You are on page 1of 7

This article was downloaded by: [131.94.16.

10] On: 19 November 2015, At: 15:39


Publisher: Institute for Operations Research and the Management Sciences (INFORMS)
INFORMS is located in Maryland, USA

Organization Science
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://pubsonline.informs.org

Mortality, Reproducibility, and the Persistence of Styles of


Theory
Jeffrey Pfeffer,

To cite this article:


Jeffrey Pfeffer, (1995) Mortality, Reproducibility, and the Persistence of Styles of Theory. Organization Science 6(6):681-686.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/orsc.6.6.681

Full terms and conditions of use: http://pubsonline.informs.org/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used only for the purposes of research, teaching, and/or private study. Commercial use
or systematic downloading (by robots or other automatic processes) is prohibited without explicit Publisher
approval, unless otherwise noted. For more information, contact permissions@informs.org.

The Publisher does not warrant or guarantee the article’s accuracy, completeness, merchantability, fitness
for a particular purpose, or non-infringement. Descriptions of, or references to, products or publications, or
inclusion of an advertisement in this article, neither constitutes nor implies a guarantee, endorsement, or
support of claims made of that product, publication, or service.

© 1995 INFORMS

Please scroll down for article—it is on subsequent pages

INFORMS is the largest professional society in the world for professionals in the fields of operations research, management
science, and analytics.
For more information on INFORMS, its publications, membership, or meetings visit http://www.informs.org
JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

we build networks of scholars and their supporters working on common topics, that
we secure control of influential journals and create technologies that encourage
others to do work that will increase the likelihood that particular ideas and streams of
inquiry will endure. Pfeffer <loes not appear to advocate any particular theory,
methodology or specific journal but to be describing what he believes contributes to
the emergence and survival of other "successful" scientific fields. Van Maanen, on the
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

other hand, eschews a formal, organized approach to the furtherance of the field. He
is more interested in understanding and facilitating the development of good ideas
that we create as we do our work and with their meaning and their quality. He is
asking evaluative questions about performances in our craft. He puts his faith in
plurality, in the dispersion of ideas from multiple sources and scholars and with the
way those ideas are written and communicated as paths to endurance of the field.
Pfeffer views the debate about form and discourse as a ·'Sideshow." He is inherently
questioning the wisdom of ignoring the impact of movements, changes, and dynamics
of a "reality" out there. Van Maanen sees the debate as "the Main Event." He does
not believe that one can be free from rhetoric which shapes what wc experience as
"reality."
As 1 noted earlier, readers will decide for themselves which view of paradigm
development is most plausible and most valuable, based on the persuasiveness of the
authors as well as on their own predilections, experiences and insights. 1 hope that
the debate prornotes a better grasp of the issues and that the end result for readers
and for the field is that the argurnents and contexts provided Pfeffer and Van
Maanen, together with other voices on the topic, will rnove us forward in our
understandings of the nature and role of paradigrns, rather than keeping us in
polarized camps. We need more vigorous and open debate in the field and these two
authors have provided a fine exernplar of what can be accomplished when passion
and erudition are presented in debates of irnportance. We are all enriched by the
candor and the capabilities of these two fine scholars as they have expounded on
these issues.

Peter J. Frost

Mortality, Reproducibility, and the


Persistence of Styles of Theory

Jeffrey Pfeffer
Graduate School of Business, Stanford Uniuersity, Stanford, California 94305-5015

It seems somehow appropriate that Peter Frost's letter as "less restrained than we are used to"was an under-
sending me a draft of John Van Maanen's (1995) statement.
article should have been dated November 7, 1994. For John is nothing if not a master of rhetoric, and his
on November 8 we witnessed, at least in the United comment on my paper employs tried and true rhetori-
States and particularly in California, the culmination of cal devices. This includes contrastive pairs (Atkinson
a season of political campaigns notable for their 1984), in this instance, implicitly Weick and a style of
viciousness and appeal to emotion rather than reason. theory that "rests on its more or less unique style"
Frost's (1995) characterization of Van Maanen's article (p. 135) versus Pfeffer, a presumed apologist for (if not

ÜRGANIZATION SCIENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995 681

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved


JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

an example of) "a logocentric tradition of empirical fields that exist in a world of increasingly scarce re-
science with its count-and-classify conventions" and sources, but that interest was secondary to trying to
"more than a little physics envy" (p. 134). Van understand the source of paradigmatic differences: not
Maanen's article also follows Edelman's (1964, p. 124) between physics and organization studies, but between
description of political speech as "a ritual, dulling the política! science, or strategic management, or eco-
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

critical faculties rather than awakening them. Chronic nomics, and organization studies.
repetition of clichés and stale phrases that serve simply The claims of others (e.g., Canella and Paetzold
to evoke a conditioned uncritical response is a time- 1994, p. 337) to the contrary, it remains the case that
honored habit among politicians and a mentally restful organization studies is very much at risk far experienc-
one for their audiences." Van Maanen promotes a ing sorne of the same processes that have occurred in
caricature of normal science and reinfarces its protago- relatcd social sciences: namely, a domination by an
nists' unacceptability with emotion-laden adjectives economistic, rational choice perspective that relies on
(shrill, sour, vain, autocratic, insufferably smug, ortho- methodological individualism, neglects institutional
dox, and naive, among many others). context or detail, relies on rational choice/actor mod-
Finally, Van Maanen employs perhaps the most els. and postulates agency theory-like (opportunistic,
time-honored tradition in political language: saying one self-interest seeking) assumptions about human behav-
thing while doing the other (Edelman 1964). For even ior. I happen to believc that such a theoretical ap-
as Van Maanen venerates dialectic reconstruction and proach is both substantively incorrect and managerially
bemoans either/or reasoning, he couches the theoreti- harmful (Pfeffer 1994, Ch. 4). 1 remain concerned that
cal issues that distinguish his approach from mine as as sorne of us create an interesting intellectual sideshow
being mutually incompatible; far instance, description about presumed paradigmatic imperialism, we have
either following from objects or being prior to recog- failed to notice the main event: the growing influence
nizing those social objects. And, even as he bemoans of rational choice, economics-líke theory on organiza-
contention and defensiveness, he plays word games tion studies.
with my name, uses provocative language, and notes
that "My {John's} remarks ... must then be understood Do Developed Paradigms Triumph?
as ... an understandable and necessary effart to defend What do the data indicate about changing intellectual
my work" (1995, p. 134, emphasis added). Having not orientations in fields? Here political science has much
attacked nor even mentioned either him or his work in to teach us. Although the field of political science was
my earlier article, the need to defend same, while once dominated by "institutional analysis, behaviorist
complaining about defensiveness, seems peculiar. methods, and group-based pluralist theory" (Green and
Van Maanen's particular article aside, what has sur- Shapiro 1994, p. 2), today rational choice theory reigns
prised me in the time since 1 first gave my talk and my supreme. In 1992, rational choice theory accounted for
article appeared is the emotion it has aroused. I am almost 40 percent of the articles published in the
surprised because, as 1 will describe below, the issucs American Political Science Reuiew, the discipline's lead-
raised are scarcely unique to organization studies, be- ing journal (Green and Shapiro 1994, pp. 2-3). More-
ing contested, albeit with occasionally less vitriol, in over, ·'the advent of rational choice theory has recast
several adjacent fields such as strategic management, much of the intellectual landscape in the discipline of
política! science, and even economics. Moreover, the political science" (Green and Shapiro 1994, p. 3); "its
points 1 made seem scarcely controversia! with respect proponents are highly sought by all major American
to their empírica! faundations and probably not even in política! science departments" (Green and Shapiro
the logic of the argument, as 1 hope to demonstrate 1994, p. 2), and "press editors eagerly pursue half-com-
shortly. pleted manuscripts by practitioners in the field"
The intent of my talk and paper was to encourage us (Ordeshook 1993, p. 74). Rational choice theory de-
to take a concept-paradigm development-whose ef- duces the microfoundations of behavior from assump-
fects on a number of outcomes had been well-studied tions about incentives, constraints, and the calculations
and to ask, both in general and with respect to organi- individuals make when confronted with incentives,
zation studies in particular, what determined the leve! constraints, and information about both. In política!
of paradigm development that characterized a field or science, rational choice includes game theory. In orga-
subdiscipline; why is it that sorne fields seem to exhibit nization science, it would include transaction cost eco-
more consensus than others? It seemed useful to also nomics and agency theory, both of which deduce, often
explore the implications of paradigmatic consensus far using sorne kind of formalism, propositions about be-

682 ÜRGANIZATJON ScJENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved


JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

havior from assumptions of economizing on the part of 1992 through December 1993, of 32 published articles,
rational actors facing incentives and constraints. 5, or 15.6%, were ecolog1cal approaches to organiza-
In their compelling critique of rational choice theory, tional analysis. It is not likely that 15.6% of the field's
Green and Shapiro pose an apparent paradox: al- scholars are ecologists. But these results are precisely
though rational choice theory has grown enormously in what onc would expect from the argument that theo-
retical consensus and coherence produces more effi-
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

importan ce and stature within political science, "the


stature of rational choice scholarship does not rest on a cient and effective research programs resulting in dis-
readily identifiable set of empírica! successes" (1994, proportionate impact and publication.
p. 5). Green and Shapiro (1994, p. 6) note that "the Even the field of economics itself holds sorne lessons
case has yet to be made that these models have ad- about disciplinary evolution and the power of paradig-
vanced our understanding of how politics works in the matic consensus. Economics did not start out in its
real world." Why should a subfield grow from being present form or with its current analytic apparatus.
virtually nonexistent in 1957 to being one of the largest Parker (1993, p. 155) noted that 30 of the 50 founders
(if not the largest) subspecialty in just 25 years without of the American Economic Association were ordained
actually accounting for empirical observations of poli- ministers, and the association was founded in 1885 as
tics in non-trivial ways? I would argue because of the "a progressive counterweight to what its members saw
paradigmatic consensus that gives rational choice a as the social Darwinism then emerging in the social
competitive advantage over its theoretical rivals in po- sciences" (1993, p. 154). Parker's review of methodolog-
litical science that lack such consensus. ical disputes within the discipline suggests that:
Is what happened in political science being replayed
Wh1le excess abstractton would seem to be a recent com-
in organization science? In 1975, the year in which
plaint, rooted m the heavy reliance on mathematics since
Williamson's (1975) first book-length exposition of
World War II, the cntic1sm 1s more than a century old. A
transaction costs reasoning appeared, and the year recent rev1ew .. of methodolog1cal disputes among American
befo re the appearance of Jensen and Meckling (1976), econom1sts begms its survey m 1860 and counts no fewer than
not surprisingly, there was little citation of economics 80 exampb of bas1c .. debates before 1900 (Parker 1993,
in organizational journals; just 2.5% of the articles in p 154)
Administrative Science Quarterly and 0% of the articles
in the Academy of Management Journal cited eco- In ways very similar to Green and Shapiro's crit-
nomics or economists. By 1985, just ten years later, the ique of rational choice theory in political science,
proportions had grown to 30% in ASQ and 10% in Parker (1993) documents both the failures of modero
AMI. By 1993, the proportion of articles citing eco- economic theory to account for empirical reality in
nomics had risen to 40% in ASQ and 24% in AMI. nontrivial ways, and also documents the various mecha-
Although citations are not the only indicator of the nisms that have been employed to develop and main-
growth of a way of doing organizational analysis, the tain dominance over thi: discipline by that style of
pattern is informative and the parallels to the growth theory. Readers troubled by my modest expression of
of rational choice in political science are striking. concern about theoretical profusion in the organiza-
One can also look within organization scicnce to see tional sciences should read Parker's (1993) documenta-
what can be accomplished by subfields that have con- tion of how serious theoretical hegemony is achieved
sensus on methods and subject matter and, most im- and maintained.
portantly, because of that consensus are cfficient in The field of strategic management provides yet an-
training graduate students and others and developing a other context in which to observe the struggle over
technology that makes scholarship more predictable paradigms and paradigm consensus. On one side of the
and more readily accomplished. Two such subfields, debate, arguing for more theoretical and methodologi-
although there are clearly others, are behavioral deci- cal orthodoxy, are, among others, Camerer (1985) and
sion theory and population ecology. Over the years, Montgomery et al. (1989). These authors bemoaned
behavioral decision theory has virtually taken over one the confusion about concepts, failure to do proper
of the major journals: what used to be called Organiza- empírica! testing, and the absence of cumulation or as
tional Behavior and Human Performance is now Organi- much progress in knowledge as they would like.
zational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, and Camerer (1985, p. 1) advocated "the deductive use of
there has been a corresponding shift in its content over mathematic:- and econom1c concepts." Taking the other
time. In the case of population ecology, in the six issues side of the debate are people such as Mahoney (1993),
of Administrative Science Quarter/y from September who argued for pragmat1sm and above all, pluralism.

ÜRGANIZATION ScIENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995 683

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved


JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

Although it is too early to tell precisely how this debate ings "refuse settlement,"they are "amusingly paradoxi-
will play itself out, there are certainly significant ad- cal," and Karl writes "stringing together ... ideas or
vances being scored by game theory and industrial propositions without connectives" (Van Maanen, pp.
organization economics. 136-37). Third, Weick often takes two logical oppo-
Thus, there is suggestive evidence from adjacent sites and shows how both may be true at the same
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

social sciences that theoretical perspectives character- time, or, working in reverse, produces a dialectic from
ized by formalism and a deductive methodology often an identity (Van Maanen, p. 137). Finally, Weick keeps
are able to achieve dominance, even when their empir- the reader's attention through presence-by enumerat-
ical contributions are minuscule. The fact of theoreti- ing, amplifying, and repeating ideas-always, however,
cal domination in the presence of modest results makes in slightly different form. Salancik's description (1977,
the power of that style of theory all the more evident; p. xiii) of Weick's development and writing about the
after all, any theory can succeed if it is actually useful enactment process is instructive:
and empirically insightful. It is a much bigger challenge
to prevail in the face of modest or few accomplish- I described severa! difficulties that I thought readers would
ments. Moreover, there is evidence that many of these have with sorne of bis ideas and pointed out sorne places
same theoretical trends are currently visible in organi- where a hmt of definition to enactment was emerging and
zation science, with a growing importance of the same could be expanded. When I later went through bis revision, I
rational choice models and perspectives that first noticed that he had carefully deleted nearly every sentence
achieved dominance in economics and then political that I alluded to. From this experience, I concluded, "To
science. define enactment is to miss the point about it."

How easy would it be far others to employ Weick's


Why Styles of Theory Prevail style, or even to build on his work? Although being
Embedded in Van Maanen's illuminating discussion of elusive in one's definitions and non-linear in one's
Karl Weick's work is a way of understanding why work thinking may make far more interesting, intellectually
of that type (to the extent John's description of it is challenging, or engaging reading, it is almost certainly
accurate), however much we may admire its insight, not a prescription far having one's work extended,
richness, lucidity, virtuosity, creativeness, and style, is replicated, or adopted by others as part and parce! of
inevitably disadvantaged in the marketplace of ideas. their own research program. Similarly, paradox and
Ideas and writing have a finite lifetime and their au- meandering are also not likely to make it easy or
thors most certainly are mortal. Great ideas may last in perhaps even likely far others to build on those mean-
the collective consciousness longer than ideas of less derings and extend the paradoxical line of thought.
originality or power, but nevertheless, citations are This is not to say that the linear, list-like, normal
almost invariably time dependent. As authors retire science-type writings that Van Maanen eschews are
from the scene, the only way their work and ideas can somehow intrinsically superior. It is simply an ecologi-
be maintained is to have others pick them up and cal argument; the ability to readily reproduce gives
develop them or carry them forward. Even contempo- ideas (just as it does other forms) survival value.
raneously, it is probably useful to have more rather Technology matters a lot in the ability of ideas or
than fewer students and colleagues doing work related theories to develop adherents, which is why theories
to one's own. lnfluence is not simply a numbers game, that come to have widespread use and currency often,
but numbers certainly count. although not always, have associated technologies that
How easy or difficult it is to recruit others to further- render their use easier. Three examples illustrate the
ing one's intellectual efforts or to pick up one's intellec- point. Population ecology, in its study of the dynamics
tual torch is not independent of the style of one's work. of birth and death over time, virtually requires a
Van Maanen uses the writing of Karl Weick as an methodology far analyzing qualitative outcomes (such
exemplar, "a distinctive and altogether useful way of as the birth or death of an organization, or its change
putting theory into print" (Van Maanen, p. 135). In from one structural forro or strategy to another) over
describing Weick's writing, he argues that it has four time. Hannan and Tuma's (1979) development of
qualities. First, it is essayistic in form, filled with event-history analysis and the software to implement
"meanderings, detours," and "distractions" (Van that analysis was clearly essential in making it easier
Maanen, p. 136). Second, the writing is characterized far others to adopt and implement their theoretical
by indeterminacy and open-endedness. Weick's writ- framework.

684 ÜRGANIZATION Sc1ENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved


JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

In the early 1980s, network concepts of organizations how to go about doing it in very specific terrns. That is
and social structure were diffuse and unorganized. why the development of replicable, teachable, transfer-
Burt (1980, p. 79) noted: able concepts and rnethods is helpful, to put it rnildly.
Anyone reading through what purport~ to be a "network"
literature will readily perceive the wisdom of Barnes' (1972)
Sorne Concluding Thoughts
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

analogy between that literature and "a termmological jungle


Reviewing the developrnent of the so-called Austrian
in which any newcomer may plant a tree." A loose federat1on
of approaches ... is currently referenced as network analys1s.
school of econornics, Foss and Knudsen (1993, p. 19)
concluded that "there has to be sorne balance between
Burt's subsequent attempts to advance bis particular the generation of new theoretic alternatives and the
conception of sociological analysis relied not only on selection among thern." Variation by itself, without
the publication of bis ideas (Burt 1980, 1992) but rnechanisrns of selection and retention, is insufficient
perhaps more importantly on bis developing a network for the developrnent of knowledge. They cited March
analysis program, "Struc:ture," that he continues to (1991) who noted that organizations need to strike a
update and refine and give away free to any who ask. balance between exploration and exploitation, and ar-
Burt understands quite well that if he can influence the gued for an optima! arnount of pluralisrn:
technology, the methodology by which social networks
We ... conclude that d1sc1phnes characterized by a too low as
are analyzed, he is well on his way to exercising influ-
well as too high degree of theoret1cal pluralism will be con-
ence over the conceptual frameworks and ideas that
fronted wnh a stnng of specific problems (Foss and Knudsen
are employed in such analyses as well. 1993, p. 20l.
Nor is this concern with technology limited to quan-
titative sociology. Heritage (1984, p. 233) noted that Among the problerns affecting too-pluralistic disci-
"conversation analysis has developed into a prominent plines are an inability to make good choices arnong
form of ethnomethodological work and has come to cornpeting theories resulting in disciplinary fragrnenta-
exert a significant influence-both methodological tion and a consequent inability to effectively generate
and substantive-on a range of social science disci- and absorb new knowledge.
plines ... its growth and diversification have become Mane and McKinley (l 993, p. 293) have documented
very extensive." Sacks (1984, p. 26), one of the founders the existence of a "uniqueness value" in organization
of the rnethod, was explicit in bis concern with rnaking studies and sorne of its consequences for the discipline:
ethnornethodological rescarch replicable and with de- We suggest that the uniqueness value has contributed most
veloping a technology that could be taught to others: directly to the undes1rabilit) of rephcat10ns and, consequently,
When I started to do research in sociology, 1 f1gured that fewer extcnsions to or refutations of previous research are
sociology could not be an actual science unless 1t was able to published. Yet ... the rapiiJ rate of mnovat1on spawned par-
handle the details of actual events, handle them fonnally, and t1ally by the umqueness value 1s not necessarily strengthening
in the first instance, be informative about them in the direct our understandmg of or knowledge concerning organi-
ways in wh1ch primitive sciences tend to be informative, that zations ... parad1gmatic specialization, reduced integration,
is, that anyone e/se can go and see whether what was said is so and infom1ation overload can occur more easily
(emphasis added).
Sorne rnight say it is a rnatter of taste or style as to
Boden (1994) has an excellent review of the debate how rnuch consensus a field should have, or how such
between organizational perspectives that ernphasize consensus gets produced. What 1 have argued here is
structural constraint and those that ernphasize the role that, at least looking cornparatively and historically,
of human agency and how conversation analysis, both that does not seern to be the case. For very under-
in its rnethods and ideas, can help integrate this false standable reasons, possessing consensus on ap-
dichotorny. But again, the irnportant point 1s that a proaches, ideas, and perhaps rnost irnportantly, rneth-
technology for analysis exists that helps others learn ods, provides advantages in enlisting others to one's
both the substance and rnethod of an approach to theoretical perspective and being productive in the
social analysis and perrnits replication and extension. sense of acquiring journal space, legitimacy, and other
Van Maanen's cornrnent ernphasizes the effect of resources. Although we may value the laissez-faire,
writing on the reader, and particularly, its persuasive let-a-thousand-flowers-bloorn spirit that currently per-
quality. Without denying the importance of persuasion, vades organization studies, we should not delude our-
one must recognize that for writing to be influential, it selves that our freedorn frorn constraint comes without
rnust suggest not only what to do in general terrns but sorne costs, or that our ability to indulge whatever

ÜRGANIZATION ScIENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995 685

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved


JEFFREY PFEFFER Crossroads

particular intellectual tastes or styles we hold dear is Theory: A Critique ofApplications m Political Science, New Haven,
guaranteed to last forever. CT: Yale University Press.
Perhaps most importantly, readers should not spend Hannan, M. T. and N. B. Turna (1979), "Methods for Temporal
too much time or effort simply debating the points of Analysis," in A. Inkeles, J. Coleman, and R. H. Tumer (Eds.),
Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 5, Palo Alto, CA: Annual
my original article. Once again, Edelman (1971, p. 17)
Reviews, 303-328.
Downloaded from informs.org by [131.94.16.10] on 19 November 2015, at 15:39 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.

says it well:
Heritage, J. (1984), Garfinkel and Ethnomethodology, Cambndge,
Adversary role playing serves to bring valued benefits to the England: Polity Press.
adversaries; and the most valued of these have little to do Jensen, M. C. and W. H. Meckling (1976), "Theory of the Firm:
with the pubhcized symbohc goals; rather, they take the form Managerial Behavior, Agency Cost and Ownership Structure,"
of the achievement of an 1denttty which will be cherished and Joumal of Fmancial Economics, 3, 305-360.
defended. Mahoney, J. T. (1993), "Strategic Management and Determmism:
Sustainmg the Conversation," Joumal of Management Studies, 30,
In this instance, the issues of how and under what
173-191.
conditions paradigmatic consensus develops and the
March, J. G. (1991), "Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational
consequences of such consensus can and should be
Learning," Organization Science, 2, 1-19.
empirically studied. This is a debate that would benefit
Mone, M. A. and W McKinley (1993), "The Uniqueness Value and
from having more light and less heat. Its Consequences for Organization Studies," Joumal of Manage-
ment Inqwry, 2, 284-296.
References
Montgomery, C. A., B. Wemerfelt, and S. Balakrishnan (1989),
Atkinson, M. (1984), Our Masters' Voices, London, England: Methuen.
"Strategy Content and the Research Process: A Critique and
Bames, J. A. (1972), Social Networks, Reading, MA: Addison Wesley
Commentary," Strategic Management Joumal, 10, 189-197.
Modular Publications, 26, 1-29.
Ordeshook, P. C (1993), "The Development of Contemporary Politi-
Boden, Deidre (1994), The Business of Talk, Cambridge, England:
cal Theory," m W. A. Barnett, M. J. Hinich, and N. J. Schofield,
Polity Press.
Cambridge, England: Cambridge Umversity Press.
Burt, R. S. (1980), "Models of Network Structure," m A. Inkeles,
N. J. Smelser, and R. H. Turner (Eds.), Annua/ Rev1ew of Parker, R (1993), "Can Econom1sts Save Economics?" American
Sociology, Vol. 6, Palo Alto, CA: Annual Rev1ews, 79-141 Prospect, 13, 148-160.
__ (1992), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competltlon, Pfeffer, J. (1993), "Barners to the Advance of Orgamzat10nal Sc1-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univers1ty Press. ence: Paradigm Development as a Dependent Variable,"
Camerer, C. (1985), "Red1recting Research m Busmess Policy and Academy of Management Review, 18, 599-620.
Strategy," Strategic Management Joumal 6, 1-15. __ (1994), Competitive Advantage Through People, Boston, MA:
Canella, A. A., Jr. and R. L. Paetzold (1994), "Pfeffer's Barriers to Harvard Business School Press.
the Advance of Organizat10nal Science: A Reioinder," Academy Sacks, H. (1984), "Methodological Remarks,"in J. M. Atkinson, and
of Management Review, 19, 331-341. J. C Heritage, Structures of Socia!Actwn: Studies in Conversation
Edelman, M. (1964), The Symbolic Uses of Politics, Urbana, IL: Analys1s, Cambridge, England: Cambridge Umversity Press,
University of Illinois Press. 21-27
__ (1971), Politics as Symbolic Action, Chicago, IL: Markham Salancik, G. R. (1977), "Preface," in B. M. Staw and G. R. Salancik
Foss, N. J. and C. Knudsen (1993), "Pluralism and Scientific Progress (Eds.), New D1rections m Organizatwnal Behauior, Chicago, IL:
in Economics,'' Working Paper, Institute of Industrial Eco- St. Clair Press, ix-xiv.
nom1cs and Strategy, Copenhagen Busmess School, Copen- Van Maanen, J. (1995), "Style as Theory," Organization Science, 6, 1,
hagen, Denmark. 132-143.
Frost, P. (1995), "Crossroads," Organization Sc1ence, 6, 1, 132. Williamson. O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, New York: Free
Green, D. P. and l. Shapiro (1994), Pathologies of Ratwnal Choice Press.

686 ÜRGANIZATION Sc1ENCE/Vol. 6, No. 6, November-December 1995

Copyright© 2001 All Rights Reserved

You might also like