You are on page 1of 11

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance

S U M M E R 1 9 9 7 V O L U M E 10 . 2

EVA and Total Quality Management


by Jeffrey M. Bacidore,
University of Michigan,
John A. Boquist,
Indiana University,
Todd T. Milbourn,
London Business School, and
Anjan V. Thakor,
University of Michigan
EVA AND TOTAL QUALITY by Jeffrey M. Bacidore,
University of Michigan,
MANAGEMENT John A. Boquist, Indiana University,
Todd T. Milbourn,
London Business School, and
Anjan V. Thakor, University of Michigan

ith increasing pressure on firms to deliver shareholder value, there


has been a resurgence of interest in two key issues. The first has
W to do with how to improve productivity within the firm as well as
relationships with customers, both of which should ultimately lead
to increased shareholder wealth. The second is concerned with the measure-
ment of the firm’s progress in meeting its shareholder value goals. More
specifically, it has to do with devising measures of corporate financial
performance and incentive compensation plans that encourage managers to
increase shareholder wealth.
Although not commonly recognized, these are related issues. The first issue
is most often discussed within the context of Total Quality Management, or
“TQM” for short. The goals of TQM are to do a better job of satisfying the
customer’s needs and to improve productive and distributional efficiency, both
through a lowering of costs and an enhancement of product quality. It seems
self-evident that the accomplishment of such goals should lead to higher profits
and greater shareholder wealth.
The second issue, although typically discussed in the context of measuring
performance in financial terms, is also concerned with motivating managers to
do what is best for shareholders. The idea is to tie managerial compensation
to performance measures that are linked to changes in shareholder wealth in
order to strengthen managers’ incentives to maximize shareholder wealth. The
most direct of such measures is, of course, the firm’s stock price itself. But stock
prices—or measures such as shareholder returns that are derived from stock
prices—have the drawback that they are driven in part by factors outside the
control of even the CEO. For this reason, tying top executives’ compensation
in a significant way to the company’s future stock price could cause them to
bear more than the optimal amount of risk. In this case, the executives are likely
to require higher expected levels of total compensation than if their bonuses
were tied instead to internal operating measures such as earnings or cash
flows—measures over which they have more control. And, as one goes farther
down into the organization, the problem becomes even more acute as lower-
level employees have even less impact on the stock price.

81
BANK OF AMERICA
VOLUME 10
JOURNAL
NUMBER
OF2 APPLIED
SUMMER
CORPORATE
1997 FINANCE
Economic Value Added, or EVA, is an increas- has not only adopted TQM but is frequently cited by
ingly popular corporate performance measure—one quality advocates for its outstanding customer focus.
that is often used by companies not only for evalu- Yet the EVA of Federal Express was negative in every
ating performance, but also as a basis for determining year between 1991 and 1995. On the other hand,
incentive pay. Like other performance measures, EVA Wabash National, a Northern-Indiana-based manu-
attempts to cope with the basic tension that exists facturer of customized truck trailers, has successfully
between the need to come up with a performance translated its TQM initiative into consistently positive
measure that is highly correlated with shareholder EVAs over a similar time period.
wealth, on the one hand, but at the same time As we argue below, a financial management tool
somewhat less subject to the “random” fluctuations in like EVA has the ability to guide managers in making
stock prices. This is a difficult tension to resolve, and trade-offs among different corporate stakeholders
it explains the relatively low correlations of all and, in so doing, it can be used to complement and
accounting-based performance measures with stock reinforce a TQM program. For this reason, we argue
returns, at least on a year-to-year basis.1 that the alleged conflict between TQM and EVA, and
The objective of this paper is to attempt to thus between TQM and shareholder wealth, is more
clarify the relationship between EVA and Total illusory than real. In the short run, of course, there are
Quality Management. At a superficial level, EVA and trade-offs among different corporate constituencies,
TQM seem to be in direct conflict with each other. and management must make hard decisions de-
Whereas the focus of EVA is on eliminating conflicts signed to make the most of limited corporate re-
of interest between managers and shareholders, and sources and investor capital. But, in the long run,
thus on creating shareholder wealth, TQM focuses TQM and EVA are mutually consistent and reinforc-
on the elimination of potential management con- ing. In theory—and if applied properly in practice—
flicts with non-investor stakeholders such as custom- both methods can be used to motivate and reward
ers, suppliers, and employees. And because of its continuous improvement along dimensions that lead
focus on multiple, non-investor stakeholders, TQM to increased shareholder wealth.
does not address the issue of how to make value-
maximizing trade-offs among different stakeholder AGENCY COSTS AND AN EFFICIENCY
groups. It fails to provide answers to questions such FRONTIER INTERPRETATION OF TQM
as: What is the value to shareholders of the increase
in employees’ human capital created by corporate A fundamental problem in most public corpo-
investments in quality-training programs? And, given rations is that the separation of ownership and
that a higher-quality product generally costs more to control creates conflicts of interest, or “agency
produce, what is the value-maximizing quality-cost problems,” of various kinds. These agency problems
combination for the company? lead to frictions that reduce the value created by the
This failure of TQM to address such trade-offs corporation for its various stakeholders. This insight
may be one of the main reasons why the adoption of is as old as the theory of the firm itself.3
TQM does not necessarily lead to improvements in What is not often recognized, however, is that
EVA.2 Consider two companies, Federal Express and the conceptual heart of the TQM philosophy is an
Wabash National. Federal Express is a company that extension of this insight.4 In his 1990 book The New

1. Over horizons of one year, no accounting-based performance measure visited by the Baldridge Award examiners found that these firms’ financial
explains more than 10% of the variation in stock prices. See P. Easton, T. Harris, performance exceeded that of a control group.
J. Ohlson, “Aggregate Earnings Can Explain Most Security Returns,” Journal of 3. And its many implications for corporate behavior have been skillfully
Accounting and Economics 15 (June/Sept. 1992), pp. 119-142. Over five years, articulated by various authors from Berle and Means to Jensen and Meckling. See
earnings explain 33%. Over periods of ten years, accounting-based perfor- A. A. Berle and G. C. Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property,
mance measures, including GAAP earnings, explain up to 60% or more of stock Macmillan, New York, 1932; Michael Jensen and William Meckling, “Theory of the
returns. Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure”, Journal of
2. The empirical evidence on this is mixed. For example, a study (Interna- Financial Economics 3-4, 1976. For more recent elaborations, see Michael Jensen,
tional Quality Study) conducted by the American Quality Foundation and Ernst and “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Takeovers,” American
Young surveyed 584 firms in the U.S., Canada, Germany and Japan that had Economic Review 76-2 (1986) and Michael Jensen, “Eclipse of the Public Corpo-
adopted TQM. It found that quality improvement strategies in these firms did not ration,” Harvard Business Review, September-October 1989.
improve shareholder value. On the other hand, a GAO study (see United States 4. This point, as well as the efficiency frontier interpretation that follows, is
General Accounting Office, Management Practices: U.S. Companies Improve based on the discussion in Greenbaum and Thakor, Contemporary Financial
Performance Through Quality Efforts, (1991)) of companies that had been site- Intermediation, Dryden Press, 1995.

82
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
FIGURE 1
THE COST-QUALITY
EFFICIENCY FRONTIER

Economics,5 Edward Deming argues that agency ods of production are the most efficient possible, and
frictions related to poor leadership, worker alien- that we are either operating at the frontier, or we are
ation, and diminished morale account for the major- stuck at some point, like x, that falls well short of it.
ity of productivity losses within organizations. More- One important insight of TQM is that most
over, most failures in organizations are caused by organizations never get to the frontier because of
systemic flaws rather than individual errors. Such internal conflicts and misguided management. And,
flaws prevent companies from achieving levels of to the extent this is so, then there is no need to worry
quality, or productivity, that they might otherwise be about trade-offs between quality and cost. A firm
capable of achieving. that is at x can move to the frontier by producing a
One way to visualize Deming’s insights is by higher quality qx at the same cost, or by producing
constructing an “efficiency frontier” for a production the same quality good at lower cost. This is the sense
process for a product or service. The cost-quality in which, as Philip Crosby puts it, “quality is free.”6
efficiency frontier shown in Figure 1 is a collection But TQM does not even view the frontier as
of combinations of per-unit-cost and quality where given. In Figure 1, for example, the frontier may be
each point represents the highest quality attainable pushed out from F1F2 to F1F3 by process improve-
at that cost, or the lowest cost at which that quality ment. The implication is that the firm need not
can be produced. The curve F1F2 represents the cost- accept the trade-offs at the frontier as a constraint on
quality efficiency frontier for a hypothetical product. its cost-quality combination choice. Management
The shaded area inside the frontier shows cost- gurus have recently proclaimed their ability to
quality combinations that are inefficient, whereas deliver “discontinuous” quality improvements—that
each point on the frontier represents an efficient is, 50% to 60% improvements as opposed to the 5%
cost-quality combination. or 10% implicit in “continuous” quality improve-
In Figure 1, one’s attention is immediately ment. And such discontinuous improvements are
focused on the cost-quality tradeoffs along the F1F2 tantamount to creating a “new frontier.”
frontier. Should we be satisfied with quality qy, How does TQM work the magic of getting to the
which costs Cy per unit, or should we strive for a efficiency frontier or pushing it out? We address this
higher quality qz, which costs Cz? The assumption question next by taking an agency-cost perspective
implicit in this illustration is that the existing meth- on TQM.

5. See W. Edwards Deming, The New Economics, MIT Press, 1990. 6. See Philip B. Crosby, Quality is Free, McGraw Hill, 1979.

83
VOLUME 10 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1997
TQM and the Agency Problem decision rights in ways that fail to increase firm value
(and this, as we take up later, is the problem EVA is
Agency problems abound in organizations. designed to remedy). But another possible draw-
Employees are agents of their supervisors. These back is lack of relevant information. In cases where
supervisors act as principals with respect to their they lack the skills or knowledge of their superiors
subordinates and as agents with respect to their in making certain decisions, empowered employees
superiors. Thus a hierarchical organization consists may commit unnecessary errors. For this reason,
of multi-layered agency relationships. Each agency employee training is a necessary prerequisite and
relationship involves moral hazard in the sense that ongoing component if a TQM program is to be
an employee may shirk in providing effort because successful.
it is personally costly to the agent. But these drawbacks aside, TQM has demon-
The classical hierarchical organization deals strated that it has the potential to alter attitudes and
with this moral hazard, or agency problem, by behavior, improve motivation, and reduce agency
asking supervisors to monitor subordinates and by costs by eliciting the best efforts from all organiza-
providing rewards in the form of wage incentives tional stakeholders. These best efforts can eliminate
and punishment in the form of job termination waste and enhance productivity significantly.
threats. But monitoring and incentive mechanisms
generally are not completely effective in eliminating TQM AND SHAREHOLDER WEALTH
the problem. That is, employees continue to behave
at least in part like agents. In supervisory relation- How does TQM relate to the objective of
ships, moral hazard at higher levels has a cascading maximizing profits or shareholder wealth? As we
effect throughout the organization. A higher-level said earlier, whereas EVA and shareholder wealth
supervisor who shirks in monitoring a lower-level maximization are focused on only one group of the
supervisor causes the latter to shirk as well, and the organization’s stakeholders, TQM seeks to eliminate
effect of this ripples through all levels below. the productivity losses in organizations that arise
TQM suggests a different approach to control- from conflicts among all stakeholders. And so, if
ling agency problems. Recognizing that supervision shareholder wealth is to be increased at the expense
and monitoring create adversarial relationships, it of other stakeholders, there may be a tension
prescribes instead a cooperative approach with between TQM and shareholder wealth maximiza-
greater delegation of authority than in the traditional tion. For example, the single-minded pursuit of
hierarchical organization.8 Lower-level employees shareholder value could lead managers to expropri-
are “empowered” by being given greater control ate wealth from the firm’s bondholders by increas-
over their activities. This greater decentralization ing the riskiness of the firm’s assets. Or managers
and relaxation of control flattens the organization could attempt to create value, at least in the short run
and distributes power rather than concentrating it at (and at the potential cost of demoralizing employ-
the top. Moral hazard problems are addressed by ees), through wage-cutting that exploits temporary
making employees take greater “ownership” of the supply-demand imbalances in the labor market.
productive processes they control, thereby reducing As another example, suppose a firm is faced
the reliance on monitoring. The idea is to make with the decision of whether or not to recall one
employees behave more like owners than agents by million units of a product that is already in the hands
expanding their decision-making authority. of customers. All units are outside the warranty
But there are some potential disadvantages of period, and a design defect has been discovered that
empowering employees. The absence of an appro- causes the product to break down periodically and
priate measurement and reward system could be a requires repairs at the customer’s expense. Never-
source of problems, since employees lacking suffi- theless, it does not pose a safety hazard for the
cient monetary incentives may exercise their new product user, and so there is no legal liability. To

7. See James Mirrlees, “The Optimal Structure of Incentives and Authority Within 8. For a defense of the superiority of cooperation over competition as a
an Organization,” Bell Journal of Economics, 7-1, 1976 for a formal analysis using this motivational device, see Ram Ramakrishnan and Anjan Thakor, “Cooperation
perspective. See also Gerald Garvey and Peter L. Swan, “Optimal Capital Structure Versus Competition in Agency,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 7-
for a Hierarchial Firm,” Journal of Financial Intermediation 2-4, December 1992. 2 (1991).

84
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
recall the product, correct the design flaw, and ship This above discussion illustrates an important
the product units back to the customers is likely to point. While a tension between TQM and share-
cost the firm over $100 million. Replacing the defec- holder wealth exists in the short run, TQM can be
tive units with new units would cost even more. fully consistent with shareholder wealth maximiza-
This company is thus on the horns of a di- tion in the long run. The enhancement of produc-
lemma. A product recall will obviously hurt profits tivity from an effective TQM program should lead to
and hence shareholder wealth. It is also possible that lower costs, higher quality, and increased market
the stock price will decline. On the other hand, TQM share, all of which ultimately result in greater
would suggest that the customer is an important shareholder wealth.
stakeholder that needs to be served, and so the Thus, when one speaks of a possible inconsis-
product should be recalled. What should the com- tency between TQM and shareholder wealth maxi-
pany do? mization, it could simply be the tension between
How management answers this question may short-run and long-run objectives that is the issue.
depend on the company’s time horizon for judging In this context, the insights provided by the “eco-
the consequences of its actions. If the time horizon nomics of reputation” are relevant.9 In particular,
is relatively short, then recalling the product is companies that seek to maximize near-term cash
probably not a good idea since it will hurt share- flows to shareholders at the expense of other
holder wealth in the short run. On the other hand, stakeholders may damage their credibility with
if the time horizon is sufficiently long, then recalling these stakeholders. Such myopic behavior can ag-
the product is probably the right thing to do. It gravate conflicts among stakeholders and sacrifice
would be a strong gesture of goodwill to one million productivity gains that would benefit shareholders
customers, a powerful signal of customer focus, and in the long run.
an unmistakable sign of commitment to the long Thus, the central message of TQM is this:
term. There would be enormous customer loyalty Corporate performance can often be improved by
benefits as well as benefits due to the positive reducing conflicts and achieving a greater alignment
advertising associated with the recall. Eventually, of incentives among different groups of stakehold-
the present value of all these benefits to the share- ers. As we shall now show, EVA seeks the same
holders may be well in excess of $100 million. outcome, but by managing more specific kinds of
agency problems.
The Case of L.L. Bean
EVA AND AGENCY COSTS
L.L. Bean, the Maine-based sporting accessories
manufacturer and marketer, faced a similar di- As we noted earlier earlier, EVA focuses prima-
lemma when it was a young company. It had sold rily on reducing conflicts of interest between man-
numerous “waterproof” hunting boots that it later agers and shareholders. Besides encouraging man-
discovered had a design flaw. When customers agers to make the most efficient possible use of
stepped in water, the leather upper often separated investor capital, EVA is also designed to eliminate
from the waterproof bottom. The company decided the incentives for both corporate overinvestment
to recall every single pair of boots and replace them and underinvestment that are provided by more
with redesigned boots that were truly waterproof. conventional accounting measures such as earnings
The cost of doing this nearly put the company out growth and ROE. And we now briefly discuss each
of business, but that single act has served as an of these problems.
enduring guiding principle for the company whose The Corporate Overinvestment Problem.
reputation for customer focus has proved enor- Among the many agency problems that exist within
mously profitable for its shareholders. the firm, those pertaining to management’s failure to
put the corporate assets at their disposal to their

9. As an example of the reputation analogy, see Douglas Diamond,


“Reputation Acquisition in Debt Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, 97-4
(1989), which shows how a concern for credit reputation may cause a firm to resist
measures that expropriate bondholders and increase shareholder wealth in the
short run.

85
VOLUME 10 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1997
highest-valued use have received considerable at- suppose his compensation is tied directly to RONA.
tention. In particular, it has been alleged that many In that case, he may wish to pass up the project
firms are overcapitalized relative to the value- because it lowers the average RONA (by blending
maximizing deployment of capital projects. The 20% with 15%).
blame is often placed on flawed compensation This example illustrates a general point. Typi-
schemes and corporate objectives that cause man- cally, there is a law of diminishing marginal returns
agers to focus on earnings and market share. Both at work, which means that growth in capital invested
of these common measures of corporate success can is likely to be achieved by investing in projects with
often be elevated by pumping in additional capital, lower rates of return than those the company
even if this is done at the expense of shareholder invested in previously. This means that, especially in
value.10 Even though equity capital is costly to the the case of already successful companies, expansion
shareholders, the measurement system treats it as of capital investments is likely to lower RONA. And,
costless, and managers accordingly behave as if it is for this reason, if managers are compensated solely
free. And so managers rewarded solely on the basis on the basis of RONA, they may pass up positive-
of earnings or earnings growth quickly recognize NPV projects.
that they can increase their incentive bonuses simply
by increasing the amount of capital at their disposal. How Does EVA Help?
In this fashion, earnings-based compensation leads
managers to “manufacture” earnings by overinvest- The driving force behind these distortions,
ing capital to the detriment of the shareholders.11 then, is that the manager is not “charged” for the
The Corporate Underinvestment Problem. capital he uses, and is not compensated for the
Many companies compensate managers based on incremental shareholder value he creates. The goal
rate-of-return measures such as Return on Equity of a good financial performance measure is to reveal
(ROE) or Return On Net Assets (RONA). Unfortu- how well the firm has performed in terms of
nately, this can cause managers to underinvest in generating operating profits in a given period, given
capital. To see this, consider a manager whose the amount of capital that was tied up to generate
present portfolio of investments yields an average those profits. The idea is that the firm’s financiers
RONA of 20%. The firm’s weighted average cost of could have liquidated their investment in the firm
capital is 10% and it has $10 million in net assets. and put the liberated capital to some other use.
Suppose the manager is faced with the opportunity Thus, the financiers’ opportunity cost of capital
to invest an additional $1 million in a project with must be subtracted from operating profits to assess
a RONA of 15%. Should the manager invest in this the firm’s financial performance. And, indeed, this
project? is the most fundamental insight of EVA. It rewards
The answer depends on what the manager managers for earnings and profits, but also taxes
wishes to maximize. If he seeks to maximize share- their capital usage. Expressed as a formula, EVA is
holder wealth, the answer is obviously yes. But defined as:

10. Indeed, it can be argued that by rewarding managers based on perfor- With this setting, it is clear that if the firm fixes the amount of capital that the
mance measures like sales growth, profit growth, earnings growth, and market manager can invest, average managers will rationally opt for T1 and talented
share growth, companies create strong incentives for managers to substitute capital managers will opt for T2. This sort of task assignment, which is efficient from the
for effort, creativity, and innate ability. See Todd T. Milbourn and Anjan V. Thakor, shareholders’ standpoint, occurs naturally without any coercion of managers or
“Intrafirm Capital Allocation and Managerial Compensation,” London Business prior knowledge of their innate abilities.
School IFA Working Paper 238, 1996. A problem with this mechanism is that we have to fix the capital input, rather
11. Earnings-based compensation also interferes with the self-selection than have the choice made by the manager using the capital. There may be
process whereby more talented managers opt for more difficult tasks that circumstances in which this is not efficient. In particular, because of his knowledge
promise higher rewards. This self-selection process works as follows. Suppose of local conditions, constraints and capabilities, the manager using the capital is likely
there are two tasks, T1 and T2, where T1 is “easy” and T2 is “difficult”. Also to be much better equipped than anyone else to determine how much capital would
suppose there are two types of managers, one of high innate ability who we be value-maximizing. It therefore makes sense to delegate the determination of the
will call “talented” and the other of lower innate ability who we will call level of capital deployment to the manager requesting that capital allocation. This
“average”. Ability differences are of little consequence for the output from T1, leads to a situation in which the manager is effectively delegated the responsibility
so suppose that the expected output in this case is the same for both types of for jointly determining both the capital and effort inputs to the project.
managers if they work equally hard and invest the same amount of capital. On Unfortunately, this can frustrate the self-selection process described earlier. The
T2, however, the expected output is higher for the talented manager than for reason is that an average manager can substitute capital for innate ability and elevate
the average manager, conditional on identical effort and capital inputs. his expected output from T2 to be above that from T1 simply by acquiring a sufficiently
Moreover, for the talented manager, expected output with T2 is higher than with large amount of capital. This would then induce him to opt for T2 and, in the absence
T1, and for the average manager, expected output is lower with T 2 than with of perfect knowledge of innate managerial ability, would cause a breakdown of the
T1. self-selection process by which managers self-select tasks based on ability.

86
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
EVA = NOPAT - WACC × Net Assets ning, or when evaluating any multi-year capital
project, EVA-based financial analysis will not (and
where should not) alter the conclusions reached on the
NOPAT = net operating profit after-tax, basis of cash-flow-based NPV analysis. But this
WACC = weighted average cost of capital, equivalence of EVA to NPV is a strength, not a
and drawback. However, it naturally causes people to
Net Assets = adjusted book value of net capital at ask why they should bother to change their financial
the beginning of the period.12 analysis procedures to accommodate EVA.
Thus, to the extent managerial compensation is The reason why such questions arise is that EVA
tied to EVA, the manager’s inclination to consume tends to be viewed by many primarily as a tool of
capital is now tempered by the fact that he must pay financial analysis.14 This is a mistake. EVA should be
a capital charge evaluated at the weighted average viewed primarily as a behavioral tool—one that
cost of capital on the net capital he uses. But, at the gives managers the strongest possible incentives to
same time, the use of EVA encourages managers to make value-adding investment and operating deci-
take all projects that promise to earn more than their sions. That is, it should be tied to compensation (or
cost of capital, thus mitigating the underinvestment not used at all) and viewed essentially as an HR tool.
problem. Its use in financial analysis should be mainly to
support its role as an important compensation
Why EVA is More a Behavioral than an variable, rather than to supplant cash-flow-based
Analytical Tool financial analysis of strategic investments.
In fact, we advocate using both EVA and cash
Of course, we would also like to know how flows for financial analysis. Doing so not only
well EVA correlates with shareholder value. Unfor- provides a richer perspective on possible future
tunately, the empirical evidence on this subject is outcomes but also permits one to cross-check the
still in a relatively primitive stage, and so offers little answers obtained by using the two approaches.15
help.13 If EVA-based NPV and cash-flow-based NPV
In theory, however, the present value of a are identical, why is it that EVA is useful for
company’s future expected EVA is equal to its compensation and NPV is not? The reason is that one
Market Value Added (MVA), which is defined as the needs flow measures of performance for periodic
difference between the market value of the firm and compensation since compensation is designed to
the (adjusted) book value of its assets. Moreover, the provide a flow of rewards. EVA is a flow measure,
present value of the expected future stream of EVA whereas NPV is a stock measure. Moreover, of the
also equals Net Present Value, or NPV. available flow measures, EVA is the only one that
A commonly-asked question then is: What does explicitly takes into account the cost of the capital
EVA add to conventional NPV analysis? The short provided by shareholders. In this respect, it is
answer is: nothing. For purposes of strategic plan- superior to another flow measure, cash flow.

12. Estimating the economic value of a firm’s net assets can be a daunting task. conservative, historical-cost-based balance sheet that is guided by generally
The balance sheet is supposed to represent the amount of capital financiers have accepted accounting principles.
invested in the firm. Unfortunately, because of a variety of accounting distortions, 13. See, for example, Gary Biddle, Robert Bowen, and James Wallace,
the total asset value on the typical balance sheet does not accurately represent “Evidence on the Relative and Incremental Information Content of EVA, Residual
either the liquidation value or the replacement-cost value of the assets in place. Income, Earnings, and Operating Cash Flow,” unpublished manuscript, 1996;
It is thus of limited use for asset valuation purposes and must be transformed. Pamela Peterson and David Peterson, “Company Performance and Measures of
Proponents of EVA, most notably Stern Stewart & Company, are careful to Value Added,” The Research Foundation of the Institute for Chartered Financial
adjust this accounting balance sheet before arriving at an estimate of the value of Analysts (1996); Jonathan Kramer and George Pushner, “An Empirical Analysis of
the firm’s assets in place. They first recommend netting the non-interest-bearing Economic Value Added as a Proxy for Market Value Added,” Financial Practice
current liabilities (NIBCLs) against the current assets to better represent the and Education 7 (1997); Stephen O’Byrne, “EVA and Market Value,” Journal of
permanent capital structure of the firm. Such netting also recognizes that the cost Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 9 No. 1 (1996); and Jeffrey M. Bacidore, John A.
of NIBCLs, like accounts payable, are accounted for in the cost of goods sold. Boquist, Todd T. Milbourn, and Anjan V. Thakor, “The Search for the Best Financial
Moreover, a variety of common debt and equity adjustments are also made. The Performance Measure,” Financial Analysts Journal, May/June 1997.
adjustments include adding back to equity the gross goodwill (i.e., adding 14. See, for example, Bennett Stewart, “EVA Works - But Not If You Make These
cumulative amortized goodwill back to total assets), restructuring and other write- Common Mistakes,” Fortune, May 1, 1995, which bemoans the fact that some
offs, capitalized value of R&D (and possibly advertising), LIFO reserve, etc. The companies adopt EVA solely for financial analysis and do not tie compensation to EVA.
debt balance is adjusted for the capitalized value of operating lease payments. The 15. In our experience, this helps to detect errors made by financial analysts
overall effect of these suggested adjustments is to produce a balance sheet that in their spreadsheets, errors to which the analyst is alerted when the free-cash-flow
reflects economic values of assets in place more accurately than the inherently and EVA-based NPVs do not coincide.

87
VOLUME 10 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1997
THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN TQM AND EVA to the discipline of EVA, management is in a better
position to ensure that its investment in TQM is
So what, then, is the relationship between EVA translating into increased shareholder value. At the
and TQM? Is EVA consistent with TQM, or its use same time, a TQM program tempered by EVA can
likely to undermine such programs. help managers ensure that they are not underinvesting
As we saw earlier, TQM has the potential to in their non-shareholder stakeholders.
bring about continuous improvements in compa-
nies’ cost-quality positions in part by doing a better CONCLUSION
job of managing conflicts among various corporate
stakeholders. And, to the extent it succeeds in raising Most financial economists agree that the aim of
revenues or reducing costs, a successful TQM public corporations is to maximize total firm value—
program may have the effect of turning negative- and that the only way such a goal can be translated
NPV projects into value-adding projects. But a TQM into practice is by focusing on the maximization of
program does nothing to eliminate the incentives shareholder value. Both TQM and EVA can be
provided by earnings-based compensation to over- viewed as organizational innovations designed to
invest corporate capital. Indeed, by placing the reduce “agency costs”—that is, reductions in firm
corporate focus on measures of customer satisfac- value that stem from conflicts of interest between
tion or employee development instead of share- various corporate constituencies. TQM programs
holder value, a TQM program could easily lead to can be viewed in large part as attempts to increase
overinvestment. value by reducing potential conflicts among non-
What’s more, TQM programs themselves in- investor stakeholders, between management and
volve an investment of corporate resources, includ- employees, employees and customers, employees
ing outlays for employee training and the costs of and suppliers, and so forth. EVA, by contrast,
management time in making changes in the organi- focuses simply on reducing conflicts between man-
zation. And not all TQM programs succeed in raising agers and shareholders by aligning the incentives of
revenues or reducing costs enough to justify the the two groups. EVA reinforces the goal of share-
investment. Moreover, as Brickley, Smith, and holder value maximization by giving managers
Zimmerman argue (in another article in this issue), incentives to operate as efficiently as possible and to
At some point, most (if not all) companies face undertake all investments that promise to earn more
diminishing marginal returns from further invest- than the cost of capital, and to reject all others.
ments in quality programs... Management’s job is to It is important to recognize, however, that the
find the value-maximizing amount of quality— focus of EVA, and of financial economics more
neither too much nor too little—based on its markets generally, on shareholder wealth does not imply
and internal capabilities. that corporate stakeholders other than stockholders
When viewed in this perspective, the central are not important in managment’s decision-making.
message of TQM can be recast as follows: Compa- The most aggressive maximizer of stockholder
nies can often add value by reducing conflicts and wealth must care about its employees, customers,
achieving a greater alignment of incentives among and suppliers. Maximizing value, in fact, means
its different groups of stakeholders. But TQM also investing corporate resources—to the point where
involves an investment of corporate resources; and, marginal costs equal marginal benefits—to all groups
as in the case of all kinds of corporate investment, or interests that affect firm value, whether to influ-
the benefits must exceed the costs by a sufficient ence the terms on which they contract with the
margin to provide the firm with an adequate return company, to maintain the firm’s reputation, or to
on investment. EVA (along with NPV) provides a reduce the threat of restrictive regulation.
financial framework both for evaluating adoption of In this sense, there is no conflict between
a TQM program and for monitoring the longer-term management’s service to its stockholders and to
effectiveness of such a program. By subjecting TQM other corporate stakeholders. And, by the same

16. James Brickley, Clifford Smith, and Jerold Zimmerman, “Management Fads
and Organizational Architecture,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 10
No. 2 (Summer 1997).

88
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
logic, there is no fundamental conflict between the system can be used to discipline a TQM program by
aims of TQM and EVA. TQM can help EVA by discouraging management from overinvesting in
ensuring that companies make the proper invest- such stakeholders. In short, the goals of TQM and
ment in human capital, and, more generally, in their EVA are mutually consistent, and both systems can
non-investor stakeholders. At the same time, an EVA be used effectively to reinforce each other.

JEFFREY BACIDORE TODD MILBOURN

is a Visiting Lecturer at the University of Michigan. is an Assistant Professor of Finance at the London Business School.

JOHN BOQUIST ANJAN THAKOR

is the Edward E. Edwards Professor of Finance, Indiana is the Edward J. Frey Professor of Banking and Finance,
University. University of Michigan.

89
VOLUME 10 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1997
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (ISSN 1078-1196 [print], ISSN Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is available online through Synergy,
1745-6622 [online]) is published quarterly on behalf of Morgan Stanley by Blackwell’s online journal service which allows you to:
Blackwell Publishing, with offices at 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, • Browse tables of contents and abstracts from over 290 professional,
USA, and PO Box 1354, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2XG, UK. Call science, social science, and medical journals
US: (800) 835-6770, UK: +44 1865 778315; fax US: (781) 388-8232, UK: • Create your own Personal Homepage from which you can access your
+44 1865 471775, or e-mail: subscrip@bos.blackwellpublishing.com. personal subscriptions, set up e-mail table of contents alerts and run
saved searches
Information For Subscribers For new orders, renewals, sample copy re- • Perform detailed searches across our database of titles and save the
quests, claims, changes of address, and all other subscription correspon- search criteria for future use
dence, please contact the Customer Service Department at your nearest • Link to and from bibliographic databases such as ISI.
Blackwell office. Sign up for free today at http://www.blackwell-synergy.com.

Subscription Rates for Volume 17 (four issues) Institutional Premium Disclaimer The Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and the Editor cannot
Rate* The Americas† $330, Rest of World £201; Commercial Company Pre- be held responsible for errors or any consequences arising from the use of
mium Rate, The Americas $440, Rest of World £268; Individual Rate, The information contained in this journal. The views and opinions expressed in this
Americas $95, Rest of World £70, Ð105‡; Students**, The Americas $50, journal do not necessarily represent those of the Publisher, Morgan Stanley,
Rest of World £28, Ð42. its affiliates, and Editor, neither does the publication of advertisements con-
stitute any endorsement by the Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and
*Includes print plus premium online access to the current and all available Editor of the products advertised. No person should purchase or sell any
backfiles. Print and online-only rates are also available (see below). security or asset in reliance on any information in this journal.


Customers in Canada should add 7% GST or provide evidence of entitlement Morgan Stanley is a full service financial services company active in the securi-
to exemption ties, investment management and credit services businesses. Morgan Stanley
may have and may seek to have business relationships with any person or

Customers in the UK should add VAT at 5%; customers in the EU should also company named in this journal.
add VAT at 5%, or provide a VAT registration number or evidence of entitle-
ment to exemption Copyright © 2004 Morgan Stanley. All rights reserved. No part of this publi-
cation may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in whole or part in any form
** Students must present a copy of their student ID card to receive this or by any means without the prior permission in writing from the copyright
rate. holder. Authorization to photocopy items for internal or personal use or for the
internal or personal use of specific clients is granted by the copyright holder
For more information about Blackwell Publishing journals, including online ac- for libraries and other users of the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC), 222
cess information, terms and conditions, and other pricing options, please visit Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA (www.copyright.com), provided
www.blackwellpublishing.com or contact our customer service department, the appropriate fee is paid directly to the CCC. This consent does not extend
tel: (800) 835-6770 or +44 1865 778315 (UK office). to other kinds of copying, such as copying for general distribution for advertis-
ing or promotional purposes, for creating new collective works or for resale.
Back Issues Back issues are available from the publisher at the current single- Institutions with a paid subscription to this journal may make photocopies for
issue rate. teaching purposes and academic course-packs free of charge provided such
copies are not resold. For all other permissions inquiries, including requests
Mailing Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is mailed Standard Rate. Mail- to republish material in another work, please contact the Journals Rights and
ing to rest of world by DHL Smart & Global Mail. Canadian mail is sent by Permissions Coordinator, Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford
Canadian publications mail agreement number 40573520. Postmaster OX4 2DQ. E-mail: journalsrights@oxon.blackwellpublishing.com.
Send all address changes to Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Blackwell
Publishing Inc., Journals Subscription Department, 350 Main St., Malden, MA
02148-5020.

You might also like