You are on page 1of 7

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Trust and the transformation of energy systems


Steve Rayner
James Martin Institute for Science and Civilization, Said Business School, Park End Street, Oxford, OX1 1HP, United Kingdom

a r t i c l e in fo abstract

Available online 21 June 2009 The author looks at diverse concepts and roles of trust in the challenge of decarbonising energy systems,
Keywords: drawing on 25 years of personal experience in the elds of energy and environmental policy research.
Trust The paper focuses on three issues-public trust in science, institutional trust in making technology
Energy choices, and the idea that high-trust societies are more sustainable than those exhibiting low-trust.
Transformation While trust is a key concept in understanding the public acceptability of technology choices, it is only
one of a suite of interrelated concepts that must be addressed, which also includes liability, consent, and
fairness. Furthermore, rational distrust among competing institutional world views may be critical in
understanding the role of social capital in socioeconomic and technological development. Thus the
concept of trust has become a portmanteau, carrying a diverse range of ideas and conditions for
sustainable energy systems. The paper concludes with three emphases for decision makers. First, the
issue is the energy system, not particular generating technologies. Second, the energy system must be
recognized to be as much a social system as it is a technical one. Third, the system requires
incorporation of the minimum level of diversity of engineering technologies and social actors to be
sustainable.
& 2009 Published by Elsevier Ltd.

1. Introduction of trust in creating a social environment conducive to technolo-


gical change including
The problem posed by this symposium is one of political
mobilization around climate change and energy policy. The issue  political consensus around the need/desirability of signi-
has been framed for us as one of managing public expectations cant systemic change (including issues of trust in science,
and marshalling public and political support behind an agenda particularly climate science).
of decarbonisation of the UK energy system while maintaining  public and industry acceptance of new grid supply techno-
energy security, promoting economic competitiveness, and logies (packages of preferences for trust, liability and con-
eliminating fuel poverty. In other words, the goal of such a sentTLC factors).
mobilization would be a socially and environmentally sustainable  interaction among diverse institutional actors (social capital
energy strategy. and the notion of generalized trust as the social context for
From a critical social science perspective, we could have a lot of decision making).
fun unpacking the assumptions underlying this framing of the
problem and dissecting the scientic, ethical, and cultural
In the course of this discussion, following the path breaking
assumptions, interpretations, and commitments that it takes for
work of Bernard Barber (1983), I will touch on several different
granted. Indeed, I have done so at length elsewhere (Rayner, 1991,
meanings of trust including
1995a, 1995b, 2000; Thompson and Rayner, 1998; Rayner and
Malone, 1998; Verweij et al., 2006). However, for the purposes of
the present discussion I will conne myself to the problem as it is  credibilitythe truth value that people assign to claims made
offered to us by the organizers. In my remarks I shall look back on by various actors.
two and a half decades of my own journey through social and  condence in technical competenceexpectations of the
institutional aspects of risk, energy, and sustainable development ability of actors to perform within elds of claimed expertise.
issues to provide a somewhat personal focus on the potential role  recognition of integrity/duciary responsibilitythe honesty,
decency and fastidiousness of actors in performing roles and
duties.
 meeting expectations of behaviour (good and bad)reliability
E-mail addresses: steve.rayner@said-business-school.oxford.ac.uk, of the behaviour of institutions and individuals, both positive
steve.rayner@sbs.ox.ac.uk (S. Rayner). and negative.

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2009 Published by Elsevier Ltd.


doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.05.035
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2618 S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623

 deference to authoritiesthe extent to which claims to scientists may ignore risks (Ofce of Science and Technology
specialist expertise are subject to public scrutiny and critique. Welcome Trust, 2000). However, in terms of the incomplete
typology of trust that I offered above, we would say that these are
The speakers brief for the symposium acknowledges that the issues of the responsibility of scientists, rather than their
interests of the various stakeholders probably do not coincide at credibility.
the outset and may or may not converge later. I will question More damaging to the credibility of scientists is their treat-
whether the framing of the problem as one of diverging interests is ment of dissidents. Work conducted under the auspices of the
sufcient to inform effective policy making and will suggest that ESRC Science in Society Programme (2007) revealed an instruc-
the issue is characterized by more far-reaching divergences in tive contrast between the treatment of dissident scientists in
world views, even among those who do not dispute the urgency of Scandinavia and the Anglo-Saxon world. Scandinavian scientic
climate policies. institutions absorb, that is to say, surround and smother their
I will go on to suggest that while trust is a key concept in dissidents. Anglo-Saxon scientic institutions publicly eject and
understanding the public acceptability of technology choices, it is disown dissidents, as clearly demonstrated by the cases of Pusztai
only one of a suite of interrelated concepts that must be and Wakeeld in the GM potatoes and MMR controversies. This
addressed. However, I will also question the central role accorded public ejection raises questions in the publics mind about who is
to trust in accounts of the importance of social capital for trying to hide what. In these cases distrust in both integrity and
economic, social and technological development. technical competence of scientists and their institutions comes to
the fore, especially in context of declining deference.
What I have elsewhere termed the novelty trap is another
2. Trust in science: is there a crisis of credibility? source of distrust in the governance of science, especially in
relation to policy and the economy (Rayner, 2004). New
At the beginning of this decade there appears to have been a technologies are often heralded with strong claims about their
widespread perception at the highest levels that there exists a novelty and the benets that they will bring. But when queries are
crisis of condence in science and technology in the UK. This was raised about whether new technology entails new risks, their
clearly highlighted in the prime ministers 2002 speech to the champions frequently back-pedal. Fifty years ago, Lewis Strauss,
Royal Society in which he unfavourably contrasted the climate for Chairman of the US Atomic Energy Commission claimed that
biotechnology research in the UK with that of India (Blair, 2002); nuclear power would yield electricity that would be too cheap to
and building a positive climate for science and technology meter (Strauss, 1954). Three decades later, amid concerns about
remains a preoccupation of the Ofce of Science and Innovation the safety of light water reactors, nuclear engineers were often
within the Department of Trade and Industry. However, the heard to claim that they were just another way of boiling water.
existence of such a crisis has not been reected in successive The public was told that that GM Crops would end hunger in the
public opinion polls which show, inter alia, that 7080% public third world (Royal Society of London et al., 2000), but when
agrees with positive statements about science and 85% agree that concerns were expressed about their environmental, human-
Scientists and engineers make a valuable contribution to health, and socioeconomic implications biotechnologists told us
society. By the way, condence in civil servants lies in middle that they are just an extension of traditional plant breeding. More
of the professions ranked, cabinet ministers were at the bottom recently, nanotechnology was hailed as the next big thing, but
(Ofce of Science and Technology Welcome Trust, 2000; MORI, again concerns about health and environmental issues were met
2002; MORI/OST, 2005). with the claim that it is just an extension of colloidal chemistry
So if there is not evidence of a widespread crisis of condence (Thomas and Kulkarni, 2003). Such U-turns are clearly damaging
in science, we might ask, Is there a problem of trust in to scientic credibility (Rayner, 2004).
governance?. Political scientists in North America and the UK One understands that claims of novelty attract public and
claim to have detected a steady 50 year trend of declining private investment, create excitement for researchers, and aid
deference to authority in general, including politicians, doctors, recruitment to university departments. However, they also invite
academics, etc. (Laird, 1989; Giddens, 1991; Beck, 1992; Nevitte, critical public scrutiny and create the danger of stigmatisation.
1996; ONeil, 2002). It is possible that scientists, who came to From the standpoint of the scientic community, concerns
occupy a position of unparalleled inuence and respect arising out about new technologies often seem to be exaggerated. The decit
of their contribution to winning the Second World War, may model of public understanding was advanced as an explanation.
wrongly conate their experience of this loss of deference to Although it is now generally proclaimed to be dead, this is only
persons of authority with lack of condence in science as an the case at the rhetorical level. It is alive and well in the practice of
activity that contributes to the public good. many scientic, commercial, and government organizations. It has
One poll result, often highlighted as a source of concern, is that actually has gone through three iterations, all of which are
which indicates that the public has higher trust in scientists currently in play.
working for NGOs than those in government (Ofce of Science and Version I frames the decit as a lack of understanding of
Technology Welcome Trust, 2000). Industry scientists, although scientic facts on the part of the public. It suggests that the media,
presumably having the most experience with many products and consumers, and publics express opposition to new technologies
technologies are trusted the least. However, these are not really because they do not have the appropriate scientic knowledge to
judgments of the technical competence of these individuals, but understand the benets and risks involved (Gross, 1994). The
realistic reections of the expected behaviour of the institutions in solution to opposition, therefore, is public scientic education
which they work. Take away the word scientists and we nd to assuage concerns so that people would cease to question
that people generally trust NGOs to be less secretive than the value and the management of the technology. If only the
governmentswho must balance a range of competing interests public understood the facts, then they would love us and leave us
and responsibilitiesand are aware that rms will protect their alone.
own intellectual property and their market positions. By the end of the last decade, this version of the decit model
This is not to say that all is rosy in the republic of science. had largely fallen from favour, at least at the rhetorical level.
There are public concerns: 3545% say that science and Almost everyone involved in negotiating the interface between
technology is developing too fast, 5575% are concerned that science and the public now acknowledges that communication is
ARTICLE IN PRESS
S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623 2619

a two-way process. As former Science Minister Lord Sainsbury Critique of the decit model throws into relief the way in
said: which scientic and political authority have become inextricable
during the past half-century. Policy makers rely on scientists
We have moved decisively away from the era in which it was (as they once relied on priesthoods) both to interpret the world
enough for science communicators simply to educate the and to be agents of human control over dangerous forces such as
public about science and its benets. What is needed now is an disease or natural disaster. Science is not simply one activity or
effective two-way dialogue and debate between those who do aspect of society, but has become its primary culture of
scientic research and the public (OST, 2002). legitimation. There is a strong assumption on both sides of the
science and policy relationship that science compels (or ought to
compel) policy. Just get the science right and if we then trust the
There is explicit agreement that scientists and science policy science we will trust the policies. Indeed, since World War II there
makers need also to listen to the public and seek to understand has been an explosion in the growth of policy-maker reliance on
and respond to their concerns. However, for the most part, the scientic assessments (often based on computer models).
reality of practice in science communication has yet to catch up
with this rhetorical change. Promoters of new technologies
continue to confront public concern by providing reassuring 3. Trust in climate sciencehow important is it for policy?
information about the technology.
Version II suggests that the public does not so much lack But, does science drive policy? Contrasting the inuence of
knowledge of facts but understanding of scientic procedures and climate change models and assessments on policy in the USA and
the limits to scientic inquiry. It suggests that the problem is not Europe strongly suggests otherwise. Debates over climate change
simply lack of scientic information about particular technologies, are multidimensional, and are often framed in terms of trust in
but a failure of public understanding of the processes of science science, both with respect to reliability of scientic claims and the
(Wynne, 1991). It is not possible, for instance, for science to prove motivations of the claimants. But, as Roger Pielke Jr (2005) points
a negative proposition, e.g. there is no risk attached to a particular out; there is invariably much room for disagreement over
activity or technology. If this version of the decit model were appropriate policy response, even where consensus on science
correct, it would predict that the public demands or expects zero- exists. The reality is that politics matters.
risk. However, in two decades of research on public behaviour George Bush senior began his campaign for the US Presidency
with respect to technological and environmental risk, I have never in 1988, when the country was facing its worst drought and heat
encountered a zero-risk expectation among the public. wave since records began. He famously told the electorate You
Decit model III suggests that neither knowledge nor under- have heard about the greenhouse effect: Wait until you see the
standing is at issue. The problem is rather a decit of public trust White House effect (New York Times, 1989). However, shortly
in science and its institutions (Haerlin and Parr, 1999; Select after taking ofce, he blamed his failure to deliver on the
Committee on Science and Technology, 2000). The informational ambiguity in the science of global warming. In language evocative
focus of science communication is now supplemented by a trust- of an inverted bell-curve he suggested that scientists were sharply
building imperative. If only the public trusted us then they would divided between those who believed in climate change and those
love us and leave us alone. who did not. With such a lack of scientic consensus, claimed the
Each of these versions of the decit model reiterates the fact President, sound policy making was impossible. Although this
that effective communication about science is an important and argument fundamentally misrepresented informed scientic
valuable activity for scientists, government, industry, and NGOs. opinion, his stance framed subsequent policy debate as between
Certainly, in the 21st century, every citizen would benet from those who trusted in climate science and climate sceptics, who
what the ESRC Science in Society Research Programme has found aws in its evidence and reasoning.
described as a capacity of popular connoisseurship of the Policy making in the USA is also very much dominated by what
potentialities and limitations of science and technology (Healey, we might call the proportionality principle, which suggests that
2004). policies must be proportional in their costs to the damages that
However, framing the relationship between science and they are designed to avoid. Hence, there is a legal requirement for
governance primarily as a problem of science communication regulatory impact analysis (benet-cost analysis) of Federal
domesticates it as a process problem that can be solved by the legislation. We should also recognize that for the past 30 years,
application of better communication techniques. When the the US has been undergoing a process of devolution of power from
proposed solution remains constant through successive problem the Federal Government back to the States. There is also a
redenitions there may be good reason to be suspicious. The goal pervasive concern about the state of the American economy and
of such communication often seems to be to preserve the its ability to support the American way of life which George
autonomy of scienceTrust us and leave us to get on with it. Bush Jr has famously declared will not be sacriced on the altar of
Decit models enable the institutions of science and governance climate change. In other words, the economy is viewed as fragile
to elide fundamental structural challenges to established patterns while nature remains robust.
of institutional authority in both science and politics. If the issue In Europe, by way of contrast, the most prominent leader of the
is one of communication, there is no need to question the 1980s, Margaret Thatcher, emerged as a veritable Green Goddess
appropriateness of existing procedures, established patterns of of the environment. Her desire to destroy the power of the miners
access to decision making, institutional prerogatives, and power and the dash for gas were both consistent with recognizing
distributions. climate change as a serious threat.
The decit-communication paradigm does not raise contro- The precautionary principle, rather than the proportionality
versial questions about the relative roles of scientic advice and principle, informs policy thinking in Europe (ORiordan and Jaeger,
moral and aesthetic judgement in the policy process. By not doing 1996). The imperative to avoid irreversible change outweighs the
so, it allows the scientic community to sidestep emerging insistence that action only be taken where the costs of doing
challenges to its own institutional autonomy and authority as nothing can be shown to outweigh those of intervention.
well as the close relationship to political power that it has enjoyed Furthermore, the past three decades has been a period in
during much of the 20th century. which Europe has moved inexorably in the direction of greater
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2620 S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623

integration and harmonization of policies and procedures among damage in recent hurricanes is directly attributable to increased
its constituent nation states. A non-human external threat to the density of costly infrastructure (condos, luxury hotels, etc.) in
health and safety of citizens is quite consistent with the expansion oodplains and on coastal margins.
and development of the greater European project. Climate has The public reaction to the Asian tsunami demonstrated (if any
provided a unifying focus for European politics, especially in the such demonstration were needed) that the public and politicians
face of apparent US unwillingness to consider meaningful climate do respond to disaster events. It is easy to understand therefore
change policies. the temptation to blame increased hurricane damage on climate
Finally, perhaps ironically in a part of the world in which no change. However, public credibility is easily undermined and,
wild nature exists, Europeans seem to be more sympathetic than once shaken, almost impossible to mend. Scientists and politi-
Americans to the idea that there are limits to the natural capacity cians concerned to advance a climate policy agenda would do well
of ecosystems to withstand change. Hence nature is viewed as to refrain from such temptation, especially since there are
fragile and economy as comparatively robust. sufcient good arguments and strong evidence on which to base
Public expectations of the government also differ on each side a precautionary agenda. With that note, I move on to my second
of the Atlantic. In the US, about 6070% of respondents to opinion theme; that of the role of trust in energy technology decisions.
polls say that they see climate as a signicant problem, but only
about 40% look to the Federal Government to do anything about it
(Pew Research Center, 2006). Increasingly state and city govern- 4. The role of trust in technology choice: the cases of new
ments and the philanthropic and private sectors are seen as nuclear options and water conservation
playing a larger role.
More Britons (7090%) than Americans tell pollsters that they The US Department of Energys Oak Ridge National Laboratory
view climate change as a signicant problem. However, almost all launched its Nuclear Power Options Viability Study in 1984 to
of them also see the Her Majestys Government as having the explore the possible availability of advanced nuclear power
primary responsibility to come up with and implement solutions reactor concepts in the 20002010 timeframe (Trauger et al.,
(MORI, 2002). 1986). The project was overwhelmingly dominated by technical
Among institutions addressing climate change worldwide, the assessments of alternative designs, mostly embodying so-called
Intergovernmental Panel, on Climate Change (IPCC) has achieved a passive safety features. However, I was invited to lead a social
high level of trust among diverse constituencies worldwide. science assessment of the issues most likely to inuence their
Although it has been subject to some cynical criticism (e.g., market and public acceptability, especially in the light of wide-
Boehmer-Christiansen, 1994) attempts to blacken its reputation spread concerns about the safety of existing nuclear power
through accusations that the summary for policymakers (SPM) reactors.
has politicized the ndings of the individual working groups This was a challenging task, not least because of the
(e.g., Singer, 1997) have only impressed a minority of climate implausibility of projecting existing electric power industry
naysayers, who are themselves vulnerable to accusations of structures, management and regulatory regimes, political prio-
political selectivity with regard to the relevant science. rities, economic conditions and technical capabilities some 20
Trust in the IPCC seems to encompass most of the dimensions years into the future.
that I referred to in my opening remarks. Its reports enjoy high First, we took a broad view, interpreting technologies as social
credibility due to recognition of the technical competence of the systems mediated by materials and devices, in which we would
scientists who make up the IPCC. Its integrity is assured through a focus on the likely entailments of any central station nuclear
highly visible series of procedures by which individual govern- power generator, regardless of its particular characteristics.
ments nominate scientists, drafts are prepared and peer reviewed Second, we approached risk as an ordinary language category.
before being submitted to government review and line-by-line That is to say, rather than anchoring on the technical concept of
approval of its reports is given in plenary sessions. Furthermore, probability times consequence, we sought to understand how
the IPCC has demonstrated admirable consistency in its ndings, people actually used the term in everyday speech.
cautiously moving over the best part of two decades, from a highly This soon revealed that ordinary folks talking about risk may
conservative initial nding that it could nd no scientic basis to not be referring to probabilities of consequences at all. In
reject the anthropogenic warming hypothesis to a carefully particular, we found that people used the term risk to refer to
drafted consensus that climate change is actually occurring an is concerns about what we came to call the TLC issues (Rayner and
to a signicant extent due to human activity. At the same time, the Cantor, 1987). These are the issues of trust, liability, and consent
IPCC has not endorsed extreme scenarios or ideas for which the (see Table 1). Concerns about consent revolved around the
evidence is contentious, including the currently popular idea that question of whether affected parties believed that they had been
increased hurricane damage costs in the Caribbean and North given the opportunity to accept or reject the technology in a
America are a direct result of a secular global warming trend. manner that they regarded as legitimate. Issues of liability
This last point brings me to the topic of the damage to public focused on whether the affected parties were satised that costs
trust that can result from the employment of bad arguments in were appropriately distributed and that appropriate arrange-
favour of good causes. For instance, Bill McGuire (2006), writing in ments were in place to make good in the event of unwanted
New Scientist has even sought to blame recent volcanic activity on consequences.
climate change! Less outlandishly, there were several press Trust hinged on whether the affected parties were satised
reports in which well-respected members of the scientic esta- that the institutions responsible for the commissioning, design,
blishment endorsed the idea that the damage caused by Katrina, implementation, management, and regulation of the technology
and other hurricane events was due to increased intensity of (including arrangements for consent and liability) were appro-
storms resulting from warming of the oceans due to anthropo- priate and adequate.
genic climatic change. To asses the future acceptability of nuclear power designs we
However, research by Pielke et al. (2005) shows that the idea focused on the approaches that electric utility companies,
that storms have consistently increased in intensity of the past regulators, and public-interest interveners took towards trust,
century may not be justied. In any case, they conclusively show liability, and consent issues, thus dened, in the decision to add
that over 85% of the increased damage costs of wind and water new generating capacity.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623 2621

With respect to consent, utilities viewed the demand for power principles of equity, at least one of which can be seen to appeal to
as a surrogate for consent to capacity addition. This is what social each of the egalitarian, hierarchical, and competitive ways of
scientists call a revealed preference approach, embodying the organizing to be found among the stakeholders. These are
idea that people vote with their pocket books and reveal their principles of parity, proportionality, and priority (Young, 1993;
preferences for trade offs through their behaviour in the market Rayner, 1995a).
(Thaler and Rosen, 1975). Of course, it is reasonable to question First, each household is allocated the same xed allowance for
how valid this view is in a situation of even regulated monopoly. human consumption, i.e., for drinking, cooking, bathing, etc. thus
In Britain 20 years later, the availability of consumer choice meeting the requirement of parity, which is in turn characteristic
among suppliers, including specialist suppliers of renewable of egalitarians, who view water as a basic need and human right
energy, may make this competitive/market position appear all rather than as a commodity.
the more reasonable. Each household then receives an additional variable allowance
Following John Rawls (1971), we characterized the regulators for use outside the housemainly irrigation of lots. This
approach to public consent as hypothetical. This reects the allowance is determined by a formula that includes the area of
idea that the social contract between citizens and government each lot (obtained from real-estate records), the evapotranspira-
permits agencies to assume consent to specic actions. This tion rates of typical plantings, and records of seasonal tempera-
hierarchical approach to consent is also consistent with a focus tures. Thus the allowance varies by lot size and by month to allow
on procedural rationality. In the case of US Public Utility for efcient irrigation of gardens. Charts showing usage alongside
Commissions, power demand forecasts were often regarded as allocation have proven effective in correcting householders
the justication for the administrative determination that a new tendency to over water their yards late in the growing season.
power station could be built. This second allowance satises hierarchical preferences for
The public-interest interveners took a different approach to proportionality in allocation.
consent, often arguing that the granting of a certicate of Consumers wishing to consume in excess of these allowances
convenience and necessity to build a new power station should are, in principle, subject to an escalating scale of charges, the rate
be made, or at least ratied, by popular referendum. In so doing, rising more precipitously as consumption increases, although in
they were demonstrating an explicit preference approach to practice punitive levels of charging have seldom been reached.
consent. Signicantly, commitment to explicit consent makes it However, this does allow for individualist householders to assert
impossible to impose risks on future generations who, by their priority in allocation, should they choose to do so.
denition, are not available to give consent. Individualists are also attracted by the market-like emphasis on
Looking at liability (see Calabrese, 1970), the utility companies establishing prices and property rights.
were committed to the idea of spreading risk as broadly as Hence, egalitarians see a strong instrument that motivates
possible away from the company itself. In other words, the cost of conservation as well as protects everyones access to sufcient
the plant, both foreseen and unforeseen, should be transferred to water for basic needs. Hierarchists appreciate the rationality of
the customers. The utilities also campaigned for the preservation the strategy and its ability to help in long term planning.
of the Price-Anderson Act that limited liability of nuclear power Individualists appreciate how the strategy protects the customers
generators in the event of an accident. freedom of choice to use as much water as can be afforded.
Regulators, on the other hand, adopted a deep pocket approach These cases of the role of trust and inextricable ideas of
to costs, seeking to make a regulatory allocation of resources fairness in shaping the acceptability of technological change in
where they would have least impact on societya so-called deep energy and water naturally lead us to consider the idea of broader
pocket approach. societal trust, which is often associated with the idea of social
Interveners took the opposite view from that of the utilities, capital.
seeking strict liability that concentrated responsibility for costs,
losses, and accidents in the hands of directors and shareholders of
utility companies. This position was clearly related to the issue of 5. Trust as social contextthe idea of high-trust societies
trust insofar as it was explicitly seen as a way to keep the
bastards honest, by making them liable for failures. With respect The idea of high-trust societies and the notion that they are
to trust as a specic variable, it was clear that the utilities trusted better developed and governed than their low-trust counterparts
good managers and successful rms. Track records say it all. became a prominent theme of social science in the 1990s. It has
Consistent with their procedural approach to consent, regula- been a major feature of scholarly and popular works by such
tors demonstrated that they trust rules and processes, especially luminaries as Francis Fukuyama (1995) and Harvard political
those of longstanding effectiveness. Interveners, also consistent scientist Robert Putnam. In particular Putnam (1993) draws a
with their approach to consent, trusted the collective wisdom of sharp contrast between performance of governance institutions in
the people. Northern and Southern Italy. In seeking to explain this phenom-
The validity of what we came to call the Fairness Hypothesis enon, Putnam explores but rejects the obvious candidates such as
of technology acceptance has yet again been demonstrated in geography (closeness to northern Europe), state expenditures on
relation to another controversial public utility service, the supply government functions (the national government actually transfers
of drinking water in Southern California. Here, in response to the wealth from North to South, education of ofcials (higher levels of
persistent shortage of supply, the Otay, San Juan Capistrano, and attainment in the South), and so forth. None of these is a
Irvine Ranch Water Districts adopted a highly unusual conserva- statistically signicant correlate of performance.
tion rate structure (Lach et al., 2006). In fact, the only variable accounting for the difference is
This system was devised with input from many stakeholders, presence of overlapping networks of voluntary organizations
who agreed that the amounts of water they were expected to use characteristic of civil society, including sporting clubs, camera
and resulting costs were fair. Indeed, the genius of this particular clubs, etc. In fact, the correlation is so strong that it not only
solution is its explicit focus on focus on fairness. Proposals for accounts for the NorthSouth split, but also for the differential
conservation water pricing have foundered elsewhere when rates of performance among provinces within both regions.
advanced solely on the basis of efciency. Furthermore, the Furthermore, Putnam makes a cogent case that civic voluntarism
procedure for establishing the rate embodies three competing historically precedes economic development and not vice versa, as
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2622 S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623

Table 1
Different kinds of institutions exhibit consistent preferences/expectations.

Consent Liability Trust

Utilities (competitive) Revealed preferences (demand) Market risk spreading (insurance and customers) Good managers and successful rms
Regulatory (hierarchical) Hypothetical (forecast need for power) Deep pocket (institutional allocation) Rules and processes
Interveners (egalitarian) Explicit (popular referendum) Strict (shareholders and directors) Will of the people

would be assumed by much development theory of the past half- Table 2


century. Role of rational distrust.
Putnam and Fukuyama seem to agree that the presence of
Checked Unchecked
multiple overlapping social networks create the conditions for
generalized social trust leading to good governance. The phenom- Hierarchy System maintenance Complacency and corruption
enon seems indisputable, but is the idea of generalized trust Competition Innovation Monopoly and extortion
adequate to explain the observations here? Egalitarianism Early warning Factional squabbling and paranoia

My own view (Rayner and Malone, 2000) is that Putnam does


not articulate a sufciently clear theory of trust and how it works
for us to be able to test his explanation. He does not recognize and, The minimum level of diversity is also an important contribu-
therefore, does not account for the different forms and foci of trust tion to surprise proong. Surprise is always relative to expecta-
discussed above. Furthermore, it is a somewhat romantic notion tions. Hence, the incorporation of multiple perspectives reduces
to suppose that face-to-face communities are necessarily high- opportunities to be surprised.
trust. History and anthropology are full of examples in which The idea that technological systems, like other social systems
small egalitarian communities generate scapegoating and witch need to observe a law of requisite variety also cautions us with
hunts, for example, colonial Salem (Owen, 1982), or post-war regard to the participatory turn in contemporary science
Papua New Guinea (Burridge, 1969). As exemplied by the and technology policy (Verweij and Thompson, 2006). A new
persecution of a highly assimilated Jewish community in Nazi emphasis on participation and discursive democracy may be
Germany or the ethnic cleansing of the former Jugoslavia, frequent useful as a corrective to systems that have relied excessively on
face-to-face association is no obstacle to demonization. Finally, a collusion between hierarchy and competition (that is to say on
robust civil society must surely function precisely where trust is government and business). However, egalitarianism without
tenuous. One that relies solely on condence and goodwill seems hierarchy and competition is no more capable of delivering the
fragile indeed. A sound theory of good governance must surely sustainability goods than the old duopoly of power. None of
recognize the positive role of rational distrust. the ways of organizing should be permitted a veto.
This suggests another explanation for the success of Northern
Italy that is wholly compatible with Putnams observations. That
is that the north was institutionally more diverse and therefore 6. Conclusions
has enjoyed a greater capacity for complex strategy switching.
Since the 12th Century, when the Kingdom of Roger the Great was More than 30 years have passed since Rodney Needham (1972)
a ourishing trading center governed by a unique combination of drew our attention to the polythetic character of the idea of belief.
Byzantine bureaucracy and Norman feudalism, the South of Italy Needham was following a long train of 20th century thought that
has been dominated by hierarchy and (mercantile) competition. It can be found in Vygotskys (1962) analogy of category formation
never developed the third mode of social organization character- as chains of resemblance, Ryle (1951) polymorphous classication,
istic of Northern Italy; that of the self governing communes, rooted Wittgenstein (1953) idea of family resemblances, and idea of
in the mediaeval system of guilds. With only two models of social polytypic classication in modern microbiology.
organization, the South, at best, could only oscillate, but not In all of these systems of concept formation, items at one end
develop. However, the presence of a third paradigm or model of a chain of objects which constitute a category need not have
provided the North with the capacity to experiment with of any conditions in common with those at the other end. As
complex combinations of strategies to suit changing political, Wittgenstein wrote about the category of games, For if you look
economic, and environmental conditions. at them you will not see something that is common to them all,
This explanation of the Italian case suggests a theory of but similarities, relationships, and a whole series of them
sustainability as the capacity for strategy switching. Such a theory (1953:31e.66).
could be applied at all levels of social organization from whole The category of games is an open concept in Wittgenstein. We
societies or regions of societies, to individual technologies, such as can recognise that games are a characteristic form of human
energy systems. activity and it can be shown that games are similar sorts of things,
Sustainable development as strategy switching seems to but no single essence or set of necessary and sufcient conditions
require at least three things: can be stated that covers al of the cases. Over 20 years have passed
since I suggested that the concept of risk is also a polyvalent
 Availability of at least three alternative organizational strategies. category in which ideas of trust, liability, and consent are as
 Experience with changing strategies, so that change is not too central to the ordinary language denition of risk as those of
daunting, and probability of occurrence and magnitude of loss. I think that
 Dynamic tension between strategies that does not allow any today, we have to treat the concept of trust in much the same way.
strategy to be excluded. In addition to the closely related meanings of integrity and
technical competence articulated by Barber (1983), we see that
Indeed, the ability of the minimum set of three strategies to trust in the discourses of risk and governance signals a wide set
check each others dysfunctional tendencies is a critical element of concepts related to expectations of societal resilience as well as
in this idea (see Table 2). interpersonal relationships. In the narrowest sense, trust is one
ARTICLE IN PRESS
S. Rayner / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 26172623 2623

key concept, alongside liability and consent, in the vital package of Ofce of Science and Technology & Welcome Trust, 2000. Science and the Public: a
TLC factors. However, in the broadest sense, the idea of trust review of science communication and public attitudes to science in Britain,
Department of Trade & Industry, London.
stands for the whole package. In the narrow sense, trust may not Ofce of Science & Technology, 2002. New Dimensions for Manufacturing: A UK
be as important as Putnam and Fukuyama assert in their works on Strategy for Nanotechnology. DTI, URN 02/1034. Department of Trade &
socioeconomic development, nor as important as diversity and Industry, London.
ONeil, O., 2002. A Question of Trust: BBC Reith Lectures 2002. Cambridge
pluralistic viewpoints. But in the widest sense as an ordinary University Press, Cambridge.
language category, trust may also stand for peoples expectations ORiordan, T., Jaeger, J. (Eds.), 1996. Politics of Climate Change: A European
of their society to deliver such development. Perspective. Routledge, London.
Owen, D.E., 1982. Spectral evidence: the witchcraft cosmology of Salem village in
We may tend to think about energy systems in (literally)
1692. In: Douglas, M. (Ed.), Essays in the Sociology of Perception. Routledge &
concrete terms, as fuel systems, power stations, distribution grids Kegan Paul, London.
and technologies of consumption such as homes and appliances or Pew Research Center, 2006. Partisanship Drives Opinion: Little Consensus
on Global Warming. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press,
factories and machines. But ultimately, energy systems are
Washington DC.
institutional systems mediated by materials and devices. Trust, Pielke Jr., R., 2005. Consensus about climate change? Science 308 (5724), 952954,
fairness and risk are institutional characteristics. Furthermore, as I (13 May).
stated in the beginning of this paper, they are aspects of Pielke Jr., R., Landsea, C., Mayeld, M., Laver, J., Pasch, R., 2005. Hurricanes and
global warming. Bulletin of the American Meteorological Society 86 (11), 1517.
fundamental world views, of individual and institutional iden- Putnam, R.D., 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
tities not merely manifestations of interests. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
The process of how we choose an energy future is, therefore, as Rayner, S., 1991. A cultural perspective on the structure and implementation of
global environmental agreements. Evaluation Review 15 (1), 75102.
important to a socially, politically, economically, and environmen- Rayner, S., 1995a. A conceptual map of human values for climate change decision
tally sustainable outcome as any technological option on the making. In: Katama, A. (Ed.), Equity and Social Considerations Related to
table. What will be the mix of administrative determination Climate Change: Papers presented at the IPCC Working Group III Workshop.
ICIPE Science Press, Nairobi.
(through technical assessment and government action), market Rayner, S., 1995b. Governance and the global commons. In: Desai, M., Redfern, P.
outcomes (through the R&D and generating capacity decisions of (Eds.), Global Governance: Ethics and Economics of the World Order. Pinter,
private rms), and public discourse (often conducted through New York.
Rayner, S., 2000. Prediction and other approaches to climate change policy. In:
surrogates such as NGOs and the media)? Whatever process is
Sarewitz, D., Pielke, Jr., R.A., Byerly, Jr., R. (Eds.), Prediction: Science, Decision
adopted to choose our energy future it must recognize several key Making, and the Future of Nature. Island Press, Washington DC.
points. Rayner, S., 2004. The novelty trap: why does institutional learning about
new technologies seem so difcult? Industry and Higher Education 18 (5),
First, the issue is the energy system, not particular generating
349355.
technologies. Second, that energy system must be recognized to Rayner, S., Cantor, R., 1987. How fair is safe enough? The cultural approach to
be as much a social system as it is a technical one. Third, the technology choice. Risk Analysis 7 (1), 39.
system requires incorporation of the minimum level of diversity Rayner, S., Malone, E.L. (Eds.), 1998. Human Choice and Climate Change: An
International Assessment, Volume 4, What Have We Learned? Battelle Press,
of engineering technologies and social actors to be sustainable in Columbus, Ohio.
the way I have suggested. Following these precepts provides the Rayner, S., Malone, E.L., 2000. Security, governance, and environment. In: Lowi, M.,
best chance that the process will lead to a social choice that will Shaw, B.R. (Eds.), Environment and Security: Discourses and Practices.
Macmillan, New York.
be exible, resilient to surprise, and able benet from rational Rawls, J., 1971. A Theory of Justice. Belknap Press, Cambridge MA.
distrust among diverse constituencies, all of which appear to be Royal Society of London, US National Academy of Sciences, Brazilian Academy of
necessary to attract broad social support. Sciences, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Indian National Science Academy,
Mexican Academy of Sciences, Third World Academy of Sciences, 2000.
Transgenic Plants and World Agriculture. National Academy Press, Washington
References DC.
Ryle, G., 1951. Thinking and language III. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society
(Supplementary Series) 25, 6582.
Barber, B.B., 1983. The Logic and Limits of Trust. Rutgers University Press, New Science in Society Programme, 2007. Science in Governance and the Governance of
Brunswick, NJ. Science. Economic and Social Research Council, Swindon.
Beck, U., 1992. Risk Society. Sage, London. Select Committee on Science and Technology, 2000. Science and Society. Third
Blair, T., 2002. Science Matters. Speech to the Royal Society, 10 April. Report, House of Lords London.
Boehmer-Christiansen, S., 1994. Global climate protection policy: the limits of Singer, S.F., 1997. A treaty built on hot air, not scientic consensus. Wall Street
scientic advice. Global Environmental Change 4 (2), 140159. Journal (July 25).
Burridge, K., 1969. Tangu Traditions. Clarendon Press, Oxford. Strauss, L.L., 1954. Speech to the National Association of Science Writers, New York
Calabrese, G., 1970. The Cost of Accidents. Yale University Press, New Haven. City, September 16th. New York Times, September 17.
Fukuyama, F., 1995. Trust. Penguin Books, London. Thaler, R., Rosen, S., 1975. The value of saving a life. In: Terleckyj, N. (Ed.),
Giddens, A., 1991. Modernity and Self-Identity. Polity Press, Cambridge. Household Production and Consumption. National Bureau of Economic
Gross, A.G., 1994. The roles of rhetoric in the public understanding of science. Research, New York.
Public Understanding of Science 3, 323. Thomas, P.J., Kulkarni, G.U., 2003. From colloids to nanotechnology: investigation
Healey, P., 2004. Scientic Connoisseurs and other Intermediaries: Mavens, Pundits on magic nuclearity palladium crystals. Current Science 85 (12), 17601766.
& Critics. Workshop report, ESRC Science in Society Programme, Oxford. Thompson, M., Rayner, S., 1998. Cultural discourses. In: Rayner, S., Malone, E.L.
Haerlin, B., Parr, D., 1999. How to restore public trust in science. Nature 400, 499. (Eds.), Human Choice and Climate Change: An International Assessment.
Lach, D., Ingram, H., Rayner, S., 2006. You never miss the water till the well runs Volume I, The Societal Framework. Battelle Press, Columbus, Ohio.
dry: crisis and creativity in California. In: Verweij, M., Thompson, M. (Eds.), Trauger, D., et al., 1986. Nuclear Power Options Viability Study, Volume III Nuclear
Clumsy Solutions for a Complex World. Palgrave, Basingstoke. Discipline Topics. Oak Ridge National LAbortory, Oak Ridge TN.
Laird, F.N., 1989. The decline of deference: the political context of risk Verweij, M., Douglas, M., Ellis, R., Engel, C., Hendriks, F., Lohmann, S., Ney, S.,
communication. Risk Analysis 9 (4), 543. Rayner, S., Thompson, M., 2006. Clumsy solutions for a complex world. Public
McGuire, B., 2006. Tearing the Earth apart. New Scientist, 2553, 27 May. Administration 84 (4), 843847.
MORI, 2002. Attitudes to risk: research study conducted for the Centre for Verweij, M., Thompson, M. (Eds.), 2006. Clumsy Solutions for a Complex World.
Environmental risk, University of East Anglia. MORI, London. Palgrave, Basingstoke.
MORI/OST, 2005. Science in Society: ndings from quantitative and qualitative Vygotsky, L., 1962. Thought and Language. MIT Press, Cambridge MA.
research. Department of Trade & Industry, London. Wittgenstein, L., 1953. Philosophical Investigations. Blackwell, Oxford.
Nevitte, N., 1996. The Decline of Deference: Canadian Value Change in Cross Wynne, B., 1991. Knowledges in context. Science Technology & Human Values 16
National Perspective. Broadview Press, Peterborough, Ontario. (1), 111121.
Needham, R., 1972. Belief, Language and Experience. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Young, P., 1993. Equity in Theory and Practice. Princeton University Press,
New York Times, 1989. Global lukewarming. November 5. Princeton.

You might also like