion
(Example 5.9), the pairwise probabilities of each alternative beating the
others are presented in Table 5.32 and the resulting scores in Table 5.33.
The probability of an alternative beating itself is not considered. In this
example, INC beats each alternative with probability greater than 50 %,
and it is best with all the indices.

Table 5.32 Pairwise winning probabilities


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 10.8 33.6 0.0 13.2 15.5
SCEN 89.2 89.2 84.2 60.5 36.7
NORM 66.4 10.8 12.7 5.5 12.2
GAME 100.0 15.8 87.3 25.7 21.3
MREG 86.8 39.5 94.5 74.3 18.4
INC 84.5 63.3 87.8 78.7 81.6

Table 5.33 Performance indices based on pairwise probabilities


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
aih 10.2 59.8 14.9 35.8 43.3 74.0
POI 14.6 71.9 21.5 50.0 62.7 79.2
POI II 0.0 64.6 13.3 37.5 51.1 79.2
Copeland 5.0 3.0 3.0 1.0 1.0 5.0
Simpson 0.0 36.7 5.5 15.8 18.4 63.3

References

Adamo, J. M. (1980). Fuzzy decision trees. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 4, 207220.
Alho, J. M., & Kangas, J. (1997). Analyzing uncertainties in experts opinions of forest plan
performance. Forest Science, 43, 521528.
Bana e Costa, C. (1986). A multicriteria decision-aid methodology to deal with conflicting
situations on the weights. European Journal of Operational Research, 26, 2234.
Bana e Costa, C. A. (1988). A methodology for sensitivity analysis in three criteria problems: A case
study in municipal management. European Journal of Operational Research, 33, 159173.
References 121

Bellman, R., & Zadeh, L. A. (1970). Decision making in fuzzy environment. Management
Science, 17, B141B164.
Belton, V., & Stewart, T. J. (2002). Multiple criteria decision analysis: An integrated approach.
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Bonissone, P. P. (1982). A fuzzy sets based linguistic approach: Theory and applications. In M. M.
Gupta & E. Sanchez (Eds.), Approximate reasoning in decision analysis (pp. 329339).
New York: North-Holland Pub. Co.
Bouyssou, D. (1992). Ranking methods based on valued preference relations: A characterization
of the net flow method. European Journal of Operational Research, 60, 6167.
Bouyssou, D., & Perny, P. (1992). Ranking methods for valued preference relations: A charac-
terization of a method based on leaving and entering flows. European Journal of Operational
Research, 61, 186194.
Bouyssou, D., Marchant, T., Pirlot, M., Perny, P., Tsoukias, A., & Vincke, P. (2000). Evaluation
and decision models A critical perspective. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Bouyssou, D., Jacquet-Lagrez, E., Perny, P., Slowinski, R., Vanderpooten, D., & Vincke, P. (Eds.).
(2001). Aiding decisions with multiple criteria. Essays in honour of Bernard Roy. Dordrecht:
Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Brans, J. P., Vincke, P., & Mareschal, B. (1986). How to select and how to rank projects: The
PROMETHEE method. European Journal of Operational Research, 24, 228238.
Briggs, T., Kunsch, P. L., & Mareschal, B. (1990). Nuclear waste management: An application of
the multicriteria PROMETHEE methods. European Journal of Operational Research, 44,
110.
Buchanan, J., Sheppard, P., & Vanderpoorten, D. (1999). Project ranking using ELECTRE III.
Research report 9901, University of Waikato, Dept. of management systems, New Zealand.
Butler, J., Jia, J., & Dyer, J. (1997). Simulation techniques for the sensitivity analysis of multi-
criteria decision models. European Journal of Operational Research, 103, 531546.
Carlin, B. P., & Louis, T. A. (2000). Bayes and empirical Bayes methods for data analysis. Boca
Raton: Chapman & Hall/CRC.
Chang, J.-R., Cheng, C.-H., & Kuo, C.-Y. (2006). Conceptual procedure for ranking fuzzy
numbers based on adaptive two-dimension dominance. Soft Computing, 10, 94103.
Charnetski, J. R., & Soland, R. M. (1978). Multiple-attribute decision making with partial
information: The comparative hypervolume criterion. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly,
25, 279288.
Chen, S.-J., & Hwang, C.-L. (1992). Fuzzy multiple attribute decision making. Methods and
applications (Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems, 375). Berlin: Springer.
536 p.
Cheng, C.-H. (1999). Evaluating weapon systems using raking fuzzy numbers. Fuzzy Sets and
Systems, 107, 2535.
Choi, D.-Y., & Oh, K.-W. (2000). ASA and its application to multi-criteria decision making. Fuzzy
Sets and Systems, 114, 89102.
dAvignon, G. R., & Vincke, P. (1988). An outranking method under uncertainty. European
Journal of Operational Research, 36, 311321.
Despic, O., & Simonovich, S. P. (2000). Aggregation operators for soft decision making in water
resources. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 115, 1133.
Dubois, D., & Prade, H. (1988). Possibility theory. An approach to computerized processing of
uncertainty. New York: Plenum Press. 263 p.
Dubois, D., Fargier, H., & Prade, H. (1994). Propagation and satisfaction of flexible constraints. In
R. R. Yager & L. A. Zadeh (Eds.), Fuzzy sets, neural networks and soft computing
(pp. 166187). New York: Van Nostrand Reinnold.
Dubois, D., Fargier, H., & Prade, H. (1996). Refinements of the maximin approach to decision
making in a fuzzy environment. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 81, 103122.
Ducey, M. J., & Larson, B. C. (1999). A fuzzy set approach to the problem of sustainability. Forest
Ecology and Management, 115, 2940.
122 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Eastman, J. R., & Jiang, H. (1996, May 2123). Fuzzy measures in multi-criteria evaluation. In:
H. Todd Mowrer, R. L. Czaplewski, & R. H. Hamre (Ed.), Proceedings of the 2nd international
symposium on spatial accuracy assessment in natural resources and environmental studies
(pp. 527534, General technical report RM-GTR-277). Fort Collins: USDA Forest Service.
Ferson, S., & Ginzburg, L. R. (1996). Different methods are needed to propagate ignorance and
variability. Reliability Engineering and System Safety, 54, 133144.
Goumas, M., & Lygerou, V. (2000). An extension of the PROMETHEE method for decision
making in fuzzy environment: Ranking of alternative energy exploitation projects. European
Journal of Operational Research, 123, 606613.
Hannan, E. L. (1983). Fuzzy decision making with multiple objectives and discrete membership
functions. International Journal of Man-Machine Studies, 18, 4954.
Hellendoorn, H., & Thomas, C. (1993). Defuzzification in fuzzy controllers. Journal of Intelligent
and Fuzzy Systems, 1, 109123.
Hokkanen, J., & Salminen, P. (1997a). Choosing a solid waste management system using
multicriteria decision analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 98, 1936.
Hokkanen, J., & Salminen, P. (1997b). Locating a waste treatment facility by multicriteria
analysis. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 6, 175184.
Hokkanen, J., & Salminen, P. (1997c). ELECTRE III and IV decision aids in an environmental
problem. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 6, 215226.
Hokkanen, J., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (1999). A multiple criteria decision model for
analyzing and choosing among different development patterns for the Helsinki cargo harbour.
Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 33, 123.
Hokkanen, J., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2000). Multicriteria decision support in a technology
competition for cleaning polluted soil in Helsinki. Journal of Environmental Management, 60,
339348.
Kangas, A. (2006). The risk of decision making with incomplete criteria weight information.
Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 36, 195205.
Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2004a). Probability, possibility and evidence: Approaches to consider
risk and uncertainty in forestry decision analysis. Forest Policy and Economics, 6, 169188.
Kangas, J., & Kangas, A. (2004b). Multicriteria approval and SMAA-O in natural resources
decision analysis with both ordinal and cardinal criteria. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision
Analysis, 12, 315.
Kangas, J., Store, R., Leskinen, P., & Mehtatalo, L. (2000). Improving the quality of landscape
ecological forest planning by utilizing advanced decision-support tools. Forest Ecology and
Management, 132, 157171.
Kangas, A., Kangas, J., & Pykalainen, J. (2001a). Outranking methods as tools in strategic natural
resources planning. Silva Fennica, 35, 215227.
Kangas, J., Kangas, A., Leskinen, P., & Pykalainen, J. (2001b). MCDM methods in strategic
planning of forestry on state-owned lands in Finland: Applications and experiences. Journal of
Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 10, 257271.
Kangas, J., Hokkanen, J., Kangas, A., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2003). Applying stochastic
multicriteria acceptability analysis to forest ecosystem management with both cardinal and
ordinal criteria. Forest Science, 49, 928937.
Kangas, A., Kangas, J., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2006a). Using SMAA methods with
dependent uncertainties for strategic forest planning. Forest Policy and Economics, 9,
113125.
Kangas, A., Kangas, J., & Laukkanen, S. (2006b). Fuzzy multicriteria approval method and its
application to two forest planning problems. Forest Science, 52, 232242.
Kangas, A., Leskinen, P., & Kangas, J. (2007). Comparison of fuzzy and statistical approaches in
multi-criteria decision making. Forest Science, 53, 3744.
Klir, G. J., & Harmanec, D. (1997). Types and measures of uncertainty. In J. Kacprzyk, H. Nurmi,
& M. Fedrizzi (Eds.), Consensus under fuzziness (International series in intelligent technolo-
gies). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
References 123

Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2001). SMAA-2: Stochastic multicriteria acceptability analysis for
group decision making. Operations Research, 49, 444454.
Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2002). Pseudo-criteria versus linear utility function in stochastic
multi-criteria acceptability analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 141,
454469.
Lahdelma, R., Hokkanen, J., & Salminen, P. (1998). SMAA Stochastic multiobjective accept-
ability analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 106, 137143.
Lahdelma, R., Salminen, P., & Hokkanen, J. (2002). Locating a waste treatment facility by using
stochastic multicriteria acceptability analysis with ordinal criteria. European Journal of Oper-
ational Research, 142, 345356.
Lahdelma, R., Miettinen, K., & Salminen, P. (2003). Ordinal criteria in stochastic multicriteria
acceptability analysis (SMAA). European Journal of Operational Research, 147, 117127.
Lahdelma, R., Miettinen, K., & Salminen, P. (2005a). Reference point approach for multiple
decision makers. European Journal of Operational Research, 164, 785791.
Lahdelma, R., Makkonen, S., & Salminen, P. (2005b). Two ways to handle dependent uncer-
tainties in multi-criteria decision problems. Omega. In press, 164, 785791.
Leskinen, P., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2004). Rank-based modelling of preferences in multi-
criteria decision making. European Journal of Operational Research, 158, 721733.
Leskinen, P., Viitanen, J., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2006). Alternatives to incorporate uncertainty
and risk attitude into multi-criteria evaluation of forest plans. Forest Science, 52, 304312.
Malczewski, J. (1999). GIS and multicriteria decision analysis. New York: Wiley. 392 p.
Martin, W. E., Schields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Kent, B. (1996). An application of social choice
theory to U.S.D.A. Forest Service decision making. Journal of Policy Modelling, 18, 603621.
Mattila, J. (2002). Sumean logiikan oppikirja. Helsinki: Art House. 289 p.
Maystre, L. Y., Pictet, J., & Simos, J. (1994). Methodes multicrite`res ELECTRE. Lausanne:
Presses Polytechniques et Universitaires Romandes.
Miettinen, K., & Salminen, P. (1999). Decision-aid for discrete multiple criteria decision making
problems with imprecise data. European Journal of Operational Research, 119, 5060.
Miettinen, K., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (1999). SMAA-O Stochastic multicriteria accept-
ability analysis with ordinal criteria. Reports of the Department of Mathematical Information
Technology Series B, Scientific Computing B5. University of Jyvaskyla.
Niskanen, V. (2003). Software computing methods in human sciences (Studies in fuzziness and
soft computing). Berlin: Springer. 280 p.
Pirlot, M. (1995). A characterization of min as a procedure for exploiting valued preference
relations and related results. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 4, 3756.
Raju, K. S., & Pillai, C. R. S. (1999). Multicriteria decision making in performance evaluation of
an irrigation system. European Journal of Operational Research, 112, 479488.
Rietveld, P., & Ouwersloot, H. (1992). Ordinal data in multicriteria decision making, a stochastic
dominance approach to siting nuclear power plants. European Journal of Operational
Research, 56, 249262.
Rogers, M., & Bruen, M. (1998a). A new system for weighting environmental criteria for use
within ELECTRE III. European Journal of Operational Research, 107, 552563.
Rogers, M., & Bruen, M. (1998b). Choosing realistic values of indifference, preference and veto
thresholds for use with environmental criteria within ELECTRE. European Journal of Oper-
ational Research, 107, 542551.
Rogers, M., Bruen, M., & Maystre, L.-Y. (2000). ELECTRE and decision support: Methods and
applications in engineering and infrastructure investment. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Rondeau, L., Ruelas, R., Levrat, L., & Lamotte, M. (1997). A defuzzification method respecting
the fuzzification. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 86, 311320.
Roy, B. (1968). Classement et choix en presence de points de vue multiples (la methode
ELECTRE). Revue Francaise dInformatique et de Recherche Operationnelle, 8, 5775.
124 5 Uncertainty in Multi-criteria Decision-Making

Roy, B. (1991). The outranking approach and the foundations of Electre methods. Theory and
Decision, 31, 4973.
Roy, B., Present, M., & Silhol, D. (1986). A programming method for determining which Paris
metro stations should be renovated. European Journal of Operational Research, 24, 318334.
Salminen, P., Hokkanen, J., & Lahdelma, R. (1998). Comparing multicriteria methods in the
context of environmental problems. European Journal of Operational Research, 104,
485496.
Schafer, G. (1976). A mathematical theory of evidence. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
297 p.
Tervonen, T., & Lahdelma, R. (2007). Implementing stochastic multicriteria acceptability analy-
sis. European Journal of Operational Research, 178, 500513.
Tervonen, T., Figueira, J. R., Lahdelma, R., & Salminen, P. (2007). Towards robust ELECTRE III
with simulation: Theory and software of SMAA-III. Submitted manuscript.
Vincke, P. (1992). Multi-criteria decision aid. Chichester: Wiley. 154 p.
Williams, D. (1991). Probability with martingales (Cambridge mathematical textbooks). Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press. 251 p.
Yager, R. R. (1978). Fuzzy decision making including unequal objectives. Fuzzy Sets and Systems,
1, 8795.
Yager, R. R. (1988). On ordered weigh averaging aggregating operators in multi-criteria decision
making. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, 18, 183190.
Yager, R. R. (1996). Knowledge-based defuzzification. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 80, 177185.
Yu, W. (1992). Aide multicrite`re a la decision dans le cadre de la problematique du tri: methodes
et applications. PhD thesis, LAMSADE, Universite Paris-Dauphine, Paris.
Zadeh, L. A. (1965). Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8, 338353.
Zimmermann, H.-J. (1985). Fuzzy set theory And its applications (p. 355). Boston: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Zimmermann, H.-J., & Zysno, P. (1980). Latest connectives in human decision making. Fuzzy Sets
and Systems, 4, 3751.
Part III
Continuous Problems
Chapter 6
Optimisation

Abstract Linear programming is the most widely utilised optimisation method in


forestry. Linear programming can be used to deal with many sustainability issues,
such as the requirement of even flow of timber over time. It can also be used to deal
with multiple goals, by using a constraint approach and Pareto front or by using a
goal programming approach. Integer or mixed integer programming can also be
used to deal with many spatial goals and constraints, like adjacency and green-up
constraints or those of clustering timber harvests. In this chapter, we present
different formulations of linear programming and their effect on the resulting
harvest schedule with numerical examples. We also present different formulations
of goal programming and the interpretation of the results in different cases. Fur-
thermore, we present some more complicated planning cases involving hierarchical
and spatial planning.

6.1 Linear Programming

6.1.1 Primal Problem

Linear programming (LP) is the most common optimisation method used in forest
management planning (e.g. Dantzig 1951; Davis et al. 2001, Buongiorno and Gilles
2003). The idea in LP is to allocate the limited resources optimally. In the LP
method, the planning problem is described with an objective function which is to be
maximised (or minimised):

X
n
max z c jx j 6:1
j1

subject to some constraints. The constraints can be either output constraints

X
n
ai j x j  bi , i 1, . . . , q 6:2
j1

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 127


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_6
128 6 Optimisation

or input constraints

X
n
ai j x j  bi , i q 1, . . . , p: 6:3
j1

Constraints are usually expressed as inequalities, but equality constraints


(i.e. constraints with instead of  or ) can also be used. In addition, LP formu-
lation includes non-negativity constraints

x j  0, 8 j 1, . . . , n: 6:4

In this formulation, each xj is a decision variable to be solved. In forest planning


problems, decision variable xj is usually area (ha) or the proportion of area treated
with alternative (activity) j. The coefficients cj tell how much this area (typically
one stand) produces the objective variable when treated with alternative j. For
instance, if the objective is to maximise the revenues and treatment alternatives are
to harvest by clear-cutting or thinning, the coefficient cj is the revenue per hectare
(/ha) from clear-cutting or thinning, respectively. If the decision variable is
proportion, then cj is presented as euros per area available ().
Regarding the output constraints (6.2) or input constraints (6.3) of an LP
problem, the right-hand sides (RHS, bi) of output constraints tell how much at
least the decision-maker requires some commodity i. An example of output con-
straints is a requirement that the volume of growing stock should be at least a
certain amount (m3). The RHSs of input constraints, on the other hand, tell how
much at most the decision-maker is able or willing to use a certain input. An
example of the input constraints is the number of working hours the decision-
maker is willing to use on forest management. The coefficients aij tell how much the
area treated with treatment j produces or uses commodity i.
The most obvious input constraint in forest management planning problems is
the area available: the total area treated with different alternatives must be equal to
the area available (or the sum of proportions must be one). In the case of area
constraints, the aij coefficients are ones, for all the treatment alternatives for the area
(or stand) in question, and bi is the area in hectares (or one in the case of pro-
portions). In this case, the equality constraint is used instead of inequalities. Finally,
all the decision variables are required to be non-negative. This means, however, no
loss of generality of the method, as variables having negative values can be
reformulated using, for example, the difference between two non-negative
variables.
Any solution that satisfies all the constraints is called a feasible solution. The
feasible solutions are in a region restricted by constraints, a so-called feasible
region. The best solution among the feasible solutions is the optimum. In LP, if
there is a unique optimal solution, it always is a corner point in the feasible region.
6.1 Linear Programming 129

The following properties of the problem are assumed:


Linearity
The objective function and all constraints need to be formulated so that the
value of objective function (or constraint) is a linear combination of the
decision variables.
It means, for instance, that the revenue and cost /m3 have to be the same
irrespective of the level of the harvests.
Additivity
The value of objective function has to be such that it can be calculated
directly as a sum of the contributions of each individual decision variable.
It also means that the decision variables need to be independent of each other.
For instance, an increase in the revenues of one treatment should not affect
the revenues of other treatments.
Divisibility
In LP, the constraints and the objective function need to be such that all the
decision variables are continuous variables. This means that if there are
several treatment options for a single forest area, the solution may divide
the area to two or more parts with different treatments. The total number of
parts is equal to the number of stands plus the number of binding input and
output constraints (excluding area constraints). If this cannot be allowed,
integer programming needs to be used.
Determinism
It is assumed that all coefficients a, b and c are known with certainty, for
instance, the future growth of the forests and future prices of timber. Thus, it
may be useful to calculate the optimal solution with several assumptions of
prices, costs, demand of timber, etc., i.e. to do sensitivity analysis. Sometimes
a mere sensitivity analysis is not acceptable, and the problems need to be
formulated a stochastic optimisation problem (see Chap. 8).
The problem is usually solved with a simplex algorithm (for a method descrip-
tion, see, e.g., Taha 2007 and Hillier and Lieberman 2001). In this book, the
examples are solved either using the Solver in Excel or IBM ILOG CPLEX
Optimization Studio V 12.5.1.0 [IBM ILOG CPLEX Optimization Studio
V12.5.1 documentation], which is commonly known merely as Cplex. For details
of using Solver in forestry problems, the readers are referred to Buongiorno and
Gilles (2003).
The possible results are:
1. No feasible solution is found:
The constraints are too tight.
2. One optimal solution.
130 6 Optimisation

3. Infinite number of optimal solutions:


The objective function is parallel to a constraint function, and the same objective
function value can be obtained in all points between two corner points.
4. The optimum is infinite:
The problem should be reformulated.

Example 6.1
Assume a factory that produces two products, say toy trains and toy cars.
Each train gives a revenue of 3 and each car 2 . Both products require two
kinds of material, say birch and spruce wood. Each train consumes 2 dm3 of
birch and 1 dm3 of spruce and the cars 1 dm3 of birch and 2 dm3 of spruce.
There is 6 dm3 of each species available. The decision variables are the
number of produced trains (x1) and cars (x2).
The problem is to maximise the profits:

max z 3x1 2x2

subject to
2x1 x2  6 birch wood consumption
x1 2x2  6 spruce wood consumption
x1 , x2  0

This simple problem can be solved graphically (Fig. 6.1). The constraints are
drawn to a figure to be able to see the feasible region. Then, the objective
function is drawn though the origin (0,0) and moved further and further away
from origin. The furthest point where the objective function still is inside the
feasible region is the optimal point, in this case (2,2).
Fig. 6.1 Constraints as a
function of decision
variables define the feasible
region (grey area)
6.1 Linear Programming 131

Example 6.2
Assume a pine forest area of 60 ha. The initial volume per hectare is 180 m3/
ha, i.e. the total volume in the area is 10,800 m3. The harvest revenue is 30 /
m3. The problem was to maximise harvest revenues in a 30-year period so
that the volume in the end would be at least the same as in the beginning; the
harvest revenues in the first 10-year period would be at least 50,000 and that it
would increase by 5000 in each of the later 10-year periods.
The decision variables in this problem are the areas (ha) of the four
treatment alternatives, x1, x2, x3 and x4. The alternative treatments are to
harvest at the first period, harvest at the second period, harvest at the last
period and not to harvest at all (the problem can also be formulated using the
first three alternatives only, i.e. making the last alternative implicit). The
volume development in these four alternative treatments is presented in
Table 6.1
Then, the objective function is

max z 5250x1 6600x2 7950x3 0x4 ;

describing the total harvest revenues over all periods in the area, assuming the
harvested volume to be 175 m3, 220 m3 or 265 m3 (Table 6.2).
The area constraint is:
x1 x2 x3 x4 60

The revenue constraints for the three periods are

5250x1 0x2 0x3 0x4  50, 000


0x1 6600x2 0x3 0x4  55, 000
0x1 0x2 7950x3 0x4  60, 000

Table 6.1 Expected volume Alternative Initial 2016 2026 2036


(m3/ha) of the forest area
Harvest1 180 5 17.5 52.5
treated with each of the
alternatives in different Harvest2 180 225 5 17.5
periods Harvest3 180 225 270 5
No harvest 180 225 270 297

Table 6.2 Harvest revenues Alternative 2016 2026 2036


at each period in these four
Harvest 1 5250 0 0
alternatives
Harvest 2 0 6600 0
Harvest 3 0 0 7950
No harvest 0 0 0

(continued)
132 6 Optimisation

Example 6.2 (continued)


Table 6.3 The solution Alternative Area (ha)
Harvest 1 9.52
Harvest 2 8.33
Harvest 3 8.09
No harvest 34.05

and the constraint for the volume in the end of the period is

52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4  10, 800:

The non-negativity constraints can be either given implicitly or selected as


an option. The result obtained with Solver is presented in Table 6.3.
The resulting level of the constraints is exactly the given constraint for the
area (60 ha), the first and second 10-year periods (50,000 and 55,000 )
and the final volume (10,800 m3). Instead, in the last 10-year period, the
harvest revenue is greater (64,315 ) than required (60,000 ). Thus, this
constraint was not binding, but there is a 4315 surplus. The rest of the
constraints were binding. The resulting optimal total harvest revenues were
then 169,315 .

6.1.2 Dual Problem

For each primal problem, there is an analogous dual problem. If the primal problem
is a maximisation problem, then the dual problem is a minimisation problem. Vice
versa, if the primal is a minimisation problem, the dual is a maximisation problem.
If the primal problem has a unique solution, so does the dual problem, and the
solution to the dual problem is the same as to the primal problem. If the primal has
no feasible solution (i.e. solution that would satisfy all the constraints), the solution
of the dual is infinite and vice versa. The primal and dual problems are so tightly
related that solving primal automatically produces the solution for dual and vice
versa.
The objective function of dual problem is formulated from RHSs of the primal
problem constraints and so-called shadow prices (or dual prices) vi. In the dual
problem, the shadow prices are the decision variables, and objective function and
all constraints are expressed as a function of them. Thus, the number of decision
variables in the dual problem is the same as number of constraints in the primal
problem.
In the dual problem, the constraints are formed from the original decision
variables, i.e. there are as many constraints as there were decision variables in the
6.1 Linear Programming 133

primal. The right-hand sides of the dual constraints are obtained from the coeffi-
cients of the primal objective function. The formulation of dual from the primal
depends on if the problem is a maximisation or minimisation problem; if the
constraints are output, input or equality constraints and if the variables are
non-negative or unrestricted. If the problem is formulated in a form (Taha 2007
p. 152), where the objective function is either of type (6.1) or the minimisation
form of it, all constraints are expressed as equal to constraints with non-negative
RHS (rather than inequalities as in 6.2 or 6.3) and all variables are non-negative, the
following rules apply. For a maximisation problem, the corresponding dual
problem is

X
p
min w b i vi 6:5
i1

subject to

X
p
ai j vi  c j , j 1, . . . , n 6:6
i1

Thus, if the primal is a maximisation problem, the constraints of the dual problem
are always  type constraints. If the primal is a minimisation problem, then the dual
constraints are of  type, i.e. (Taha 2007 p. 153)

X
p
ai j vi  c j , j 1, . . . , n: 6:7
i1

The shadow prices, vii 1,. . .,p, for equality () constraints are unrestricted,
meaning that they can be either positive or negative. Usually the constraints for
other than area constraints are not equality constraints, and for output constraints,
the shadow prices are non-positive and, for the input constraints, the shadow prices
are non-negative. For constraints that are not binding in the solution, the shadow
prices are zero.
The shadow prices measure how much the objective function value changes if
the RHS of one constraint is changed by one unit and all other things remain equal.
Then, the shadow price for area, for instance, can be interpreted as a measure of the
value of one unit of land in the production. The properties can be derived from the
equality

X
n X
p
z c jx j bi v i w 6:8
j1 i1

and if z is revenue and bi is the area available, then vi must be the worth of unit area
(assuming that all possible other input and output constraints have RHS bi 0).
134 6 Optimisation

Xn X
p
In a nonoptimal solution c jx j < bi vi , the revenues are less than the worth of
j1 i1
the land. Thus, optimal solution is obtained when all the resources are completely
exploited. In a more general situation, the formula (6.8) implies that, in the optimal
solution, the value of resources (used inputs from input constraints times the
shadow prices) is the same as the value of outputs (objective function value -
produced outputs from output constraints times the shadow prices). The shadow
prices describe the effect of marginal changes. It means that there is a range where
the RHSs can be changed so that the given shadow price applies. If the change is
larger, then the shadow prices change (Taha 2007 p. 125).
The shadow prices can also be used to calculate the reduced cost of an activity.
The reduced costs are calculated as

X
p
rc j c j  ai j v i 6:9
i1

The reduced cost can be calculated to all activities that are included in the solution
and those that are not in the solution and also for new activities that have not been
considered at all. If the activity is in fact in the solution, the reduced cost is always
zero. If the activity is not in the solution, the reduced cost is negative: the costs
(calculated using shadow prices) of the alternative are higher than the profits. If the
reduced cost of the new activity is positive, it can profitably be included in the
solution.

Example 6.3
In Example 6.2., the problem was

max z 5250x1 6600x2 7950x3 0x4 ;

subject to

x1 x2 x3 x4 60
5250x1 0x2 0x3 0x4  50, 000
0x1 6600x2 0x3 0x4  55, 000
0x1 0x2 7950x3 0x4  60, 000
52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4  10, 800:

The dual problem for this is

(continued)
6.1 Linear Programming 135

Example 6.3 (continued)


min w 60v1 50, 000v2 55, 000v3 60, 000v4 10, 800v5

subject to

1v1 5250v2 0v3 0v4 52:5v5  5250


1v1 0v2 6600v3 0v4 17:5v5  6600
1v1 0v2 0v3 7950v4 5v5  7950
v1 0v2 0v3 0v4 297v5  0

Thus, the objective is to minimise the shadow price over the five constraints
of the primal. Each shadow price refers to one constraint. For all constraints
except for the area constraint, the shadow prices need to be non-positive, as
the constraints are output constraints. For the area constraint (i.e. an equality
constraint), the shadow price is unrestricted. The Solver result for this is
presented in Table 6.4. For the harvests in period 3, the shadow price is 0, as
the constraint is not binding. For the area constraint, the shadow price is
8086.13 /ha. It means that the optimal harvest revenues could be increased
with this amount, if there were one more unit land, i.e. it is the value of one
additional hectare of land. The shadow prices for the harvests in the first two
periods are negative. It means that the optimal harvest revenue could be
increased by 0.27 or 0.15 if the RHSs of these constraints were reduced
by one or how much the decision-maker would need to give up in the
optimal harvest level, if the constraint were increased by one . The shadow
price of the last constraint, the final volume, is 27.23. It means that the
optimal harvest revenue could be increased by 27.23 , if the constraint were
reduced by one m3. The shadow price of the end-volume constraint applies in
the range 856.5 < RHS < 10,958.5 and the shadow price for area in the range
of 856.5 < RHS < 10,958.5 and the income requirements from 0 to 53,403,
58,742 or 64,315, respectively. In this example, the reduced costs for all the
activities are zero, as all the activities are in the final solution, i.e. all
treatments have an area.
Table 6.4 The Solver Constraint Value Shadow price
solution for the dual problem
Area 60 8086.13
Period 1 50,000 0.27
Period 2 55,000 0.15
Period 3 64,315 0
End 10,800 27.23

(continued)
136 6 Optimisation

Example 6.3 (continued)


If a new alternative, thinning at second period, were considered with
harvest revenues 2700 /ha and volume in each period would be

Alternative Initial 2016 2026 2036


Thinning 180 225 135 202

the reduced cost for this alternative would be

2700  1  8086:13 0  0:27 2700  0:15 0  0 202  27:23


526:58;

meaning that this new alternative would be included in the optimal solution, if
it were included in the analysis. When it was included in the analysis, the
result was such that harvesting with clear-cutting in the second period is no
more in the solution (Table 6.5). Now, its reduced cost is also negative
meaning that it is not profitable. Also the optimal value is better, 180,702 .
The shadow prices for the new constraints are presented in Table 6.6. With
the new treatment included, the shadow price of the land has increased. Thus,
it relates to the value of land in the production, not necessarily to the market
value of land.

Table 6.5 The new solution Alternative Area (ha) Reduced cost
and the reduced costs
Harvest 1 9.52 0.00
Harvest 2 0.00 1343.68
Harvest 3 7.55 0.00
No harvest 16.74 0.00
Thinning 2 26.19 0.00

Table 6.6 The new shadow Constraint Value Shadow price


prices
Area 60 8441.05
Period 1 50,000 0.32
Period 2 70,702 0.00
Period 3 60,000 0.04
End 10,800 28.42
6.2 Forest Planning with LP 137

6.2 Forest Planning with LP

6.2.1 Formulating a Problem in an Estate Level

When there are m stands, with nk alternatives for each stand, the problem can be
formulated with

X
m X
nk
max z ck j xk j 6:10
k1 j1

subject to

X
m X
nk
ak ji xk j  bi , i 1, . . . , q 6:11
k1 j1

m X
X nk
ak ji xk j  bi , i q 1, . . . , p 6:12
k1 j1

X
nk
xk j hk , k 1, . . . , m 6:13
j1

x jk  08k 1, . . . , m, j 1, . . . , nk 6:14

where nk is the number of treatment alternatives for stand k, p is the number of


constraints, bi is the RHS value of constraint i and xkj is the area of stand k on which
treatment alternative j is applied. The total area of stand k is hk. In this case, a separate
area constraint is required for each m stands. The constraints (6.11) and (6.12) can be
defined as utility constraints, which describe the preferences of the decision-maker.
The area constraints (6.13), on the other hand, are merely technical constraints.
The formulation above is not, however, the only possibility for forestry prob-
lems. A frequently referred classification of forestry LP approaches is the one
presented by Johnson and Scheurman (1977). They divided the various LP problem
formulations applied to harvest scheduling into two basic types. With model I, each
activity variable is associated with a particular treatment schedule alternative that
covers the whole planning horizon. The example above follows this model I
formulation. In model II, instead, each individual treatment option forms a separate
activity variable. It means, for instance, that all stands that are clear-cut at the same
time can be combined into one calculation unit. This means, generally taken, that
138 6 Optimisation

optimisation problems formulated according to model II typically are greater and,


thus, need more calculation capacity to be solved in the same time as the same
problem formulated by model I. Nevertheless, according to Clutter et al. (1983),
some harvest-scheduling problems might be handled more efficiently through a
model II formulation.

Example 6.4
A real forest holding will be used to highlight how the introduction of
constraints impacts the timing and intensity of harvesting operations. The
forest for the real case examples is a small 47.3 ha forest from North
Karelia, Finland. It consists of 41 stands, which is primarily composed of
Scots pine and has a fairly even age distribution. The timescale of the
problem is for the next 30 years, which is separated into six five-year
periods. When considering harvesting options, one perspective could be to
manage the forest through a purely economic context. A commonly used
approach is to maximise the net present value of the forest holding, and the
formulation would be

max z NPV 6:15

subject to
!
X
T X nk 
m X  m X
X nk
CFk jt xk j PV k jT xk j PVLk jT xk j
NPV 6:16
t1 k1 j1 1 it k1 j1 1 iT
X
n
xk j hk , 8k 1, . . . , m 6:17
j1

where NPV is the net present value of the holding, CFkjt is the cash flow
from stand k and treatment option j at period t, i is the interest rate (for
this example, it is 3 %) and PVkjT and PVLkjT are, respectively, the
present value of the timber and present value of the land for the holding at
the last period. Here the first constraint is a technical constraint that is only
used to define NPV, and the definition could be embedded to the objective
function.
The results are shown in Fig. 6.2, with a net present value of 518,912. The
harvesting operations are concentrated in periods 1, 4 and 5, with smaller
harvesting operations for the remaining periods. Had the holding had a
perfectly even age distribution, it could be expected that each period would
have similar harvesting operations. In this case, the optimal solution could
also be found by just selecting the best treatment option for each stand
separately, as there are no area-level constraints.

(continued)
6.2 Forest Planning with LP 139

Example 6.4 (continued)

Fig. 6.2 The periodic flows without even-flow constraints

6.2.2 Even-Flow and End-Inventory Constraints

The previous formulation did not consider either the balancing of operations over
time, to provide for either continual resources or to balance the work requirements
over time. When employing even-flow constraints, the addition of an end-inventory
constraint is essential; otherwise, the formulation will propose a solution to harvest
all which is possible and be unsustainable for periods beyond what the formulation
considered. The formulation below maximises first period income subject to the
even-flow and end-inventory constraints:

X
m X
nk
max z CFkj1 xk j 6:18
k1 j1

subject to

X
m X
nk m X
X nk
CFkjt1 xk j  CFkjt xk j  0, t 1, . . . , T  1 6:19
k1 j1 k1 j1
140 6 Optimisation

X
m X
nk m X
X nk
PV k jT xk j  PV kj1 xk j  0 6:20
k1 j1 k1 j1

X
nk
xk j hk , k 1, . . . , m 6:21
j1

Example 6.5
The effects of introducing the even-flow constraints are easily seen in
Fig. 6.3. Each period provides the same amount of income for each of the
six periods. For this example, the net present value is 512,047 , which
implies a cost of 6865 to implement this set of constraints. The present
value of the holding can fluctuate within the periods; however, at the end
period, it is identical to the initial present value of the holding, which is
428,510 .

Fig. 6.3 The periodic flows with even-flow constraints


6.2 Forest Planning with LP 141

6.2.3 Production Possibility Frontier

Two- and three-dimensional curves can be used to analyse the joint production
possibilities of two or three given outputs. The frontier analysis identifies possible
and efficient production combinations for the outputs examined with given
resources. Any point inside the curve implies that the resources available are not
fully used or are used inefficiently (Zhang and Pearse 2011). The production
possibility frontier is often called a Pareto front.
In forest planning, the production possibility frontiers can be created with LP. In
the case of two-dimensional production possibility frontier, one objective variable
is maximised and the other variable of the frontier is used as the constraint. By
varying the value of the constraint between its minimum and maximum values, the
LP solution gives the value for the other variable (e.g. Karkkainen et al. 2014). This
is also the easiest way to do multi-objective optimisation, and it is called the
-constraint method (Miettinen 1999).

Example 6.6
To demonstrate the creation of a production possibility frontier (PPF), a
problem with two clear variables is used, using the materials from 6.2.2. The
problem used by all methods is to maximise the first five-year period of income,
subject to both a non-declining income requirement and an end-volume con-
straint. The production possibility frontier will be between the periodic
incomes (i.e. the first five-year period) and the end volume of the stand. The
mathematical representation is similar to that found in 6.2.2, with a slight
change in the end-inventory constraint, replacing Eq. 6.20 with 6.22 as follows:
X
m X
nk
vk jT xk j  V end 6:22
k1 j1

where the Vend is a variable set by the decision-maker. To produce a PPF, Vend
is set at equally spaced intervals, detailed in Table 6.7 and shown in Fig. 6.4,
and for each value the problem is solved.
Table 6.7 The target end volume and iterative results used to produce the production
possibility frontier, using linear programming
End-volume constraint (m3) First period income () Volume (m3)
3185 72,287 3528
3885 71,722 3885
4585 69,705 4585
5285 67,423 5285
(continued)

(continued)
142 6 Optimisation

Example 6.6 (continued)


Table 6.7 (continued)
End-volume constraint (m3) First period income () Volume (m3)
5985 64,770 5985
6685 61,623 6685
7385 58,296 7385
8085 54,596 8085
8785 50,794 8785
9485 46,870 9485
10,185 42,798 10,185
10,885 38,616 10,885
11,585 34,235 11,585
12,285 29,769 12,285
12,985 25,238 12,985
13,685 20,635 13,685
14,385 15,953 14,385
15,085 11,180 15,085
15,785 6215 15,785
16,485 706 16,485

Fig. 6.4 The production possibility frontier highlighting the trade-off between first period
income and volume remaining at the end of the planning horizon
6.3 Goal Programming 143

6.3 Goal Programming

6.3.1 Soft Constraints

Goal programming (GP) is a special case of linear programming. It was first


described by Charnes and Cooper (1961). A forestry application of GP was first
presented by Field (1973). After that, several applications of GP to forest man-
agement planning have been presented (e.g. Daz-Balteiro and Romero 2001,
2003). Mendoza (1987) provided an overview of GP formulations and extensions
with special reference to forest planning. Tamiz et al. (1998) provided a more
general overview of GP elaborations and applications. By using goal program-
ming, some crucial problems of standard linear programming (LP) can be
avoided. However, the GP problem is solved similarly as in standard linear
programming.
In standard linear programming, a single overriding management goal is
assumed, which is represented by the objective function. For interpretational
purposes, it is recommendable to use a single-criterion objective function, the
variables of which are commensurable and compatible. Other objectives are taken
into account through constraints. The description of management goals by standard
LP constraints may be unsatisfactory for several reasons. The selection of the goal
to be handled as the objective function is arbitrary. The objective function is
optimised within the feasible region defined by the rigid LP constraints; thus, the
constraints may, in fact, receive a greater weight than the objective. Rigid con-
straints may also cause infeasibility problems.
In comparison to standard LP, GP facilitates the incorporation of the decision-
makers preferences into optimisation problems. In addition, GP formulations
may better reflect the multi-criteria nature of forest management. However, GP
does not solve all the problems related to LP. For example, proportionality,
divisibility and additivity assumptions of LP also hold with GP and may be
problems.
In GP, all the objectives are handled in the same manner: they are expressed by
goal constraints. A goal constraint includes goal variables that measure the amount
by which the contribution of all activities to the goal in question falls short or
exceeds the goal target level (i.e. the right-hand side of the constraint). The
objective function of a GP problem is to minimise the (weighted) distance from
all target levels associated with the management goals. When goal variables are
included in a constraint, the problem of infeasibility linked to the constraint is
avoided.
There are a large variety of GP formulations which used to express the priorities
of the decision-maker. Two of the most fundamental GP formulations are the
144 6 Optimisation

weighted GP, WGP (Ignizio 1976), and the minimax GP, MGP (Flavell 1976). The
WGP approach minimises the aggregated weighted deviations from the target and
provides an efficient solution. The MGP approach minimises the maximum
weighted deviations from the target and provides an equitable solution.
The general formulation of the WGP problem is

X
p
min z w 
i d i wi d i 6:23
i1

subject to

X
n
ai j x j d 
i d i Gi , i 1, . . . , p 6:24
j1

X
n
ai j x j  or or  bi , i p 1, . . . , P 6:25
j1

x j , d
i , d i  08i, j 6:26

where (6.23) is the goal programming objective function, (6.24) is a goal constraint,
(6.25) is an ordinary LP constraint, p is the number of goals represented by goal
constraints and P is the total number of constraints.
In the objective function and in the goal constraints, d i is the underachieve-
ment deviation variable and d i is the overachievement deviation variable. Both of
the deviation variables are required to be non-negative (6.25). Minimising the
differences ensures that one of these deviation variables is always zero, and the
other can deviate from zero. If the underachievement variable is greater than zero,
Xn
then amount d i needs to be added to ai j x j in order to achieve the target level Gi
j1
for goal i, and if d
i is greater than zero, this amount needs to be subtracted from it
to achieve the goal.
The general formulation of the MGP problem is

min D 6:27

subject to

w 
i d i wi d i  D  0, i 1, . . . , p 6:28

and subject to Eqs. 6.24, 6.25 and 6.26, where D is the maximum deviation away
from all targets i.
6.3 Goal Programming 145

The deviations can be weighted according to their importance; in the objective


function, wi is the weight given to each unit of underachievement deviation, and
wi is the weight given to each unit of overachievement deviation. The weights can
be interpreted to have two separate roles in the problem. As scaling factors, weights
wi and wi reduce deviations expressed in different measurement units to a
common unit of measurement. As importance weights, they describe the relative
importance of the goal variables. Because of these intermingling roles, the inter-
pretation of weights as the relative importance of goals, respectively, is not
unambiguous unless these roles are clearly separated. For instance, Kangas and
Pukkala (1992) presented an approach where the greatest or smallest attainable
target level (Gu-max i) of each goal constraint was first solved. This target level was
considered to represent the greatest possible sub-utility, referring to the objective in
question. The goal objective was to minimise the weighted sum of relative devia-
tions from the maximum or minimum attainable target levels. Weights were
determined using the analytic hierarchy process (Saaty 1977; 1980). Thus, the
formulation of the GP model was (assuming same weight for positive and negative
X p
wi   
deviations) min di di , where dividing with Gumax i works as a
i1
G umax i
scaling factor and w as the relative importance of the goal.
Other definitions are the same as before; xj is the jth activity variable, aij is the
contribution to goal i made by each unit of activity j and n is the number of activity
variables. Standard LP constraint may be used if any deviation from a goal target
level is unacceptable. Also, constraint with only one deviation variable, either d i or
di , can be applied.
Crucial issues when utilising GP include: (i) specifying the target levels of the
goals, (ii) determining the weights used in the objective function, (iii) making goals
measured with different units commensurable and (iv) appropriately selecting the
goal programming model. Any mathematical programming problem has to be
formulated so that the solution is as much as possible in line with the preferences
of the decision-maker. Prior information on the preferences of the decision-maker is
needed to formulate the problem appropriately.
Specifying a set of a priori relative weights for the goals is often found to be
difficult. Several methods for estimating the weights through an interactive process
have been presented (e.g. Duckstein et al. 1988; Tecle et al. 1994, Eyvindson
et al. 2015). Unfortunately, for most decision-makers, it is difficult to supply the
right information concerning his preferences, required to determine the search
direction and the step size in this direction. The better the first problem formulation,
the faster the optimal solution can be found. In the very first problem formulation,
some a priori weights are always required.
One obvious complication in goal programming is the setting of the targets. If
the targets are set too low, the resulting solution can be inefficient, i.e. it does not lie
in the production possibility frontier. This problem can be avoided, if the targets are
set to be high enough.
146 6 Optimisation

Example 6.7
Assume again a forest area of 60 ha with initial mean volume of 180 m3/ha.
The planning horizon is 30 years and divided to three 10-year periods. The
treatment possibilities are the same as the previous example, clear-cut at the
first, second or third period, the thinning at second period and no harvests.
The forest is assumed to develop according to Table 6.1 and the resulting
incomes according to Table 6.2, added with the development of the thinning
alternative given in Example 6.3 (x5). The decision-maker has set goals for
the incomes from the three periods, as well as for the volume at the third
period. The goals are 60,000 for each period and 14,000 m3 for the final
volume. The WGP problem is formulated as

min z d   
1 d1 d2 d2 d3 d3 de de ;

describing the deviations from the four goals. The area constraint is the same
as in the earlier example:

x1 x2 x3 x4 x5 60

The revenue constraints for the three periods are now

5250x1 0x2 0x3 0x4 0x5 d 


1  d 1 60, 000

0x1 6600x2 0x3 0x4 2700x5 d 


2  d 2 60, 000

0x1 0x2 7950x3 0x4 0x5 d 


3  d 3 60, 000

and the constraint for the volume in the end of the period is

52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4 202x5 d 


e  d e 14, 000:

The result is to harvest 11.43 ha in the first period, thin 22.22 in the second
period, clear-cut 7.55 ha in the third period and leave 18.80 ha not harvested.
All the income goals for three periods are achieved, so that corresponding
deviation variables are zero. The only deviation variable not at a zero level is
that of underachievement of the end volume, which has a value of
3289.17 m3. Thus, the end volume is 10,710.83 m3. If a weight of 50 is
given to the deviations of the end volume, i.e. minimising

min z d   
1 d 1 d 2 d 2 d 3 d 3 50d e 50d e ;

the results did change. The end volume is now equal to the starting volume.
On the other hand, now the negative deviation in the first period revenues was
60,000 and third period revenues was 46,526.26, meaning that if a high

(continued)
6.3 Goal Programming 147

Example 6.7 (continued)


weight was given to the end-volume deviation, it was not optimal to clear-cut
at the first period at all and some of the clear-cutting would not be done in the
third period. Instead, there was 22.22 ha thinning in the second period and
5.85 ha clear-cutting in the third period and 31.93 ha were not harvested at all.
The MGP problem is formulated in a similar fashion, only the objective
function is different, and four constraints are added. The objective function is
now

min D

which describes the maximum deviation for all targets defined by the follow-
ing constraints:
 
d 
1 d1  D  0
 
d2 d
2 D 0
 
d3 d
3 D 0
 
de d
e D 0

The revenue constraints and the constraint for the end-period volume remain
the same. The result is to harvest 10.87 ha in the first period, thin 21.13 in the
second period, clear-cut 7.18 ha in the third period and leave 20.82 ha not
harvested. This provides an income of 57,059 per period, and the end
volume is at 11,059 m3. If a weight of 50 is given to the deviations of the
end volume, i.e. one constraint changes to
 
50d 
e 50d e  D  0;

the results will change. The end volume is now much closer to the starting
volume, at 13,525 m3. The revenues for all of the periods suffer from an equal
negative deviation, so that revenues for all periods are 36,249. There was
6.9 ha clear-cutting in the first period, 13.43 ha thinning in the second period
and 4.56 ha clear-cutting in the third period, and 35.11 ha were not harvested
at all. One thing to notice is that for both of the MGP problem formulations,
none of the targets were fully met, and the deviations were evenly allocated
(dependent on the weight) to all of the goals. In this case, four goals were
used, three of which were evaluated in euros and one in volume of timber.
When the deviations are weighted equally, one cubic metre timber is consid-
ered equivalent to one euro. Thus, if the goals cannot be expressed in the same
units, they should be weighted so that the end result is appropriate for the
decision-maker (e.g. Kangas and Pukkala 1992).
148 6 Optimisation

Example 6.8
Earlier in Example 6.5, the formulation used constraints to ensure the even
flow of income and the requirement to have the end inventory at least equal to
the starting inventory. These constraints can be softened by including them
into the objective function as a penalty. In the following formulation, the
objective is to maximise first period income while minimising the deviations
from even-flow and end-inventory requirement:

X
m X
nk
max z CFkj1 xk j
k1 j1
!
X
T  
 p
t dt p 
t dt p
e de p 
e de 6:29
t1

subject to

m X
X nk m X
X nk
CFk jt1 xk j  CFk jt xk j  d 
t d t 0,
k1 j1 k1 j1
6:30
t 1, . . . , T  1
XX
m n k Xm X nk
PV kjT xk j  PV kj1 xk j  d 
e de 0 6:31
k1 j1 k1 j1

X
nk
xk j hk , k 1, . . . , m 6:32
j1

d
t , d t  0, t 1, . . . , T  1 6:33
d
e , de 0 6:34

where p  
t , pt , pe and pe are the penalties associated with negative (pos-
itive) deviations. The penalties can be chosen by the preferences of the
decision-maker. In this case, the shadow prices of the problem with hard
constraints (the example in 6.2.2) were used as penalties. The use of
(absolute values of) shadow prices reflects the costs associated with
obtaining even flow for each constraint (see also Lappi and Siitonen
1985). In this case, the penalties were 0.781, 0.584, 0.386, 0.239, 0.118
and 0.103 for the five periodic income constraints and the end-inventory
constraint, respectively.

(continued)
6.3 Goal Programming 149

Example 6.8 (continued)

Fig. 6.5 The periodic flows with soft even-flow constraints

The effects of softening the constraints can be seen in Fig. 6.5. The first
period income is higher than all of the other income periods, and the incomes
for periods 26 are all equal. The end inventory remains the same as the initial
inventory. In this case, the softening of the even-flow constraints is conducted
simply by introducing variables which measures the deviation between each
income period and including the deviations into the objective function. In the
results, it is rather clear that all of the negative deviations occur between
periods 1 and 2, and there are no deviations for any of the other periods. So
while there is a softening between period 1 and the remaining periods, there is
no softening between periods 26.
In order to soften the remaining periods, we need to reconsider the
measurement of the even flow constraint. In the previous example, Eq. 6.30
requires the future period to be equal to the previous period plus the deviation.
When measured in this fashion, the majority of the deviations will be allo-
cated between only two periods, in this case between periods 1 and 2. Rather
than measuring the deviations between the periods, even flow could be

(continued)
150 6 Optimisation

Example 6.8 (continued)


measured as the deviation of future periods compared to the initial period, as
in Eq. 6.35. In this way, the deviations of earlier periods will not influence the
current period. As an example, the same formulation will be used, with only
the change in measuring even flow, and the corresponding penalties

X
m X
nk m X
X nk
CFk jt1 xk j  CFk j1 xk j  d 
t d t 0,
k1 j1 k1 j1
6:35
t 1, . . . , T  1

where the only change is the bolded value, from t to 1. This changes the
shadow prices, and thus the penalties were 0.197, 0.198, 0147, 0.121, 0.118
and 0.103 for the five periodic income constraints and the end-inventory
constraint, respectively.
The effects of changing how the even-flow constraint was measured can be
observed in Fig. 6.6. Now periods 1, 3 and 4 are identical, while periods 2 and
5 are allocated in the majority of the deviations. As both negative and positive
deviations are penalised, none of the periods will have an income greater than
the first period.

Fig. 6.6 The periodic flows with soft even-flow constraints and lower penalties
6.3 Goal Programming 151

6.3.2 Balancing Different Goals

When managing the resources of a forest, the decision-maker(s) may wish to


consider a wide range of goals. In the previous examples, the focus has been on
mainly economic considerations, which are measured in monetary terms. Any
forest value which can be measured and predicted can be included into the formu-
lation as a goal. Other forest values, which either cannot be accurately measured or
predicted, can be included in the planning calculations in different ways by using
proxy variables, e.g. different indices based on expert modelling (e.g. Kangas
et al 1998) or by defining those types of forests where the forest value at hand
typically exists. For instance, currently mushroom yields are difficult to predict, but
as some mushrooms occur in maturing spruce stands, the goal or constraint related
to this forest type can ensure the possibility for mushroom picking opportunities.
When utilising goals which have different measurement units, they need to be
made comparable through normalisation (Jones and Tamiz 2010). A variety of
normalisation methods are available, and the choice of which method is used will
influence the solution obtained. The percentage, ratio and interval normalisation
methods are commonly used in GP. The percentage normalisation divides the
deviation by the target for each goal, so that all of the deviations are measured in
percentages. Ratio normalisation is done by dividing the deviation by the maximum
value for the respective targets. Interval normalisation is done by dividing the
deviation by the difference of the maximum and minimum value for the respective
targets.
The choice of which GP formulation will be used must be based on the needs of
the decision-maker(s). In fact, the goal programming formulation should be
designed specifically to accommodate the needs of the decision-maker(s). The
general structure of the GP formulation can be adapted in a variety of different
ways. The decision-maker may be able to segregate the goals based on their priority
or may desire a solution which is between the most efficient solution and the most
equitable solution. A general GP structure has been formulated (Romero 2004)
which can allow for the inclusion of a wide range or modifications. In addition,
when dealing with multiple decision-makers, the formulation could be adjusted to
allow for the inclusion of multiple targets for the same goal and for different sets of
goals for each decision-maker (Eyvindson et al. 2010).

Example 6.9
The impact of making adjustments to the GP formulation is described through
an example that uses the same forest holding as in Sect. 6.2.1; however, a
different selection of goals will be used. Two GP formulations will be
described, and the differences in their solutions, when all other variables
remain the same, will highlight the importance of appropriately selecting the
model used. The first formulation will be extended GP (Romero 2004); this

(continued)
152 6 Optimisation

Example 6.9 (continued)


formulation merges the WGP and MGP formulation together through the
introduction of a parameter . All of the goals will be normalised with
through the interval normalisation method. Only those deviations which are
considered undesirable are included by assigning a weight of 1 to the devi-
ations which are undesirable and a weight of 0 to the deviations which are
desirable. The parameter is user controlled and allows for compromise
solutions between the WGP solution and MGP solution to be found. The
formulation is as follows:

X
p
 
min z 1  D w 
i d i wi d i 6:36
i1

subject to

2 0; 1 6:37

and subject to Eqs. 6.23, 6.24 and 6.25, where is a user-defined parameter
between 0 and 1.
The results for this formulation are found alongside the previous formu-
lation in Table 6.8.
In the previous GP formulation, all of the goals were treated in the same
fashion. The deviations for the set of goals were minimised based on the same
metric. It is also possible to formulate the GP problem so that different
partitions of goals are treated differently. This may be beneficial when
managing a forest where the goals can be segregated into either economic
or ecological goals (Eyvindson 2012). The modified GP formulation is as
follows:

X
q1
 
min z D w 
i d i wi d i 6:38
i1

subject to

X
n
ai j x j d 
i  d i Gi , i 1, . . . , q1 6:39
ji
 
w 
i d i wi d i  D  0, i q1 1, . . . , q1 q2 6:40
X
n
ai j x j  or or  bi , i q2 1, . . . , q2 q3 6:41
ji

(continued)
6.3 Goal Programming

Example 6.9 (continued)


Table 6.8 The solutions to the different GP formulations
Extended GP Balanced GP
Target value (Gi) Normalisation factor (ki) w w 1 2 3 4
0 0.5 1
Present value 190,000 236,248 1/k 0 190,000 190,000 191,726 200,427
Income (115 years ) 100,000 444,936 1/k 0 68,136 39,809 76,472 54,256
Income (1630 years ) 100,000 239,673 1/k 0 82,836 100,000 87,326 75,359
Total volume (m3) 13,000 15,925 1/k 0 12,123 12,482 12,158 13,000
Volume of broadleaved trees (m3) 1500 1894 1/k 0 1761 1883 1429 1755
Clear-cut area (ha) 4 22.7 0 1/k 4 4 9.5 4
153
154 6 Optimisation

Example 6.9 (continued)


and Eq. 6.25. We have q goals which are partitioned as follows:

q q1 q2 q3 , being

i 1, . . . , q1 , goals to be satisfied based on optimising the average


achievement (WGP),
i q1 1, . . . , q1 q2 , goals to be satisfied based on optimising the
balanced achievement (MGP), and
i q2 1, . . . , q2 q3 which provides lower bounds for the goals.
Using the same targets and normalisation factor as the previous example, a
plan can be developed for comparison. For this formulation, all goals must be
separated into partitions. Those goals which are related to ecological values
will be allocated to q1, economic values will be allocated to q2, and there will
be nothing allocated to the q3 partition besides the area constraints. In this
way, the partition q1 will focus on maximising the average achievement
between the ecological goals, and partition q2 will focus on maximising the
balanced achievement between the economic goals.
The partitions, normalisation constants and results are displayed in
Table 6.8. In this case, four of the goals meet or exceed their target values
(present value, timber volume, broadleaved volume and clear-cut area). Both
of the income goals are rather far from the goal. If the decision-maker is
unhappy with the solution, the weights associated with the different goals can
be adjusted. None of these plans are dominated, and each highlights different
perspectives of efficient forest management. The selection of the most appro-
priate alternative is the one which most accurately reflects the preferences of
the decision-maker, which is subjectively defined by the decision-maker
himself/herself.

6.4 General Forest Planning Problem Formulation

All the problem formulations above can be defined using a general problem
formulation. For instance, it is possible to formulate a constraint that the harvesting
level at period 2 must be greater than that in the first period; the difference can be
set to greater or equal than zero using constants a and b in the constraint (6.47). In
the earlier formulation, the difference variable needs to be explicitly formulated.
The model is presented as

X
p X
q
max or min z a0k xk b0k zk 6:42
k1 k1
6.4 General Forest Planning Problem Formulation 155

subject to

X
p X
q
ct  atk xk btk zk  Ct , t 1, . . . , r 6:43
k1 k1
m X
X ni
xk  xik j wi j 0, k 1, . . . , p 6:44
i1 j1

X
ni
wi j 1, i 1, . . . , m 6:45
j1

wi j  0, 8i, j 6:46
zk  0, 8k 6:47

The objective function is a sum of p interesting input and output variables xk and
q other decision variables zk. Thus, this formulation allows for maximising with
respect to several criteria at the same time, using fixed constants a0k that can be
given by the decision-maker as weights. The other decision variables in the
objective function include, for instance, slack and surplus variables used for goal
programming.
The objective function (6.42) and constraints (6.43) are formulated so that explicit
summation across the separate stands is not needed. The output and input variables
are directly presented at forest estate-level variables xk, which should be fairly
intuitive to the decision-makers. Instead, the summation is done in the constraint
(6.44). There, it is set that the aggregated value of xk is the sum of xijk , the amount of
variable k produced or consumed by unit i if schedule j is applied, over m treatment
units and the ni treatment schedules in these treatment units, weighted with the
proportion of area in each unit i treated according to schedule j, wij. It should be
noted that xijk is expressed in a stand level, not per hectare (RHS of 6.45 is 1).
The coefficients c and C denote the lower and upper bounds given to the utility
constraints. In usual LP formulation, these kinds of constraints need to be presented
using two separate constraints for the upper and lower bound. These are dealt with
the knowledge that only one of the bounds can be binding at a time.
The JLP/J algorithm is able to utilise the above-presented problem formulation in
such a way that the area constraint (6.45) and the summation of input and output
variables (6.44) are carried out automatically, i.e. the decision-maker does not need to
give these formulations to the algorithm (for JLP, see Lappi 1992; for J, see http://
mela2.metla.fi/mela/J/index.htm). The algorithm uses a so-called generalised upper-
bound technique to solve the problem, where the area constraints are embedded to
constraints of the form (6.43) (Lappi 1992 p. 108) so that the number of active
constraints in the problem can be effectively reduced. Both in the problem formula-
tion and in solving the problem, the special features of a forest planning problem are
applied. That helps in reducing the calculation times.
156 6 Optimisation

The general problem formulation also allows for domain-specific goals or


constraints. The domain is a sub-selection of stands, defined by the decision-
maker. It could be, for instance, a buffer zone along a stream or a lekking area
for game bird capercaillie, for which the forest cover is required to remain at a
specific level. Domain-specific constraints and goals can be defined using domain-
specific xk variables which are obtained by summing only over those stands which
belong to the domain in question, i.e.

XX
ni
xkDt  xik j wi j 0, k 1, . . . , p, t 1, . . . , r:
i2Dt j1

In JLP/J, the domains can be defined with logical statements using stand variables,
and they are treated computationally efficiently (Lappi 1992).
The problem formulation can be further generalised to also include the factories
to which the timber is taken (Lappi and Lempinen 2014). This is achieved by
adding to the objective function two new terms that describe the amount of item
transported to a given factory f and the utility obtained from that item as

X
p X
q p X
X F
max or min z a0k xk b0k zk 0k f xk f
k1 k1 k1 f 1
p X
X F
0k f yk f 6:48
k1 f 1

where and are fixed constants that serve as weights to the different variables.
Here, xkf is the amount of timber assortment k transported to factory f, and ykf is
describes the (location-specific) benefits from transporting assortment k to factory f.
That variable can be used to account for the transportation costs. The capacity of
factories can be accounted for by setting a lower or upper limit to xkf. The previous
formulation is obtained as a special case from this, assuming these constants are set
to zero. The constraints (6.43) are generalised in the same fashion as

X
p X
q p X
X F p X
X F
ct  atk xk btk zk 0k f xk f 0k f yk f  Ct ,
k1 k1 k1 f 1 k1 f 1 6:49
t 1, . . . , r

In addition, the formulation requires technical constraints similar to (6.44) for the
items transported to the factories and the utilities and a constraint stating that all
timber needs to be transported somewhere.
6.5 Integer Programming 157

6.5 Integer Programming

In some cases, the decision variables can only have integer values; for instance, the
number of employees in an enterprise is an integer variable. Such problems can be
solved using integer programming (IP). In some cases, part of the variables can
have integer values while the rest of them are continuous. Such problems call for
mixed integer programming (MIP). A special case of integer variables is a case
where only binary values (0 and 1) are allowed. Examples of binary variables are,
for instance, transportation routes. It is not possible to take a part of any one route,
but one needs to follow one route from beginning to end. The problems caused by
divisibility (e.g. division of calculation units for different treatment options) may
also be avoided by applying integer programming or IP.

Example 6.10
In Example 6.1., the problem is clearly an integer problem: one can only
produce whole toys. The solution to the problem in 6.1 was an integer
solution, but if the other constraint was slightly changed, so that there is
7 dm3 of spruce available, the optimal solution would not be an integer
solution anymore. In this problem, the optimal integer solution can also be
found graphically. In Fig. 6.7., all the possible integer solutions are presented
with blue dots. In the example, the optimal solution is to produce 1.67 trains
and 2.67 cars, with revenue of 10.33 . The optimal integer solution is to
produce two pieces of both trains and cars, with revenue of 10 , i.e. less than
the optimal revenue in the original problem.

Fig. 6.7 The possible


integer solutions
158 6 Optimisation

The optimum of the integer problem can at best be as good as the solution of the
ordinary LP problem. Thus, the IP solution is always bounded by the original LP
solution. This can be used when solving the IP problems.
There are two popular ways of solving the integer problems, namely, the branch-
and-bound algorithm and cutting plane method (Taha 2007). These algorithms
exploit a normal simplex algorithm and computing power. The strategy includes
three steps (Taha 2007 p. 370):
1. Relax the solution space of the ILP by replacing any binary value y with the
continuous range 0  y  1 and deleting the integer restrictions on all the integer
variables. The result of the relaxation is a regular LP.
2. Solve the LP problem, and identify its continuous optimum.
3. Starting from the continuous optimum point, add special constraints that itera-
tively modify the LP solution space in a manner that will eventually give an
optimum point that satisfies the integer requirements.
In branch and bound, the special constraints are two additional constraints. They
are such that if an optimal solution to integer variable x1 was 0.5 in the solution, it is
in the next phase required to be either x1  0 or x1  1. As both of these constraints
cannot be satisfied at the same time, two new LP problems are formed from the
original one, with one additional constraint in both of them. Then, both these new
problems are solved, i.e. the problem is branched to two. If needed, the problem is
branched further and further, and the best solution found this way is finally selected.
Thus, integer problems can be much harder to solve than ordinary LP problems.
However, the optimal solution to the original problem can only be the solution of
one of these new problems. In some cases, it is possible to determine that the search
needs not to be continued in one of the branches, since better results can be obtained
from other branches. Then it is possible to intelligently reduce the work needed.

Example 6.11
In Example 6.10, the optimal solution to the original problem was to produce
1.67 trains and 2.67 cars with revenue of 10.33. As the problem is an integer
problem, in the first branching of the branch-and-bound technique, x1 is
required to be either x1  1 or x1  2. The resulting two solutions are:

LP1 : x1 1, x2 3 and objective function value is 9:


LP2 : x1 2, x2 2 and objective function value is 10:

As both of these branches produced an integer solution, no further branching


is needed. Then, the better of these solutions is selected, namely, the solution
LP2.
6.5 Integer Programming 159

Example 6.12
Assume a forest area with three different stands and three management
options for each of them, not harvesting, thinning and clear-cutting. The
problem is to maximise the harvested volume while the growing stock
volume needs to be at least 2300 m3. The harvesting volumes and remaining
growing stock volumes for the three stands and three alternatives are
presented in Table 6.9. Note that in this example both these volumes are
given in m3 per whole stand area, not per hectare.
As a normal LP problem, this problem can be presented as

max z 0x11 559x12 1260x13 0x21 762x22 1770x23 0x31


585x32 1170x33 ;

where xij is the proportion of stand i managed with treatment alternative j


subject to
x11 x12 x13 1
x21 x22 x23 1
x31 x32 x33 1

indicating that, in each stand, the sum of proportions must be equal to


one and

1821x11 798x12 21x13 1800x21 1098x22 18x23 1170x31


702x32 8x33  2300

is the constraint for end volume. The resulting harvest volume is 2184.3 m3,
and the proportions of the treatments in each stand are presented in Table 6.10.
The solution is an integer solution in stands 1 and 3, but stand 2 is divided. If
an integer solution is made by rounding this solution, i.e. thinning the stand
2, the resulting harvest volume is 1906 m3, and the corresponding end volume
is 2598 m3. Thus, the end volume is much larger than required and the
harvesting volume is clearly worse than in the LP result.

Table 6.9 The problem data


Variable No harvest Thinning Clear-cut
Stand 1 Harvest volume 0 559 1260
End volume 1281 798 21
Stand 2 Harvest volume 0 762 1770
End volume 1800 1098 18
Stand 3 Harvest volume 0 585 1170
End volume 1170 702 8

(continued)
160 6 Optimisation

Example 6.12 (continued)

Table 6.10 Proportions of No harvest Thinning Clear-cut


treatment alternatives
Stand 1 1 0 0
Stand 2 0 0.72 0.28
Stand 3 0 1 0

If the decision variables x11x33 are required to have binary values, the
resulting harvest volume is 1932 m3, and the corresponding end volume is
2387 m3. The MIP result is clearly more efficient than the solution obtained
from rounding. The resulting treatment recommendations are also different:
in the MIP solution, stand 1 is not harvested and stand 2 is thinned but stand
3 is clear-cut.

6.6 Hierarchical Forest Planning

Forest planning is essentially hierarchical planning. In strategic planning, the main


targets for the use of forest resources are set. Tactical planning is based on these
targets, and its task is to assure the most effective use of the available resources, and
operational control takes care that special tasks are meaningfully implemented. In
addition, the typical scales of forest planning, i.e. stand, forest holding and larger
area, are interlinked so that the decisions made at one hierarchical level affect the
other levels.
The basic idea in hierarchical planning is to decompose a problem into smaller
entities, which are easier to manage both in relation to the issues themselves and to
the data (e.g. Wu and David 2002). A key challenge in hierarchical planning is to
ensure consistency between the planning levels (Weintraub and Cholaky 1991).
The two basic approaches of hierarchical planning are top-down and bottom-up.
In the top-down approach, the use of forest resources is planned and decided first at
the top level. Technically, this approach allocates resources optimally from the point
of view of organisations top-level goals, subject to the production possibilities of the
whole planning area (Kurttila et al. 2001). After the top-level allocation, the problem
can be decomposed into tactical planning tasks and/or subarea-level planning prob-
lems (Weintraub and Cholaky 1991). However, the top-down approach may include
some weaknesses regarding, for example, the acceptability at the lower levels. For
example, the cutting proposals may be unrealistic on the lower level (e.g. Weintraub
and Davis 1996), which may make the implementation of the operations difficult.
In the bottom-up approach, the bottom-level processes and planning are
emphasised first. A limited number of efficient and approved plan alternatives
can be first created for the bottom levels. The top-level plan is then composed as
an aggregate of these plan alternatives (e.g. Kurttila et al. 2001; Kangas et al. 2014).
6.7 Spatial Goals and Constraints in Linear Programming 161

If several alternative plans are accepted from the lower levels, the aggregation can
be carried out by utilising, for example, integer optimisation, where the top-level
goals are included in the objective function. The alternative plans at lower level
(e.g. holding level) are binary variables (see Sect. 6.4). Treating the lower-level
plans as indivisible guarantees acceptance and feasibility at lower level. A weak-
ness of the bottom-up approach is that the aggregate solution may appear to be not
acceptable at the top level if the combinations of the lower-level alternatives are not
in line with the top-level goals.
The above descriptions of the basic approaches and in particular their weak-
nesses highlight the importance of structured feedback mechanisms and negotia-
tions between the planning levels. For example, more accurate operational and
tactical constraints from the lower levels may be needed to act as feedback methods
to the strategic level. To tackle these issues, Bettinger et al. (2005), for example,
developed a model for large-scale landscape planning that included both top-down
and bottom-up approaches.

6.7 Spatial Goals and Constraints in Linear Programming

6.7.1 Adjacency Constraints and Green-Up Constraints

In some countries and areas, there are legal limits or recommendations on the
maximum clear-cut size. Adjacency constraints ensure that the predetermined
maximum size of the clear-cut is not exceeded. In addition, another related term
is the exclusion period, which defines the length of the so-called green-up period
which specifies the duration for the adjacency constraints (Goycoolea et al. 2009).
The reasons for making use of adjacency constraints include the fixed statutory
limits on the maximum clear-cut size, environmental factors to do with wildlife
habitats or overall diversity and the damage, risks or changed growing conditions
imposed on adjacent stands by clear-cuttings.
The maximum clear-cut size and exclusion period can be included in the
calculations by using the stand adjacency relations as additional constraints in the
optimisation problem (e.g. Murray 1999). Adjacency can be defined between stands
sharing a common border or it can be based on the distances between stands.
The general mathematical representation of adjacency constraints as a harvest-
scheduling problem includes the objective function, the adjacency and exclusion
period constraints, which restrict the harvesting of adjacent stands during a spec-
ified exclusion period, the integer variable constraints and possibly other constraints
related to sustainability and the even flow of removals. The problem with the
adjacency constraints is that the solving time for the problems may be very large,
as a large number of constraints need to be applied (Weintraub et al. 1994). If each
of the stands (or a predefined cluster of stands) is roughly the size of the maximum
clear-cut area, the problem is still fairly easy, but in case the stands are clearly
162 6 Optimisation

smaller than the maximum clear-cut area, i.e. several different combinations of two
or more stands need to be considered, the problem is much more complicated
(Bettinger et al. 2009). The former of these problem types is referred to as URM
(unit restriction model) and the latter as ARM (area restriction model) (Goycoolea
et al. 2009).
The URM model with an adjacency constraint, assuming each stand only has
two treatment options, to clear-cut (x 1) or do nothing (x 0), is formulated as
follows:

X
m
max z ck xk 6:50
k1

subject to

X
m
aik xk  bi , i 1, . . . , q 6:51
k1

xk xl  1, k 1, . . . , m, l 1, . . . , N k 6:52
xk 2 0; 1, 8k 6:53

where the objective function and the first q constraints are basic constraints desired,
and constraint 6.52 says that for each stand k, the sum of treatments in the stand and
its neighbourhood Nk is at most 1. It means that if stand k is treated, none of its
neighbours can be, and if even one of the neighbours is treated (xl 1), stand
k needs to be left untreated. If a green-up period of n years is included, it means that
each stand has an option to be treated at any of the T time periods considered. Then,
the problem is formulated with

X
m X
T
max z ckt xkt 6:54
k1 t1

subject to

X
m
aikt xkt  bi , i 1, . . . , q, t 1, . . . , T 6:55
k1

X
tn
xkt  1, k 1, . . . , m, t n 1, . . . , T  n 6:56
ttn

xkt xlt0  1, k 1, . . . , m, l 1, . . . , N k , t 1, . . . , T, t0
t  n, . . . , t n 6:57
xit 2 0; 1, 8i, t 6:58
6.7 Spatial Goals and Constraints in Linear Programming 163

where the objective function and the first q constraints now include the harvesting
period. Constraint 6.56 says that each stand k can only be harvested once during
time periods [tn,t n], and 6.57 says that stand k at period t can only be harvested
if none of the stands in the neighbourhood Nk are harvested within the green-up
period of n years.
In essence, two main lines of optimisation techniques are used: firstly, the
LP-based integer programming (IP) and mixed integer programming (MIP) tech-
niques and, secondly, heuristics. As the adjacency constraints increase the problem
size very fast, many different problem formulations have been developed, to make
the problem easier (McDill and Braze 2000).

Example 6.13
Assume an estate with 9 square-shaped stands. The number and volume of
each of the stands are given with a table as

150 (1) 30 (2) 70 (3)

180 (4) 25 (5) 215 (6)

50 (7) 60 (8) 200 (9)

The goal is to maximise the harvested volume, while requiring that no


adjacent stands can be harvested (URM).
The objective function then is
150x1 30x2 70x3 180x4 25x5 215x6 50x7 60x8 200x9.
The adjacency constraints need to be defined for each neighbouring pairs;
for instance, stand 5 has 4 neighbours, 2, 4, 6 and 8.
The constraints thus are:

x1 x2  1
x1 x4  1
x2 x3  1
x2 x5  1
x3 x6  1
x4 x5  1

(continued)
164 6 Optimisation

Example 6.13 (continued)


x4 x7  1
x5 x6  1
x5 x8  1
x6 x9  1
x7 x8  1
x8 x9  1;

i.e. altogether 12 adjacency constraints are needed to solve this problem. The
solution to the problem is to harvest 5 stands

1 (1) 0 (2) 1 (3)

0 (4) 1 (5) 0 (6)

1 (7) 0 (8) 1 (9)

which produces 495 m3. Introducing a green-up time, the number of


constraints needed would be much higher.

6.7.2 Spatial Goals Suitable for Linear Programming

The decision-maker can have also other kinds of spatial goals than the maximum
clear-cut size. For example, reducing the fragmentation in the forest area or
clustering the harvests in order to save in costs cannot be dealt with adjacency
constraint formulations. In that case, the problem needs to be formulated in a
different way. The problem with spatial goals is that they very often are nonlinear
and therefore not useful in the LP setting. There are, however, some possibilities.
For instance, the perimeter of an old-growth forest area can be used (O hman and
Wikstrom 2008) as
!
X
T X
m X
nk X
minz Bk x k j  2Sil pilt 6:59
t1 k1 j1 i, l2Y

where B is the perimeter of an old-growth stand i, xij is the binary decision variable,
S is the length of the common border for two stands i and l and p is the indicator
variable which has value 1 if both the stands i and l are old-growth forest at period t.
References 165

The above objective function thus aims to minimise the perimeter of continuous old
forest patches that are formed by several adjacent stands. Likewise, the perimeter of
clear-cut areas can be minimised, which would force the optimisation to make
larger clear-cut areas (O hman and Eriksson 2010).

References

Bettinger, P., Lennette, M., Johnson, K. N., & Spies, T. A. (2005). A hierarchical spatial
framework for forest landscape planning. Ecological Modelling, 182, 2548.
Bettinger, P., Boston, K., Siry, J., & Grebner, D. L. (2009). Forest management and planning.
Amsterdam: Academic. 360 p.
Buongiorno, J., & Gilles, J. K. (2003). Decision methods for forest resource management.
Amsterdam : Academic. 439 p.
Charnes, A., & Cooper, W. W. (1961). Management models and industrial applications of linear
programming (Vol. I). New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Clutter, J. L., Fortson, J. C., Pienaar, L. V., Brister, G. H., & Bailey, R. L. (1983). Timber
management. A quantitative approach. New York: Wiley.
Dantzig, G. B. (1951). Maximization of a linear function of variables subject to linear inequalities.
In T. C. Koopmans (Ed.), Activity analysis of production and allocation. New York: Wiley.
Davis, L.-S., Johnson, K. N., Bettinger, P. S., & Howard, T. E. (2001). Forest management to
sustain ecological, economic and social values (4th ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill. 804 p.
Daz-Balteiro, L., & Romero, C. (2001). Combined use of goal programming and the analytic
hierarchy process in forest management. In D. L. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. Mendoza, &
M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic hierarchy process (AHP) for natural resource and environ-
mental decision making (Managing Forest Ecosystems, Vol. 2, pp. 8195). Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Daz-Balteiro, L., & Romero, C. (2003). Forest management optimization models when carbon
captured is considered: A goal programming approach. Forest Ecology and Management, 174,
447457.
Duckstein, L., Korhonen, P., & Tecle, A. (1988). Multiobjective forest management: A visual,
interactive, and fuzzy approach. In B. M. Kent & L. S. Davis (Eds.), The 1988 symposium on
systems analysis in forest resources (General technical report, RM-161, pp. 6874). Fort
Collins: USDA Forest Service.
Eyvindson, K. (2012). Balancing equity and efficiency of goal programming for use in forest
management planning. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 42, 19191925.
Eyvindson, K., Kangas, A., Kurttila, M., & Hujala, T. (2010). Using preference information in
developing alternative forest plans. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 40, 23982410.
Eyvindson, K., Kurttila, M., Hujala, T., & Kangas, A. (2015). Interactive preference elicitation
incorporating a priori and a posteriori methods. Annals of Operations Research, 232, 99113.
Field, D. B. (1973). Goal programming for forest management. Forest Science, 19, 125135.
Flavell, R. B. (1976). A new goal programming formulation. Omega, 4(6), 731732. doi:10.1016/
0305-0483(76)90099-2.
Goycoolea, M., Murray, A., Vielma, J. P., & Weintraub, A. (2009). Evaluating approaches for
solving the area restriction model in harvest scheduling. Forest Science, 55(2), 149165.
Hillier, F. S., & Lieberman, G. J. (2001). Introduction to operations research (7th ed.). New York:
McGraw Hill. 1214 p.
Ignizio, J. P. (1976). Goal programming and extensions. Lexington: Lexington Books.
Johnson, K. N., & Scheurman, H. L. (1977). Techniques for prescribing optimal timber harvest
and investment under different objectives Discussion and synthesis (Forest science mono-
graphs, 18). Washington: Society of American Foresters.
Jones, D., & Tamiz, M. (2010). Practical goal programming (Vol. 141). New York: Springer.
166 6 Optimisation

Kangas, J., & Pukkala, T. (1992). A decision theoretic approach applied to goal programming of
forest management. Silva Fennica, 26, 169176.
Kangas, J., Alho, J., Kolehmainen, O., & Mononen, A. (1998). Analyzing consistency of experts
judgments Case of assessing forest biodiversity. Forest Science, 44(4), 610617.
Kangas, A., Nurmi, M., & Rasinmaki, J. (2014). From strategic plan to a tactical plan using
hierarchic optimization. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29, 154165.
Karkkainen, L., Kurttila, M., Salminen, O., & Viiri, H. (2014). Effects of energy wood harvesting
on timber production potential and biological diversity in North Karelia, Finland. Forest
Science, 60, 10771088.
Kurttila, M., Pukkala, T., & Kangas, J. (2001). Composing landscape level forest plans for forest
areas under multiple private ownership. Boreal Environmental Research, 6, 285296.
Lappi, J. (1992). JLP: A linear programming package for management planning (Research notes,
414). Helsinki: Finnish Forest Research Institute.
Lappi, J., & Lempinen, R. (2014). A linear programming algorithm and software for forest-level
planning problems including factories. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research. doi:10.1080/
02827581.2014.886714.
Lappi, J., & Siitonen, M. (1985). A utility model for timber production based on different interest
rates for loans and savings. Silva Fennica, 19, 271280.
McDill, M. E., & Braze, J. (2000). Comparing adjacency constraint formulations for randomly
generated forest planning problems with four age-class distributions. Forest Science, 46,
423436.
Mendoza, G. A. (1987). Goal programming formulations and extensions: An overview and
analysis. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 17, 575581.
Miettinen, K. (1999). Nonlinear multiobjective optimization. Springer.
Murray, A. T. (1999). Spatial restrictions in harvest scheduling. Forest Science, 45, 4552.
hman, K., & Eriksson, L.-O. (2010). Aggregating harvest activities in long term forest planning
O
by minimizing harvest area perimeters. Silva Fennica, 44, 7789.
hman, K., & Wikstr
O om, P. (2008). Incorporating aspects of habitat fragmentation into long-term
forest planning using mixed integer programming. Forest Ecology and Management, 255,
440446.
Romero, C. (2004). A general structure of achievement function for a goal programming model.
European Journal of Operational Research, 153(3), 675686.
Saaty, T. L. (1977). A scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures. Journal of Mathe-
matical Psychology, 15, 234281.
Saaty, T. L. (1980). The analytic hierarchy process. New York: McGraw-Hill. 287 p.
Taha, H. A. (2007). Operations research: An introduction (8th ed.). New York: Pearson Prentice
Hall. 838 p.
Tamiz, M., Jones, D., & Romero, C. (1998). Goal programming for decision making: An overview
of the current state-of-the-art. European Journal of Operational Research, 111, 569581.
Tecle, A., Duckstein, L., & Korhonen, P. (1994). Interactive multiobjective programming for
forest resources management. Applied Mathematics and Computing, 63, 7593.
Weintraub, A., & Cholaky, A. (1991). A hierarchical approach to forest planning. Forest Science,
37(2), 439460.
Weintraub, A., & Davis, L. (1996). Hierarchical planning in forest resource management:
Defining the dimensions of the subjected area (pp. 214). Petawawa National Forestry Insti-
tute, Canadian Forest Service, Information Report PI-X-124.
Weintraub, A., Barahona, F., & Epstein, R. (1994). A column generation algorithm for solving
general forest planning problems with adjacency constraints. Forest Science, 40, 142161.
Wu, J., & David, J. L. (2002). A spatially explicit hierarchical approach to modeling complex
ecological systems: Theory and applications. Ecological Modelling, 153, 726.
Zhang, D., & Pearse, P. H. (2011). Forest resource economics. Vancouver: University of British
Columbia Press.
Chapter 7
Heuristic Optimisation

Abstract Many forest management planning problems include characteristics that


make them hard to be solved by the use of linear programming-based methods. For
example, management planning problems that involve spatial aspects commonly
require the use of heuristics. The number of heuristic algorithms designed for
solving such problems has been rapidly increasing during the last decade. In this
chapter, we present some groups of methods, such as methods based on local
improvements, population-based methods and reduced-cost-based methods that
originate from linear programming. In addition, decentralised methods such as
cellular automaton are introduced. We describe some of the algorithms belonging
to each of these groups in more detail, for instance, genetic algorithms, simulated
annealing and tabu search. Additionally, we describe for what sort of planning cases
the different methods might be suitable and what are the benefits and drawbacks of
those methods in forest planning.

7.1 Principles of Heuristic Optimisation

7.1.1 Definitions

A heuristic is a technique which seeks good (i.e. near-optimal solutions) at a


reasonable computational cost without being able to guarantee either feasibility or
optimality, or even in many cases to state how close to optimality a particular
feasible solution is (Reeves 1993). In the context of forest planning, the used
heuristic techniques iteratively search for optimal combination of treatments for
stands. Thus, the treatments of stands are the actual decision variables in the search
process, and the quality of the solution is usually measured by the value of the
planning-area-level objective function. Many currently used heuristic algorithms
are called metaheuristic algorithms (Reeves 1996). Metaheuristics mean a tech-
nique beyond mere heuristics; they are a set of intelligent strategies to enhance the
efficiency of heuristic procedures (Beheshti and Shamsuddin 2013). Laporte and
Osman (1995) defined a metaheuristic as: An iterative generation process which
guides a subordinate heuristic by combining intelligently different concepts for
exploring and exploiting the search space, learning strategies are used to structure
information in order to find efficiently near-optimal solutions.

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 167


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_7
168 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Forest-planning problems often have an integer nature, i.e. the compartments


should not be split into parts. This is especially the case when there are spatial goals
or constraints in the problem formulation. Such problems can be either dispersion
type of problems where adjacency and green-up constraints are needed or clustering
type of problems where similar types of stands are clustered, for instance, to
enhance species viability (e.g. Harrison and Fahrig 1995, Kurttila 2001, O hman
2001, Nalle et al. 2004). The integer nature of planning problems and the use of
spatial goals are the most important reasons for the increased popularity of heuris-
tics in forest planning.
In the LP context, the spatial goals need to be linear, such as the perimeter of the
old-growth forest. In heuristic context also non-linear spatial goals are applicable,
for instance, the core area of old-growth forest, meaning continuous old-growth
forest area without counting the edges (e.g. O hman and Eriksson 1998). Sometimes
it is beneficial to cluster harvesting areas, at least when the individual compartments
are small. That can be achieved, for instance, by maximising the length of bound-
aries between cells harvested at the same time or minimising the perimeter of
contiguous harvest areas (Lu and Eriksson 2000; O hman and Eriksson 2002,

2010; Ohman and Lamas 2003; Heinonen et al. 2007; Pukkala et al. 2009). The
idea in clustering the harvests is in saving money from road building and mainte-
nance as well as from timber transportation costs.
Many dispersion problems can be solved with linear programming, and it is also
possible to solve some clustering problems with LP (or MIP). In real-life forest-
planning problems, both dispersion and clustering problems where the solution is a
set of integers are hard or even impossible to solve using mathematical
programming-based techniques. Instead, heuristic techniques can solve these
kinds of problems (see Kurttila 2001, Borges et al. 2002 and Baskent and Keles
2005 for reviews on the use of spatial objectives and heuristic techniques in forest
planning).
The operational principles of heuristic techniques are usually rather easy to
understand, and there can be interaction between the optimisation model and the
decision-maker or planner. Furthermore, heuristics do not set very strict rules for
the planning problem formulation, i.e. they typically enable the formulation of the
optimisation problem better in line with the multiple objectives and preferences of
the decision-maker (e.g. Kangas 1999). Although they do not necessarily find the
technical global optimum of the given complicated problem, solutions nearer to the
real-life optimum might be found by using them than by LP, for instance, if the
preferences of the decision-maker can be described more realistically (e.g. Kangas
1999).
Some heuristics techniques are deterministic, i.e. from the same initial solution,
they return always the same final solution (e.g. direct search phase of HERO,
threshold accepting) (Burke and Kendall 2005). Some other techniques are sto-
chastic (e.g. simulated annealing, genetic algorithm), which means that from the
same initial solution they may return different final solutions due to the random
characteristics of their search processes. These random characteristics allow, for
example, the techniques to perform moves that decrease the objective function
7.1 Principles of Heuristic Optimisation 169

Fig. 7.1 A surface of a


bivariate function with two
local optima and global
optimum at the top of the
peak in the middle

objective fu
nction valu
e

value that enable them to move to a new location in a solution space. As a result,
they have an ability to escape from the local optima (Fig. 7.1). In a deterministic
algorithm, the local optima can be avoided by forcing the algorithm to move to
unexplored areas. Another possibility would be to use a large number of different
initial solutions to increase the probability for finding good solutions.
In principle, heuristics could be replaced by carrying out an exhaustive search,
i.e. explore the whole solution space. However, the solution space in forest planning
is usually enormous. Even for a very small forest of 20 compartments each having
4 treatment alternatives, the total amount of alternatives is already
420 1.099  1012.
An additional categorisation of heuristic methods can be based on the nature
they deal with solution candidates. This categorisation is used in this chapter when
introducing different heuristic optimisation techniques. One set of heuristic tech-
niques processes only one solution at the time. These techniques are introduced in
Sects. 7.2 and 7.3. On the contrary, for example, genetic algorithms maintain and
process a population of solutions. This presentation is given in Sect. 7.4. This is
followed by a description of decentralised optimisation methods that process the
solution at local and global levels. Additional ways to group the heuristic methods
can be found in Beheshti and Shamsuddin (2013). For instance, the algorithms can
be grouped according whether a memory of past solutions is used (like in tabu
search) or not or if they use variable neighbourhood in the search or not and so
on. The chapter ends with a brief discussion on possibilities to improve the heuristic
search processes.
170 7 Heuristic Optimisation

7.1.2 Objective Function Forms

Heuristic optimisation techniques do not demand any specific objective function


form, which means that the design of the objective function can be case specific.
According to Pukkala (2002), there are four basic alternatives to formulate the
objective function for a multi-objective forest-planning situation:
1. One objective is minimised or maximised via the objective function and the
other goals are expressed as strict constraints.
2. The objective function measures the deviations of several objective variables
from their target levels. These levels are given in other equations of the problem
formulation. Strict constraint can also be included in the problem formulation.
3. A single objective is included in an objective function which is augmented with
a penalty function. The penalty function measures how much additional objec-
tive variables deviate from their target values. The penalty function has the same
unit as the single objective variable.
4. A multi-attribute utility function is developed and used as the objective function.
Although the formulation 1 (in linear case) corresponds to the typical LP problem
and formulation 2 to the GP formulation, all four formulations can be solved with
heuristic optimisation techniques.
The penalty function tries to minimise the deviations from the target values that
have been specified for certain objective variables, usually at planning-area level.
For example, the maximisation of NPV from the whole planning area may be
augmented with a certain core-area demand (e.g. 10 % of the forests of the planning
area should be old-forest core areas, i.e. old-forest area that has at least a predefined
distance to the edge of the forest) for each subperiod through a penalty function
(e.g. O hman and Eriksson 1998). Alternatively, the whole objective function
includes only penalty functions, e.g. costs from deviating from planning-area-
level harvest volume target, costs from harvested area with low volume per
compartment area ratio, cost of violated adjacency constraints or costs of harvest
blocks violating the harvest block size constraint (Lockwood and Moore 1993).
In the former case, the total amount of core area is evaluated for each of the
tested solutions and if the core-area target is not met, the penalty decreases the
maximised NPV so much that the probability for accepting such solution is low. In
the latter case, the value of the objective function is minimised, and the function
corresponds to the GP formulation. The penalty functions can be also designed so
that small deviations from the target values are penalised relatively less than values
more distant from the targets. In both cases, these penalties should either reflect the
real costs of not achieving the target levels of the constraints, or otherwise they
should reflect the preferences of the decision-maker.
In the case of a multi-attribute utility function, different function forms can be
used. The use of additive utility function enables the presentation of objective
variables in a hierarchical manner (see Chaps. 3 and 4). In an additive utility
7.2 HERO 171

function, total utility U is calculated so that the weights, i.e. relative importance ai,
of the objective variables are scaled to sum equal to one

X
p
U ai ui qi 7:1
i1

where U is the total utility, p is the number of objectives, ui is the sub-utility


function of objective variable i getting values between 0 and 1 and qi is the quantity
that the current solution produces or consumes objective variable i at the planning-
area level. Objectives are either forest products and values, such as timber, amenity
and biodiversity, or resources, such as costs and labour requirement.
The sub-utility function depicts the change in the utility as the value of the
objective variable changes (for more details see Sect. 3.2). The sub-utility function
is estimated separately for each objective variable. When estimating the sub-utility
function, first the maximum and minimum values that can be achieved for the
objective variable from the planning area are computed (as single objective
optima). Typically the minimum value of the objective variable gets sub-utility
zero and the maximum value of the objective variable gets a sub-utility of one
(i.e. utilities in interval scale are used although ratio scale would be equally usable).
The desirability of the intermediate values is estimated and the values are given
relative priorities, which define the sub-utility function. A sub-utility function can
be linear, non-linear or piecewisely linear. Estimation can be based equally well on
subjective preference evaluations, expertise, objective measurements or informa-
tion produced by empirical research. One advantage of the method is that it operates
with case-specific production possibilities.
Also multiplicative parts or interactive terms can be added to the utility model.
Multiplicative parts are useful when the objective variables are not interchangeable,
i.e. if a good gain in one variable cannot compensate for an inferior result in
another. The general form of the utility model that includes multiplicative parts is:
!
X
p Y
P  
U ai ui qi uj qj 7:2
i1 j p1

The latter part of the function includes the objectives that are not interchangeable
with the other objectives. It would also be possible to apply a purely multiplicative
utility model.

7.2 HERO

The HERO heuristic optimisation method is a direct ascent method. It has been
especially developed for tactical forest planning mainly at area of non-industrial
forest-holding level planning (Pukkala and Kangas 1993; Kangas et al. 2001). The
172 7 Heuristic Optimisation

optimisation phase of HERO may be divided into two stages: random search for
creating initial solutions and direct search phase for improving the best initial solution.
In the beginning of the optimisation process, the random search phase assigns
one treatment schedule for each compartment. The values and the sub-priorities of
the objectives are computed, as well as the total utility. Several initial candidate
solutions are usually produced and the best of them is used in the second phase. In
the direct search phase, one compartment at a time is examined to see whether some
other feasible and simulated treatment schedule, which is not in the current solu-
tion, would increase the total utility. If the utility increases, the current treatment
alternative is replaced by the one that increases the total utility. Once all the
treatment schedules of all the compartments have been studied in this way, the
process is repeated again until no more schedules increasing the utility can be
found. In order to improve the probability for finding a good-quality solution, the
whole process is repeated several times (say, 1001000 times), and the solution
with the greatest utility value is taken as the optimal solution. In this way, the
optimisation phase of HERO combines random and systematic search components.

Example 7.1
Altogether 191 treatment alternatives were simulated for a 70 ha forest
holding that had been divided into 75 compartments. The planning period
included two 10-year subperiods. Monsu forest-planning software was used
in the planning calculations (Pukkala 2006). The objective function was an
additive utility function, and it included the following objectives (and relative
weights): cutting income during the 1st subperiod (0.4), cutting income
during the 2nd subperiod (0.3) and standing timber volume at the end of the
whole planning period (0.3). For standing timber volume at the end of the
planning period, the sub-utility reached a value 1.0 when the initial standing
timber volume of the holding (10,500 m3) was reached. The sub-utility
function of cutting income from the first period was linear between its
minimum and maximum value, and the sub-utility of cutting income from
the 2nd planning period was formulated so that it reached the value of 0.9 at
the point, where the cutting income was the same as the initial value growth
per year in the holding multiplied by the number of years (10  18,000 ).
Three different parameter definitions were defined for the HERO and the
achieved results are presented in Table 7.1.

Table 7.1 The results from three different heuristic searches


Number of Cutting Cutting Standing
initial random Number of Total income 1st income 2nd timber
solutions optimisations utility U period period volume
1 1 0.63119 83,401 115,685 10,508
1000 5 0.64833 64,315 15,0765 10,518
1000 500 0.65344 78,305 13,7004 10,509

(continued)
7.3 Metaheuristic Methods Using Local Improvements 173

Example 7.1 (continued)


The total utility measures directly the technical quality of the solution. As
the number of random solutions and number of optimisations increase, also
the total utility increases. Note that the aspiration level concerning standing
timber level is always met, but the aspiration level for cutting income during
the 2nd period is not reached.

7.3 Metaheuristic Methods Using Local Improvements

7.3.1 Simulated Annealing and Threshold Accepting

Simulated annealing (SA) is a local optimisation method, and it attempts to avoid


getting trapped in local optima by allowing random deteriorations in the objective
function value (e.g. Dowsland 1993). SA is originally based on the cooling process
of liquid material, and the terminology of the method follows the terms of the
physical cooling process (Kirkpatrick et al. 1983). Thus, the starting temperature
defines the starting conditions of the process. The speed of the cooling process
(defined through the cooling multiplier) affects the temperature and changes the
stage of the material so that as the material cools and becomes more solid, the
random elements cannot change the solution as easily any more. The cooling
process continues until the freezing temperature is reached and the material is
solid. The search process of SA can continue until the current solution, i.e. the
combination of treatments, cannot be improved anymore and if the user-specified
stop rule has not been met earlier.
SA starts its search process from an initial solution that can be created by
selecting randomly one treatment schedule for each stand, for example. In the
search process, randomly assigned neighbouring solutions are evaluated. In
forest-planning context, the neighbourhood usually means that the treatment sched-
ule of one randomly selected management unit is changed at a time (Bettinger
et al. 2002). In SA the moves that improve the value of the objective function are
always accepted. To avoid being trapped to a local optimum, the method accepts
moves that do not improve the objective function value with a probability that
decreases as the temperature gets cooler. The probability for accepting the
non-improving moves is calculated as follows:
 
p exp U New U Old T i 1 7:3

where Ti is the current temperature and UOld is the current objective function value
and UNew is the new smaller objective function value. During the optimisation
process, the temperature cools, according to a user-specified cooling schedule. At
high temperatures the probability for accepting inferior moves is high (imitating the
melted metal moving easily), but as the temperature decreases (the metal solidifies),
174 7 Heuristic Optimisation

the probability decreases. Parameters that the user has to specify when using SA are
starting and stopping temperature, cooling schedule and the number of iterations at
each temperature. The number of iterations can change during the cooling process,
for example, it can increase when the temperature cools. This is also a user-
specified characteristic.
Threshold accepting (TA) (Dueck and Scheuer 1990) is a deterministic version of
SA. TA has shown to be able to produce solutions as good, or even better, than SA
(Dueck and Scheuer 1990; Bettinger et al. 2002, Heinonen and Pukkala 2004). In TA,
moves that improve the solution are always accepted. Moves not improving the
current solution are accepted when they result in an objective function value greater
than the current value minus the threshold. In the beginning of the search, the threshold
value can be large, which enables wider movements in the solution space. The
threshold is gradually decreased and finally only improvements are accepted. The
search is stopped when the threshold becomes very small (freezing threshold) or when
several consecutive thresholds are tested without any change in the solution.

Example 7.2
The planning data are the same as in Example 7.1. In this example SA and TA
were the used optimisation techniques. For both techniques, the number of
initial iterations, number of iteration multiplier and number of initial random
solutions had same values. For SA, the initial temperature was 0.0013, the
cooling multiplier which is used to reduce the temperature after the specified
number of iterations was 0.9, and the stopping temperature was 0.000065. For
TA, the initial threshold value was 0.0013, the threshold value multiplier was
0.9, and the stopping threshold was 0.0001.
Figure 7.2 illustrates the basic difference between SA and TA. The total
utilities develop slightly differently in SA and in TA. SA allows some quite
big deteriorations in the utility value, whereas they are smaller than the
defined threshold in TA.
U
0.68
0.66
0.64
0.62
0.6
0.58
0.56
0.54
0.52
0.5

SA TA

Fig. 7.2 Development of the total utility in SA and in TA during the first 150 moves
7.3 Metaheuristic Methods Using Local Improvements 175

7.3.2 Tabu Search

Search memory in the form of tabu lists is the key characteristics of tabu search
(TS). The lists direct and diversify the search process, for instance, by prohibiting
the repetition of recent moves. The user-specified tabu tenure determines the
number of iterations during which the treatment schedules that participated in a
move may not be included in or removed from the solution.
As in previous techniques, the search process of TS starts from an initial
solution. Then, several candidate moves are produced. The user should define the
number of candidate moves (at minimum one and at maximum all the neighbouring
solutions) and how they are produced. The candidates may be produced by
selecting randomly both the compartment and one of its treatment schedules that
is not in the current solution. Alternatively the candidate moves can be produced
systematically. Among these candidate moves, the move that produces an elite
solution (the best solution so far) is always accepted even if it is tabu. Among the
non-tabu moves, the move that produces the largest improvement (or the smallest
deterioration) to the objective function is made. If non-tabu moves are not avail-
able, the move with smallest tabu tenure (the treatment alternative that would next
become non-tabu) is made. The duration of tabu tenure can be longer for moves that
have entered the solution than for moves that have been removed from the solution
or vice versa (for more details, see, e.g., Glover and Laguna 1993 and Richards and
Gunn 2000).
Since the TS may concentrate in a small area in the solution space, the search can
be further diversified by purposefully selecting rarely considered treatments
options. For example, Boston and Bettinger (1999) diversified the search by using
the long-term memory (frequency that each treatment alternative has been entered
in the solution) so that after 3000 repetitions, the algorithm developed a new
solution using the least selected treatment alternatives. The TS routine was started
again from this new solution, and the best solution so far was saved.

Example 7.3
This example illustrates the functioning of the short-term tabu tenure. The
example data consists of nine compartments, which have a varying number of
simulated treatment alternatives as follows:

Compartment 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Number of simulated treatment alternatives 4 5 2 3 4 5 4 5 4

In the optimisation, the first move changes the solution in compartment


2. The tabu tenure for the alternative that has been removed from the solution
is 10 and for the alternative that entered solution the tabu tenure is 2.

(continued)
176 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Example 7.3 (continued)

Compartment 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
The treatment alternative that is in the initial 1 2 1 3 4 4 1 2 3
solution
Solution 2 1 5 1 3 4 4 1 2 3
Treatment alternative/tabu tenure 2/10
5/2

The second move changes the solution in compartment 9. The tabu tenures
of the previously changed treatment alternatives as well as the treatment
alternatives that were changed during the current move are updated.

Compartment 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
The treatment alternative number that 1 5 1 3 4 4 1 2 3
is in the current solution
Solution 3 1 5 1 3 4 4 1 2 1
Treatment alternative/tabu tenure 2/9 3/10
5/1 1/2

7.3.3 Defining the Parameters

The problem with heuristic optimisation techniques is that although they can
produce feasible solutions within a relatively short time, the quality of the solution
remains unknown, especially in complex or large problems. The selected technique
has an effect both on the time needed to find the solution and on the objective
function value (Bettinger et al. 2002; Pukkala and Kurttila 2005). However, even if
the technique would be suitable for the planning problem at hand, the user has to
define several technique-specific parameter values, which also affect the perfor-
mance (Baskent and Jordan 2002). In addition, the user has to decide how the initial
solution(s) is produced. In practice, it is impossible to determine the single optimal
set of parameters for a certain technique, because the planning situations vary much
(Pukkala and Heinonen 2006).
Pukkala and Heinonen (2006) presented a method for optimising the search
process of three heuristic techniques (SA, TA and TS). The method optimises the
values of parameters that the applied heuristic optimisation techniques need for
quick and slow convergence requirement. In addition, the obtained solution with
the best parameter set is simultaneously produced and displayed to the user.
However, due to long computing times, the everyday use of the method is imprac-
tical, but it is a valuable technique when heuristic techniques are developed and
7.3 Metaheuristic Methods Using Local Improvements 177

compared with each others. For improved practical usability, the method could be
used to develop some practical rules concerning good technique-specific parameter
values. It would be logical to try to relate these rules on the number of compart-
ments, on the number of treatment schedules or on the size of the neighbourhood
(Park and Kim 1998; Pukkala and Heinonen 2006).

7.3.4 Defining the Neighbourhood

In forest planning and particularly in situations where spatial objectives are


employed, it may be beneficial to examine two or more simultaneous treatment
alternative changes (e.g. Bettinger et al. 1999). For example, if the treatment
alternatives are changed simultaneously in two compartments, the values of
nonspatial objective variables may remain practically unchanged but the spatial
objective may be improved significantly. For this reason, so-called
two-compartment neighbourhood moves may allow wider exploration of the solu-
tion space and more refinements to the solution (e.g. Bettinger et al. 2002, Heinonen
and Pukkala 2004). In the study of Bettinger et al. (1999) TS with 2-opt moves gave
good results when applied to a forest-planning problem with even-flow and adja-
cency constraints. Also Bettinger et al. (2002) found out that the same technique
performed very well in three different forest-planning problems. More recently, the
study of Heinonen and Pukkala (2004) compared one- and two-compartment
neighbourhoods in local neighbourhood search-based heuristics (SA, TS, HERO
and random ascent). The two-compartment neighbourhood was found to be clearly
better than one-compartment neighbourhood (Heinonen and Pukkala 2004).
It is possible to further develop the neighbourhood structure, for example, by
using three-compartment neighbourhoods and also by taking into account the
physical and relative locations of the compartments in neighbourhood definition.
In addition to the neighbourhood definition, the methods by which the candidate
solutions are selected can be improved. Borges et al. (2014) selected the stand
where the treatment was to be selected with a probability proportional to the
number of alternatives this stand had, when in basic SA process this probability
is the same for all stands. They also tested a case where the probability was
proportional to the variation in the NPV for the treatment alternatives. Selecting
such stands more often than stands with only a few or similar alternatives serves in
diversifying the search area.
Another possibility to enlarge the local search neighbourhood is the use of
strategic oscillation (SO) in TS (Glover and Laguna 1993). SO is suitable for
forest-planning problems that include different constraints concerning, for exam-
ple, even-flow and adjacent cuttings. The constraints create barriers in the search
space, i.e. they make it disjoint, which reduces the search possibilities. For example,
suppose that a 10 ha compartment, j, is adjacent to 45 ha area consisting of one or
more compartments that would be cut during the period 2. The 10 ha compartments
ideal harvest time is also period 2. However, scheduling the cutting of this
178 7 Heuristic Optimisation

compartment to period 2 would increase the opening size greater than 50 ha, which
in this case is the maximum allowed opening size. Therefore, some other compart-
ments must be removed from the 45 ha opening before compartment j can be
harvested in period 2. However, if the current volume harvested in period 2 is
near the minimum constrained level, then removing other compartments from this
opening will violate the harvest flow constraint. Thus, finding a sequence of feasible
moves that add compartment j to harvest period 2 is difficult or impossible if
constraints are constantly enforced (Richards and Gunn 2003). The basic idea of
SO is to enlarge and smooth the constrained search neighbourhood by allowing
infeasible moves. The search is carried out near constraint boundaries so that the
solution visits both feasible and infeasible regions. The solution is forced back to
the feasible region by using penalty terms that increasingly penalise the objective
function as the violations of the constraints increase. In the study of Richards and
Gunn (2003), SO was found to be the most important design factor for constrained
planning problem that was solved by different TS versions.

7.4 Population-Based Methods

7.4.1 Genetic Algorithms

Unlike the heuristic optimisation techniques described above, genetic algorithms


(GA) process simultaneously a population of solution alternatives. This population
is then evaluated and bred in the search process. The terminology of GA has
correspondence to natural selection and genetics (Table 7.2). The alternative
solutions are called chromosomes, which are processed by crossing over and by
mutation and evaluated through fitness function. These operations result in new
generation of chromosomes.
The GA starts from the initial population that can be created through random
processes or by utilising other heuristic optimisation techniques. In the following

Table 7.2 Terminology of GA with respect to forest-planning terminology


GA term Forest-planning term
Population User defined number of forest-plan alternatives
Chromosome Forest plan
Gene Forest stand/compartment
Allele Treatment alternative
Crossover An exchange of parts between two parent forest-plan alternatives
Mutation Random change in the stands treatment alternative
Fitness value Objective function value
Offspring New generation of forest-plan alternatives from breeding
7.4 Population-Based Methods 179

step of GA, the initial population is bred. It is possible to replace the whole initial
population (i.e. change all forest plans in the population) or it can be replaced
incrementally so that only part of the initial population is replaced by new chro-
mosomes. New chromosomes can be created by using crossover or mutation. The
selection of parent chromosomes for these operations can be random or the selec-
tion probability can depend on the chromosomes fitness values. For example, the
selection of the other parent can be based on the probability proportional to its
ranking, and the other parent can be selected randomly. Also the mechanisms
concerning the breeding process (number of crossovers, the length and location
of crossovers, number and generation principles of mutations) must be defined. In
addition, the user must also define the principles concerning the removal of
chromosomes. It can be based on the fitness value so that the probability of removal
is the highest for chromosomes that have a low fitness value. The new chromo-
somes form the new generation of chromosomes and the GA process ends when a
certain number of generations have been produced or when a certain amount of
generations have been produced without improvement (for more details, see, e.g.,
Reeves 1993 and Sastry et al. 2005).

Example 7.4
By using the data from Example 7.3, different crossover methods (e.g. Sastry
et al. 2005) are illustrated. Crossovers are performed to two parent chromo-
somes by applying one-point crossover, two-point crossover and uniform
crossover, which can be considered as generic crossover techniques. In
one-point crossover, one crossover point is randomly selected and the alleles
on one side of the point are exchanged between the parents. In two-point
crossover, two points are randomly selected. In uniform crossover, every
allele is exchanged between randomly selected two chromosomes with a
certain probability, pe, known as the swapping probability (which is usually
taken to be 0.5).
One-point crossover

Parent 1 1 2 1 3 4 4 1 2 3

Parent 2 2 2 2 4 3 6 4 2 3

New chromosome 1 1 2 1 3 3 6 4 2 3

New chromosome 2 2 2 2 4 4 4 1 2 3

(continued)
180 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Example 7.4 (continued)


Two-point crossover

Parent 1 1 2 1 3 4 4 1 2 3

Parent 2 2 2 2 4 3 6 4 2 3

New chromosome 1 1 2 2 4 3 6 1 2 3

New chromosome 2 2 2 1 3 4 4 4 2 3

Uniform crossover

Parent 1 1 2 1 3 4 4 1 2 3

Parent 2 2 2 2 4 3 6 4 2 3

New chromosome 1 2 2 1 4 3 4 1 2 3

New chromosome 2 1 2 2 3 4 6 4 2 3

The principle of mutation is also illustrated below. The mutation proba-


bility has been defined to be 0.3, which means that the treatment alternative
changes at maximum in 30 % of forest stands. In this example, the mutation
takes place in the new chromosome 1 that was created through two-point
crossover. The mutation occurs in two alleles as follows:

New chromosome 1 1 2 2 4 3 6 1 2 3
After mutation 2 2 2 1 3 6 1 2 3

7.4.2 Other Population-Based Methods

Many other population-based methods also have nature-inspired names and char-
acteristics (Beheshti and Shamsuddin 2013). Examples of these methods are ant
colony optimisation (ACO) and particle swarm optimisation (PSO). The general
class of swarm-based algorithms is made up of simple particles or agents interacting
7.4 Population-Based Methods 181

locally with each other and with their environment. Each particle follows method-
specific rules and tries to end up in a good solution during the search process.
Consequently, local and random interactions among the particles are led to an
intelligent global behaviour. An example of the use of ACO in forest-planning
context can be found from Zeng et al. (2007) and of the use of PSO from Shan
et al. (2012). Zeng et al. (2007) used ACO in spatial planning problem in which the
aim was to create such clear-cut area patterns that would have minimum risk to
wind damages.

Example 7.5
In this example, the properties of different heuristic techniques are
highlighted by using the same materials as in earlier LP example (Sect.
6.6). To demonstrate the differences between the heuristics technique and
exact techniques, the solutions produced from three heuristic methods (sim-
ulated annealing, tabu search and HERO) are compared to the PPF created by
integer programming. To reiterate, the problem used by all methods is to
maximise the first 5-year period of income, subject to both a non-declining
income requirement and an end-volume constraint. The mathematical repre-
sentation is similar to that found in Sect. 6.6, with an addition of the integer
constraint, which is done so that the exact method is comparable to the
heuristic formulation:

X
m X
nk
max z ckj1 xk j
k1 j1

subject to

m X
X nk X
J
ckjt1 xk j  ckjt xk j  0, 8t 1, . . . , T  1
k1 j1 j1
m X
X nk
vk jT xk j  V end
k1 j1

xk j 2 0; 1, 8k, j
X
nk
xk j hk , 8k 1, . . . , nk
j1

(continued)
182 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Example 7.5 (continued)

Table 7.3 Parameters used TS HERO SA


for the heuristics
Repeats 1 1 1
Initial solutions 100 200 100
Maximum iterations 5000 10 5000
Entry tenure 10
Exit tenure 20
Starting temperature 0.999
Freezing temperature 0.001
Cooling factor 0.999
Iterations per temperature 100
Iteration multiplier 1

where the Vend is a variable set by the decision-maker. The parameters used
by the heuristics are detailed in Table 7.3.
To produce a PPF the Vend is set at equally spaced intervals, detailed in
Table 7.4.
Both Table 7.4 and Fig. 7.3 highlight the difference between the heuristic
techniques and the integer programming technique. Where the integer pro-
gramming technique was able to find solutions to each problem, the heuristic
method was unable to find solutions for the problem when the constraints
become too restrictive (in this case, when the requirement for volume exceeds
9485 m3). From Fig. 7.3 it is possible to see how far the heuristic solutions are
from the optimal frontier and how the solutions do not span the entire range of
possibilities as the integer programming solutions do. Again, changing the
search parameters of heuristic techniques might change the results.

(continued)
Example 7.5 (continued)
Table 7.4 Solution from the series of heuristic and integer programming
Integer programming Tabu search HERO Simulated annealing
End-volume First period Volume First period Volume First period Volume First period Volume
constraint income (m3) income (m3) income (m3) income (m3)
1 3185 71,474 3576 50,206 6361 44,147 5976 42,611 5952
2 3885 70,977 3889 53,177 5783 44,142 6301 45,841 5417
3 4585 68,728 4616 56,249 5364 47,307 5868 40,130 5245
4 5285 65,915 5305 58,599 5306 42,672 6273 42,016 5965
7.4 Population-Based Methods

5 5985 63,457 5985 48,433 7149 45,931 6827 42,846 6335


6 6685 60,363 6706 49,888 6792 43,375 6840 39,044 6823
7 7385 56,942 7431 45,191 7617 42,323 7817 38,604 7681
8 8085 52,650 8098 40,956 8629 34,695 8582 32,593 8109
9 8785 48,923 8794 38,579 8800 29,387 8815 33,239 8799
10 9485 45,316 9493 33,299 9710 31,184 9491 30,675 9829
11 10,185 40,378 10,190
12 10,885 36,631 10,893
13 11,585 32,196 11,591
14 12,285 28,005 12,296
15 12,985 23,409 13,020
16 13,685 19,320 13,692
17 14,385 14,139 14,396
18 15,085 9472 15,086
19 15,785 4117 15,800
20 16,485 0 16,565

(continued)
183
184 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Example 7.5 (continued)

,
,
,
,
,
,
,

, , , ,

Fig. 7.3 Production possibility frontier, a comparison of exact techniques and heuristic
techniques

7.5 Local/Global Methods

7.5.1 Cellular Automaton

Cellular automaton (CA) is a bottom-up-type approach and it differs from the


above-described top-down-type metaheuristic (HERO, SA, TA, TS and GA)
approaches. The main difference is that CA is capable to deal with local objectives,
such as clustering and connecting certain types of stands (Mathey and Nelson
2008). This capability is achieved through decentralised optimisation process in
which the decision related to the treatment of the stand is based on the properties of
the stands physical neighbourhood. All this suggests that CA is in its best in spatial
forest-planning problems.
The local capabilities of CA mean that the approach typically first considers the
optimisation task from the perspective of individual treatment unit. The treatment
7.5 Local/Global Methods 185

Fig. 7.4 The most common cell neighbourhoods in cellular automata: von Neumann, Moore and
hexagonal neighbourhood

units applied in CA are typically regular sized and shaped raster cells (see Fig. 7.4).
However, Heinonen and Pukkala (2007) applied the approach also to compartments
which have varying shapes and areas. In the local optimisation phase, the local
objectives can be, for example, NPV maximisation, which means that the treatment
schedule that gives the highest overall NPV for it is selected. However, the value of
local objectives can be affected by neighbouring units. For example, the NPV can
be affected by road-building costs which can decrease if also neighbouring units are
cut simultaneously (Mathey and Nelson 2008). CA has capabilities that are partic-
ularly suitable for these kinds of examinations.
In CA, the treatments of units that are included in the solution are modified by
using mutation and innovation. Mutation refers to random change in the units
treatment, and it is based on mutation probability that decreases during the iterative
search process. Innovation, in turn, refers to the selection of the best treatment
alternative for the unit according to the objective function value. Also the use of
innovations is based on probability function.
However, forest-level objectives and constraints are evident in harvest-
scheduling problems. This means that the solution needs to be evaluated and
improved with respect to forest-level objectives as well. This means that in some
treatment units, the locally optimal solution must be adapted according to forest-
level goals. In decentralised planning approach such as CA, an important issue is to
identify which stands should modify their treatment schedule to be suboptimal in
order to find a forest-level solution that meets the forest-level constraints or gives
good values for forest-level goals. In recent forest-planning studies, Mathey and
Nelson (2008) used penalty function and Heinonen and Pukkala (2007) additive
value function to incorporate forest-level objectives in the optimisation problem.
CA can be used with parallel and sequential updating rules (Heinonen and
Pukkala 2007). Parallel updating means that all mutations and innovations that
are identified during the iteration are made simultaneously at the end of the
iteration. In sequential mode the changes are implemented immediately. As a result,
the changes in previous cells or units are known when a certain cell is inspected. In
sequential mode the objective function value increases quickly at first. However,
the parallel mode might have possibilities for finding more diverse solutions.
186 7 Heuristic Optimisation

There are also other decentralised approaches available for forest-planning


purposes. Hoganson and Rose (1984) introduced a related method, in which optimal
solutions were first searched at stand level. Then the dual prices of LP were used to
tie the stand-level solutions together so that the forest-level constraints can be met.
The beneficial property of CA and other decentralised methods is the ability to
quickly produce good local solutions in which the spatial interdependencies
between neighbouring stands have already been considered. This ability relates to
different solution spaces of centralised and decentralised heuristics for the
advantage of the latter one. The local optimisation phase which considers
neighbourhood relations between treatment units can organise the forest treatments
of the planning area in a natural way at this early part of the optimisation. This may
offer excellent preconditions to forest-level optimisation phase as well.

7.5.2 Reduced-Cost Approach

The reduced-cost method utilises certain fundamental concepts of LP. An early


example of the use of the RC method can be found from Hoganson and Rose
(1984). The idea behind RC is that first the treatment that maximises the reduced
cost of the calculation unit (e.g. stand compartment or raster cell) is selected (for
more details on RC, see Sect. 6.1.2 of this book). However, the calculation of RC
demands knowledge or estimates on shadow prices from the whole planning-area-
level problem as the dual prices of forest-level constraints appear in the RC
function. They can thus be used to tie the stand-level problems together to the
planning-area level. In RC the shadow prices are updated by following heuristic
rules (see Pukkala et al. 2009 for an example using a variant of subgradient
method). Thus, the method is run through the following process:
1. Produce an initial solution (select a treatment schedule for each calculation unit).
2. Set initial estimates of shadow prices.
3. Select the best schedule for every stand using RC calculation equation (with
multiple objectives, the basic single stand-level objective variable is replaced
with a function that depends on several variables).
4. Calculate the values of forest-level goals (constraining variables).
5. Update the shadow prices accordingly.
6. Repeat steps 35 for a certain number of iterations (e.g. in Pukkala et al. 2009
100 iterations was used).
During iterations, the shadow prices of the constraints that are not met are
increased until the constraints are met. The basic method can be used when there
is only one nonspatial objective variable. However, with modifications the
method has been found functional also for dealing with multiple objectives
and also with spatial goals. The spatial goals mean that the optimal management
of the stand or calculation unit depends on the management of neighbouring
units.
7.5 Local/Global Methods 187

Example 7.6
We use an example from Pukkala et al. (2009) in which the performance of
cellular automaton (CA), reduced-cost (RC) method and simulated annealing
(SA) was compared in the same planning area. The aim was to cluster cutting
areas (dark grey colour, Fig. 7.5) and remaining old forests (light grey
colour). The example calculations are comparable from the viewpoint of
the time consumption of optimisation as this was the same in all three
solutions. In example calculations, raster cells were used as calculation
units in optimisation. The solutions below thus indicate that it was not
optimal to follow the initial stand boundaries (black lines). In addition, the
result shows that with the same time consumption RC and CA performed
clearly better than SA (for more details, see also Pukkala et al. 2009).

RC

CA

Fig. 7.5 The resulting spatial configuration of an example area (Pukkala et al. 2009)

(continued)
188 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Example 7.6 (continued)

SA

Fig. 7.5 (continued)

7.6 Combining Optimisation Techniques

In order to improve the performance of the heuristic search processes, combining


heuristic techniques with other heuristic techniques or with LP has been examined
also in forest-planning context. Examples of combining heuristics include the study
of Kurttila and Pukkala (2003). They combined SA and HERO so that the idea of
cooling and that of accepting inferior solutions were applied in the same way as in
SA, whereas the neighbourhood was searched in the same way as in the HERO,
i.e. sequentially. All moves that improved the objective function value were
accepted. At every temperature, all schedules for all compartments were inspected
once and sequentially after which the temperature was changed, and the same
process was repeated until a stopping temperature was reached. Thus, also some
inferior moves were accepted during the direct search phase of HERO, but as the
temperature decreased, the probability of accepting these moves was decreased.
In the study that compared the performance of six heuristic techniques (Pukkala
and Kurttila 2005), the performance of this technique was rather good. It was
always faster than TS, SA and GA. In spatial planning problems only GA gave
clearly better objective function values than the combination of SA and HERO. In
another study (Hurme et al. 2007), SA and HERO were combined so that after the
search process of SA terminated, the direct search phase of the HERO was ran
through once, which guaranteed that the current local optimum was certainly found.
In addition, simple and fast technique like HERO can be used to produce initial
solutions for GA and for other heuristics as well (Pukkala and Heinonen 2006).
Also Falcao and Borges (2002) combined two heuristics so that others of them
References 189

applied systematic search and other random search. The developed sequential
quenching and tempering technique first applies systematic search rather similarly
as HERO to all stands in the forest. After all stands have been inspected and local
optimum has been found, the technique makes a random perturbation. This means
that a new treatment alternative is randomly assigned for a certain number of
stands. After this, the systematic search phase is resumed.
In the study of O hman and Eriksson (2001), LP was integrated with SA. SA was
used for solving the spatial dimension of the planning problem, whereas LP was
used for solving the nonspatial dimension. Two alternatives to combine these
techniques were tested. In the first alternative, SA was used first to solve the spatial
part of the planning problem, where the aim was to cluster old forests by applying
two different measures related to core area, namely, the amount of core area and the
amount of edge habitat. The SA solution was used to prohibit such stand-level
treatment schedules from the LP problem that did not produce old-forest areas to
the same extent as the treatment schedule that had been selected for the optimal SA
solution. In the second alternative, the procedure began with LP problem formula-
tion. From the LP solution, the shadow prices were utilised in the SA problem. The
results indicated that the combination of these two techniques produced more
effective results than the approach that used SA alone.
Bettinger et al. (2002) in their study tested a hybrid of TS and GA. The hybrid
utilised 1-opt and 2-opt moves and the diversification routine of the TS. After
performing these phases, the two best solutions (one from the 1-opt process and one
from the 2-opt process) were used as parent chromosomes and a crossover routine
of GA was performed so that two new chromosomes were created. The new
chromosome with the highest objective function value was then taken as a starting
solution of the new TS process. This hybrid and seven other heuristic techniques
were compared in three different forest-planning problems (one nonspatial and two
spatial planning problems). In the comparison, this algorithm was classified
according to its performance to a group very good as were also SA, TA, great
deluge and TS with 1-opt and 2-opt moves.

References

Baskent, E. Z., & Jordan, G. A. (2002). Forest landscape management modelling using simulated
annealing. Forest Ecology and Management, 165, 2945.
Baskent, E. Z., & Keles, S. (2005). Spatial forest planning: A review. Ecological Modelling, 188,
145173.
Beheshti, Z., & Shamsuddin, S. M. H. (2013). A review of population-based meta-heuristic
algorithms. International Journal of Advances in Soft Computing and Its Applications, 5, 135.
Bettinger, P., Boston, K., & Sessions, J. (1999). Intensifying a heuristic forest harvest scheduling
search procedure with 2-opt decision choices. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 29,
17841792.
Bettinger, P., Graetz, D., Boston, K., Sessions, J., & Woodam, C. (2002). Eight heuristic planning
techniques applied to three increasingly difficult wildlife planning problem. Silva Fennica, 36,
561584.
190 7 Heuristic Optimisation

Borges, J. G., Hoganson, H. M., & Falcao, A. O. (2002). Heuristics in multi-objective forest
planning. In T. Pukkala (Ed.), Multi-objective forest planning (pp. 119151). Dordrecht:
Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Borges, P., Eid, T., & Bergseng, E. (2014). Applying simulated annealing using different methods
for the neighborhood search in forest planning problems. European Journa of Operational
Research, 233, 700710.
Boston, K., & Bettinger, P. (1999). An analysis of Monte Carlo integer programming, simulated
annealing, and tabu search heuristics for solving spatial harvest scheduling problems. Forest
Science, 45, 292301.
Burke, E. G., & Kendall, G. (2005). Search methodologies. Introductory tutorials in optimization
and decision support techniques. New York: Springer. 620 p.
Dowsland, K. A. (1993). Simulated annealing. In C. R. Reeves (Ed.), Modern heuristic techniques
for combinatorial problems (pp. 2069). Oxford: Blackwell Scientific Publications.
Dueck, G., & Scheuer, T. (1990). Threshold accepting: A general purpose optimization algorithm
appearing superior to simulated annealing. Journal of Computer Physics, 90, 161175.
Falcao, A., & Borges, J. G. (2002). Combining random and systematic search heuristic procedures
for solving spatially constrained forest management scheduling models. Forest Science, 48,
608621.
Glover, F., & Laguna, M. (1993). Tabu search. In C. R. Reeves (Ed.), Modern heuristic techniques
for combinatorial problems (pp. 70150). Oxford: Blackwell Scientific Publications.
Harrison, S., & Fahrig, L. (1995). Landscape pattern and population conservation. In L. Hansson,
L. Fahrig, & G. Merriam (Eds.), Mosaic landscapes and ecological processes (IALE studies in
landscape ecology, Vol. 2, pp. 293308). London: Chapman and Hall.
Heinonen, T., & Pukkala, T. (2004). A comparison of one- and two-compartment neighbourhoods
in heuristic search with spatial forest management goals. Silva Fennica, 38, 319332.
Heinonen, T., & Pukkala, T. (2007). The use of cellular automaton approach in forest planning.
Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 37, 21882200.
Heinonen, T., Kurttila, M., & Pukkala, T. (2007). Possibilities to aggregate raster cells through
spatial objectives in forest planning. Silva Fennica, 41, 89103.
Hoganson, H. M., & Rose, D. W. (1984). A simulation approach for optimal timber management
scheduling. Forest Science, 30, 220238.
Hurme, E., Kurttila, M., M onkkonen, M., Heinonen, T., & Pukkala, T. (2007). Maintenance of
flying squirrel habitat and timber harvest: A site-specific spatial model in forest planning
calculations. Landscape Ecology, 22, 243256.
Kangas, J. (1999). The analytic hierarchy process (AHP): Standard version, forestry application
and advances. In F. Helles, P. Holten-Andersen, & L. Wichmann (Eds.), Multiple use of forests
and other natural resources (Forestry sciences, Vol. 61, pp. 96105). Dordrecht: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Kangas, J., Pukkala, T., & Kangas, A. S. (2001). HERO: Heuristic optimization for multi-criteria
forestry decision analysis. In D. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.),
The analytic hierarchy process in natural resource and environmental decision making
(Managing forest ecosystems, Vol. 3, pp. 5165). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Kirkpatrick, S., Gelatt, C. D., Jr., & Vecchi, M. P. (1983). Optimization by simulated annealing.
Science, 220, 671680.
Kurttila, M. (2001). The spatial structure of forests in the optimization calculations of forest
planning A landscape ecological perspective. Forest Ecology and Management, 142,
129142.
Kurttila, M., & Pukkala, T. (2003). Combining holding-level economic goals with spatial
landscape-level goals in the planning of multiple ownership forestry. Landscape Ecology,
18, 529541.
Laporte, G., & Osman, I. H. (1995). Routing problems: A bibliography. Annals Operations
Research, 61, 227262.
References 191

Lockwood, C., & Moore, T. (1993). Harvest scheduling with spatial constraints: A simulated
annealing approach. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 23, 468478.
Lu, F., & Eriksson, L. O. (2000). Formation of harvest units with genetic algorithms. Forest
Ecology and Management, 130, 5767.
Mathey, A.-H., & Nelson, J. (2008). Decentralized forest planning models A cellular automata
framework. In K. von Gadow & T. Pukkala (Eds.), Designing green landscapes (Managing
forest ecosystems, Vol. 15, pp. 169186). Dordrecht: Springer.
Nalle, D. J., Montgomery, C. A., Arthur, J. L., Polasky, S., & Schumaker, N. H. (2004). Modeling
joint production of wildlife and timber. Journal of Environmental Economics and Manage-
ment, 48, 9971017.
hman, K., & Eriksson, L. O. (1998). The core area concept in forming contiguous areas for long
O
term forest planning. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 28, 10321039.
hman, K., & Eriksson, L. O. (2002). Allowing for spatial consideration in long term forest
O
planning by linking linear programming and simulated annealing. Forest Ecology and Man-
agement, 161, 221230.
hman, K., & Eriksson, L.-O. (2010). Aggregating harvest activities in long term forest planning
O
by minimizing harvest area perimeters. Silva Fennica, 44, 7789.
hman, K. (2001). Forest planning with consideration to spatial relationships (Vol. 198).
O
Doctoral dissertation, Department.of Forest Resource Management and Geomatics, SLU.
Acta Universitatis Agriculturae Sueciae, Silvestria. 32 pp.
hman, K., & Eriksson, L.-O. (2001). Allowing for spatial consideration in long-term forest
O
planning by linking linear programming with simulated annealing. Forest Ecology and Man-
agement, 161, 221230.
hman, K., & Lamas, T. (2003). Clustering of harvest activities in multi-objective long-term
O
forest planning. Forest Ecology and Management, 176, 161171.
Park, M.-W., & Kim, Y.-D. (1998). A systematic procedure for setting parameters in simulated
annealing algorithms. Computers and Operations Research, 25, 207217.
Pukkala, T. (2002). Introduction to multi-objective forest planning. In T. Pukkala (Ed.), Multi-
objective forest planning (pp. 120). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Pukkala, T. (2006). Monsu-metsasuunnitteluohjelmisto. Versio 5. Ohjelmiston toiminta ja kaytt o.
Joensuun yliopisto. 53 s.
Pukkala, T., & Heinonen, T. (2006). Optimizing heuristic search in forest planning. Nonlinear
Analysis: Real World Applications, 7, 12841297.
Pukkala, T., & Kangas, J. (1993). A heuristic optimization method for forest planning and
decision-making. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 8, 560570.
Pukkala, T., & Kurttila, M. (2005). Examining the performance of six heuristic search techniques
in different forest planning problems. Silva Fennica, 39, 6780.
Pukkala, T., Heinonen, T., & Kurttila, M. (2009). An application of the reduced cost approach to
spatial forest planning. Forest Science, 55(1), 1322.
Reeves, C. R. (1993). Genetic algorithms. In C. R. Reeves (Ed.), Modern heuristic techniques for
combinatorial problems (pp. 151196). Oxford: Blackwell Scientific Publications.
Reeves, C. R. (1996). Modern heuristic techniques for combinatorial problems. Oxford: Blackwell
Scientific Publications. 320 p.
Richards, E. W., & Gunn, E. (2000). A model and tabu search method to optimize stand harvest
and road construction schedules. Forest Science, 46(2), 188203.
Richards, E. W., & Gunn, E. A. (2003). Tabu search design for difficult forest management
optimization problems. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 33, 11261133.
Sastry, K., Goldberg, D., & Kendall, G. (2005). Genetic algorithms. In E. G. Burke & G. Kendall
(Eds.), Search methodologies. Introductory tutorials in optimization and decision support
techniques (pp. 97125). New York: Springer.
Shan, Y., Bettinger, P., Cieszewski, C., & Wang, W. (2012). Pitfalls and potential of particle
swarm optimization for contemporary spatial forest planning. Forest Systems, 21, 468480.
Zeng, H., Pukkala, T., Peltola, H., & Kellomaki, S. (2007). Application of ant colony optimization
for the risk management of wind damage in forest planning. Silva Fennica, 41(2), 315332.
Chapter 8
Uncertainty in Optimisation

Abstract Most of the applications dealing with linear programming use determin-
istic programming. Stochastic programming is, however, a more realistic way of
formulating forest management planning problems, and it produces solutions that
have a better expected value than the deterministic solutions. In this chapter, we
present the linear and goal programming problems from the previous chapter using
stochastic programming approach and deterministic equivalent problem formula-
tion. We present approaches based on one stage and two stages. We describe the
uncertainty using a scenario tree. We show how the value of stochastic solution and
value of perfect information are calculated from the results. We also show how the
computationally more easy chance-constrained and robust programming methods
work in these cases. Finally, we present an approach of robust portfolio modelling
for dealing with the uncertainty.

8.1 Stochastic Programming

8.1.1 Effect of Uncertainty on Optimisation

Mathematical programming, especially linear programming (LP), is still perhaps


the most often applied approach to optimisation calculations of forest management
planning at forest area level. When numerical optimisation is applied in forest
planning, however, uncertainty about forest development is often ignored and the
optimisation is done as if under certainty. This can lead to two kinds of results. First,
a suboptimal alternative may be chosen. This being the case the realised objective
function value is less than the optimal objective function value would have been.
This loss is called regret (Bell 1982). Second, the true worth of the optimal
solution may be overestimated. This kind of loss is called disappointment (Bell
1985).
In an LP problem, there may be uncertainty concerning the objective function
coefficients, the values of the right-hand sides of the constraints and in the technical
coefficients (coefficients describing how the actions affect the objectives). It has
been noted that uncertainty about coefficients of the objective function causes
optimisation to be optimistically biased. It means that the gains of the optimal
solution will be overestimated, if there are errors in the objective function

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 193


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_8
194 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

coefficients (Hobbs and Hepenstal 1989). Errors in the right-hand sides of con-
straints have the opposite effect (Itami 1974). Uncertainty about the production
coefficients causes exaggeration of the gains of the optimal solution. The obtained
solutions may be infeasible due to the uncertainty (Pickens and Dress 1988). The
above-mentioned problems concern also other optimisation methods than LP, for
instance, heuristic methods or non-linear programming (e.g. Kangas and Kangas
1999).
It is possible to deal with the uncertainty in different ways. It is possible to deal
with the uncertainty explicitly by using stochastic programming (Birge and
Louveaux 1997; King and Wallace 2012). The feasibility of the solutions can be
enhanced by using chance-constrained or robust programming formulations, which
are computationally much easier to solve than actual stochastic programming
formulations. In forestry, stochastic optimisations have not been used very often
(see however Andalaft et al. 2003; Eriksson 2006; Alonso-Ayoso et al. 2011; Aouni
et al. 2012; Kangas et al. 2012, 2013). Usually these applications are designed for
cases of natural hazards such as fire or wind risk (e.g. Gassmann 1989, Boychuk and
Martell 1996, Ntaimo et al. 2013). Instead, chance-constrained and robust program-
ming have been more common (e.g. Pickens and Dress 1988; Pickens et al. 1991;
Hof et al. 1992, 1996, Hof and Pickens 1991, Bevers 2007; Palma and Nelson
2009).
If the uncertainty is due to ignorance or ambiguity, stochastic programming or
chance-constrained programming formulations do not apply. Then, fuzzy linear
programming may be utilised (e.g. Mendoza and Sprouse 1989). The applications
based on fuzzy linear programming and fuzzy goal programming are also numerous
(e.g. Duckstein et al. 1988; Mendoza and Sprouse 1989; Pickens and Hof 1991;
Bare and Mendoza 1992; Mendoza et al. 1993; Tecle et al. 1994; Hof et al. 1995;
Ells et al. 1997). Even one LP application involving possibility theory has been
published (Krcmar et al. 2001).
It can be shown that accounting for the uncertainty explicitly in decision-making
will produce better expected outcomes under uncertainty and more robust solutions
than the deterministic approach (King and Wallace 2012). In the stochastic
approach it is also possible to explicitly minimise the risks of very poor outcome
of the decisions. Moreover, it is possible to model adaptive decisions. It means that
when modelling the problem, we need to ask ourselves what are the consequences if
the planned action proves not to be feasible due to uncertainties. For instance, if the
DM promises to deliver a given amount of timber to the buyer, but the harvested
amount falls short of that, the DM may select a new area to be harvested or buy the
missing amount from another forest owner. While such consequences typically are
not accounted for in the deterministic problem formulation, they need to be
accounted for in the stochastic formulation in order to realistically represent the
planning problem.
8.1 Stochastic Programming 195

8.1.2 Basics of Stochastic Programming

In stochastic programming, the uncertainties are usually presented in discrete form,


using a scenario tree. It means that we need to know the distribution of the uncertain
variables (or at least we need to be able to estimate it), and then we need to take a
sufficient sample of the distribution so that we can adequately describe the uncer-
tainty. The more scenarios we have, the better the description of uncertainty. On the
other hand, increasing the number of scenarios will make the problem harder to
solve. Thus, we need to find the suitable amount of scenarios to balance between
these two conflicting demands (King and Wallace 2012).
The goal is to find a solution that is feasible for all scenarios and which and
maximises the expectation of some function of the decision variables and the
random variables (e.g. Birge and Louveaux 1997). The feasibility of the solution
in all conditions is ensured by introducing a separate constraint for each scenario.
Thus, stochastic programming is otherwise similar to LP, but the amount of
constraints is much higher and dependent on the number of scenarios.

Example 8.1
Assume the same pine forest area of 60 ha that was presented in Example 6.2.
The initial volume per hectare is 180 m3/ha, i.e. the total volume in the area is
10,800 m3. The problem was to maximise harvested volumes in a 30-year
period so that the volume in the end would be at least the same as in the
beginning. Assume further that the future development of the area is uncer-
tain. There are three equally probable scenarios of the future development
(Table 8.1). It also means that there are three equally probable scenarios of
the future harvested volumes (Table 8.2).
Then, the objective function is

max z 0:33  175x1 220x2 265x3 0x4 0:33


 175x1 215:5x2 255:5x3 0x4 0:33
 175x1 224:5x2 275x3 0x4 ;

describing the expected value of the harvested volume over all the scenarios.
There are only one set of decision variables for all the scenarios, which
means that one decision is made that will be implemented. The area
constraint is

x1 x2 x3 x4 60

(continued)
196

Example 8.1 (continued)


Table 8.1 Predicted volume (m3/ha) of the forest area treated with each of the alternatives in different periods and each of the alternative scenarios
Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3
Alternative Initial 2016 2026 2036 2016 2026 2036 2016 2026 2036
Harvest1 180 5 17.5 52.5 5.0 16.3 45.5 5.0 18.8 60.0
Harvest2 180 225 5 17.5 220.5 5.0 16.3 229.5 5.0 18.8
Harvest3 180 225 270 5 220.5 260.2 5.0 229.5 280.0 5.0
No harvest 180 225 270 297 220.5 260.2 283.6 229.5 280.0 310.8

(continued)
8 Uncertainty in Optimisation
8.1 Stochastic Programming 197

Example 8.1 (continued)


The end-inventory constraint for the volume needs to be built separately for
each of the three scenarios:

52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4  10, 800


45:5x1 16:3x2 5x3 283:6x4  10, 800
60:0x1 18:8x2 5x3 310:8x4  10, 800:

The result obtained with Solver is presencted in Table 8.3. The expected
harvested volume over all the scenarios is 5908.2, and it varies over the
scenarios (Table 8.4). The resulting level of the constraints is exactly the
given constraint for the area (60 ha), but the end volume varies. The end
volume is exactly at the required limit for the worst-case scenario (2) but
above it for the other two scenarios.
If the problem were solved in deterministic fashion, using the expected
development of the area, it would mean 1.37 more hectares harvested during
the third period (Table 8.3). The expected harvest level would be higher than in
stochastic case (6277.7), but the expected end volume would be lower
(10,909.1) (Table 8.4). In the worst scenario the solution would not be feasible.

Table 8.2 Predicted harvested volume (m3/ha) of the forest area treated with each of the
alternatives in different periods and each of the alternative scenarios
Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3
Alternative 2016 2026 2036 2016 2026 2036 2016 2026 2036
Harvest1 175.0 0.0 0.0 175.0 0.0 0.0 175.0 0.0 0.0
Harvest2 0.0 220.0 0.0 0.0 215.5 0.0 0.0 224.5 0.0
Harvest3 0.0 0.0 265.0 0.0 0.0 255.2 0.0 0.0 275.0
No harvest 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Table 8.3 The solution for Stochastic Deterministic


the stochastic programming Alternative solution solution
problem and the respective
Harvest1 0.00 0.00
deterministic problem
Harvest2 0.00 0.00
Harvest3 22.31 23.68
No harvest 37.69 36.32

Table 8.4 The expected harvest level and end volume, and the respective values for each
of the scenarios in the stochastic and deterministic solution
Stochastic Deterministic
Harvest End volume Harvest End volume
Expected 5908.2 11309.7 6277.7 10909.1
Scenario1 5912.8 11304.7 6276.2 10904.3
Scenario2 5693.9 10800.0 6043.9 10417.9
Scenario 3 6135.7 11824.4 6512.8 11405.1
198 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

This problem formulation, where the constraints are hard, will produce a worst-
case solution as in the above example, meaning that the constraints need to be
fulfilled even in the worst-case scenario, which in turn means that the solution is
selected based on the worst-case scenario. That will often be unnecessarily expen-
sive for the decision-maker, especially so if the probability of the worst-case
scenario is very low. It is the ultimate risk-avoiders solution.
When hard constraints are replaced with soft constraints, violations of the
original constraints are possible, but they are penalised so that the selected solution
has the best expected value. Soft constraints produce solutions that are always
feasible. Moreover, as real-life decisions are rarely imperative, the soft-constraint
approach will reflect the true decision process better than hard constraints. For
instance, the even-flow requirements are such that the DM typically can accept
small deviations from the exactly even solution. If this is the case, it is often
advisable to use soft constraints to avoid making the decision purely based on the
worst-case scenario. In stochastic programming, soft constraints are referred to as
simple recourse (King and Wallace 2012).
The penalties for the deviations should reflect the true costs of violating the
original constraints. For instance, the penalties could be due to additional costs of
raw material, production or transportation if the demand of product is higher than
expected, or they could be due to lower price obtained from sold products, if the
demand for the products were lower than expected (Kangas et al. 2012). In all cases
such real costs are not valid. For instance, if the decision-maker wishes to have an
even flow of timber from his/her forest estate, it would typically mean reduction in
the NPV when compared to the unconstrained case. If the DM is willing to reduce
the NPV, then the penalties could reflect this will. In such a case, the shadow prices
could be used as penalties (e.g. Gilabert and McDill 2011; Eyvindson and Kangas
2015), as they reflect the time preferences of DM (Lappi and Siitonen 1985).

Example 8.2
Assume the same pine forest area of 60 ha that was used in Example 6.2. The
initial volume per hectare is 180 m3/ha, i.e. the total volume in the area is
10,800 m3. In this case, the problem was to maximise harvest revenues with
end-inventory constraint. In addition, it was assumed that there are three
possible trends in timber prices. In one scenario, the prices stay at 30/ha,
in another they decline and in another there is an increasing trend. The
predicted revenues for each of the scenarios and each of the periods are
shown in Table 8.5.
Table 8.5 The expected Scenario1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3
revenues for each of the
Harvest1 5250 4900 5600
scenarios
Harvest2 6600 5720 7480
Harvest3 7950 6360 9540

(continued)
8.1 Stochastic Programming 199

Example 8.2 (continued)


Then, the objective function is

max z 0:33  5250x1 6600x2 7950x3 0x4 0:33  4900, x1


5720:5x2 6360:5x3 0x4 0:33  5600x1 7480:5x2 9540x3
0x4 0:33  4d   
1 2d 1 4d 2 2d 2 4d 3 2d 3 ,

describing the expected revenues from the harvested volume and the expected
penalty due to the deviations of the end-inventory target level over all the
scenarios. Thus, the deviations here are for the different scenarios rather than
different variables as in the basic GP formulation. There are only one set of
decision variables for all the scenarios, which means that one decision is
made that will be implemented. The area constraint is

x1 x2 x3 x4 60

The end-inventory constraint for the value needs to be built separately for
each of the three scenarios:

30  52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4 d


1  d 1  324, 000
24  52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4 d2  d

2  324, 000
36  52:5x1 17:5x2 5x3 297x4 d
3  d
3  324, 000

The penalty used for negative deviations was 4 and that for positive
deviations was 2. The result obtained with Solver is presented in Table 8.6.
All the harvests are carried out in the third period. In the first scenario, no
deviations in the end-inventory constraint are needed. In the worst-case
scenario there is a negative deviation from the target and in the best scenario
a positive one. In this formulation, the harvested area is slightly larger than
either in the deterministic or the stochastic programming formulations with
the hard constraints.

Table 8.6 The solutions and periodic revenues for each of the scenarios
Solution Positive deviation Negative deviation
Harvest1 0.00 0 0
Harvest2 0.00 64,800 0
Harvest3 24.04 0 64,800
No harvest 35.96 0 0
200 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

8.1.3 Modelling Forest Planning Problems with Stochastic


Programming

In a stochastic programming setting, the traditional forest planning problems like


the even-flow and end-inventory constraint case can be modelled in several differ-
ent ways, which will produce very different results. If the problem is modelled
exactly in the same way as in normal LP, but by introducing a separate constraint
for all the scenarios, the problem will look like

X
m X
nk
 
max z E ck ji1 xk j
k1 j1

subject to

X
m X
nk m X
X nk
ckjit1 xk j  ckjit xk j  0, 8i 1, . . . , I, t 1, . . . , T  1
k1 j1 k1 j1
m X
X nk m X
X nk
PV kjiT xk j  PV kji1 xk j  0, 8i 1, . . . , I
k1 j1 k1 j1

X
nk
xk j hk , 8k 1, . . . , m
j1

Example 8.3
This problem is applied to the same real forest holding from Example 6.4. As
a recap, the forest holding from North Karelia is 47.3 ha, consists of 41 stands
and is primarily composed of Scots pine. The focus of this problem is the
same as 6.2.2, where the focus is to maximise the first-period income subject
to six 5-year even-flow constraints and an end-inventory constraint. A set of
100 scenarios were generated by introducing uncertainty into the inventory
data for both mean height and basal area. Both errors were assumed to be
normally distributed with mean zero and standard deviation equal to 10 %.
The problem does have a feasible solution; however, there is a rather signif-
icant decrease in the initial harvest levels. Compared to the deterministic
solution from Example 6.5, the first-period income decreases a total of 10,479
from 73,488 to 63,009. It is worth noting that the expected periodic incomes

(continued)
8.1 Stochastic Programming 201

Example 8.3 (continued)


are increasing from period to period, which is due to requiring the incomes to
be at least as high as in the previous period in all scenarios. The expected
values for the six criteria can be seen in Fig. 8.1 (left).

Fig. 8.1 The expected periodic flows using hard constraints (left) and soft constraints
(right)

If the problem is formulated as a stochastic programming with simple recourse,


the problem looks like
!
Xm X nk
  1X I XT  
max z E ck ji1 xk j  p    
t d it pt d it pE d iE pE d iE
k1 j1
I i1 t1

subject to

X
m X
nk m X
X nk
ckjit1 xk j  ckjit xk j d 
it  d it 0, 8i 1, . . . , I, t 1, . . . , T  1
k1 j1 k1 j1
m X
X nk m X
X nk
PV kjiT xk j  PV kji1 xk j d 
iE  d iE 0, 8i 1, . . . , I
k1 j1 k1 j1

X
nk
xk j hk , 8k 1, . . . , m
j1

d
it , d it  0, 8 i 1, . . . , I, t 1, . . . , T

d
iE , d iE  0, 8 i 1, . . . , I
202 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

In the above formulation, the objective is thus to maximise the objective


function value and minimise the expected penalties. This approach is suitable,
if the decision-maker does not require that the constraints are met in each
scenario, but there can be some small deviations. Often the even-flow con-
straints are allowed to have some variation. Minimising the expected penalties
means that risks (of not obtaining the even flow) for the decision-maker are
already explicitly included in the problem formulation. It is possible to model
the risks of the problem also in other ways. For instance, it is also possible to
formulate the problem so that only the negative deviations are penalised,
meaning the expected downside risk (Krzemienowski and Ogryczak 2005) is
minimised. One possible avenue is to define a maximum for the deviations
(Kangas and Eyvindson 2013) or otherwise set a lower limit to the worst-case
solution. It is also possible to regulate the acceptable level of risk by using a
higher penalty for higher violations and a low penalty for lower violations. In
all cases, regulating the risk will cost the decision-maker in the value of
objective function. Using stochastic programming enables the decision-maker
to explicitly calculate the costs for reducing the risk and make a decision on
how much he/she is willing to pay in order to regulate the risks to acceptable
level (Eyvindson and Kangas 2015). That makes it possible to acknowledge the
risk attitude of the decision-maker in the calculations. Including more than one
criteria is possible through stochastic goal programming (Eyvindson and
Kangas 2014).

Example 8.4
By changing the constraints from hard to soft, the deviations are
minimised in a weighted fashion. This problem corresponds to Example
6.8, where the primary difference is for this example we are maximising
the objective function over a large set of scenarios. The penalties are
minimised using the same weighting scheme as in Example 6.8, and we
are only interested in the negative deviations. With this information, it is
possible to calculate the solution that is optimal across all the scenarios
simultaneously (stochastic solution) and for each scenario a solution that is
optimal specifically for that solution (wait-and-see solution). The expected
periodic incomes are presented in Fig. 8.1 (right). It can be noted that the
soft constraints mean on average more even incomes than in the previous
example and much higher first-period incomes. Table 8.7 provides the
solutions to the three cases, the first is the expected result if we were to
use the deterministic solution (the solution from Example 6.8), the second
is if we incorporate inventory uncertainty using soft constraints, and the
third is the expected result of the optimal solutions for each of the
scenarios separately.

(continued)
8.1 Stochastic Programming 203

Example 8.4 (continued)


Table 8.7 The deterministic, stochastic and wait-and-see solutions for the periodic
incomes and end value
PV0 INC1 INC2 INC3 INC4 INC5 INC6 PV30
Deterministic
Expected 429,267 67,524 68,029 71,563 68,358 72,159 72,145 428,788
Std 5,146 3,635 4,138 4,254 2,683 1,799 1,877 2,292
Min 414,286 57,696 58,527 60,901 61,742 69,190 67,841 422,894
Stochastic
Expected 429,267 70,002 68,224 67,774 68,118 68,987 70,891 435,755
Std 5,146 2,971 2,117 1,632 1,419 1,268 1,275 2,243
Min 414,286 62,785 62,785 63,938 64,631 65,615 68,225 430,555
Optimal
Expected 429,267 74,358 74,358 74,358 74,358 74,358 74,358 429,267
Std 5,146 1,084 1,084 1,084 1,084 1,084 1,084 5,146
Min 414,286 71,475 71,475 71,475 71,475 71,475 71,475 414,286

8.1.4 Value of Information and Stochastic Solution

If the decision-maker knew before making the decision, which of the possible
future scenarios would happen, it would be possible to make an optimal decision
for that specific scenario. If we calculate the optimal solution separately for all the
scenarios and calculate the expected value of the optimal objective function values
over the scenarios, we have the expected solution with perfect information (often
called wait-and-see solution). When we compare that to the expected value of the
stochastic solution, where the decisions are made without knowing which of the
scenarios will happen, we can calculate the expected value of perfect information,
EVPI, or more shortly just the value of information, VOI (Lawrence 1999). VOI
can thus be defined as the expected objective function value with the information
the expected objective function value without the information. In stochastic pro-
gramming with simple recourse it consists both of the primary objective to be
maximised and the expected value of the penalties. The VOI then means a sum that
a rational decision-maker at most should pay for the perfect information. The value
of information comes from the possibility to improve the decisions if we have better
information (e.g. Kangas 2010; Kangas et al. 2012, 2013; Eyvindson and Kangas
2015). As having more information can never cause worse decisions, VOI will
always be higher than or equal to zero.
It is possible also to calculate the expected value of the stochastic solution,
EVSS. EVSS means the improvement on the expected value of the solution when
compared to the expected value of the deterministic solution. In the case of
204 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

deterministic solution, the solution is calculated only with the expected values of all
parameters, so it only applies to this specific scenario. The solution may look good
or even better than the stochastic solution in this one scenario, but when the true
value of this solution is calculated in each of the scenarios, the expected value of the
deterministic solution cannot be better than the stochastic solution. Thus, EVSS is
also always equal to or higher than zero.

Example 8.5
From Example 8.4 before, the expected value of the solution in the deter-
ministic goal programming solution, stochastic solution and the optimal
solution for each of the scenarios was calculated. The expected value of
deterministic solution is calculated so that for each scenario, the realised
objective function value and the realised penalties for the deterministic
decision are calculated, and an average is taken. From these, the VOI and
EVSS were calculated.
Both the expected and the worst-case behaviour of the stochastic solution
are slightly better than that of the deterministic solution; the average improve-
ment in first-period incomes is 3.5 % and in worst-case incomes 8.1 %
(Table 8.7). If the decision-maker could have the full information on which
of the scenarios would happen, the expected optimal incomes would become
74,358, with the worst case being 71,475. The expected periodic incomes
in that case would be 9.2 % better than in the deterministic solution and 5.8 %
better than in the stochastic solution. The worst-case incomes would be
19.2 % and 12.2 % better, respectively.
The VOI of the optimal solution compared to the stochastic programming
solution would be (73,3580)(70,0023674) 7030, meaning 148.6/ha.
The expected value of the stochastic solution EVSS is (70,0023674)
(67,52410,045) 8849, i.e. 187.1/ha for explicitly accounting for the
uncertainty. In this case the EVSS is higher than VOI, and in both cases a
large proportion of the value comes from avoided penalties. Remarkable
increase in the incomes of the decision-maker would thus be possible by
either explicitly accounting for the uncertainty or by acquiring better (in this
case perfect) information or both.

8.1.5 Two-Stage Stochastic Programming

Often it is possible to gain additional information in time. It means that we can


make additional measurements or that we can observe the state of the system
developing in time, like in the case of climate change when we will gradually
learn, which of the scenarios the true one is. Likewise, we will observe the
8.1 Stochastic Programming 205

development of prices of timber in time and use that observation to reduce the
uncertainty on the price development in the immediate future. It means that after
new information has been measured, or otherwise revealed, it is possible to make
recourse actions. Rather than just modelling the decisions that will be implemented,
we will be able to decide on what we will do if a given scenario proves to be the
correct one. This kind of stochastic programming is two-stage programming, where
the first stage is for the decisions to be implemented, and the second stage is for
adjustments when new information is available.
The two-stage stochastic programming differs from the one-stage stochastic
programming in that all the scenarios have their own decision variables. However,
when the new information has not yet been revealed, the decision for each of the
scenarios has to be the same. This can be handled with so-called non-anticipativity
constraints by which the decisions in the first stage are required to be similar.
Another way to handle the situation would be to just define one common decision
variable for the first-stage decisions in all the scenarios.

Example 8.6
This example is for the same 60 ha pine area as Example 6.2. In this case, the
problem was to maximise first-period harvest revenues with even-flow and
end-inventory constraints. In addition, it was assumed that there are three
possible trends in timber prices. In one scenario, the prices stay at 30/ha, in
another they decline, and in another there is an increasing trend. The
predicted revenues for each of the scenarios and each of the periods are
shown in Table 8.5. We assume that the decision-maker has to make the
decision for the first period without knowing which of the scenarios will
happen, but after the first period the DM can make the decisions with full
information on the future prices. The decision variables in this problem are
the areas (ha) of the four treatment alternatives in three scenarios.
The objective function is

max z 0:33  5250x11 0:33  4900x21 0:33  5600x31 ;

describing the expected first-period harvest revenues over all scenarios in the
area. The area constraints are:

x11 x12 x13 x14 60


x21 x22 x23 x24 60
x31 x32 x33 x34 60

(continued)
206 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

Example 8.6 (continued)


Table 8.8 The solutions and periodic revenues for each of the scenarios
Scenario1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3
Solution Revenues Solution Revenues Solution Revenues
Harvest1 6.09 31,993.2 6.09 29,860.3 6.09 34,126.1
Harvest2 10.60 69,931.3 5.22 29,860.3 14.42 107,835.4
Harvest3 8.80 69,931.3 4.70 29,860.3 11.30 107,835.4
No harvest 34.51 43.99 28.19

The even-flow constraints for the three periods are:

6600x12  5250x11 0
5720x22  4900x21 0
7480x32  5600x31 0
7950x11  6600x12 0
6360x21  5720x22 0
9540x31  7480x32 0

The constraints for the value of the area in the end of the period are:

1575x11 525x12 150x13 8910x14  324000


1260x21 420x22 120x23 7128x24  324000
1890x31 630x32 180x33 10692x34  324000

And finally the non-anticipativity constraints

x11  x21 0
x11  x31 0

The results are shown in Table 8.8. In all cases, the end value of the area is
exactly the required. The first-period cuttings are again selected based on the
worst-case scenario, but in the second and third periods, the cuttings are
selected optimally for each scenario. It means that in the scenario of increas-
ing and stable prices, the revenues increase from the first period.

8.2 Robust Programming

Another option for decision-making under uncertainty is the robust programming.


Under this approach, DM is willing to accept a suboptimal solution for the nominal
values of the data in order to ensure that the solution remains feasible and near
optimal when the data changes (Bertsimas and Sim 2004). Robust programming is
8.2 Robust Programming 207

not a single method, but it is more like a collection of different formulations with
these goals in mind.
One approach in robust optimisation is to require that the solution is feasible in
all scenarios of future development (strict robustness, Ben-Tal and Nemirowski
1999; Bertsimas and Sim 2004). The idea is then to optimise the worst-case
solution. This approach is, however, very conservative and produces far lower
objective function values than would be necessary, in the same way as with
stochastic programming with hard constraints (Fischetti and Monaci 2009). The
main point of the robust optimisation counterpart of the original problem is that it is
tractable, meaning it is typically much easier to solve than the stochastic version.
This approach may be very useful, for example, if the DM wishes to have a
constraint that the population size of some wildlife species should be at least the
minimum viable population size, i.e. the feasibility of the solution is a real issue.
As the problem is just to optimise the worst-case solution, the whole distribution
of errors is not required as in the stochastic programming. It is usually sufficient to
use a range of possible values, which is narrower than the true range, so that the
values that have a very low probability are ignored. This way, the worst-case
solution is not quite as poor as it would be if the whole range of values were used
(Liebchen et al. 2009).
To overcome the problem of overly conservative solutions, other concepts of
robustness have been presented. For instance, Bertsimas and Sim (2003) have
proposed methods where it is assumed that not all of the coefficients will be at
their worst-case values simultaneously and define systems that are feasible if less
than a predefined size of subset of the coefficients take the worst-case values. In
effect, this robust programming formulation of the problem means that a buffer,
which depends on user-defined protection parameters, is added to the constraints
(Palma and Nelson 2009).
Fischetti and Monaci (2009) proposed so-called light robustness. This approach
allows for some slack in the constraints, so that it is a combination of stochastic
optimisation with recourse and robust optimisation.

Example 8.7
To highlight the differences between robust optimisation and stochastic
optimisation, the same North Karelian holding will be used. The objective
function will remain the same, to maximise the first-period income subject to
six 5-year even-flow constraints and an end-inventory constraint. The uncer-
tainties for the robust optimisation formulation are evaluated for each vari-
able using a precision estimate, which describes the uncertainty of the
variable. For this example, all precision estimates were set to 10 % of the
variable under consideration. Using a formulation similar to Palma and
Nelson (2009), the following results (Table 8.9) were found for a set of
different protection levels (). When the protection level is set to 0, the result

(continued)
208 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

Example 8.7 (continued)


is equivalent to the LP formulation, and there is no protection against
the uncertainty. The higher the protection level, the more conservative is
the result, and if the protection level is equal to the number of uncertain
parameters the protection is the total. The results can be related to those
of the stochastic programming formulations in Example 8.4; however,
a direct comparison between the two formulations should be made
with care, as the underlying uncertainties involved are rather different
(Table 8.10).

Table 8.9 The robust solutions for four different protection values and periodic revenues
PV0 INC1 INC2 INC3 INC4 INC5 INC6 PV30
0 497,430 73,488 73,488 73,488 73,488 73,488 73,488 429,270
0.5 497,430 71,603 72,062 72,561 73,193 74,206 75,223 431,560
1 497,430 70,281 70,997 71,713 73,021 74,788 76,556 433,860
2 497,430 68,263 69,248 70,337 71,907 74,285 77,963 435,600

Table 8.10 The robust solutions evaluated using the scenarios generated for the stochastic
programming problem for the periodic incomes and end value
PV0 INC1 INC2 INC3 INC4 INC5 INC6 PV30
0
Expected 49,7433 67,524 68,029 71,563 68,358 72,159 72,145 428,788
Std 6,167 3,635 4,138 4,254 2,683 1,799 1,887 2,292
Min 481,862 57,696 58,527 60,901 61,742 69,190 67,841 422,894
0.5
Expected 497,945 66,606 66,741 71,731 69,832 71,580 73,734 430,931
Std 5,685 3,525 3,626 2,640 2,126 1,760 1,896 2,055
Min 485,966 58,581 58,606 65,052 65,096 68,137 69,803 425,814
1
Expected 497,781 65,415 65,525 70,492 70,166 72,626 75,228 433,538
Std 5,540 3,209 3,505 2,369 1,905 1,788 1,808 2,264
Min 485,715 58,254 57,836 64,691 66,010 69,087 71,537 427,929
2
Expected 495,998 64,810 64,369 68,649 69,344 72,304 77,099 434,800
Std 5,186 2,901 3,046 2,148 1,738 1,647 1,713 1,630
Min 483,320 57,850 57,788 64,006 65,497 68,894 73,758 428,836
8.3 Chance-Constrained Programming 209

8.3 Chance-Constrained Programming

Instead of assuming that the constraints need to be met at all scenarios, it is also
possible to require that the constraints are met with a given probability, by formu-
Xn
lating the constraint ai j x j  bi as (Hof and Pickens 1991)
j1

!
X
n
P ai j x j  bi  i 8:1
j1

In this formula the probability of the solution to be feasible is set to i, which may
be, for instance, 95 %. This problem can be solved with the usual LP method, by
taking a new constraint level e b i from the 95 % percentage point of the cumulative
distribution of bi. Thus, the value of the constraint is increased in order to choose a
solution that is on the safe side despite the uncertainty. If a critical population size is
used as a constraint, the actual population size needs to be the larger the more
uncertainty there is about the critical value (Haight and Travis 1997). This approach
does not guarantee feasibility in all cases. This approach can be useful, if the
feasibility is important, as in the viability case, but the worst-case scenario has
very small probability or the robust optimisation produces unacceptable solutions
for most cases.
Uncertainty about the parameters a, i.e. in how the population reacts to the
treatment, can also be considered using chance-constrained optimisation. If the
Xn
coefficients a are assumed to be normally distributed, constraint ai j x j  bi can
j1
be presented as (Hof et al. 1992)
v
X uX
n u n X n
i j x j i t x j xh 2i jh  bi 8:2
j1 j1 h1

where ij is the mean of aij and 2ijh is the covariance of aij and aih, and i is the
standard normal deviate corresponding to the required probability. This formulation
Xn Xn
follows from ai j x j being normally distributed with mean i j x j and variance
j1 j1
n X
X n
x j xh 2i jh : If the constraints are assumed to be mutually independent, any
h1 j1
number of this type of constraints can be included in the problem formulation. The
problem is a non-linear optimisation problem, which can be solved, for example,
with simulation (Pickens et al. 1991) or with a so-called cutting-plane algorithm
210 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

(Weintraub and Abramovich 1995). Thus, the solution is also based on adding a
buffer to the constraint like in robust programming, but in robust programming the
resulting model is linear.
It can be required that not only each constraint is met with a given probability,
but that a set of constraints is met with a given probability (joint probability chance
constraint). Also, it is possible to maximise the probability for meeting the con-
straints instead of using a constant probability (Hof and Pickens 1991; Hof
et al. 1992).

8.4 Robust Portfolio Modelling

8.4.1 Principles of the Method

Robust portfolio modelling (RPM) is a decision support methodology for analysing


large-scale project portfolio problems (Liesio et al. 2007). Portfolio problems refer
to decision situations, where only a subset of possible projects can be implemented
with available resources in recognition of multiple criteria. Examples of these kinds
of situations are different funding decisions and, in forestry context, selection of the
cutting areas among the forest stands that can be cut during the specific time period
subject to, for example, sustainable cutting level and labour constraints.
The RPM method includes the following phases (see also Fig. 8.2):
1. Weight information, i.e. loose statements concerning the importances of the
decision criteria, is produced.
2. Project performances and possible uncertainties related to them are defined.
3. Constraints are defined.
4. Efficient (non-dominated) portfolios are generated.
5. The performance measures for projects and portfolios that help to analyse their
robustness are calculated.

Core projects Preceding


Large set of Additional Decision
Loose (treatment core Selected
projects alternatives) information rules,
statements heuristics Core
-> SELECT
on e.g. Add. core projects
Multiple criteria
weights
Borderline
projects
Borderline
Resource
Compute -> FOCUS ON
constraints Add. exter. Discarded
non-
Updated Negotiation, exterior
Incomplete dominated Exterior N-d- Preceding iteration projects
information portfolios projects
portfolios exter.
-> DISCARD

Fig. 8.2 RPM-decision support process (Liesi


o et al. 2007)
8.4 Robust Portfolio Modelling 211

In phase (1) the decision-makers uncertain preferences are included in the


specified additive weighting function (see Chap. 4). Incomplete information about
criterion weights can be captured through linear inequalities (e.g. Salo and Punkka
2005) and also by statistical models that measure the uncertainties of the preference
information (Alho et al. 2001; Leskinen 2001). For example, the decision-maker
may be able to define only that criterion i is the most important one, but she is not
able to define the importance order of other criteria. In phase (2) the uncertain
project performances are defined, for example, through intervals (Liesio
et al. 2007). Both uncertainty sources affect the overall values of the individual
projects and therefore the contents of the efficient portfolio. If the prevailing
uncertainties increase, also the number of potentially efficient portfolios increases.
In addition, also the defined constraints or project costs (phase 3) may be uncertain
(Liesio et al. 2008).
The above-listed uncertainties may result in extremely large number of potential
non-dominated portfolios. Liesio et al. (2007, 2008) present dynamic programming-
based formulations for determining all potential non-dominated portfolios. The
algorithms are supported by examinations concerning the efficient use of resources
and whether the portfolio belongs to the non-dominated set.
Difficulties in obtaining complete and correct preference and project perfor-
mance information suggest that robust solutions that perform reasonably well
across the full range of different parameter values should be found and examined
more carefully. For this purpose, RPM includes a calculation of a core index (Liesio
et al. 2007). If the core index of a project is 1, the project is included in all
non-dominated solutions and it is called as a core project. If the value of the core
index is 0, the project has not been included in any non-dominated solution and it is
called as an exterior project. If the value of the core index is between 0 and 1, the
project has been included in some portfolios and it is called a borderline project.
Thus, the decision-maker should concentrate on examining these borderline pro-
jects aiming to decrease their number. If the decision-maker is able to express her
preferences or project performance measures more accurately after he/she has
inspected the results, and if the made changes only narrow the initial variation,
the number of non-dominated portfolios and borderline projects decreases and the
amount of core and exterior projects increases. This is one way to proceed towards
more robust solution in phase (5). In addition, the decision-maker may apply
different projects and portfolio-level decision rules, interactive decision support
and subjective elicitation in final selection phase (Liesio et al. 2007).

8.4.2 Use of RPM in Forest Planning

The effects of uncertainties in, for example, forest owners preferences or stand
inventory data from the viewpoint of the resulting forest plans may be twofold.
Firstly, the predicted stand-level and planning-area-level outcomes (e.g. harvestable
timber volume) are incorrect, but the treatment recommendations for the stands are
212 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

correct. As a result, the correct outcome from the stand will be realised when the
treatment is carried out. Secondly, the stand-level and planning-area-level outcomes
are incorrect and also the treatment recommendations for some stands (e.g. timing of
thinning) are incorrect.
RPM-like approaches that utilise optimisation, Monte Carlo simulations and
calculations of the robustness measures can be rather directly adopted to many
kinds of forest management-related decision problems. Kurttila et al. (2009) exam-
ined the effects of forest owners preference uncertainties in a way that has
similarities with the RPM. Their analysis included uncertainties that were generated
from the inconsistent pairwise comparison data and uncertain aspiration level that
concerned the amount of cuttings during the first planning period.

Example 8.8: Uncertainties in the Cutting-Amount Goal


A forest owner may not be able to define exactly, for example, the cutting
amount he/she wants to achieve during a certain time period. One possibility
to overcome this problem is to use multi-attribute utility function and
sub-utility functions as the objective function. The uncertainty related to the
aspired amount of certain objective variable can be taken into account by
varying the point where the sub-utility reaches the value of 0.9 or 1.0. In the
Fig. (8.3), these points have been drawn randomly from a uniform distribu-
tion between the values a and b, which describes the decision-makers
uncertain aspiration zone. One thousand realisations were derived between
the defined values and they were included in the objective function that was
optimised. Note, however, that reaching the aspiration point depends also on
the relative weights of the used objective variables, other objectives and the
production possibilities of the area. In addition, exceeding the aspiration point
is in this example not penalised, only the marginal utility is smaller.

Fig. 8.3 An example of Priority


three different aspiration 1
levels between values a and 0.9
b that were defined by the 0.8
forest owner (Kurttila
et al. 2009)
0.6

0.4

0.2

0
min a b max
Value of objective variable
8.4 Robust Portfolio Modelling 213

After the preference uncertainties have been included in the objective function,
optimisation calculations are carried out and efficient forest plans can be produced
by utilising techniques described in Chaps. 6 and 7.
In addition to the described example, the RPM-based approach can be utilised in
several other forestry-related decision problems. For example, it is suitable for
operational harvest-scheduling problems, funding decisions concerning voluntary
biodiversity protection (e.g. Punkka 2006) and many other selection problems
where, for example, budget constraints cause that all projects cannot be carried
out at the same time.

Example 8.9: The Result of Recognising the Uncertainties in the Owners


Aspiration Level
The 1000 uncertain aspiration levels were included in the objective function
and 1000 efficient forest plans were produced by utilising simulated
annealing heuristic technique (Chap. 7) in the optimisation. The result was
that the uncertainties affected only 13 stands (the total amount of stands was
62) (Fig. 8.4). In addition, only two or three treatment alternatives became
selected for these stands.

56 2/4
48 2/8
47 2/5
44 2/8
stand number

40 2/6
36 2/8
30 2/10
28 2/5
22 2/7
15 3/6
6 2/5
5 2/8
4 2/8

40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%


proportion
Fig. 8.4 The stand-level result from optimisation calculations for 13 uncertain stands. At
the right side of the figure, for example, the number 2/4 means that four treatment
alternatives were simulated for the stand and only two of them became selected in the
created forest plans. The proportion refers to the core index of the selected treatment
alternative
214 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

References

Alho, J. M., Kolehmainen, O., & Leskinen, P. (2001). Regression methods for pairwise compar-
isons data. In D. L. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, & M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic
hierarchy process in natural resource and environmental decision making (pp. 235251).
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Alonso-Ayoso, A., Escudero, L. F., Guignard, M., Quinteros, M., & Weintraub, A. (2011).
Forestry management under uncertainty. Annals of Operations Research, 190, 1839.
Andalaft, N., Aldalaft, P., Guignard, M., Magendzo, A., Wainer, A., & Weintraub, A. (2003). A
problem of forest harvesting and road building solved through model strengthening and
lagrangean relaxation. Operations Research, 51, 613628.
Aouni, B., Ben Abdelaziz, F., & La Torre, D. (2012). The stochastic goal programming model:
Theory and applications. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 19, 185200.
Bare, B. B., & Mendoza, G. A. (1992). Timber harvest scheduling in a fuzzy decision environ-
ment. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 22, 423428.
Bell, D. E. (1982). Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Operations Research, 30,
961981.
Bell, D. E. (1985). Disappointment in decision making under uncertainty. Operations Research,
33, 127.
Ben-Tal, A., & Nemirowski, A. (1999). Robust solutions of uncertain linear programs. Operations
Research Letters, 25, 113.
Bertsimas, D., & Sim, M. (2003). Robust discrete optimization and network flows. Mathematical
Programming Series B, 98, 4971.
Bertsimas, D., & Sim, M. (2004). The price of robustness. Operations Research, 52, 3553.
Bevers, M. (2007). A chance constrained estimation approach to optimizing resource management
under uncertainty. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 37, 22702280.
Boychuk, D., & Martell, D. L. (1996). A multistage stochastic programming. model for sustainable
forestlevel timber supply under risk of fire. Forest Science, 42(1), 1026.
Birge, J. R., & Louveaux, F. (1997). Introduction to stochastic programming. New York: Springer.
421 p.
Duckstein, L., Korhonen, P., & Tecle, A. (1988). Multiobjective forest management: A visual,
interactive, and fuzzy approach. In B. M. Kent & L. S. Davis (Eds.), The 1988 symposium on
Systems Analysis in Forest Resources (General technical report RM-161, pp. 6874). Fort
Collins: USDA Forest Service.
Ells, A., Bulte, E., & van Kooten, G. C. (1997). Uncertainty and forest land use allocation in
British Columbia: Vague priorities and imprecise coefficients. Forest Science, 43, 509520.
Eriksson, L. O. (2006). Planning under uncertainty at the forest level: A systems approach.
Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 21, 111117.
Eyvindson, K., & Kangas, A. (2014). Stochastic goal programming in forest planning. Canadian
Journal of Forest Research, 44, 12741280.
Eyvindson, K., & Kangas, A. (2015). Integrating risk preferences in forest harvest scheduling.
Annals of Forest Science.
Fischetti, M., & Monaci, M. (2009). Light robustness. In R. K. Ahuja, R. H. M ohring, & C. H.
Zaroliagis (Eds.), Robust and online large-scale optimization. Models and techniques for
transportation systems (pp. 6481). Berlin: Springer. 421 p.
Gassmann, H. I. (1989). Optimal harvest of a forest in the presence of uncertainty. Canadian
Journal of Forest Research, 19, 12671274.
Gilabert, H., & McDill, M. (2011). Optimizing inventory and yield data collection for forest
management planning. Forest Science, 56, 578591.
Haight, R. G., & Travis, L. E. (1997). Wildlife conservation planning using stochastic optimization
and importance sampling. Forest Science, 43, 129139.
Hobbs, B. F., & Hepenstal, A. (1989). Is optimization optimistically biased? Water Resources
Research, 25, 152160.
References 215

Hof, J. G., & Pickens, J. B. (1991). Chance-constrained and chance-maximizing mathematical


programs in renewable resource management. Forest Science, 37(1), 308325.
Hof, J. G., Kent, B. M., & Pickens, J. B. (1992). Chance constraints and chance maximization with
random yield coefficients in renewable resource optimization. Forest Science, 38, 305323.
Hof, J. G., Pickens, J. B., & Bartlett, E. T. (1995). Pragmatic approaches to optimization with
random yield coefficients. Forest Science, 41, 501512.
Hof, J. G., Bevers, M., & Pickens, J. (1996). Chance-constrained optimization with spatially
autocorrelated forest yields. Forest Science, 42, 118123.
Itami, H. (1974). Expected objective value of a stochastic linear program and the degree of
uncertainty of parameters. Management Science, 21, 291301.
Kangas, A. (2010). Value of forest information. European Journal of Forest Research, 129,
863874.
Kangas, A., & Eyvindson K. (2013). Modelling forest planning problems with stochastic optimi-
zation. In R. Kiris (Ed.), Proceedings of the international symposium for the 50th anniversary
of the forestry sector planning in Turkey (pp. 8997), 2628 November 2013 Antalya.
816 p. Ankara 2013.
Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (1999). Optimization bias in forest management planning solutions due
to errors in forest variables. Silva Fennica, 33, 303315.
Kangas, A., Hurttala, H., Makinen, H., & Lappi, J. (2012). Value of quality information in
selecting stands to be purchased. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 42, 13471358.
Kangas, A., Hartikainen, M., & Miettinen, K. (2013). Simultaneous optimization of harvest
schedule and measurement strategy. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29, 224233.
King, A. J., & Wallace, S. W. (2012). Modelling with stochastic programming. New York:
Springer. 173 p.
Krcmar, E., Stennes, B., van Kooten, G. C., & Vertinsky, I. (2001). Carbon sequestration and land
management under uncertainty. European Journal of Operational Research, 135, 616629.
Krzemienowski, A., & Ogryczak, W. (2005). On extending the LP computable risk measures to
account downside risk. Computational Optimization and Applications, 32, 133160.
Kurttila, M., Muinonen, E., Leskinen, P., Kilpelainen, H., & Pykalainen, J. (2009). An approach
for examining the effects of preferential uncertainty on the contents of forest management plan
at stand and holding level. European Journal of Forest Research, 128, 3750.
Lappi, J., & Siitonen, M. (1985). A utility model for timber production based on different interest
rates for loans and savings. Silva Fennica, 19, 271280.
Lawrence, D. B. (1999). The economic value of information. New York: Springer. 393 p.
Leskinen, P. (2001). Statistical methods for measuring preferences (Publications in social sci-
ences, 48). Joensuu: University of Joensuu.
Liebchen, C., Lubbecke, M., M ohring, R., & Stiller, S. (2009). The concept of recoverable
robustness, linear programming recovery, and railway applications. In R. K. Ahuja, R. H.
Mohring, & C. H. Zaroliagis (Eds.), Robust and online large-scale optimization. Models and
techniques for transportation systems (pp. 127). Berlin: Springer-Verlag. 421 p.
Liesio, J., Mild, P., & Salo, A. (2007). Preference programming for robust portfolio modeling and
project selection. European Journal of Operational Research, 181, 14881505.
Liesio, J., Mild, P., & Salo, A. (2008). Robust portfolio modelling with incomplete cost information
and project interdependencies. European Journal of Operational Research, 190(3), 679695.
Mendoza, G. A., & Sprouse, W. (1989). Forest planning and decision making under fuzzy
environments: An overview and illustration. Forest Science, 33, 458468.
Mendoza, G. A., Bare, B. B., & Zhou, Z. (1993). A fuzzy multiple objective linear programming
approach to forest planning under uncertainty. Agricultural Systems, 41, 257274.
Ntaimo, L., Gallego-Arrubla, J. A., Gan, J., Stripling, C., Young, J., & Spencer, T. (2013). A
simulation and stochastic integer programming approach to wildfire initial attack planning.
Forestry Sciences, 59, 105117.
Palma, C. D., & Nelson, J. D. (2009). A robust optimization approach protected harvest scheduling
decisions against uncertainty. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 39, 342355.
216 8 Uncertainty in Optimisation

Pickens, J. B., & Dress, P. E. (1988). Use of stochastic production coefficients in linear program-
ming models: Objective function distribution, feasibility, and dual activities. Forest Science,
34, 574591.
Pickens, J. B., & Hof, J. G. (1991). Fuzzy goal programming in forestry An application with
special solution problems. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 39, 239246.
Pickens, J. B., Hof, J. G., & Kent, B. M. (1991). Use of chance-constrained programming to
account for stochastic variation in the A-matrix of large-scale linear programs. A forestry
application. Annales of Operations Research, 31, 511526.
Punkka, A. (2006). Luonnonarvokaupan tukeminen monikriteerisill a paat
osmalleilla. Systems
Analysis Laboratory, Helsinki University of Technology. (In Finnish).
Salo, A., & Punkka, A. (2005). Rank inclusion in criteria hierarchies. European Journal of
Operational Research, 163, 338356.
Tecle, A., Duckstein, L., & Korhonen, P. (1994). Interactive multiobjective programming for
forest resources management. Applied Mathematics and Computing, 63, 7593.
Weintraub, A., & Abramovich, A. (1995). Analysis of uncertainty of future timber yields in forest
management. Forest Science, 41, 217234.
Part IV
Cases with Several Decision Makers
Chapter 9
Group Decision-Making and Participatory
Planning

Abstract The use of public participation has become common in many forest
management planning situations. In this chapter, we define the concepts of partic-
ipatory planning and group decision-making, as well as stakeholder and decision-
maker. We describe the purposes and potential benefits of participatory planning,
for the participating stakeholders and for the organisations applying the approach in
their planning processes. We present the definitions for different levels of partici-
pation and discuss how a suitable participation process for different types of
planning cases could be designed. We discuss the importance of facilitation and
describe different facilitator roles in supporting group decision-making. We also
present criteria that may be used to measure the success of participation.

9.1 Decision-Makers and Stakeholders

Environmental management problems are typically messy, i.e. wicked (Church-


man 1967). This type of problems involves complex interdependencies, which
cannot be completely controlled or even understood. There may be high risks and
uncertainties involved and/or lack of scientific agreement on the cause of problems.
Moreover, goals and objectives are multiple or unclear. For these reasons, an
undisputable and solvable definition for wicked problems cannot be formulated.
Since an optimal solution cannot be found, the planning process needs to concen-
trate on finding a solution that is good enough. Therefore, working with environ-
mental management problems typically means searching a viable, acceptable
solution. For this reason, working together with multiple decision-makers and
various types of stakeholders is important.
The stakeholders are defined to be any group or individual who can affect, or is
affected by, the achievement of a corporations purpose (Freeman 1984). They
could be persons like forest owners, farmers, forest workers or local inhabitants or
stakeholder groups such as tourism and recreation services, organisations
concerned with nature conservation, rural communities, hunters associations, sport-
ing and recreation associations or wood and forest industry (International Labour
Office (ILO) 2000). Each of them can have different objectives concerning the use
of forests or other natural resources, which further complicates the evaluation. They
may even have different worldviews or core values, which may affect their

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 219


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_9
220 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

perception of the environmental problem at hand (Hjorts 2004). In those kinds of


situations, group decision-making enables learning on each others initial views and
finding an agreement on how the problem can be approached. Only after that the
actual group planning process may begin.
Group decision-making is inevitable, for example, when dealing with forest
planning of forest holdings owned by several people. In addition, group decision-
making is commonly used in business decision-making, for instance, wood pro-
curement organisations. In group decision-making, the total utility to be maximised
can be taken as a combination of utilities of the persons belonging to the group. In
group decision-making, typically at least some agreement among participants can
be found, due to the organisational culture (Hjorts 2004).
Public participation means that citizens are involved in the environmental or
natural resource decision-making that has an effect on them. Public participation is
also seen as part of sustainable development. This is further underlined by the
UNECE (1998) convention on access to information and access to justice in
environmental matters. In the case of public participation, the views of participants
are often fundamentally different and even conflicting (Hjorts 2004). In such
situations, people often focus on protecting their own interests so that conflicts
are an inherent part of public participation (Susskind and Cruishank 1987;
Hellstrom 1997).
The most distinct difference between these two cases is the actual power to make
the decisions. The group typically withholds all the power to make the actual
decisions, but in participatory planning, this is not the case, but usually the
managing agency holds all the power. Thus, the level of participation may vary
from mere informing the public to total control of public, depending on how much
power the managing organisation is willing to give up.
In most cases, organising a participatory planning process is voluntary for the
managing organisation. In some cases, however, the use of participatory planning is
required by law. Such is the case in many environmental impact assessment (EIA)
processes. In Finnish forestry, participatory planning has been used for instance in
the decision-making of Metsahallitus (formerly Forest and Park Service,
e.g. Wallenius 2001, Hiltunen 2012) and municipalities owning forests, such as
Raahe, Helsinki and Tampere (e.g. Tikkanen 1996, Sipila and Tyrvainen 2005).
Participatory approach has also been used for many policy programmes, like the
National Forest Programme and its regional counterparts (e.g. Tikkanen 2003,
Primmer and Kyllonen 2006, Saarikoski et al. 2010). In addition, participation
has been used in defining nature conservation programmes, such as NATURA
2000 (Metsien suojelun. . . 2006).
There are several reasons for promoting public participation. The specific
purposes may depend on the issues involved, the perspectives and interests of
participants and the existing cultural, political and organisational contexts. It can
be assumed that the final decisions are made with more competence, when local
knowledge is included and expert knowledge is scrutinised by the public (Webler
et al. 1995). Furthermore, the legitimacy of the final decision may be better, when
9.2 Designing the Appropriate Process 221

the citizens whose interests the project has an effect on are involved in the decision-
making.
In relation to forestry, ILO (2000; see also Hjorts 2004) has identified seven
purposes:
1. Increase awareness of forestry issues and mutual recognition of interests.
2. Gather information and enhance knowledge on forests and their use.
3. Improve provision of multiple forest goods and services.
4. Stimulate involvement in decision-making and/or implementation process.
5. Enhance acceptance of forest policies, plans and operations.
6. Increase transparency and accountability of decision-making.
7. Identify and manage conflicts and problems together, in a fair and equitable way.
According to Heberlein (1976), the reason why people want to participate in the
decision-making is that people feel there is a discrepancy between the values held
by agency personnel and the public. This may be the case especially in decision-
making concerning the environment, as the values in the society have been fast
evolving. Public participation is not, however, the only way to involve public
opinion in decision-making regarding natural resources. The public views and
values probably have their influence on the missions of the agencies doing the
planning. Similarly, the views of the public affect through the agency personnel.
Moreover, public opinion also affects the democratic decision-making system,
which supervises the work of agencies making the actual decision.
Group decision-making can often be aided with the same kind of methods as the
decision-making of one decision-maker. However, group decision-making requires
specific attention to support the groups collaboration. In addition, group decision-
making involves dealing with common understanding and social learning. The
same methodology can also often be used in a public participation process
(e.g. Kangas 1994, Pykalainen et al. 1999, Kangas and Store 2003). However,
there are many other aspects that also need to be accounted for, such as equity and
equality.

9.2 Designing the Appropriate Process

The public participation process can be divided in many ways. First, it can be seen
either as a method, a mean to an end or as an approach or ideology (Buchy and
Hoverman 2000). It can vary from passive participation organised by an agency to
self-mobilisation of local people at the face of some decision of interest to them
(Pretty 1995). Participation processes can also be divided to open (every interested
citizen can attend the process) and closed (only people invited by the managing
organisation can attend) or to combined (all interest groups participate at the same
time) and separated (each interest group has its own process) (Tikkanen 2003).
222 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

One important division is division with respect to power given to the participat-
ing people (e.g. Arnstein 1969, Tikkanen 2003). Germain et al. (2001) divide the
process to six levels:
1. Informing
2. Manipulation
3. Consultation
4. Collaborative decision-making
5. Delegated power
6. Total control of participants
In the first case, the managing agency informs the public about their future plans,
but there is no public avenue for feedback or negotiation. The process may aim at
educating people and/or changing their attitudes. It may be that the managing
agency truly believes that if the public knew what the professionals know, they
would think the same way (Daniels and Walker 1996). Such thinking can, however,
also apply to the participants (Webler et al. 2001).
In the second case, participation is organised, but it is illusory in the sense that
the public has no true power on the outcome. The purpose of the process may be to
engineer support for the project or just to improve the image of the management
agency (Germain et al. 2001; Kouplevatskaya-Yunusova and Buttound 2006). This
kind of participation process may have a co-optation function, meaning that people
can complain about the project, although the agency is not responding, or the
process can have a ritualistic function, meaning that the participation is required
by law, but there is no direct need for the participation (Heberlein 1976).
In the third case, people can also express their own opinions about the project,
but the managing agency retains the power to make the decisions (Germain
et al. 2001). In this case, the public cannot be sure if their opinions are accounted
for or not (Heberlein 1976). It often places the public to a situation where they only
can react to the decision the agency has made (Germain et al. 2001). Thus, although
majority of studies have found that the public meetings influence the decisions of
the managing agencies (Chess and Purcell 1999), people may feel that they are not
adequately heard. And, at the same time, the personnel of the managing agency may
feel that the public is never satisfied, whatever they do (Buchy and Hoverman
2000). In this level, public participation is usually carried out using public hearings,
conferences and formation of advisory groups (Hjorts 2004).
In the fourth case, the public is partly responsible for the resulting plan (Hytonen
2000). The aim in this level is to build consensus through collaborative problem-
solving, negotiation, conciliation and mediation and joint decision-making (Hjorts
2004).
In the last two levels, the public has a dominant role in the decision-making.
It has often been noted that a problem in public participation is the resistance of
the managing agencies (e.g. Garcia Perez and Groome 2000). On the other hand, it
has also been noted that people usually avoid participating in the decision-making
(Riedel 1972). Even if the people want to participate, it may be that they are only
interested in one or two issues. It may be that the local inhabitants are interested in
9.2 Designing the Appropriate Process 223

forest management in their immediate neighbourhood or in the areas they visit


regularly but not on the regional level where the participatory planning processes
are most often organised (e.g. Kangas et al. 2008). The silent majority may be
satisfied with the work of the managing organisations, so that those participating
have the most extreme views.
In participatory planning, the problem-setting phase includes (i) analysing the
planning situation, (ii) identifying the people affected by the decisions, (iii)
assessing if there is a conflict and the severity of the possible conflicts,
(iv) defining the level of power given to the participants and (v) gaining internal
commitment in the managing agency for the participatory process (Kangas
et al. 1996).
There exist several handbooks and guides for planning a participatory process
(e.g. Bleiker and Bleiker 1995, ERM 1995, English et al. 1993, ILO 2000; see also
Webler 1997). In more detail, the participatory planning process can be planned, for
instance, using the list of questions presented by English et al. (1993):
What is the goal of the participation process?
Who counts as affected party?
Who should participate in the process?
Where should participation occur in the decision-making process?
What should be the roles and responsibilities of the participants?
How to handle ethical principles?
How to balance technical and value issues?
How much influence on the decision should the process have?
How long should the process last?
How should the process relate to other decision-making activities?
One possibility to analyse the level of participation is to use the so-called
VroomYetton approach (see Vroom and Jago 1988). The VroomYetton model
is a set of questions that lead to the different levels of participation in a decision-
making of an organisation (Fig. 9.1.) It has been later developed to better suit a
public participation situation (Lawrence and Deagen 2001; Tikkanen 2003).
This approach may, however, be too simple, as there is evidence that only a few
people are willing to commit themselves to very intensive planning (e.g. Riedel
1972). Instead, they would like to have many different channels for participation,
varying from low to high intensity: some people will only want to have information
concerning the project, some would like to be consulted in the projects and some
would also like to participate in the decision-making (ERM 1995). People would
also like to be able to choose the level of participation suitable for them. The ERM
(1995) manual advises planners to provide possibilities for participating at all these
levels.
Participation includes many phases, and in each of these phases, several different
tools can be used. Janse and Konijnendijk (2007) present a set of tools for urban
forest planning, but this set of tools can be used also for other types of participatory
processes (Table 9.1). For instance, the information required for participatory
planning can be obtained with several different ways, for instance, using public
224 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

1. Does the problem YES NO


possess a quality
requirement?

2. Do you have
sufficient information NO YES
to make a high quality
decision?

3. Is the problem
NO YES
structured?

4. Is acceptance of
decision by subordinates
important for effective YES NO NO YES YES NO
YES NO
implementation?

5. If you were to make


the decision by yourself,
is it reasonably certain NO YES YES NO NO YES NO YES
that it would be accepted
by subordinates?

6. Do subordinates share
the organizational goals YES NO
NO YES YES NO NO NO YES YES
to be attained in solving
the problem?

7. Is conflict among NO YES


subordinates over the
preferred solutions likely?

C11 G11 C11 A11 C1 C11 G11 A1 G11 A1

Fig. 9.1 Original VroomYetton model (Vroom and Yetton 1973; Lawrence and Deagen 2001).
A1: The manager solves the problem alone using information presently available to the manager.
A11: The manager obtains any necessary information from subordinates and then decides on a
solution alone. C1: The manager shares the problem with relevant subordinates individually
without bringing them together as a group, gets their ideas and suggestions and then makes
decision alone. C11: The manager shares the problem with subordinates in a group meeting,
getting their ideas and suggestions, and then makes a decision that might or might not reflect the
subordinates influence. G11: The manager shares the problem with subordinates as a group, and
together manager and the subordinates attempt to reach agreement on a solution

hearings, surveys or different group decision support methods (see also Heberlein
1976, Hytonen 2000, Vacik et al. 2014). Nowadays, it is possible to utilise modern
technology in collecting the information, for instance, using public participation
GIS systems (PPGIS; see, e.g. Rantanen and Kahila 2009) or their mobile counter-
parts (Kangas et al. 2015). Each of these methods has its own drawbacks and
benefits. Vacik et al. (2014) classified collaborative planning methods in four
categories with respect to their ability to fulfil certain criteria of successful plan-
ning. These include methods for
(i) Problem identification (such as World Cafe)
(ii) Modelling participants interests (such as stakeholder analysis)
(iii) Simple problem modelling (such as multi-criteria approval)
(iv) Creative problem modelling (such as cognitive mapping)
(v) Problem-solving (such as analytic hierarchy process):
9.2 Designing the Appropriate Process 225

Table 9.1 Categorisation of individual tools (Janse and Konijnendijk 2007)


Tool categories Tool sub-categories Tools
Information provision Information distribution Newsletter
Website
Contact and information office
Public events Information meetings
Public exhibitions
Information stands
Public sensitisation/awareness raising
events
Events dedicated to the presentation of
project vision documents
Information collection Social surveys/interviews Social surveys
Interviews while walking through the
forest
Other surveys/Inventories Land-use surveys
Botanical surveys
Forest inventory
Involvement of experts Involvement of the public Sounding board group
and the public at large at large/interest groups Public workshops
Thinking days with the public
Expert analysis/connois- Connoisseur approach future man-
seur approach agers meeting local connoisseurs
Expert analysis of urban woodland
design
Expert interviews
Thinking days with experts
Involvement of children Youth workplay happening
and youths Design of a play forest with children
Education activities
Communication with children and teen-
agers through participation in practice
Youth round table
Processing and use of Assessment and analysis Working group sessions
information of information Visioning processes
Multi-criteria analysis
GIS tools Thematic maps/GIS mapping
Mapping of social values and meanings
of urban green areas
Assessing the recreational potential of
urban forest areas by means of GIS

There exist also several methodologies that are intended to cover the whole
participatory planning process. The readers interested are referred to a thorough
review by Tippett et al. (2007).
226 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

9.3 Facilitation and Different Facilitator Roles

When organising public hearings or decision workshops, safeguarding a smooth


process and enabling social learning become essential. This is why facilitators and
facilitator skills are important in group decision events. A facilitator is a neutral
person who is an expert of the planning process and group learning. Tasks of a
facilitator may include:
Planning schedule and tasks for the group meeting
Preparing the room with enough space, constellation of chairs, tables, flip charts,
papers, pens, etc.
Creating a collaborative atmosphere
Introducing the tasks and taking care of the time
Granting speech turns and ensuring equal participation
Asking constructive questions and summing up what has been discussed
Facilitator may take different roles depending on the requirements of the plan-
ning process and the situation at hand. The default role is a facilitator who conducts
the group process. A mediator, in turn, goes deeper into the translation and conflict
resolution activity when there are disagreements within the group. In environmental
management planning, a decision analyst or a modeller may appear as a third type
of facilitator. In the best case, a decision analysis expert or a systemic modelling
expert is a different person complementing the work of the facilitator with drawing
illustrations or doing ad hoc data analyses based on the groups requests and
discussion. But in more realistic cases, under resource constraints, a decision
analysis expert may be also taking the role of a facilitator (Khadka et al. 2013).

9.4 Success of the Participation Process

The success of public participation can be viewed from two different viewpoints:
outcome and process (Chess and Purcell 1999). They also relate to specific concepts
of justice, namely, distributive justice and procedural justice (Smith and
McDonough 2001).
Some people may evaluate the public participation only with respect to the
outcome of the process. The criteria for the outcome include better accepted
decisions, consensus, education and improved quality of decisions (e.g. English
et al. 1993). It may, however, be difficult to say whether the outcome is favourable
or not: people may use the participation process to delay difficult decisions or to
block unwanted proposals. It is also not easy to say how much the outcome is due to
the participation process and how much due to some other factors (Chess and
Purcell 1999).
The process also has an effect to the success. It has been noted that a fair
procedure make people react less negatively to unfair outcome (Brockner and
9.4 Success of the Participation Process 227

Siegel 1996) and that fair outcome could make people think more positively about
the process (Van den Bos et al. 1997). On the other hand, people may raise
questions concerning the process if the outcome is not to their liking (Webler and
Tuler 2001).
Although researchers and practitioners agree on the importance of the process,
there still is no agreement on what the process should be like (Tuler and Weber
1999). There exist several criteria given to the participation process. Some of them
may be theoretical, such as fairness, competence and reasonableness, and
some may be based on participants goals and satisfaction (Chess and Purcell 1999).
The participants goals, on the other hand, may vary according to culture, environ-
mental problem, historical context, etc.
Tuler and Weber (1999) studied the opinions of participants concerning a good
process. They found seven normative principles that emerged from the interviews.
These principles are also general and concrete enough so that they can be used to
evaluate the success of a planning process (e.g. Kangas et al. 2014).
1. Access to the process
2. Power to influence process and outcomes
3. Structural characteristics to promote constructive interactions
4. Facilitation of constructive personal behaviours
5. Access to information
6. Adequate analysis
7. Enabling of social conditions necessary for future processes
Access to the process means getting people present and involved in the partic-
ipation process. It also means that in order to succeed, organisations have to
actively reach out to people (Chess and Purcell 1999).
Structural characteristics to promote constructive interactions emphasise the
structure of social interaction: the time, location, availability and structure
(e.g. seatings) of the meetings. The time and location need to be such that not
only experts who work on the case can attend (Heberlein 1976). Facilitation of
constructive personal behaviour, on the other hand, emphasises the behaviour of the
people involved. Respect, openness, understanding and listening are required. For
instance, the process may be good in every other respect, but if people feel that they
have not been treated with dignity, the process does not feel fair and the participants
lose their interest (Smith and McDonough 2001; Booth and Halseth 2011).
With respect to access to information, people feel that both the knowledge and
experiences of laymen and experts should be heard. Adequate analysis means that
people want to be able to understand the scientific reasoning behind the plans (Tuler
and Weber 1999).
Finally, enabling the social conditions necessary for future processes emphasises
that participatory process should not fuel the conflicts. On the contrary, it should
build better relationships between the interest groups in the region.
One task of planning is to uncover common needs and understanding (Webler
et al. 1995). According to McCool and Guthrie (2001), especially managers stress
learning as an important aspect of successful participatory planning process.
228 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

According to the review made by Chess and Purcell (1999), the managing agencies
could enhance the success of the participatory process also (i) by holding public
meetings in addition to other forms of participation, (ii) by providing significant
technical assistance to participants, (iii) by conducting vigorous outreach, (iv) by
discussing social issues and (v) by fielding questions adequately. On the other hand,
the unsuccessful participation in their review was characterised by (i) poor outreach
to potential participants, (ii) limited provisions of technical information, (iii) pro-
cedures that disempower citizens, (iv) unwillingness to discuss social issues and
(v) timing of hearings after the decisions have been made or otherwise late in the
decision-making process. Good examples of unsuccessful planning processes are
presented by Garcia Perez and Groome (2000) and Booth and Halseth (2011).
While these general criteria for successful participatory process were clear,
different people emphasise different issues. For instance, Webler et al. (2001)
found five different perspectives emphasising different issues, and Webler and
Tuler (2001) found four differing perspectives in two different participatory pro-
cesses. The perspectives in the latter were that (a) a good process is credible and
legitimate, (b) a good process is competent and information driven, (c) a good
process fosters fair democratic deliberation and (d) a good process emphasises
constructive dialogue and education. In the former case, the perspectives were a bit
different: (a) a good process should be legitimate, (b) a good process should
promote a search for common values (c) a good process should realise democratic
principles of fairness and equality, (d) a good process should promote equal power
among all participants and viewpoints and (e) a good process should foster respon-
sible leadership. Inspired by this analysis, Kangas et al. (2010) distinguished four
stakeholder groups with different orientations towards the participation process in
the case of regional forest planning processes: pragmatic consensus seekers,
reformers, expertise-oriented actors and participation sceptics.
Thus, some people emphasise discussion among the participants, some high-
quality information, some fairness and some leaders taking the responsibility. The
differences may be due to both participation situations and the participating people
and their occupation and previous experiences in participatory processes (Webler
and Tuler 2001; Webler et al. 2001). For instance, being a politician or a proponent
of property rights had a significant effect on the preferred way of participation. The
best techniques depend on the planning situation. The good process also depends on
the planning context (Webler and Tuler 2001). Glass (1979) states that none of the
methods used for participatory planning is able to satisfy all the objectives of
participation. Moreover, it also means that using several different methods may
be advisable. Mixing different types of methods in a participatory planning process
has been evidenced to bring wider benefits, for example, simultaneously a trans-
parent and acceptable process and an operable and concrete outcome (Myllyviita
et al. 2014). Also Menzel et al. (2012) and Hujala et al. (2013) suggest that by
including both computerised and noncomputerised methods in planning processes,
the greatest benefits may be achieved.
References 229

References

Arnstein, S. (1969). A ladder of citizen participation. Journal of American Institute Planners, 35,
216224.
Bleiker, A., & Bleiker, H. (1995). Public participation handbook for officials and other pro-
fessionals serving the public (9th ed.). Monterey: Institute for Participatory Management and
Planning.
Booth, A., & Halseth, G. (2011). Why the public thinks natural resources public participation
processes fail: A case study of British Columbia communities. Land Use Policy, 28, 898906.
Brockner, J., & Siegel, P. (1996). Understanding the interaction between procedural and distrib-
utive justice: The role of trust. In R. M. Kramer & T. R. Tyler (Eds.), Trust in organizations:
Frontiers of theory and research (pp. 390413). Thousand Oaks: Sage.
Buchy, M., & Hoverman, S. (2000). Understanding public participation in forest planning: A
review. Forest Policy and Economics, 1, 1525.
Chess, C., & Purcell, K. (1999). Public participation and the environment: Do we know what
works? Environmental Science and Technology, 33, 26852692.
Churchman, C. W. (1967). Wicked problems. Management Science, 14, 141142.
Daniels, S. E., & Walker, G. B. (1996). Collaborative learning: Improving public deliberation in
ecosystem-based management. Environmental Impact Assessment Review, 16, 71102.
English, M., Gibson, A., Feldman, D., & Tonn, B. (1993). Stakeholder involvement: Open process
for reaching decisions about future uses of contaminated sites. Final report to the US Depart-
ment of energy. University of Tennessee. Knoxville: Waste management Research and Edu-
cation Institute.
Environmental Resources management (ERM). (1995). Manual on public participation for inves-
tors in Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Final report to the European
Bank for Reconstruction and Development. London: Environmental Resources Management.
Freeman, R. E. (1984). Strategic management: A stakeholder approach. Boston: Pitman.
Garcia Perez, J. D., & Groome, H. (2000). Spanish forestry planning dilemmas: Technocracy and
participation. Journal of Rural Studies, 16, 485496.
Germain, R. H., Floyd, D. W., & Stehman, S. V. (2001). Public perceptions of the USDA forest
service public participation process. Forest Policy and Economics, 3, 113124.
Glass, J. J. (1979). Citizen participation in planning: The relationship between objectives and
techniques. Journal of the American Planning Association, 45, 180189.
Heberlein, T. A. (1976). Some observations on alternative mechanisms for public involvement:
The hearing, public opinion poll, the workshop and the quasi-experiment. Natural Resources
Journal, 16, 197212.
Hellstrom, E. (1997). Environmental forest conflicts from a international comparative point of
view. In B. Solberg & M. Miina (Eds.), Conflict management and public participation in land
management (EFI proceedings no. 14). Joensuu: European Forest Institute.
Hiltunen, V. (2012). Developing decision support in participatory strategic forest planning in
Mets ahallitus. Dissertationes Forestales 141. University of Eastern Finland, School of Forest
Sciences. 47 pp.
Hjorts, N. C. (2004). Enhancing public participation in natural resource management using Soft
OR An application of strategic option development and analysis in tactical forest planning.
European Journal of Operational Research, 152, 667683.
Hujala, T., Khadka, C., Wolfslehner, B., & Vacik, H. (2013). Supporting problem structuring with
computer-based tools in participatory forest planning. Forest Systems, 22(2), 270281.
Hytonen, L. A. (2000). Osallistamismenetelmat metsatalouden paat atieteen
oksenteossa. Mets
aikakauskirja 3/2000, 443456.
International Labour Office. (2000). Public participation in forestry in Europe and North America.
Report of the FAO/ECE/ILO Joint Committee Team of Specialists on participation in Forestry.
International Labour Office, Geneva.
230 9 Group Decision-Making and Participatory Planning

Janse, G., & Konijnendijk, C. C. (2007). Communication between science, policy and citizens in
public participation in urban forestry Experiences from the Neighbourhoods project. Urban
Forestry and Urban Greening, 6, 2340.
Kangas, J. (1994). An approach to public participation in strategic forest management planning.
Forest Ecology and Management, 70, 7588.
Kangas, J., & Store, R. (2003). Internet and teledemocracy in participatory planning of natural
resource management. Landscape and Urban Planning, 62, 89101.
Kangas, J., Loikkanen, T., Pukkala, T., & Pykalainen, J. (1996). A participatory approach to
tactical forest planning (Acta Forestalia Fennica, Vol. 251). Helsinki: Finnish Forest Research
Institute. 24 p.
Kangas, A., Haapakoski, R., & Tyrvainen, L. (2008). Integrating place-specific social values into
forest planning Case of UPM-Kymmene forests in Hyrynsalmi, Finland. Silva Fennica, 42,
773790.
Kangas, A., Saarinen, N., Saarikoski, H., Leskinen, L. A., Hujala, T., & Tikkanen, J. (2010).
Stakeholder perspectives about proper participation for Regional Forest Programmes. Forest
Policy and Economics, 12, 213222.
Kangas, A., Heikkila, J., Malmivaara-Lamsa, M., & L ofstr
om, I. (2014). Case Puijo Evaluation
of a participatory urban forest planning process. Forest Policy and Economics, 45, 1323.
Kangas, A., Rasinmaki, J., Eyvindson, K., & Chamber, P. (2015). A mobile phone application for
the collection of opinion data for forest planning purposes. Environmental Management, 55,
961971.
Khadka, C., Hujala, T., Wolfslehner, B., & Vacik, H. (2013). Problem structuring in participatory
forest planning. Forest Policy and Economics, 26(1), 111.
Kouplevatskaya-Yunusova, I., & Buttound, G. (2006). Assessment of an iterative process: The
double spriral of re-designing participation. Forest Policy and Economics, 8, 529541.
Lawrence, R. L., & Deagen, D. A. (2001). Choosing public participation methods for natural
resources: A context-specific guide. Society and Natural Resources, 14, 857872.
McCool, S. F., & Guthrie, K. (2001). Mapping the dimensions of successful public participation in
messy natural resources management situation. Society and Natural Resources, 14, 309323.
Menzel, A., Nordstrom, E.-M., Buchecker, M., Marques, A., Saarikoski, H., & Kangas, A. (2012).
Decision support systems in forest management: Requirements from a participatory planning
perspective. European Journal of Forest Research, 131(5), 13671379.
Metsien suojelun osallistavat prosessit Suomessa. Sidosryhmien osallistuminen prosesseihin.
(2006). Maa- ja metsatalousministeri on raportteja. 50 p.
Myllyviita, T., Hujala, T., Kangas, A., Eyvindson, K., Sironen, S., Leskinen, P., & Kurttila,
M. (2014). Mixing methods Assessment of potential benefits for natural resources planning.
Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research. doi:10.1080/02827581.2013.859297.
Pretty, J. (1995). Participatory learning for sustainable agriculture. World Development, 23(8),
12471263.
Primmer, E., & Kyll onen, S. (2006). Goals for public participation implied by sustainable
development, and the preparatory process of the Finnish National Forest Programme. Forest
Policy and Economics, 8, 838853.
Pykalainen, J., Kangas, J., & Loikkanen, T. (1999). Interactive decision analysis in participatory
strategic forest planning: Experiences from State owned boreal forests. Journal of Forest
Economics, 5, 341364.
Rantanen, H., & Kahila, M. (2009). The SoftGIS approach to local knowledge. Journal of
Environmental Management, 90, 19811990.
Riedel, J. A. (1972). Citizen participation: Myths and realities. Public Administration Review, 32,
211220.
Saarikoski, H., Tikkanen, J., & Leskinen, L. A. (2010). Public participation in practice
Assessing public participation in the preparation of regional forest programs in Northern
Finland. Forest Policy and Economics, 12(5), 349356.
References 231

Sipila, M., & Tyrvainen, L. (2005). Evaluation of collaborative urban forest planning in Helsinki,
Finland. Urban Forestry and Urban Greening, 4, 112.
Smith, P. D., & McDonough, M. H. (2001). Beyond public participation: Fairness in natural
resource decision making. Society and Natural Resources, 14, 239249.
Susskind, L., & Cruishank, J. (1987). Breaking the impasse: Consensual approaches to resolving
public disputes. New York: Basic Books.
Tikkanen, J. (1996). Taajametsien osallistava suunnittelu. Kokemuksia MetsaRaahe suunnitte-
luprojektista. Metsantutkimuslaitoksen tiedonantoja 603.
Tikkanen, J. (2003). Alueellisen metsaohjelmaty on osallistamismenettely Pohjois-Suomen
metsakeskuksissa vuosina 19971998 ja 20002001. Mets atieteen aikakauskirja 3/2003,
321344.
Tippett, J., Handley, J. F., & Ravetz, J. (2007). Meeting the challenges of sustainable development
A conceptual appraisal of a new methodology for participatory ecological planning. Progress
in Planning, 67, 998.
Tuler, S., & Weber, T. (1999). Voices from the forest: What participants expect of a public
participation process. Society and Natural Resources, 12, 437453.
UNECE. (1998). Convention on access to information, public participation in decision-making
and access to justice in environmental matters. New York: United Nations Economic Com-
mission for Europe.
Vacik, H., Kurttila, M., Hujala, T., Khadka, C., Haara, A., Pykalainen, J., Honkakoski, P.,
Wolfslehner, B., & Tikkanen, J. (2014). Evaluating collaborative planning methods supporting
programme-based planning in natural resource management. Journal of Environmental Man-
agement, 144, 304315.
Van den Bos, K., Lind, K. E. A., Vermunt, R., & Wilke, A. M. (1997). How do I judge my outcome
when I do not know the outcome of others? The psychology of the fair process effect. Journal
of Personality Social Psychology, 72, 10341046.
Vroom, V., & Jago, A. (1988). Managing participation in organizations. Englewood cliffs:
Prentice Hall. 239 p.
Vroom, V. H., & Yetton, P. W. (1973). Leadership and decision-making. Pittsburgh: University of
Pittsburgh Press.
Wallenius, P. (2001). Osallistava strateginen suunnittelu julkisten luonnonvarojen hoidossa.
Metsahallituksen metsatalouden julkaisuja 41.
Webler, T. (1997). Organizing public participation: A critical review of three handbooks. Human
Ecology Review, 3, 245254.
Webler, T., & Tuler, S. (2001). Public participation in watershed management planning: Views on
process from people in the field. Human Ecology Review, 8, 2939.
Webler, T., Kastenholz, H., & Renn, O. (1995). Public participation in impact assessment: A social
learning perspective. Environmental Impact Assessment Review, 15, 443463.
Webler, T., Tuler, S., & Krueger, R. (2001). What is a good public participation process? Five
perspectives from the public. Environmental Management, 27, 435450.
Chapter 10
Voting Methods

Abstract For many participatory planning cases, the use of voting methods may be
an effective approach. Voting methods have long traditions in making social
choices the main difference between group multi-criteria analysis and voting
typically is that in voting the judgments are carried out holistically, without
decomposing the problem to criteria. Because of the similarities behind group
decision-making and voting, there are also several decision support tools that
share properties from both these two approaches. In this chapter, we first present
evaluation criteria for voting systems. After that, we describe many common voting
schemes that could be utilised in forest planning. Finally, we present some decision
support tools for multi-criteria planning based on voting theory such as multi-
criteria approval and multi-criteria approval voting.

10.1 Social Choice Theory

10.1.1 Outline

The basic task of social choice is to combine individual preferences into a collective
choice. When individual utility functions are combined, the aggregation could be
interpreted as a social welfare function (Martin et al. 1996). Social welfare can be
interpreted to include monetary terms such as commodity consumption as well as
other values such as collective activities, resource distribution, equity of genera-
tions, quality of life, etc. (Arrow 1951). Sustainable forest management can be seen
as maximising the social welfare obtainable from the forests (Kant and Lee 2004).
The social choice situation can be described with four components or parts:
Voters or players
Choice alternatives
The information of voters preferences over the alternatives
An aggregation device (voting model, voting procedure or voting method)
Throughout the history of democracy, voting has proved to be an efficient tool
for making choices among decision alternatives, e.g. in different kinds of elections.
It is also, in one form or another, known to everybody. It means that voting is also a

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 233


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_10
234 10 Voting Methods

reasonable approach for forest planning when multiple decision-makers are


involved (e.g. Kangas et al. 2006a).
In the voting theory, special attention has been paid to systems that are neutral
and difficult to manipulate, although it can be shown that any non-dictatorial voting
scheme is subject to manipulation (Gibbard 1973; Satterthwaite 1975). However,
some methods require more information to manipulate an election than others
(Nurmi 1987).

10.1.2 Evaluation Criteria for Voting Systems

There are several properties that are assumed to be reasonable requirements of a


voting system (e.g. Martin et al. 1996; Bouyssou et al. 2000). These include:
Unrestricted domain or universality: the preferences are not constrained, and the
system should be able to produce a definite result with all possible sets of
preferences.
Non-dictatorship: no one person can dictate the result.
Non-imposition or citizen sovereignty: it should be possible to select any of the
candidates with some preferences.
Monotonicity: if the relative rating of the other candidates does not change,
voting a candidate higher should never lower the candidate in resulting ordering,
nor should voting a candidate lower raise a candidate in the ordering.
Unanimity (Pareto efficiency): if all voters prefer x to y, y should not be chosen.
Independence from irrelevant alternatives: the ranking of two candidates, x and
y, should only depend on the ranking of x and y and not on some other
alternatives.
Even if these requirements seem like fairly modest, it has been shown that there is
no method of aggregating individual preferences over three or more alternatives
that would satisfy these conditions for fairness and always produce a logical result
(Arrow 1951).
Often at least one of the Arrows conditions may be irrelevant (Kant and Lee
2004). Therefore, a suitable method can probably be found for most problems. In
all, voting theory can be seen as a credible alternative in group decision-making and
participatory planning. However, it is not suitable to all problems: for instance,
problems involving distribution of resources need to be solved with other methods
(Sen 1997).
In addition to these requirements, many others have been set to voting systems.
Among others, these include:
Consistency: if the voters in two arbitrary groups in separate elections select the
same candidate, the result should not change if the groups are combined.
Neutrality: the system itself does not promote any alternative. The rules in the
case of ties, however, may violate this rule.
10.2 Positional Voting Schemes 235

Anonymity: the voters name does not affect.


For a complete list of requirements, the readers are referred to Cranor (1996).

10.2 Positional Voting Schemes

10.2.1 Plurality Voting

Many voting systems have a lot to do with the utility theory. The most common of
these, plurality voting (also called as first-past-the-post), takes into account the
preference ordering of the voters, albeit only with respect to the best candidate. A
major drawback of this method is that it is generally considered to be very easy to
manipulate. It is often worthwhile for a voter to vote for some other alternative than
the best choice, for instance, in order to avoid the worst choice.
The Block vote is the most common extension of the plurality to multi-seat
elections (Reynolds and Reilly 1997). The voter must vote for the number of the
candidates as to be elected, giving one vote to each. Majority voting is similar to
plurality voting, except that the winning candidate must receive more than 50 % of
the votes. Plurality voting satisfies the monotonicity criterion.

Example 10.1
Assume 21 voters and three candidates, a, b and c. The preference orders of
the voters are:
10 voters have a preference order a > b > c.
6 voters have a preference order b > c > a.
5 voters have a preference order c > b > a.
Thus, in plurality voting a has ten votes and wins the election. Yet, majority
of voters, 11, think that candidate a is the worst possible selection.

10.2.2 Approval Voting

The approval voting method was independently proposed by several people in the
1970s (Brams and Fishburn 1983). It is a voting procedure in which each voter
votes for as many candidates as he/she wishes. In other words, the voter votes for all
candidates of whom he/she approves. Each candidate approved by the voter
receives one vote. The candidate receiving the greatest total number of votes is
declared to be the winner.
This method is harder to manipulate by any one voter than plurality voting. This
is because it requires information about the distribution of approvals of the
236 10 Voting Methods

alternatives in order to be manipulated (Nurmi 1987). Usually it is, however, a good


strategy to vote sincerely. It can be shown that the optimal strategy in approval
voting is to vote for all candidates that are better than average (e.g. Kim and Roush
1980). One drawback in approval voting is that it tends to promote moderate
candidates or candidates that no one has ranked to the last places. This voting
system is also monotonic.
The approval voting is argued to be the best voting system, provided that the real
preferences of voters are dichotomous (i.e. candidates are either approved or
disapproved, Yilmaz 1999). This might not be the case except occasionally. Tri-
chotomous or multichotomous preferences can, however, also be applied in mod-
ified voting schemes. For example, Yilmaz (1999) proposed a system where voters
classify the candidates in three classes: favourite, acceptable and disapproved.
Then, the candidates are compared pairwisely so that a candidate scores a vote
whenever it is ranked higher than the pair. It means that a favourite scores a point
against acceptable and disapproved, while acceptable only scores a point against
disapproved candidates. If one candidate has a majority against all others, it is
chosen. Otherwise, the candidate with most disapproval votes is eliminated and the
procedure is applied again until the winner can be found. Felsenthal (1989), on the
other hand, proposed a method where voters can approve a candidate, disapprove it
or abstain from voting.
Approval voting has been used in participatory planning, for example, by
Hiltunen et al. (2008) and Vainikainen et al. (2008) for the planning in the state-
owned forests in Finland.

Example 10.2
Assume the same 21 voters and three candidates, a, b and c as in Example
10.1. The preference orders of the voters are also the same as above:
10 voters have a preference order a > b > c.
6 voters have a preference order b > c > a.
5 voters have a preference order c > b > a.
Now, the result depends on how many candidates each voter approves. If each
voter approves only the best alternative, candidate a wins, similarly as in
plurality voting. If all voters approve the two best alternatives, a gets 10 votes,
b gets 21 votes and c gets 11 votes. In this case, b wins. If only those
preferring c vote approve also the second best candidate, b gets 11 votes
and wins.
10.2 Positional Voting Schemes 237

10.2.3 Borda Count

The Borda count, originally introduced by de Borda (1781), takes into account the
whole preference ordering: given n candidates, each voter casts n votes for the most
preferred candidate, n1 votes for the second most preferred one and finally 1 vote
for the least preferred candidate (e.g. Saari 1994). Equivalent results can be
obtained by giving n1 votes for the preferred, n2 for the second most preferred
and finally 0 for the least preferred alternative. The winner is the candidate getting
the most votes. It has been proved, among others by Black (1976), that the Borda
count chooses the alternative which, on average, stands highest in the voters
preference orderings.
The problem with this method is that the result may be a function of the number
of candidates (Riker 1982). The Borda count also fails to satisfy the independence
of irrelevant alternative criterion. This method has also been criticised because of
its susceptibility to manipulation. The method can be manipulated, for example, by
including irrelevant alternatives or by altering the preference ordering. However, it
is more difficult to manipulate than many other methods: the voters would need to
know the other voters Borda scores before the voting in order to manipulate it
(Nurmi 1987; Mueller 1989). Like other positional voting systems, Borda count is
monotonic.
Also truncated forms of Borda count have been presented. Truncation means
that not all alternatives need to be given a score: only the top set of the alternatives
is given a score, while the rest of the alternatives score zero points (Saari and van
Newnhizen 1988). Such an approach may seem tempting, especially if there are
many alternatives to be considered. However, this approach may give different
results depending on how the ranking is truncated, although the preferences of the
voters remain the same. It means that given three candidates, for example, any one
of them can be elected, depending on whether only the best, the best two or all
candidates are ranked. The same problem, however, applies to approval voting: the
result depends on how many of the best alternatives are approved (Saari and van
Newnhizen 1988).
Borda count method has also been used for in real participatory planning cases,
for example, Martin et al. (1996) used it for oil and gas leasing problem on forest
service lands, Vainikainen et al. (2008) and Hiltunen et al. (2008) on the forest
planning in the state-owned forests in Finland.

Example 10.3
Assume the same 21 voters and three candidates, a, b and c as in Example
10.1. The preference orders of the voters are also the same as above:
10 voters have a preference order a > b > c.
6 voters have a preference order b > c > a.

(continued)
238 10 Voting Methods

Example 10.3 (continued)


5 voters have a preference order c > b > a.
In this case, the candidates get votes as:
a: 10 2 6 0 5 0 20
b: 10 1 6 2 5 1 27
c: 10 0 6 1 5 2 16
In this case, candidate b wins.

10.3 Pairwise Voting

Any voting system which chooses the Condorcet winner when it exists is known as
a Condorcet method (de Condorcet 1785). In this method, each voter ranks all
candidates in order of preference. Candidates are then paired and compared in turn
with each of the other candidates. The vote counting procedure then takes into
account each preference of each voter for one candidate over another. The Con-
dorcet winner is a choice which obtains a majority of votes against any other
alternative in pairwise elections. The Condorcet winner does not always exist, but
if it does, it can be found using Copeland rule or Simpson rule. Condorcets method
is said to eliminate the need for strategic voting.
Copelands method is a variant of the Condorcet method in which the candidates
are ranked on the basis of the pairwise victories (Copeland 1951). This method
belongs to majoritarian procedures. Pairwise victories, defeats and ties are counted
for each candidate; alternative a scores 1 points if a majority of voters prefer it to
some other alternative b and 1 if majority of voters prefer b to a. The sum of these
scores gives the Copeland score and the candidate with the largest score is declared
the winner. This method often leads to many ties.
In Simpsons voting rule, the number of voters preferring a to b, N(a,b), is
counted over all b distinct from a (Simpson 1969). The Simpsons score is the
minimum of these values. Then, to win with Copeland score, an alternative must
defeat all the other alternatives at least by a tiny marginal, but for winning with
Simpsons rule, it may be enough if any other alternative does not have a large
majority against it.
Selecting the Condorcet winner is often perceived as an important property of
the voting methods. The Condorcet criterion is, in fact, regarded as so important
that voting schemes are evaluated with respect to how probable it is that the
Condorcet winner is elected with this scheme if one exists. This probability is
called the Condorcet efficiency (e.g. Gerhlein and Lepelley 2001). For example,
neither plurality voting nor approval voting nor Borda count always choose the
10.3 Pairwise Voting 239

Condorcet winner. Except for Borda count, they even can choose the Condorcet
loser, i.e. the alternative that loses to all the other alternatives in pairwise voting.
Borda count is the most likely method to choose the Condorcet winner, when the
number of alternatives is large (Mueller 1989). On the other hand, Condorcet
criterion is also criticised, since it does not note the differences in the pairwise
votes, i.e. preference intensities (Heckelman 2003).

Example 10.4
Assume the same 21 voters and three candidates, a, b and c as in Example
10.1. The preference orders of the voters are also the same as above:
10 voters have a preference order a > b > c.
6 voters have a preference order b > c > a.
5 voters have a preference order c > b > a.
The preferences of voters can be presented as a matrix giving the number of
voters preferring row alternative to column alternative, i.e. the pairwise votes:

a b c

a 10 10

b 11 16

c 11 5

In this case, b gets the majority against both a (11 votes) and c (16 votes) and
it wins. With Copeland criterion, the results are:

a b c

a -1 -1

b 1 1

c 1 -1

With this criterion, a has a score 2, b 2 and c 0, and candidate b is the winner
also with this criterion.
240 10 Voting Methods

Example 10.5
If three new voters are included in the example above, with preferences
c > a > b, and the preferences are otherwise similar than above, the pairwise
votes would be:

a b c

a 13 10

b 11 16

c 14 8

which means that a majority of voters think that a > b (13 voters), that c > a
(14 voters) and that b > c (16 voters). Thus, the preferences of majority are
not transitive. In this case, Condorcet winner does not exist. With Simpsons
score, however, alternative b is chosen, since it loses to a only by two votes.

10.4 Fuzzy Voting

The voting schemes can also be formed using fuzzy set theory. In fuzzy voting
systems, the preference relations of the alternatives are assumed fuzzy (Kacprzyk
et al. 1992; Nurmi et al. 1996; Garca-Lapresta and Martnez-Panero 2002). The
simplest example of fuzzy voting is the fuzzy approval voting. The classic approval
voting can be formalised to a formula

1, if alternative xi is approved by voter k
r ik 10:1
0, otherwise

and then, the final vote for alternative i is

X
m
r xi r ik ; 10:2
k1

where m is the number of voters. A fuzzy version of approval voting is obtained


simply by defining the approval of the alternatives r ik 2 0; 1, i.e. the degree of
approval may vary from 0 to 1 (Garca-Lapresta and Martnez-Panero 2002). The
final vote is achieved by summing the approvals of the alternatives i over voters k in
a similar fashion as in classic approval voting.
10.4 Fuzzy Voting 241

The fuzzy approach can also be used for other voting schemes. For instance, the
classic Borda count voting can be formalised as a pairwise voting using a prefer-
ence matrix R for each voter k as (Garca-Lapresta and Martnez-Panero 2002)
0 1
k
r 11 k
r 12 . . . r 1n
k
Brk k
r 22 k C
. . . r 2n
Rk B
@...
21 C 10:3
... ... ...A
k
r n1 k
r n2 . . . r nn
k

where n is the number of alternatives and



1, if alternative xi is preferred to alternative x j by voter k
r ikj 10:4
0, otherwise

Then, voter k gives alternative xi score

X
n
r k x i r ikj 10:5
j1

which equals the number of alternatives that are worse than alternative xi. The final
vote is obtained by summing the individual votes as
X
m
r xi r k x i 10:6
k1

The fuzzy relations can be defined, e.g. so that relation rij 0.5 means that
alternatives i and j are equally good, rij 0.0 means that j is strictly preferred and
rij 1.0 means that i is strictly preferred to j. Values between 0.5 and 1.0 represent
slight preference of i and values between 0.0 and 0.5 slight preference of j.
Typically, a reciprocal property is assumed, giving rij rji 1. Furthermore, it is
assumed that the preference relation of alternative i with itself is 0.5 (Garca-
Lapresta and Martnez-Panero 2002). The fuzzy relation can also be defined so as
to describe the certainty of the preference, not only the intensity of preference.
The vote of individual k for alternative xi can be defined as the sum of preference
intensities among the alternative and those worse than it as (Garca-Lapresta and
Martnez-Panero 2002)
X
n
r k xi r ikj 10:7
j1
r ikj > 0:5

The final vote is calculated similarly as in classic Borda. It would, however, be


possible also to use other borderline than 0.5 for preference intensity.
The fuzzy approach gives more freedom to voters to give scores according to
their real preferences. However, the greatest value of fuzzy voting schemes may be
242 10 Voting Methods

the fact that many of the famous results of voting theory, namely, Arrows impos-
sibility theorem and the results of Gibbard and Satterthwaite, can be done away
(Nurmi et al. 1996). It means that by modifying the assumptions, it is possible to
form aggregating rules that satisfy the Arrows conditions. Another example of
modified assumptions is the probability voting.

10.5 Probability Voting

In probability voting, the voters are asked to give the probabilities for voting any
one candidate instead of strict preference relations. In probabilistic approval voting,
on the other hand, the probability for approving any one candidate is required.
These probabilities play the same role as the individual preference relations. They
are to be interpreted so that the more likely an individual is to vote for a certain
alternative, the more desirable that alternative is (Nurmi et al. 1996). The individual
probabilities pji of individual j voting for alternative i can be aggregated to the
probability of a group pi simply by calculating the mean probability for alternative
i among all the members of the group. Even this simple voting scheme fulfils all the
Arrows conditions, but the results may be harder to interpret than in normal votes.
The actual decisions could even be calculated with a lottery. For instance, a
probabilistic version of Borda count was presented by Heckelman (2003). In this
system, a classic Borda count vote is first taken. However, the final decision is
obtained by a lottery, where the probability of each alternative to win is its Borda
score relative to the sum of all Borda points. In unique decision situations this might
be a bit peculiar system (Nurmi et al. 1996). However, when a series of decisions is
made, probability voting may give also a small interest group an influence which is
in proportion to its size (Heckelman 2003).

10.6 Multi-criteria Approval

10.6.1 Original Method

Fraser and Hauge (1998) presented an application of approval voting, called multi-
criteria approval (MA), which can be used in multi-criteria decision-making.
Technically taken, in multi-criteria approval the voters of social choice theory are
substituted with multiple criteria. The standard version of MA has been developed
for one decision-maker, but if the decision-makers can agree upon the importance
order of the criteria and the border for approval for each criterion, the standard
version suits also for group decision-making.
Multi-criteria approval method begins with the determination of the alternatives
and the criteria. The criteria are ranked by their importance. The next step is to
10.6 Multi-criteria Approval 243

determine which of the alternatives will be approved for each criterion. Fraser and
Hauge (1998) defined the border as the average evaluation of the alternatives with
respect to the criterion considered. In other words, in maximisation problems each
alternative i, with respect to each criterion j, is approved if the criterion value is
above average and disapproved if otherwise. (In minimisation problems, the direc-
tion is changed or the values are first multiplied by 1.) With numerical criterion
Xm
c j ai
values cj(ai), the border is the mean criterion value c j of the m alter-
i1
m
natives, with respect to each criterion j. This approval border is justified by the fact
that according to approval voting theory, the optimal strategy for a voter is to vote
for all the candidates that are above average (e.g. Kim and Roush 1980). When the
criterion is evaluated in an ordinal scale, a middle rank has been used for approval
(e.g. Laukkanen et al. 2002). The approval border could, however, be defined also
in other ways.
There are five possible classes of voting results: unanimous, majority, ordinally
dominant, deadlocked and indeterminate (Fig. 10.1). The voting result is unani-
mous if one alternative has been approved with respect to all criteria, while the
other alternatives have not. Majority result occurs when one alternative has been
approved with respect to the majority of criteria, in the importance order, starting
with the most important one. If there are, for example, five criteria, for a majority
result one alternative needs to be approved by at least the three most important of
them.
If one alternative has been defined to be superior on the grounds of the order of
criteria, the result is ordinally dominant. For instance, if two alternatives are
approved by the same number of criteria, the one which is approved by the more
important criteria is better. Alternative k is classified to be ordinally dominant if
(Fraser and Hauge 1998):
 
f n* ki  0 8n* , 1  n*  n, 8i 6 k 10:8

  X
n *

where f n* ki gi jk
j1
and
8
>
> 1, if c j ak > c j ^ c j ai  c j
<
0, if c j ak > c j ^ c j ai > c j
gi jk 10:9
>
> 0, if c j ak  c j ^ c j ai  c j
:
1, if c j ak  c j ^ c j ai > c j

The process is based on the idea that approval with respect to a more important
criterion can completely compensate disapproval with respect to a less important
criterion (Fraser and Hauge 1998). However, approval with one more important
criterion does not compensate disapproval with respect to two less important criteria.
244 10 Voting Methods

Unanimous c1 c2 c3 Majority c1 c2 c3

a1 + + + a1 + - +

a2 + + - a2 + + -

a3 + - + a3 - + +

Ordinally c1 c2 c3
Indeterminate c1 c2 c3
dominant
a1 - - +
a1 - + +
a2 + - -
a2 - + -
a3 - + +
a3 + - +

Fig. 10.1 The possible voting outcomes

The result is deadlocked if there are two or more alternatives that are defined to
belong to the above-mentioned classes. These alternatives are approved and
disapproved with respect to the same criteria, and so it is not possible to determine
one single superior alternative. The result is indeterminate if there is not enough
information to determine one superior alternative. This is the case, for instance, if
alternative A is approved by more criteria than B, but on the other hand, B is
approved by more important criteria than A. In this case, more information is
needed in order to make the recommendation.
The MA method has been used in a real planning case, for example, by
Laukkanen et al. (2002) for forest planning and (2004, 2005) for selecting timber
harvest options.

Example 10.6
The problem 4.6. was analysed with MA, using the average criterion value as
the approval border. The approval borders for the criteria were 74.1 for net
incomes, 0.47 for stumpage value and 5.36 for scenic beauty. The original
values are presented in Table 10.1 and the alternatives that are approved and
disapproved in Table 10.2. Net incomes are assumed to be the most important
criterion, stumpage value the second and scenic beauty the least important
one.

(continued)
10.6 Multi-criteria Approval 245

Example 10.6 (continued)

Table 10.1 Original values


Alternative Net income 1000 Stumpage value million Scenic beauty index
NAT 0 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 38 0.6 5.4
GAME 33 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

Table 10.2 Approvals and disapprovals of the alternatives with respect to each criterion
Alternative Net income 1000 Stumpage value million Scenic beauty index
NAT 
SCEN 
NORM 
GAME 
MREG 
INC  

In all, three alternatives were approved with respect to net incomes and
four with respect to other criteria. None of the alternatives was approved with
respect to all three criteria, but five of them were approved with respect to two
criteria. Thus, INC cannot be selected, since it is only approved by one
criterion. Since MREG and SCEN were approved with respect to the most
important criterion, they are better than NAT, NORM and GAME (the last
three lose to first two in the comparison with n* 1 and f(n*) 1). Of the
last two alternatives, MREG is approved with respect to stumpage value, and
SCEN is not, so that SCEN has f(n*) 1 with n* 2. MREG alternative is
the winner with a majority result.

10.6.2 Fuzzy MA

Fuzzy MA is based on a concept of fuzzy approval. In this case, the approval border
with respect to each criterion is defined with a membership function (cij) for a
statement A~ alternative i with criterion value cij is approved with respect to
criterion j. Thus, it describes a degree of approval.
246 10 Voting Methods

The results of fuzzy MA can be calculated in the same way as the results of basic
MA (Kangas et al. 2006b). In (10.8) it is required that f(n*)ki always remains positive.
However, as the values of gijk only have values 1, 0 and 1, the smallest negative
value possible is in fact 1. Therefore, in fuzzy MA, the condition is given as
 
f n* ki > 1 8n* , 1  n*  n, 8i 6 k 10:10

  X
n *

where f n* ki gi jk
j1
and
   
gi jk ck j  ci j : 10:11

If the condition were not relaxed from (10.8), it would mean that all alternatives
that are even slightly less approved than the best alternatives with respect to the most
important criteria are immediately out of question. This is not in line with the concept
of fuzzy approval. However, the relaxation does not affect to the results: given a crisp
approval border, fuzzy MA gives the same recommendation as basic MA. Thus, basic
MA is a special case of the fuzzy MA. In the fuzzy case, it is possible that there are
several alternatives that have f(n*)ki > 1. Then, the one with greatest value is
chosen. It also means that the possibility of ties is lower than in basic analysis.

Example 10.7
The approval borders in the problem above are defined to be fuzzy so that the
minimum approval border is min 0.2(max-min) and the maximum
approval border min 0.8 (max-min) for each criterion variable. Thus, to
be at all approved, the alternative must have net incomes above 20 % of the
maximum level (assuming minimum level is 0) and to be fully approved,
above 80 % of the maximum level. In between, the alternatives are more or
less approved. The fuzzy approvals are given in Table 10.3.
Then, the alternatives are compared pairwisely with respect to each crite-
rion in turn, i.e. with n* 1, 2, 3. In the first comparison with respect to net
incomes (Table 10.4), alternatives NAT, NORM and GAME already obtain f
(n*) 1, since they are not at all approved with respect to net incomes and
INC is fully approved. Thus, these alternatives are out of question. In the next
comparison, the comparisons based on stumpage value are added to these
values (Table 10.5). In this time, no alternatives were excluded. However, the
comparison between NAT and SCEN turned in favour of NAT. Thus, if INC
alternative were not among the alternatives, NAT could be a good choice.
When the final comparison with respect to scenic beauty is added, MREG is
the winner (Table 10.6). Its worst value, 0.31, is better than the other
alternatives left, SCEN (0.46) and INC (0.92).

(continued)
10.6 Multi-criteria Approval 247

Example 10.7 (continued)


Table 10.3 Fuzzy approvals
Alternative Net income 1000 Stumpage value million Scenic beauty index
NAT 0 1 0.92
SCEN 0.36 0.1 1
NORM 0 1 0.71
GAME 0 1 0.92
MREG 0.56 0.76 0.29
INC 1 0 0

Table 10.4 Comparisons with respect to net incomes


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.36 0 0 0.56 1
SCEN 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.2 0.64
NORM 0 0.36 0 0.56 1
GAME 0 0.36 0 0.56 1
MREG 0.56 0.2 0.56 0.56 0.44
INC 1 0.64 1 1 0.44

Table 10.5 Comparisons with respect to stumpage value added


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.54 0 0 0.32 1
SCEN 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.86 0.54
NORM 0 0.54 0 0.32 1
GAME 0 0.54 0 0.32 1
MREG 0.32 0.86 0.32 0.32 0.32
INC 0 0.54 0 0 0.32

Table 10.6 Comparison with respect to scenic beauty added


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 0.46 0.21 0 0.31 1
SCEN 0.46 0.25 0.46 0.15 0.46
NORM 0.21 0.25 0.21 0.1 1
GAME 0 0.46 0.21 0.31 1
MREG 0.31 0.15 0.1 0.31 0.61
INC 0.92 0.46 0.71 0.92 0.61

(continued)
248 10 Voting Methods

Example 10.7 (continued)


The same information can be obtained from a cumulative approval
sum (calculated from values in table 10.3). Whenever one alternative loses
in cumulative approval at least 1 unit, this alternative is dropped from the
analysis. In Fig. 10.2, the cumulative approval of NAT, GAME and NORM is
0 with respect to the first criterion, and they all lose 1 unit to the INC
alternative. Thus, from the remaining alternatives, MREG has the best cumu-
lative approval in the end.

Fig. 10.2 Cumulative approvals of the alternatives

10.6.3 Multi-criteria Approval Voting

There exists also another version of MA, namely, the multi-criteria approval voting
(MAV) (Pasanen et al. 2005). In this approach, it is assumed that the importance
order of criteria can be implicitly accounted for in MA. An implicit importance
ordering can be assumed if the approval of alternatives is not dependent on the
mean value of the criterion but chosen by the decision-makers (Pasanen et al. 2005).
It is assumed that the chosen approval border carries all the information concerning
References 249

the importance differences of criteria: the more important criterion, the higher the
approval border. Thus, an importance order of criteria is not required.
The recommendation is based on the decision-maker adjusting the approval
borders until only one alternative is approved with respect to all criteria, and that
is the recommended alternative. Another possibility would be to count which of the
alternatives is accepted with respect to largest number of criteria. In both cases, the
approval borders really need to reflect the approval of the alternatives, so that the
recommendation is not made based on the approval with respect to several criteria
that are not important.
This approach has also been utilised in a real-life strategic planning case in
Northern Finland (Hiltunen et al. 2009).

Example 10.8
In Example 10.6, no alternative is approved with respect to all criteria. In
order to have one alternative approved with respect to all criteria, the
approval border of at least one criterion needs to be lower. For instance, if
the approval border of scenic beauty is reduced to 5.2, MREG is approved
with respect to all criteria. If the approval border of stumpage value is reduced
to 0.28, SCEN is approved with respect to all criteria, and if the approval
border of net incomes is reduced to 38, NORM is approved with respect to all
criteria. The choice, which approval border to reduce, depends on the impor-
tance of the criteria to the decision-maker.

References

Arrow, K. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.
Black, D. (1976). Partial justification of the Borda count. Public Choice, 28, 115.
Bouyssou, D., Marchant, T., Pirlot, M., Perny, P., Tsoukias, A., & Vincke, P. (2000). Evaluation
and decision models A critical perspective. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Brams, S. T., & Fishburn, P. (1983). Approval voting. Boston: Birkhauser.
Copeland, A. H. (1951). A reasonable social welfare function, mimeographed. In Seminar on
Applications of Mathematics to the Social Sciences, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.
Cranor, L. F. (1996). Declared-strategy voting: An instrument for group decision making.
Academic dissertation. http://www.research.att.com/~lorrie/pubs/diss/diss.html
de Borda, J.-C. (1781). Mathematical derivation of an election system. Isis, 44, 4251. English
translation by A. de Grazia (1953).
de Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur lapplication de lanalyse a la probabilite des decisions
rendues a la pluralite des voix (Essay on the Application of the Analysis to the Probability
of Majority Decisions). Paris: De lImprimerie royale.
Felsenthal, D. S. (1989). On combining approval with disapproval voting. Behavioral Science, 34,
5360.
Fraser, N. M., & Hauge, J. W. (1998). Multicriteria approval: Application of approval voting
concepts to MCDM problems. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 7, 263272.
250 10 Voting Methods

Garca-Lapresta, J. L., & Martnez-Panero, M. (2002). Borda count versus approval voting: A
fuzzy approach. Public Choice, 112, 167184.
Gerhlein, W. V., & Lepelley, D. (2001). The Condorcet efficiency of Borda Rule with anonymous
voters. Mathematical Social Sciences, 41, 3950.
Gibbard, A. (1973). Manipulation of voting schemes: A general result. Econometrica, 41,
587601.
Heckelman, J. C. (2003). Probabilistic Borda rule voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 21, 455468.
Hiltunen, V., Kangas, J., & Pykalainen, J. (2008). Voting methods in strategic forest planning
Experiences from Metsahallitus. Forest Policy and Economics, 10, 117127.
Hiltunen, V., Kurttila, M., Leskinen, P., Pasanen, K., & Pykalainen, J. (2009). Mesta Internet
application for supporting discrete choice situations in strategic level participatory natural
resources planning. Forest Policy and Economics, 11, 19.
Kacprzyk, J., Fedrizzi, M., & Nurmi, H. (1992). Group decision making and consensus under
fuzzy preferences and fuzzy majority. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 49, 2131.
Kangas, A., Laukkanen, S., & Kangas, J. (2006a). Social choice theory and its applications in
sustainable forest management A review. Forest Policy and Economics, 9, 7792.
Kangas, A., Kangas, J., & Laukkanen, S. (2006b). Fuzzy multicriteria approval method and its
application to two forest planning problems. Forest Science, 52, 232242.
Kant, S., & Lee, S. (2004). A social choice approach to sustainable forest management: An
analysis of multiple forest values in Northwestern Ontario. Forest Policy and Economics, 6,
215227.
Kim, K. H., & Roush, R. W. (1980). Introduction to mathematical consensus theory. New York:
Marcel Dekker.
Laukkanen, S., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2002). Applying voting theory in natural resource
management: A case of multiple-criteria group decision support. Journal of Environmental
Management, 64, 127137.
Laukkanen, S., Palander, T., & Kangas, J. (2004). Applying voting theory in participatory decision
support for sustainable timber-harvesting. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 34,
15111524.
Laukkanen, S., Palander, T., Kangas, J., & Kangas, A. (2005). Evaluation of the multicriteria
approval method for timber-harvesting group decision support. Silva Fennica, 39, 249264.
Martin, W. E., Schields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Kent, B. (1996). An application of social choice
theory to U.S.D.A. Forest Service decision making. Journal of Policy Modelling, 18, 603621.
Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Nurmi, H. (1987). Comparing voting systems. Dordrecht: D. Reidel Publishing Company.
Nurmi, H., Kacprzyk, J., & Fedrizzi, M. (1996). Probabilistic, fuzzy and rough concepts in social
choice. European Journal of Operational Research, 95, 264277.
Pasanen, K., Kurttila, M., Pykalainen, J., Kangas, J., & Leskinen, P. (2005). Mesta
Non-industrial private forest landowners decision support for the evaluation of alternative
forest plans over the Internet. International Journal of Information Technology and Decision
Making, 4, 601620.
Reynolds, A., & Reilly, B. (1997). The international IDEA handbook of electoral system design.
Stockholm: International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance.
Riker, W. H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. Prospect Heights: Waweland Press, Inc.
Saari, D. G. (1994). Geometry of voting (Studies in economic theory, Vol. 3). New York: Springer.
Saari, D. G., & van Newnhizen, J. (1988). The problem of indeterminacy in approval, multiple and
truncated voting systems. Public Choice, 59, 101120.
Satterthwaite, M. A. (1975). Strategy-proofness and Arrows conditions: Existence and correspon-
dence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions. Journal of Economic
Theory, 10, 187217.
Sen, A. K. (1997). On economic inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
References 251

Simpson, P. (1969). On defining areas of voter choice: Professor Tullock on Stable Voting.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83, 478490.
Vainikainen, N., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2008). Empirical study on voting power in participa-
tory forest planning. Journal of Environmental Management, 88, 173180.
Yilmaz, M. R. (1999). Can we improve upon approval voting? European Journal of Political
Economy, 15, 89100.
Chapter 11
Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Abstract In this chapter, we describe planning process examples suitable for


public participation in different scales, from managing the forests of one city park
to preparing of national forest programmes. We also discuss the decision support
methods and tools required for handling a participatory planning process. Planning
problems with several decision-makers are often messy. Such cases require prob-
lem structuring methods, where the perceptions and characteristics of the problem,
as well as decision criteria and constraints, are explored together with the stake-
holders. There are several approaches specifically designed for this sort of work,
like SCA, SODA and SSM, but it is also possible to utilise common multi-criteria
analysis tools for this purpose. We also describe how surveys and hearings fit for
collecting information from the public. The information collected can also be
location-specific information collected and utilised though participatory GIS sys-
tems. Finally, we present how the multi-criteria analysis methods and tools
presented previously can be utilised as group decision support in stakeholder
working groups.

11.1 Participatory Planning Case Types

11.1.1 Participation in Public Urban Forests

Forest areas near urban residential areas face high use-pressures. Urban citizens
want to use the forest for various kinds of recreation: sports, berry and mushroom
picking, relaxing in nature, etc. Not only locals but also tourists may want to visit
the forest for recreational purposes. Simultaneously the forest is taxpayers property
and public decision-makers typically wish to make money with harvestings. Some
parts of the forest may contain valuable habitats and thus candidates for nature
protection. Moreover, nature-based tourism entrepreneurs may want to place their
business, such as a guided forest adventure path, in the urban forest. Planning the
use of urban public forest is evidently a participatory planning challenge, not only
because of the stakeholders multiple values and wishes associated with the forest
but essentially due to the fact that widely used public property requires inclusive
public decision-making. This requirement follows the ethical principles of proce-
dural justice (see Lawrence et al. 1997). These planning processes are typically also

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 253


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_11
254 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

shaped by the motivations of local political groups as well as rather active local
civil society associations (NGOs) advocating the benefits of different stakeholder
groups. This is why the opinions of various associations are often asked separately
from queries targeted to individual inhabitants, visitors and tourists.
In participatory planning of city forests, public hearings are the most traditional
way of informing people and gathering views and wishes from stakeholders.
Because those have shown not to prevent conflicts very well, also visitor interviews
and city dweller surveys have been used to complement public hearings. In the city
of Kuopio, eastern Finland, for example, a comprehensively designed participatory
process comprising multiple participation forms has been implemented in the
planning of Puijo area (Kangas et al. 2014a). The process was evaluated quite
successful, however with some shortcomings relating to how participants can
influence the plan and are able to observe their influence and how they can access
information (Kangas et al. 2014a). As a comparative alternative, the participatory
planning process of the urban forest in the city of Lycksele, northern Sweden,
incorporated a more straightforward but comprehensive decision-making phases:
stakeholder analysis, problem structuring, generation of alternatives, elicitation of
preferences and ranking of alternatives (Nordstrom et al. 2010). This process
appeared successful in integrating multi-criteria analysis into public participation,
and according to evaluation challenging aspects of this kind of processes are how to
handle place-specific criteria, develop alternatives and aggregate individual pref-
erences (Nordstr om et al. 2010). In urban areas, people may have their favourite
spots where they walk their dogs or visit with their kids or where they go for
jogging, for instance. Therefore, especially in urban forests, the place-specific
values may be important, meaning that people may have opinions concerning
how a specific stand or stands are managed rather than how the urban areas in
general are managed (Tyrvainen et al. 2007). The place-specific values, on the other
hand, may depend on the main uses of the area.

11.1.2 Regional Forest Planning

Regional forest planning refers to a geographical planning scale that goes beyond
individual forest stands and parcels and landscapes. Regional planning can be either
spatially explicit planning (actions and treatments are designated to certain loca-
tions) or nonspatial policy planning where only nonspatial strategic guidelines are
formulated in a participatory manner (e.g. Ananda and Herath 2003).
One regional forest-planning type focuses on rather large areas of state-owned
forests, such as the whole eastern Finland. In these cases, the owner of the planning
processes, state forest enterprise Metsahallitus invites representatives of the main
stakeholder groups to local participatory group meetings, in which collaborative
group decision-making workshops are conducted and a mix of voting, multi-criteria
approval and utility analysis methods are used along with qualitative discussions of
future visions and goals (Pykalainen et al. 1999, 2007; Hiltunen et al. 2008, 2009).
11.1 Participatory Planning Case Types 255

In the case of Metsahallitus, the planning process is in principle spatially explicit,


but in practice it is used as if it was nonspatial, to give targets for the cutting
amounts for smaller areas, and in these areas, the actual harvests are clustered for
efficiency (Laamanen and Kangas 2011; Kangas et al. 2014b).
In this type of regional forest planning, the participating stakeholders are
professional participants in the sense that they often represent their organisations
also in other forest-related boards in local or regional level. Therefore, they know
rather well the basic concepts and the institutional planning context and each
others viewpoints, which differ notably from the situation of public layman
participation in planning of city forests above. For planning consultants and work-
shop facilitators, the professional participation situation is on one hand fruitful,
allowing for relatively detailed technical analyses and demanding multi-criteria
assessments (e.g. Hiltunen et al. 2009). On the other hand, the situation easily
approaches routine governing within the preset planning frame without innovative
ideas or true opportunities for the participants to influence the goals, criteria,
alternatives or resulting consensus plan. In the planning process, designers may
mitigate this situation by selecting more open collaborative planning methods that
support creativity in the initial phases of the process (e.g. Vacik et al. 2014).
Another regional forest-planning type focuses on notably smaller regions, log-
ical socioecological units such as a village, local river basin or concentration of
herb-rich forests or surroundings of a bright-watered lake. In these cases, a planning
consultant gathers landowners of the region to negotiate of participating in peatland
management or habitat conservation project, which spans holding borders and thus
works in a landscape level. As incentives the landowners may be offered agglom-
eration payments if they choose to locate the protected habitats in ecologically
favourable pattern (Drechsler et al. 2010; Hujala and Kurttila 2010). This type of
regional coordination efforts has recently been given growing attention because of
the emerging objectives of ecosystem services provision in landscape level
(e.g. Reed et al. 2014). Rickenbach et al. (2011) have recognised that transforma-
tion from ownership-centric management to cross-boundary, multiscalar forest
management requires policy innovations to support landscape-level approach;
wider participation of landowners as well as private NGOs, volunteers and various
professionals; and perhaps, most importantly, boundary spanners that facilitate
information sharing and transfer between peer landowners. Facilitators of such
processes are not only advisors but also connectors, mediators and change agents.
To merge participation and decision support in regional forest planning,
Tikkanen and Kurttila (2007) have proposed an ideal model for a participatory
regional approach, representing a collaborative and open procedure with rather
intensive participatory elements without dangering property rights. The ideal model
comprises the following components (Tikkanen and Kurttila 2007, p. 118120):
1. Establishing the planning area
2. Informing and surveying starting points
3. Acquisition of advance information
4. Field work
256 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

5. Composition of regional appendix


6. Composition and release of holding-specific forest fact sheet
7. Composition of estate-level Forest Management Plans
8. Composition and release of the regional information package
The regional forest-planning processes, as described above, may be relatively
easily integrated with the existing forest resource information management and
forest-planning practices. The planning consultants will need to gather and handle
wide socioecological information and master spatial optimisation techniques
(e.g. Kurttila 2001, Jumppanen et al. 2003). Together with the collaboration
requirements of local participation events, it is thus obvious that successful regional
planning following the ideal model includes tasks for different types of facilitators,
some more competent in decision support software and illustrations, others in group
learning or constructive negotiation support.

11.1.3 Preparation of Policy Programmes

Designing forest policies in national and regional levels means a participatory task
to prepare such strategic lines for developing the forest branch and fostering
sustainable forestry that both the wide majority of institutional stakeholders and
the general public can accept. The Intergovernmental Panel of Forests (IPF) and the
Intergovernmental Forum on Forests (IFF) introduced the concept and principles of
national forest programmes (NFPs) in the 1990s under the auspices of United
Nations Commission on Sustainable Development (UNCED) (Liss 1999; Pulzl
and Rametsteiner 2002). The principles include, e.g. integration of international
agreement frameworks with the sovereignty and leadership of each country, holistic
and intersectoral approach as well as partnership and participation of all interested
parties (FAO 1996; Liss 1999). Moreover, the NFP principles include the long-term
and iterative process of planning, implementation and monitoring (FAO 1996).
For the participatory planning process, the NFPs mean a lot of public informing
activities, evoking public debate to learn about citizens views, foresight activities
to generate long-term socioeconomic and harvesting scenarios, multiple forms of
feedback gathering and prioritising actions in designated stakeholder advisory
groups. Major challenges in this type of process include the translation of citizen
views into meaningful programme content, integration of technical and political
nature of the programme (see Pregernig and Brocher 2013) and supporting the
implementation.
Analysis of Finnish NFP process showed that the long history of forest pro-
gramming in Finland since 1950s had yielded a policy preparation system in which
some new participation principles could be rather easily implemented, but the
improved participation served mainly the legitimating and awareness raising pur-
poses (Primmer and Kyllonen 2006). In the case of Germany, the National Forest
Programme was launched at 1999 with round-table discussions, and most of the
11.1 Participatory Planning Case Types 257

participants welcomed the opportunity. Elsasser (2007) observed notable differ-


ences between the views of German NFP stakeholder participants and general
public on the NFP aims, signalling a legitimation deficit and thus a need to inform
and incorporate citizens more explicitly in NFP processes. In evaluation the whole
process was deemed to have ambiguous goals and little commitment from the
administration (Winkel and Sotirov 2011). Later on, the process was also deemed
to have little effect on actual forest decisions. The evaluation of participation in the
NFP process of Slovak Republic (Sarvasova et al. 2014) showed weakness in
intersectorality (narrow forestry approach), but strength in public impact opportu-
nities (early involvement of invited actors to the policy formulation process) and
transparency (public communication of the process and content). In Kyrgyzstan the
National Forest Policy process was mainly used for improving the image of the
administration (Kouplevatskaya-Yunusova and Buttound 2006). These examples
imply that in the national level of forest policy formulation, the democratic and
decision-theory ideals of participation are hard to be widely achieved.
Like NFPs, subnationally prepared regional forest programmes (RFPs) belong to
the multilevel system of environmental governance (Hogl et al. 2012). The aims of
the RFPs include implementing and contributing to the design of national policy,
supporting networked action and promoting forest-based regional development
(Niskanen and Vayrynen 1999). Although RFPs are like NFPs in the sense that
they are only strategic policy programmes, they target much more concrete
networked action and regional stakeholders stronger commitment than national
programmes. This makes RFP quite a difficult task from the perspective of partic-
ipative planning. This is because in a policy process, the result should be a common
goal for the whole region, but at least in Finland, the policy process does not bind
the participants. Thus, getting a commitment from all participants to actually work
for achieving the goals set is crucial for the effectiveness of the RFP (Kangas
et al. 2010). If the participants are not committed, the goals derived in the process
just will not get implemented. Therefore, collaborative governance methods that
foster building trust and social capital among invited stakeholders and target joint
action are important in the RFP process (Saarikoski et al. 2013).
Since 1997, the Forest Act (1996/1093) in Finland has required the Forest Centre
as forest management authority to prepare Regional Forest Programmes in
13 subnational forestry regions. The RFPs cover all uses of forests, from forest
industry and silviculture to recreation and nature conservation. During the process,
the information concerning, e.g. the use of timber, standing stock, threatened
species, key biotopes, employment and the realised forest operations are updated.
Based on this information and the analysis of economic, social and environmental
effects of forestry, goals for future forestry in the region are set. In this phase,
regional characteristics can be taken into account together with local knowledge,
which enables using regionally formulated criteria and indicators when comparing
the alternative scenarios (Kurttila et al. 2014). Finally, based on the set goals, the
need of state subsidies for sustainable forestry and other measures to ensure
achieving these goals is considered. These programmes form a statutory instrument
in implementing forest policy in Finland, and they also form the basis for the NFP.
258 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

The Finnish RFPs are produced in a participatory fashion. Key stakeholder


groups such as forest industry, varying administrative organisations, forest workers
and municipalities as well as recreational and environmental nongovernmental
organisations are involved through Regional Forest Councils, which form advisory
bodies in the RFP processes. The final decision concerning the RFP is made by the
Board of Directors of each Forest Centre region.
The analyses on Finnish RFP processes show, for example, improved commu-
nication among regional stakeholders (Leskinen 2004) and RFPs role as an
institutionalised cooperation forum for information exchange and learning on
sustainable forest management, timber markets and biodiversity protection matters
(Saarikoski et al. 2010). However, the RFPs have been observed weak in engaging
general public, reconciling different perspectives, connecting to practice and build-
ing capacity to take action (Saarikoski et al. 2010, 2013; Primmer 2011).

11.2 Problem Structuring Methods

11.2.1 Background

Problem modelling is an important phase of any decision support process, bridging


the problem identification and problem-solving phases (Martins and Borges 2007).
Problem structuring is group-learning activity, mainly falling within the problem
modelling phase, which enables, through a systemic investigation, gaining a
nuanced understanding of the decision problem at hand so that problem-solving is
meaningfully possible. Khadka et al. (2013) characterise problem-structuring activ-
ity to include the following features:
Information exchange
Group negotiation
Experiences utilised
Methods applied
Facilitation done
Output generated
Learning achieved
The MCDM methods presented so far do not provide enough tools for efficient
problem structuring that would appreciate participants subjective perceptions and
pluralism among the stakeholders. Therefore, specific problem structuring tech-
niques or so-called Soft OR (i.e. communicative operational research) methods
have been developed. They may be useful for exploring the situation in such a way
that formal MCDM methods can be successfully applied in later phases. MCDM
methods may also be used within the problem structuring phase, but they cannot
replace the more comprehensive exploration of the decision situation. Problem
structuring methods are useful especially when the problem is messy,
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 259

i.e. ill-defined including complexities, uncertainties and various subjective inter-


pretations of the situation (see Churchman 1967; Rosenhead 1989; Belton and
Stewart 2002). Ill-defined problem means that people are attempting to take some
purposeful action that will improve the current situation, but the possible actions to
improve it are unknown, and the goals undetermined. Problem structuring methods
strive for understanding the phenomenon in its context and from the participants
perspective (Rouwette et al. 2009). While pursuing consensus and commitment,
problem structuring methods are intended to (Mingers and Rosenhead 2004):
Pay attention to multiple objectives and perspectives
Be cognitively accessible to a broad range of participants
Operate iteratively so that the problem representation adjusts to reflect the
discussions among the participants
Permit partial or local improvement to be identified
The problem structuring approaches vary in their scope and complexity.
According to Franco and Montibeller (2010), the main features of problem struc-
turing methods are: (i) the assumption of subjectivism (different views about the
world), (ii) groups as the key organisational entity in making decisions and (iii) the
limited role of quantification in the analysis (mostly qualitative modelling). In
practice problem structuring often means composing conceptual models
(e.g. mind maps) and creating and negotiating views of the decision situation, its
components, inputs and outputs in a systemic view and with the aid of an external
group-learning expert (Khadka et al. 2013). All this requires a lot of time and
commitment from participants, when compared to public participation using, for
instance, public hearings. These methods are suitable when workshops are used as a
form of participation. There is empirical evidence that the use of problem structur-
ing methods has resulted in mutual learning and commitment in joint agreements
among participants (Franco 2007, 2009; Rouwette et al. 2009; White 2006).
A skilled facilitator is a necessity to enable successful problem structuring
(Franco 2009). In this activity, the facilitators tasks include enabling constructive
group negotiation, equal participation, encouragement and a concrete outcome.
Khadka et al. (2013) distinguish general problem structuring activity following
the main aims of structuring problems, and formal methods, which have been
introduced and defined (e.g. by Mingers and Rosenhead 2004) as problem struc-
turing methods.
One simple and popular way in non-formal problem structuring is to ask the
participants to write their ideas and views on Post-It notes and then distribute them
to the walls. This way, a lot of detailed ideas can be generated by individuals, which
are directly recorded and also easily seen by other participants (e.g. Belton and
Stewart 2002, p. 41). In the beginning, the ideas appear in an unstructured format,
but as it is easy to move the Post-Its around, structure can eventually emerge, when
similar ideas are clustered together. Clustering of the ideas together will further
stimulate discussion and improve mutual understanding. But it is important that the
facilitator allows the participants to cluster the ideas and label the groups, because it
retains the power on content and ownership of results among the participants.
260 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

According to Belton and Stewart (2002), the main benefits of this approach is
that all people have an equal chance to contribute with their ideas, there is a degree
of anonymity involved, and the process cannot be dominated by more powerful or
eloquent persons. The method is flexible and powerful, because the facilitator may
use any kind of subtasks for the participant group, for example, different clusterings
for future vision, constraints, uncertainties, etc.
Since the early years of 2000s, the operational research community has shifted
attention from developing and studying individual problem structuring methods
towards enhancing the related participatory modelling paradigm in which the
specific method is less important than the principles followed (Franco and
Montibeller 2010). The formal problem structuring methods are still important
items in participatory planning experts toolbox. In this book, three most commonly
used problem structuring methods (according to Mingers and Rosenhead 2011) are
presented, namely, Strategic Options Development and Analysis (SODA, e.g. Eden
and Simpson 1989; Eden 1989), soft systems methodology (SSM, e.g. Checkland
1981, 1989) and Strategic Choice Approach (SCA, e.g. Friend and Jessop 1969;
Friend and Hickling 2005; Friend 2011). In its developed form, SODA is also called
JOURNEY making (JOintly Understanding, Reflecting, and NEgotiation strategy,
Eden and Ackermann 2001). In real-life forest planning application, soft OR has
been used by Hjrtso (2004).

11.2.2 Strategic Options Development and Analysis (SODA)

SODA is based on cognitive mapping (Eden 1988). It was developed as a way to


represent individuals construct systems based on Kellys personal construct
theory (Kelly 1955). SODA aims at presenting the problem as the decision-maker
sees it, as a network of means and ends, or options and outcomes. The concepts
linked to the network are action-oriented, which makes it a suitable approach for
strategy development (e.g. Belton and Stewart 2002 p. 49). The cognitive maps can
be done in paper, but there exists also software for doing them, for instance,
Decision Explorer (Eden and Ackermann 1998). Using computer enables a thor-
ough analysis of the maps.
In the map, alternatives or contrasting ideas can be expressed as pairs or words
connected with dots like saw mill . . . paper mill. Concepts are linked with arrows
to other concepts that they imply like employment or deterioration of water
quality. The arrows can also be marked with minus signs to imply countereffects,
like loss of agriculture may imply negative effects on quality of life (Fig. 11.1).
The (desired) outcomes or ends are concepts where the arrows lead (e.g. quality of
life) and strategic options or means are the concepts from which the arrows lead to
outcomes (e.g. pulp mill . . . saw mill).
One cognitive map typically presents the cognition of one individual. In order to
utilise cognitive mapping in group work, these individual maps need to be merged.
This is what the SODA method is about. The idea is to structure multiple conflicting
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 261

increase forestry ...


status quo
loss of agriculture

reduced flow in rivers ...


maintained flow of rivers
loss of afro-montane -
ecosystems ...
- viability of forestry ... preservation of
afro-montane quality of
collapse of forestry - life
deterioration in ecosystems
water quality ...
-
preservation of
water quality
-
controlled forestry ...
uncontrolled
forestry employment

pulp mill ... saw mill


secondary industry

Fig. 11.1 An example of cognitive map for a problem of allocating land to exotic forest
plantations (Modified from Belton and Stewart 2002)

aspects and put the individual views into context. Giving the individual views
anonymously, through software, may help in reducing conflicts, as people can
concentrate on ideas rather than on persons (Ackermann and Eden 1994). It is,
however, also possible to make a group map from the start (Ackermann and Eden
2001).
According to Eden (1990), SODA includes the following phases (all of which do
not have to be included in the process):
1. Initial individual interviews and cognitive mapping
2. Feedback interview where the initial maps are verified
3. Analysis for key issues
4. Refinement of issues
5. A workshop focusing on awareness
6. A workshop focusing on orientation
7. A workshop focusing on action portfolios
In the initial interview, participants express their view of the problem situation,
and the facilitator or consultant aims at capturing the ideas on the map. In the
second phase, the facilitator goes through the map with the participant, either
exploring the goals and then working gradually down to the options or exploring
the options and then gradually working up to the goals. The idea is to make sure the
map really expresses the view of that participant.
In phase three, the individual maps are first merged. This group map contains all
the concepts of each member of the group, but in the group map, they can be seen in
262 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Fig. 11.2 A cluster Goals or


rearranged as a tear-drop disastrous outcomes
(Modified from Ackermann
and Eden 2001)
Issues or
possible strategies

More detailed options

the context of all other ideas (Eden 1990). Then, the key issues are identified with
formal research. First, clusters of material that are closely linked to each other are
searched for. Each cluster represents a problem within which there are problem-
related goals and strategic options (Eden and Ackermann 2001). The clusters are
rearranged so that the goals are at the head of the cluster and options in the tail of the
cluster (Fig. 11.2). The clusters are linked to other clusters so that goals of one
cluster lead to options of another and options of one problem are consequences of a
subordinate problem. The issues best describing each cluster are the key issues. In
phase four, the resulting model is further refined, using interviews with experts. It
means that issues missing are searched for, or orphan issues are included to the
groups and so on. In phases from five to seven, it is used as a device facilitating
negotiations within the group.
The cognitive map resulting from merging can be analysed using concepts such
as domain, centrality and criticality (Eden and Ackermann 1998, see also Mendoza
and Prabhu 2003). The idea is that these concepts help finding important items from
the maps.
Domain reflects the number of items linked to a particular item, irrespective of
the causal directions (direction of the arrows). High domain values indicate a large
number of items directly affecting or affected by this particular item. In Fig. 11.1,
item pulp mill . . . saw mill has fairly high domain with 4 connections and loss of
agriculture fairly low with 2 connections.
Centrality reflects not only the direct impacts of an item to other items but also
the indirect impacts, through indirect connections to other items downstream the
impact chains. The central score can be calculated as

S1 S2 Sn
Ci ... 11:1
1 2 n

where Sj describes the j-level connections and n is the number of connections


considered. The contribution of direct connections (S1) is higher than that of the
connections further away. In Fig. 11.1, loss of agriculture has two direct connec-
tions and four second-level connections; thus, its central score with n 2 would
be four.
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 263

Criticality reflects the number of critical items linked to a particular item, where
the critical items are defined by the decision-makers. It can be calculated how many
critical items affect a particular item, and how many items are affected by it. The
former is related to the number of different paths to a particular item, and the latter
is related to the number of paths from it. For calculating the criticality of an item, all
paths to it or from it are counted, and the critical items in these paths are summed.
For instance, in Fig. 11.1, there is a path from increase in forestry status quo to
quality of life either through loss of agriculture or through loss of afro-montane
ecosystems and thus preservation of ecosystems. If employment is a critical factor, it
is in two backward paths from quality of life and respectively in two forward paths from
pulp mill and saw mill. For a more detailed example, see Mendoza and Prabhu (2003).

11.2.3 Soft Systems Methodology (SSM)

Soft systems methodology (SSM) is a learning system that is developed to aid a


system redesign. It is assumed that in any human activity system, i.e. in a system
of people making decisions and taking actions, each person has his/her own way of
thinking about the problematic situation (Checkland 2001). This is called
Weltanschaung or world view. For instance, the people who from one perspective
are declared as terrorists can from another perspective be seen as freedom fighters.
The SSM in its original form consists of seven stages (Fig. 11.3). These stages,
however, need not to be rigidly followed and can be used more or less as an aid in
the learning process.

Enter situation Define possible


considered changes which are
problematical 1. Take action in to both desirable and
improve the feasible 6.
problem situation
7.

Express the Compare models


problem situation 2. with real-world
actions 5.
THE REAL WORLD

SYSTEMS THINKING ABOUT THE REAL WORLD

Formulate root definitions Build conceptual models of


of relevant systems of the systems named in
purposeful the root definitions 4.
activity 3.

Fig. 11.3 The 7-stage representation of soft systems methodology (Modified from Checkland
2001)
264 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

In stages 1 and 2, the participants are supposed to find out what the problem is
and express it. In the first versions of SSM, the finding-out process was carried out
with so-called rich pictures (e.g. Khisty 1995). In the rich pictures, the participants
are supposed to represent important relationships (e.g. between the citizens and city
administration) and problem issues related to them (e.g. how can the citizen impact
the city to improve the recreation possibilities) as pictures.
In the later versions of SSM, this finding-out process was carried out with
so-called analyses 1, 2 and 3 (Checkland 2001). In the first analysis, the actors
who have interest in the situation or could be affected by it are identified. In the
second analysis, it is analysed what social roles are significant in the situation, what
norms of behaviour are expected from role holders and what values are used to
judge the role holders behaviour, i.e. the culture of the social system. In the third
analysis, the situation is examined politically, by asking questions about the
disposition of power. Thus, the method has also evolved in time (Checkland 1999).
The third stage is carried out by naming relevant systems for carrying out
purposeful activity. The term relevant here means that the system described is
thought to help in exploring the problem situation. The system is analysed using the
so-called CATWOE elements (Checkland 1985):

C customers Who would be victims or beneficiaries of this system were it to


exist?
A actors Who would carry out the activities of this system?
T transformations What input is transformed into what output by this system?
W world view What image of the world makes this system meaningful?
O owner Who could abolish this system?
E environmental What external constraints does this system take as given?
constraints

These questions are used to define the so-called root definitions of the system. A
different root definition is needed for each perspective. Examples of root definitions
can be found, e.g. in Khisty (1995).

Example 11.1
A hypothetical example of root definition for a situation where the citizens of
a city would like to create a recreation area from a forested area could be as
follows:
C Citizen of the city
A Committee chosen from among the citizen
T Transforming the forest area to a recreation area
W Improved recreation possibilities improve the well-being of all residents
O Committee chosen from among the citizen
E Budget constraints

(continued)
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 265

Example 11.1 (continued)


From the city point of view, the situation could be seen as a possibility to
engage the citizen in the administration:

C City council members


A City staff
T Engaging the citizen more tightly to the city administration
W Improving the citizen activity would improve the mutual understanding and prevent
conflicts
O The city council
E Time, staff and expertise

Organize a
citizen committee
Investigate the different
uses of the area and
using intensity
Inquire
user preferences
for routes

Collect available
GIS information
of the area
Make a plan
for skiing, riding Check costs of the
and cycling routes alternative route
plans

Select alternative

Monitor
operational
Take control
activities Define criteria for action
effectiveness, efficacy,
efficinecy

Fig. 11.4 A hypothetical example of a CM for creating a recreation area with facilities for
different users

In the fourth stage, conceptual models (CM) of systems are built by participants
using these root definitions as a basis. A different system is built for each relevant
world view. Conceptual modelling of the system means assembling the verbs,
describing the activities that should be in the system named in the root definitions
266 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

and structuring the verbs according to logical dependencies (Checkland 2001). For
each system, also a subsystem for monitoring and controlling the system is added. It
means defining criteria for effectiveness (is the proposed action the right thing to
do), efficacy (do the selected means produce intended results) and efficiency (the
ability to do the task without wasting resources) of the system.
The process is carried out in four steps (Checkland 1999):
1. Using verbs in imperative, write down the activities necessary to carry out T in
CATWOE. Aim for 7  2 activities.
2. Select activities which could be done at once.
3. Write those out on a line and then those dependent on these on the line below,
continue in this fashion until all activities are accounted for. Indicate the
dependencies by arrows.
4. Redraw to avoid overlapping arrows where possible. Add monitoring and
control.
In Fig. 11.4, a hypothetical example of a CM from citizen perspective, for
Example 11.1, is presented.
Then, the participants compare the real-world system with these ideal systems
and debate about the changes that are feasible and/or desirable and the actions that
need to be done (Fig. 11.3). The comparison is supposed to reveal the norms,
standards and values among the participants. The idea is that when people compare
the ideal models defined from different perspectives, their own way of perceiving
the world also changes (Checkland 1985). Thus, they are supposed to learn from
each others.
In Example 11.2, a hypothetical example of the SSM methodology for improv-
ing a regional forest policy process is presented.

Example 11.2
Background: In Finland, the Forest Centre (FC) organisation is a forestry
administration body, the duties of which include promoting sustainable
forestry by means of law enforcement, counselling of private forest owners
and participating in the development of regional forest-based economies. A
particular statutory task of the FC is to compile once in 5 years regional forest
programmes for each of the (currently 13) forestry regions incorporating the
main forestry stakeholders.

Step 1: Problem Definition


Problem: The Forest Centre region of Deep Finland (pseudonym) is
claimed to have an inefficient impact on forestry sectors success and
peoples well-being in its region.

(continued)
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 267

Example 11.2 (continued)


History: The Regional Forest Programme of Deep Finland, coordinated by
the FC, has been created in cooperation with regional forest council for the
period 20142018. The process gathered representatives of relevant inter-
est parties to form a comprehensive strategic plan for forest-related issues.
The plan is currently being implemented and monitored, and the new
programme process will begin in 2017.
The owners: The development director of the FCs region (programme
responsible), Secretary General of the National Forest Programme.
The actors: Members of the regional forest council (nominated by the Min-
istry of Agriculture and Forestry), decision-makers and employees of
regional institutions related to forests, forest-related companies and entre-
preneurs as well as forest owners in the region, researchers who act as
consultants in the transformation process.
Internal need and pressure for change: Strategic objective of the FC to
achieve and strengthen the role as an acknowledged expert organisation,
which facilitates the sustainable success of the forest sector in Deep
Finland Region.
External need and pressure for change: Societal needs for legitimacy and
political pressures for more influential regional development and cost-
effective activity. Diversified values of citizens. Agenda for following
all-inclusively the National Forest Programme: Sustainable welfare
from diversified forests.

Step 2: Envisioning
What and where are we now? CATWOE
C client/customer: Citizenry of the region in general, forest owners and
people working within the forest-based sector, in particular, regional
NGOs
A actors: Members of the regional forest council
T transformation process: A series of meetings where alternative futures
are discussed and finally a suitable action strategy is agreed after.
W world view: A constructive and collaborative planning process results in
an outcome which is both desirable and feasible.
O owners: The development director of the FC region (programme respon-
sible), Board of the FC region, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry (Unit
for Forestry Promotion), NGOs that were not invited for participation.
E environmental constraints: Conflicting values, attitudes and interests
among the participants, limited time resource for in-depth discussions,
lack of information on which to base the decisions.

(continued)
268 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Example 11.2 (continued)


Core concept is formulated in the following form: The regional forest
programme has been formulated through a participative process. However,
the process has failed in reaching true collaboration, and thus, commit-
ment to the plan is only partial. The decisions have been based on
inadequate information on peoples (citizens and stakeholders) perspec-
tives. Additionally, the FC lacks tools and money needed for monitoring
and affecting the fulfilment of the plan.
Core vision: What do we want to be in the year 2020? The FC region of Deep
Finland administrates a comprehensive repertoire of tools for collaborative
planning, which contributes to a constructive formulation of the forest
programme, which is desirable and feasible. The programme process
includes a monitoring system, with which the development actions can
be adaptively modified. Thus, both the controllability and transparency of
the programme have been improved, and the FC is publicly regarded as an
effective expert organisation for regional development.

Step 3: Analysis of the Present and Comparison with the Vision


There seems to be a need for experimenting with different alternative collab-
oration methods, studying possible conflicting values regarding desirable
participation methods and, most importantly, establishing a more thorough
programme monitoring system.
The analysis of a subsystem: Programme monitoring system:
C client/customer: The employees of the FC, members of the regional
forest council.
A actors: The same as above, as well as companies and entrepreneurs in the
forest sector in the region, relevant public institutions providing statistics
(e.g. municipalities, environmental administration).
T transformation process: Gathering relevant accumulative information
flow into a special knowledge management system and deciding how to
utilise the system in the meetings of the regional forest council.
W world view: Statistics on activities in forest sector can be monitored in
(almost) real time, and that will help the council to manoeuvre the devel-
opmental activities of the region.
O owners: Companies or entrepreneurs not willing to join the information
exchange scheme, employees of the Forest Centre who might not be ready
for the change in working culture.
E environmental constraints: Inflexibility of public agencies, incompatibil-
ity of information systems in different organisations, time schedule and
functionality of national forest resource data system.

(continued)
11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 269

Example 11.2 (continued)


Core concept of the subsystem year 2014: The information needed in mon-
itoring has been discussed in the meetings of the regional forest council.
Core vision of the subsystem year 2017: The requested information flow has
been piloted and proven successful for contributing the council meetings.
Year 2020: The adaptive monitoring and management scheme is fully func-
tioning as an essential part of the work of the regional forest council.
Analysis of the social system: Members of the current regional forest council
are very interested in the new forms of participating the processes in forest
sector, and they are a bit frustrated because of the slow progress of the
project; the employees of Forest Centre possess some resistance for
change, which brings some tension to the meetings: some consultancy to
talk the issues through is needed.
Analysis of the political system: The ministry pushes strongly to get the new
up-to-date national forest resource data system work: along with new
monitoring-based methods for acquiring and distributing money, the FC
has to overcome its resistance as well as the doubts of losing power with
allowing more open collaborating methods. Simultaneously, the forest
programme is becoming a more legitimate tool for promoting regional
economy among the public.

Step 4: Mission, i.e. Changing the Situation Towards the Direction Stated
in the Core Vision
Next Step 1: The regional forest council establishes a project for enhancing
the process of composing and monitoring the regional forest programme.
Next Step 2: Decision-support researchers study the possible conflicting
values regarding the desirable participation schemes.
Next Step 3: In the light of the study results, the researchers and the council
jointly experiment with different alternative methods for collaborative
planning (e.g. interactive utility analysis, joint gains).
Next Step 4: Based on the experiences and the feedback of the experiments,
guidelines for applying alternative collaboration approaches and methods
in regional forest programme process are formulated.
Next Step 5: The enhanced programme process with guidelines, knowledge of
values and monitoring system is mobilised. The legitimacy and efficiency
of the process increases, and the FC reaches the targeted reputation.
270 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

11.2.4 Strategic Choice Approach (SCA)

Problem structuring towards collaborative decision-making under various uncer-


tainties involves considerations of alternative opportunities in future decision
points. The strategic choice approach (Friend and Hickling 2005, Friend 2011)
offers practical guidelines on how to transform complex uncertain world to a chain
of deliberate actions. The approach rests on the principle of reducing first those
uncertainties that are most prevalent. This strategically made uncertainty reduction
actions are expected to result in better informed decisions.
Aligned with problem structuring philosophy, the SCA enables exploring the
complexity of the planning situation with the aid of visual communication tools.
The approach recognises and offers different response strategies to three main types
of uncertainties, namely, (i) uncertainties about the working environment,
(ii) uncertainties about guiding values and (iii) uncertainties about related decisions
(Friend and Hickling 2005, Fig. 11.5). The uncertainties about the working envi-
ronment may be reduced via technical type of further investigations, such as
desktop research or scenario calculations. The uncertainties about guiding values
may be mitigated via clarifying objectives, e.g. with the aid of stakeholder

Fig. 11.5 The uncertainty areas in SCA


11.2 Problem Structuring Methods 271

Fig. 11.6 The modes in SCA

consultations or value surveys. Adopting a broader view and conducting intersectoral


impact analyses or trade-off assessments, for instance, may in turn reduce the
uncertainties about related decisions. The systematic exploration of these uncertainty
categories enables the group to select which uncertainties to reduce first and how, in
order to know better which choice will be a good one over time.
The SCA includes four working modes: shaping, designing, comparing and
choosing (Fig. 11.6). The group may choose any of those and switch between the
modes, enabling an iterative exploration process. With this procedure, planning is a
communicative process of making choices in a strategic way and with the goodness
of choice after reducing uncertainties as the guiding principle. Like in other
problem structuring processes, the key to success in the SCA is the capabilities of
the facilitator to manage the collaborative knowledge-building efforts.
De Carvalho and Magrini (2006) applied SCA in managing conflicts of water
resource management in Brazil. In their study context, SCA appeared useful
because of the support that it provided to manage the political, administrative and
legal uncertainties. In the shaping mode, the most relevant decision areas
(e.g. water agency, basin plan, allocation of resources and user fees) were
recognised with related uncertainties. Subsequently, a decision graph was compiled
to show the dependencies between choices made in each decision area. In the
272 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

designing mode, mutually exclusive decision options were constructed for each
decision area, and after analysing incompatibilities of choice combinations, an
options table with feasible alternatives was produced. In the comparing mode, a
decision tree was used to assess further the feasibility of choice combinations. In
this phase, comparing areas, i.e. criteria efficacy, cost, fiscal and impact, was
established to aid the comparison and yield a sum of ratings and most feasible
decisions. In the choosing mode, the six most important recognised uncertainties
were elaborated and linked with possible uncertainty reduction actions (e.g. identify
and quantify the environmental demands of the river basins, undertake studies for
an Integrated Committee, ensure legal definition for the Water Agencies). The final
product of the process was a commitment package showing and explaining the
strategic choices made, suggested immediate decisions, postponed decisions and
space for future choices within each decision area. With the aid of this product, the
conflict management process may start all over again with a more strategically
aligned framing.
Franco (2009) presents practical reflections of modified SCA workshops in UK
construction business context. In 5-h facilitated workshops, groups of seven to nine
participants from multi-organisational teams considered the previous project vic-
tories and strategically important decision areas to design a future project. A
pre-workshop questionnaire and related summary suggestions provided cost-
efficiency and meaningful preparation for the workshops. First, in the shaping
mode of SCA, Post-It notes placed and rearranged on a flipchart were used and a
special seating arrangement supported easy and active participation. Both strategic
and operational aspects were discussed, but the latter were more interesting for the
participants. Later on, the participants further developed and prioritised the options
for action, roughly corresponding to the designing and comparing modes of SCA.
Discussion focused on effective immediate actions and included aspects of uncer-
tainties, however, not explicitly assessed in this case. Another comparable use case
of SCA within the same industry (Franco 2009) evidenced participants explicit
wish to focus more on the strategic aspects of designing a new project, possibly due
to the 6 months time since the project evaluated had ended, leaving the operational
concerns on the background.
The reflection of these two cases includes the observation that along with
gaining more experience of SCA, the facilitator was in the second case able to
make clearer distinctions between decision areas, different types of uncertainties
and comparison areas during the discussion (Franco 2009). The participants
evaluation via semi-structured interviews, in turn, revealed that SCA was per-
ceived as a transparent mechanism that help participants understand each other
and, to structure, clarify and learn about the issues within the case. Further, the
participants considered that the openness in SCA enabled them to jointly examine
the issues to reduce manipulative behaviour, and they felt comfortable of
expressing their views and gaining some ownership and commitment during the
workshops (Franco 2009).
11.3 Tools for Eliciting the Public Preferences 273

11.3 Tools for Eliciting the Public Preferences

11.3.1 Surveys

Surveys provide representative information on the population. A random sample of


people is selected and their opinions are asked using a questionnaire. The sample
can also be quite large, so that it is possible to investigate the opinions of larger
number of people than with any other method. In surveys, the questions are usually
structured and therefore easy to analyse quantitatively. On the other hand, this also
means that the questionnaires are rigid.
The response rates in questionnaires are usually quite low (around 4058 %,
Hytonen 2000), and the high rate of nonresponse may cause bias to the results. This
may happen, if some groups respond more than others (e.g. Janse and Konijnendijk
2007). There may also be a trade-off between the length of the questionnaire and the
response rate.
One potential problem with surveys is that the public responding may be
uninterested and uninformed so that their preferences may be based on false
(or nonexistent) information of the consequences of the alternative actions
(e.g. Lauber and Knuth 1998). Thus, the preferences might be different if people
had more information on the subject.
Another potential problem is that the questions asked in surveys may be too
general to provide information that is directly useful for decision-making in a
particular case (e.g. Satterfield and Gregory 1998). For instance, the general
environmental values may seem quite similar among people, but the reactions of
people to an actual planning situation may still vary a lot. Therefore, the results of
surveys can best be used as background information in a certain decision situation
(Hytonen 2000). On the other hand, it is often possible to form the survey specif-
ically for a certain planning situation (e.g. McDaniels and Thomas 1999).
The data presented and the questions used for preference gathering in the
decision support methods may, however, be too difficult for the public to under-
stand (e.g. Heberlein 1976). Moreover, small differences in the wordings may
produce different results.
The information provided along the questions may also influence the public
opinion (e.g. McComas and Scherer 1999). It is possible that those who carry out
the survey may manipulate the information to serve their needs. On the other hand,
it may be that overly positive information may not seem credible to participants.
It has been noted that one-sided positive information had the most persuasive
influence on those people, who already had positive assertions to the plan, and
two-sided balanced information for those persons, who initially opposed the plan
(Hovland et al. 1965). Furthermore, one-sided information had greatest effect on
uneducated people and two-sided to educated people. All in all, information has
least effect when people already have well-formed opinions about the subject
(e.g. McComas and Scherer 1999).
274 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Due to all these problems, Heberlein (1976) argues that opinions of public
gathered through survey may be poor indicators of the true preferences of public.

11.3.2 Public Hearings

In public hearings, it is possible to consider the opinions of smaller groups. In


hearings people typically can express their opinions in a nonstructured way, so that
the questions asked do not affect to the result. This way, they can also provide
information that the organisers have not thought of asking. However, the problem is
that the unstructured responses are much harder to analyse than structured surveys
(for an example, see Hytonen et al. 2002). They need to be analysed using
qualitative procedures, usually by classifying the answers in some way. It may
also be that much of the information received is not useful in the planning process.
For instance, people may state facts concerning the area rather than their
preferences.
As the hearings are not based on sampling, there is no guarantee on how well the
attending group represents the society at large. It may be that the hearing only
reflects the well-known views of well-identified interest groups or that only oppo-
nents of the propositions attend to the meetings (Heberlein 1976). In the worst case,
the public hearings may represent the opinions of those dominating the discussion,
not even the persons in the meeting (Hytonen 2000). The ordinary people attending
to the meeting might not actually participate. It may be very intimidating to present
ones opinion in public, so that the opinions shared in the meetings are those of
experts, people most severely affected by the decisions or people who are not
intimidated by behavioural norms of the meetings (Heberlein 1976). However,
there is also evidence that the opinions gathered with public hearings have been
in most respects similar to the results of the survey (ORiordan 1976).
On the other hand, people attending the hearings are likely to have more
information on the issues than people at large (e.g. Lauber and Knuth 1998).
They may also be more interested on the issues at stake. The difficult question is
how much the opinion of persons, who do not have adequate information and who
are even not interested on it, should be accounted for in the planning.

11.3.3 Location-Specific Preferences

One promising method for public participation surveys is the social values mapping
(Tyrvainen et al. 2007). In this method, the participants are provided a map, and
they assign (predefined) areas with values according to their preferences. The
values may include beautiful sceneries, space and freedom, or peace and tranquil-
lity. This approach is easily comprehended by the public and also provides the
planners spatially located information on the preferences of the public. The
11.4 Decision Support for Group Decision-Making 275

participants could also themselves delineate the areas they value, but this approach
is by far more laborious to the planners (Kangas et al. 2008). In the city of Helsinki,
postal survey responses of peoples favourite places were complemented with GIS
analysis, yielding aggregated map with place-specific perceptions (Tyrvainen
et al. 2007). A comparative approach was used in the urban forest planning in
Lycksele, where stakeholder interviews were used to capture and map place-
specific values and use those in a multi-criteria decision-making process with
evaluation of alternatives (Nordstrom et al. 2011).
Also more straightforward online tools, such as SoftGIS (Rantanen and Kytta
2009), have been used to gather local knowledge to support urban planning. Along
with the development of information and communication technology, public par-
ticipation GIS (PPGIS) applications have been emerging rapidly during the past
decade (Brown and Kytta 2014). The most prevalent research and development
needs of PPGIS relate to how to increase participation rates, improve participation,
control threats of spatial data quality and evaluate the effectiveness of the action,
and one of the key issues is how to integrate PPGIS data into planning decision
support (Brown and Kytta 2014).
In PPGIS, the participants have more freedom in expressing their opinions than
they would have in postal surveys, i.e. more people can answer and it may also be
possible to give the information at any time the participants are in the Internet.
However, a new trend in measuring experiences is that they should be measured at
the moment when they are actually experienced (i.e. EMA the ecological
momentum assessment, Shiffman et al. 2008). That way, the participants may be
able to give more reliable responses, as the experiences and feelings are not
forgotten before they can be expressed. Measuring the opinions at the exact time
and location, when and where they are experienced, is possible by making PPGIS
applications to mobile phones with GPS functions (e.g. Kangas et al. 2015).

11.4 Decision Support for Group Decision-Making

11.4.1 Combined Use of MCA Methods in Group Settings

Decision analysis methods are often useful in a group decision-making or partici-


patory planning context. They force all the decision-makers to systematically
discuss all the important issues (Mustajoki et al. 2011). Without a systematic
analysis, it could be that some issues are addressed several times while other issues
are not covered at all. It may be that people have already made their minds, and
rather than learning from each other, the pros or favoured alternatives and cons of
competing alternatives are repeated over and over again (Dyer and Forman 1992).
Decision analysis methods are usually considered as most useful in fairly small
groups.
276 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

There are two basic possibilities in using MCDM methodology in group


decision-making: (1) to do a combined analysis for all decision-makers at the
same time or (2) to do separate decision analyses for all decision-makers and
then either combine them to obtain priorities of the group or use them as a basis
for negotiation.
Combined decision analysis means that only one analysis is carried out and it is
supposed to capture the preferences of the group as a whole. In principle, for a
combined analysis, the group should have a consensus on every parameter needed
in the analysis, in order to produce meaningful results. Decision-makers should
have, for instance, basically similar objectives.
In AHP, combined analysis means that each pairwise comparison should be
made as a group. If a consensus cannot be reached, a good compromise is required.
In such a case, the individual pairwise judgements can be combined using a
geometric mean of the pairwise comparisons to form one compromise value
(Dyer and Forman 1992). A geometric mean is used instead of arithmetic mean
to preserve the reciprocal property of the pairwise comparisons matrix (Aczel and
Saaty 1983).
In other MCDM methods, the group can, for example, vote to find the appro-
priate judgment. This kind of analysis is possible with any other MCDM method
besides AHP, for instance, with any of the outranking methods or multi-criteria
approval method.
The problem with the combined approach is that it is not possible to show the
effect of each individual in the group on the analysis. It makes it easy for domi-
nating participants to manipulate the results to their liking. Furthermore, the
compromise value obtained by geometric mean or voting may not describe the
preferences of any of the participants. On the other hand, it is possible that decision-
makers commit themselves more readily to a plan made together.
When the analyses are made separately for each decision-maker in a group, it is
possible to explicitly take decision-makers individual preferences into account. If
the separate analyses are combined, it is possible to show explicitly the effect each
member has on the final result. For instance, the correlations between the result with
and without one decision-maker can be analysed (e.g. Vainikainen et al. 2008).
Moreover, even if the analyses were not combined at all, learning more about the
other participants preferences might in itself help in building consensus.
One possibility for doing separate analyses for different decision-makers is to
calculate the mean of priorities (e.g. Forman and Peniwati 1998). This approach is
possible for all decision analysis methods that provide global priorities for the
alternatives. Such methods are, for instance, SMART and AHP. Instead, methods
such as outranking cannot be used this way. In a separate analysis, the decision
models need not to be the same for all decision-makers. For instance, each decision-
maker can include criteria that the other DMs do not consider as important.
Another way to make separate analyses is to include a separate player level to the
analysis (Fig. 11.7). Then, the decision-makers are included as one level in the
11.4 Decision Support for Group Decision-Making 277

Overall goal

Player 1 Player 2 ... Player n

Decision ...
Decision Decision Decision ... Decision
goal 1 goal n goal 1 goal 1 goal n

Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Alternative 3 ... Alternative n

Fig. 11.7 AHP hierarchy including player level

decision hierarchy (Kangas 1994; Pykalainen et al. 1999). Each decision-maker can
also in this case have his/her own decision model. Then, the players can also have
different weights in the analysis, with respect to the size of the group they represent
or years of experience on the matters handled or so on. If all the players have equal
weights, the results of the player-level aggregation and mean of DMs priorities are
also equal. If the players have varying weights, a weighted mean of the priorities
would produce the same results. Thus, the choice between these approaches is
basically a matter of convenience. The selection of weights for the groups is, by no
means, self-evident. Therefore, doing separate analyses for each group and using
them as basis of negotiation may be a good option.
The use of MCDA methods can also be combined to a more general participatory
planning context. The outline for such a situation using AHP is given by Kangas
et al. (2001). The outline (slightly modified) is as follows:
(i) Description of the planning situation.
Preliminary identification of the relevant actors, interests, interested parties
and institutions.
(ii) Detailed identification of the planning problem.
Starting an open participation process with traditional participation means
and information gathering channels. Organising the first open meeting.
Agreement on the need for the planning process with the public. Reproduc-
tion of problem images as stated by different actors and interested parties.
Agreeing upon the rules to be followed if no compromise could be gained in
the process.
278 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

(iii) General formulation of the problem.


Explaining how the decision-making process is intended to be carried out in
the preliminary stage and gaining commitment for the approach; modifying
the approach if necessary. Forming a planning group. The planning group
might include a professional planner, representatives of interested parties and
other individuals. The tasks of the group include working as a link between
all the interests and the organisation responsible of planning, taking part in
the planning work on a voluntary basis and controlling the process.
(iv) Creating decision models.
Each interest within the planning group creates its own decision model with
AHP together with planners. The planner would help to analyse how the
different objectives can be integrated or are in conflict with one another. The
planner together with the members or representatives of the interest parties
can form an optimal solution from their point of view. Planning calculations
are performed for each interest. As background information on the planning
problem, calculations on the areas production possibilities as well as con-
ventional cost-benefit analyses are presented to the participants. All the other
information gained through the participatory process so far is analysed, too,
especially that of qualitative nature. If found appropriate, the decision
models are also derived representing that information mass.
(v) The planning group tries to negotiate a solution.
The planners duty is to present possible compromise solutions and conduct
the negotiations. Planning calculations and their results are interpreted,
justified and applied as background information in the negotiation process.
New calculations, if necessary, are carried out interactively. AHP calcula-
tions are made using their multiparty options with differing weights of the
participants so that participants can see the effects of different weighting
schemes. Assessments are made on how well each interests concerns are
addressed in alternative solutions, and holistic evaluations and conditional
conclusions are carried out. Especially those activities and goals, and their
combinations, are carefully considered, which could not be included in the
AHP calculations.
(vi) Presenting the results of the working group.
The results are presented in an open meeting and in different participation
channels (such as newspapers, internet, open houses, etc.). Gaining feedback
from the public. Also, alternative solutions with probable consequences
might be presented to the public, especially if no initial consensus has been
gained in (v). If a general agreement is achieved, proceed to the next phase.
Otherwise, return to phase (v).
(vii) The planning group agrees on the follow-up procedure.
The planner writes a report including conclusions about the standpoints of
every interest party. The plan is presented widely for the public.
(viii) Control of the actual implementation of the chosen plan, as agreed upon
in (vii).
11.4 Decision Support for Group Decision-Making 279

Assessing the need for continuous planning procedures according to princi-


ples of adaptive planning. Assessing the need for new planning processes.

Example 11.3
Assume three decision-makers who have given their preferences with respect
to net incomes (Example 4.5) using pairwise comparisons. The comparisons
are presented in Table 11.1ac. The single preferences were combined at the
level of single comparisons using the geometric mean (Table 11.2). Then, the
aggregate preferences were used to calculate the aggregate priorities
(Table 11.3). For comparison, the priorities of the single decision-makers
were also calculated from the preferences in n and their arithmetic mean was
calculated. The obtained combined priorities from these two cases are almost
identical, the difference being due to rounding.

Table 11.1 Preferences of the three DM with respect to net incomes


(a)
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1 0.25 0.5 0.5 0.143 0.111
SCEN 4 1 2 2 0.333 0.2
NORM 2 0.5 1 1 0.25 0.143
GAME 2 0.5 1 1 0.2 0.143
MREG 7 3 4 5 1 0.5
INC 9 5 7 7 2 1
(b)
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1 0.5 1 1 0.333 0.25
SCEN 2 1 2 2 0.333 0.25
NORM 1 0.5 1 1 0.25 0.333
GAME 1 0.5 1 1 0.25 0.333
MREG 3 3 4 4 1 0.5
INC 4 4 3 3 2 1
(c)
NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1 2 3 3 0.333 0.25
SCEN 0.5 1 2 2 0.333 0.2
NORM 0.333 0.5 1 1 0.25 0.2
GAME 0.333 0.5 1 1 0.2 0.2
MREG 3 3 4 5 1 0.5
INC 4 5 5 5 2 1

(continued)
280 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Example 11.3 (continued)

Table 11.2 Aggregate preferences


NAT SCEN NORM GAME MREG INC
NAT 1 0.630 1.145 1.145 0.251 0.191
SCEN 1.587 1 2 2 0.333 0.215
NORM 0.874 0.5 1 1 0.25 0.212
GAME 0.874 0.5 1 1 0.215 0.212
MREG 3.979 3 4 4.642 1 0.5
INC 5.241 4.642 4.718 4.718 2 1

Table 11.3 Priorities of the three decision-makers, the arithmetic mean of them and the
priorities based on the aggregate preferences
DM 1 DM 2 DM 3 Mean priority Aggregate priority
NAT 0.036 0.076 0.135 0.082 0.071
SCEN 0.113 0.126 0.088 0.109 0.11
NORM 0.064 0.077 0.056 0.066 0.067
GAME 0.061 0.079 0.054 0.065 0.066
MREG 0.272 0.279 0.265 0.272 0.276
INC 0.455 0.363 0.402 0.407 0.41

11.4.2 Utilising GDSS Software for Distributed Group


Negotiation

While teledemocracy (e.g. Kangas and Store 2003) and public participation GIS
(e.g. Rantanen and Kytta 2009) have improved opportunities to include public
opinions to participatory planning over distance, the software solutions to support
distributed group negotiation have also been under development (e.g. Ackermann
and Eden 1994). However, most hitherto solutions of computerised support to
group decision-making and negotiation in forest planning have concentrated on
showing maps or simulation-optimisation exercise results to participants as illus-
trations to stimulate discussion (Hujala et al. 2013).
One opportunity to add software support to group decision-making processes
(or participatory planning in general) is to conduct media analyses and bring their
results for participants contemplation as one source of framing information or as
seeds for taking perspectives in workshops. For example, Bengston et al. (1999)
made an automated content analysis of some 30 000 online news stories on US
national forests and distinguished four broad categories of values (recreational,
commodity, ecological and moral/spiritual/aesthetic) and yearly trends among
them. According to those authors conclusions, media content analysis may be
effectively used to guide how to shape forest management and policy based on
References 281

changing societal values. This type of analyses, which nowadays can be done also
from user-driven content of social media applications (e.g. Facebook, Twitter), may
complement and partly even replace traditional value surveys in participatory
planning processes (see, e.g. Halpern and Gibbs 2013). An emerging concept,
e-government (see Criado et al. 2013) opens new opportunities to use active online
citizens and citizen groups to provide policy support and design policy innovations,
also in the field of natural resource governance.
Group decision support systems (GDSS) combine computer, communication and
decision support technologies to support problem formulation and solution in group
meetings (Watson et al. 1998). An example of such is the use of CherIng role-play
programme as a facilitation support in context of applying drama theory and com-
panion modelling in a community forest management project in the Philippines
(Campo et al. 2009). The use of MESTA software to offer visual support for multi-
criteria approval exercise in the case of state forest planning in Finland (Hiltunen
et al. 2009) may also been seen as GDSS application. However, GDSS over distance,
i.e. distributed negotiation support or e-negotiation systems (Kersten and Lai 2010)
for participatory forest-planning situations, are still in their early infancy.
Etezadi-Amoli (2010) reviews the various challenges relating to the adoption
and use of e-negotiation systems and recognises that the delicate role of emotions in
negotiation makes it difficult to provide online negotiation tools for wider use.
Evidently, however, along with the evolution of desktop-conferencing systems,
also desktop-negotiating systems become more potential to be used in group
decision-making purposes. Further research needs to recognise this line of devel-
opment and provide case study analyses of distributed GDSS in participatory forest-
planning context.

References

Ackermann, F., & Eden, C. (1994). Issues in computer and non-computer supported GDSSs.
Decision Support Systems, 12, 381390.
Ackermann, F., & Eden, C. (2001). SODA Journey making and mapping in practice. In
J. Rosenhead & J. Mingers (Eds.), Rational analysis for problematic world revisited
(pp. 4360). Chichester: Wiley.
Aczel, J., & Saaty, T. L. (1983). Procedures for synthesizing ratio judgments. Journal of Math-
ematical Psychology, 27, 93102.
Ananda, J., & Herath, G. (2003). The use of analytic hierarchy process to incorporate stakeholder
preferences into regional forest planning. Forest Policy and Economics, 5(1), 1326.
Belton, V., & Stewart, T. J. (2002). Multiple criteria decision analysis: An integrated approach.
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Bengston, D. N., Fan, D. P., & Celarier, D. N. (1999). A new approach to monitoring the social
environment for natural resource management and policy: The case of US national forest
benefits and values. Journal of Environmental Management, 56(3), 181193.
Brown, G., & Kytta, M. (2014). Key issues and research priorities for public participation GIS
(PPGIS): A synthesis based on empirical research. Applied Geography, 46, 122136.
282 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Campo, P. C., Mendoza, G. A., Guizol, P., Villanueva, T. R., & Bousquet, F. (2009). Exploring
management strategies for community-based forests using multi-agent systems: A case study
in Palawan, Philippines. Journal of Environmental Management, 90, 36073615.
Checkland, P. (1981). Systems thinking, systems practice. Chichester: Wiley.
Checkland, P. (1985). From optimizing to learning: A development of systems thinking for the
1990s. Journal of Operations Research Society, 36, 757767.
Checkland, P. (1989). Soft systems methodology. In J. Rosenhead (Ed.), Rational analysis for
problematic world. Chichester: Wiley.
Checkland, P. (1999). Soft systems methodology: A 30-year retrospective. In P. Checkland (Ed.),
Systems thinking, systems practice. Chichester: Wiley.
Checkland, P. (2001). Soft systems methodology. In J. Rosenhead & J. Mingers (Eds.), Rational
analysis for problematic world revisited (pp. 6190). Chichester: Wiley.
Churchman, C. W. (1967). Wicked problems. Management Science, 14, 141142.
Criado, J. I., Sandoval-Almazan, R., & Gil-Garcia, J. R. (2013). Government innovation through
social media. Government Information Quarterly, 30(4), 319326.
De Carvalho, R. C., & Magrini, A. (2006). Conflicts over water resource management in Brazil: A
case study of inter-basin transfers. Water Resource Management, 20(2), 193213.
Drechsler, M., Watzold, F., Johst, K., & Shogren, J. F. (2010). An agglomeration payment for cost-
effective biodiversity conservation in spatially structured landscapes. Resource and Energy
Economics, 32(2), 261275.
Dyer, R. F., & Forman, E. H. (1992). Group decision support with the analytic hierarchy process.
Decision Support Systems, 8, 99124.
Eden, C. (1988). Cognitive mapping. European Journal of Operational Research, 36, 3543.
Eden, C. (1989). Using cognitive mapping for strategic options analysis (SODA). In J. Rosenhead
(Ed.), Rational analysis for problematic world. Chichester: Wiley.
Eden, C. (1990). Strategic thinking with computers. Long Range Planning, 23, 3543.
Eden, C., & Ackermann, F. (1998). Making strategy: The journey of strategic management.
London: Sage Publications.
Eden, C., & Ackermann, F. (2001). SODA The principles. In J. Rosenhead & J. Mingers (Eds.),
Rational analysis for problematic world revisited (pp. 2142). Chichester: Wiley.
Eden, C., & Simpson, P. (1989). SODA and cognitive mapping in practise. In J. Rosenhead (Ed.),
Rational analysis for problematic world. Chichester: Wiley.
Elsasser, P. (2007). Do stakeholders represent citizen interests? An empirical inquiry into
assessments of policy aims in the National Forest Programme for Germany. Forest Policy
and Economics, 9(8), 10181030.
Etezadi-Amoli, J. (2010). The adoption and use of negotiation systems. In D. M. Kilgour &
C. Eden (Eds.), Handbook of group decision and negotiation (Advances in group decision and
negotiation, Vol. 4, pp. 393408). Dordrecht: Springer.
FAO. (1996). Basic principles and operational guidelines. Formulation, execution and revision of
national forestry programmes. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations (FAO).
Forman, E., & Peniwati, K. (1998). Aggregating individual judgments and priorities with the
analytic hierarchy process. European Journal of Operational Research, 108, 165169.
Franco, L. A. (2007). Assessing the impact of problem structuring methods in multi- organiza-
tional settings: An empirical investigation. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 58(6),
760768.
Franco, L. A. (2009). Problem structuring methods as intervention tools: Reflections from their use
with multi-organisational teams. Omega, 37(1), 193203.
Franco, L. A., & Montibeller, G. (2010). Facilitated modelling in operational research. European
Journal of Operational Research, 205(3), 489500.
Friend, J. (2011). The strategic choice approach. In Wiley encyclopedia of operations research and
management science. doi:10.1002/9780470400531.eorms0971.
References 283

Friend, J., & Hickling, A. (2005). Planning under pressure: The strategic choice approach (3rd
ed.). London: Routledge, 387 pp.
Friend, J. K., & Jessop, W. N. (1969). Local government and strategic choice. London: Tavistock.
112 p.
Halpern, D., & Gibbs, J. (2013). Social media as a catalyst for online deliberation? Exploring the
affordances of Facebook and YouTube for political expression. Computers in Human Behav-
ior, 29(3), 11591168.
Heberlein, T. A. (1976). Some observations on alternative mechanisms for public involvement:
The hearing, public opinion poll, the workshop and the quasi-experiment. Natural Resources
Journal, 16, 197212.
Hiltunen, V., Kangas, J., & Pykalainen, J. (2008). Voting methods in strategic forest planning
Experiences from Metsahallitus. Forest Policy and Economics, 10(3), 117127.
Hiltunen, V., Kurttila, M., Leskinen, P., Pasanen, K., & Pykalainen, J. (2009). Mesta: An internet-
based decision-support application for participatory strategic-level natural resources planning.
Forest Policy and Economics, 11(1), 19.
Hjorts, N. C. (2004). Enhancing public participation in natural resource management using Soft
OR An application of strategic option development and analysis in tactical forest planning.
European Journal of Operational Research, 152, 667683.
Hogl, K., Kvarda, E., Nordbeck, R., & Pregernig, M. (2012). Legitimacy and effectiveness of
environmental governance Concepts and perspectives. In K. Hogl, E. Kvarda, R. Nordbeck,
& M. Pregernig (Eds.), Environmental governance: The challenge of legitimacy and effective-
ness (pp. 126). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Hovland, C. I., Lumsdaine, A. A., & Sheffield, F. D. (1965). Experiences on mass communication.
New York: Wiley.
Hujala, T., & Kurttila, M. (2010). Facilitated group decision making in hierarchical contexts. In
D. M. Kilgour & C. Eden (Eds.), Handbook of group decision and negotiation (Advances in
group decision and negotiation, Vol. 4, pp. 325337). Dordrecht: Springer.
Hujala, T., Khadka, C., Wolfslehner, B., & Vacik, H. (2013). Supporting problem structuring with
computer-based tools in participatory forest planning. Forest Systems, 22(2), 270281.
Hytonen, L. A. (2000). Osallistamismenetelmat metsatalouden paat oksenteossa. Metsatieteen
aikakauskirja, 3(2000), 443456.
Hytonen, L. A., Leskinen, P., & Store, R. (2002). A spatial approach to participatory planning in
forestry decision making. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 17, 6271.
Janse, G., & Konijnendijk, C. C. (2007). Communication between science, policy and citizens in
public participation in urban forestry Experiences from the neighborwoods project. Urban
Forestry and Urban Greening, 6, 2340.
Jumppanen, J., Kurttila, M., Pukkala, T., & Uuttera, J. (2003). Spatial harvest scheduling approach
for areas involving multiple ownership. Forest Policy and Economics, 5(1), 2738.
Kangas, J. (1994). An approach to public participation in strategic forest management planning.
Forest Ecology and Management, 70, 7588.
Kangas, J., & Store, R. (2003). Internet and teledemocracy in participatory planning of natural
resource management. Landscape and Urban Planning, 62, 89101.
Kangas, J., Loikkanen, T., Pukkala, T., & Pykalainen, J. (1996). A participatory approach to
tactical forest planning (Acta forestalia Fennica, Vol. 251). Helsinki: The Finnish Society of
Forest Science. 24 p.
Kangas, J., Hytonen, L., & Loikkanen, T. (2001). Integrating the AHP and HERO into the process
of participatory natural resources planning. In D. Schmoldt, J. Kangas, G. A. Mendoza, &
M. Pesonen (Eds.), The analytic hierarchy process in natural resource and environmental
decision making (Managing forest ecosystems, Vol. 3, pp. 187197). Dordrecht: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Kangas, A., Haapakoski, R., & Tyrvainen, L. (2008). Integrating place-specific social values into
forest planning Case of UPM-Kymmene forests in Hyrynsalmi, Finland. Silva Fennica, 42,
773790.
284 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Kangas, A., Saarinen, N., Saarikoski, H., Leskinen, L. A., Hujala, T., & Tikkanen, J. (2010).
Stakeholder perspectives about proper participation for Regional Forest Programmes. Forest
Policy and Economics, 12, 213222.
Kangas, A., Heikkila, J., Malmivaara-Lamsa, M., & Lofstr
om, I. (2014a). Case PuijoEvaluation
of a participatory urban forest planning process. Forest Policy and Economics, 45, 1323.
Kangas, A., Nurmi, M., & Rasinmaki, J. (2014b). From strategic plan to a tactical plan using
hierarchic optimization. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29, 154165.
Kangas, A., Rasinmaki, J., Eyvindson, K., & Chambers, P. (2015). A mobile phone application
for the collection of opinion data for forest planning purposes. Environmental Management,
55, 961971.
Kelly, G. A. (1955). The psychology of personal constructs (Vol 1 and 2). New York: Norton.
Kersten, G., & Lai, H. (2010). Electronic negotiations: Foundations, systems, and processes. In
D. M. Kilgour & C. Eden (Eds.), Handbook of group decision and negotiation (Advances in
group decision and negotiation, Vol. 4, pp. 361392). Dordrecht: Springer.
Khadka, C., Hujala, T., Wolfslehner, B., & Vacik, H. (2013). Problem structuring in participatory
forest planning. Forest Policy and Economics, 26(1), 111.
Khisty, J. (1995). Soft systems methodology as learning and management tool. Journal of Urban
Planning and Development, 121, 91107.
Kouplevatskaya-Yunusova, I., & Buttound, G. (2006). Assessment of an iterative process: The
double spiral of re-designing participation. Forest Policy and Economics, 8, 529541.
Kurttila, M. (2001). The spatial structure of forests in the optimization calculations of forest
planning A landscape ecological perspective. Forest Ecology and Management, 142(1-3),
129142.
Kurttila, M., Heinonen, T., Hujala, T., Kangas, A., Nuutinen, T., Pukkala, T., Pykalainen, J.,
Rasinmaki, J., & Tikkanen, J. (2014). The use of forest decision support systems in Finland. In
J. G. Borges, E.-M. Nordstr om, J. Garcia-Gonzalo, T. Hujala, & A. Trasobares (Eds.),
Computer-based tools for supporting forest management. The experience and the expertise
world-wide (pp. 116133). Sweden: Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences.
Laamanen, R., & Kangas, A. (2011). Large scale forest owners information needs in operational
planning of timber harvesting Some practical views in Metsahallitus, Finnish state owned
enterprise. Silva Fennica, 4, 711727.
Lauber, B. T., & Knuth, B. A. (1998). Refining our vision of citizen participation: Lessons from a
moose reintroduction project. Society and Natural Resources, 11, 411424.
Lawrence, R. L., Daniels, S. E., & Stankey, G. H. (1997). Procedural justice and public involve-
ment in natural resource decision making. Society & Natural Resources, 10(6), 577589.
Leskinen, L. A. (2004). Purposes and challenges of public participation in regional and local
forestry in Finland. Forest Policy and Economics, 6(6), 605618.
Liss, B. -M. (1999). National Forest Programmes. Concept for a Policy and Planning Framework
towards Sustainable Forest Management. GTZ/TWRP. 9 pp.
Martins, H., & Borges, J. (2007). Addressing collaborative planning methods and tools in forest
management. Forest Ecology and Management, 248(12), 107118.
McComas, K. A., & Scherer, C. W. (1999). Providing balanced risk information in surveys used as
citizen participation mechanisms. Society and Natural Resources, 12, 107119.
McDaniels, T. L., & Thomas, K. (1999). Eliciting preferences for land use alternatives: A
structured value referendum with approval voting. Journal of Policy Analysis and Manage-
ment, 18, 264280.
Mendoza, G. A., & Prabhu, R. (2003). Qualitative multi-criteria approaches to assessing indicators
of sustainable forest resource management. Forest Ecology and Management, 174, 329343.
Mingers, J., & Rosenhead, J. (2004). Problem structuring methods in action. European Journal of
Operational Research, 152, 530554.
Mingers, J., & Rosenhead, J. (2011). Introduction to the special issue: Teaching soft O.R., problem
structuring methods, and multimethodology. INFORMS Transactions on Education, 12(1),
13.
References 285

Mustajoki, H., Saarikoski, H., Marttunen, M., Ahtikoski, A., Hallikainen, V., Helle, T., Hypp onen,
M., Jokinen, M., Naskali, A., Tuulentie, S., Varmola, M., Vatanen, E., & Ylisirni o, A. L.
(2011). Use of decision analysis interviews to support the sustainable use of the forests in
Finnish Upper Lapland. Journal of Environmental Management, 92, 15501563.
Niskanen, A., & Vayrynen, J. (1999). Regional forest programmes: A participatory approach to
support forest based regional development (EFI proceedings, Vol. 32). Torikatu: European
Forest Institute. 236 pp.
Nordstrom, E.-M., Eriksson, L. O., & O hman, K. (2010). Integrating multiple criteria decision
analysis in participatory forest planning: Experience from a case study in northern Sweden.
Forest Policy and Economics, 12(8), 562574.
Nordstrom, E.-M., Eriksson, L. O., & O hman, K. (2011). Multiple criteria decision analysis with
consideration to place-specific values in participatory forest planning. Silva Fennica, 45(2),
253265.
ORiordan, J. (1976). The public involvement program in the Okangan basin study. In A. E. Utton,
W. R. D. Sewell, & T. ORiordan (Eds.), Natural resources for a democratic society: public
participation in decision-making. Boulder: Westview.
Pregernig, M., & Br ocher, M. (2013). The role of expertise in environmental governance.
Theoretical perspectives and empirical evidence. In B. Siebenhuner, M. Arnold,
K. Eisenack, & K. Jacob (Eds.), Long-term governance for social-ecological change
(pp. 2946). New York: Routledge.
Primmer, E. (2011). Policy, project and operational networks: Channels and conduits for learning
in forest biodiversity conservation. Forest Policy and Economics, 13, 132142.
Primmer, E., & Kyll onen, S. (2006). Goals for public participation implied by sustainable
development, and the preparatory process of the Finnish National Forest Programme. Forest
Policy and Economics, 8(8), 838853.
Pulzl, H., & Rametsteiner, E. (2002). Grounding international modes of governance into National
Forest Programmes. Forest Policy and Economics, 4(4), 259268.
Pykalainen, J., Kangas, J., & Loikkanen, T. (1999). Interactive decision analysis in participatory
strategic forest planning: Experiences from State owned boreal forests. Journal of Forest
Economics, 5, 341364.
Pykalainen, J., Hiltunen, V., & Leskinen, P. (2007). Complementary use of voting methods and
interactive utility analysis in participatory strategic forest planning: Experiences gained from
western Finland. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 37(5), 853865.
Rantanen, H., & Kytta, M. (2009). The SoftGIS approach to local knowledge. Journal of
Environmental Management, 90(6), 19811990.
Reed, M. S., Moxey, A., Prager, K., Hanley, N., Skates, J., Bonn, A., Evans, C. D., Glenki, K., &
Thomson, K. (2014). Improving the link between payments and the provision of ecosystem
services in agri-environment schemes. Ecosystem Services, 9, 4453.
Rickenbach, M., Schulte, L. A., Kittredge, D. B., Labich, W. G., & Shinneman, D. J. (2011).
Cross-boundary cooperation: A mechanism for sustaining ecosystem services from private
lands. Journal of Soil and Water Conservation, 66(4), 91A96A.
Rosenhead, J. (Ed.). (1989). Rational analysis for problematic world. Chichester: Wiley.
Rouwette, E. A. J. A., Vennix, J. A. M., & Felling, A. J. A. (2009). On evaluating the performance
of problem structuring methods: An attempt at formulating a conceptual model. Group
Decision and Negotiation, 18(6), 567587.
Saarikoski, H., Tikkanen, J., & Leskinen, L. A. (2010). Public participation in practice
Assessing public participation in the preparation of regional forest programs in Northern
Finland. Forest Policy and Economics, 12(5), 349356.
Saarikoski, H., kerman, M., & Primmer, E. (2013). The challenge of governance in regional
forest planning: An analysis of participatory forest program processes in Finland. Society &
Natural Resources, 25(7), 667682.
Sarvasova, Z., Dobsinska, Z., & Salka, J. (2014). Public participation in sustainable forestry: The
case of forest planning in Slovakia. iForest Biogeosciences and Forestry, 7, 414422.
Satterfield, T., & Gregory, R. (1998). Reconciling environmental values and pragmatic choices.
Society and Natural Resources, 11, 629647.
286 11 Participatory Planning Processes in Action

Shiffman, S., Stone, A. A., & Hufford, M. R. (2008). Ecological momentary assessment. Annual
Review of Clinical Psychology, 4, 132.
Tikkanen, J., & Kurttila, M. (2007). Participatory and regional approach on forest planning.
Present state and an ideal model for private land in Finland. In H. Makinen (Ed.), Enhancing
training on collaborative planning of natural resources management (Reports of Finnish
Environment Institute, Vol. 26, pp. 112122).
Tyrvainen, L., Makinen, K., & Schipperijn, J. (2007). Tools for mapping social values of urban
woodlands and other green areas. Landscape and Urban Planning, 79, 519.
Vacik, H., Kurttila, M., Hujala, T., Khadka, C., Haara, A., Pykalainen, J., Honkakoski, P.,
Wolfslehner, B., & Tikkanen, J. (2014). Evaluating collaborative planning methods supporting
programme-based planning in natural resource management. Journal of Environmental Man-
agement, 144, 304315.
Vainikainen, N., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2008). Empirical study on voting power in participa-
tory forest planning. Journal of Environmental Management, 88, 173180.
Watson, R. T., DeSanctis, G., & Poole, M. S. (1998). Using a GDSS to facilitate group consensus:
Some intended and unintended consequences. MIS Quarterly, 12(3), 463478.
White, L. (2006). Evaluating problem-structuring methods: Developing an approach to show the
value and effectiveness of PSMs. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 57(7),
842855.
Winkel, G., & Sotirov, M. (2011). An obituary for national forest programmes? Analyzing and
learning from the strategic use of new modes of governance in Germany and Bulgaria.
Forest Policy and Economics, 13, 143154.
Part V
Behavioral Viewpoints
Chapter 12
Behavioural Aspects

Abstract Decision support tools are often criticised from the point of view that
people are typically not maximising their utility as normative decision theory
expects but rather following rules. We discuss the approaches that describe decision
analysis from the behavioural point of view and emphasise that while people
without aid do not necessarily maximise their utility, they might make better
(i.e. closer to the maximum utility) decisions when aided. Decision support based
on the image theory is presented as one possible solution in combining the
behavioural and decision aid viewpoints. In addition, the chapter introduces some
most prevalent biases and distortions (e.g. framing effect, groupthink) that may
appear and ought to be mitigated in participatory and group decision-making
settings.

12.1 Criticism Towards Decision Theory

12.1.1 Outline

Ever since the first publications of decision theory based on maximising utility,
there have also been researchers criticising the theory. There have been arguments
whether people actually do maximise utility in decision-making or are they simply
aiming at satisfactory decisions. Similarly, there have been arguments concerning
whether people just follow heuristic rules in their decision-making or do they
behave rationally (e.g. Janis and Mann 1977; March 1994). As a connecting concept
between the rationality assumptions and their criticism, bounded rationality (Simon
et al. 1992) retains the assumption of a general pursuit for rationality but acknowl-
edges various reasons for not being able to act fully rationally and thus selecting
other strategies to manoeuvre with choices in the complex world.
Furthermore, the decision-makers having modern planning tools available have
not always found them useful in real problems (Kasanen et al. 2000). This may
partly be due to problems with interpretation of the results from MCDM. Partly the
problem may be that insufficient emphasis has been put in decision aid on important
aspects such as structuring the problem and creating choice alternatives. As a result
of that, the decision support may have suffered from a falsely aligned focus or a lack
of concrete and helpful decision suggestions, and in this sense the criticism has been

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 289


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_12
290 12 Behavioural Aspects

justified. This indicates that decision aid methods need to be developed also from
behavioural point of view. Some research efforts have recently been made in order
to provide forest planners with tools and approaches for more meaningful decision
support in practical processes (e.g. De Meo et al. 2013; Hujala et al. 2013; Haara
et al. 2014). These pieces of work target in particular the above challenges of
problem structuring and delivery of forest plan alternatives in participative or
interactive planning situations.
One reason for not perceiving decision support useful may be the decision cost:
making calculations and using planning procedures cost money, time and energy
(Pingle and Day 1996). Even when planning procedures produce better decisions,
the improvement also has to be large enough to cover this cost in order to make
planning calculations worthwhile. This line of thought has led decision scientists to
consider the cost-effectiveness of the new information via analysing the value of
information (e.g. Birchler and Butler 2007), which has also been transferred to the
forest inventory and planning context (Kangas 2010; Makinen et al. 2012). One
may presume that a similar type of cost-effectiveness assessment takes place in
everyday decision-making of individuals or in the practical choices that private land
owners make: they economise their behaviour (see Pingle and Day 1996) with, for
example, following an authority (e.g. Hujala et al. 2007), adopting a peer advice or
creating decision rules or heuristic choice strategies that yield reasonable good
decisions with reasonably low costs or efforts. This does not necessarily mean
non-rational behaviour: the heuristic choice may be sufficiently close to an optimal
one when taking into account the planning costs, albeit usually with very high
uncertainties involved.
Partly the criticism towards the decision theory may be due to misunderstand-
ings concerning the aims of the theory or the practice it is supposed to serve. For
instance, French (1989) says:
How often have I heard decision analysis berated because it supposedly applies simplistic
ideas to complex problems, usurping decision makers and prescribing choice!
Yet I believe it does nothing of the sort. I believe that decision analysis is very delicate,
subtle tool that helps decision makers explore and come to understand their beliefs and
preferences in the context of the particular problem that faces them. Moreover, the
language and formalism of decision analysis facilitates communication between decision
makers. Through their greater understanding of the problem and the others view of the
problem, the decision makers are able to make a better informed choice. There is no
prescription: only the provision of a framework in which to think and communicate.

Although part of the criticism may be unjustified, there still are problems that
should be tackled when decision analysis is further developed. The decisions people
actually do are often choices between two alternatives: status quo or a change of
some sort. For instance, people decide to harvest a stand or not to harvest a stand.
The decisions are also sequential: one small decision after another small decision is
made, rather than solving big complex problems and so on (Beach and Mitchell
1987, 1990). Lindblom (1959), for instance, discusses incremental decisions.
12.1 Criticism Towards Decision Theory 291

12.1.2 Satisficing or Maximising?

When it is studied how people really make their decisions without the help of
decision aid, it can be noted that the decisions have characteristics of satisficing
rather than maximising (e.g. March 1994). For instance, when deciding about a new
person in an enterprise, the decision-maker is said to be maximising his utility, if he
wants to hire the best person likely to be found, and satisficing, if he wants just to
hire a person that meets the standards given.
It is clear that in real decision-making, it is hardly ever possible to go through all
the possible alternatives. In many everyday decisions it is not sensible to go through
even a few alternatives. It is also never possible to know for sure all the conse-
quences of the decisions made. From this respect, every decision is made in a
satisficing fashion, as it can never be guaranteed that no better alternative is
available.
On the other hand, it is hard to believe that people would be satisficing in a sense
that they would select an alternative just fulfilling the given requirements, if they
know a better option is available. For instance, how many decision-makers would
hire a person they know will do in a job, if they knew that a superior alternative
exists? In this respect, every decision is made in a maximising fashion, given the
knowledge available.
In experiments it has been noted that people actually tend to do better decisions
if they know what is possible to attain, which gives support to this claim (MacLeod
and Pingle 2005). On the other hand, this behaviour can also be explained from
satisficing point of view: the level decision-makers is satisfied with, the aspiration
level, rises based on what is attainable and what other people have attained
(Wierzbicki 1982; Oechssler 2002).
There has been a passionate debate concerning whether people satisfice or
maximise in the last 50 years, starting from Simons famous papers (1955, 1957).
However, the debate is pointless from the decision aid point of view. It is not
important how the people do their decisions unaided, what is important is whether
they can do better when aided.
It is, however, possible that decision-making has both satisficing and
maximising characteristics. According to March (1994), most decisions include
some elements of satisficing, but it is rarely found in its pure form. It seems quite
possible that a person first screens the alternatives available and leaves out every
alternative that does not fulfil the standards and selects the best alternative from
among those alternatives that do. This is also what is assumed in the image theory
(Beach and Mitchell 1987, 1990). If people really do make decisions this way, it
may be useful to acknowledge this also in developing decision aid. This would
mean developing decision support methods that first provide aid for the screening
phase and after that assist the decision-maker in the choice phase.
292 12 Behavioural Aspects

12.1.3 Rules or Rational Behaviour?

When making decisions without aid, people often follow rules. The decision-
makers can ask themselves (March 1994):
1. What kind of situation is this? (The question of recognition)
2. What kind of person am I? What kind of organisation is this? (The question of
identity)
3. What does a person such as I, or an organisation such as this, do in a situation
such as this? (The question of rules)
The identities and rules, on the other hand, are shaped by the social roles of the
decision-makers, by culture and norms. The rules are also shaped by past experi-
ences: certain actions lead to certain outcomes, and these are used to formulate
decision rules and strategies (Einhorn 1982). When a certain strategy has yielded
good results in earlier decisions, the same strategy is also used in future decisions.
According to March (1994), rules formulate through several processes:
1. Analysis, through the anticipation and evaluation of future consequences by
intentional decision-makers
2. Bargaining, through negotiation, conflict and compromise among decision-
makers having inconsistent preferences and identities
3. Imitation, though copying of rules practices and forms used by others
4. Selection, through differential birth and survival rates of unchanging rules and
the decision-making units using them
5. Learning, through experience-based changes of routines and of the ways rou-
tines are used
It has also been widely argued if people follow heuristic rules or if they make their
decisions rationally by maximising utility. The decisions can be explained from
both perspectives. For those who favour the rule idea, maximising utility is just one
learned rule among others. For those favouring the idea of rational behaviour, rules
are just constraints derived from rational action at a higher level (March 1994). In
each decision, both aspects can often be seen. From the decision aid point of view,
also this discussion is fruitless, unless understanding the rules people use somehow
helps to develop decision aid tools.

12.2 Image Theory

Image theory is a descriptive theory on decision-making, but it can also be used in


decision aid. Image theory is based on four types of images: self-image, trajectory
image, action image and projected image.
The self-image consists of the personal beliefs, basic values, morals and ethics of
a person (Beach and Mitchell 1987). The self-image is shown in the principles a
12.2 Image Theory 293

person uses in his decision-making, in goals they adopt, and to audit possible
actions. When the decision-maker is an organisation, self-image consists of the
organisations principles, which the individual decision-maker may or may not
share but which they usually regard as imperatives of the organisation (Beach
and Mitchell 1990).
The trajectory image consists of goals the decision-maker has set concerning the
future (Beach and Mitchell 1987). The goals may be concrete, such as obtaining a
certain job, or an abstract state, like improving ones skills in languages. Action
images are plans that the decision-maker has for achieving the goals. The plans
form a sequence that is meant to bring about progress towards a goal. The plan
consists of tactics, the concrete actions with which the plan can be implemented
(Fig. 12.1). The sequence of tactics may include clear actions, actions that have to
be executed at the same time (1 and 2) or tactics that are alternative ways (3 and 4).
To be adopted, a candidate plan must be compatible with the self-image and also
provide means for achieving the goals.
The projected image represents the anticipated future, if (1) the decision-maker
adopts a certain plan or (2) if he continues with the plans that are currently being
implemented. This anticipated future is then compared to the trajectory image or
the goals of the decision-maker. The projected image of the plan currently
implemented also enables the decision-maker to evaluate the progress made so far.
According to image theory, there are two kinds of decisions: adoption decisions
and progress decisions (Beach and Mitchell 1987). In adoption decision, candidates
for plans (or goals) are either adopted or rejected. An adoption decision requires
that the candidate plan is at least compatible with the images. Progress decisions are
made to decide whether to continue implementing a plan, if the compatibility of the
projected image and trajectory image is not good. It means that if a plan does not
seem to help in achieving the goals, it is first rejected and then a new plan is
adopted.
The planning situation itself can be divided to two phases: screening and choice
(Beach and Mitchell 1987). In the screening phase, alternatives that violate the self-
image are rejected, as well as such plans where the projection image violates the
trajectory image. This is done using a so-called compatibility test. In the choice
phase, the profitability of the remaining candidate alternatives is compared and the
best alternative is chosen (Fig. 12.2).
The screening phase is non-compensatory, i.e. alternatives that fail in one
respect may be rejected, even if they are very good in other respects. Screening
may be based on gut feeling: a certain alternative just does not feel right. The
compatibility is measured with rejection thresholds (Beach and Mitchell 1987).
Formally, the rejection threshold can be expressed as a weighted index of violations

X
n X
m
I W p V t p , V t p 2 f0; 1g 12:1
t1 p1
294 12 Behavioural Aspects

PLAN

T1 T3

Start Goal
T and T or T
implementation attainment
T2 T4

Fig. 12.1 A hypothetical plan with its component tactics (Modified from Beach and Mitchell
1987)

Several suitable Choice


alternatives Profitability
test

Alternatives Screening One suitable


Compatibility alternative
and test
criteria
No suitable
Decision
alternatives

Search for new alternatives


Reduce the rejection threshold

Fig. 12.2 Decision-making process with image theory (Turunen 2003)

where Wp is the weight of principle p and Vtp is an indicator variable having value
1 if a certain tactics t in the plan violates the principle p and 0 otherwise. Then, a
threshold value for I needs to be decided. It may mean, for instance, that all forest
plans that do not provide sufficient incomes are rejected, if the incomes have a large
weight. Instead, a violation in the target number of game animals may not cause
rejection of the whole plan, if the weight is sufficiently low. Of course, if I 0, no
violations at all are allowed. Thus, deciding the rejection threshold is very impor-
tant, but it may also be very difficult for a decision-maker. This phase represents the
satisficing part of image theory.
The choice part, on the other hand, is compensatory, so that good score in one
respect can compensate a not-so-good score in another. This part can be carried out
with usual decision support methods.
12.3 Biases and Distortions in Decision Support Situations 295

Example 12.1
Assume that in the example of 4.6, incomes should be at least 10,000 and the
stumpage value of timber at the end of the period should be at least 200,000.
Assume as well that the rejection threshold is 0 so that no violations are allowed.
In this case, two alternatives are rejected in the screening phase: the NAT
and INC alternatives, due to violations from the targets. The rejected alter-
natives are stroke through (Table 12.1).
In the choice phase, the remaining alternatives are compared using addi-
tive utility function. The values in the natural scale are transformed to utility
scale by with Eq. (3.4). The global priority is then calculated using equal
weights (0.33) for each criterion. The results are presented in Table 12.2. The
best alternative in this case is MREG alternative.
Table 12.1 Results from the Net Stumpage Scenic
screening phase incomes value beauty
NAT 0.00 0.71 5.5
SCEN 79.6 0.28 5.7
NORM 38.0 0.60 5.4
GAME 33.0 0.61 5.5
MREG 102.3 0.51 5.2
INC 191.7 0.13 4.9

Table 12.2 Local and global priorities of the remaining alternatives


Net incomes Stumpage value Scenic Beauty Global priority
SCEN 0.78 0.46 1.00 0.74
NORM 0.37 0.98 0.95 0.76
GAME 0.32 1.00 0.96 0.75
MREG 1.00 0.84 0.91 0.91

12.3 Biases and Distortions in Decision Support Situations

Peoples experiences and perceptions of the world surrounding them may be biased
in many ways. People, for example, interpret probabilities quite differently than the
laws of probability dictate (Tversky and Kahneman 1982). For instance, people
may think that when tossing a coin for heads and tails, a sequence H-T-H-T-T-H is
more likely than the sequence H-H-H-T-T-T (which does not appear random) or
sequence H-H-H-H-T-H (in which the coin does not seem fair).
Biases may also be due to availability of data (Tversky and Kahneman 1982).
For instance, it may be that people assess the risk of damages in forest based on how
often it has happened in their own or in their acquaintances forests. Biases may
also be due to anchoring to initial estimates (Tversky and Kahneman 1982). For
instance, if people are given a number and asked to adjust it upwards or downwards
to assess some value (like the percentage of unemployed people), they give the
296 12 Behavioural Aspects

higher values the higher the initial value is. Anchoring also contains a scale
adjustment effect: for example, a reasonable price level for any product in ones
mind may rise or fall significantly based on what product segment has been recently
been under contemplation.
The other cognitive biases that may be relevant in forest planning context
include, with suggested strategies to be tackled in practical decision support, for
example:
Choice-supportive bias: the past decisions are remembered better than they
actually were (suggestion: place critical view on past experiences when explor-
ing future alternatives).
Confirmation bias: the preconceptions are strengthened with selective attention
and selective interpretation (suggestion: decompose the preconceptions and
challenge them with evidence and logical reasoning).
Denomination effect: altogether more money is spent if used in small amounts
instead of paying one bill (suggestion: consider all costs in the planning period
and provide an overall view for the decision-maker).
Framing effect: coming to different interpretations based on how the information
is presented (suggestion: pay attention to neutrality of presenting the informa-
tion, and favour multiple ways of illustrations and information delivery
perspectives).
Hyperbolic discounting: overfavouring immediate benefits in an inconsistent
way over time (suggestion: consider using mind games to force the decision-
maker to assess their present and future choices from the present and predicted
future points of time).
Loss aversion: trying to avoid losses more than to acquire gains (suggestion:
consider all gains and losses for the whole planning period in a unified frame-
work and present the overall view).
Status quo bias: favouring actions and practices as they have been before
(suggestion: when proposing something new, invest on comprehensive justifi-
cations and risk analyses; present also the risks that are related to not changing
anything).
Such biases may affect the rules by which the decisions are made. They also may
have an effect on the results obtained from decision analysis. Such are the cases
analysed in prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky 1979). In experiments it has
been examined how people make their decision when facing a risky situation.
Usually it has been assumed that people tend to maximise expected utility,
i.e. most of the people obey this norm most of the time. In the answers given,
however, several types of deviations from this theory have been noted. Kahneman
and Tversky (1979) presented three deviations, which they named to be certainty
effect, reflection effect and isolation effect.
The certainty effect means that people tend to overweight (compared to
maximising expected utility) such outcomes that are certain, compared to outcomes
that are merely probable (Kahneman and Tversky 1979). For example, if people
have to choose from two prospects, A and B, where A includes probable incomes
and B certain incomes, 80 % chose alternative B although the expected utility EU of
12.3 Biases and Distortions in Decision Support Situations 297

A is 0.84000 3200, i.e. greater than 3000 in B. On the other hand, when people
had to choose from prospects C and D, in which the probability of winning was one
fourth of that in prospects A and B, the results were opposite. This result indicates
that reducing the winning probability from certain to probable (from 1 to 0.25)
reduces the utility more than reduction from probable to less probable (from 0.8 to
0.2). Over half of the people participating in the experiment violated the expected
utility theory.

Prospect A B
4000 with probability 0.8 3000 with certainty
0 with probability 0.2
EU 3200 3000
Choice percentages 20 80

Prospect C D
4000 with probability 0.20 3000 with probability 0.25
0 with probability 0.80 0 with probability 0.75
EU 800 750
Choice percentages 65 35

If, instead of winnings, losses are considered, the situation is different. If the
winnings in the example above are changed to losses, people choose prospect A in
92 % of cases, although the expected loss is greater than in prospect B, but prospect
D rather than C. It means that people tend to avoid certain losses and are ready to
gamble with even bigger losses in order to avoid them (Kahneman and Tversky
1979). The result with negative prospects is the mirror image of those with positive
prospects. This effect is called reflection effect.

Prospect A B
4000 with probability 0.8 3000 with certainty
0 with probability 0.2
EU 3200 3000
Choice percentages 92 8

Prospect C D
4000 with probability 0.20 3000 with probability 0.25
0 with probability 0.80 0 with probability 0.75
EU 800 750
Choice percentages 42 58

Isolation effect means that if there are identical parts in prospects, they are
discarded from the analysis, and the focus in on the part that distinguish two
prospects (Kahneman and Tversky 1979). This may, however, lead to inconsistent
preferences because the problems can be decomposed in several ways.
298 12 Behavioural Aspects

Assume a two-stage game. In the first stage, there is a 0.75 probability to end the
game without winning anything and a 0.25 probability to move to second stage. In
the second stage, the choice is between winning 4000 with probability 0.8 or
winning 3000 with certainty. The choice has to be made before the first stage. In
this game, the choice is really between 0.250.80 0.2 probability of winning 4000
(EU 800) and 0.25 probability of winning 3000 (EU 750). Yet, 78 % of people
chose the second alternative with smaller EU. This is because the first stage was not
considered in the choice.
These phenomena form the basis for prospect theory. In prospect theory, the
choice process is divided to two phases: editing and evaluating. In the editing phase,
the prospects are simplified. The editing can include several different operations.
First, as people react differently to gains and losses, the prospects are presented as
gains and losses with respect to a reference point (current assets). Prospects can
sometimes also be simplified by combining probabilities with identical outcomes. It
is also often possible to segregate the certain gains and losses from uncertain ones.
For instance, if prospect is such that the decision-maker obtains 300 with proba-
bility 0.8 and 200 with probability 0.2, it can be simplified so that the decision-
maker gets 200 certainly and 100 more with probability 0.8. Similarly, in a prospect
where the decision-maker loses 400 with probability 0.6 and 100 with probability
0.4, the loss of 100 is certain, and in addition, the decision-maker can lose 300 with
probability 0.6. In the editing phase, also very unlikely outcomes are ignored and
the probabilities are rounded. This editing is not, however, without problems:
performing several editing tasks in different orders may result in different prospects
(Kahneman and Tversky 1979).
In the choice phase, the decision-making situation under risk is described so that
the probabilities of each given outcome is weighted using a subjective weight, in
order to reflect the impact of the probability on the overall value of the prospect.
The possible outcomes are also weighted according to their subjective values,
measuring the value of the outcomes compared to a reference point. Losses and
gains are treated separately and can have different subjective values. It is assumed
that with respect to losses, the utility function is convex (i.e. utility function of a risk
seeker), and with respect to gains the function is concave (i.e. utility function of a
risk avoider) (Fig. 12.3). It is also typical that the function is clearly steeper for
losses than for gains (Kahneman and Tversky 1979). However, the behaviour of a
person may markedly change when the gains and losses are very large when
compared to the overall situation of the person. For instance, the possibility to
lose ones apartment or the possibility to buy an apartment might be such cases.
In addition to the above cognitive distortions that decision choices may face,
participatory group decision-making situations contain the challenge of various
social biases, which a well-informed and skilful group facilitator is able to be taking
into account. For example, stakeholders of a policy process may express strategic
behaviour and bargain with exaggerated requirements (for forest conservation,
harvest levels, etc.) in order to eventually after negotiations and seemingly
compromising behaviour gain what they initially targeted. The facilitator may
cope this with creating an open confidential atmosphere where the participants may
12.3 Biases and Distortions in Decision Support Situations 299

Fig. 12.3 Utility function


derived from prospect
theory

feel comfortable to express their views openly from the early phase. Another
strategy to foster cooperative behaviour in group decision-making is to apply
role-playing games, when taking and changing roles helps the participants to
consider the complex situation from different perspectives, which may help them
to find a collaborative, constructive mode of decision contemplation. Some social
biases that may be relevant in forest planning context, with suggested mitigation
strategies are, for example:
Shared information bias: people discuss information that everybody knows
already, and they thus reinforce the existing knowledge without focusing on
unshared information (suggestion: organise time for more marginal topics so
that new knowledge could be collaboratively constructed).
System justification (social counterpart to the status quo bias): people reinforce
the existing social, economic and political arrangements without a willingness to
go for changes or innovations (suggestion: use collaborative planning methods
that are explicitly targeted to design and elaborate innovative ideas).
Groupthink: group members eagerly seek for group cohesion and consensus with
a cost of not evaluating critically the alternative viewpoints or raising contro-
versial issues into discussion; the group also overrates its own performance and
decisions (suggestion: assign roles for critical evaluation, break deliberately the
group coherence by inviting outsider experts, and invest on methods that are
designed for assessing alternative solutions and perspectives).
300 12 Behavioural Aspects

References

Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1987). Image theory: Principles goals and plans in decision
making. Acta Psychologica, 66, 201220.
Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1990). Image theory: A behavioral theory of decisions in
organizations. Research in Organizational Behavior, 12, 141.
Birchler, U., & Butler, M. (2007). Information economics. London: Routledge. 462 pp.
De Meo, I., Ferretti, F., Hujala, T., & Kangas, A. (2013). The usefulness of Decision Support
Systems in participatory forest planning: A comparison between Finland and Italy. Forest
Systems, 22(2), 304319.
Einhorn, H. J. (1982). Learning from experience and suboptimal rules in decision making. In
D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, & A. Tversky (Eds.), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and
biases (pp. 268286). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
French, S. (1989). Readings in decision analysis. London: Chapman and Hall. 210 p.
Haara, A., Kurttila, M., Pykalainen, J., Hokajarvi, R., & Kilpelainen, H. (2014). Constructing
forest plans interactively based on owner-driven evaluation of the holding- and stand-level
alternatives. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29 (Sup 1), 185194.
Herbert, A., & Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 69, 99118.
Hujala, T., Pykalainen, J., & Tikkanen, J. (2007). Decision making among Finnish non-industrial
private forest owners: The role of professional opinion and desire to learn. Scandinavian
Journal of Forest Research, 22(5), 454463.
Hujala, T., Khadka, C., Wolfslehner, B., & Vacik, H. (2013). Supporting problem structuring with
computer-based tools in participatory forest planning. Forest Systems, 22(2), 270281.
Janis, I. L., & Mann, L. (1977). Decision making. A psychological analysis of conflict, choice and
commitment. New York: Free Press. 488 p.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.
Econometrica, 47, 263291.
Kangas, A. S. (2010). Value of forest information. European Journal of Forest Research, 129(5),
863874.
Kasanen, E., Wallenius, H., Wallenius, J., & Zionts, S. (2000). A study of high-level managerial
decision processes, with implications for MCDS research. European Journal of Operational
Research, 120, 496510.
Lindblom, C. (1959). The science of Muddling through. Public Administrative Review, 7988.
March, J. (1994). A primer on decision making How decisions happen. New York: Free Press.
289 p.
MacLeod, W. P., & Pingle, M. (2005). Aspiration uncertainty: Its impact on decision performance
and process. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 56, 617629.
Makinen, A., Kangas, A., & Nurmi, M. (2012). Using cost-plus-loss analysis to define optimal
forest inventory interval and forest inventory accuracy. Silva Fennica, 46(2), 211226.
Oechssler, J. (2002). Cooperation as a result of learning with aspiration levels. Journal of
Economic Behaviour and Organization, 49, 405409.
Pingle, M., & Day, R. H. (1996). Models of economizing behavior: Experimental evidence.
Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 29, 191209.
Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man: Social and national. New York: Wiley. 247 p.
Simon, H. A., Egidi, M., Viale, R., & Marris, R. (1992). Economics, bounded rationality and the
cognitive revolution. Brookfield: Edward Elgar. 232 pp.
Turunen, M. (2003). Mielikuvateoria s aann
ostelyn kehitt
amisess
a. Diploma thesis, Helsinki
University of Technology, Department of Water Resources Engineering.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1982). Judgement under uncertainty. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, &
A. Tversky (Eds.), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases (pp. 320). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Wierzbicki, A. P. (1982). A mathematical basis for satisficing decision making. Mathematical
Modelling, 3(5), 391405.
Chapter 13
Final Remarks

Abstract In this chapter, we discuss the overall selection of decision support tools
and usefulness of decision support tools in general. First, we acknowledge the
varying suitability of different methods for different purposes. After that, we
discuss the possibilities of combining different decision support tools to improve
the decision process and outcome. We illustrate the effect of information require-
ments on the selection of decision support tools. Furthermore, we discuss the
requirements different tools set to the skills of the planning consultants, decision-
makers and stakeholders. It is important that everyone involved is able to under-
stand how the tools work and how the results should be interpreted. We provide
practical recommendations on what type of decision support methods and tools suit
different purposes, and what aspects need to be taken into account when making
method choices. We conclude the chapter with summarising the most prevalent
challenges in the development and use of decision support methods and tools for
advancing multiple-purpose forestry.

Planning situations and decision-makers needs vary greatly case by case. Acquir-
ing decision support for tactical planning is different from acquiring it for strategic
planning, for non-industrial private forest planning compared to public or industrial
forestry, for an individual decision-maker compared to a consortium, for planning
solely for wood production in comparison to ecosystem management planning,
when using quantitative criteria in comparison to qualitative criteria, etc. The
decision support methods presented above have demonstrated that their properties
vary greatly. It is therefore obvious that the different methods are at their best in
different planning situations.
There is no method that is universally best or even applicable for all situations.
On the other hand, every method can be used in forest planning for tasks for which
it is especially suitable. The choice of best or simply suitable decision support
method requires knowledge and experience of many methods, consideration of
case-specific requirements and acquainting oneself with the planning situation
i.e. planning of planning (e.g. Kangas et al. 2001a; Kangas and Kangas 2002,
2005).
It may not be enough to select the one best planning method for one situation: in
many cases the recommendable option may be to select a combination of methods
(Mingers and Brocklesby 1997). Depending on the planning situation at hand, it

Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015 301


A. Kangas et al., Decision Support for Forest Management, Managing Forest
Ecosystems 30, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-23522-6_13
302 13 Final Remarks

may be wise to combine optimisation and MCDA, several different MCDA


methods, MCDA with problem structuring methods or several different problem
structuring methods in one decision support process. Some method-oriented studies
indicate that it would be useful to utilise more than just one MCDS method or
hybrid approach in many planning situations, especially for behavioural reasons
(e.g. Bell et al. 2001, Kangas et al. 2001a, Belton and Stewart 2002). In addition to
serving decision-makers and stakeholders varying wishes, a method mix, espe-
cially a combination of qualitative and quantitative decision support methods, is
evidenced to yield wide benefits when evaluating the success of the planning in
terms of transparency, flexibility, consensus building and operability (Myllyviita
et al. 2014).
One possible way to go forward with method selection is to think about the three
worlds: material, personal and social, and select the method(s) related to what
components are emphasised in the planning situation (Fig. 13.1). Nevertheless, it
has to be kept in mind that the usefulness of delivered decision support depends
more on the application of the methods (Myllyviita et al. 2014) than on the choice
of methods as such. Therefore, rather than selecting a perfectly matching profound
method without proper skills and experience to use the method, it may be more
beneficial to select a method which is somehow suitable to the planning situation
but in which the planning consultant is familiar with and able to apply it in a
creative in-depth way.
It is especially important to take into consideration what kinds of people are
participating in the planning process. People differ in their knowledge and skills,
learning styles and interaction preferences, and they are differently equipped for
participating in decision analyses. Different methods, as well as applications of
different measurement scales (i.e. ordinal versus cardinal, interval versus ratio), suit
people differently when enquiring about their preferences (Sironen et al. 2014). On
the other hand, the choice of the MCDS method to be used is also dependent on the
quality of information that is available or meaningful to acquire on decision-
makers and stakeholders preferences.
An important consideration for the selection of MCDS method is also the quality
of the information available for evaluating the decision alternatives with respect to
the decision criteria. A multi-criteria decision support method is advised to be
chosen so that all information that is available through a reasonable effort could be
utilised as fully as possible. Exact information is used for criteria with exact values,
and ordinal or dichotomous information is used for criteria with low-quality data.
Also the information concerning risks and uncertainties is advised to be as fully
utilised as possible, because incorporating these information may affect how
recommendable the different decision alternatives appear to the decision-makers.
However, compromises must often be made when choosing the methods.
Methods that enable deep analyses and complete exploitation of the available
data are typically hard to use and understand. Conversely, very easy and simple
methods, such as basic multi-criteria approval, often lead to loss of information,
although those types of methods may be by default favoured by the practical
stakeholders. It is the planning consultants ethical duty to balance between the
13 Final Remarks 303

Appreciation Analysis Assessment Action


of of of to

Social social practices, distortions, ways of generate


power conflicts altering empowerment
relations interests existing and
structures enlightenment

Personal individual differing alternative generate


beliefs perceptions and conceptualizations accomodation
meanings personal and constructions and
emotions rationality consensus

Material physical underlying alternative select and


circumstances causal physical implement
structure and structural best alternatives
arrangements

Fig. 13.1 A framework for mapping methods (Mingers and Brocklesby 1997)

decision-makers wishes for simple methods and the possibilities that the more
advanced methods would provide to the quality of planning.
The behavioural viewpoint is important not only in choosing the method to be
applied but also when applying any decision support method. The planning process
should be understandable and pedagogical, so that all the participants can fully
understand the reasoning and results. A recommended approach, particularly in
participatory or any other planning where ordinary people are involved, would be to
use simple and straightforward MCDS methods. This is the case especially in
Internet-mediated planning (Kangas and Store 2003). Unfortunately, practical
MCDS applications are often too technically oriented and either simplify reality
too much or are too difficult to use, understand and interpret (e.g. Corner and
Buchanan 1997). One option to mitigate this challenge is to raise awareness among
decision-makers and stakeholders about the various available methods by
conducting small demo decision tasks before the actual planning tasks. When not
spending too much time for these tasks, the participants may get insight on the way
in which the introduced method may be helpful in their decision-making in future.
Another recommendable option for practical decision support processes would
be to apply an easily understandable decision support method, or a method the
participants have used before, in order to become familiar with the planning task
and to understand the very nature of the decision problem. Using decision analysis
tools might also be easier, if people have familiarised themselves with the situation
using problem structuring methods such as SWOT, SODA, SSM or SCA. On the
other hand, it is possible also to use the value tree approach as a problem structuring
304 13 Final Remarks

method from the start, when accompanying it with discussions with stakeholders
(e.g. Mustajoki et al. 2011). Voting method analysis may be a suitable starting
point, when the problem has been clarified. After that, people may be ready to
answer more demanding inquiries and, thus, to give higher-quality preference
information. Then, detailed and in-depth analyses by more complicated methods
would be possible. A good example of such process is the combined use of voting
methods and an interactive utility analysis in the case of planning of Finnish state
forests (Pykalainen et al. 2007).
However, in some cases, moving from an easily understood method to an
in-depth analysis by more complicated methods might lead to a problem. Namely,
people may be willing to produce similar results even with more complicated
methods, after first obtaining results from the easily understood method. This
being the case, it might be difficult to argue why there is a change in ranks (and
in recommendations) when evaluating alternatives if uncertainties or probabilities
are included, for instance. This puts additional requirements on the interpretation of
the results.
In any planning process, it is also useful to perform as comprehensive a decision
analysis as the data allows. Although complicated methods and calculations may
not enhance peoples involvement in planning processes, the methods often pro-
duce enlightening detailed results for the analysts and decision-makers. Moreover,
it often makes sense to invest in acquiring higher-quality and more accurate
information on both evaluation data and preferences and to apply corresponding
analysis methods (Kangas et al. 2001b). This is particularly the case in conflict
management situations (Shields et al. 1999). The participatory workshops may then
use the summaries of the more profound analysis to strive for stakeholders better
understanding of the situation and commitment towards deliberated, concerted
action.
In real-life planning, it is typical that some criteria can be measured on cardinal
scale, but it is difficult and sometimes even impossible to express all criteria in ratio
or even in interval scale. As a consequence, there often are both ordinal and cardinal
information in decision-making processes. Consequently, there is a need for deci-
sion support methods that can make use of ordinal and interval information.
Another challenge is that in many decision support methods, the required inquiries
are difficult for decision-makers. It would often be easier to express ordinal than
cardinal preferences for many decision-makers and for stakeholders in participatory
approaches.
Forcing people to make priority comparisons in cardinal scales could, in some
cases, lead to more biased estimates of true preferences than applying ordinal
inquiries. Ordinal preferences can be taken as implicitly uncertain, as is often the
case with stated preferences in actual decision processes. As a result, ordinal
statements may reflect the true preferences better than exact cardinal values
(e.g. Larichev 1992, Shepetukha and Olson 2001). This might sometimes also be
the case with the evaluations of alternative decisions with respect to a single
criterion, especially concerning forest functions evaluated on subjective prefer-
ences, such as the scenic beauty of forest landscape (Sugimura 1993).
13 Final Remarks 305

In many forest and environmental planning processes, we have to contend with


more or less incomplete information bases, with mixed data and sometimes even
purely descriptive data that might allow only ordinal rankings. Thus, it can be
concluded that methods like multi-criteria approval and SMAA-O have potential
for wide application in todays forest and other natural resource management and
that their application potential will most probably increase in the future. However,
applying cardinal information and ratio-scale methods allows for trade-off ana-
lyses, which are pivotally important when planning multiple-use or multifunctional
forestry. For that reason, it is always reasonable to employ such information and
methods, if they are available. A further conclusion has been that whatever the
planning task and the MCDS method, interactive use of the method greatly
improves the efficiency of the process, as well as education and learning
(e.g. Pykalainen 2000; Pykalainen et al. 2007).
In order to provide detailed decision support, MCDS methods need to be
complemented with numeric simulation and optimisation tools. Such tools espe-
cially contribute to the examination of future production possibilities and to the
generation of alternative efficient forest plans, although they may fail to satisfac-
torily cover whole complex decision problems of multiple-purpose forestry due to
data quality and availability issues. Simulation and optimisation results can then be
utilised together with other information sources, such as GIS analyses, expert
judgements, subjective preferences and descriptive data, in an MCDS framework.
If suitable data is available, interactive multi-objective optimisation may be a very
attractive option, however (Miettinen and Makela 1999).
Accounting for the uncertainties in planning is also ever more important. We are
facing important uncertainties, for instance, due to climate change and its effects on
forest growth, mortality, insect outbreaks, floods and storms. It can be shown that
better decisions can be done, when the uncertainty is taken into account in the
planning, in the form of stochastic programming (King and Wallace 2012). Thus, it
is wise to utilise also the information concerning the uncertainties in the planning,
and usually information concerning the uncertainties in forest inventory, growth
and yield predictions or climate change scenarios is readily available. In discrete
settings, analysing the uncertainties with the probabilities of each of the manage-
ment options being best is advisable.
Research focusing on OR techniques has been active in recent years in general
and increasingly so within the field of natural resource management. In addition,
OR methods have gained interest not only of researchers in different disciplines but
also of decision-makers and planners outside the scientific community. In the
forestry practice, optimisation methods are utilised in very many countries as an
integral part of the planning process (Borges et al. 2014), and MCDS methods have
also been applied in many real-life planning cases and in many different countries,
to better meet the many challenges of todays forest management. These challenges
include providing decision support for multiple-purpose forestry and participatory
planning but also for managing risks and uncertainty and for making comprehen-
sive use of different kinds of information from various sources. It is evident that the
need and demand for OR applications in forestry and environmental planning will
306 13 Final Remarks

further increase in the future, placing high demands and great opportunities for
decision analysts and facilitators of our time.

References

Bell, M. L., Hobbs, B. F., Elliott, E. M., Ellis, H., & Robinson, Z. (2001). An evaluation of multi-
criteria methods in integrated assessment of climate policy. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision
Analysis, 10, 229256.
Belton, V., & Stewart, T. J. (2002). Multiple criteria decision analysis: An integrated approach.
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Borges, J. G., Nordstr
om, E. -M., Garcia-Gonzalo, J., Hujala T., & Trasobares, A. (Eds.). (2014).
Computer-based tools for supporting forest management. The experience and the expertise
world-wide. Report of Cost Action FP 0804 Forest Management Decision Support Systems
FORSYS. Sveriges lantbruksuniversitetet. ISBN 978-91-576-9236-8.
Corner, J., & Buchanan, J. (1997). Capturing decision maker preference: Experimental compar-
ison of decision analysis and MCDM techniques. European Journal of Operational Research,
98, 8597.
Kangas, J., & Kangas, A. (2002). Multiple criteria decision support methods in forest manage-
ment: An overview and comparative analyses. In T. Pukkala (Ed.), Multi-objective forest
planning (pp. 3770). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Kangas, J., & Kangas, A. (2005). Multiple criteria decision support in forest management
Fundamentals of the approach, methods applied, and experiences gained. Forest Ecology
and Management, 207, 133143.
Kangas, J., & Store, R. (2003). Internet and teledemocracy in participatory planning of natural
resource management. Landscape and Urban Planning, 62, 89101.
Kangas, J., Kangas, A., Leskinen, P., & Pykalainen, J. (2001a). MCDM methods in strategic
planning of forestry on state-owned lands in Finland: Applications and experiences. Journal of
Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 10, 257271.
Kangas, J., Pesonen, M., Kurttila, M., & Kajanus, M. (2001b). AWOT: Integrating the AHP with
SWOT analysis. In K. Dellman (Ed.), Proceedings of the sixth international symposium on the
analytic hierarchy process ISAHP 2001 (pp. 189199). Kursaal Bern, Berne-Switzerland.
Bern, 24 August 2001
King, A. J., & Wallace, S. W. (2012). Modelling with stochastic programming. New York:
Springer. 173 p.
Larichev, O. I. (1992). Cognitive validity in design of decision-aiding techniques. Journal of
Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 1, 127138.
Miettinen, K., & Makela, M. M. (1999). Comparative evaluation of some interactive reference
point-based methods for multi-objective optimization. Journal of the Operational Research
Society, 50, 949959. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jors.2600786.
Mingers, J., & Brocklesby, J. (1997). Multimethodology: Towards a framework for mixing
methodologies. Omega, International Journal of Management Science, 5, 489509.
Mustajoki, H., Saarikoski, H., Marttunen, M., Ahtikoski, A., Hallikainen, V., Helle, T., Hypponen,
M., Jokinen, M., Naskali, A., Tuulentie, S., Varmola, M., Vatanen, E., & Ylisirni o, A. L.
(2011). Use of decision analysis interviews to support the sustainable use of the forests in
Finnish Upper Lapland. Journal of Environmental Management, 92, 15501563.
Myllyviita, T., Hujala, T., Kangas, A., Eyvindson,K., Sironen, S., Leskinen, P., & Kurttila,
M. (2014). Mixing methods Assessment of potential benefits for natural resources planning.
Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research, 29 (Suppl. 1), 2029.
Pykalainen, J. (2000). Interactive use of multi-criteria decision analysis in forest planning.
Doctoral thesis, University of Joensuu, Faculty of Forestry, Joensuu.
References 307

Pykalainen, J., Hiltunen, V., & Leskinen, P. (2007). Complementary use of voting methods and
interactive utility analysis in participatory strategic forest planning: Experiences gained from
western Finland. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 37, 853865.
Shepetukha, Y., & Olson, D. L. (2001). Comparative analysis of multiattribute techniques based
on cardinal and ordinal inputs. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 34, 229241.
Shields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Keny, B. M. (1999). Models for conflict resolution in ecosystem
management. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 33, 6184.
Sironen, S., Leskinen, P., Kangas, A., & Hujala, T. (2014). Variation of preference inconsistency
when applying ratio and interval scale pairwise comparisons. Journal of Multi-Criteria Deci-
sion Analysis, 21(34), 183195.
Sugimura, K. (1993). Evaluation of forest functions by local people: development of a research
method. In: Proceedings of the IUFRO conference. Forestry Research Insitute of the Republic
of Korea, Seoul, Korea, 2025 September 1993.

You might also like