You are on page 1of 9

International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Review of Financial Analysis

Cognitive biases in investors' behaviour under stress: Evidence from the


London Stock Exchange
Spyridon Kariofyllas a, Dionisis Philippas b,⁎, Costas Siriopoulos c
a
Department of Business Administration, University of Patras, 26504 Rio, Greece
b
Department of Finance, ESSCA School of Management, 55 Quai Alphonse Le Gallo, Boulogne, 92513 Paris, France
c
Zayed University, College of Business, P.O. Box 144534, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The paper examines the implications arising from the effect of two cognitive biases, representativeness and con-
Received 5 November 2016 servatism, for securities price behaviour on the London Stock Exchange. In a single- and multi-factor framework
Received in revised form 12 August 2017 of abnormal returns, the aspects of trend and consistency in the performance ratios of UK companies are exam-
Accepted 13 September 2017
ined on the base of behavioural finance theories with respect to cognitive biases. The findings obtained by the
Available online 15 September 2017
multi-factor model confirm the existence of two cognitive biases and trends that investors observe in financial
JEL classification:
performance over the long-term horizon, which is not the case for the single-factor model.
G01 © 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
G02
G12
G14

Keywords:
Cognitive biases
Representativeness
Conservatism

1. Introduction Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam


(1998) and Hong and Stein (1999). Addressing this issue is a challenge,
The financial performance of companies is subject to performance as the failure of forecasts, particularly over long horizons, is strongly re-
measures, changes in the direction of a price trend (price reversals) lated to investors' systematic mispricing of trend and consistency, being
and cognitive psychological phenomena. Focusing on cognitive psychol- influenced by cognitive biases while processing financial information.
ogy, there is a plethora of cognitive biases, such as conservatism, repre- Trend and consistency in the financial information constitute a pattern
sentativeness, anchoring, ambiguity aversion and so on, all of which of manifestation, incorporating cognitive biases in the information set
play a catalytic role in pricing implications and investment decisions. used for evaluation. While the consistency of past performance se-
The predictability of returns, particularly over long horizons, is the re- quences may possibly incorporate representativeness biases and there-
sult of time-varying discount rates, which are subject to an efficient fore over-reaction, the lack or even the short-term existence of such
market or systematic mispricing. In this context, price reversals and consistency may lead to an under-reaction due to conservatism.1
market inefficiency are the outputs of investors' information- Even though there is a considerable amount of empirical literature
processing biases due to the key role of the pervasive cognitive biases, concerning market inefficiency as the output of investors' information-
leading to rejection of the efficient market hypothesis and its validity. processing biases due to systematic mispricing, few studies, to the best
The paper discusses the pricing effects in the London Stock Exchange of our knowledge, have examined the influence of cognitive biases,
(LSE), when investors' information-processing for firms on the basis of focusing mainly on US data (see Antoniou, Doukas, & Subrahmanyam,
behavioural patterns (i.e. trend and consistency) is determined by two 2013; Chan, Frankel, & Kothari, 2004; Coval & Shumway, 2005;
cognitive biases, conservatism and representativeness, which confirm
(or reject) the validity and forecasting ability of three notable behav- 1
Over-reaction and under-reaction, noted as financial anomalies, are documented pat-
ioural finance theories of market inefficiency developed by Barberis, terns of price behaviour that are inconsistent with the predictions of efficient markets and
rational expectations with regard to asset pricing (De Bondt & Thaler, 1985). Behavioural
finance rests on cognitive psychology (systematic errors made by people in the way in
⁎ Corresponding author. which they think and take decisions) and limits to arbitrage (effectiveness of arbitrage in
E-mail addresses: skariofylla@upatras.gr (S. Kariofyllas), dionisis.philippas@essca.fr different circumstances, limited because of capital requirements, lack of full information,
(D. Philippas), Konstantinos.Syriopoulos@zu.ac.ae (C. Siriopoulos). risk involved in making markets efficient, etc.).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2017.09.003
1057-5219/© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62 55

Goetzmann & Kumar, 2008; Stambaugh, Yu, & Yuan, 2012; literature; that is, the earnings per share ratio. Secondly, we expand
Subrahmanyam, 2007) and the Spanish market (Forner & Sanabria, the hypothesis test horizon and we prolong the time period after the
2010). portfolio construction by adding one or two years in all the hypothesis
In light of the above and to make our arguments comparable to the tests; that is, from two or three years to four years. Our results also high-
benchmark in the related literature, we set up an extended design of hy- light a contradiction to the existing literature for the multi-factor
pothesis testing on the basis of patterns of trend and consistency with models, with their alpha values providing strong evidence for the occur-
respect to an empirical model which uses abnormal returns on rence of reversals, demonstrating the over-reaction of investors to-
London Stock Exchange firms for single-factor and multi-factor asset wards trends and the under-reaction in the processing of performance
pricing models. This empirical framework employs some model specifi- information stemming from conservatism bias over the long-term hori-
cations, adding value to the existing literature by highlighting a number zon. Finally, our empirical analysis provides an extensive examination of
of important findings and methodological aspects. companies in the UK in a multifactor modelling framework and
Under the first specification, we use a comprehensive dataset com- comprises the first attempt to do so. Consequently, the findings may
prising annual financial information for the financial institutions in the be of great interest concerning the association between behavioural
United Kingdom spanning a period from 1980 to 2012. Our modelling and international risk factors such as contagion in (and after) a period
framework is applied for the full period (1980–2012), as well as for of crisis, autonomous policy-making and stress events such as the
the period 1980–2006, which is a period before a number of sequential recent developments after Brexit, and so on.
financial stress events occurred, beginning with the US financial crisis in The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 pre-
2007, thereby addressing cognitive biases in depth by isolating the peri- sents the empirical design and the testing hypotheses of this study.
od before and whether major stress events are included. Section 3 provides a detailed description of the data. Section 4 develops
In the second specification, we classify the companies every year the modelling framework and Section 5 discusses the empirical
into five equal quintiles based on their growth. Thus, we make a distinc- findings. Finally, Section 6 concludes.
tion between financial performance and the company's share price
performance, which is measured using stock returns. This choice of fi- 2. Empirical design: cognitive biases and performance
nancial performance measure provides new insights, complementing
the existing literature (see, for example, Barberis et al., 1998; Chan Our study exhibits an extended empirical test design, using trend
et al., 2004; Wu, Wu, & Victor, 2009), which uses earnings due to its sa- and consistency of financial ratios in the London Stock Exchange to con-
lience and availability. Moreover, it assists in overcoming the systematic firm (or reject) the behavioural finance theories formed by Barberis
correlation between variables that predict future cash flows and expect- et al. (1998), Daniel et al. (1998) and Hong and Stein (1999). These be-
ed returns, as Fama and French (2006, 2008) and Chen, Novy-Marx, and havioural finance theories have been continuously developed over the
Zhang (2011) point out. last two decades and are based on the existence of the two main cogni-
The last model specification draws on three hypotheses with respect tive biases (Chan et al., 2004), conservatism and representativeness.
to a portfolio strategy for both periods tested by adopting long positions To begin with, it is essential to describe briefly the role of the two
(high stock growth) and short positions (low stock growth), for compa- cognitive biases, conservatism and representativeness, in investors' be-
nies that are consistent (or not) for both the upper and lower quintiles. liefs and their impact on pricing effects, assessing the three behavioural
The idea behind this is to examine the two positions under the influence finance theories of market inefficiency for the formation of investor ex-
of representativeness and conservatism. In line with the studies by pectations. Representativeness is the tendency of investors to classify
Hirshleifer (2001) and Rubinstein (2001), we examine in and out of firms into discrete groups based on similar characteristics. This implies
sample whether the consistency of past performance of financial ratios that consistency in the sequence of past performance causes investors
forecasts the future stock returns of companies, thus assessing the to place a firm into a group and form predictably biased expectations
predictive ability of the behavioural hypotheses. Finally, in an attempt about future performance. According to Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Siew
to expand the hypothesis-testing horizon and consequently provide Hong (2002), the pricing implication of representativeness is that inves-
evidence over a long-term period, we prolong the period of study tors might over-extrapolate from past performance and cause overreac-
after the portfolio construction by adding one- and two-year lags to all tion, thereby setting prices too high or too low, which generates return
of the hypothesis tests (i.e. from two years to three and four years). reversals in the future when expectations are proved false. The promi-
We test our empirical design by utilising an expanded version of the nence of the representativeness can be seen mainly in the halo effect,
Fama-French market risk-free rate model and the three-factor model of where investors observe a positive characteristic of the firm and then
mimicking portfolio (Fama & French, 1993, 1997) and a fourth momen- form expectations about other characteristics, and the clustering illusion
tum factor, similar to Carhart's (1997) decomposition of mutual funds and hot hand effects, where investors incorrectly characterise a
returns. Using the alphas (adjusted returns) for the Fama-French sequence of repeated returns as a trend (see, among others, Daniel
three-factor and the momentum factor models, we distinguish the ef- et al., 2002; Lakonishok, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1994; Papadamou &
fect of trends and consistency of financial performance beyond returns Siriopoulos, 2004; Sirri & Tufano, 1998).
or other firms' ratios. On the other hand, conservatism indicates under-reaction and pre-
The outcome of our empirical analysis is two main findings of great dicts momentum in pricing (see Daniel & Titman, 2006; Dechow &
importance. The first finding is that, over the long-term horizon, inves- Sloan, 1997; Rabin, 2002). Conservatism is an individual's tendency to
tors extend the trends that they observe in financial performance in a update their beliefs slowly, based on a Bayesian rule, in which they
stable manner. We argue that a company's financial performance overweight their prior beliefs and underweight the sample evidence.
which has past trends or consistencies leads to foreseeable return be- The result is that the agent might not revise his or her beliefs about fu-
haviour. The second important finding is that our results differ from ture earnings sufficiently upon observing a series of good earnings out-
those in the relevant literature (i.e. Chan et al., 2004; Daniel & Titman, comes, or there might also be overconfidence based on an individual's
2006; Forner & Sanabria, 2010) in the case of the multi-factor alphas. prior information.
This is particularly the case when we estimate the abnormal returns Assessing the three behavioural finance theories (hereafter behav-
using the models that calculate the alphas by adding factors such as ioural models), the first behavioural model, developed by Barberis et al.
size and momentum. (1998), assumes that investors permanently adopt faulty methods of pro-
Our paper adds to the existing literature by innovating in several cessing financial information based on the historical data, believing either
ways. Firstly, we enrich the financial performance measures by adding that there is a trend or an average return; thus, given the hypothesis of
a profitability ratio that has not previously been used in the relevant limited arbitrage, they over- or under-react. An investor's belief is that
56 S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62

earnings move between two regimes, the first being one in which earn- Hypothesis I. Companies will experience a reversal in returns after a
ings follow a mean reverting process (a shock to earnings will be reversed long period of exceptional performance, due to representativeness.
in the next period) and the second one in which earnings exhibit a trend
(a shock might be followed by an additional shock in the same direction After the formation of trending, representativeness suggests that
in the following period). Barberis et al.'s (1998) model relies on both consistency of performance will influence the investor sentiment (opti-
representativeness and conservatism as the drivers of these incorrect in- mist or pessimist). The more consistent the performance, the greater
ferences. The biased inferences generate both under- and over-reaction the bias will be. In this context, our second hypothesis predicts that
in prices if arbitrage is limited in capital markets. companies with a more consistent prior performance will face a greater
The second behavioural model is that of Daniel et al. (1998) and momentum of return reversal—i.e. conservatism.
examines the effects of excessive self-confidence and self-attribution. Hypothesis II. Companies will experience a greater reversal in returns
Confidence leads to overestimation of personal perceptions and/or in- after a long period of continuous and exceptional performance, com-
formation, as well as underestimation of broad information. Thus, future pared to companies with non-continuous exceptional performance.
behaviour depends to a great extent on past behaviour, i.e. conserva-
tism. On the other hand, due to self-attribution, investors overestimate Finally, following the approach of Chan et al. (2004) about
the public signals that indicate the validity of the private signals they re- confirming and disconfirming signals, we state our third hypothesis as
ceive, thus confirming their confidence, but underestimate uncon- follows:
firmed signals as mere noise. Consequently, investors have too great a
Hypothesis III. Following an unconfirmed signal, companies with pre-
confidence in their abilities as long as the public signals confirm their
vious continuous exceptional performance will experience a greater re-
private ones. Hence, cumulative good news forms trends in growth
versal in returns compared to companies with previous non-contiguous
and profits, which in turn lead to a higher share premium and subse-
exceptional performance.
quent reversal, i.e. representativeness. Finally, Hong and Stein (1999)
assume two heterogeneous groups of investors, based on how they em- Next, we establish the process with regard to testing the three hy-
ploy the information available to them. The first group (news watchers) potheses based on trend and consistency. Firstly, we establish a scale
under-reacts to new information (conservatism), whereas the second for trend by classifying the companies into five equal quintiles based
group (momentum traders) extends past information, partially on their growth in each year. The upper quintile contains the 20% of
correcting the biases of the first, but occasionally leading to over- companies with the highest growth in the five-year period in terms of
reaction. each ratio. There are then three intermediate categories, previously
A common assumption in all the models above is that arbitrage mentioned as “non-trading”, and finally the lower quintile, which con-
forces are limited and therefore cannot eliminate systematic tains the 20% of companies with the lowest growth. To examine the pos-
mispricing resulting from investors' biased information processing. sibility that investors react to financial performance according to the
We note that neither Daniel et al.'s (1998) nor Hong and Stein's three behavioural models, we have applied strategic trading, introduced
(1999) models draw on representativeness or conservatism per se by Chan et al. (2004), thereby creating two portfolios: (i) high stock
in terms of motivating the behaviour of investors. However, in both growth, classified as the long position; (ii) low stock growth, classified
models, the assumptions made can be viewed as operationally simi- as the short position. We hold these portfolios from the month of the
lar to investors' inferences subject to the representativeness and/or portfolio construction to forty-eight months ahead without
conservatism heuristics applied on the basis of the consistency of restructuring. If the differences between the performances of both
prior company performance. The pricing implications arising from long and short portfolios result in a negative sign, Hypothesis I is
biased self-attribution in Daniel et al. (1998) are more relevant in confirmed.
studying trends and consistency of performance, because investors To construct a measure of consistency, we initially follow the
become increasingly overconfident as public signals confirm their classification above. Then, for each of the two extreme quintiles
private signals, leading to an upward trend in expectations and (upper and lower), we classify the companies based on the consis-
overpriced stocks due to biased self-attribution and thereby tency of performance within each. Hence, for the upper group of
representativeness. companies, if the growth rate of a company is above the median for
In light of the above, we set out the specifications of our empirical at least four of the five years (recalculated every year), it is consid-
design which we use in the modelling framework. Based on repre- ered to be stable and is characterised as “consistent”; otherwise, it
sentativeness, we start with the assumption that investors use con- is considered unstable and characterised as “inconsistent”. Once
sistent growth rates from the past to place companies in three again, we create two portfolios with respect to the long and the
groups and thereby create biased expectations and mis-valued short positions. The first portfolio consists of those companies
stocks. The first group contains the companies with high growth: proved in the two-step process to be consistent for both the upper
this is considered by the investors and consequently investors over- and lower quintiles; the second portfolio comprises those companies
estimate them. The second group contains the companies with low characterised as inconsistent for the upper and lower quintiles, fol-
growth: investors expect their growth rate to decay and hence they lowing the same trading strategy. The differences in the performance
underestimate them. The remaining companies are considered of the portfolios thus structured must also be negative to confirm
non-trending companies, a group that was initially introduced by Hypothesis II.
Chan et al. (2004). This group refers to the companies that exhibit a Finally, to test Hypothesis III—i.e. the relationship between the con-
circular motion in their ratios, leading investors to believe they will sistency (or not) of the previous financial performance and the reaction
revert to past performance. This approach was adopted by Barberis of investors, as well as the confirmation or rejection of the forecast—we
et al. (1998) in their term “mean-reverting”. initially follow the ranking of companies in Hypothesis II. Then, we
Taking into consideration that the longer the period over which in- perform tests to observe the performance of each company at a time
vestors observe a trend, the easier it is for them to rank a company in point that follows the “consistent” or “inconsistent” period. If the
an aforementioned group, the observation period is here considered to performance is above the median of the reference period, we character-
be five years. Therefore, our first hypothesis, which is derived from ise it as a “confirming” (otherwise “disconfirming”) company. Following
the pricing implication of representativeness (Daniel et al., 2002), pre- this new classification, we again create long portfolios consisting
dicts return reversals while evidence of long-term reversals is noted of “confirming” companies and short portfolios consisting of
by De Bondt and Thaler (1985, 1987) and Ball, Kothari, and Shanken “disconfirming” companies. The differences must be negative to confirm
(1995). Hypothesis III.
S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62 57

Following the strategy setting given above, representativeness af- Table 1


fects the first portfolio, while conservatism affects the second. Behav- Description of UK company ratios.

ioural models forecast more negative performances of the portfolio Five-year period Returns EPS OIPS NIPS SPS
that includes the consistent shares in which the shareholder has strong 1980–1985 493 411 417 0 410
belief than in the portfolio that includes the inconsistent shares. This oc- 1986–1990 549 539 539 18 531
curs because investors' uptake of an unconfirmed signal is delayed—i.e. 1991–1995 634 647 650 61 646
the prices of the high-growth rate companies will gradually languish, 1996–2000 899 927 925 487 930
2001–2005 1099 1135 1136 1078 1139
while the prices of the low-growth rate companies will recover. Indeed,
2006–2012 1425 1426 1490 1420 1490
the more stable a company's past performance, the more intense the re- Total 5099 5085 5157 3064 5146
versal is bound to be and, as a consequence, a negative difference is also
Note: The table presents a description of the companies with five-years of annual data, for
expected in contrast to the inconsistent companies. It should also be the ratios of interest.
noted that during the testing of Hypothesis III, the window of portfolio
observation and strategic differences is extended to four years, as op-
posed to two years in Chan et al. (2004), to observe the differences in the Bank of England in 2009 and so on. In this context, we can examine
behaviour—as in the case of the previous two tests—over the long term. whether the consistency of past financial performance in the period
To interpret our results, we derive implications taking into consider- without major stress events, which comprises the overall trend, predicts
ation two assumptions. The first is that the investors' behaviour on the future returns, including the stress period, hence providing a compara-
LSE market exhibits no serious differentiation from that of other major tive analysis of how investors' perception changed under the pressure of
international financial hubs (e.g. the US market), in contrast with the stress observed in the UK financial system over these years such as the
study of Forner and Sanabria (2010) which focused on the Spanish mar- high pressure experienced in the UK financial sector, particularly in
ket. The UK market portfolio includes foreign assets, domestic and for- 2009.
eign human capital, and real-estate portfolios, offering an extensive Using as a benchmark the FTSE All Share Index, which includes 612
financial infrastructure and international diversification. Moreover, the companies from all sectors, we draw on four accounting ratios for 239
quantitative easing strategy adopted in the UK in 2009 has encouraged UK companies. The ratios of interest are the sales per share ratio
a cumulative boost in asset purchases within a discrete strategy in the (denoted as SPS), the net income per share ratio (denoted as NIPS),
money and capital markets. Consequently, the second assumption is the operating income per share ratio (denoted as OIPS) and the earnings
that arbitrage power is similar to other investigated markets and all in- per share ratio (denoted as EPS), which together show the financial per-
vestors use the same reasoning and are affected by the same biases. formance of a firm's various operations (Barth, Elliott, & Finn, 1999). To
calculate the growth rate of the ratios, we choose companies with at
least five years of available data in the WorldScope database, using the
3. Data selection
formula provided by Thompson Reuters for calculating discrete
changes. Moreover, we add the stock returns of the companies of our
A major part of our sample comes from the Thompson Reuters
sample and we rank the companies according to their last account as
WorldScope database and covers the annual accounting data of financial
at the end of December on the basis of their market performance over
institutions in the UK for the period spanning 1980 to 2012. Moreover,
the previous five years.
we use the database of the University of Exeter Centre for Finance and
We include operating income per share in addition to net income
Investment, which rebalances to control for survivorship bias for the
per share to mitigate the noise in the income measure due to large,
multi-factor models (four-factor model), following Gregory, Tharayan,
one-time items—i.e., special items, as in Chan et al. (2004). In this con-
and Christidis (2013). Accounting for survivorship bias and persistence
text, net income and operating income are divided by a firm's assets
or its reversal effect, we follow a neutral position between the two the-
and then per share to provide computation of the performance mea-
oretical fundamental contrasting views (Brown, Goetzman, Ibbotson, &
sures for periods with negative revenue, because simple earnings per
Ross, 1992; Grinblatt & Titman, 1992),2 avoiding possible drawbacks of
share growth measures are not meaningful in this context. Dividing
the methodological approach and arguing that even with possible survi-
earnings numbers with their corresponding capital base enables us to
vorship bias effect, the approach adopted is substantially different from
interpret the performance in terms of profitability, a common approach
both these views on the issue.
in the literature (see Chan et al., 2004; Fama & French, 2006, 2015;
The timespan was chosen to ensure the robustness of data and the
Sloan, 1996). The use of per share values mitigates the drawback of all
inclusion of significant economic stress events which affected the UK fi-
growth measures, which is that merger and acquisition activity can af-
nancial sector from 2007.3 Our empirical framework is applied for two
fect growth rate measures; moreover, it enhances the cross-sectional
periods; the first one is from 1980 to 2006, where no major stress events
comparability of the performance of firms of different sizes and miti-
occurred that would significantly affect the UK financial sector; the sec-
gates the potential problems of heteroscedasticity in regression testing.
ond is the full time period from 1980 to 2012, which incorporates a
Table 1 provides information concerning the companies with com-
number of stress events occurring after 2007, i.e. the US subprime mort-
plete data, distinguished by ratio and five-year periods, over the period
gage crisis in 2007, the impact of quantitative easing implemented by
studied. The amount of data provides sufficient robustness for an in-
2
depth analysis, particularly as the quantity of company data increased
The existing literature has two theoretical fundamental contrasting views on this as-
pect, focusing on mutual funds' performance and not on strategies. In the first one, Brown
significantly over the years, as shown. Finally, calculating the cross-
et al. (1992) argue that spurious persistence will be induced. In the second, Grinblatt and sectional correlations of the growth rate of the ratios of interest in addi-
Titman (1992) argue that performance reversals or non-persistence are more likely. tion to the capitalisation of the companies, there is no strong correlation
3
Cited examples of stress events are: i) the US subprime mortgage crisis and Lehman between the ratios and/or capitalisation.4
Brothers' bankruptcy in 2007–2008, following a number of announcements of credit
losses and write-downs by banks, mortgage lenders and other institutional investors; ii)
the credit default swaps clearing relating to European entities in July 2009; iii) the 4. Empirical modelling
European sovereign debt crisis starting in 2010 with a rescue package for European coun-
tries; iv) the sharp drop of stock prices in major stock exchanges across the US, Middle This section sets out the modelling framework with respect to the
East, Europe and Asia, caused by contagion of the European sovereign debt crisis and slow
empirical design. Our empirical modelling is consistent with the
economic growth of the US. Moreover, three quantitative easing programmes were imple-
mented by the FED (2008, 2009 and 2012), two by the Bank of England (2009 to 2012) and
4
the liquidity providing/standard tender programme by ECB (2009) in a coordinated move The results of the cross-correlations are not presented here, but are available upon
to ease the credit crunch effects. request.
58 S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62

single-factor and the Fama-French three- and four-factor models, which investors who are influenced by cognitive biases while processing fi-
take the form: nancial information. Secondly, the idea behind this choice is that
 country-specific multi-factor models explain the stock returns to a
Single−factor model : Rp;t −r fr ¼ ap þ βp Rm;t −r fr þ up;t ð1Þ greater extent and provide better conclusions and descriptions of
 returns than international models (Fama & French, 1993, 2006, 2008,
Three−factor model : Rp;t −r fr ¼ ap þ βp Rm;t −r fr þ sp SBM t 2012, 2015; Griffin, 2002; Hou, Xue, & Zhang, 2015). Therefore, the ex-
þ hp HMLt þ up;t ð2Þ planations offered draw on different exposures to macroeconomic fac-
tors, different degrees of internationalisation in companies across

Four−factor model : Rp;t −rfr ¼ ap þ βp Rm;t −r fr þ sp SBMt countries, different accounting representations and regulations, etc.
þ hp HMLt þ wp WMLt þ up;t ð3Þ (Gregory et al., 2013).
The different versions of asset pricing models for different markets
where Rp,t is the return on portfolio p at time t; rfr is the risk-free rate re- provide passable descriptions of average returns for portfolios formed
turn at time t proxied by the UK Treasury bill yield; Rm,t is the return on on the basis of size and value, or size and momentum. Fama and
the market portfolio at time t proxied by the Financial Times All Share French (2012) argue that in the case of the size-momentum portfolios
Index; SBMt is the time t value-weighted return of the factor- in Europe, four-factor asset pricing models are less successful. In the
mimicking portfolio constructed by the returns of (S)mall (M)inus case of the UK stock market, evidence from Lee, Liu, and Strong
(B)ig companies; HMLt is the time t value-weighted return of the (2007) questions the ability of the three-factor model to control ade-
factor-mimicking portfolio constructed by the returns of (H)igh quately for risk. Bauer, Cosemans, and Schotman (2010) also report
(M)inus (L)ow book-to-market value companies; and WMLt is the that there is evidence of time-varying betas when using the three-
time t value-weighted return of the factor-mimicking portfolio con- factor model. Another reason is that portfolios with tilts towards other
structed by the returns of (W)inners (M)inus (L)osers in the past peri- anomalies that seem to be related to historical average returns are
od. The factor loadings βp, sp, hp and wp capture portfolio risk exposures; more troublesome for the models (Fama & French, 2008). Finally,
ap is the interpretation of the portfolio's abnormal returns; and finally there are significant indications lending support for the existence of
up , t is the residual of portfolio p at time t. The established scale for two cognitive anomalies in various time periods, as there are numerous
trend is consistent with the abnormal returns for the single-factor and statistically significant reversals in returns that stem from over-
multi-factor models, equivalent to the intercept of the time series re- reactions caused by representativeness; on the other hand, there is ev-
gressions. Finally, stocks are sorted into quintiles according to growth idence of under-reaction generated by conservatism bias, which pre-
measures at the end of every year. Therefore, the returns on holdings dicts momentum in returns.
of equally weighted portfolios of top quintile stocks and bottom quintile
stocks and the differences between portfolios are calculated. 5. Empirical findings
The choice of this modelling framework is made for a variety of rea-
sons. Firstly, quantitative models in the social science of finance are This section presents the empirical findings and discusses the impli-
metaphors providing a useful framework with figurative knowledge cations associated with the present research hypotheses for the single-
and epistemologically meaningful form (McGoun, 2003). To the extent factor and multi-factor (three- and four-factor) alphas. We address
that a scholar should try to examine the financial performance of the every research hypothesis separately by presenting the results for the
firms using benchmarks, financial relationships are easier to be exam- full period 1980–2012 and the results for the period 1980–2006. More-
ined. The sensitivity of asset returns to overall market fluctuations and over, we use the same structure of panels in every table of results
cognitive biases is the risk determined by the relative prices of risky cap- (panels A, B, C and D) to show the five-year change in performance
ital assets (MacKenzie, 2006); thus, diversification is a process that can for the NIPS, OIPS, SPS and EPS respectively, providing the single-and
be extended to other existing paradigms in social sciences. This can be multi-factor alphas. Comparing the full period and the period
achieved with new metaphors developed within the current paradigm 1980–2006 for every hypothesis tested, we can arrive at conclusions re-
and puzzle-solving robustness (Lagoarde-Segot, 2015), revealing garding the extent to which the sequence of major stress events,

Table 2
Results for Hypothesis I – Full time period.
Note: The table displays the average annual abnormal returns for portfolios over period t and subsequent 1-, 2-, 3- and 4-year periods. The period studied is 1980–2012. The rows illustrate
the single-factor, three-factor and four-factor alphas. Stocks are sorted into quintiles based on growth measures in December of every year. The returns on holding equally weighted port-
folios of top and bottom quintile stocks and the difference between portfolios are calculated. Only the differences are shown in each panel. As the long and short portfolios are formed each
year, the 2-, 3- and 4-year abnormal return measures are from overlapping rolling periods. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#) denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the 1% and 5%
levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.063 −0.367# −0.247 0.199 0.035
Three-factor alphas 0.065 −0.031 −0.054# −0.007 −0.063⁎
Four-factor alphas 0.108⁎ −0.028 −0.039 −0.006 −0.042

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.063 −0.085 −0.037 −0.098 −0.124⁎
Three-factor alphas 0.009 −0.051⁎ −0.071⁎ −0.091⁎ −0.098⁎
Four-factor alphas 0.008 −0.071⁎ −0.064⁎ −0.089⁎ −0.096⁎

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.093 0.003 −0.115# −0.022 −0.062
Three-factor alphas −0.039⁎ −0.059⁎ −0.064⁎ −0.080⁎ −0.086⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.027 −0.056⁎ −0.055⁎ −0.087⁎ −0.077⁎

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.096 −0.013 −0.015 −0.116⁎ −0.180⁎
Three-factor alphas 0.016 −0.048⁎ −0.066⁎ −0.073⁎ −0.063⁎
Four-factor alphas 0.023 −0.054⁎ −0.051⁎ −0.077⁎ −0.066⁎
S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62 59

Table 3
Results for Hypothesis I – Period 1980–2006.
Note: The table displays average annual abnormal returns for portfolios over periods ahead and subsequent 1-, 2-, 3- and 4-year periods. The time period spans from 1980 to 2006. The
rows illustrate the single-factor, three-factor and four-factor alphas. Stocks are sorted into quintiles based on growth measures in December of every year. The returns on holding equally
weighted portfolios of top and bottom quintile stocks and the difference between portfolios are calculated. Only the differences are shown in each panel. As the long and short portfolios are
formed each year, the 2-, 3- and 4-year abnormal return measures are from overlapping rolling periods. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#) denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the
1% and 5% levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.060 −0.501⁎ −0.285 0.248⁎ 0.038
Three-factor alphas −0.016 −0.069 −0.071# −0.028⁎ −0.073#
Four-factor alphas 0.034 −0.079 −0.070 −0.023# −0.041

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.073 −0.091 0.004 −0.081 −0.123⁎
Three-factor alphas −0.006 −0.061⁎ −0.086⁎ −0.102⁎ −0.099⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.011 −0.090⁎ −0.086⁎ −0.097⁎ −0.106⁎

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.095 0.005 −0.101# −0.014 −0.048
Three-factor alphas −0.057⁎ −0.091⁎ −0.078⁎ −0.085⁎ −0.090⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.050⁎ −0.093⁎ −0.065⁎ −0.092⁎ −0.091⁎

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.070 0.015 −0.008 −0.093⁎ −0.183⁎
Three-factor alphas 0.003 −0.056⁎ −0.071⁎ −0.087⁎ −0.066⁎
Four-factor alphas 0.011 −0.071⁎ −0.060⁎ −0.092⁎ −0.070⁎

starting with the US subprime mortgage crisis in 2007, expanded differentiation between the two periods studied, as shown in the tables
dynamically in the following years and influenced the behaviour of above. Finally, we observe that the three- and four-factor alpha values
the companies. show no significant changes from the period 1980–2006 to the full pe-
riod, indicating that performance trends generate systematic reversal.
5.1. Empirical results for Hypothesis I
5.2. Empirical results for Hypothesis II
Tables 2 and 3 show the annual averages of abnormal returns for the
two periods studied, being the differences in the equally weighted com-
Our second research hypothesis addresses the extent to which com-
ponents of the quotas for the upper and lower quintiles (portfolios) dur-
panies with consistent financial performance produce more reversals in
ing the formation year plus one, two, three and four years following.
returns and fewer trends in comparison with companies with inconsis-
Each panel in the tables shows the single- and multi-factor alphas for
tent performance. A given firm-year is consistent with the high growth
the companies classified on the basis of the five-year change in perfor-
(low growth) trend if it is above (below) the median growth of other
mance for all the ratios of interest. Panel A shows firms sorted by the
contemporaneous firm-years.5 Within the top and bottom quintiles,
change in net income per share from five years previously to the last
firm-year observations are consistent (inconsistent) if all five or four
year, divided by total assets per share from five years previously. Panel
(three or fewer) sub-years of growth are consistent with the five-year
B shows firms sorted by the change in operating income per share
trend. Tables 4 and 5 display the annual averages for the abnormal
from five years previously to the last year, treated in the same way as
returns from the equally weighted components of the quotas for the dif-
panel A. Panel C shows firms sorted by change in sales per share from
ferences in the upper and lower quintiles (portfolios) in the formation
five years previously to the last year. Finally, panel D shows firms sorted
year plus one, two, three and four years following, for the full period
by earnings per share treated in the same way as panel C.
and the period 1980–2006.
When examining the results of the single-factor model in Table 3, the
Each panel in the tables shows the single- and multi-factor alphas for
negative alphas become apparent. Hypothesis I is verified four years after
the companies classified on the basis of the five-year change in perfor-
portfolio formation in the case of the OIPS ratio, and three and four years
mance for all the ratios of interest. Panel A uses quintiles based on the
after portfolio formation in the case of the EPS ratio. These findings
percentage change in five-year net income per share divided by total as-
provide evidence of similarities in investors' behaviour, in line with the
sets per share in the initial year. Panel B uses quintiles based on the
study by Chan et al. (2004). We next turn to the results derived from
change in five-year operating income per share treated in the same
the calculation of the three- and four-factor alphas for the full period.
way as Panel A. Panel C uses quintiles based on the percentage change
We find that in the case of the OIPS, SPS and EPS, the alpha values are neg-
in five-year sales per share and, finally, panel D uses quintiles based
ative to a large extent for the differences formed by the portfolios, and
on the percentage change in five-year earnings per share.
most of the cases (27 cases) are statistically significant. These findings
In the case of the single-factor alphas, as shown in Table 4, the find-
support our hypothesis that performance trends generate systematic
ings are of minor importance as we find negative values, as expected,
reversal, in line with the study by Lakonishok et al. (1994), who provide
with only two cases that are statistically significant. However, and in
evidence for these values versus the well-notarised stocks.
contrast to the results for Hypothesis I, the findings derived from the
Comparing the results for Hypothesis I for the two periods studied,
multi-factor models for Hypothesis II are quite interesting. We find ev-
we establish that in the case of the single-factor model, the NIPS ratio
idence that the pattern of past financial performance strongly affects
exhibits significant changes in the period 1980–2006 in that the re-
the stock returns, although not as clearly as for Hypothesis I. For all test-
quired negative alpha values for differences are confirmed one and
ing periods and all methods of estimating the alpha coefficients, we
three years after portfolio formation. This does not apply for the entire
period studied. Consequently, it is apparent that the crisis magnified 5
The counts of the UK companies and data to compute the five-year past returns and
the intensity of the phenomenon, most likely because of the removal the five-year past growth rates for the four measures of financial performance are calculat-
of noise traders and the shift in investors adopting a purely fundamental ed. The results of the cross-correlations are not presented here, but are available upon
and conservative approach. Unlike the other three ratios, there is no request.
60 S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62

Table 4
Results for Hypothesis II – Full time period.
Note: The table displays the average annual abnormal returns on buying and selling an equally weighted portfolio of top and bottom quintile stocks, respectively, at year t and in subse-
quent 1-, 2-, 3- and 4-year periods. The time period spans from 1980 to 2012. The rows show the difference in long/short returns between consistency groups. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#)
denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the 1% and 5% levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.153 −0.295 −0.553⁎ −0.332 0.034
Three-factor alphas −0.022 −0.024 0.037 0.039 −0.015
Four-factor alphas −0.018 0.006 0.033 0.090⁎ −0.048

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.253 −0.226 −0.130 −0.089 −0.095
Three-factor alphas −0.105⁎ −0.083⁎ −0.100⁎ −0.057 −0.055
Four-factor alphas −0.149⁎ −0.044 −0.130⁎ −0.083 −0.057

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.039 −0.004 −0.178⁎ −0.142 −0.074
Three-factor alphas −0.076⁎ −0.077⁎ −0.026# −0.051# −0.039
Four-factor alphas −0.107⁎ −0.052⁎ −0.044⁎ −0.059# −0.037

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.101 −0.196 −0.269 −0.218 −0.040
Three-factor alphas 0.013 −0.076 −0.086⁎ −0.083 −0.012
Four-factor alphas 0.080 −0.062 −0.093# −0.075 −0.020

observe negative and statistically significant values. However, in the for the period 1980–2006. Panels A, B, C and D in both tables show the
case of the NIPS ratio for the three-factor model and the EPS ratio for results on the basis of the five-year change in performance of the NIPS,
the four-factor model, we find no statistically significant negative differ- OIPS, SPS and EPS respectively. Panel A shows the returns for quintiles
ences. Therefore, the rejection of Hypothesis II is statistically supported, formed based on the change in five-year net income per share divided
albeit not pronounced. by total assets per share in the initial year. In the same way, panel B
Next, we undertake comparisons for the two periods studied with shows the returns for quintiles formed based on the change in five-
respect to Hypothesis II. Starting with the single-factor model, there is year operating income per share. Panel C shows the returns for quintiles
no strategic differentiation in the alpha values between the two periods formed based on the percentage change in five-year sales per share.
examined for any ratio or any time period. This supports the view of the Lastly, panel D shows returns for quintiles formed based on the percent-
equivocality of the results for the behavioural dimension of the impact age change in five-year earnings per share. In the same manner, a given
of the crisis. In contrast to the single-factor model, the results of the firm-year is consistent with the high growth (low growth) trend if it is
multi-factor models for the period 1980–2006 are as moderate as the above (below) the median growth of other contemporaneous firm-
previous ones, supporting the view that the pattern of past financial years. Within the top and bottom growth quintiles, firm-year observa-
performance strongly affects the stock returns, leading to the rejection tions are considered consistent (inconsistent) if all five or four (three
of Hypothesis II. or fewer) years of sub-period growth are consistent with the five-year
trend.
5.3. Empirical results for Hypothesis III In the case of the single-factor model for the full time period, we ob-
serve different portfolios with statistically significant negative prices in
Table 6 displays the results of the strategies analysed to verify two cases, the NIPS ratio and the OIPS ratio, both after four years of port-
Hypothesis III for the full period and Table 7 displays the relevant results folio formation. The findings for the three- and four-factor models for

Table 5
Results for Hypothesis II – Period 1980–2006.
Note: The table displays the average annual abnormal returns on buying and selling an equally weighted portfolio of top and bottom quintile stocks, respectively, over year t and subse-
quent 1-, 2-, 3- and 4-year periods. The time period spans from 1980 to 2006. The rows show the difference in long/short returns between consistency groups. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#)
denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the 1% and 5% levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.139 −0.666 −0.742⁎ −0.200 −0.182
Three-factor alphas −0.047 0.024 0.112# 0.016 0.001
Four-factor alphas −0.042 −0.013 0.038 0.094⁎ −0.048

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.225 −0.174 −0.170 −0.091 −0.090
Three-factor alphas −0.098⁎ −0.092⁎ −0.107⁎ −0.053 −0.058
Four-factor alphas −0.150⁎ −0.091⁎ −0.106⁎ −0.099 −0.072

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.026 −0.020 −0.237⁎ −0.170 −0.050
Three-factor alphas −0.068⁎ −0.072⁎ −0.013 −0.048 −0.048
Four-factor alphas −0.125⁎ −0.039 −0.030 −0.048 −0.049

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.070 −0.189 −0.251 −0.145 −0.073
Three-factor alphas −0.032 −0.096 −0.096# −0.115 0.001
Four-factor alphas −0.024 −0.057 −0.127# −0.102 −0.014
S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62 61

Table 6
Results for Hypothesis III – Full time period.
Note: The table displays the average annual returns on buying and selling an equally weighted portfolio of top and bottom quintile stocks, respectively, in the year that subsequent oper-
ating performance was revealed and the following four years. The period spans from 1980 to 2012. All rows show the differences between consistency groups. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#)
denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the 1% and 5% levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.259 −0.093 0.005 0.147 0.802#
Three-factor alphas −0.086⁎ −0.053 −0.049# −0.012 −0.018
Four-factor alphas −0.106⁎ −0.014 −0.031 −0.009 −0.023

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.123 0.081 0.400# −0.322# −0.463⁎
Three-factor alphas −0.022 −0.042# −0.034 −0.054# −0.060⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.037 −0.086⁎ 0.004 −0.045 −0.066⁎

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas 0.015 0.174 −0.132 −0.122 −0.088#
Three-factor alphas −0.071# −0.126⁎ 0.004 −0.059⁎ −0.022#
Four-factor alphas −0.017 −0.087 −0.003 −0.044⁎ −0.020

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.167 −0.065 −0.008 −0.116 −0.091
Three-factor alphas −0.045# −0.067⁎ −0.071⁎ −0.096⁎ −0.053⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.025 −0.039 −0.090⁎ −0.073⁎ −0.059⁎

Hypothesis III show significant differences in the alpha values from investors to form biased expectations of future firm performance. In
those in the studies by Chan et al. (2004) and Dechow and Sloan the UK, this is vital because the UK financial sector is an international
(1997). Our results indicate that consistent performers exhibit a greater hub for all types of investor and it raises a series of concerns regarding
reversal effect following a disconfirmatory year. We have negative and the spin-off that could be triggered by momentum and price reversals,
statistically significant alpha values for the full period in the majority especially with the recent implementation of the Bank of England quan-
of t cases (17 cases). Therefore, the third hypothesis is accepted under titative easing strategy where investors placed firms into groups based
the multi-factor analysis for the period studied. Finally, in the case of on past performance which were not subsequently realised.
Hypothesis III, the single-factor model shows no differentiation in the This paper examines the effects of the cognitive biases of representa-
period 1980–2006. There is also no difference in the alpha values in ei- tiveness and conservatism on behavioural investment decisions with
ther period for the other three ratios. The multi-factor model shows that respect to the existence of trends and consistency on the London
20 out of 40 cases have statistically significant negative alphas, meaning Stock Exchange over the period 1980 to 2012. Under single- and
that Hypothesis III is accepted for both periods studied, providing evi- multi-factor model specifications, we examine the extent to which
dence of under-reaction in the processing of performance information financial information viewed from a long-term perspective provides
stemming from conservatism bias. support for the notion that past performance forecasts long-term future
performance, by considering three research hypotheses.
6. Conclusion In line with the first hypothesis, the findings indicate the occurrence
of reversals, demonstrating the over-reaction of investors towards trends.
Considerable efforts have been made by empirical researchers in re- In the second hypothesis, we tested whether the stability of past financial
cent years to document investor behaviour that relies on representa- performance would cause more reversals than momentum. We find
tiveness and conservatism bias at longer horizons, which can lead limited evidence that consistency in past growth rates offers amelioration

Table 7
Results for Hypothesis III – Period 1980–2006.
Note: The table presents the average annual returns for buying and selling an equally weighted portfolio of top and bottom quintile stocks, respectively, in the year that subsequent op-
erating performance was revealed and the following four years. The period spans from 1980 to 2006. All rows show the differences between consistency groups. A star (⁎) and a hashtag (#)
denote that the alpha coefficients are significant at the 1% and 5% levels according to the Newey–West test, respectively.

Periods ahead 0 1 2 3 4

Panel A
Net income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.725⁎ −0.077 −0.139 0.162 0.855#
Three-factor alphas −0.070 −0.082⁎ −0.091⁎ 0.034 0.013
Four-factor alphas −0.108 −0.022⁎ −0.050# 0.021 −0.005

Panel B
Operating income per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.147 0.057 0.451# −0.320 −0.470⁎
Three-factor alphas −0.033 −0.039 −0.048 −0.059# −0.069⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.074 −0.080⁎ 0.006 −0.040 −0.074⁎

Panel C
Sales per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.035 −0.011 −0.040 −0.086 −0.097#
Three-factor alphas −0.046 −0.061⁎ −0.032# −0.074⁎ −0.025#
Four-factor alphas −0.029 −0.035⁎ −0.048⁎ −0.068⁎ −0.019

Panel D
Earnings per share (difference) Single-factor alphas −0.137 0.047 −0.037 −0.094 −0.075
Three-factor alphas −0.065⁎ −0.108⁎ −0.069⁎ −0.092⁎ −0.063⁎
Four-factor alphas −0.050 −0.064⁎ −0.092⁎ −0.076# −0.076⁎
62 S. Kariofyllas et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 54 (2017) 54–62

in terms of the predictability of returns (representativeness bias). Finally, De Bondt, W., & Thaler, R. (1987). Further evidence of investor overreaction and stock
market seasonality. Journal of Finance, 42(3), 557–581.
we examine whether the confirmation or rejection of established consis- Dechow, P. M., & Sloan, R. H. (1997). Returns to contrarian investment strategies: Test of
tency or inconsistency of financial performance can lead to reversals in naïve expectations hypotheses. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1), 3–27.
the third hypothesis. Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and
bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56.
Our findings broadly argue that investors' behaviour in terms of Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1997). Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics,
their strategies has a smooth trend during stress periods, as if other 43(2), 153–193.
similar events have provided adequate information—and indeed Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2006). Profitability, investment, and average returns. Journal of
Financial Economics, 82(3), 491–518.
instruments—to handle a future stress event. Notwithstanding our Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2008). Dissecting anomalies. Journal of Finance, 63(4),
findings, the predictability of returns documented in the literature re- 1653–1678.
mains an ongoing debate within the topic of market efficiency, posing Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2012). Size, value and momentum in international stock
returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(3), 457–472.
challenges to continue testing behavioural finance theories within
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2015). A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial
recent developments worldwide. Emphasis should also be given to Economics, 16(1), 1–22.
markets with limited arbitrage and to markets with undisputed debt Forner, C., & Sanabria, S. (2010). Post-earnings announcement drift in Spain and behav-
crisis characteristics. ioural finance models. The European Accounting Review, 19(4), 775–815.
Goetzmann, W. N., & Kumar, A. (2008). Equity portfolio diversification. Review of Finance,
12(3), 433–463.
Acknowledgements Gregory, A., Tharayan, R., & Christidis, A. (2013). Constructing and testing alternative ver-
sions of the Fama–French and Carhart models in the UK. Journal of Business Finance
and Accounting, 40(1–2), 172–214.
The authors would like to thank the participants of the 12th Interna- Griffin, J. M. (2002). Are the Fama and French factors global or country specific? Review of
tional Conference on International Finance, Prato, Italy (2014), for their Financial Studies, 15(3), 783–803.
constructive comments and suggestions. Grinblatt, M., & Titman, S. (1992). The persistence of mutual fund performance. Journal of
Finance, 47(5), 1977–1984.
Hirshleifer, D. (2001). Investor psychology and asset pricing. Journal of Finance, 56(4),
References 1533–1598.
Hong, H., & Stein, J. (1999). A unified theory of under reaction momentum trading, and
Antoniou, C., Doukas, J. A., & Subrahmanyam, A. (2013). Cognitive dissonance, sentiment overreaction in asset markets. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2143–2184.
and momentum. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 48(1), 245–275. Hou, K., Xue, C., & Zhang, L. (2015). Digesting anomalies: An investment approach. Review
Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Shanken, J. (1995). Problems in measuring portfolio performance: of Financial Studies, 28, 650–705.
An application to contrarian investment strategies. Journal of Financial Economics, Lagoarde-Segot, T. (2015). Diversifying financial research: From financialization to sus-
38(1), 79–107. tainability. International Review of Financial Analysis, 39(5), 1–6.
Barberis, N., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). A model of investor sentiment. Journal of Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Contrarian investment, extrapolation
Financial Economics, 49(3), 307–343. and risk. Journal of Finance, 49(5), 1541–1578.
Barth, M., Elliott, J., & Finn, M. (1999). Market rewards associated with patterns of increas- Lee, E., Liu, W., & Strong, N. (2007). UK evidence on the characteristics versus covariance
ing earnings. Journal of Accounting Research, 37(2), 387–413. debate. European Financial Management, 13(4), 742–756.
Bauer, R., Cosemans, M., & Schotman, P. C. (2010). Conditional asset pricing and stock MacKenzie, D. (2006). An engine, not a camera: How financial models shape markets. Cam-
market anomalies in Europe. European Financial Management, 16(2), 165–190. bridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Brown, S. J., Goetzman, W., Ibbotson, R. G., & Ross, S. A. (1992). Survivorship bias in per- McGoun, S. (2003). Finance models as metaphors. International Review of Financial
formance studies. Review of Financial Studies, 5(4), 553–580. Analysis, 12(4), 421–433.
Carhart, M. M. (1997). On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance, Papadamou, S., & Siriopoulos, C. (2004). American equity mutual funds in European mar-
52(1), 57–82. kets: Hot hands phenomenon and style analysis. International Journal of Finance and
Chan, W. S., Frankel, R., & Kothari, S. P. (2004). Testing behavioral finance theories using Economics, 9(2), 85–97.
trends and consistency in financial performance. Journal of Accounting and Economics, Rabin, M. (2002). Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. Quarterly Journal of
38(12), 3–50. Economics, 117(3), 775–816.
Chen, L., Novy-Marx, R., & Zhang, L. (2011). An alternative three-factor model. Working Rubinstein, M. (2001). Rational markets: Yes or no? The affirmative case. Financial
paper, Washington University in St. Louis, University of Chicago, and University of Analysts Journal, 57, 15–29.
Michigan. Sirri, E., & Tufano, P. (1998). Costly search and mutual fund flows. Journal of Finance,
Coval, J., & Shumway, T. (2005). Do behavioural biases affect prices? Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1589–1622.
60(1), 1–34. Sloan, R. (1996). Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about
Daniel, K., & Titman, S. (2006). Market reactions to tangible and intangible information. future earnings? Accounting Review, 71(3), 289–315.
Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1605–1643. Stambaugh, R., Yu, J., & Yuan, Y. (2012). The short of it: Investor sentiment and anomalies.
Daniel, K. D., Hirshleifer, D., & Siew Hong, T. (2002). Investor psychology in capital mar- Journal of Financial Economics, 104(2), 288–302.
kets: Evidence and policy implications. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(1), Subrahmanyam, A. (2007). Behavioral finance: A review and synthesis. European Financial
139–209. Management, 14(1), 12–29.
Daniel, K. D., Hirshleifer, D., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1998). Investor psychology and secu- Wu, C. H., Wu, C. S., & Victor, L. (2009). The conservatism bias in an emerging stock mar-
rity market under- and overreactions. Journal of Finance, 53(6), 1839–1885. ket: Evidence from Taiwan. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 17(4), 494–505.
De Bondt, W., & Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact? Journal of Finance,
40(3), 793–805.

You might also like