You are on page 1of 4

UNIVERSITY OF RIZAL SYSTEM

Binangonan Campus

GRADUATE STUDIES
ADVANCE MICROECONOMICS
JULIET A. CARAMONTE, DBA Student
Submitted to : DR. V.V. SALENTES

Labor Market
The labor market, also known as the job market, refers to the supply and demand for labor in
which employees provide the supply and employers the demand. It is a major component of
any economy and is intricately tied in with markets for capital, goods and services.

Labor Market, At Macroeconomic and Microeconomic level

Macroeconomic level
Supply and demand are influenced by domestic and international market dynamics, as well as
factors such as immigration, the age of the population and education levels.

Relevant measures include unemployment, productivity, participation rates, total income and


gross domestic product (GDP).

The Labor Market in Macroeconomic Theory 


According to macroeconomic theory, the fact that wage growth lags productivity growth
indicates that supply of labor has outpaced demand. When that happens, there is downward
pressure on wages, as workers compete for a scarce number of jobs and employers have
their pick of the litter. Conversely, if demand outpaces supply, there is upward pressure on
wages, as workers have more bargaining power and are more likely to be able to switch to a
higher paying job, while employers must compete for scarce labor.

Image by Julie Bang © Investopedia 2019


Some factors can influence labor supply and demand. For example, an increase in
immigration to a country can grow the labor supply and potentially depress wages, particularly
if newly arrived workers are willing to accept lower pay. An aging population can deplete the
supply of labor and potentially drive up wages.

These factors don't always have such straightforward consequences, though. A country with
an aging population will see demand for many goods and services decline, while demand
for healthcare increases. Not every worker who loses his job can simply move into healthcare
work, particularly if the jobs in demand are highly skilled and specialized, such as doctors. For
this reason, demand can exceed supply in certain sectors, even if supply exceeds demand in
the labor market as a whole.

Factors influencing supply and demand don't work in isolation, either. If it weren't for
immigration, the U.S. would be a much older, and probably less dynamic society, so while an
influx of unskilled workers might have exerted downward pressure on wages, it likely offset
declines in demand. 

Other factors influencing contemporary labor markets, and the U.S. labor market in particular,
include: the threat of automation as computer programs gain the ability to do more complex
tasks; the effects of globalization as enhanced communication and better transport links allow
work to be moved across borders; the price, quality and availability of education; and a whole
array of policies such as the minimum wage.

The U.S. Labor Market


The macroeconomic view of the labor market can be difficult to capture, but a few data points
can give investors, economists and policymakers an idea of its health. The first
is unemployment. During times of economic stress, the demand for labor lags behind supply,
driving unemployment up. High rates of unemployment exacerbate economic stagnation,
contribute to social upheaval and deprive large numbers of people the opportunity to lead
fulfilling lives.

In the U.S., unemployment was around 4% to 5% before the financial crisis, when large
numbers of businesses failed, many people lost their homes, and demand for goods and
services — and the labor to produce them — plummeted. Unemployment reached 10% in
2009 but declined more or less steadily to 4.9% in January 2016.
Labor productivity is another important gauge of the labor market and broader economic
health, measuring the output produced per hour of labor. Productivity has risen in many
economies, the U.S. included, in recent years due to advancements in technology and other
improvements in efficiency.

In the U.S., however, growth in output per hour has not translated into similar growth in
income per hour. Workers are creating more goods and services per unit of time, but not
earning more compensation. Growth in the employment cost index averaged under 0.7% per
year from 2001-2015, while growth in productivity exceeded 2%.

Microeconomic level,
Individual firms interact with employees, hiring them, firing them and raising or cutting wages
and hours. The relationship between supply and demand influences the hours the employee
works and compensation she receives in wages, salary and benefits.

The Labor Market in Microeconomic Theory


Microeconomic theory analyzes labor supply and demand at the level of the individual firm
and worker. Supply, or the hours an employee is willing to work, initially increases as wage
increases. No workers will work voluntarily for nothing (unpaid interns are, in theory, working
to gain experience and increase their desirability to other employers) and more people are
willing to work for $20 an hour than $5 an hour.

Gains in supply may accelerate as wages increase, since the opportunity cost of not working
additional hours grows. But supply may then decrease at a certain wage level: The difference
between $1,000 an hour and $1050 is hardly noticeable, and the highly-paid worker who's
presented with the option of working an extra hour or spending her money on leisure activities
may well opt for the latter.
Demand at the microeconomic level depends on two factors, marginal cost and marginal
revenue product. If the marginal cost of hiring an additional employee, or having existing
employees work more hours, exceeds the marginal revenue product, it will cut into earnings,
and the firm would theoretically reject that option. If the opposite is true, it makes rational
sense to take on more labor.

Neoclassical microeconomic theories of labor supply and demand have received criticism on
some fronts. Most contentious is the assumption of "rational" choice — maximizing money
while minimizing work — which to critics is not only cynical but not always supported by the
evidence. Homo sapiens, unlike Homo economicus, may have all sorts of motivations for
making specific choices. The existence of some professions in the arts and non-profit sector
undermines the notion of maximizing utility. Defenders of neoclassical theory counter that
their predictions may have little bearing on a given individual, but are useful when taking large
numbers of workers in aggregate.

Thank you..

You might also like