You are on page 1of 17

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance

S U M M E R 1 9 9 5 V O L U M E 8. 2

The EVA® Financial Management System


by Joel M. Stern, G. Bennett Stewart III, and Donald H. Chew, Jr.,
Stern Stewart & Co.
THE EVA® FINANCIAL by Joel M. Stern, G. Bennett Stewart III,
and Donald H. Chew, Jr.,
MANAGEMENT SYSTEM Stern Stewart & Co.

he information revolution, along with tioned to serve as the nerve-endings of the organi-
the pace of technological change of all zation—and it will be used to benefit the firm only
T kinds and the rise of a global economy, insofar as those managers and employees are highly
is leading to major changes in the struc- motivated and focused on the right goals.
ture and internal control systems of large organiza- And so, as some organizational theorists are
tions. Centrally-directed economies are failing, state- now coming to understand, companies that push
owned enterprises are being privatized, and non- decision-making down into lower levels of the
profits are experimenting with new ways of motivat- organization must also change their internal control
ing employees and “selling” their services. At the systems. Such companies will typically find it neces-
same time, the huge conglomerates built up during sary to rethink both their performance measurement
the 1960s and ’70s—the epitome of central planning and their reward systems to help ensure that oper-
in the private sector—are being steadily pulled apart ating managers use their expanded decision-making
and supplanted by more focused competitors. powers in ways that increase the value of the firm.
In each of these spheres of activity—private, In this sense, decentralization, performance mea-
public, and non-profit—the spread of powerful surement, and compensation policy constitute a
computer and telecommunications networks is con- “three-legged stool” of effective corporate control.1
tributing to a worldwide move toward decentraliza- In this article, we argue that for many large
tion or, to use the more fashionable term, “empow- companies the top-down, earnings per share-based
erment.” With the flattening of management hierar- model of financial management that has long domi-
chies, corporate decision-making is being driven nated corporate America is becoming obsolete. The
down through the ranks to managers and employees most serious challenge to the long reign of EPS is
closer to the company’s operations and customers. coming from a measure of corporate performance
But, as organizational theorists have long un- called “Economic Value Added,” or EVA. As Peter
derstood, there are significant costs associated with Drucker noted in a recent Harvard Business Review
decentralizing decision-making. Today’s informa- article, EVA is by no means a new concept. Rather
tion systems may now be capable of providing top it is a practical, and highly flexible, refinement of
management with real-time monitoring of the rev- economists’ concept of “residual income”—the value
enues and profits of the most farflung operations. that is left over after a company’s stockholders (and
But what software is programmed to report oppor- all other providers of capital) have been adequately
tunities lost by operating heads too comfortable with compensated. As Drucker also observed, EVA is thus
the status quo? And what accounting systems are a measure of “total factor productivity”—one whose
capable of distinguishing reliably between profit- growing popularity reflects the new demands of the
able and unprofitable corporate investment deci- information age. For companies that aim to increase
sions at the time the decisions are being made? their competitiveness by decentralizing, EVA is likely
The answer, of course, is that this kind of to be the most sensible basis for evaluating and
information cannot be passed on by computer rewarding the periodic performance of empowered
systems. Such information resides with experienced line people, especially those entrusted with major
line managers and employees—those who are posi- capital spending decisions.

1. The term is borrowed from James Brickley, Clifford Smith, and Jerold original derivation of the concept, see Michael Jensen and William Meckling,
Zimmerman, “The Economics of Organizational Architecture,” in this issue. For the “Specific and General Knowledge, and Organizational Structure,” also in this issue.

32
BANK OF AMERICA
JOURNAL OF
JOURNAL
APPLIEDOF
CORPORATE
APPLIED CORPORATE
FINANCE FINANCE
EVA, moreover, is not just a performance mea- of their operating divisions to produce a given
sure. When fully implemented, it is the centerpiece amount of profits each year. Because new capital
of an integrated financial management system that appropriations for all the divisions (the total amount
encompasses the full range of corporate financial of which effectively determined the denominator in
decision-making—everything from capital budget- the EPS calculation) were usually tightly controlled
ing, acquisition pricing, and the setting of corporate from the top, a given amount of profits aggregated
goals to shareholder communication and manage- across all the divisions (the numerator) enabled top
ment incentive compensation. By putting all finan- management to hit the target barring a sharp eco-
cial and operating functions on the same basis, an nomic downturn.
EVA system effectively provides a common language The strategy of corporate diversification that
for employees across all corporate functions, linking became popular in the late 1960s and 1970s—that is,
strategic planning with the operating divisions, and the acquisition of businesses in completely unre-
the corporate treasury staff with investor relations lated industries (which Chandler has called “both a
and human resources. disaster and an historical aberration”)2—can also be
In the pages that follow, we begin by describing explained in part as an attempt by top management
the shortcomings of the top-down, EPS-based model to increase its ability to “manage” reported earnings.
of financial management. Next we explain both the For one thing, the popular practice of buying
rise of hostile takeovers and the phenomenal success companies with lower P/Es in stock-for-stock ex-
of LBOs in the 1980s as capital market responses to changes automatically boosted reported EPS (such
the deficiencies of the EPS model. The EVA financial “EPS bootstrapping,” as the practice was called, was
management system, we go on to argue, borrows pure accounting artifice with no economic substance
important aspects of the LBO movement—particu- whatsoever). And, to the extent a portfolio of
larly, its focus on capital efficiency and ownership unrelated businesses produced less variable operat-
incentives—but without the high leverage and con- ing cash flows for the entire firm, such corporate
centration of risk that limit LBOs to the mature sector diversification served to smooth reported earnings.3
of the U.S. economy. In the final section, we present Also contributing to top management’s ability to
the outlines of an EVA-based incentive compensa- deliver smoothly rising earnings—at least for a
tion plan that is designed to simulate for managers time—was the annual rite of negotiating divisional
and employees the rewards of ownership. budget targets. In a time-honored practice known as
“sandbagging,” division heads with greater knowl-
THE OLD SYSTEM: EPS-BASED edge of their businesses’ prospects than corporate
FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT staffers would underestimate the profit potential of
their own units when negotiating their budgets with
As Alfred Chandler has argued, the centralized headquarters. And, having “low-balled” their esti-
top-down approach to managing large corporations mates and negotiated easy targets, such operating
was well suited to the relatively stable business heads also often found it in their own interest to
environment that prevailed during the first two or “bank” excess profits for a rainy day—for example,
three decades after World War II. The principal by shifting revenues or costs.
challenge of top management then was to achieve This kind of “satisficing” behavior by division
the huge economies of scale in manufacturing and heads can be readily explained by standard features
marketing that were available to firms finding oppor- of the corporate reward system. In most companies,
tunities for growth in the same or closely related division heads’ annual bonus awards were capped
businesses. at a fairly modest fraction (say, 20-30%) of base
In this age of stability, the top managements of salary, thus limiting their participation in exceptional
most large U.S. companies aimed to report steady profits. And really extraordinary divisional perfor-
increases in earnings per share by calling on each mance in any one year could have the unwanted

2. Alfred Chandler, in “Continental Bank Roundtable on Corporate Strategy in And the fact that unrelated businesses must be acquired at large premiums over
the ’90s,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 6 No. 3 (Fall, 1993), p. 44. their fair market value (which we like to describe as “charitable contributions to
3. Finance theory says that shareholders should be unwilling to place random passers by”) tends to make corporate diversification a doubly losing
significant value on corporate diversification because they can achieve such strategy for the firm’s shareholders.
diversification more cheaply on their own simply by diversifying their portfolio.

33
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
effect of sharply raising future years’ budgeted relatively stable, and international competitors and
targets (as well as casting doubt on the integrity of corporate raiders remained dormant.
the manager’s forecasts).
But if the problems arising from budget nego- ....................................................................................
tiations were that obvious, then why didn’t CEOs THE CASE OF RJR NABISCO
abandon the practice altogether and just give their In his last year as CEO of RJR Nabisco, Ross Johnson
division heads a fixed percentage of the divisional reportedly ordered John Greeniaus, the head of RJR’s
profits? After all, this system has reportedly served tobacco unit, to spend the excess profits of his division on
Warren Buffett well at a number of his companies. additional advertising and promotion. Greeniaus later
As some economists and management experts shared this information about the potential profitability of
have rightly pointed out, excessive reliance on his unit with Henry Kravis of Kohlberg Kravis & Roberts,
divisional profit-sharing plans can discourage coop- which reportedly played a major role in KKR’s $25 billion
eration among divisions. Purely “objective” divi- bid for and eventual purchase of RJR Nabisco, the largest
sional performance measures have the potential not LBO to date.5
only to undermine attempts to exploit synergies
among different business units (presumably the In the early 1980s, however, the deficiencies of
reason they are under the same corporate umbrella the top-down, EPS-based system began to show in
in the first place), they can even create internal several ways. Strategically diversified conglomerates
conflicts that end up reducing overall firm value. such as General Mills (which proudly called itself the
But another, more compelling explanation for “all-weather growth company”),6 Northwest Indus-
the widespread use of negotiated budgets is that tries, Beatrice Foods, and ITT saw their stock prices
many top managements were content to tolerate, if underperforming market averages even as the com-
not actually encourage, such counterproductive panies were producing steady increases in EPS. The
practices. For, besides making the life of division operations of such diversified firms began to be
heads easier, the budgeting process also helped top outperformed by smaller, more specialized compa-
management produce the smoothly rising EPS in- nies. And, as it became progressively more clear that
tended to satisfy shareholders. Thus, while division large, centralized conglomerates were worth far less
heads were “sandbagging” their estimates for head- than the sum of their parts, corporate raiders launched
quarters, top managements were in some sense the deconglomeration movement.
sandbagging their shareholders, managing inves- At the heart of the failure of the top-down, EPS-
tors’ expectations while concealing the true profit based control system was its refusal to empower
potential of the business. divisional managers, to make them feel and act as if
As Gordon Donaldson has argued, the under- they were stewards of investor capital. One impor-
standing implicit in this management philosophy of tant consequence of this “lack of ownership” was
the ’60s and ’70s was that a company’s shareholders that business units evaluated mainly on the basis of
are only one of several important corporate constitu- operating profits had little reason to be concerned
encies whose interests must be served. Top manag- with the level of investment required to achieve their
ers saw their primary task not as maximizing share- profits. The primary incentive of operating managers
holder value, but rather as achieving the proper was to achieve (moderate) growth in profits, which
balance among the interests of shareholders and could be accomplished in two ways: (1) improve the
those of other “stakeholders” such as employees, efficiency of existing operations or (2) win more
suppliers, and local communities.4 In this view of the capital appropriations from headquarters. Because
world, reporting steady increases in EPS was equiva- most corporate measurement systems did not hold
lent to giving shareholders their due. And, in fact, corporate managers accountable for new capital, it
such a management approach worked reasonably did not take managers long to recognize that it was
well—at least as long as product markets were easier to “buy” additional operating profits with

4. See Gordon Donaldson, “The Corporate Restructuring of the 1980s and Its 6. See Gordon Donaldson, “Voluntary Restructuring: The Case of General
Import for the 1990s, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 6 No. 4 (Winter Mills,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4 No. 3 (Fall 1993).
1994).
5. Source: Brian Burrough and John Helyar, Barbarians at the Gate (Harper
& Row, 1991), pp. 370-371.

34
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
At the heart of the failure of the top-down, EPS-based control system was its refusal
to empower divisional managers, to make them feel and act as if they were stewards
of investor capital.

capital expenditures—even if the investment did not We thought all the while that we were doing quite well. Our
promise anything like an acceptable rate of return7— stock tripled during that period of time, we raised the
than to wring out efficiencies with cutbacks. dividend four years in a row, and 20% percent earnings
This standard capital budgeting procedure led growth seemed pretty darn good...
in turn to what might be called the “politicization” of But we were still subjected to a hostile takeover [in
corporate investment, a process in which persuasive 1986]—and deservedly so. We were not earning adequate
and well-positioned business unit managers received rates of return on the capital we were investing to achieve
too much capital while their less favored counter- that 20% growth. We were not realizing the values that
parts received too little. The top-down EPS system were there for someone else to realize for our sharehold-
also tolerated the widespread practice of corporate ers.... For this reason, and with hindsight, it now seems
cross-subsidization, in which the surplus cash flow clear why outsiders could come in and see a way of buying
of profitable divisions was wasted in futile efforts to our company for $4.2 billion—way above its then current
shore up unpromising divisions or in diversifying market value—and improving it so it was worth $5.2
acquisitions.8 The result of this politicization of cor- billion a few years later. And I think that’s an important
porate decision-making was chronic overinvestment lesson for corporate America.10
in some areas and underinvestment in others. In
many cases, moreover, it was the potentially more In many cases, as takeover critics have argued,
profitable, but capital-starved business units that the push for capital efficiency led to cutbacks in
ended up being sold in LBOs to their own manage- corporate employment and investment. In the vast
ment teams, with the financial backing of outsiders majority of such cases, however, “downsizing” was
like KKR and Clayton & Dubilier. a value-adding strategy precisely because of the
natural tendency of corporate management in ma-
CORPORATE RAIDERS AND ture industries to pursue growth at the expense of
CAPITAL EFFICIENCY profitability, to overinvest in misguided attempts to
maintain market share or, perhaps worse, to diver-
As noted, the widespread corporate misalloca- sify into unrelated businesses.11 This is why the vast
tion and waste of capital under the EPS-based system majority of leveraged restructurings took place in
did not escape the attention of corporate raiders in industries with excess capacity—oil and gas, tires,
the 1980s.9 In making their own assessments of paper, packaging, publishing, commodity chemi-
potential value, the raiders used a performance cals, forest products, and retailing.
metric that was quite different from EPS. They were In an article published in this journal called “The
concerned primarily with companies’ ability to gen- Causes and Consequences of Hostile Takeovers,”12
erate cash flow (as opposed to earnings) and with Harvard professor Amar Bhide compared the eco-
their efficiency in using capital. nomic motives and consequences of 47 hostile
takeovers of companies larger than $100 million
.................................................................................... attempted in 1985 and 1986 to those of a control
LESSONS FROM THE SAFEWAY LBO group of 30 “friendly” takeovers in the same years.
Consider the following testimony from Peter Magowan, Whereas most of the friendly deals were designed to
who was CEO of Safeway Stores both before and after the take advantage of vaguely defined “synergies” or to
company’s LBO by KKR in 1986: diversify the corporate “strategic” portfolio, the large
“When Safeway was a public company, our profits grew majority of hostile deals were motivated by profits
at 20% per year for five years in a row, from 1981 to 1985... expected from “restructuring”—that is, from cutting

7. Just before KKR took over RJR, Ross Johnson reportedly approved a $2.8 9. For estimates of the extent of the corporate misuse of capital and of the
billion dollar outlay for a state-of-the-art cookie manufacturing facility with a resulting gains from corprate control transactions, see Michael Jensen, “Corporate
projected pre-tax rate of return of only 5%. (From Peter Waldman, “New RJR Chief Control and the Politics of Finance,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4
Faces a Daunting Challenge at Debt-Heavy Firm,” Wall Street Journal, March 14, No. 2 (Summer, 1991).
1989, p. A1:6). 10. Peter Magowan, “Continental Bank Roundtable on Performance Measure-
8. The shareholder value destroyed by such unprofitable reinvestment of ment and Management Incentives,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4
corporate cash flow has been described by Michael Jensen as the “agency costs of No. 3, p.33.
free cash flow.” For the original formulation of this argument, see “The Agency 11. See footnote 8.
Costs of Free Cash Flow: Corporate Finance and Takeovers,” American Economic 12. Amar Bhide, “The Causes and Consequences of Hostile Takeovers,”
Review Vol. 76 No. 2, (May, 1986). Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 2 No. 2 (Summer 1989).

35
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
overhead, improving focus by selling unrelated off either to single-industry firms or to private
businesses, and ending unprofitable reinvestment of investment groups in combination with operating
corporate profits. management. Which brings us to the subject of
The targets of hostile and friendly deals were leveraged buyouts, or LBOs.
accordingly very different. Whereas the targets of
friendly mergers tended to be single-industry firms THE RISE OF THE LBO: AN INTERIM STAGE IN
with heavy insider ownership that had performed THE PUSH FOR A NEW CORPORATE
quite well (as measured by earnings growth, ROE, GOVERNANCE SYSTEM
and stockholder returns), the targets of hostile deals
were typically low-growth, poorly performing, and Contrary to popular opinion, LBOs are one of
often highly diversified companies in which man- the remarkable success stories of the 1980s. So
agement had a negligible equity stake. (A Fortune impressive were the results of the first wave of LBOs
magazine poll also ranked their managements as that Harvard professor Michael Jensen was moved to
among the worst in their industries, as judged by write an article in 1989 for the Harvard Business
their management peers.) Review entitled, “The Eclipse of the Public Corpora-
There were also notable differences between tion.” There Jensen observed that LBO partnerships
the consequences of friendly and hostile deals, like KKR and Forstmann Little, which acquire and
although some differences were not as dramatic as control companies across a broad range of indus-
they have been made out to be. Contrary to the tries, represent a “new form of organization”—one
claims of takeover critics, hostile deals did not that competes directly with corporate conglomer-
typically lead to large cutbacks in investment or blue- ates. With staffs of fewer than 50 professionals, LBO
collar employment.13 And when they did—again, partnerships were said to provide essentially the
usually in consolidating industries with excess ca- same coordination and monitoring function per-
pacity—the cutbacks were roughly proportional to formed by corporate headquarters staffs numbering,
those made by other industry competitors not sub- in some cases, in the thousands. As Jensen put it,
jected to takeover. Those layoffs that did take place “The LBO succeeded by substituting incentives held
after hostile takovers tended to be concentrated in out by compensation and ownership plans for the
corporate headquarters and not on the factory floor. direct monitoring and often centralized decision-
And, as for the R & D issue, the targets of hostile making of the typical corporate bureaucracy.”14 For
takeovers didn’t spend much on R & D to begin operating managers, in short, the LBO held out a
with—and this was also true of LBO firms (as we “new deal”: greater decision-making autonomy and
discuss later). ownership incentives in return for meeting more
So, if they were not laying off rank-and-file demanding performance targets.
workers and gutting investment and research pro-
grams in the drive to make a quick buck, how were The Important Differences
corporate raiders—after paying large premiums over
market and hefty fees to lawyers and investment Let’s look more closely at the differences be-
bankers—paying the rent? The answer Bhide offers tween LBO firms and the way most public compa-
is that, besides making cutbacks in overhead and nies were run in the 1980s.
unprofitable corporate reinvestment, the raiders First of all, as newly private companies, LBO
played a “limited, but significant arbitrage role” in firms no longer had any motive for reporting higher
buying large diversified conglomerates, dismantling EPS. Thus, LBOs effectively increased their after-tax
them, and then selling the parts for a sum greater cash flow by choosing accounting methods that
than the value of the conglomerate whole. Of the 81 would minimize reported earnings—and hence
businesses sold by the 47 targets of hostile offers in taxes paid—for a given level of pre-tax operating
Bhide’s sample, at least 78 had been previously profits. Many public companies, when confronted
acquired rather than developed from within. And with the same choice, would routinely choose
roughly 75% of those divested operations were sold accounting methods designed to boost reported

13. For macro data that confirm this finding about the 1980s in general, see 14. Michael Jensen, “Active Investors, LBOs, and the Privatization of Bank-
Michael Jensen (1992), cited above. ruptcy,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 2 No. 1 (Summer 1988).

36
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
For operating managers, the LBO held out a “new deal”: greater decision-making
autonomy and ownership incentives in return for meeting more demanding
performance targets.

earnings, even if this resulted in higher taxes and ....................................................................................


hence lower after-tax cash flow.15 THE CASE OF DURACELL
More important, where operating managers in Consider, for example, what Robert Kidder, CEO of
many large U.S. companies tend to treat investor Duracell, had to say about the firm’s goals after it was
capital as a “free” good, a major concern of LBO firms purchased from Dart & Kraft by KKR in an LBO:
was to produce sufficient operating cash flow to “The debt schedule is very effective in forcing manage-
meet their high required interest and principal ment to attend to profitability in the near term. But, let me
payments. In the average LBO of the 1980s, the debt- emphasize that another important consideration—in
to-assets ratio increased from about 20% to 90%. some sense, more important than short-term cash flow—
Such heavy debt financing had the effect of making is carrying through on strategic commitments. There is a
the cost of capital in LBO companies highly visible widespread public misconception that because you’re an
and, indeed, contractually binding. Failure to ser- LBO, you have to do everything possible to generate short-
vice debt could mean loss of operating managers’ term cash flow, and that LBOs thus simply represent a
jobs (as well as their own equity investment); and it means of sacrificing future profit for immediate gain....
would almost certainly mean a reduction of the LBO Now, I don’t mean to suggest that we don’t do everything
partnership’s financial (and reputational) capital. possible to reduce waste and cut costs. But, when I talk with
The heavy use of debt financing also provided Henry Kravis at lunch, we don’t spend our time talking
what amounted to an automatic internal monitoring- about cost reductions. We talk about how we’re increasing
and-control system. That is, if problems were devel- the strategic value of the company—and by that I mean
oping, top management would be forced by the our long-term cash flow capability.”17
pressure of the debt service to intervene quickly and
decisively. By contrast, in a largely-equity-financed In the average Fortune 1000 firm, as Jensen
firm, management could allow much of the equity notes, the CEO’s total compensation changes by
cushion to be eaten away before taking the neces- less than $3 for every $1000 change in shareholder
sary corrective action.16 value. By comparison, the average operating head
In addition to this explicit cost-of-capital target, in an LBO firm in the ’80s experienced a change of
operating managers were also provided—if not roughly $64 per $1000; and the entire operating
required to purchase—a significant equity stake. management team owned about 20% of the equity,
Such ownership was designed in part to encourage and thus earned close to $200 per $1000 change in
managers to resist the temptation, potentially strong value.18 Moreover, the partners of the LBO firm
in cases of high leverage, to produce “short-term” itself (the KKRs of this world), which is the proper
profits at the expense of the corporate future. For, equivalent of a conglomerate CEO, controlled about
even in those LBOs with exit strategies clearly 60% of the equity through their buyout funds.
defined at the outset, managers who are also signifi- Given such dramatic concentrations of owner-
cant owners have incentives to devote the optimal ship and improvements in the pay-for-performance
level of corporate capital—neither too much nor too correlation, researchers were not surprised to find
little—to expenditures with longer-run payoffs such major operating improvements in companies that
as advertising and plant maintenance. Regardless of were taken private through LBOs. There is now a
how an LBO is eventually cashed out—whether by large body of academic evidence on LBOs in the
means of an IPO, a sale to another firm, or a recap 1980s that attests to the following:19
involving another private investment group or man- shareholders earned premiums of 40% to 50%
agement team—it is still true that the greater the level when selling their shares into LBOs;
of productive investment undertaken by operating operating cash flow of LBOs increased by about
managers, the higher the value of their shares when 40%, on average, over periods ranging from two to
traded in. four years after the buyout;

15. Corporate managers persist in such EPS-boosting practices even in the face 17. “CEO Roundtable on Corporate Structure and Management Incentives,”
of academic evidence that the stock market rewards higher cash flow rather than Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 3 No. 3 (Fall 1990), pp. 8-9.
reported earnings in cases—such as LIFO vs. FIFO inventory accounting and 18. Jensen (1989).
purchase vs. pooling accounting for acquisitions—where the two measures go in 19. For a review of research on LBOs, their governance changes, and their
opposite directions. productivity effects, see Krishna Palepu, “Consequences of Leveraged Buyouts,”
16. For a demonstration of this point, see Jensen (1989), cited earlier. Journal of Financial Economics 27, No. 1 (1990), 247-262.

37
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
in cases where LBOs later went public or were sold “Unlike the boards of public companies, our board
to another company or investor group, the average members come to the table already knowing a great deal
firm value (that is, the market value of debt plus about the operations and expected behavior of the busi-
equity) increased by 235% (96%, when adjusted for nesses in various economic and competitive situations.
general market movements) from two months prior to This knowledge comes from the extensive due diligence
the buyout offer to the time of going public or sale (a process we have conducted just prior to the acquisitions.
holding period of three years, on average). So we are able to determine when management has really
there is little evidence in LBOs of a drop in employ- gotten off the track far more quickly and confidently than
ment levels or average wages of blue-collar workers; most public company directors....
LBO firms were not doing much R & D to begin with; We [also] have a much tighter performance measure-
only about 10% of LBO firms were engaging in ment system, by necessity, than most public companies
enough R & D before the LBO to report it separately in I’m familiar with. The pressure to ensure that goals are
their financial statements; being met is just far greater than that which exists in
LBO boards, with typically eight or fewer mem- most public companies. At the same time, this sense of
bers, represent about 60% of the equity, on average. urgency does not prevent us from setting and pursuing
As the last finding suggests, however, it was long-term goals. Our goal at the Blackstone Group is
not just better-designed performance measures and maximizing shareholder value, and you can’t command
stronger ownership incentives that lay behind the a high price for a business if all you’ve been doing is
success of LBOs. The LBO governance system is liquidating its assets and failing to invest in its future
also fundamentally different from that of most pub- earnings power. And since management are also major
lic corporations. In fact, LBOs borrow several of the equity holders in the company, we are confident that
central governance features of venture capital firms. they are constantly attempting to balance short-term and
Much as in venture capital firms like Kleiner long-term goals in creating value.” 20
Perkins, the boards of companies owned by LBO
partnerships like KKR and Clayton & Dubilier are What Went Wrong with the LBOs?
designed in large part to overcome many of the
information problems facing boards of directors in All this is not to suggest that the LBO movement
public companies. The directors of a typical LBO was without flaws, or to deny that mistakes were
don’t merely represent the outside shareholders, made in structuring many of the deals. Beginning in
they are the principal shareholders. Moreover, they 1989, there was a sharp increase in the number of
have become the principal owners only after having defaults and bankruptcies of LBOs. Most of the
participated in an intensive “due diligence” process problems, it turns out, came in the deals transacted
intended to reveal the true profit potential of the in the latter half of the 1980s. Of the 41 LBOs with
business. And, as in the case of venture capital firms, purchase prices of $100 million or more transacted
the board members in LBOs also typically handle the between 1980 and 1984, only one defaulted on its
corporate finance function, including negotiations debt. By contrast, of the 83 large deals done between
with lenders and the investment banking commu- 1985 and 1989, at least 26 defaulted and 18 went into
nity. If operating companies get into financial or bankruptcy.21
operating difficulty, the board intervenes quickly, What went wrong with the later deals? Just as
often appointing one of its members to step in as Jensen was the first economist to see the value-
CEO until the crisis passes. adding potential of LBOs, he was also the first to
identify the source of the problems that were arising
.................................................................................... in the later transactions. Stated in brief, Jensen’s
THE CASE OF THE BLACKSTONE GROUP analysis pointed to a “gross misalignment of incen-
James Birle, General Partner of the Blackstone Group, tives” between the dealmakers who promoted the
comments as follows on the differences between the LBO transactions and the lenders and other investors who
governance process and that of most public companies: funded them. Such a “contracting failure” led to a

20. James Birle, “Continental Bank Roundtable on the Role of Corporate 21. Steven Kaplan and Jeremy Stein, “The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and
Boards in the 1990s,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 5 No. 3 (Fall 1992), Financial Structure in the 1980s,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 6 No. 1
pp. 68. (Spring 1993).

38
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Where operating managers in many large U.S. companies tend to treat investor
capital as a “free” good, the heavy debt financing in LBOs had the effect of making
the cost of capital highly visible and, indeed, contractually binding.

concentration of overpriced, poorly structured deals First, of course, is their reliance on high lever-
in the second half of the ’80s.22 age. The role of debt financing in LBOs limits their
Jensen’s diagnosis was supported, moreover, use primarily to mature industries with modest
by an important study by Steven Kaplan and Jeremy capital requirements, tangible assets, and highly
Stein demonstrating that (1) buyout prices as mul- stable cash flows. Although some steady-state ser-
tiples of cash flow rose sharply in LBOs completed vice companies may prove suitable for LBOs, high-
in the period 1986-1988, especially in junk-bond- growth and high-tech companies will generally not.
financed transactions; (2) junk bonds displaced In the latter case, the expected costs of debt financing
much of both the bank debt and the private subor- in the form of lost investment opportunities are just
dinated debt in the later LBOs, thereby sharply too large.25
raising the costs of reorganizing troubled compa- The second limitation of LBOs stems from one
nies; and (3) management and other interested of their principal benefits: the concentration of
parties, notably the dealmakers, put in less equity equity ownership. Concentration of ownership also
and took out more money up front in later deals.23 means a concentration of risk-bearing. One of the
main advantages of the public corporation is its
The Limitations of LBOs efficiency in spreading risk among well-diversified
investors. At some point, increasing the “firm-spe-
A private market correction to the contracting cific” risk borne by the management team becomes
problem noted by Jensen and others was already self-defeating because such managers will require
underway when regulators intervened heavily in the sufficiently higher compensating rewards (in the
summer of 1989. There was already a general form of stock or profit sharing) that there will be less
movement toward larger equity commitments, less left over for shareholders, even after considering the
debt, lower transaction prices, and lower upfront incentive benefits of such concentrated ownership.26
fees when S&L legislation (FIRREA) and HLT regu- It is this heavy concentration of risk, not mana-
lations created a downward spiral in high-yield bond gerial shortsightedness, that explains why so many
prices (and, some would argue, in business activity LBOs return to public ownership in five years or less.
in general). And much tightened oversight by bank When they enter into an LBO, both owners and
regulators made it virtually impossible to reorganize operating managers are betting on their ability to
troubled companies outside of Chapter 11 (by increase the value of the organization. But, in order
contrast, low-cost, expeditious private work-outs to limit the scope of their bet and minimize their
were a common event for the first wave of LBOs exposure to risks beyond their control, they typically
during the severe recession of 1981-82).24 have an exit or cash-out strategy. In his study of “The
As a consequence, LBOs and other HLTs under- Staying Power of Leveraged Buyouts,” Steven Kaplan
went a sharp decline during the early 1990s. But, in reported that, as of early 1993, roughly half of the
the past few years, LBOs have begun to show signs large LBOs ($100 million or more) of the 1980s had
of a resurgence. Nevertheless, even with the con- reverted to public ownership. Even so, some 90% of
tracting problems of the late ’80s largely corrected, the 2,500 LBOs (large and small) transacted since the
there are still inherent limitations in the LBO form late 1970s still remain private; and, as Kaplan also
that are likely to ensure them at most a fairly reported, those LBOs that had gone public through
specialized role in the U.S. economy. IPOs retained two distinguishing features of the LBO

22. See the comments by Michael Jensen in “The Economic Consequences of 25. Although some observers have predicted an extension of the LBO form
High Leverage and Stock Market Pressures on Corporate Management: A Roundtable to high-growth, high-tech companies, the lower leverage and greater dispersion
Discussion,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance Vol. 3 No. 2 (Summer 1990), pp. of equity that is best suited to such riskier companies will ultimately work to
8-9. For a more formal elaboration of this argument, see Michael Jensen, “Corporate undermine the very sources of financial discipline that have helped to make LBOs
Control and the Politics of Finance,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4 so effective. For a discussion of corporate debt capacity that bears on this issue,
No. 2 (Summer, 1991), pp. 25-27. see Michael Barclay, Clifford Smith, and Ross Watts, “The Determinants of
23. As reported in Kaplan and Stein (1993). Corporate Leverage and Dividend Policies,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance,
24. See Michael Jensen, “Corporate Control and the Politics of Finance,” Winter 1995.
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 27-29. As Jensen writes, 26. See the article in this issue by Randy Beatty, “Management Incentives,
“Such regulations...reduced the flexibility of lenders to work with highly leveraged Monitoring, and Risk-bearing in IPO Firms,” which shows that riskier IPOs actually
companies who could not meet lending covenants or current debt service tend to have lower percentage ownership.
payments. These changes, coming on top of the departure of Drexel, the principal
market maker, caused a sharp increase in defaults.”

39
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
form: (1) considerably higher leverage (though First, increase the return derived from the assets
below buyout levels) compared to that of their already tied up in the business. Run the income
public competitors; and (2) significantly more con- statement more efficiently without investing any
centrated equity ownership by insiders (over 40%, more capital on the balance sheet.
on average).27 Second, invest additional capital and aggressively
build the business so long as the return earned
EVA: A NEW FINANCIAL MODEL exceeds the cost of that new capital. (Targets based
FOR PUBLIC COMPANIES on rates of return such as ROE or ROI, incidentally,
can actually discourage this objective when divisions
The accomplishments of the LBO movement are earning well above their cost of capital, because
have some important lessons for the structure and taking on some EVA-increasing projects will lower
governance of public companies. For most large their average return.)
public companies, of course, it will not make sense Third, stop investing in, and find ways to release
to raise leverage ratios to 90%. Nor will it generally capital from, activities that earn substandard returns.
be cost-effective to provide significant stock owner- This means everything from turning working capital
ship for most operating managers. In such cases, top faster and speeding up cycle times to consolidating
management must design a performance measure- operations and selling assets worth more to others.
ment and reward system that simulates the feel and Besides making the cost of capital explicit, the
payoff of ownership. This is the principal aim of an EVA performance measure can also be designed to
EVA financial management system. encourage tax-minimizing accounting choices and
Like LBOs, but without the costs of high lever- to incorporate a number of other adjustments in-
age or excessive risk-bearing, an EVA-based perfor- tended to eliminate distortions of economic perfor-
mance measurement system makes the cost of mance introduced by conventional accounting mea-
capital explicit. In its simplest form, EVA is net sures like earnings or ROE. For example, one notable
operating profit after taxes less a charge for the shortcoming of GAAP accounting stems from its
capital employed to produce those profits. The insistence that many corporate outlays with longer-
capital charge is the required, or minimum, rate of term payoffs (like R & D or training) be fully
return necessary to compensate all the firm’s inves- expensed rather than capitalized and amortized over
tors, debtholders as well as shareholders, for the risk an appropriate period. While well-suited to credi-
of the investment.28 tors’ concerns about liquidation values, such ac-
To illustrate, a company with a 10% cost of capi- counting conservatism can make financial state-
tal that earns a 20% return on $100 million of net ments unreliable as guides to going-concern values.
operating assets has an EVA of $10 million. This says More important, to the extent GAAP’s conservatism
the company is earning $10 million more in profit is built into a company’s performance measurement
than is required to cover all costs, including the op- and compensation system, it can unduly shorten
portunity cost of tying up scarce capital on the bal- managers’ planning horizon.
ance sheet. In this sense, EVA combines operating In setting up EVA systems, we sometimes advise
efficency and balance sheet management into one companies to capitalize portions of their R&D,
measure that can be understood by operating people. marketing, training, and even restructuring costs. In
For operating heads and top management alike, cases of other “strategic” investments with deferred
EVA holds out three principal ways of increasing payoffs, we have also developed a procedure for
shareholder value: keeping such capital “off the books” (for internal

27. As Steven Kaplan has noted, there appear to be two distinct species of Capital Asset Pricing Model, which allows for a specific, market-based evaluation
LBOs: (1) a “shock-therapy” variety, in which the LBO provides a vehicle for largely of risk for a company and its individual business units using the concept of “beta.”
“one-time” improvements; and (2) a relatively permanent, “incentive-intensive” In addition, the tax benefit of debt financing is factored into the cost of capital, but
type, in which the company’s investors and managers become convinced that the in such a way as to avoid the distortions that arise from mixing operating and
company is fundamentally more valuable as a private company than public. See financing decisions. To compute EVA, the operating profit for the company and
Steven Kaplan, “The Staying Power of the Leveraged Buyouts,” Journal of Applied for each of the units is charged for capital at a rate that blends the after-tax cost
Corporate Finance, Spring 1993. This article is a shorter, less technical, and partly of debt and equity in the target proportions each would plan to employ rather than
updated version of another article with the same title published in the Journal of the actual mix each actually uses year-by-year. Moreover, operating leases are
Financial Economics 29 (1991). capitalized and considered a form of debt capital for this purpose. As a result, new
28. EVA is charged for capital at a rate that compensates investors for bearing investment opportunities are neither penalized nor subsidized by the specific forms
the firm’s explicit business risk. The assessment of business risk is based upon the of financing employed.

40
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Even with the contracting problems of the late ’80s largely corrected, there are
limitations inherent in the LBO form that are likely to ensure them at most a fairly
specialized role in the U.S. economy.

evaluation purposes) and then gradually readmitting through the income statement and balance sheet to
it into the manager’s internal capital acount to reflect key operating and strategic levers available to them
the expected payoffs over time. As these examples in managing their business. This framework has
are meant to suggest, EVA can be used to encourage proven to be quite useful in focusing management’s
a more far-sighted corporate investment policy than attention, diagnosing performance problems,
traditional financial measures based upon GAAP benchmarking with peers, and enhancing planning.
accounting principles. More generally, it has helped people up and down
In defining and refining its EVA measure, Stern the line to appreciate the role they have to play in
Stewart has identified over 120 shortcomings in improving value. It can also help guard against an
conventional GAAP accounting. In addition to GAAP’s excessive preoccupation with improving individual
inability to handle R&D and other corporate invest- operational metrics to the detriment of overall per-
ments, we have addressed performance measure- formance. For example, a drive to increase produc-
ment problems associated with standard accounting tivity—or, say, a single-minded obsession with win-
treatments of the following: inventory costing and ning the Malcolm Baldridge Award—could lead to
valuation; depreciation; revenue recognition; the unwarranted capital spending or to shifts in product
writing-off of bad debts; mandated investments in mix that result in less EVA and value, not more. In
safety and environmental compliance; pension and the end, management must be held accountable for
post-retirement medical expense; valuation of con- delivering value, not improving metrics.29
tingent liabilities and hedges; transfer pricing and
overhead allocations; captive finance and insurance THE EVA FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT SYSTEM
companies; joint ventures and start-ups; and special
issues of taxation, inflation, and currency translation. As we suggested at the beginning of this article,
For most of these accounting issues, we have crafted the real success of business today depends not on
a series of cases to illustrate the performance mea- having a well-thought-out, far-reaching strategy, but
surement problem, and devised a variety of practical rather on re-engineering a company’s business sys-
methods to modify reported accounting results in tems to respond more effectively to the new business
order to improve the accuracy with which EVA environment of continuous change. Our contention
measures real economic income. at Stern Stewart is that just as this information revolu-
Of course, no one company is likely to trigger tion has created a need for business process re-engi-
all 120 measurement issues. In most cases, we find neering, it has also precipitated a need to re-engineer
it necessary to address only some 15 to 25 key issues the corporate financial management system.
in detail—and as few as five or ten key adjustments What do we mean by a financial management
are actually made in practice. We recommend that system? A financial management system consists of
adjustments to the definition of EVA be made only all those financial policies, procedures, methods,
in those cases that pass four tests: and measures that guide a company’s operations and
Is it likely to have a material impact on EVA? its strategy. It has to do with how companies address
Can the managers influence the outcome? such questions as: What are our overall corporate
Can the operating people readily grasp it? financial goals and how do we communicate them,
Is the required information relatively easy to track both within the company and to the investment
or derive? community? How do we evaluate business plans
For any one company, then, the definition of EVA when they come up for review? How do we allocate
that is implemented is highly customized with the resources—everything from the purchase of an indi-
aim of striking a practical balance between simplicity vidual piece of equipment, to the acquisition of an
and precision. entire company, to opportunities for downsizing and
To make the measure more user-friendly, we restructuring? How do we evaluate ongoing operat-
have also developed a management tool called “EVA ing performance? Last but not least, how do we pay
Drivers” that enables management to trace EVA our people, what is our corporate reward system?

29. Nevertheless, our research suggests a remarkably strong correlation assessment of such criteria as customer responsiveness, innovation, time-to-
between a company’s EVA performance, its shareholder value added (or “MVA”), market, and management quality. See Bennett Stewart, “EVA: Fact and Fantasy,”
and its standing in Fortune’s Most Admired survey, a ranking based upon an Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 7 No. 2 (Summer 1994).

41
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
Many companies these days have ended up operating managers to make the right decisions.
with a needlessly complicated and, in many re- There’s no real accountability built into the system,
spects, hopelessly obsolete financial management there’s no real incentive for operating heads to
system. For example, most companies use dis- choose only those investment projects that will
counted cash flow analysis for capital budgeting increase value.
evaluations. But, when it comes to other purposes
such as setting goals and communicating with in- ....................................................................................
vestors, the same companies tend to reach for THE CASE OF BRIGGS AND STRATTON
accounting proxies—measures like earnings, earn- At the annual shareholders’ meeting in 1991, Chairman
ings per share, EPS growth, profit margins, ROE, Fred Stratton of Briggs & Stratton noted that the company’s
and the like. To the extent this is true, it means there stock was up 70% from the previous year, having
is already a “disconnect” between the cash-flow- outperformed the S&P 500 by about 40%. Stratton attrib-
based capital budget and accounting-based corpo- uted the company’s success in large part to the company’s
rate goals. To make matters worse, the bonuses for newly adopted “performance measurement and compen-
operating people, as we noted earlier, tend to be sation system” based on EVA.
structured around achieving some annually negoti- “Part of our problem in the early 1980s,” comments
ated profit figure. president and chief operating officer John Shiely, “was an
This widespread corporate practice of using antiquated functional ‘top-down’ structure. Nobody other
different financial measures for different corporate than the CEO and the president was being held account-
functions creates inconsistency, and thus consider- able for the profitability of our various lines. Under
able confusion, in the management process. And, Chairman Fred Stratton’s direction, we developed a plan
given all the different, often conflicting, measures to totally revamp the organization into discrete operating
of performance, it is understandable that corporate divisions. While the initial move was painful, the positive
operating people tend to throw their hands in the results were almost immediate. By pushing operating
air and say, “So, what are you really trying to get responsibility, including capital decisions, down to the
me to do here? What is the real financial mission of level where they could be effectively managed, we accom-
our company?” plished a dramatic improvement in earnings and cash
With EVA, all principal facets of the financial flow. Each of our seven new divisions now has its own
management process are tied to just one measure, functional management, resources, and capital. Each
making the overall system far easier to administer must develop very detailed strategic business unit plans.
and understand. That is, although the process of And each has an EVA incentive based on value created by
coming up with the right definition of EVA for any the division.”
given firm is often complicated and time-consuming, “Before moving to an EVA system, the company took
the measure itself, once established, becomes the pride in making almost all components in-house. We now
focal point of a simpler, more integrated overall buy premium engines, at significantly lower cost, from
financial management system—one that can serve to outside sources. Molded plastics and other components,
unite all the varied interests and functions within a once made in small batches in-house, now flow from
large corporation. suppliers in huge quantities. As a result, operating profits
Why is it so important to have only one mea- have risen while the amount of capital required to gener-
sure? As we noted earlier, the natural inclination of ate them has fallen sharply.”
operating managers in large public companies is to
get their hands on more capital in order to spend and EVA is the internal measure management can
grow the empire. This tendency in turn leads to an decentralize throughout the company and use as the
overtly political internal competition for capital— basis for a completely integrated financial manage-
one in which different performance measures are ment system. It allows all key management decisions
used to gain approval for pet projects. And because to be clearly modelled, monitored, communicated,
of this tendency toward empire-building, top man- and rewarded according to how much value they
agement typically feels compelled to intervene ex- add to shareholders’ investment. Whether reviewing
cessively—not in day-to-day decision making, but in a capital budgeting project, valuing an acquisition,
capital spending decisions. Why? Because they don’t considering strategic plan alternatives, assessing
trust the financial management system to guide their performance, or determining bonuses, the goal of

42
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Although the process of coming up with the right definition of EVA for any given
firm is often complicated and time-consuming, the measure itself, once established,
becomes the focal point of a simpler, more integrated financial management
system—one that can serve to unite all the varied interests and functions within a
large corporation.

increasing EVA over time offers a clear financial over time. Paying for improvements in rather than
mission for management and a means of improving absolute levels of EVA is designed mainly to solve the
accountability and incentives. In this sense, it offers problem of “unequal endowments.” This way, man-
a new model of internal corporate governance. agers of businesses with sharply negative EVA can
be given a strong incentive to engineer a turn-
EVA AND THE CORPORATE REWARD SYSTEM around—and those managers of businesses already
producing large positive EVA do not receive a
Incentive compensation is the anchor of the windfall simply for showing up.
EVA financial management system. The term “in- Besides leveling the playing field for managers
centive compensation” is not quite right, however, inheriting different circumstances, bonuses tied to
for in practice too much emphasis gets placed on improvements in rather than levels of EVA are also
the word “compensation” and not enough on the “self-financing” in the following sense: to the extent
word “incentive.” The proper objective is to make that a company’s current stock tends to reflect
managers behave as if they were owners. Owners current levels of EVA, it is only changes in current
manage with a sense of urgency in the short term levels of EVA that are likely to be correlated with
but pursue a vision for the long term. They wel- changes in stock price.30 And, to the extent the
come change rather than resisting it. Above all else, managers of a given company succeed in increasing
they personally identify with the successes and the a company’s EVA and so earn higher bonus awards
failures of the enterprise. for themselves, those higher bonuses are more than
Extending an ownership interest is also the paid for by the increase in shareholder value that
best way to motivate managers in the information tends to accompany increases in EVA.
age. As the pace of change increases and the As with a true ownership stake, EVA bonuses
world becomes ever less predictable, line manag- are not capped. They are potentially unlimited (on
ers need more general as opposed to specific the downside as well as upside), depending en-
measures of performance to which they will be tirely on managerial performance. But, to guard
held accountable. They need more leeway to re- against the possibility of short-term “gaming” of the
spond to changes in the environment. They need a system, we have devised a “bonus bank” concept
broader and longer-range mandate to motivate and that works as follows: Annual bonus awards are
guide them. Maximizing shareholder value is the not paid out in full, but instead are banked forward
one goal that remains constant, even as the spe- and held “at risk,” with full payout contingent on
cific means to achieve it are subject to dramatic continued successful performance. Each year’s bo-
and unpredictable shifts. nus award is carried forward from the prior year
Making managers into owners should not be and a fraction—for example, one third—of that
undertaken as an “add-on” to current incentive total is paid out, with the remainder banked into
compensation methods. Rather, it should replace the next year.
them. In place of the traditional short-term bonus Thus, in a good year, a manager is rewarded—
linked to budget and ordinary stock option grants, much like a shareholder who receives cash divi-
the EVA ownership plan employs two simple, dis- dends and capital appreciation—with an increase
tinct elements: (1) a cash bonus plan that simulates in both the cash bonus paid out and in the bonus
ownership; and (2) a leveraged stock option (LSO) bank carried forward. But, in a poor year—again,
plan that makes ownership real. much like a shareholder—the penalty is a shrunken
cash distribution and a depletion in the bank bal-
The EVA Bonus Plan: Simulating Ownership ance that must be recouped before a full cash
bonus distribution is again possible. Because the
The cash bonus plan simulates ownership pri- bonus paid in any one year is an accumulation of
marily by tying bonuses to improvements in EVA the bonuses earned over time, the distinction be-

30. Our own research indicates that the changes in companies’ EVAs over a sales explained just 10% of the MVA changes, growth in earnings-per-share about
five-year period account for nearly 50% of the changes in their market value added, 15% to 20%, and return on equity only 35%. For a description of this research, see
or MVAs, over that same time frame. (MVA, which is a measure of the shareholder Bennett Stewart, “Announcing the Stern Stewart Performance 1,000,” Journal of
value added by management, is roughly equal to the difference between the total Applied Corporate Finance Vol. 3 No. 2 (Summer 1990).
market value and the book value of the firm’s equity.) By comparison, growth in

43
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
tween a long-term and a short-term bonus plan fundamental contradiction: How can managers with
becomes meaningless. limited financial resources be made into significant
When combined with such a bonus bank sys- owners without unfairly diluting the current share-
tem, EVA incentive plans tied to continuous im- holders? Showering them with stock options or
provement also help to break the counterproductive restricted stock is apt to be quite expensive for the
link between bonuses and budgets that we de- shareholders, notwithstanding the incentive for the
scribed earlier. EVA targets are automatically reset managers. And asking the managers to buy lots of
from one year to the next by formula, not annual stock is apt to be excessively risky for them.
negotiation. For example, if EVA should decline for One approach we recommend to resolve this
whatever reason, management will suffer a reduced, dilemma is to encourage (or require) managers to
possibly negative bonus in that year. In the following purchase common equity in the form of special
year, however, the minimal standard of performance leveraged stock options (LSOs). Unlike ordinary
for the next year’s bonus will be set somewhat options, these are initially in-the-money and not at-
lower—again, by a pre-set formula. This automatic the-money, are bought and not granted, and project
lowering of expectations is designed to help compa- the exercise price to rise at a rate that sets aside a
nies retain and motivate good managers through bad minimal acceptable return for the shareholders be-
times by giving them a renewed opportunity to earn fore management participates.
a decent bonus if they can reverse the company’s Although managers’ purchase of LSOs could be
fortune. At the same time, however, it avoids the funded by them as a one-time investment, we
problem—inherent in the stock option “repricing” typically recommend that managers be allowed to
practices of so many public companies—of reward- buy them only with a portion of their EVA bonuses.
ing managers handsomely when the stock drops Besides providing even more deferred compensa-
sharply and then simply returns to current levels. tion, this practice helps ensure that only those
In combination with a bonus bank, then, the use managers who have added value in their own
of objective formulas to reset targets eliminates the operations are allowed to participate in the success
problems of “sandbagging” on budgets and encour- of the entire enterprise.
ages collaborative, long-range planning. Instead of To illustrate how an LSO operates, consider a
wasting time managing the expectations of their company with a current common share price of
supervisors, managers are motivated to propose and $10. The initial exercise price on the LSO is set at a
execute aggressive business plans. Moreover, be- 10% discount from the current stock price, or $9,
cause it compensates the end of creating value rather making the option worth $1 right out of the gate.
than the means of getting there, the EVA bonus plan But instead of just handing the LSOs to manage-
is entirely consistent with the movement to decen- ment, managers are required to purchase them for
tralize and empower. the $1 discount, and that money is put at risk.
In sum, the banking of bonuses tied to continu- Another difference between LSOs and regular op-
ous improvements in EVA helps companies to tions is that the exercise price is projected to
smooth cyclical bumps and grinds, extends manag- increase at a rate that approximates the cost of
ers’ time horizons, and encourages good performers capital (less a discount for undiversifiable risk and
accumulating equity in their bank accounts to stay illiquidity)—let’s say 10% per annum. In this case,
and poor performers running up deficits to go. In so over a five-year period (and ignoring compound-
doing, the EVA bonus bank functions as both a long- ing for simplicity), the exercise price will rise 50%
term and short-term plan at one and the same time. above the current $9 level to $13.50. In sum,
management pays $1 today for an option to pur-
Leveraged Stock Options: Making chase the company’s stock (currently worth $10)
Ownership Real for $13.50 five years down the road.
Only if the company’s equity value grows at a
The annual EVA cash bonus is intended to rate faster than the exercise price will management
simulate an owner’s stake. In many cases, however, come out ahead. Indeed, if the exercise price rises
it will often be valuable to supplement the bonus at a rate equal to the cost of capital (less the dividend
plan with actual stock ownership by management. yield), then the LSOs wll provide exactly the same
Pursuit of that goal, however, runs headlong into this incentives as an EVA bonus plan. It rewards manage-

44
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
LSOs can be seen as putting management in the position of participating in an LBO,
but without requiring an actual LBO of the company.

ment for generating a spread between the company’s The net effect was to increase the cash portion of the
rate of return on capital and the cost of that capital EVA bonus, and to increase significantly management’s
(as reflected by the rate of increase in the exercise interest in upside stock performance, but in exchange for
price) times the capital employed by management to taking more risk. In particular, LSOs are purchased only
purchase the shares. if earned (whereas before options were granted to
Perhaps a better comparison, however, is be- management each year as a matter of course), and the
tween the incentives held out by LSOs and those LSOs will come into the money only after a significant
provided by leveraged buyouts. LSOs can be seen as appreciation of the stock price.
putting management in the position of participating Investors reacted favorably to this restructuring of
in an LBO, but without requiring an actual LBO of the incentive pay. From a price of $65 a share at the close of
company. By virtue of their being purchased 10% in the 1993 fiscal year (June 30), B & S’s shares rose to $85
the money, LSOs effectively replicate the 90% debt over a period of just several months as the market began
and 10% equity that characterized the structure of the to appreciate the powerful new incentives for manage-
LBOs of this past decade. Companies ranging from ment represented by the plan.
Briggs & Stratton, Centura Bank, CSX, Fletcher Chal-
lenge (the largest industrial company in New Zealand), In sum, the EVA ownership plan replaces the
R.P Scherer, and Varity have adopted LSO plans. traditional short-term bonus linked to budget and
At bottom, then, LSOs (and LBOs, as we have ordinary stock option grants with two components:
seen) also boil down to EVA, to the idea that (1) a cash bonus plan that simulates ownership; and
management should participate only in those returns (2) a leveraged stock option plan that confers actual
in excess of a company’s required rate of return. But ownership. The cash bonus plan simulates owner-
while conceptually identical to an EVA bonus plan, ship by tying bonuses to sustained improvements in
LSOs are likely to be an even more powerful EVA over time, with a large portion of awarded
motivator because they amplify the risks and re- bonuses held in escrow and subject to loss to ensure
wards for management. Any improvement in EVA that improvements are permanent. The LSO plan
that investors think will be sustained is capitalized corrects the deficiencies of normal stock option
into the value of the shares; for example, a company plans in two ways: the leverage factor allows man-
with a cost of capital of 10% that increases its EVA by agers to purchase significantly more stock for a given
$1 million will see its value appreciate by $10 million. amount of dollars (thus replicating an LBO’s effect on
For managers holding the LSOs, such capitalized ownership); and a steadily rising exercise price
increases in value are themselves further leveraged ensures that managers win only if shareholders do.
10 to 1, thus creating $100 of added managerial
wealth for each $1 improvement in EVA. This IN CLOSING
leveraging effect makes LSOs a potent way to get
management to concentrate on building EVA over An EVA financial management system repre-
the long haul. sents a way to institutionalize the running of a
.................................................................................... business in accordance with basic microeconomic
BACK TO BRIGGS & STRATTON and corporate finance principles. When properly
Having tasted success with their initial EVA bonus plan, implemented, it is a closed-loop system of deci-
management’s appetite was whetted for taking more risk sion-making, accountability, and incentives—one
in return for the prospect of an even greater return. In that has the potential to make the entire organiza-
August 1993, the board approved a revised Stock Incen- tion and not just the CEO responsible for the
tive Plan “to reward executives based on their ability to successes and failures of the enterprise. It can
continuously improve the amount of EVA earned on result in a self-regulated and self-motivated system
behalf of shareholders.” Under the new plan, the company’s of “internal” governance.
annual stock option grants were replaced with an equiva- As a concept, EVA starts simple, but in practice
lent increase in target EVA bonus awards, but with the it can be made as comprehensive as necessary to
requirement that one half of actual bonuses earned each accommodate management’s needs and preferences.
year would automatically be used to purchase leveraged EVA is most effective, however, when it is more
stock options (LSOs) at a cost equal to 10% of the than just a performance measure. At its best, EVA
company’s prevailing stock price. serves as the centerpiece of a completely integrated

45
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 2 SUMMER 1995
framework of financial management and incentive bank that ensures that only consistent, sustainable
compensation. When used in that manner, the increases in value are rewarded.
experience of a lengthening list of adopting com- EVA bonuses are tied to a performance measure
panies throughout the world strongly supports the that is highly correlated with shareholder value, thus
notion that an EVA system can refocus energies aligning managers’ with shareholders’ interests.
and redirect resources to create sustainable value— The strength of the correlation between changes in
for companies, customers, employees, sharehold- EVA and in shareholder value also means that the
ers, and for management. EVA compensation system is effectively “self-financ-
The anchor of the EVA financial management ing”; that is, managers win big only when sharehold-
system is a powerful incentive compensation plan ers are winning—and managers are truly penalized
that consists of two parts: (1) a cash bonus plan tied when shareholders lose.
to continuous improvement in EVA, in which a Proper internal governance is certainly no guar-
significant portion of the awarded bonuses are antee of success, and it is no substitute for leadership,
carried forward in a “bonus bank” and held at risk; entrepreneurism, and hustle. But an EVA financial
and (2) a leveraged stock option (LSO) plan, in which management and incentive system can help. We like
managers use part of their cash bonus awards to to say that EVA works like the proverbial Trojan
make highly leveraged purchases of company stock. Horse: What is wheeled in appears to be an innocu-
Such an EVA reward system holds out major ous new financial management and incentive pro-
benefits over more conventional compensation plans: gram, but what jumps out is a new culture that is right
Rewarding managers for continuous improvement for times of rapid change and decentralized deci-
in (rather than levels of) EVA means that new sion-making. By increasing accountability, strength-
managers neither receive windfalls for inheriting ening incentives, facilitating decentralized decision-
already profitable divisions, nor are they penalized making, establishing a common language and inte-
for stepping into turnaround situations. grated framework, and fostering a culture that prizes
In contrast to compensation plans that continually building value above all else, it significantly im-
revise performance criteria to provide “competitive” proves the chances of winning. That’s all any share-
compensation levels each year, the EVA bonus plan holder can reasonably expect from governance in
has a “long-term memory” in the form of a bonus today’s business environment of continuous change.

JOEL STERN DON CHEW

is Managing Partner of Stern Stewart & Co. is Executive Vice President, as well as a founding partner, of
Stern Stewart.
BENNETT STEWART

is Senior Partner of Stern Stewart & Co.

EVA® is a registered trademark of Stern Stewart & Co.

46
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (ISSN 1078-1196 [print], ISSN Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is available online through Synergy,
1745-6622 [online]) is published quarterly on behalf of Morgan Stanley by Blackwell’s online journal service which allows you to:
Blackwell Publishing, with offices at 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, • Browse tables of contents and abstracts from over 290 professional,
USA, and PO Box 1354, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2XG, UK. Call science, social science, and medical journals
US: (800) 835-6770, UK: +44 1865 778315; fax US: (781) 388-8232, UK: • Create your own Personal Homepage from which you can access your
+44 1865 471775, or e-mail: subscrip@bos.blackwellpublishing.com. personal subscriptions, set up e-mail table of contents alerts and run
saved searches
Information For Subscribers For new orders, renewals, sample copy re- • Perform detailed searches across our database of titles and save the
quests, claims, changes of address, and all other subscription correspon- search criteria for future use
dence, please contact the Customer Service Department at your nearest • Link to and from bibliographic databases such as ISI.
Blackwell office. Sign up for free today at http://www.blackwell-synergy.com.

Subscription Rates for Volume 17 (four issues) Institutional Premium Disclaimer The Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and the Editor cannot
Rate* The Americas† $330, Rest of World £201; Commercial Company Pre- be held responsible for errors or any consequences arising from the use of
mium Rate, The Americas $440, Rest of World £268; Individual Rate, The information contained in this journal. The views and opinions expressed in this
Americas $95, Rest of World £70, Ð105‡; Students**, The Americas $50, journal do not necessarily represent those of the Publisher, Morgan Stanley,
Rest of World £28, Ð42. its affiliates, and Editor, neither does the publication of advertisements con-
stitute any endorsement by the Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and
*Includes print plus premium online access to the current and all available Editor of the products advertised. No person should purchase or sell any
backfiles. Print and online-only rates are also available (see below). security or asset in reliance on any information in this journal.


Customers in Canada should add 7% GST or provide evidence of entitlement Morgan Stanley is a full service financial services company active in the securi-
to exemption ties, investment management and credit services businesses. Morgan Stanley
may have and may seek to have business relationships with any person or

Customers in the UK should add VAT at 5%; customers in the EU should also company named in this journal.
add VAT at 5%, or provide a VAT registration number or evidence of entitle-
ment to exemption Copyright © 2004 Morgan Stanley. All rights reserved. No part of this publi-
cation may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in whole or part in any form
** Students must present a copy of their student ID card to receive this or by any means without the prior permission in writing from the copyright
rate. holder. Authorization to photocopy items for internal or personal use or for the
internal or personal use of specific clients is granted by the copyright holder
For more information about Blackwell Publishing journals, including online ac- for libraries and other users of the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC), 222
cess information, terms and conditions, and other pricing options, please visit Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA (www.copyright.com), provided
www.blackwellpublishing.com or contact our customer service department, the appropriate fee is paid directly to the CCC. This consent does not extend
tel: (800) 835-6770 or +44 1865 778315 (UK office). to other kinds of copying, such as copying for general distribution for advertis-
ing or promotional purposes, for creating new collective works or for resale.
Back Issues Back issues are available from the publisher at the current single- Institutions with a paid subscription to this journal may make photocopies for
issue rate. teaching purposes and academic course-packs free of charge provided such
copies are not resold. For all other permissions inquiries, including requests
Mailing Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is mailed Standard Rate. Mail- to republish material in another work, please contact the Journals Rights and
ing to rest of world by DHL Smart & Global Mail. Canadian mail is sent by Permissions Coordinator, Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford
Canadian publications mail agreement number 40573520. Postmaster OX4 2DQ. E-mail: journalsrights@oxon.blackwellpublishing.com.
Send all address changes to Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Blackwell
Publishing Inc., Journals Subscription Department, 350 Main St., Malden, MA
02148-5020.

You might also like