You are on page 1of 41

Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.

ae

Relationship and Granger Causality between Competition

g.
tin
and Innovation: Banks in the Eurozone

ee
lM
ua
nn
Authors

tA
en
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

em
ag
an
fM
yo
em
ad
Ac
19
20
he
rt
fo
d
te
p
ce
ac
40
09
#1
ion
iss
bm
Su
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

10940

Relationship and Granger Causality between Competition and Innovation: Evidence from

Banks in the Eurozone

Abstract

Based on samples of banks from the initial 11 Eurozone member states, this study achieves two

goals. First, this paper presents new evidence to explore the relationship between competition

and innovation. Second, this paper examines Granger causality runs between the two variables.

Using the technology gap ratio to measure bank innovation and the Lerner index and Boone

indicator to measure bank competition, the paper reveals an inverted-U relationship between

competition and innovation. Using the full sample, the Granger causality tests indicate a full

negative bidirectional causality between competition and innovation. When separate Granger

causality test is examined on each of the upward slope and the downward slope of the inverted-U

curve, the results indicate a positive bidirectional causation between competition and innovation

along the upward slope, whereas a lack of support of causality link between competition and

innovation along the downward slope.

Keywords: Competition, Innovation, Stochastic frontier analysis, Granger causality, Technology

gap ratio, Lerner index, Boone indicator, Bank, Eurozone

JEL Classification: D21, G21, L10, O30


Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

1. Introduction

The relationship between product market competition and innovation has been a

controversial topic for the past several decades. Existing empirical studies that investigate the

relationship between competition and innovation mainly focus on manufacturing and technology

industries (e.g., Besen & Johnson (1986) in the broadcasting industry, Robinson (2001) in the

healthcare industry, and Gruber and Koutroumpis (2012) in the telecommunication industry).

Very few studies investigate this issue in the banking sector. Among those who have contributed

to investigating the relationship between competition and innovation in the financial sector are

Schaeck and Cihak (2008), Bos et al. (2013), Chava et al. (2013), and Cornaggia et al. (2015). To

further substantiate this area of knowledge, this study applies Data Envelopment analysis (DEA)

to explore the relationship between competition and innovation for a sample of 11 Eurozone

members with respect to different benchmark currencies.

This study focuses on a sample of European banks because the Eurozone provides a

mature ground for analyzing the effects of changes in the intensity of competition and innovation.

Spanning 1998 to 2015, the sample period of this study incorporates several major periods of

global economic expansion and recession. During the last two decades, bank market

consolidation has been a major trend worldwide. The global phenomena of technological

innovation, bank market liberalization and deregulation have facilitated the process of bank

mergers and acquisitions. In Europe, this bank consolidation process was emphasized by the

efforts to establish a single European financial market, based on the belief that market

competition would increase bank productivity through bank innovation.

1
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Along with the goal of creating a single European financial market since the 1990s,

European banks have also experienced dramatic changes in the regulatory environment, aimed at

creating a level playing field for competition among banks. For examples, the idea of ‘single

passport’, was implemented to allow banks to operate across all EU member countries with

uniform standard in acquiring licenses, maintaining capital requirements, and meeting

supervisory guidelines. These financial revolutions have brought significant implication for

competition among European banks. Furthermore, over the past decade, the European Union

banking market has also had to face the challenge of the financial consolidation and integration

of the additional twelve new member-states.

To analyze the relationship between competition and innovation in Eurozone banks, I

pursue a two-step approach. In the first step, I examine whether the relationship between bank

competition, measured by the Lerner index and the Boone indicator, and bank innovation,

measured by technology gaps, exhibits a linear relationship, e.g., Schumpeter (1942), Nickell

(1996), Blundell et al. (1999), Carlin et al. (2004) and Okada (2005), or an inverted-U

relationship, e.g., Aghion et al. (2005) and Bos et al. (2013). In the second step, if there is a

significant relationship from the first step, I run another causality check between competition and

innovation in banking. Using dynamic panel data Granger causality tests, this study aims to

extend the existing literature by examining the link between the level of competition and the

level of innovation.

This paper contributes to the extant innovation management literature in two ways. The

first contribution is that this paper, to the best of my knowledge, is the first to explore the

relationship between competition and innovation in the European banking industry. Other

2
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

existing papers, e.g. Bos et al. (2013) and Cornaggia et al. (2015), mostly focus on samples from

the US banking industry. The European Union is the second largest economy in the world;

therefore, a précis on the link between competition and innovation would be unreliable if we

ignored the European banking industry. Also, there are several noteworthy divergences between

the U.S. and E.U. capital markets. Compared to the US market, the competition for depositor

money is more severe in Europe because not only there are many more banks, but also there are

non-bank competitors. For example, post offices in some European nations accept deposits.

Consequently, European banks fund much of their operations by borrowing. Compared to the

American rivals, European banks have much higher loan-to-deposit ratio. As for bank customers,

European companies rely far more heavily on bank lending. Generally, the fact that

approximately 80 percent of corporate debt in Europe originates from bank lending, and the

remaining 20 percent comes from the corporate bond markets is a total inverse of the U.S.

The second contribution of this paper is that this paper is the first to use a panel Granger

causality approach to test the direct relationship between bank competition and bank innovation.

Existing literature usually examines unidirectional impact from competition to innovation and

not the other way around. (e.g. Scherer (1967); Levin et al. (1985); Aghion and Griffith (2005);

Aghion et al. (2005); Bos et al. (2013); Cornaggia et al. (2014); Hashmi et al. (2005)). It is

obvious that new technologies can profoundly affect the functioning of the banking industry. The

most recent examples include the use of mobile banking apps that are disrupting conventional in-

store banking business. These disruptive innovations can deliver important benefits to

competition and consumers, in terms of new and better services, and can stimulate innovation

and price competition from established providers.

3
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

The results show that the squared term of the bank competition variable is negatively

significantly related with innovation, proving that the relationship between bank competition and

innovation reveals an inverted-U relationship.

Using the full sample, the Granger causality tests indicate a full bidirectional negative

causality between competition and innovation. Using the partial sample contained in the upward

slope of the inverted-U, the Granger causality tests indicate full bidirectional positive causality

between competition and innovation. Using the partial sample contained in the downward slope

of the inverted-U, the Granger causality tests shows that there is no causality link between bank

competition and bank innovation. The causality results are robust when both competition

measurements, Lerner index and Boone indicator, show the similar findings.

The findings above show that even thought the relationship between competition and

innovation displays an inverted-U shape, only the upward slope demonstrates a meaningful

causality association. The bidirectional causality along upward slope suggests that increasing

competition encourages banks to innovate to outshine their peers, and that increasing

technological innovation boosts banks to invest more expenses to keep up with their competitors.

The market competition later reaches a sufficient level that an increase in innovation can no

longer improve any competition.

2. Literature Review

Schumpeter (1942) first suggests that market competition depresses firms’ initiative to

innovate because of losing monopoly rents. However, some later empirical evidence from

Nickell (1996), Blundell et al. (1999), Carlin et al. (2004) and Okada (2005) discover a positive

4
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

relationship between competition and innovation. Aghion et al. (2001) propose an "escape-

competition effect" to explain these findings, in which they argue that competition may

encourage firms to innovate to surpass their competitors. Using data from the manufacturing

industry in the UK, Aghion et al. (2005) later discover an inverted-U relationship between

competition and innovation. Reconciling the theory with evidence, they suggest that the escape-

competition effect initially kicks in until competition becomes so saturated that the diminishing-

returns effect starts to dominate the relationship.

*** Insert Figure 1 ***

In recent years, with the global trend of bank consolidation, the number of banks in

Europe has also reduced (refer to Figure 1). Smirlock et al. (1984) and Maudos (1998) argue that

the remaining largest banks, because of bank market consolidation, have become more efficient,

and the bank market has become less competitive. Until the 2000s, there was a general belief that

mergers did not clearly contribute to banks’ devotion to financial technology improvements due

to low competition, e.g. Berger and Hannan (1989, 1998); Hannan and Berger (1991); Neumark

and Sharpe (1992); Houston and Ryngaert (1994); Pilloff (1996). Clearly, low competition in the

banking industry has discouraged bank innovation.

From the year 2000, the aftermath of the dot-com bubble has forced more emerging firms

to pay attention to the presence of asymmetric information, contagion phenomena and imperfect

competition, or the specific impacts of bank competition and regulation on bank performance

(among others, De Bandt and Davis (2000); Allen and Gale (2000); Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine

(2000); Bikker and Haaf (2002); Berger et al. (2004); Weill (2004); Hasan et al. (2009); Schaeck

et al. (2009); Tabak et al. (2011)). Banks have since then shown more willingness to spend

5
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

increased investment on improving financial technology due to soaring competition in the market.

These studies clearly show that competition has forced the growth of innovation, regardless of a

low or high competitive environment.

On the other hand, along with technological advancement, bank market liberalization and

deregulation have facilitated the process of bank mergers and acquisitions. As a result, the bank

industry has become more concentrated and less competitive. Studies and evidence presented by

Altunbas and Marqués-Ibáñez (2007), Cloodt et al. (2006), and Penetta et al. (2009) provide

further support for the interpretation that innovation is the factor that fosters market competition.

Accordingly, it is ambiguous whether a change in bank competition precedes a change in

a bank innovation or vice versa. Up to now, not many authors have used Granger-type causality

tests to investigate the empirical relationship between bank market competition and bank

innovation. Among others, Idun and Aboagye (2014) use the example of Ghana and find

evidence of unidirectional Granger causality from bank competition to economic growth as

well as bidirectional Granger causality between financial innovation and economic growth.

Most existing literature only examines unidirectional causality tests running from competition

to innovation and not from efficiency to innovation. (e.g. Scherer (1967); Levin et al. (1985);

Aghion and Griffith (2005); Aghion et al. (2005); Bos et al. (2013); Cornaggia et al. (2014);

Hashmi et al. (2005))

3. Data and Methodology

3.1 Data

6
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

The sample of this study consists of all the banks of the initial eleven Eurozone member

states: Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands,

Portugal and Spain. The list of all the banks is collected from the European Central Bank

website. Year-end financial data from each bank is gathered from two sources: BankScope and

DataStream. These two databases complement each other for the missing data. The sample

period covers from 1989 (the last data available before the Euro was introduced on Jan 1, 1990)

to 2015 (the most recent available data when this study was conducted). Referring to Table 1,

there are a total of 114,926 bank-year observations for over 8,300 banks.

*** Insert Table 1 ***

Figure 1 shows that the total number of banks in the Eurozone has declined consistently

throughout the sample period. This finding is in line with the fact that the rising intensity of

competition in the European banking sector has induced more bank consolidations, and that

improving technological innovation has facilitated the process of bank mergers and acquisitions

(Ferreira 2013). Data are expressed in the Euro currency of the year 1990. The sample of this

paper covers several European countries with various institutional settings. I control for such

different characteristics by including some state-level control variables such as Herfindahl

Hirschman Index (HHI) and total banking system assets. Such different characteristics are well

controlled when I study the effect of competition on innovation and vice versa.

3.2 Measuring Innovation - Technology gap ratio

The existing studies on innovation have mostly focused on the manufacturing industry.

These studies mainly rely on patents, R&D expenditures, or population of research personnel as

7
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

indicators of innovative level (e.g., Helpman (1993) and Cohen and Klepper (1996)). Evaluating

innovative activity in the financial sector is more challenging, as patents in the financial sector

rarely exist and do not exist at all in the European Union. The fact that R&D information are not

applicable in the banking sector, as addressed by Frame and White (2004), has hampered the

motivation of financial innovation for a long time.

Following Bos et al. (2013) and Iren and Tee (2017), this study uses the technology gap

between a firm and a benchmark covering all available technologies as a proxy for innovation.

The technology gap of each firm is measured by an array of different indicators reflecting both

input into and output from financial innovations. According to their methodology, firms are

always assumed to minimize production cost along with the invention or adoption of new

technology. To present the idea of such technical change in a cost function, I apply a meta

frontier approach, as pioneered in the studies done by Hayami and Ruttan (1970), Lau and

Yotopoulos (1989), and Mundlak and Hellinghausen (1982). The meta frontier embodies the

most updated technologies available across firms and across time. Any technology improvement

will be measured, from time to time, against the benchmark meta frontier, which merges all

existing technologies.

Innovation is reflected by changes in the technology gap, which measures the difference

between currently available technology and optimal technology over the whole period, with

values between zero and one, with value one being the highest level of innovation. To obtain the

technology gap of each firm in each year, I apply Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) to estimate

the minimum cost frontier available in each year and then envelope the annual cost frontiers to

obtain a meta frontier (refer to Hayami and Ruttan (1970), Mundlak and Hellinghausen (1982),

8
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

and Lau and Yotopoulos (1989)). In the first step, the following annual translog cost frontiers are

estimated using stochastic frontier analysis:

TCit  f * ( wit , yit , zit )e vit  uit (1)

where TC is defined as total operating cost, with i = 1, ..., I bank in t = 1, ..., T period. w

represents the vector of input prices, y is the output vector, z is a vector of control variables, v is

random noise assumed to be i.i.d. with vit ~ N(0, σ2v) and independent of the explanatory

variables (see Aigner and Schmidt (1977) and Coelli et al.(1998)). u is the inefficiency term

assumed to be i.i.d. and is independent of vit.

Following Bos and Schmiedel (2006), I treat a bank as an intermediary between

depositors and borrowers. Accordingly, bank outputs are defined as loans (Y1) and investments

(Y2), and off-balance sheet items (Y3). More precisely, loans consist of commercial and

industrial, real estate, consumer, and other outstanding credits. Investments consist of securities,

equity investments, and other investments. Off-balance sheet items represent credits and other

guarantees which are not reported on the balance sheet. The study covers three input prices,

namely the price of labor (W1), the price of financial capital (W2), and the price of financial

capital (W3). The price of labor (W1) equals the total employee expenses scaled by the total sum

of assets. The price of financial capital (W2) equals the total interest expenses per unit of total

assets, and the price of physical capital (W3) equals all non-interest operating expenses divided

by the sum of assets. Finally, the variable equity/total assets (Z) controls for differences in equity

capital risk across banks. In line with Mester (1996), banks with lower equity ratios are assumed

to be riskier. The dependent variable in equation (1) is the total operating cost (TC).

*** Insert Table 2 ***

9
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 2 displays the statistical values of all the input prices, outputs, and dependent

variables in estimating the technology gaps.

Banks are assumed to minimize total costs and operate in perfectly competitive input

markets. Cost efficiency score estimates are obtained as follows:

CEit  exp( ˆ it ) (2)

where CE=1 for banks that operate on the annual frontier (no inefficiency). Banks

locating above the annual cost frontier are inefficient and have cost efficiency scores less than

one.

In the second step, I use Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) to estimate the meta frontier

as the envelope around the annual cost frontiers. The annual cost frontiers are represented by the

parameter estimates. The estimates of the technology gap (GAP) are estimated by fitting the

minimum cost meta frontier (fmeta) as follows:

T N
Min.Distance    | ln f * ( wit , yit , zit )  ln f meta ( wit , yit , zit ) |
t 1 i 1

subject to ln f * ( wit , yit , z it )  ln f meta ( wit , yit , zit )

In the above constrained minimization problem, the absolute distance between the annual

cost frontier and the meta frontier is minimized subject to the constraint that the total cost from

the annual frontier is equal to or larger than total cost from the meta frontier. As a result, the

technology gap is defined as:

f meta ( wit , yit , zit )


GAPit  (3)
f * ( wit , yit , zit )

10
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Innovations by banks improve their technology set and, consequently, shrink the gap

between the current technology set and the best available technology set, or meta frontier. The

result is an increase in GAPit, which is bounded between 0 and 1, where a firm reaches 1 when it

operates on the meta frontier. In short, the higher the value of GAPit ratio, the more innovated a

bank is.

Table 3 shows the summary statistics of technology gap ratio by the eleven Eurozone

member states from 1998 to 2015.

*** Insert Table 3 ***

3.3 Measuring Competition - Lerner Index

Following Schaeck and Cihak (2008), I use the Lerner index of market power to measure

the degree of competition in banks. The Lerner index is a popular measure of the level of

competition in banking. It specifies the divergence between product prices and marginal cost of

production, which indicates the degree of market power. To gauge an Lerner index, we must first

estimate the subsequent translog cost function using three input factors (labor, deposits, and

capital), one output (total assets), and three netputs (fixed assets, loan loss provisions, equity

capital) as follows:

2 2
1 1 2 2
ln C   0  1 ln A   2 ln A2    kWk   h ln Yh    km ln Wk ln Wm
2 k 1 h 1 2 k 1 m 1
2 2 2 2
1 2 2
   k ln A ln Wk    k ln A ln Yh   kh ln Wk ln Yh   ln Yh ln Yn (4)
m 1 m 1 k 1 h 1 2 h1 n1
 ln c  ln  c

11
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

where C denotes total cost, A is total assets, W is the vector of inputs (the price of labor

(W1), the price of financial capital (W2), and the price of physical capital (W3)), and Y is the

vector of outputs (loans (Y1) and investments (Y2), and off-balance-sheet items (Y3)).

Then I calculate marginal cost by differentiating Eq. (4) with respect to A as follows

C c
mcit   [1  1 ln A  1 ln W1  2 ln W2  1 ln Y1   2 ln Y2 ] it (5)
A A

I calculate the Lerner index as the mark-up of output prices over marginal cost of

production as follows

pit  mc
LI it  (6)
pit

where pit denotes the output price of bank i at time t and is defined as total revenue

(interest and noninterest revenue) divided by total assets. The Lerner index ranges between zero

and one. The larger the Lerner index, the less the competition and the more the market power.

*** Insert Figure 2 ***

Figure 2 illustrates the evolution of the Lerner indices, by country, over time. Higher

value of the Lerner index indicates lower level of competition. Overall, there are upward trends

of the competition level in every country, indicating that the banking sector in the Eurozone is

having progressively less competition. During the recessions in 2000 and 2008, more banking

players left the markets, the surviving banks thus enjoy more market powers, as indicated by the

surges in the graph. The banking systems in Portugal and Germany exhibit, on average, the

highest level of competition, indicating that banks in these markets do not wield much market

12
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

power. Meanwhile the banking system in Italy has always displayed the highest values of the

Lerner index of above 0.7, indicating banks in Italy are facing less competition.

3.4 Measuring Competition - Boone Indicator

Another popular way of measuring competition is the Boone indicator, as introduced by

Boone (2008). Unlike the Lerner index, the Boone indicator is calculated as the elasticity of

profits in relation to marginal costs. The underlying principle behind the Boone indicator is the

positive relationship between profit and bank efficiency. The formation of the Boone indicator is

based on Relative Profit Differences (RPD) that, from its theoretical properties, proves to be

more robust than the Lerner-Index.

Boone develops a broad set of theoretical models (see Boone (2000), (2001) and (2008),

Boone et al. (2004), and CPB, (2000)), and establishes the Boone indicator as a proxy for bank

competition. Following Boone et al. (2004), I consider every bank in our sample set to follow a

demand function in which each bank i produces one product qi. The bank faces a linear demand

curve of the form:

p(qi , q j  i )  a  bqi  d  q j (7)


j i

and has constant marginal costs mci. It maximizes profits πi = (pi – mci) qi with the optimal

output level qi. By having a > mci and 0 < d ≤ b, the first order condition for a Cournot-Nash

equilibrium can then be written as:

a  2bqi  d  q j  mci  0 (8)


i j

When N banks produce positive output levels, the N first-order of equation (8) becomes:

13
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

qi (mci )  [(2b / d  1)a  (2b / d  N  1)mci   mc j ] / [(2b  d ( N  1))(2b / d  1)] (9)


j

Profits πi is defined as variable profits excluding entry costs k. Hence, a bank enters the

market if πi ≥ k in equilibrium. Equation (9) displays a linear relationship between output and

marginal cost.

In a bank market, competition can increase in three ways. First, competition increases

when the bank products become quick substitutes, that is, d increases (assuming d<b). Second,

competition increases when entry costs k decline and entry occurs. Boone et al. (2004) show that

efficient firms achieve more profit when there is a stronger substitution and a lower entry cost.

Third, competition increases when b, which measures price sensitivity of the demand for bank

services, increases along with the greater market power of bank i and all other banks.

Following equation (9), the relationship between profits and marginal costs can be

rewritten as:

(2bp / d p  1)a p  (2bp / d p  N p  1)mc1, p   j mc jp


 1, p (mc1, p )  (10)
[(2bp / d p ( N p  1))(2bp / d p  1)]( p p  mc1, p )

where price, p p , stands for the price of the bank service in period p. The Boone indicator, BI, is

the profit elasticity of marginal costs derived from this equation (10):

BI  d  1, p / dmc1, p ( mc1, p /  1, p )  0 (11)

14
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

The value of BI is always expected to be negative, where mc1, p is the average value of

marginal cost in period p and  1, p is the average profit in period p. As such, the more negative

the Boone indicator, the higher the degree of competition.

*** Insert Figure 3 ***

Figure 3 illustrates the evolution of the Boone indicator, by country, over time. Like the

Lerner indices, there are upward trends of the Boone indicator in every country, indicating that

the Boone indicator is a close substitute for the Lerner index. The bank competition dropped

seemingly when there were recessions in the 2000 and 2008. Although the trends of the Boone

indicators among the Eurozone nations are like those of the Lerner indexes, the rank of

competition among the countries is different. Using the Boone indicators, the banking systems in

Luxembourg and Netherlands exhibit, on average, the lowest values for the Boone indicator,

indicating that banks in these markets were facing more competition than in other countries.

Meanwhile, the banking system in Portugal and Ireland have always displayed the highest values

of the Boone indicator, indicating that banks in these two countries were enjoying the benefits of

less competition.

4. Empirical Results and Discussions

4.1 The Impact of Competition on Innovation

*** Insert Table 4 ***

This section aims to study the effect of competition on innovation in the Eurozone banks.

Table 4 shows the results of the Generalized Least Squares (GLS) and the Ordinary Least

15
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Squares (OLS) models using Technology Gap ratios as dependent variables. Models 1-4 display

the effect of the competition level, as measured using the Lerner index, on innovation while

models 5-8 shows the effect of the competition level, as measured using the Boone indicator on

innovation. All eight models show statistically significant linear and inverted-U relationships

between competition and technology gap ratios. All four square terms under Model 1-4 and one

of the four square terms under Model 5-8 are significant at the one percent level. The relationship

between competition and innovation is strong, as indicated by the reported R-squares ranging between

0.33 and 0.55. When the innovation index, as measured by the technology gap ratio, is compared against

the composite competition index, as measured by the average values of the Lerner index and the Boone

indicator, we obtain a clear inverted-U bell curve as indicated in Figure 4. The innovation experiences a

quadratic concave function against the market competition. The innovation level reaches its peak of 2.2

when the competition index is around 0.6.

*** Insert Figure 4 ***

These results are consistent with theory and evidence reported by Bos et al. (2013) in the

US banking industry and Aghion et al. (2005) and Hashmi (2007) in other industries. To avoid

the problem of endogeneity, Hausman-Wu tests are performed across all models in Table 4. The

endogeneity test shows that the competition term and its squared term are safely treated as

endogenous regressors. Based on the Hansen test, which is used for testing over-identifying

restrictions in a statistical model, the null hypothesis that the instrument variables are valid

cannot be rejected.

Table 4 further presents several robustness checks to examine whether a significant linear

or inverse-U relationship exists for many alternative model specifications. First, I use the Boone

16
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

indicator in model specification 5 and 6 to mirror model 1 and 2. The results of using the Boone

indicator are quite like the results of the Lerner index, except for the significance level of the

square term being ten percent instead of one percent. Second, model specification 3 and 4

includes several control variables, such as equity-to-asset ratio, market share, total assets, asset

growth, square term of asset growth, and Herfindahl Hirshman Index (HHI). A linear and an

inverted-U relationship between competition and technology gap ratio are again obtained after

controlling for other factors that may affect innovation. Third, using the Boone indicator as an

alternative competition variable, I include similar control variables in model 7 and 8. The

significance level drops a little. For the GLS model, the inverted-U relationship shows a 5%

significance level, while for the OLS model, the inverted-U relationship shows a 10%

significance level.

The risk variable (equity divided by total assets) coefficient is positive and significant at

the 1% level. This finding shows that an increase in the equity ratio is associated with a higher

technology gap ratio, suggesting that banks in Europe tend to invest more to improve their

technologies when the debt level is lower. This finding is against Aghion et al. (2005) and Bos et

al. (2013), who propose that debt pressure leads to more innovation. Market share is negatively

associated with technology gap across all models. This negative effect reflects an example of

diseconomy of scale where the banks suffer from a larger increase in marginal costs when output

is increased. Meanwhile, bank size in terms of total assets is mostly positively related to the

dependent variable in all models, suggesting that banks with larger assets, especially loan

amounts, tend to increase investments in technology more efficiently than smaller banks.

17
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Asset growth is negatively related to technology gap, suggesting that an expanding bank

may not always keep pace with the need for relevant technology improvement. I also include a

quadratic term of asset growth to account for nonlinearities. The square term of asset growth

displays a U-shape or a positive relationship with technology gap. Such a finding indicates that

once a bank reaches an optimal expansion rate, the bank is likely to invest aggressively to ensure

its business is supported by updated technology.

4.2 Granger Causality Tests

The Granger causality test, first proposed by Granger (1969), is a popular statistical test

for verifying whether one time-series variable can forecast another. A variable X, that changes

over time, is said to Granger-cause another variable Y, which also evolves over time, if both X's

own past values and Y's own past values can make better predictions than only Y's own past

values. In our case, I would like to investigate a two-way effect between bank competition and

innovation. In other words, I analyze whether

a) bank competition Granger-causes bank innovation (if predictions of innovation based

on its own past values and on the past values of bank competition are better than

predictions of innovation based only on its own past values.) or

b) bank innovation Granger-causes bank competition (if predictions of competition

based on its own past values and on the past values of bank innovation are better than

predictions of competition based only on its own past values.)

In both cases a) and b), I follow Berger (1995) and run the following Granger causality

tests.

18
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

n n
yit   0    j yi (t 1)   j xi (t 1)  Z it  i   it (12)
j 1 j 1

4.2.1 Granger Causality Tests on the Entire Sample

Based on equation (12), I first regress measures of innovation (technology gap ratio) on

lags of both itself (yt-1 , yt-2 ) , and on the measures of competition ( xt-1 , xt-2 ); Zit is a vector of

control variables; ηi is a bank-specific effect and εit denotes the error term. A similar regression is

then run with the competition variable (Lerner index or Boone indicator) as dependent variable.

For this analysis, a panel data estimator is used together with bank-fixed effects.

*** Insert Table 5 ***

Based on full sample of 114,926 year-firm observations, Table 5 shows the results of

Granger causality tests between competition and innovation. I perform eight model specifications

based on equation (12). In each model, I use two annual lags in the baseline setup. Compared to

a deeper lag structure, this lag setup avoids losing excessive information. In this Granger

causality analysis, I focus on the joint significance of the two annual lags of x. If the two annual

lags are significant, we can predict that x Granger-causes y, in the sense of changes in x

preceding changes in y.

Columns (1) and (2) in Table 5 are based on two annual lags of the dependent and

independent variable. In these baseline regressions, I include log market share and log total

assets as control variables. In column (1), the technology gap ratio is predicted by its own lags

and the lags of the Lerner index. Both sums of lagged coefficients are negative and significant at

the one percent level. e.g. one unit increase of technology gap ratio at t-1 causes 0.3458 decrease

19
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

in the current technology gap ratio, and one unit increase of Lerner index at t-1 causes 0.1254

increase in the current technology gap ratio. Likewise, column (2) shows that the Lerner index is

predicted by its own lags and the lags of technology gap ratio. Both sums of lagged coefficients

are also negative and significant at the one percent level. e.g. one unit increase of technology gap

ratio and of Lerner index at t-1 decrease the current Lerner index by 0.0015 and 0.3256,

respectively. The results of the Granger causality tests suggest that there is a full bidirectional

causality running between bank competition (based on the Lerner index) and bank innovation,

including a -0.2 causality of running from competition to innovation, and a -0.0015 causality

running from innovation to competition.

To control for the factors that may also affect the dependent variables, I incorporate four

additional control variables, i.e., asset growth, square term of asset growth, Herfindahl Hirshman

Index (HHI), and log of total banking system assets. Each European country in the sample

carries unique institutional settings; I control for such different characteristics by adding HHI

and banking system assets1 which are calculated on the state level. As such, I also include a set

of country dummies to control for the variation on the country level. The results are presented in

columns (3) and (4). Both sums of lagged coefficients are again negative and significant at the

one percent level. There is a full bidirectional causality running between bank competition

(based on the Lerner index) and bank innovation. This finding validates the findings of column

(1) and (2) that causality runs from bank innovation to bank competition based on the Lerner

index and vice versa.

Like the results of Table 4, the results in column (3), where bank innovation is used as a

dependent variable, show a negative coefficient of asset growth and a positive coefficient of
1
Total banking system assets are added to control for the size of the different systems (Bresnahan, 1989).

20
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

square term of asset growth. These findings suggest that a bank may not improve its required

technology as fast as its business expansion, and that there is a turning point where the bank

increases its technology level faster than its asset growth. Column (4), where the Lerner index is

used as a dependent variable, on the other hand, has a positive coefficient of asset growth and a

negative coefficient of square term of asset growth. These findings indicate that the faster a bank

expands its assets, the more competitive the bank is, and that there is an inverted-U relationship

between bank competition and bank asset growth: once a bank reaches its maximum competition

point, an increase in asset growth rate will only shrink the bank competition. The HHI and the

log of total banking system assets are negatively and significantly related to their dependent

variables, as shown in column (3) and (4). As such, banks operating in more concentrated and

larger markets have less innovation and less competition.

As a robustness check, I repeat the tests in model specification (1) - (4) by replacing the

Lerner index with the Boone indicator, and the results are presented in columns (5) - (8). In the

baseline setup of column (5) and (6), the technology gap ratio is predicted by its own lags and

the lags of the Boone indicator, and the Boone indicator is predicted by its own lags and the lags

of technology gap ratio. Both sums of lagged coefficients are negative and significant at the one

percent level. This result is consistent with the result in column (1) and (2). The magnitudes of

the estimates using Boone indicators are less than the ones using Lerner indexes. For example,

there is a -0.1033 causality of running from competition (Boone indicator) to innovation, as

compared to a -0.2 causality effect using Lerner index. The different outcomes resulting from

different measures of bank competition are not surprising. Amir (2000), Bulow and Klemperer

(1999), Rosenthal (1980) and Stiglitz (1989), for example, present models in which the Lerner

index tends to overestimate industry competition level when the competition level is highly

21
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

intense. Corts (1999) also shows that the estimates of the Lerner index sometimes underestimate

the level of market conduct compared to the Boone indicator.

By adding four additional control variables, column (7) and (8) mirror the tests on

column (3) and (4) respectively, with the Boone indicator as a measure of competition. In

column (7), technology gap ratio is predicted by its own lags and the lags of the Boone indicator.

All four control variables are significant as well. The result of column (8) also shows some

supporting outcomes to the one in column (4). Similar to its base model in column (6), the Boone

indicator is predicted by its own lags and the lags of technology gap ratio. Among the four

control variables, only HHI shows some significant results at the very marginal 10% level.

Overall the results using Boone indicators as a robustness check are consistent with those using

Lerner indexes.

The results from Table 5 are based on the basic assumption of the existence of a linear

relationship between the dependent variable and the independent variable. However, as indicated

by the findings in Table 4, the relationship between innovation and competition exhibits an

inverted-U curve. More competition (a lower Lerner Index) Granger causes more innovation and

also that even more competition (an even lower Lerner Index) now Granger-causes more

innovation. Thus, to overcome the fundamental contradiction of findings between Table 4 and

Table 5, I run Granger Causality tests separately on both the negative slope and the positive

slope of the inverted-U curve. The results and explanations are presented at the following section.

4.2.1 Separate Granger Causality Test on Upward-Slope and Downward-Slope of the

Inverted-U Curve

22
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

As indicated by the concave quadratic function in Figure 4, the relationship between

innovation and competition displays an inverted-U curve, it seems that the initial increase in

competition corresponds with the increase in innovation (Part 1 of Figure 4), and that the further

increase in competition, at the later stage, contracts the innovation (Part 2 of Figure 4). It is more

appropriate if we run a separate Granger Causality test on each of the upward-sloping side and of

the downward-sloping side of the inverted-U relationship.

*** Insert Table 6 ***

Running Granger causality test on the upward-sloping side of Figure 4, we obtain the

results in Table 6. Based on partial sample of 77,050 year-firm observations, Table 6 shows

better fits of regressions than the ones in Table 5. The R-squares in Table 6 improve significantly,

ranging between 0.2856 and 0.4952. Like the tests conducted in Table 5, I use two annual lags in

the baseline setup. Columns (1) to (4) check the Granger causality between innovation and

competition, proxied by the Lerner index, and columns (5) to (8) check the Granger causality

between innovation and competition, proxied by the Boone indicator.

As opposed to the Granger results in Table 5, which only show a negative bidirectional

causality between competition and innovation, Table 6 shows significant a positive bidirectional

causality between competition and innovation. For example, under column (1), there is a positive

0.1347 causality of running from competition (Lerner index) to innovation, and under column (2),

there is a positive 0.0477 causality of running from innovation to competition (Lerner index).

These findings are not surprising along an upward sloping curve, where innovation increases as

competition increases.

23
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

*** Insert Table 7 ***

I repeat another Granger causality test on the downward-sloping side of Figure 4. The

results, based on partial sample of 37,876 year-firm observations, are presented in Table 7. As

opposed to the Granger results in Table 6, which shows a significant positive bidirectional

causality between competition and innovation, Table 7 shows that there is no significant

causality link between competition and innovation. For example, under column (1), technology

gap ratio is predicted by its own lags but is not predicted by the lags of the Lerner index, and

under column (2), Lerner index is predicted by its own lags but is not predicted by the lags of the

technology gap ratio. Same findings are found when more control variables are included, as in

column (3) and (4), as well as when the Lerner index is replaced by the Boone indicator, as in

column (5) till (8).

Table 7 suggests that competition and innovation do not have causality effect on one

another. Such findings are unexpected because it is contradicting the proposition of Schumpeter

(1942) who suggests that there is a negative relationship between competition and innovation

because of the diminishing monopoly power of concentrated firms that are losing motivation to

innovate.

5. Conclusion

This study analyzes the relationship between bank competition and bank innovation using

sample data from the banks of the first 11 Eurozone member states who founded the European

Economic and Monetary Union on 1 January 1999. As such, I collect my sample data as early as

1998. I use the technology gap ratio to measure bank innovation, and use the Lerner index and

24
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

the Boone indicator to measure bank competition. Across the sample period of this study, both

the Lerner index and the Boone indicator point out a general trend that the competition in the

banking industry decreases along with the falling number of banks in Europe.

Using a large sample of data from European banks, this paper seeks to contribute to the

literature on financial innovation in several respects. In the first respect, this study examines the

relationship between competition and innovation in the Eurozone banking industry. I examine

whether the relationship between bank competition and bank innovation exhibits a linear

relationship, as discovered in other industries by Schumpeter (1942), Nickell (1996), Blundell et

al. (1999), Carlin et al. (2004) and Okada (2005), or an inverted-U relationship, as indicated by

Aghion et al. (2005) and Bos et al. (2013). The findings support the latter, when I discover a

significant positive relationship between bank innovation and the coefficient of square term of

asset growth. This suggests that a bank may not improve its required technology as fast as its

business expansion at the initial stage of the industry cycle, but the bank increases its technology

level faster than its asset growth at the later stage. These findings are robust to both GLS and

OLS estimation methods, as well as alternative measures of bank competition such as the Boone

indicator, and remain consistent when I account for other controlled factors that exogenously

affect bank innovation.

In the second respect, using full sample of observations, I apply Granger causality tests to

examine the link between bank competition and bank innovation. Specifically, I am keen to find

out whether bank competition Granger-causes bank innovation or bank innovation Granger-

causes bank competition. The study considers Granger causality models with two lags, both

dependent and independent variables. Granger tests indicate a full negative bidirectional

25
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

causality between competition and innovation. These results are robust to both competition

proxies, Lerner index and Boone indicator, and to both GLS and OLS estimation methods. The

results remain stable when I control for other factors, including HHI and banking system assets

that impose state-level variation of different institutional settings.

In the third respect, I run Granger causality tests separately on both the negative slope

and the positive slope of the inverted-U curve. The results indicate a positive bidirectional

causation between competition and innovation along the upward slope, but deny any causality

link between competition and innovation along the downward slope. These results are robust to

both Lerner index and Boone indicator, and remain stable when I control for other factors,

including HHI and banking system assets that impose state-level variation of different

institutional settings.

In summary, this study suggests that bank competition and bank innovation display an

inverted-U relationship, and that both variables can be used to predict one another. However,

bank innovation and bank competition show positive bidirectional causation only along the

upward slope, that is, when both variable are rising together. After the peak of the inverted-U

curve, there is no significant causality between competition and innovation.

The fact that there is a positive causality between competition and innovation provides

new propositions from two angles. First this evidence supports the assumption of Aghion et al.

(2001) who claim that competition cultivates innovation as firms attempt to excel to overcome

peer pressure and excel in business. Second, new technologies can profoundly affect the

functioning of the banking industry and improve its competition. The most recent examples

include the use of mobile banking apps that are disrupting conventional in-store banking

26
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

business. These disruptive innovations can deliver important benefits to competition and

consumers, in terms of new and better services, and can stimulate price competition from

established providers.

On the other hand, the fact that the causality effect stops after certain threshold point

suggests that more competition does not motivates further innovation because there is a ultimate

bottleneck in technological advancement. It also suggests that banks are no longer willing to

spend more money to deliver innovation because the marginal cost of innovation exceeds the

marginal benefit of hammering competitors. Along with technological advancement, bank

market liberalization and deregulation have aided the process of bank mergers and acquisitions.

As a result, the bank industry has become more concentrated and less competitive.

References

Aigner, D.J., Lovell, C.A.K., Schmidt, P. (1977), “Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic
Frontier Production Function Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 6 (1), 21-37.

Akhavein, J., Berger, A. N., Humphrey, D. B. (1997), "The effects of megamergers on efficiency
and prices: Evidence from a bank profit function", Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 12,
pp. 95–139.

Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. (2005), "Competition and
innovation: an inverted-U relationship", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120 (2), 701–728.

Aghion, P., Griffith, R. (2005), "Competition and Growth: Reconciling Theory and Evidence",
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Aghion, P., Harris, C., Howitt, P., Vickers, J. (2001), "Competition, imitation and growth with
step-by-step innovation", Review of Economic Studies, 68 (3), 467–492.

Allen, F., Gale, D. (2000), "Financial contagion", Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1–33.

Altunbas, Y., Marqués-Ibáñez, D. (2007), "Mergers and acquisitions and bank performance in
Europe. The role of strategic similarities", Journal of Economics and Business, 60, 204–222.

27
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Amir, R. (2000), "Market structure, scale economies and industry performance", CIE Discussion
Papers, University of Copenhagen. Department of Economics. Centre for Industrial Economics.

Berger, A. N. (1995), "The Profit-Structure Relationship in Banking -Tests of Market-Power and


Efficient-Structure Hypotheses", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 27, issue 2, 404-31.

Berger, A. N., Bonaccorsi di Patti, E. (2006), "Capital structure and firm performance: A new
approach to testing agency theory and an application to the banking industry", Journal of
Banking and Finance, Vol. 30, pp. 1065–1102.

Berger, A.N., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Levine, R., Haubrich, J.G. (2004), "Bank concentration and
competition: an evolution in the making", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36, 433–453.

Berger, A.N., Hannan, T.H. (1989), "The price-concentration relationship in banking", The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 291–299.

Berger, A.N., Hannan, T.H. (1998), "The efficiency cost of market power in the banking
industry: a test of the ‘Quiet Life’ and related hypotheses", The Review
of Economics and Statistics, 80, 454–465.

Besen, S.M., Johnson, L.L. (1986), "Compatibility standards, competition, and innovation in the
broadcasting industry", Rand Corporation, R-3453-NSF, November.

Bikker, J., Haaf, K. (2002), "Competition, concentration and their relationship: an empirical
analysis of the banking industry", Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 2191–2214.

Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Reenen, J. V. (1999), "Market Share, Market Value and Innovation in a
Panel of British Manufacturing Firms", Review of Economic Studies, 66(3), 529–554.

Boone, J. (2000), "Competition", CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 2636, December.

Boone, J. (2001), "Intensity of competition and the incentive to innovate", International Journal
of Industrial Organization, 19, 705–726.

Boone, J. (2008), "A new way to measure competition", Economic Journal, 118, 1245 -1261.

Boone J., Griffith, R., Harrison, R. (2004), "Measuring Competition", presented at the Encore
Meeting 2004 "Measuring competition".

Bos, J.W.B., Kolari, J.W., Van Lamoen, R.C.R. (2013), "Competition and innovation: Evidence
from financial services", Journal of Banking and Finance, 37, 1590–1601.

Bos, J.W.B., Schmiedel, H. (2006), "Is there a single frontier in a single European banking
market?", ECB Working Paper Series, No 701.

28
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Bresnahan, T.F. (1989), "Empirical studies of industries with market power", Handbook of
Industrial Organization, Vol. 2., Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

Bulow, J., Klemperer, P. (1999), "Prices and the winner’s curse", RAND Journal of Economics,
33, 1-21.

Carlin, W., Schaffer, M., Seabright, P. (2004), "A Minimum of Rivalry: Evidence from
Transition Economies on the Importance of Competition for Innovation and Growth",
Contributions to Economic Analysis and Policy, 3(1), 1–43.

Chava,S., Oettl, A., Subramanian, A., Subramanian, K.V. (2013), "Banking deregulation and
innovation", Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 109, Issue 3, Pages 759-774.

Cloodt, M., Hagedoorn, J., Van Kranenburg, H., (2006), "Mergers and acquisitions: Their effect
on the innovative performance of companies in high-tech industries", 35,5, Pages 642–654.

Coelli, T., Prasado Rao, D. S., Battese, G. E. (1998), "An Introduction to Efficiency and
Productivity Analysis", Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

Cohen, W.M., Klepper, S. (1996), "Firm size and the nature of innovation within industries: the
case of process and product R&D", Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 232–243.

Cornaggia, J., Mao, Y., Tian, X., Wolfe, B. (2015), "Does banking competition affect
innovation?", Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 115, Issue 1, Pages 189-209.

Corts, K. (1999), "Conduct parameters and the measurement of market power", Journal of
Econometrics, 88, 227-250.

CPB (2000), "Measuring competition: how are cost differentials mapped into profit
differentials?", Working Paper No. 131, CPB Netherlands Bureau of Economic Research, The
Hague.

De Bandt, O., Davis, E.P., (2000), "Competition, contestability and market structure in European
banking sectors on the Eve of EMU", Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, 1045–1066.

Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Levine, R. (2000), “Bank Concentration: Cross-Country Evidence”, World


Bank, Mimeo (available on-line)

Ferreira, C. (2013), "Bank market concentration and bank efficiency in the European Union: a
panel Granger causality approach", Journal International Economics and Economic Policy, 10,
365–391.

Frame, S.W., White, L.J. (2004), "Empirical studies of financial innovation: lots of talk, little
action", Journal of Economic Literature, 42, 116–144.

29
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Granger, C.W.J. (1969) "Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral
methods", Econometrica, 37,424–438.

Gruber, H., Koutroumpis, P. (2012), "Competition enhancing regulation and diffusion of


innovation: the case of broadband networks", Journal of Regulatory Economics, Volume 43,
Number 2, Page 168.

Hannan, TH., Berger, AN. (1991), "The rigidity of prices: evidence from the banking industry",
American Economic Review, 81, 938–945.

Hasan, I., Koetter, M., Wedow, M. (2009), "Regional growth and finance in Europe: is there a
quality effect of bank efficiency?", Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 1446–1453.

Hashmi, A.P. (2013), "Competition and Innovation: The Inverted-U Relationship Revisited",
Review of Economics and Statistics, Volume 95(5).

Hayami, Y., Ruttan, V.W. (1970), "Agricultural productivity differences among countries",
American Economic Review 60 (5), 895–911.

Helpman, E. (1993), "Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights", Econometrica, 61,
1247–1280.

Houston, J.F., Ryngaert, M. (1994), "The overall gains from large bank mergers", Journal of
Banking and Finance, 18, 1155–1176.

Idun, A.A., Aboagye, A.Q.Q. (2014), "Bank competition, financial innovations and economic
growth in Ghana", African Journal of Economic and Management Studies, Vol. 5 Issue: 1,
pp.30-51.

Iren, P., Tee, K. (2017), " Boardroom Diversity, Corporate Governance & Innovation in the UAE
Banks", Working Paper No. ZU-WP 2017-04-02.

Lau, L.J., Yotopoulos, P.A. (1989), "The meta-production function approach to technological
change in world agriculture", Journal of Development Economics 31 (2), 241–269.

Levin, R.C., Cohen, W.M., Mowery, D.C., (1985), "R&D Appropriability, Opportunity, and
Market Structure: New Evidence on Some Schumpeterian Hypotheses", American Economic
Review, 75, issue 2, p. 20-24.

Maudos, J. (1998), "Market structure and performance in Spanish banking using a direct measure
of efficiency", Applied Financial Economics, 8, 191–200.

Mester, L. (1996), “A Study of Bank Efficiency Taking into Account Risk-Preferences”, Journal
of Banking and Finance, 20, 1025-1045.

30
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Mundlak, Y., Hellinghausen, R. (1982), "The intercountry agricultural production function:


another view", American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62, 664–672.

Neumark, D., Sharpe, S.A. (1992), "Market structure and the nature of price rigidity: evidence
from the market for consumer deposits", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 657–680.

Nickell, S. (1996), "Competition and Corporate Performance", Journal of Political Economy,


vol. 104, issue 4, 724-46.

Okada, Y. (2005), "Competition and Productivity in Japanese Manufacturing Industries" NBER


Working Paper No.11540.

Pilloff, S.J. (1996), "Performance changes and shareholder wealth creation associated with
mergers of publicly traded banking institutions", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28,
294–310.

Robinson, J.C. (2001), "The Corporate Practice of Medicine: Competition and Innovation in
Health Care", Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 26.3, 655-657.

Rosenthal, R. (1980), "A model in which an increase in the number of sellers leads to a higher
price", Econometrica, 48, 1575-1579.

Schaeck, K., Cihak, M. (2008), " How does competition affect efficiency and soundness in
banking? New empirical evidence", ECB Working Paper Series, N. 932.

Schaeck, K., Cihak, M.,Wolfe, S. (2009), "Are more competitive banking systems more stable?",
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41, 711–734.

Scherer, F. M. (1967), "Market Structure and the Employment of Scientists and Engineers",
American Economic Review, 57(3), 524–531.

Schumpeter, J.A. (1942), "Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy", Harper and Row, New York,
NY.

Smirlock M., Gilligan T., Marshall, W. (1984), "Tobin’s q and the structure-performance
relationship", American Economic Review, 74,1050–1060.

Stiglitz, J. (1989), "Imperfect information in the product market", in (R. Schmalensee and R.
Willig, eds.) Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume I, Elsevier Science Publishers.

Tabak, B.M., Dimas, D.M., Cajueiro, D.O. (2011), "Profit, Cost and Scale Efficiency for Latin
American Banks: concentration-performance relationship", Banco Central do Brasil, Working
Paper Series N. 244.

Weill, L. (2004) "On the relationship between competition and efficiency in the EU banking
sector", Kredit und Kapital, 37, 29–352.

31
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Figure 1: Total number of banks in Eurozone, 1998-2015


8,500
8,000
7,500
7,000
6,500
6,000
5,500
5,000
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Figure 2: Competition Level - proxied by Lerner Indices


0.9

0.8

0.7

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Belgium Germany Ireland Spain

France Italy Luxembourg Netherlands


Austria Portugal Finland

32
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Figure 3: Competition Level - proxied by Boone indicators


0
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
-0.02

-0.04

-0.06

-0.08

-0.1

-0.12

-0.14

-0.16

Belgium Germany Ireland Spain


France Italy Luxembourg Netherlands

Austria Portugal Finland

33
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 1: Yearly number of banks across 11 Eurozone states


Year Belgium Germany Ireland Spain France Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Austria Portugal Finland Total by year
1998 123 3,238 78 402 1,226 934 212 634 898 227 348 8,320
1999 117 2,996 80 386 1,163 894 209 615 878 223 345 7,906
2000 118 2,742 81 368 1,099 861 202 586 848 218 341 7,464
2001 112 2,526 88 366 1,050 843 194 561 836 212 369 7,157
2002 111 2,363 85 359 989 821 184 539 823 202 369 6,845
2003 108 2,225 80 348 939 801 172 481 814 200 366 6,534
2004 104 2,148 80 346 897 787 165 461 796 197 363 6,344
2005 100 2,089 78 348 854 792 157 401 818 186 363 6,186
2006 105 2,050 78 352 829 807 154 345 809 178 361 6,068
2007 110 2,026 81 357 808 821 155 341 803 175 360 6,037
2008 105 1,989 501 362 728 818 153 302 803 175 357 6,293
2009 104 1,948 498 352 712 801 147 295 790 166 349 6,162
2010 106 1,929 489 337 686 778 146 290 780 160 338 6,039
2011 108 1,898 480 335 660 754 141 287 766 155 327 5,911
2012 103 1,869 472 314 639 714 141 266 751 152 313 5,734
2013 103 1,842 458 290 623 694 147 253 731 151 303 5,595
2014 103 1,808 446 226 496 670 148 218 707 150 271 5,243
2015 99 1,774 416 218 467 656 143 209 678 147 281 5,088
Total 114,926

0
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 2: Variables, Definitions and Summary Statistics, 1998-2015


Variable Definition Mean Std Dev Min Max Kurtosis Skewness
TC Total cost 816.5470 2,538.1470 0.0420 30,215.1550 3.2482 2.547
PBT Profit before taxes 288.4780 752.9540 0.5050 25,102.7520 -0.0152 0.3582
Y1 Loans 23,415.6870 68,214.7420 0.1010 1,025,478.3580 2.5473 -1.3205
Y2 Investments 20,421.6750 62,357.1590 0.1000 1,256,853.2480 0.2523 -0.2852
Y3 Off-balance sheet items 33,543.6150 125,789.3470 0.1200 10,254,783.2140 1.8523 -0.5852
W1 Labor price 0.1296 0.7563 0.000 89.5260 1.285 -0.2483
W2 Financial capital price 0.0156 0.5246 0.000 0.7260 2.302 0.5893
W3 Physical capital price 2.0950 7.1248 0.0010 45.6520 2.142 -1.214
Z Equity/assets 11.0776 35.2654 0.0010 105.3250 -1.2452 0.4975
Assets Total assets 64,899.8750 185,246.9530 1,500.0100 2,485,789.2010 -0.2583 1.2145
N=114,926. All variables are denoted in 1,000s of EUR, corrected for inflation

Table 3: Technology Gap Ratios Summary Statistics by countries, 1998-2015


Country Mean Std Dev Min Max Kurtosis Skewness
Belgium 0.6894 0.0746 0.385 1 -1.4383 0.2328
Germany 0.7839 0.096 0.295 1 -0.9312 0.3391
Ireland 0.9642 0.0755 0.455 1 1.4689 -1.3019
Spain 0.9998 0.1053 0.5698 1 8.0000 -4.2426
France 0.6053 0.0685 0.2589 1 0.2823 0.8690
Italy 0.8797 0.0856 0.4325 1 -1.5485 -0.3043
Luxembourg 0.5991 0.0542 0.1025 1 -1.3142 0.4977
Netherlands 0.7855 0.0754 0.2587 1 1.4707 -0.2460
Austria 0.6813 0.0701 0.1896 1 1.4142 -0.4665
Portugal 0.7553 0.0851 0.3548 1 -1.5783 0.2968
Finland 0.8371 0.0985 0.4589 1 -1.4403 -0.2424

1
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

10940

Table 4: Competition and technology gaps


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Specification estimation GLS OLS GLS OLS GLS OLS GLS OLS

Competition (Lerner) 1.4200*** 0.9550*** 1.2102*** 0.5470***


(0.0855) (0.1866) (0.0555) (0.1210)
Competition^2 (Lerner) -0.6450*** -0.2451*** -0.6211*** -0.0850***
(0.0244) (0.0584) (0.0548) (0.0210)
Competition (Boone) 2.5601*** 1.6551** 1.5600*** 1.2320***
(0.7588) (0.8271) (0.0852) (0.0152)
Competition^2 (Boone) -0.0560*** -0.0050* -0.0020** -0.0140*
(0.0140) (0.0030) (0.0010) (0.0082)
Equity/total assets 0.0010*** 0.0000** 0.0120*** 0.0251***
(0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0001)
Market share (log) -1.5870*** -0.8751* -1.4231*** -1.4250*
(0.1753) (0.5117) (0.1247) (0.8096)
Total Assets (log) -0.0040*** 0.0150** 0.0220*** 0.0210*
(0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0117)
Asset growth -4.4561*** -1.1231 -3.1251*** -1.1122**
(1.2632) (1.2815) (0.3952) (0.5295)
Asset growth (squared) 0.5473*** 0.4252* 0.2121*** 0.0127
(0.0914) (0.2361) (0.0353) (0.0140)
Herfindahl Hirshman Index 3.1251*** 1.4523*** 1.1217*** 1.2149*
(0.6242) (0.1782) (0.2802) (0.7142)
Country dummies No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
Fixed/Random effects Fixed Fixed Random Random Fixed Fixed Random Random
Observations 89582 114926 89582 114926 89582 114926 89582 114926
Number of banks 7457 8320 7457 8320 7457 8320 7457 8320
R-square 0.45 0.33 0.55 0.48 0.34 0.30 0.44 0.41
Hansen J statistics 1.745 1.895 0.797 0.547 2.142 2.485 0.658 0.756

p-value 0.12 0.1566 0.678 0.845 0.1452 0.2275 0.687 0.566


Based on Eq. (11). Clustered standard errors in parentheses; Asterisks indicate significance at the following levels: *0.10, **0.05, ***0.01
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 5: Granger causality tests between competition and innovation (technology gaps)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Dependent variable Tech. Gap Lerner Tech Gap Lerner Tech Gap Boone Tech Gap Boone

Tech. Gap (t-1) -0.3458*** -0.0015*** -0.3042*** -0.0025*** -0.3658*** -0.0121*** -0.3254*** -0.0358***
(0.0024) (0.0004) (0.0253) (0.0003) (0.0515) (0.0010) (0.0421) (0.0095)
Tech. Gap (t-2) -0.1452*** -0.0000 -0.0958*** -0.0000 -0.1825*** -0.0120*** -0.1285*** -0.0100**
(0.0145) (0.0010) (0.0092) (0.0001) (0.0085) (0.0085) (0.0258) (0.0080)
Tech. Gap (Total) -0.4910 -0.0015 -0.4000 -0.0025 -0.5483 -0.0132 -0.4539 -0.0458
F-statistic 875.00*** 14.52*** 820.00*** 12.25*** 745.00*** 10.21*** 786.00*** 22.32***
Lerner (t-1) 0.1254*** -0.3256*** 0.1045*** -0.2965***
(0.0245) (0.0263) (0.0142) (0.0152)
Lerner (t-2) -0.3254 -0.1425*** -0.2352 -0.1025***
(0.6523) (0.0142) (0.3253) (0.0015)
Lerner (Total) -0.2000 -0.4681 -0.1307 -0.3990
F-statistic 124.85*** 754.22*** 105.87*** 741.36***
Boone (t-1) 0.0214*** -0.4235*** 0.0125*** -0.3954***
(0.0025) (0.0423) (0.0001) (0.0052)
Boone (t-2) -0.1247 -0.0879*** -0.0951 -0.0541***
(0.1125) (0.0010) (0.0852) (0.0014)
Boone (Total) -0.1033 -0.5114 -0.0826 -0.3413
F-statistic 143.54*** 812.22*** 148.99*** 712.52***
Market share (log) -0.0458*** -0.0325*** -0.0025*** -0.0018*** -0.0596*** -0.0358*** -0.0412*** -0.0012***
(0.0010) (0.0025) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0025) (0.0012) (0.0001)
Total Assets (log) -0.0214*** -0.0120*** -0.0020 -0.0001 -0.0852*** -0.0423*** 0.0000 0.0000
(0.0025) (0.0010) (0.0100) (0.0020) (0.0023) (0.0024) (0.0001) (0.0010)
Asset growth 0.0254*** 0.0101*** 0.0485*** 0.0125
(0.0052) (0.0010) (0.0125) (0.0526)
Asset growth (squared) -0.0025*** -0.0152*** -0.0251** -0.0152
(0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0035) (0.0523)
Herfindahl Hirshman index -0.2233* -0.0024* -0.0025* -0.2521*
(0.1313) (0.0014) (0.0015) (0.1483)
Banking system assets (log) -0.1859*** -0.2524*** -0.0002** -0.0205
(0.0258) (0.0014) (0.0001) (0.0325)
Country dummies No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
Observations 114926 114926 114926 114926 114926 114926 114926 114926
Number of banks 8320 8320 8320 8320 8320 8320 8320 8320
R-squared 0.1545 0.3526 0.1725 0.4025 0.1424 0.3356 0.1728 0.3825
Clustered standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1; Herfindahl Hirshman index and banking system assets are measured on the state level.

1
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 6: Granger causality tests between competition and innovation on the upward slope
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Dependent variable Tech. Gap Lerner Tech Gap Lerner Tech Gap Boone Tech Gap Boone

Tech. Gap (t-1) 0.2541*** 0.0425*** 0.4012*** 0.0105*** 0.2589*** 0.0015*** 0.2689*** 0.0028***
(0.0021) (0.0021) (0.0253) (0.0003) (0.0421) (0.0001) (0.0214) (0.0001)
Tech. Gap (t-2) 0.1042*** 0.0052*** -0.0248*** 0.005 -0.0025*** -0.0011 -0.0015*** -0.0125
(0.0015) (0.0001) (0.0092) (0.0100) (0.0006) (0.0058) (0.0005) (0.0852)
Tech. Gap (Total) 0.3583 0.0477 0.3764 0.0155 0.2564 0.0004 0.2674 -0.0097
F-statistic 795.00*** 18.26*** 685.00*** 21.25*** 705.00*** 11.15** 658.00*** 13.55**
Lerner (t-1) 0.0258*** 0.2536*** 0.0982*** 0.0985**
(0.0015) (0.0025) (0.0002) (0.0456)
Lerner (t-2) 0.1089 -0.1528*** 0.0852 -0.1025***
(0.1589) (0.0258) (0.0898) (0.0005)
Lerner (Total) 0.1347 0.1008 0.1834 -0.0040
F-statistic 110.55*** 625.55*** 102.55*** 632.25***
Boone (t-1) -0.0526*** 0.0852*** 0.0325*** 0.0756***
(0.0010) (0.0025) (0.0001) (0.0022)
Boone (t-2) -0.0015 0.0563*** -0.0025 0.058***
(0.0152) (0.0001) (0.0125) (0.0015)
Boone (Total) -0.0541 0.1415 0.0300 0.1336
F-statistic 25.85*** 352.55*** 15.58** 258.44***
Market share (log) -0.0356*** -0.0256*** -0.0145*** -0.0052*** -0.0248*** -0.0582*** -0.0121*** -0.0201***
(0.0040) (0.0025) (0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0022) (0.0012) (0.0001)
Total Assets (log) -0.0156*** -0.0020*** -0.0120 -0.0001 -0.0772*** 0.2533*** 0.0002 0.0000
(0.0045) (0.0001) (0.0100) (0.0020) (0.0025) (0.0035) (0.0035) (0.0010)
Asset growth 0.0094*** 0.0204*** 0.0555*** 0.0269
(0.0023) (0.0010) (0.0155) (0.1025)
Asset growth (squared) -0.0143*** 0.0102*** -0.0244*** -0.1025
(0.0011) (0.0002) (0.0065) (0.5283)
Herfindahl Hirshman index -0.0253 -0.0020 -0.0005 -0.1521
(0.4564) (0.0032) (0.0015) (0.1685)
Banking system assets (log) 0.0125*** -0.2524*** -0.0102*** -0.0102
(0.0025) (0.0028) (0.0050) (0.0444)
Country dummies No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
Observations 77050 77050 77050 77050 77050 77050 77050 77050
Number of banks 5574 5574 5574 5574 5574 5574 5574 5574
R-squared 0.2856 0.4823 0.3052 0.4952 0.2652 0.4028 0.2935 0.4258
Clustered standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1; Herfindahl Hirshman index and banking system assets are measured on the state level.

2
Kienpin Tee, Zayed U., kienpin.tee@zu.ac.ae

Table 7: Granger causality tests between competition and innovation on the downward slope
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Dependent variable Tech. Gap Lerner Tech Gap Lerner Tech Gap Boone Tech Gap Boone

Tech. Gap (t-1) 0.1523*** -0.0254 0.1852*** -0.0248 0.0258*** -0.0025 0.0685*** -0.0021
(0.0024) (0.2562) (0.0025) (0.0245) (0.0025) (0.0125) (0.0043) (0.0059)
Tech. Gap (t-2) 0.0154*** -0.0025 -0.0014*** -0.0011 0.0025*** -0.002 0.4856*** -0.0336
(0.0025) (0.0058) (0.0001) (0.0058) (0.0001) (0.0250) (0.0025) (0.0800)
Tech. Gap (Total) 0.1677 -0.0279 0.1838 -0.0259 0.0283 -0.0045 0.5541 -0.0357
F-statistic 654.00*** 2.05 580.00*** 2.15 550.00*** 1.52 510.00*** 2.11
Lerner (t-1) -0.1587 0.0478*** -0.0258 0.0578***
(0.2523) (0.0210) (0.1852) (0.0152)
Lerner (t-2) -0.0254 -0.0523*** -0.0589 -0.0214***
(0.0526) (0.0250) 0.1058 (0.0025)
Lerner (Total) -0.1841 -0.0045 -0.0847 0.0364
F-statistic 3.05 568.00*** 2.89 525.00***
Boone (t-1) -0.0458 0.1058*** -0.2535 -0.0235***
(0.0852) (0.0254) (0.4258) (0.0058)
Boone (t-2) -0.0025 -0.0254*** -0.0254 0.0852***
(0.0254) (0.0002) (0.0658) (0.0025)
Boone (Total) -0.0483 0.0804 -0.2789 0.0617
F-statistic 4.25 458.00*** 3.55 385.00***
Market share (log) -0.0856*** -0.0645*** -0.0155*** -0.0108*** -0.0352*** -0.0748*** -0.0952*** -0.0212***
(0.0025) (0.0025) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0075) (0.0025) (0.0085)
Total Assets (log) -0.0956*** -0.0240*** -0.0120 -0.0018 -0.0741*** -0.0896*** 0.0080 0.0000
(0.0105) (0.0010) (0.0250) (0.0056) (0.0025) (0.0055) (0.0080) (0.0021)
Asset growth 0.0344*** 0.0258*** 0.0563*** 0.0665
(0.0063) (0.0010) (0.0085) (0.0852)
Asset growth (squared) -0.0185*** -0.0222*** -0.0858*** -0.0285
(0.0012) (0.0002) (0.0035) (0.0110)
Herfindahl Hirshman index -0.0589 -0.0015 -0.0125*** -0.1221
(0.1058) (0.0014) (0.0005) (0.1483)
Banking system assets (log) -0.1526*** -0.1232*** -0.0002** -0.0104
(0.0345) (0.0011) (0.0001) (0.0852)
Country dummies No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes
Observations 37876 37876 37876 37876 37876 37876 37876 37876
Number of banks 2746 2746 2746 2746 2746 2746 2746 2746
R-squared 0.1825 0.3058 0.2052 0.3522 0.1628 0.2582 0.1825 0.3025
Clustered standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1; Herfindahl Hirshman index and banking system assets are measured on the state level.

You might also like