You are on page 1of 12

Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Competition and innovation: Evidence from financial services q


Jaap W.B. Bos a,⇑, James W. Kolari b, Ryan C.R. van Lamoen c
a
Maastricht University School of Business and Economics, P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands
b
Mays Business School, Texas A&M University, 351R Wehner Building, 4218 TAMU, College Station, TX 77843-4218, USA
c
Utrecht School of Economics, Utrecht University, Janskerkhof 12, 3512 BL Utrecht, The Netherlands

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper presents new evidence on the relationship between competition and innovation by extending
Received 5 November 2011 previous literature from manufacturing to financial services. We introduce a new measure of overall
Accepted 29 December 2012 innovation by estimating and enveloping annual minimum cost frontiers to create a global frontier.
Available online 23 January 2013
The distance to the global frontier constitutes each bank’s technology gap, which decreases if the bank
manages to innovate. Our innovation measure enables us to derive and estimate the model of Aghion
JEL classification: et al. (2005b) at the firm level for the US banking industry. Based on individual bank Call Report data
D21
for the period 1984–2004, consistent with theoretical and empirical work by Aghion et al., we find evi-
G21
L10
dence of an inverted-U relationship between competition and innovation that is robust over several dif-
O30 ferent specifications. Further evidence on major structural changes in the US banking industry indicates
that banks moved beyond their optimal innovation level and that interstate banking deregulation
Keywords: resulted in lower bank innovation. Policy implications to financial reform and prudential regulation
Competition are discussed also.
Innovation Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Stochastic frontier analysis
Technology gap
Banking

1. Introduction previous studies investigate this hypothesis in the financial sector.


Also, most previous studies focus on product innovation, whereas
Seminal work by Schumpeter (1942) posits that product market process innovation is largely ignored.
competition discourages innovation by diminishing monopoly The present paper seeks to fill this gap in the literature by
rents. By contrast, Aghion et al. (2001) assert that competition examining the relationship between competition and innovation
may foster innovation as firms attempt to escape competition.1 in financial services. While there is no reason to believe that the
Providing partial support for both conjectures, some empirical stud- degree of competition influences innovation differently than other
ies find an inverted-U pattern between competition and innovation industries, as Frame and White (2004) point out, revolutionary
(e.g., Scherer, 1967; Levin et al., 1985). In an attempt to reconcile changes in financial institutions and instruments have transpired
theory and evidence, Aghion and Griffith (2005) and Aghion et al. in the financial industry over the past 20 years. In this regard,
(2005b) propose a theoretical model that is able to explain an in- banks have innovated to increase the efficiency of the production
verted-U relationship between competition and innovation, wherein of financial services as well as the quality and variety of financial
an escape competition effect initially dominates until competition products. As a result, innovative banks can more effectively screen
reaches a sufficient level at which the rent dissipation effect thereaf- loan applicants, offer services at lower costs, and more efficiently
ter prevails. Their empirical evidence for manufacturing industries in intermediate between liquidity demand and supply.
the UK tends to support the hypothesis of an inverted-U pattern. No We contribute to the competition/innovation literature in two
major ways. First, we introduce a new overall measure of financial
innovation. Instead of using traditional innovation outputs (e.g.,
q
We thank Rob Alessie, Claire Economidou, Clemens Kool, Luis Orea, Mark patents which are mostly relevant to manufacturing), we examine
Sanders, participants, at the 2008 North American Productivity Workshop at New banks’ ability to minimize costs through innovations. Following
York University, and seminar participants at Utrecht School of Economics for
earlier work by Hayami and Ruttan (1970), Mundlak and Helling-
helpful comments, as well as the Center for International Business Studies at Texas
A&M University for financial support. The usual disclaimer applies.
hausen (1982), and Lau and Yotopoulos (1989), we estimate and
⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +31 433884844. envelope annual minimum cost frontiers to create a global frontier.
E-mail addresses: j.bos@maastrichtuniversity.nl (J.W.B. Bos), j-kolari@tamu.edu The distance to the global frontier constitutes each bank’s technol-
(J.W. Kolari), r.vanlamoen@uu.nl (R.C.R. van Lamoen). ogy gap, which decreases if the bank manages to innovate. The use
1
See literature reviews by Kamien and Schwartz (1982) and Symeonidis (1996).

0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.12.015
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1591

of this innovation measure enables us to examine the innovation whether the consolidation process has gone too far, and examines
behavior of financial firms for which patents and R&D expenditures the impact of interstate banking deregulation. Section 6
are unavailable as metrics. Each innovation leads to lower produc- concludes.
tion costs in both the theoretical model and our proposed innova-
tion measure. Because a well-functioning financial sector is crucial 2. Financial innovation in US banking
to the economy (King and Levine, 1993; Pagano, 1993; Levine,
1997, 2004; Levine and Zervos, 1998; Levine et al., 2000), it is Deregulation of prices, products, and geographic restrictions on
important to understand its innovation dynamics. Recent work permissible banking activities over the past 30 years has increased
by Michalopoulos et al. (2009) demonstrates in a dynamic setting the contribution of market forces to financial innovation in the
that continuous financial innovation is a requirement for endoge- banking industry. In this regard, Miller (1986) argues that efforts
nous growth. While numerous studies have been published on to circumvent regulatory and tax burdens are key drivers of
bank innovation, they typically focus on specific bank technologies, financial innovation. Also, Vives (2001) observes that deregulation
rather than bank innovation in general. For example, Hannan and and financial innovations, including advances in information technol-
McDowell (1984) examine how market concentration affects the ogy, management techniques, and risk adjustment (e.g., derivatives,
adoption of ATMs. Our technology gap measure provides estimates securitization, and off-balance sheet activities), have substantially
of overall innovation to gain a broader perspective on its potential increased competition in US and European banking markets.
effects. Also, while most competition/innovation studies employ Frame and White (2004) comprehensively survey the small
industry-level data and therefore implicitly assume the same relation body of financial innovation literature comprised of 39 empirical
across industries despite considerable cross-industry heterogeneity, studies. They define financial innovation as comprising activities
our new measure affords the opportunity to study competition/inno- that internally reduce bank costs and risks or externally better
vation behavior at the firm level for a single industry. meet the convenience and needs of customers.2 Financial innova-
Second, we document the impact of historic consolidation in the tions are grouped into new products (e.g., automated teller machines
US banking industry on innovation behavior. Driven by globaliza- or ATMs, credit and debit cards, adjustable-rate mortgages, etc.),
tion, technological change, deregulation, and other forces, the US new production processes (e.g., electronic payments and record
banking industry has experienced dramatic changes in its structure keeping, automated credit scoring models, securitization of loans,
and competition (Jones and Critchfield, 2005). In our sample period etc.) and new organizational forms (e.g., interstate banking organiza-
from 1984 to 2004, the industry consolidated from over 14,000 tions, diversified banks with traditional and nontraditional financial
banks to around 7500 banks (Jones and Critchfield, 2005). In this services, etc.). The practical significance of these financial innova-
period, the average size of banks grew as banks with assets totaling tions lies in their contribution to enhancing financial intermediation,
more than $10 billion increased their share of industry assets from which allocates savings to investment and thereby contributes to
30% to over 70% (Rhoades, 2000). Similar consolidation trends have economic growth (see King and Levine (1993), Levine (1997), and
occurred in the European Union, United Kingdom, Japan, and other others cited above). Frame and White (2004) conclude that the fol-
countries around the world (Carletti et al., 2007). A major concern lowing factors tend to increase innovation in financial services: reg-
is that consolidation has lowered competition. For example, Cetor- ulation, institution size, higher education and income, and first-
elli and Strahan (2006) find that, in banking markets that are mover, cost, and reputational advantages. Given the important role
highly concentrated, nonfinancial firms have significantly less ac- of financial innovation in the financial system and the economy as
cess to credit (see also Stiroh and Strahan, 2003). Also, Fraser a whole, they infer that there is considerable room for future re-
et al. (2011) report evidence of market power after large bank search in this ‘‘relatively untilled field.’’
mergers that adversely affects the stock prices of borrowing firms. A separate branch of the banking literature relevant to this pa-
Relevant to our purpose, a number of interesting questions natu- per examines technical change in the context of cost and profit effi-
rally arise. As consolidation has taken place, what are the coinci- ciency analyses of financial institutions.3 In general, the efficiency
dent trends in US bank competition and innovation over time? literature tends to support the institution size effect in financial
How has consolidation affected the relationship between competi- innovation cited by Frame and White (2004). Elyasiani and Mehdian
tion and innovation? And, what is the role of deregulation in bank (1990) and Hunter and Timme (1991) find that larger banks experi-
innovation dynamics? Our empirical analyses provide detailed evi- enced greater cost efficiency gains compared to small banks in the
dence on these important questions. 1980s. Humphrey (1993) finds that large banks had more technical
In brief, based on annual data series for all insured US commer- change than small banks in the late 1970s. Also, Berger and Mester
cial banks spanning two decades, our evidence strongly supports (1997) find that, while large banks had decreasing cost efficiency
an inverted-U relationship between bank competition and technol- over time, they exhibited increasing profit efficiency compared to
ogy gaps. This finding agrees with theory and evidence by Aghion small banks in the 1980s and 1990s. Similarly, Berger and Mester
et al. (2005b) and Hashmi (2007) in other industries. We also find (2003) report decreasing cost productivity but increasing profit pro-
that average price cost margins have increased considerably during ductivity among US banks in the period 1991–1997. Consistent with
our sample period, which implies declining competition as consol- these studies, Wheelock and Wilson (1999) report greater techno-
idation has occurred. Further evidence suggests that: (1) the US logical gains among large banks in the 1980s and 1990s, which led
banking industry as a whole has consolidated beyond its optimal them to conclude that competitive and regulatory changes in the
innovation level and (2) interstate banking deregulation has low- banking industry have benefited larger over smaller banks. Lastly,
ered innovation through its effect on competition. In view of these Altunbas et al. (1999) find that larger banks in 15 European countries
adverse trends, we discuss potential implications to policy makers
making sweeping financial reforms and changes in prudential reg- 2
Van Horne (1985) more broadly defines financial innovation as making markets
ulations at the present time. more operationally efficient or complete (i.e., the number and types of securities that
Section 2 provides a brief overview of studies on financial span all possible return and risk contingencies or states of the world demanded by
innovation in the US banking industry. Section 3 describes the market participants). Also, Allen and Gale (1994) propose that financial innovation is
associated with efficient risk sharing due to the completion of markets.
theoretical model developed by Aghion et al. (2005b) to explain 3
For example, Van Horne (1985) observes that financial innovations are motivated
the inverted-U pattern. Section 4 overviews the data and method- by operational inefficiencies. Less efficient financial institutions are less competitive
ology. Section 5 empirically investigates the existence of an in- and, therefore, less likely to survive. Importantly, as Ross (1989) points out,
verted-U relationship, discusses model robustness, considers institutions are the major agents of innovation in financial markets.
1592 J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

experienced more gains from technical change than smaller banks in banks gain an information advantage over other banks. Conversely,
the period 1989–1996. if information dissemination is increased by information technology
While the above studies find that institution size is positively innovations, competition will increase due to widespread access to
related to financial innovation in line with Schumpeter’s hypothe- proprietary information that levels the playing field. They conclude
sis, few empirical studies have attempted to link financial innova- that the relative importance of these two information effects is an
tion and competition. Based on a sample of about 3800 US empirical question.
commercial banks in the period 1971–1979, Hannan and McDo- In sum, consistent with empirical evidence, theoretical studies
well (1984) report evidence that the likelihood of ATM adoption predict a variety of competition and innovation relationships for
is positively related to bank size, market concentration (i.e., financial services, in addition to a greater likelihood of financial
three-firm concentration ratios in SMSAs or counties), and mem- innovation by larger institutions. Previous empirical studies typi-
bership in a bank holding company. They infer that Schumpeter’s cally focus on a particular innovation, rather than total innovation
hypothesis is supported by these empirical results. Chourchane by financial institutions. The main reason for this limitation is the
et al. (2002) employ bivariate and multivariate logit analyses to inability to measure overall innovation. We seek to contribute to
examine the competitive effects of internet banking for about the financial innovation literature by proposing and estimating a
1600 US commercial banks in 1999. Unlike Hannan and McDowell, general measure of innovation referred to as the technology gap.
they find that the market concentration of competitive rivals low- Our new innovation measure enables tests of theories about com-
ers the likelihood of banks entering internet banking markets. Also, petition and innovation as well as new insights into the innova-
faced with uncertain demand, larger banks are more likely to enter tiveness of the US banking industry.
internet banking than smaller banks, who prefer to delay their
investment decision until larger banks have committed assets to
the technological change. Another study by Mantel and McHugh 3. The model
(2001) considers the question of whether, given regulatory over-
sight of consumer protection issues, there is sufficient competition Aghion et al. (2005b) propose a model that includes both an
and innovation in consumer electronic payments, including credit ‘‘escape competition effect’’ (positive effect of competition on inno-
cards, debit cards, e-cash, and smart cards. They conclude that pri- vation) and a ‘‘Schumpeterian effect’’ (negative effect of competi-
vate sector efforts to achieve adequate consumer safety are as tion on innovation) to explain an inverted-U relationship
effective as regulatory intervention. Also, financial innovation in between competition and innovation. Their theoretical and empir-
electronic consumer payments would increase to a greater extent ical analyses are conducted at the industry level. By contrast, we
due to market forces than regulation. Finally, Akhavein et al. focus on competition and innovation behavior at the firm level
(2005) test for the impact of market competition on the adoption by applying their model to the banking industry and deriving the
of small business credit scoring for a sample of 96 large US banks average flow of innovations for a bank operating in one or several
in 1997. Like prior studies, bank organization size is positively re- geographical banking markets.
lated to early adoption of credit scoring methods. However, market The Aghion et al. (2005b) model assumes a continuum (with to-
concentration as measured by an average Herfindahl–Hirschman tal mass equal to one) of identical consumers in the economy that
index (HHI) across local geographic markets is not significant. use a constant intertemporal discount rate r and have the utility
Overall, these studies yield mixed evidence on the link between function u(yt) = ln yt. Here we extend their model to the banking
competition and innovation but confirm larger banks are innova- industry. Banks produce the final good yt (financial services) using
tion leaders. input services from a continuum of intermediate sectors according
R1
Other studies posit a variety of theories concerning innovation to the production function ln yt ¼ 0 ln xjt ; dj, where xjt is an aggre-
and financial services. Van Horne (1985) conjectures that uncer- gate of two intermediate goods A and B produced by two banks
tainty about regulations, tax laws, inflation, international events, (duopoly) in sector j. Each intermediate sector represents a geo-
and technology will lead to a continuing stream of financial inno- graphical (e.g., local) banking market.5 The subutility function is de-
vations. Boot and Thakor (1997) theorize that a universal banking fined as xj = xAj + xBj. Consumers maximize the subutility function
system comprised of joint commercial and investment banks will with respect to their (normalized) budget constraint.6
produce less innovation than functionally-separated financial It is assumed that the bank production function exhibits con-
institutions due to adverse spillover effects of (for example) secu- stant returns, and banks use labor as an input at the (exogenous)
rities innovations on commercial banking profits. However, they normalized wage rate w(t) = 1. The unit cost of production is
argue that in mixed financial systems with both universal and independent of the quantity produced, such that the unit cost
functionally-separate institutions, large universal banks will have structure becomes ci ¼ cki , where cki is the unit labor require-
a competitive advantage to influence changes in regulations that ment of bank i, c is the size of an innovation (assumed to be lar-
favor financial innovations in which scope economies are ger than one), and ki is the technological level of a bank. Hence,
required.4 Related work by Bhattacharyya and Nanda (2000) theo- innovations lower the unit cost by decreasing the required units
rizes that larger investment banks will be more likely to innovate of labor per unit of output. The relative costs of a bank depend
new financial services due to larger market shares with greater rev- only on the technological gap. The maximum technological gap
enue incentives. Smaller banks have less incentive to innovate but in a sector is assumed to be one (m = 1), and technological ad-
are expected to be more aggressive than large banks in their intro- vances occur through step-by-step innovations instead of leap-
duction strategy (e.g., attracting large bank customers). And, another frogging models.7 The R&D cost function w(n) = n2/2 is expressed
study by Hauswald and Marquez (2003) proposes that financial in units of labor n. Furthermore, a Poisson process for innovations
innovation in information processing and dissemination can change
competition in the banking industry (see also Wilhelm, 2001). Ad- 5
Competition in banking occurs at a local level for many products and services
vances in information technology that improve information process- (e.g., see Pilloff, 1999, and Berger et al., 1999).
6
ing capabilities of banks will tend to decrease competition as some The income of consumers is normalized to unity by using expenditure as the
numeraire for prices in each period.
7
It is impossible for laggard banks to surpass a technological leader by means of an
innovation without drawing even with this leader. See Aghion et al. (1997) for several
4
The stakeholder capture theory proposes that some agents can sway public policy appealing features of a model of step-by-step innovation compared to the Schumpe-
decisions in their favor (e.g., see Kroszner and Strahan, 1999). terian leapfrogging models.
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1593

is assumed and laggards or neck-and-neck banks move one techno- tition increases (i.e., a Schumpeterian effect). The reason for this
logical step ahead with a Poisson hazard rate of n (R&D intensity) negative effect on innovation is that more competition reduces
by spending w(n) on R&D. The laggard bank moves ahead with the rents that a laggard bank can attain by innovating. Whether
the hazard rate n + h if it puts effort into R&D, where h is a help the escape competition or Schumpeterian effect dominates de-
factor that represents R&D spillovers or the ability to copy the tech- pends on the fraction of leveled and unleveled sectors in the stea-
nology of a leader. The R&D intensities of leading banks, laggard dy state, as determined by the research intensities of laggards and
banks, and neck-and-neck banks are n1, n1, and n0, respectively. neck-and-neck banks.
By assumption, leaders do not innovate (n1 = 0), as laggard banks We extend Aghion et al. (2005b) by examining how the average
can copy their previous technology immediately (so that the max- flow of innovations of a firm (as opposed to industry) changes with
imum gap remains one). competition. The steady-state probabilities that a market is leveled
Product market competition is modeled by the ability of banks and unleveled are l0 and l1, respectively. During any unit time
to collude. It is assumed that banks are able to collude if they are interval, the steady-state probability that a market changes state
operating in a leveled bank market segment but cannot collude if (from leveled to unleveled or vice versa) is an aggregate of the
the bank market segment is unleveled. It is important to note that probability of being a certain type of market times the Poisson haz-
multi-market contact may facilitate collusive behavior. For exam- ard rate that firms move ahead. For unleveled and leveled markets
ple, it is possible to give a competitor a higher market share in this probability is l1(n1 + h) and 2l0n0, respectively. The condi-
one market to induce collusive behavior, while using the other tion l1(n1 + h) = 2l0n0 must hold in the steady-state, as the frac-
market for disciplining purposes. We assume that a bank may face tion of leveled and unleveled markets must remain unchanged. The
another bank in several markets, but it does not face the same bank probability of being a laggard bank (branch) or leader in a certain
in all markets.8 Furthermore, it is assumed that a bank facing one geographical market is pl1 and (1  p)l1, respectively.11 The aver-
competitor in several markets has the same technology gap in these age flow of innovations for a bank or branch in a geographical mar-
markets.9 The profits of laggard and leader banks are p1 = 0 and ket is12:
p1 = 1  c1, respectively. Laggard banks make zero profit, as leaders
capture the market and earn a profit equal to their revenue (normal- ð1 þ pÞ2n0 ðn1 þ hÞ
ized to one due to the income in the budget constraint) minus the I ¼ l0 n0 þ pl1 ðn1 þ hÞ þ ð1  pÞl1 n1 ¼ ; ð3Þ
2n0 þ n1 þ h
costs (equal to the inverse of the innovation parameter c). The profit
of neck-and-neck banks ranges from zero to one-half of the profits of which equals the sum of the probability of being a certain type of
a technological leader. The inability to collude leads to zero profits, bank (branch) times the research intensity.13 This average flow of
as banks are assumed to be in Bertrand competition with undifferen- innovations in a certain geographical market follows an inverted-U
 
tiated products and similar unit costs, p0 ¼ ep1 ; e 2 0; 12 . Competi- pattern.14 Moreover, the average flow of innovations from the per-
tion is parameterized by D = 1  e and equals the incremental profit spective of bank IT that operates in S geographical markets is the
of an innovating bank in a leveled market normalized by the profit of sum of the average flow of innovations in each geographical market
a leader. j:
Aghion et al. (2005b) derive the research intensities and exam-
ine how they are affected by changes in competition. It is assumed
X
S
that the discount rate is zero (r = 0). The research intensities of IT ¼ Ij : ð4Þ
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2 j¼1
neck-and-neck banks and laggards are n0 ¼ h þ 2Dp1  h and
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2 The intuition behind the inverted-U relationship is straightfor-
n1 ¼ h þ n20 þ 2p1  h  n0 , respectively.10 Differentiating these
ward. If the degree of competition is initially low, neck-and-neck
research intensities with respect to the competition parameter D banks earn high profits and have little incentive to innovate. By
gives (see Aghion et al., 2005b, p. 722): contrast, laggard banks have relatively more incentive to innovate
due to low initial profits (i.e., zero in the model) but high potential
@n0 p1 profits if they manage to catch up with a technological leader. We
¼ > 0: ð1Þ
@ D n0 þ h can infer that banks will leave their status as a neck-and-neck (lag-
 
@n1 @n0 n0 gard) bank relatively slowly (rapidly). Consequently, a bank will be
¼ 1 þ < 0: ð2Þ
@D @D n1 þ h þ n0 a neck-and-neck bank most of the time, such that the escape-com-
petition effect dominates. If there is not much competition in a
Obviously, from Eq. (1), the research intensity of a neck-and-neck market, increased competition should lead to a higher average
firm is positively affected by increases in the degree of competi- innovation rate. The reverse is true in the case of high initial com-
tion (i.e., an escape-competition effect). Their innovation incen- petition. Now laggard banks have little incentive to innovate due to
tives increase with more competition, as their pre-innovation nominal gain after a successful innovation. However, neck-and-
rents are reduced more than post-innovation rents. Eq. (2) shows neck banks have relatively more incentive to innovate due to large
that the research intensity of a laggard bank decreases as compe- incremental potential profit. These outcomes imply that banks will
leave their status as a neck-and-neck (laggard) bank relatively rap-
8
idly (slowly). In this scenario, a bank will be a laggard bank most of
According to this assumption, the geographical markets are not represented by
the same set of firms. Without this assumption, only a positive or negative effect of
the time, such that the Schumpeterian effect dominates and the
competition on innovation is observed at a particular point in time if firms face leader never innovates. Hence, if the degree of competition is ini-
similar technological gaps across markets. This assumption does not exclude the tially high, increased competition should lead to a lower average
possibility that large firms are present in all markets, but implies that there is some innovation rate.
variety in the set of competitors.
9
Suppose that banks A and B are competitors in two local markets. If bank A is a
11
technological leader in one market, this bank can use its technological advantage in The probability that a bank or branch operates in an unleveled sector pl1 +
both markets. This assumption implies that markets are either leveled or unleveled. (1  p)l1 = l1.
12
Our treatment here is similar to what Park and Pennacchi (2009) use for large multi- Since two neck-and-neck firms are trying to gain a technological lead, the average
market banking organizations. flow of innovations in an intermediate sector is equal to I = 2l0n0 + l1(n1 + h).
10 13
See Aghion et al. (2005b) for a derivation of equilibrium research intensities as The term (1  p)l1 n1 = 0, since it is assumed that leaders do not innovate (n1 = 0).
14
well as escape competition and Schumpeterian effects. See Aghion et al. (2005b) for the proof at the industry level.
1594 J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

4. Data and methodology tween zero and one (i.e., the firm is on the meta frontier).17 At
t = 1 the firm faces a technology gap of OA/OD, which narrows to
4.1. Data OA/OB at t = 2 as the firm improves its technology set. While firm I
faces a technology gap of OA/OD in period t = 1, the technology gap
Year-end 1984–2004 data are gathered for individual US in- of firm II is smaller (OF/OG).
sured commercial banks from Call Reports of Income and Condi- We follow recent work by Battese et al. (2004), O’Donnell et al.
tion provided by the Federal Reserve System. Data are expressed (2008), and Bos and Schmiedel (2007) by obtaining technology
in 1984 US dollars. gaps from initially employing Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA)
to estimate the minimum cost frontier available in each year and
then enveloping the annual cost frontiers to obtain a meta frontier
4.2. Estimating technology gaps (see also Hayami and Ruttan (1970), Mundlak and Hellinghausen
(1982), and Lau and Yotopoulos (1989)).18
Metrics for measuring technical change have evolved over time. In the first step, the following annual translog cost frontiers are
Led by Tinbergen (1942), the econometric approach utilizes a time estimated using stochastic frontier analysis19:
trend when estimating the cost (or production) function. Likewise,
the index number theory approach of Solow (1957) identifies neu-
TC it ¼ f  ðwit ; yit ; zit Þev it þuit ; ð5Þ
tral technical change with constant marginal rates of substitution. where w represents the vector of input prices, y is the output vector,
As shown in Fig. 1a, these approaches capture innovation by means z is a vector of control variables, v is random noise assumed to be
of a parallel shift in the cost curve, in which other parameters of i.i.d. N(0, rv), and u is the inefficiency term assumed to be i.i.d.
the cost function are unchanged. Nj(l, ru)j. To take into account inefficiency, we use stochastic fron-
Diewert (1976) and others add flexibility to the measurement of tier analysis, which is ignored by conventional measures of produc-
technical change by relaxing the assumption that the latter was tivity (e.g., TFP) that measure technical change as efficiency change
constant. Likewise, Baltagi and Griffin (1988) introduce a general (Bos et al., 2009).
index of technical change that allows for nonconstant technical We assume that banks minimize total costs and operate in per-
change. Building on advances by Gollop and Jorgenson (1980) fectly competitive input markets. Bank production is modeled
and others, they further allow for biased technical change, as mar- using the well-known intermediation approach.20 Output y consists
ginal rates of substitution are allowed to vary over time. Consistent of year-end stocks of loans, investments, and off-balance sheet
with these approaches, Fig. 1a shows a nonparallel shift in the cost items. Input prices w correspond to the prices of fixed assets, labor,
curve is possible.15 and borrowed funds.21 The equity ratio z is included as a control var-
Since the cost function describes the process whereby firms are iable to account for different risk profiles of banks (Hughes and Mes-
assumed to minimize costs in producing output, the set of esti- ter, 1993). The composed error term in Eq. (5) is eit = mit + uit. Firm-
mated parameters reflects the state of technology. What separates specific inefficiency estimates u are obtained by using the expected
technical change from other means of minimizing costs (such as value of uit conditional on the total error eit (i.e., E(uitjeit)). Cost effi-
adjusting the input mix or reducing waste) is the fact that, whereas ciency score estimates are obtained as follows:
the latter measures use the currently implemented technology,
dit ¼ ½expðu
CE ^ it Þ; ð6Þ
technical change consists of the invention or adoption of new tech-
nology. In an attempt to reconcile this view of technical change where CE equals one for banks that operate on the annual frontier
with the notion of estimating cost functions, early work by Hayami (no inefficiency). Banks with inefficiencies operate above the annual
and Ruttan (1970), Mundlak and Hellinghausen (1982) and Lau cost frontier and have cost efficiency scores less than one.
and Yotopoulos (1989) introduce a meta frontier approach. The In the second step, the meta frontier is estimated as the enve-
meta frontier encompasses the set of available technologies across lope around the annual cost frontiers. We utilize the parameter
firms and/or across time. Technical change consists of the adoption estimates for the annual cost frontiers and obtain estimates of
of a new technology as measured against the benchmark meta the technology gap (GAP) by fitting the minimum cost meta fron-
frontier, which combines all available technologies.16 tier (fmeta) as follows:
Fig. 1a illustrates the notion of technical change using a simple
paradigm with two inputs (x1, x2) and one output (y) for two firms I X
T X
N

Min:Distance ¼ jlnf ðwit ; yit ; zit Þ
and II. Two annual frontiers are drawn corresponding to t = 1 and
t¼1 i¼1
time t = 2. Each frontier represents the minimum cost curve based
on available technology for a certain level of output. The cost effi-  lnfmeta ðwit ; yit ; zit Þjs:t: lnfmeta ðÞ

ciency of firm I located at point E at time t = 1 is OD/OE. If firm I is at 6 lnf ðÞ: ð7Þ
point C at t = 2, its efficiency is OB/OC. Fig. 1a also shows that firm II
is located at point H and faces a cost efficiency of OG/OH at time In this constrained minimization problem, the absolute distance be-
t = 1. The dashed line that envelops the annual frontier represents tween the annual cost frontier and the meta frontier is minimized
the minimum cost frontier over the whole period, or meta frontier. subject to the constraint that the total cost from the annual frontier
Innovation results in a lower gap between the annual minimum is equal to or larger than total cost from the meta frontier. As a re-
cost frontier and the meta frontier. sult, the technology gap is defined as:
Innovation is reflected by changes in the technology gap, which
17
measures the difference between currently available technology The notion of technology gaps was first used by Krugman (1979) and proxied in
the literature by total factor productivity (TFP) differentials (Griffith et al., 2004).
and optimal technology over the whole period with values be- 18
Kumbhakar and Lovell (2000) provide an elaborate discussion of the development
and application of SFA to efficiency measurement.
15 19
The relationship between biased technical change and innovation is explained in Homogeneity of degree one in input prices and symmetry are imposed.
20
Acemoglu (2002). See Freixas and Rochet (1997) for a more elaborate discussion on measuring the
16
Our approach to measuring innovation via shifts in the cost function (i.e., activities of banks.
21
technical change) has considerable precedent in previous empirical literature Input prices are computed as follows: the price of fixed assets is depreciation
(Subramanian and Nilakanta, 1996; Ruttan, 1997; Agrell et al., 2002; Bleaney and divided by fixed assets, the price of labor is personnel expenses divided by the
Wakelin, 2002). Also, our approach closely aligns with the theoretical concept of number of fte-employees and the price of borrowed funds is interest expenses
technology gap posited by Aghion et al. (2001, 2005b). divided by total borrowed funds.
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1595

.15
x2/y

.1
Frontier at t = 1

Density
E
D H

.05
A BC
F Frontier at t = 2

x1/y

0
1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
annual frontiers meta frontier Year

Fig. 1. Technology gap ratio.

fmeta ðwit ; yit ; zit Þ 4.3. Measuring competition


GAPit ¼ : ð8Þ
f  ðwit ; yit ; zit Þ
We follow Aghion et al. (2005b) by using the price cost margin
Innovations by firms may lead to improvements in their technology (viz., Lerner index or markup) as the main indicator of competition
set and, consequently, a smaller gap between the current technol- and subtract it from one as follows:
ogy set and the (potentially available) best technology set, or meta  
frontier. The result is an increase in GAPit, which is bounded be- Pit þ F it
C it ¼ 1  ; ð9Þ
tween 0 and 1, where the latter is reached when firms operate on Rit
the meta frontier.
We can now relate the role innovation plays in the model of where Pit is the profit of a bank, Fit represents fixed costs, and Rit
Aghion et al. (2005b) to the technology gap derived in Eq. (8) denotes sales. The price cost margin is calculated by dividing the
and depicted in Fig. 1a. Recall their model crucially assumes that net income after taxes and extraordinary items plus expenses of
leaders do not innovate and that the maximum gap remains one. premises and fixed assets by total non-interest income plus total
Additionally, innovations are expected to lower the unit cost of interest income.
production, laggards cannot surpass the leader without first draw- The price cost margin has a number of attractive features. First,
ing even, and neck-and-neck firms may innovate and move the it is a firm-specific measure of competition instead of a measure
technology frontier forward. Clearly, the technology gap derived based on a certain geographical market. Because some banks com-
above satisfies these conditions. pete mainly at the local level and others mainly at the national or
The technology gap of a leader that is positioned on the global international level, with a firm-specific price cost margin, we can
frontier in two consecutive periods will maintain a technology assume that all changes in competition are reflected in the price
gap equal to one. Likewise, a laggard can close the technology cost margins of banks regardless of the geographical market in
gap by lowering his cost (catching up) and moving towards the glo- which banks are located. Second, changes in the price cost margin
bal frontier (lowering the technology gap). Neck-and-neck firms can reflect both changes in a firm’s profits and changes in its costs.
may operate on the annual cost frontier under the best potential Hence, the price cost margin incorporates both the Schumpeterian
available technology in the current period and, subsequently, shift effect and the escape competition effect. If innovation only changes
the annual cost frontier towards the global frontier in the next per- firms’ costs, then regressing the technology gap ratio on the price
iod by improving their technology set through innovations. In sum, cost margin can never result in an inverted-U relationship. Of
the technology gap as a measure of overall innovation agrees with course, this feature of the price cost margin also has a downside:
with the concept of innovation proposed by Aghion et al. (2005b). if the price cost margin only changes due to changes in firms’ costs,
Fig. 1b shows the distribution of banks over the period 1984– it suffers from endogeneity. For this reason, we take into account
2004 with a technology gap equal to 1. These banks were operating endogeneity in our estimation procedure described in the next
on the global frontier and thus utilized the best potential technol- subsection.
ogy set over the period given their combination of outputs and in- From Table 1, we observe that the competition measure ranges
put prices. Most banks had a technology gap equal to 1 during the between 0 and 2. Outliers have been removed after visual inspec-
late 1980s and early 1990s compared to the other years. By con- tion of scatter plots of the technology gap against the price cost
trast, there were relatively fewer banks operating at the best avail- margin. A range between 1 and 1 for the price cost margin was
able technology in the early to mid-2000s. It should be noted that considered to be reasonable. Therefore, the analysis excludes
some banks may innovate in a certain year, while other banks 1324 observations outside this range (i.e., less than 1% of the total
introduce similar technologies or adopt the same technology in la- amount of observations). Some authors choose to remove negative
ter years. This behavior may result in higher technology gaps for price cost margins, but this approach creates a bias in the results as
banks that innovate earlier and an increase in the technology gap only firms with positive price cost margins are considered. The
for banks that innovate (or adopt the same technology) in later dataset contains 14,073 observations with negative price cost mar-
periods.22 gins. Excluding negative price cost margins also results in an in-
verted-u relationship, but the domain in which the
22
For example, Hannan and McDowell (1984) find that large banks have a higher Schumpeterian effect dominates is smaller. Our empirical findings
conditional probability of adopting ATMs. were robust to different thresholds.
1596 J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

Table 1
Descriptive statistics.

Full sample Observations Mean Std. dev. Minimum Maximum


Technology gap 151,476 0.989 0.029 1.07e08 1.000
Price cost margin 151,476 0.179 0.090 0.993 0.964
Total assets (millions of USD) 151,476 458.740 7416.978 1.067 967,365
Risk (equity/total assets) 151,476 0.096 0.034 7.36e05 0.998
Salary expenses per fte in thousands of USD 151,476 35.143 12.756 0.048 537.160
1988
Technology gap 11,492 0.997 0.013 0.258 1.000
Price cost margin 11,492 0.127 0.102 0.989 0.470
Total assets (millions of USD) 11,492 231.109 2333.1 1.067 150,241
Risk (equity/total assets) 11,492 0.085 0.029 7.36e05 0.426
Salary expenses per fte in thousands of USD 11,492 25.399 6.174 2.182 129.219
1994
Technology gap 9772 0.993 0.020 0.030 1.000
Price cost margin 9772 0.199 0.072 0.898 0.964
Total assets (millions of USD) 9772 301.159 2849.972 1.924 210,487
Risk (equity/total assets) 9772 0.095 0.031 0.004 0.699
Salary expenses per fte in thousands of USD 9772 33.094 9.201 1.111 206.214
2004
Technology gap 6843 0.965 0.057 0.157 1.000
Price cost margin 6843 0.255 0.094 0.725 0.718
Total assets (millions of USD) 6843 1000.112 17129.53 3.152 967,365
Risk (equity/total assets) 6843 0.105 0.037 0.038 0.832
Salary expenses per fte in thousands of USD 6843 50.111 15.900 1.8 347.2667

The descriptive statistics are based on the sample of the preferred specification in Table 2 (specification 2). Some years (1984–1987) are not included in the sample due to the
use of first-differences and lags as instruments. The total number of observations is approximately 220,000. We obtain 151,476 observations in the preferred specification due
to missing values of certain variables, the exclusion of outliers, applying first-differences and using lags of the endogenous regressors as instruments.

4.4. Empirical specifications and estimation procedures first differences. An important assumption is that these lags are not
correlated with the disturbance term.24 The Hansen test is per-
We consider several empirical specifications based on the fol- formed to examine the instrument exogeneity assumption. Under
lowing model: the null hypothesis in this test, the instruments are valid. We inves-
tigate the relevance of the instruments by examining the F-statistics
GAPit ¼ b1 C it þ b2 C 2it þ c0 Zit þ ai þ eit ; ð10Þ of the instrument set in regressions of the endogenous variables on
where the technology gap is the dependent variable, Cit is the com- the instrument set (and other exogenous variables).
petition variable, c0 is a 1  n parameter vector, and Zit is a n  1 Additionally, we employ a model specification in which inter-
vector of control variables. A squared term for the competition var- state banking deregulation at the state level is used as an instru-
iable is included to account for the inverted-U relationship between ment. Before the late 1970s, restrictions on interstate banking
competition and innovation proposed by Aghion et al. (2005b). Tak- protected banks from outside competition. Deregulation concern-
ing the first-differences of Eq. (10) to eliminate the unobserved het- ing interstate banking unleashed competitive forces by allowing
erogeneity ai gives: banks to enter new markets and pose a threat to incumbent banks
(Stiroh and Strahan, 2003). This regime shift is a dummy variable
DGAPit ¼ b1 DC it þ b2 DC 2it þ c0 DZit þ Deit : ð11Þ that takes the value one from the year in which states entered into
The competition variable may be endogenous due to reverse an interstate banking agreement with other states, and zero before
causality with the innovation variable. To deal with this endogene- this year (Stiroh and Strahan, 2003). However, it is questionable
ity, it is necessary to find relevant instruments (i.e., correlated with whether such policy reforms in the banking sector are suitable
the endogenous variable) that are not correlated with the error instruments for competition. Kroszner and Strahan (1999) argue
term (instrument exogeneity). We use the two-step efficient gen- that several technological and financial innovations influenced
eralized method of moments estimator (GMM), where lags of these the deregulation process by affecting the lobby behavior of banks.
endogenous variables in levels are used as instruments for the In this regard, these authors cite some specific technologies (e.g.,
endogenous variables in first-differences.23 The lag structure will the introduction of the ATM) that spurred banks’ efforts to seek
depend on the order of serial correlation in the residuals. If there deregulation. Even though the technology gap ratio captures a
is no serial correlation in the residuals (in levels), lags from period broad spectrum of implemented innovations, the endogeneity of
t  2 (and onwards) can be used as instruments. However, if there this regime shift due to reverse causality with technological devel-
is first-order serial correlation (in the residual in levels), lags from opments remains questionable.
period t  3 (and onwards) can be used. We perform the Arellano- One empirical drawback of neglecting control variables in Eq.
Bond test for serial correlation. This test is based on an examination (10) is that other factors that are correlated with competition can
of residuals in first differences. Testing for first-order serial correla- influence innovation. Therefore, we introduce a model specifica-
tion in levels is based on testing for second-order serial correlation in tion with several control variables that allows for the possibility

23 24
OLS estimations were performed for exploratory purposes, but the OLS estimator An argument against the exogeneity of these lags is that the dependent variable
gives biased and inconsistent estimates of causal effects in the presence of in the current period may reflect expectations in the past. If this is the case and
endogenous regressors. GMM has some efficiency gains compared to the traditional behavior in the past is based on expectations of the future, these lags as instruments
IV/2SLS estimator. For example, the two-step GMM estimator utilizes an optimal are not exogenous. For example, the technology gap ratio in the current period may
weighting matrix that minimizes the asymptotic variance of the estimator. Also, reflect expectations concerning the technology gap in previous periods, and this
GMM is more efficient than the 2SLS estimator in the presence of heteroskedasticity. expectation may have affected competitive behavior in the past.
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1597

of nonzero elements in the parameter vector c. Our control vari- point of view, we also performed a Hausman-Wu test for the pre-
ables are equity divided by total assets, firm size in terms of total ferred specification (with lags from period t  3 and t  4 as instru-
assets, and the average wage per fte-employee. Equity to total as- ments) to examine the endogeneity of these variables from an
sets is an inverse measure of debt pressure. Aghion et al. (2005a) empirical point of view. The endogeneity test showed that the com-
argue that debt pressure is positively related to innovation, as petition variable and its squared term should be treated as endoge-
firms increase innovation to escape the threat of bankruptcy. The nous regressors. Since the Arellano-Bond test for serial correlation
relationship between firm size and innovation is a Schumpeterian indicates first-order autocorrelation in the residuals in levels, the
hypothesis. Plausible explanations of a positive relationship be- lags are taken from periods t  3 and t  4. According to the Hansen
tween firm size and innovation are potential scale economies in test, the null hypothesis that the instruments are valid cannot be re-
R&D as well as diversification benefits that lower risk (Kamien jected. F-statistics are used to examine the instrument relevance
and Schwartz, 1982). Lastly, the variable average wage per full- assumption. The F-statistics for the regressions with the competition
time equivalent employee proxies for labor productivity and, variable and its squared term as a dependent variable are 905.16 and
therefore, is positively related to innovation. 545.13, respectively. Since an F-statistic of 10 is often used as a rule
We also estimate Eq. (11) for two different time periods to of thumb to examine instrument relevance, we conclude that the
examine the stability of the inverted-U pattern over time. The Rie- instruments are relevant. The optimal price cost margin in preferred
gle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 specification 1 is around 5.2%. Translated into 1984 dollars, a 1%
eliminated interstate banking restrictions at the national level point decrease in the price cost margin results on average in approx-
and is used to demarcate two periods: 1984–1993 and 1994–2004. imately $627,000,000 lower costs for the whole banking sector (eval-
uated at the average number of banks per year in the sample of
4.5. Descriptive statistics about 11,000).27
Fig. 2a shows the empirical relationship between the technol-
Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics for banks’ technology ogy gap ratio and competition measure based on the preferred
gap, price cost margin, total assets, equity ratio, and average wage model specification 1. These findings are consistent with the theo-
per fte-employee. The number of banks declined from about retical and empirical results of Aghion et al. (2005b) and Hashmi
14,000 in 1984 to 7500 in 2004. The descriptive statistics show (2007). Aghion et al. (2005b) use UK data (industry averages) over
that innovation decreased over the period, while price cost mar- the period 1973–1994 and find an optimal price cost margin
gins increased. We also observe increases in total assets, the equity around 6.0% after using policy instruments to deal with the endo-
ratio and salary expenses per fte-employee over the period. geneity of competition (see Aghion et al., 2005b, Table 1, specifica-
tion 4, p. 708).28
To examine the robustness of our results, we check whether an
5. Results inverse-U relationship exists for a number of alternative model
specifications. Table 2 gives the results. As shown there, model
This section describes the empirical results. First, we examine specification 2 shows the OLS estimation results without dealing
whether an inverted-U relationship exists. Second, we investigate with the endogeneity of the competition variable. The optimal
the robustness of our results by comparing them to alternative price cost margin is around 21.8%. However, the OLS estimator
specifications.25 Third, and last, we evaluate the effect of the consol- yields biased and inconsistent estimates of the causal effect of
idation process on innovation in US banking and investigate how the the regressor on an outcome in the presence of endogenous regres-
interstate banking deregulation process, which was aimed in part at sors. The competition variable and its squared term are endoge-
enhancing competition, affected innovation. nous from a theoretical point of view due to reverse causality
with innovation.
5.1. Is there an inverted-U relationship? Model specification 3 includes several control variables, and
lagged values of the competition variable (from periods t  3 and
Our main focus is to examine the effect of competition on inno- t  4) are used as instruments. An inverted-U relationship between
vation in US banking. Table 2 shows the results for the preferred competition and technology gap ratio is again obtained after con-
and alternative specifications (denoted 1 and 2–6, respectively). trolling for other factors that may affect innovation. According to
The results in Table 2 suggest a statistically significant inverted- the Hansen test, the instruments are valid in this specification.
U relationship between competition and technology gap ratios in The optimal price cost margin is around 5.8% and thus higher than
all model specifications. The two-step GMM estimator is used in the optimal markup from the preferred specification. The risk var-
most of the specifications.26 The competition variable and its iable’s (equity divided by total assets) estimated coefficient is neg-
squared term are individually and jointly significant at the 1% level. ative and significant at the 1% level. As such, a decrease in the
The preferred model specification 1 shows the results with lagged equity ratio is associated with a higher technology gap ratio. This
values in levels of the competition variable and its squared term as finding is consistent with Aghion et al. (2005a), who propose that
instruments. Although competition is endogenous from a theoretical debt pressure may lead to more innovation. Both firm size and the
average wage per fte-employee are not significantly related to the
25
We also performed a Kernel regression to allow for more flexibility in the
technology gap ratio.
relationship between competition and the technology gap ratio. The Kernel regression
also shows evidence of an inverted-U relationship between competition and
innovation.
26 27
An important drawback of the two-step efficient GMM estimator is that the This estimate is obtained by evaluating the marginal effect of the competition
standard errors are downward biased in small samples. Windmeijer (2005) proposes variable on the technology gap ratio at the average price cost margin. The marginal
a finite sample corrected estimate of the variance. The corrected variance leads to effect on the technology gap ratio is translated into annual frontier dollar values
more accurate inference in small samples. There is also a finite sample bias of the evaluated at the average global frontier, average technology gap ratio, and the average
two-step GMM estimator itself. Therefore, the correction of the variance is only useful technology gap ratio plus the marginal effect.
28
for improving inference when the estimator does not contain a large finite sample Hashmi (2007) also conducts an industry-level analysis based on data from
bias. However, these issues may not be a problem with the dataset used in this paper publicly-traded manufacturing firms in the US over the period 1970–1994. Instead of
due to the large number of observations. As a robustness check, we performed using an instrumental variable approach, he uses the first lag of the competition
regressions with the Windmeijer correction. As expected, the correction had a variable and the squared term directly. His empirical results indicate an optimal price
negligible effect on the standard errors. cost margin around 22.9% (see Hashmi, 2007, Table 2, specification 1, p.13).
1598 J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

Table 2
Competition and technology gaps.

Specification estimation 1 (Preferred) 2-step GMM 2OLS 1984– 32-Step GMM 4 2-Step GMM 5 2-Step GMM 6 2-Step GMM
procedure period 1984–2004 2004 1984–2004 1984–2004 1984–1993 1994–2004
DCompetitionit 1.600⁄⁄⁄ 0.0600⁄⁄⁄ 1.474⁄⁄⁄ 1.424⁄⁄⁄ 0.678⁄⁄⁄ 2.511⁄⁄⁄
(0.095) (0.009) (0.106) (0.069) (0.070) (0.180)
DCompetition2it 0.844⁄⁄⁄ 0.038⁄⁄⁄ 0.783⁄⁄⁄ 0.753⁄⁄⁄ 0.336⁄⁄⁄ 1.369⁄⁄⁄
(0.058) (0.005) (0.062) (0.042) (0.041) (0.121)
DEquityit/total assetsit 0.124⁄⁄⁄
(0.037)
DTotal assetsit ($1,000,000) 8.51e08
(6.40e08)
DAverage wage per fteit 5.88e05
(5.74e05)
AR (1) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
AR (2) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.002 0.000
AR (3) 0.969 0.100 0.795 0.814 0.798 0.899
Optimal price cost margin 5.2% 21.8% 5.8% 5.4% 0.01% 8.3%
Hansen J statistic 1.064 0.797 2.089 1.151 1.071
(0.588) (0.671) (0.148) (0.562) (0.585)
Observations 151,476 198,785 151,476 166,437 65,020 86,456

Based on Eq. (11). Standard errors (in parentheses) are robust against heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. Asterisks indicate significance at the following levels:  0.10,
 0.05. The p-values are reported for Arellano-Bond serial correlation tests. Chi-squared statistics and associated p-values are reported for the Hansen test.
⁄⁄⁄
0.01.

In model specification 4, the lag structure of the instruments is and most of our other model specifications (except for the OLS re-
changed by using lags of the competition variable and its squared sults). However, the average price cost margin declined in some
term from period t  3. A regime shift associated with interstate years in our sample period. For example, the average price cost
banking deregulation is added to the instrument set, such that margin declined every year from 1993 at 19.8% to 2000 at 16.9%.
there is one over-identifying restriction. The instruments are valid This means that movements along the inverted-U relationship
based on the Sargan–Hansen test. We find a statistically significant were toward the optimal point that enhances innovation. Never-
(individually and jointly) inverted-U relationship between compe- theless, the average price cost margins soared again in 2001 to
tition and the technology gap ratio, with an optimal markup of 2004 from around 17.3% to approximately 24.5%. This translates
approximately 5.4%. Model specifications 5 and 6 show the results into a movement away from the optimal point, given that banks
for time periods before and after the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking were positioned on average to the left side of the inverted-U rela-
and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994, respectively. Again, the in- tionship during the whole sample period. Thus, we find that the
verted-U pattern is robust in these two time periods. consolidation process in the US banking industry has been accom-
panied by: (1) a large increase in average price cost margins and (2)
5.2. How have the consolidation trend and interstate banking movement away from the optimal point that enhances innovation.
deregulation affected competition and innovation in US banking? How has interstate banking deregulation affected competition
and innovation? In model specification 4 the interstate banking
In an oral statement before the US House of Representatives, deregulation was used as an instrument for competition.29 This
Ludwig (1997) cites the Riegle-Neal Act as a successful example dummy variable assumes that the effect of deregulation was ab-
of how removing restrictions promotes competition and states that sorbed immediately in the competitive environment and does not
this ‘‘. . . increased competition should benefit consumers and busi- control for the exact year in which each state effectively deregulated
nesses through lower costs, increased access, improved services and allowed interstate banking. To allow for flexibility in the re-
and greater innovation.’’ More recently, Zarutskie (2006) has inves- sponse function, we follow Stiroh and Strahan (2003) and construct
tigated the effect of the Riegle-Neal Act on firm borrowing and a dummy variable for every two consecutive years after the (state-
investment. She concludes that banking market reforms such as specific) deregulation year in which the state entered into an inter-
Riegle Neal have a differential impact, which depends on the ef- state banking agreement with other states. The response function is
fects that the reforms have on (process) innovations in the indus- estimated by regressing the competition variable on the full set of
try, as the latter play an important role in bank loans to more dummy variables that captures the dynamic effects of deregula-
opaque and younger firms. Extending our earlier results from spec- tion.30 The equation is estimated in first-differences to eliminate
ifications 4–6 concerning an inverted-U pattern for competition the unobserved heterogeneity that is constant over time.
and innovation, we next consider whether the consolidation trend X
7
and interstate banking deregulation was associated with a change C it ¼ ak Dkst þ ai þ eit ; ð12Þ
in competition and innovation (i.e., a shift along the horizontal axis k¼1
in Fig. 2a).
Comparing the results for specifications 5 (for the period 1984–
1993) and 6 (for the period 1994–2004), we observe that the opti-
mal price cost margin increased significantly, from 0.01% to 8.3%. 29
We also estimated a specification in which we regressed the technology gap on
Fig. 2b shows the average price cost margin and number of banks the competition variables and the deregulation variable as a control variable. The
over the sample period 1984–2004. In this period the number of deregulation variable was insignificant in this specification.
30
banks declined from 14,323 in 1984 to 7548 in 2004, while the We also estimated a specification where we regressed the technology gap on the
competition variables and the deregulation dummies that captures the dynamic
average price cost margin increased from 9.3% in 1984 to 24.5% effects of deregulation. The total summed effect of the deregulation variables is
in 2004. The average price cost margin in 1984 was already higher insignificant in this specification. This suggests that there is no direct total effect of
than the optimal markup in our preferred specification (or 5.2%) deregulation on innovation.
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1599

.25
14000
.8
.6

Average price cost margin


Number of banks
12000

.2
Technology gap
.4

10000
.2

.15
0

8000

.1
−.2

1985 1990 1995 2000 2005


0 .5 1 1.5 2 Year
1−Price cost margin
Number of banks Average price cost margin

Fig. 2. The competition-innovation relationship.

Table 3
Our results show a clear downward trend in the response of compe-
Competition and the dynamic effect of interstate banking deregulation. tition to interstate banking deregulation. This evidence suggests that
the negative competitive effects of the regime shift increased over
Estimation procedure OLS
time. The total effect of deregulation on the price cost margin is ob-
DYears 1–2 0.000 tained by summing the coefficients of the deregulation variables. The
(0.001)
DYears 3–4 0.003⁄⁄
total effect of the interstate banking deregulation is significant at the
(0.001) 1% level and increased the price cost margins by approximately
DYears 5–6 0.007⁄⁄⁄ 12.6%.
(0.002) To make inferences about its effects on innovation, we need to
DYears 7–8 0.024⁄⁄⁄
know the level of competition before deregulation. The average
(0.002)
DYears 9–10 0.026⁄⁄⁄ price cost margin before the year of deregulation is 10.5%. This is
(0.002) higher than the optimal price cost margin in all of the specifica-
DYears 11–12 0.029⁄⁄⁄ tions, except for specification 2 in which endogeneity problems
(0.002) are not treated. In view of the inverted-U relationship between
DYears 13 thereafter 0.037⁄⁄⁄
(0.002)
competition and innovation, we infer that the technology gap ratio
decreased on average after the deregulation of interstate banking
Total summed effect 0.126⁄⁄⁄
(0.011)
(i.e., the leftward movement begins left of the optimal point). In
sum, the interstate banking deregulation process appears to have
Observations 202,168
led to a reduction in innovation in the US banking industry.
These results are based on Eq. (12). Standard errors (in parentheses) are robust with
respect to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. Asterisks indicate significance
at the following level:  0.10. 6. Conclusion
⁄⁄
0.05
⁄⁄⁄
0.01. This paper seeks to contribute to the financial innovation liter-
ature by examining the relationship between competition and
innovation in the US banking industry. We develop and estimate
where Cit is the competition variable, and Dkst is the deregulation
a new measure of overall innovation by estimating technology
variable that has been in effect for period k in state s. Each period
gap ratios obtained from global frontier analyses of US banks.
consists of two consecutive years starting from year 1 until year
Year-end data for all insured US commercial banks in the period
13. Only the last period consists of more than 2 years and captures
1984–2004 are employed. Consistent with Aghion et al. (2005b)
the effect of deregulation from year 13 and thereafter in the post-
and others, our results suggest an inverted-U relationship between
implementation period. Table 3 shows the results.
competition and innovation in the US banking industry. This rela-
Most regression coefficients are negative and suggest that
tionship is robust to alternative model specifications using control
deregulation of interstate banking had an adverse effect on compe-
variables and different instruments, in addition to different sample
tition.31 We performed an F-test to investigate whether the re-
periods. Further analyses indicate that interstate banking deregu-
sponses are homogenous over time. The null hypothesis that the
lation negatively affected competition on average. The downward
slope coefficients are equal to each other is rejected at the 1% level,
trend in competition after this deregulation implies a leftward
with a p-value of the F-test equal to zero. A possible explanation for
movement along the inverted-U curve. Since banks were below
the decrease in competition is that more multi-market contact (due
(or left of) the optimal level of competition in our sample period,
to interstate banking deregulation) facilitated tacit collusion. Our re-
interstate banking deregulation tended to reduce innovation on
sults are consistent with the findings of Stiroh and Strahan (2003),
average. Moreover, our results show that the consolidation move-
who argue that banking deregulation triggered a reallocation of
ment has been accompanied by marked increases in the price cost
banking assets from low profit to high profit banks resulting in in-
margins of banks over time (e.g., from 9.3% in 1984 to 24.5% in
creased profitability in the banking sector. Hence, the reallocation
2004). These margins are higher than the optimal price cost mar-
process in the industry led to higher price cost margins on average.
gins in most of our model specifications.
At the present time, sweeping financial reforms and changes in
31
There seems to be no significant effect in the first two years after deregulation. prudential regulatory policies are being made by governments and
1600 J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601

regulatory agencies around the world. During the recent global Diewert, W.E., 1976. Exact and superlative index numbers. Journal of Econometrics
4 (2), 115–145.
financial crisis, massive government intervention in many coun-
Elyasiani, E., Mehdian, S.M., 1990. A nonparametric approach to measurement of
tries sought to stabilize the financial system via mergers of large efficiency and technological change: the case of large US commercial banks.
failing banks and other financial institutions. Given this consolida- Journal of Financial Services Research 4 (2), 157–168.
tion of large, troubled banks, as well as the average position of US Frame, W.S., White, L.J., 2004. Empirical studies of financial innovation: lots of talk,
little action? Journal of Economic Literature 42 (1), 116–144.
banks on the inverted-U curve, we infer that further diminution of Fraser, D.R., Kolari, J.W., Pynnönen, S., Tippens, T.K., 2011. Market power, bank
competition in the US banking industry could negatively affect megamergers, and the welfare of bank borrowers. Journal of Financial Research
financial innovation in the years to come. Our results point to a a 33 (4), 641–648.
Freixas, X., Rochet, J., 1997. Microeconomics of Banking. MIT Press, Cambridge.
need to consider the systematic effects on the financial system of Gollop, F.M., Jorgenson, D.W., 1980. US productivity growth by industry, 1947–
reforms and regulatory changes, such as how competition and 1973. In: Kendrick, J.W., Vaccara, B.N. (Eds.), New Developments in Productivity
innovation are affected on the industry level, rather than focusing Measurement and Analysis. University Chicago Press (for NBER), Chicago.
Griffith, R., Redding, S., Reenen, J.V., 2004. Mapping the two faces of R&D:
on individual banks. Regulatory policies promoting competition productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries. The Review of Economics
would tend to reverse declines in innovation, reduce the size of and Statistics 86 (4), 883–895.
very large institutions whose failure might threaten national and Hannan, T.H., McDowell, J.M., 1984. The determinants of technology adoption: the
case of the banking firm. Rand Journal of Economics 15 (3), 328–335.
global economies (i.e., too-big-to-fail firms, or TBTFs), and foster Hashmi, A., 2007. Competition and Innovation: The Inverted-U Relationship
safety and soundness of not only individual institutions but the Revisited. Working paper, University of Toronto.
financial system as a whole. Future research on the competitive Hauswald, R., Marquez, R., 2003. Information technology and financial services
competition. Review of Financial Studies 16 (3), 921–948.
and innovation effects of recent crises on banking institutions is
Hayami, Y., Ruttan, V.W., 1970. Agricultural productivity differences among
recommended to corroborate adverse trends identified in this pa- countries. American Economic Review 60 (5), 895–911.
per and analyze policy options to improve industry conditions. Hughes, J.P., Mester, L.J., 1993. A quality and risk-adjusted cost function for banks:
Evidence on the ‘‘too-big-to-fail’’ doctrine. Journal of Productivity Analysis 4 (3),
293–315.
References Humphrey, D.B., 1993. Cost and technical change: effects from bank deregulation.
Journal of Productivity Analysis 4 (1–2), 9–34.
Hunter, W.C., Timme, S.G., 1991. Technological change in large US commercial
Acemoglu, D., 2002. Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 69 (4),
banks. Journal of Business 64 (3), 339–362.
781–809.
Jones, K.D., Critchfield, T., 2005. Consolidation in the US banking industry: is the
Aghion, P., Griffith, R., 2005. Competition and Growth: Reconciling Theory and
‘‘long, strange trip’’ about to end? FDIC Banking Review 17 (4), 31–61.
Evidence. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Kamien, M.I., Schwartz, N.L., 1982. Market Structure and Innovation. Cambridge
Aghion, P., Harris, C., Vickers, J., 1997. Competition and growth with step-by-step
University Press, New York, NY.
innovation: an example. European Economic Review 41 (3–5), 771–782.
King, R.G., Levine, R., 1993. Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right.
Aghion, P., Harris, C., Howitt, P., Vickers, J., 2001. Competition, imitation and growth
Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3), 717–737.
with step-by-step innovation. Review of Economic Studies 68 (3), 467–492.
Kroszner, R.S., Strahan, P.E., 1999. What drives deregulation? Economics and
Aghion, P., Bloom, B., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., 2005a. Competition and
politics of the relaxation of bank branching restrictions. Quarterly Journal of
Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship. NBER Working Paper 9269.
Economics 114 (4), 1437–1467.
Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., 2005b. Competition and
Krugman, P., 1979. A model of innovation, technology transfer, and the world
innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (2),
distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy 87 (2), 253–266.
701–728.
Kumbhakar, S.C., Lovell, C.A.K., 2000. Stochastic Frontier Analysis. Cambridge
Agrell, P.J., Bogetoft, P., Tind, J., 2002. Incentive plans for productive efficiency,
University Press, Cambridge, MA.
innovation and learning. International Journal of Production Economics 78 (1),
Lau, L.J., Yotopoulos, P.A., 1989. The meta-production function approach to
1–11.
technological change in world agriculture. Journal of Development Economics
Akhavein, J., Frame, W.S., White, L.J., 2005. The diffusion of financial innovations: an
31 (2), 241–269.
examination of the adoption of small business credit scoring by large banking
Levine, R., 1997. Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda.
organizations. The Journal of Business 78 (2), 577–596.
Journal of Economic Literature 35 (2), 688–726.
Allen, F., Gale, D., 1994. Financial Innovation and Risk Sharing. MIT Press,
Levine, R., 2004. Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence. Working Paper series
Cambridge, MA.
10766, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Altunbas, Y., Goddard, J., Molyneux, P., 1999. Technical change in banking.
Levine, R., Zervos, S., 1998. Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American
Economics Letters 64 (2), 215–221.
Economic Review 88 (3), 537–558.
Baltagi, B.H., Griffin, J.M., 1988. A general index of technical change. Journal of
Levine, R., Loayza, N., Beck, T., 2000. Financial intermediation and growth: causality
Political Economy 96 (1), 20–41.
and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 31–77.
Battese, G.E., Rao, D.S.P., O’Donnell, C.J., 2004. A metafrontier production function
Levin, R.C., Cohen, W.M., Mowrey, D.C., 1985. R&D appropriability, opportunity, and
for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating
market structure: new evidence on some Schumpeterian hypotheses. American
under different technologies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 21 (1), 91–103.
Economic Review 75 (2), 20–24.
Berger, A.N., Mester, L.J., 1997. Efficiency and productivity change in the US
Ludwig, E.A., 1997. Oral statement before the subcommittee on capital markets,
commercial banking industry: a comparison of the 1980s and 1990s. Federal
securities and government sponsored enterprises at the US house of representatives.
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 97-5.
Mantel, B., McHugh, T., 2001. Competition and Innovation in the Consumer
Berger, A.N., Mester, L.J., 2003. Explaining the dramatic changes in performance of
Payments Market? Considering Demand, Supply, and Public Policy Issues.
US banks: technological change, deregulation, and dynamic changes in
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Emerging Markets Working Paper EPS-2001-4.
competition. Journal of Financial Intermediation 12 (1), 57–95.
Michalopoulos, S., Laeven, L., Levine, R., 2009. Financial Innovation and Endogenous
Berger, A.N., Demsetz, R.S., Strahan, P.E., 1999. The consolidation of the financial
Growth. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No.
services industry: causes, consequences, and implications for the future. Journal
15356, –.
of Banking and Finance 23 (2–4), 135–194.
Miller, M., 1986. Financial innovation: the last twenty years and the next. Journal of
Bhattacharyya, S., Nanda, V., 2000. Client discretion, switching costs, and financial
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21 (4), 459–471.
innovation. Review of Financial Studies 13 (4), 1101–1127.
Mundlak, Y., Hellinghausen, R., 1982. The intercountry agricultural production
Bleaney, M., Wakelin, K., 2002. Efficiency, innovation and exports. Oxford Bulletin of
function: another view. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62, 664–672.
Economics and Statistics 64 (1), 3–15.
O’Donnell, C., Rao, D., Battese, G., 2008. Metafrontier frameworks for the study of
Boot, A.W., Thakor, A.V., 1997. Banking scope and financial innovation. Review of
firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empirical Economics 34 (2), 231–
Financial Studies 10 (4), 1099–1131.
255.
Bos, J.W.B., Schmiedel, H., 2007. Is there a single frontier in a single European
Pagano, M., 1993. Financial markets and growth: an overview. European Economic
banking market? Journal of Banking and Finance 31 (7), 2081–2102.
Review 37 (2–3), 613–622.
Bos, J.W.B., Kolari, J.W., van Lamoen, R., 2009. Competition and Innovation: Evidence
Park, K., Pennacchi, G., 2009. Harming depositors and helping borrowers: the
from Financial Services. TKI Working Paper 09-16, Tjalling Koopmans Institute,
disparate impact of bank consolidation. The Review of Financial Studies 22, 1–40.
Utrecht School of Economics.
Pilloff, S.J., 1999. Multimarket contact in banking. Review of Industrial Organization
Carletti, E., Hartmann, P., Spagnolo, G., 2007. Bank mergers, competition, and
14 (2), 163–182.
liquidity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (5), 1067–1105.
Rhoades, S.A., 2000. Bank Mergers and Banking Structure in the United States, 1980–
Cetorelli, N., Strahan, P.E., 2006. Finance as a barrier to entry: bank competition and
1998. Staff Studies 174, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
industry structure in local US markets. The Journal of Finance 61 (1), 437–461.
Ross, S.A., 1989. Institutional markets, financial marketing, and financial innovation.
Chourchane, M., Nickerson, D., Sullivan, R.J., 2002. Financial Innovation, Strategic
Journal of Finance 44 (3), 541–556.
Real Options, and Endogenous Competition: Theory and an Application to
Ruttan, V.W., 1997. Induced innovation, evolutionary theory and path dependence:
Internet Banking. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Conference on
sources of technical change. The Economic Journal 107 (444), 1520–1529.
Innovation in Financial Services and Payments.
J.W.B. Bos et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 1590–1601 1601

Scherer, F.M., 1967. Market structure and the employment of scientists and Tinbergen, J., 1942. Zur theorie der langfristigen wirtschaftsentwicklung.
engineers. The American Economic Review 57 (3), 524–531. Weltwirtschafliches Archiv 55 (1), 511–549.
Schumpeter, J.A., 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper and Row, New Van Horne, J.C., 1985. Of financial innovations and excesses. Journal of Finance 40
York, NY. (3), 620–631.
Solow, R.M., 1957. Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Vives, X., 2001. Competition in the changing world of banking. Oxford Review of
Review of Economics and Statistics 39 (3), 312–320. Economic Policy 17 (4), 535–547.
Stiroh, K.J., Strahan, P.E., 2003. Competitive dynamics of deregulation: evidence Wheelock, D.C., Wilson, P.W., 1999. Technical progress, inefficiency, and
from US banking. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35 (5), 801–828. productivity change in US banking, 1984–1993. Journal of Money, Credit and
Subramanian, A., Nilakanta, S., 1996. Organizational innovativeness: exploring the Banking 31 (2), 212–234.
relationship between organizational determinants of innovation, types of Wilhelm, W.J.J., 2001. The internet and financial market structure. Oxford Review of
innovations, and measures of organizational performance. Omega 24 (6), Economic Policy 17 (2), 235–247.
631–647. Windmeijer, F., 2005. A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient
Symeonidis, G., 1996. Innovation, Firm Size and Market Structure: Schumpeterian two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics 126 (1), 25–51.
Hypotheses and Some New Themes. OECD Economics Department Working Zarutskie, R., 2006. Evidence on the effects of bank competition on firm borrowing
Paper 161. and investment. Journal of Financial Economics 81 (3), 503–537.

You might also like