You are on page 1of 29

 

 
 

The Political Economy of  


the FATF & IMF in Pakistan  
during 2019 (Part 1) 
4​th​ January, 2020 

Usman W. Chohan, MBA, PhD 1 2 


 

Discussion Paper 

Discussion Paper Series: ​CASS​ ​Studies in Political Economy 

Abstract: ​ ​This paper presents a series of perspectives on the political economy of 
the FATF and IMF in Pakistan for the calendar year 2019 (Vol. 1). It raises concerns 
about the excess politicization of the financial task force and how this impedes the 
fairness and efficiency of the international financial supervisory system. This then 
draws attention to the endogenous limitations of developing countries in coping with 
exogenous impositions of a political-economic nature. 

This paper was prepared at the Centre for Aerospace and Security Studies (CASS) during 
the calendar year 2019.   

1
​Centre for Aerospace and Security Studies (CASS) 

2
​Critical Blockchain Research Initiative (CBRI) 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

The Political Economy of the  


FATF & IMF in Pakistan during 2019 (Part 1) 

The Maturity of Debts and Governments 3 

Has the FATF failed? 6 

India & the FATF: The Fox in the Henhouse 9 

The Austerity Delusion 13 

Watchdog or Lapdog? 17 

The Disquiet in People’s Lives 21 

References 24 
 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

The Maturity of Debts and 


Governments 
Usman W. Chohan 

The looming fears of an economic recession in Pakistan and a difficult negotiation 


process with the International Monetary Fund are drawing increased public and media 
attention to the debt and deficit position of the country. Judging from recent figures 
and from a wider consensus of estimates, Pakistan’s ability to borrow and to repay are 
coming under increased stress. 

In its annual headlining report ​Fiscal Monitor,​ the IMF has projected that Pakistan’s 
public debt-to-GDP ratio might exceed 84% of gross domestic product (GDP) by 2023, 
which is 12 percentage points higher than the 72% level left by the previous PML-N 
government. It projects a 77% public debt-to-GDP ratio at the end of the current fiscal 
year and 79.1% by the following year. With respect to the fiscal rules that Pakistan has 
set for itself under the Fiscal Responsibility and Debt Limitation Act, Pakistan’s debt 
should not be more than 60% of GDP. 

This has turned into a thorny issue for political wrangling in both parliamentary 
debates and TV talk shows, but this tends to detract from a longer-term perspective 
on Pakistan’s profile of indebtedness. I believe it helps to take a step back and consider 
the debt problem of emerging markets more broadly, before looking at our debt 
repayment schedule in a more dispassionate manner, so as not to confound the 
long-term nature of indebtedness with the short-termism of government tenure. 

Looking at the schedule of Pakistan’s debt, one should observe that a significant 
portion of the debt that is maturing now was incurred as far back as the Musharraf 
years (early 2000s). Pointing the finger at the current government belies the fact that 
borrowings from past liabilities are the chickens that now come to roost, and that 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

borrowings undertaken now will need to be shouldered by public institutions of the 


next generation, up to and even exceeding the next two decades. 

When we speak of dissuading governments from reliance on external borrowing, we 


are really doing so with our future generations in mind; and when we lament our 
current fiscal state, we are in fact acknowledging the lack of remedial action in the 
past. But this time-sensitivity is lost in the political to-and-fro that blurs the lines 
between the long-term nature of sovereign burdens and the short-termism of 
governments that seek to “backload” the costs to subsequent governments rather than 
shoulder the pain in the immediate term. 

To put it another way, the problem is more broadly one of different time horizons 
(maturities) of political institutions versus government liabilities. Sovereign 
borrowings occur on 10-year or 20-year horizons, while the governments over the 
past 40 years would have considered themselves lucky to even approach the end of a 
full five-year term. Time inconsistency leads to problems of expediency in shoring up 
the short-term balance sheet rather than in biting the bitter pill of long-term 
structural reform. 

As such, governments (around the world, not just in Pakistan) tend to prefer “kicking 
the can” down the road, until there are no more cans left to kick. The ballooning of 
emerging market debts is in part a reflection of the phenomenon identified above. 

It is not the specific number that matters, but rather the subjacent policy credibility 
that has remained wanting regardless of the government in power. That credibility 
deficit is in fact the greatest deficit Pakistan faces – and one that is much more searing 
than the current account deficit that has perennially characterized our economic 
situation. 

This is in part a structural problem of producing less of what the world needs than 
purchasing more of what the world offers, but it is also attributable to the institutional 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

tensions that excess politicization in the past has wrought upon the manner in which 
business is conducted in the country. 

As an example, various governments have put tacit if not overt pressure on the 
independence of central banks, and this has left a bitter legacy on the nation’s 
monetary and fiscal discipline. Similarly, the odious nature of at least a portion of 
borrowings incurred in the name of the country has meant that little of what has been 
taken has been channeled towards the appropriate objectives. 

Prudent debt management is an essential component in macroeconomic stability and 


economic growth. When a country’s economy is growing at 3%, as ours is now, but its 
population is also growing at 3%, then per capita income growth is zero. What the 
current government will have to borrow to bridge the balance sheet gap shall mature 
years from now, and the burden it is facing is the product of the choices of earlier 
regimes which are now coming due. 

The key word in both debt management and governance, in my judgment, is ​maturity.​  
Maturity in governance requires a long-term approach that balances the expediencies 
of the present with the challenges of the future. Maturity in debt management means 
that short-term financing needs must consider the time-inconsistency of taking from 
the savings of future generations to fuel consumption in the present. In either case, 
what the country requires is a longer-term orientation that emphasizes above all 
greater “maturity.” 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

Has the FATF failed? 


 

The Financial Action Task Force (FATF) is an inter-ministerial body that aims to 
curtail international money laundering and terrorist financing by setting standards for 
national financial architectures. It is a voluntary body comprising 40-odd countries, 
with affiliate regional groups including the Asia-Pacific Group (APG), which Pakistan 
joined as a Senior Associate (but not full) Member. 

Created in 1989, the FATF was a prescient idea in its recognition that the illegal flow of 
money around the world would create havoc in an increasingly interconnected world, 
particularly as the Cold War was ending and former Warsaw Pact countries would face 
challenges (organized crime, money laundering, black money) of integration into the 
global financial system. Over the years, the scope of the FATF has grown, from 
anti-money laundering to terrorist financing, and from 30 standards two decades ago 
to “40+9” today. 

Given the lapse of thirty years, we can fast forward to today and examine its current 
initiatives. Above all, the FATF poses a threat to move Pakistan, already on its ‘grey list’ 
of countries, towards full blacklisting. This would have significant impacts for the 
Pakistani economy in terms of on the banking system, on the flow of remittances, on 
philanthropic organizations, on individual accounts, on the flow of foreign investment, 
and on our negotiations with international organizations such as the IMF. 

As such, the FATF has a loaded gun pointed at the entire Pakistani financial 
architecture under two violent premises: first, that economic sanctions against an 
entire country can compel it to fix a complex and amorphous financial architecture 
are short quarterly deadlines; second, that the entire Pakistani economy must assume 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

collective guilt for a triflingly small group of people or organizations that ​might​ pose “a 
significant threat to the global financial system.” 

This provides us with the right occasion to ask whether the FATF really is doing the 
job it was intended to do. Is it really curtailing “significant threat to the global financial 
system”? Has money laundering or terrorist financing gone down in the past 30 years 
that the FATF has been around? Has the amount of black money slushing around the 
world been controlled or reduced? 

The answer is that, by any indication, the amount of black money floating around the 
global shadow economy has exploded, both in absolute terms, as well as relative to the 
total global money, in the past 30 years. Economists are reticent to provide exact 
estimates, given the inherently shadowy nature of black money, but the scale of the 
problem has expanded in to the ​trillions​ of dollars. The Panama Papers, the Paradise 
Papers, and litany of other exposés have begun to paint a picture of a world that the 
FATF, in misdirecting its violence towards Pakistan, seems largely oblivious to.   

But whereas the FATF has failed on that account, the real question is why the FATF has 
fallen so short of its stipulated objectives. Evidently, the FATF has been looking in all 
the wrong places. Instead of focusing its fire on countries such as Iran and Myanmar, 
if the FATF truly cared about international money laundering and dark money, it 
would most certainly be waging a war against the Cayman Islands, the Bahamas, 
Vanuatu, Guernsey, Gibraltar, the British Virgin Islands, and Delaware. Indeed, the 
greatest centers of non-transparent financial gimmickry and suspect acts are not in 
Third World nations. They are in fact right at the heart of Western capitalism: in 
locations such as London, New York, Delaware, and Frankfurt. 

This can be illustrated in countless ways, but a very recent example of Deutsche Bank, 
the largest financial institution in the largest European country, is particularly 
illuminating. It has been recently revealed that between 2011 and 2014, Deutsche Bank 
had laundered more than 175 million euros (more than 28 billion rupees at the current 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

exchange rate) for Russian organized crime syndicates. Internally labelled the 
“Russian Laundromat” scheme, the prestigious German bank was engaged in precisely 
the sorts of activities which the clueless FATF, based not very far away in Paris, was 
meant to stop. But instead of the extremely politicized FATF, it was in fact a proactive 
consortium of journalists – civil society at its best – that forced these revelations into 
the public and compelled Deutsche Bank to admit to its fraudulent money laundering 
practices. 

So while dirty money is flowing through the swankiest Western capitals, countries 
such as Pakistan are being forced into impossible deadlines to transform their 
financial systems at the risk of externally-imposed sanctions. A parallel can be drawn 
between the FATF and the Western “human rights lobby” which shrills down to 
developing countries how they should behave while turning a blind eye to serious 
infractions in their own territories, or how their own industries (e.g. Western weapons 
and arms industries) boil the pot of turmoil in the first place. The FATF similarly asks 
countries such as Pakistan to “do more” without accepting due culpability of the OECD 
countries which not only tolerate but in fact thrive on an international shadow 
banking system. 

Instead of lambasting traditional bête-noires including Iran, North Korea, Myanmar, 


and now possibly Pakistan, perhaps the FATF should actually focus on the roots of the 
problem of black money in the world. When that happens, the tremendous failures of 
the now irredeemably politicized FATF will point to fact that the worst culprits in the 
world’s shadow economy don’t wear long black beards and black turbans, but swanky 
black ties and striped black suits. 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

India & the FATF: The Fox in the 


Henhouse
Pakistan has been in the crosshairs of the Financial Action Task Force (FATF), which 
put the country on its ‘grey list’ and now threatens it with outright blacklisting. The 
decision to proceed with blacklisting will depend on whether Pakistan is ‘doing 
enough’ to restructure its financial architecture to the FATF’s satisfaction. As such, it 
is crucial that the FATF’s assessment be nonpartisan, dispassionate, and nonpolitical. 
At the same time, those who are chairing the FATF must be able to demonstrate that 
they shall neither abuse the FATF’s mandate for their narrow interests, nor weaponize 
it against any member country. 

In that context, it has been a cause of alarm in Pakistan, and a disgrace for the FATF, 
that India has vied for co-chairmanship of the Asia-Pacific Group (APG), which is the 
regional mirror body of the FATF. The underlying concern is that India’s subversion of 
the FATF will compromise the integrity and impartiality of the body by distorting its 
assessments. This would effectively turn the APG and FATF it into instruments of 
economic violence in Pakistan, since blacklisting could have worrisome effects on 
Pakistan’s banking system, on its flow of remittances, on its philanthropic 
organizations, on the flow of foreign investment, and on the country’s negotiations 
with international organizations such as the IMF. 

There are two important arguments that must be advanced in rejecting India’s 
legitimacy as co-chair of the APG. The first argument is about the massive conflict of 
interest that it would create in international financial oversight if the venal Indian fox 
watches the henhouse; while the second argument regards India’s own horrific record 
of black money. India is by any measure one of the worst possible candidates for the 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331



 

job, both in terms of the scale of India’s black money problem, as well as the failures of 
the solutions it has tried (especially demonetization). 

On the first point, it is not lost on Pakistani observers that putting India as 
co-chairman of the APG would create a massive conflict of interest in the task force, 
given the animosity that the Indian government has fomented through a litany of 
aggression. At a time when India is instigating a standoff with Pakistan, is the world 
really to think that India should co-chair financial oversight of Pakistan? India’s 
chairmanship should be seen in light of a hybrid war, in usurping control of a financial 
standard-setter towards a mercenary agenda. 

A recent occurrence with the Standing Committee on the Interior (SSC-I) puts the 
already dubious partisanship of the FATF in perspective. On March 12​th​ 2019, the SSC-I 
panel slammed the FATF for discriminating against Pakistan and according 
preferential treatment to India by ignoring substantial evidence about New Delhi’s 
involvement in terror financing. The SSC-I, chaired by Senator Rehman Malik, 
regretted that India “continued enjoying an undeclared immunity as no action was 
being taken against it despite all evidence of terror financing.” 

Senator Malik explained that he had written a letter to FATF President Marshall 
Billingslea on Feb 14​th​, seeking action against Indian Prime Minister Narendra Modi for 
protecting international fugitives involved in the biggest-ever credit fraud and money 
laundering. He said that he had sent the letter with all the evidence proving that Prime 
Minister Modi was involved in money laundering and terror financing as he was 
supporting the RSS (Rashtriya Swayamsevak Sangh) — “the biggest terrorist 
organization.” 

However, the weak response of Mr. Billingslea was that the FATF “was not an 
investigative or prosecutorial body,” a point which Senator Malik contested, since if 
the FATF could not open a case against PM Modi for terror financing and money 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


10 
 

laundering, “then how was taking up a case against Pakistan and putting it on the ‘grey 
list’”? 

Senator Malik disclosed that he had written another letter to the FATF president, 
explaining how it was legal to take stern action against PM Modi. In his letter to the 
FATF president, Senator Malik reminded him that a formal inquiry against Pakistan 
was initiated based on a complaint from the United States alleging Pakistan’s 
involvement in terror funding and money laundering, and consequently the FATF 
placed Pakistan on the ‘grey list’. “Therefore, the stance taken by the FATF vis-à-vis 
my complaint against Indian Prime Minister Narendra Modi was not based on facts 
and practice of the FATF,” the Senator appropriately noted. The Pakistani public must 
recognize the double-standards in the FATF’s ploy. 

On the second line of argument, the fact that India should be using the FATF is 
incredible given its own horrific record of dark money and shadowy transactions. 
According to the India Association of Chartered Certified Accountants (ACCA), India’s 
shadow economy amounts to 17.22% of GDP, which would equate to ​$516 billion 
dollars.[1] ​In other words, India’s shadow economy alone is larger than the entire 
economy of the UAE, Malaysia, or Denmark. Are we really to think that such a country 
is capable of overseeing black money elsewhere? 

Given that India has massive black money problem, we might consider the solutions 
they have tried to implement. In that regard, the BJP government’s shoddy and 
sweeping attempts to supposedly counter the black economy have included a 
demonetization campaign, which a consensus of economists and the Reserve Bank of 
India alike have deemed an abject failure, not just in hurting economic growth and 
decimating more than 1.5 million jobs, but also in growing the number of illicit 
transactions (particularly counterfeit currency to replace the demonetization) by an 
alarming 480%.[2] With so much dark money slushing around, including for illicit 
activities and terrorist initiatives, the idea of India being a co-chair is absurd. 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


11 
 

Both of these lines of argument, of hijacking the APG for political interests, or of 
failing to curb their own black economy, are necessary to understand the dilemma 
that Pakistan’s financial architecture faces. Pakistan must do its utmost to prevent 
Indian subversion of the APG and the FATF, because given the consequences that 
blacklisting entails, it may be very unpleasant to sit with the venal Indian fox guarding 
our financial henhouse. 

[1]​ Indian Express (2017). “Indian ‘shadow economy’ to shrink to 13.6 per cent of GDP by 

2025: ACCA” 
https://indianexpress.com/article/business/economy/indian-shadow-economy-to-shr
ink-to-13-6-per-cent-of-gdp-by-2025-acca-4731993/ 

[2]​ The Economic Times (2018). “Demonetisation led to highest fake currency, 

suspicious transactions: Report” 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


12 
 

The Austerity Delusion 


The recently announced annual budget is one that would clearly be described as 
austerity-focused, with a view to satisfying the IMF board’s whims so that an already 
negotiated Extended Fund Facility might be approved and lines of credit to Pakistan 
might resume. The budget comprises various belt-tightening measures on public 
expenditures, but there are also targets for raising revenues both through expanding 
the width of the tax base and also through a disproportionate squeeze on law-abiding 
tax filers through tougher tax rates. 

The austerity mindset with which the budgetary measures have been announced looks 
very good at first glance. After all, in a society where 99% of the population does not 
contribute to the fiscal base, how can the economy run except through unsustainable 
kashkol ​borrowing? This is the problem that, the IMF has correctly surmised, there is 
no room for in the 21​st​ century. The Pakistani masses, as well as the elites now being 
brought to account by NAB, must get their collective act together. If they cannot do so 
voluntarily, then a tough fiscal regime must be imposed from-on-high by the IMF. 

But the dismal context in which the austerity-budget was presented leaves much for 
the public to worry, particularly for those 20 lakh who have done their fiscal duty to 
the nation. Above all, it is useful to take a step back and ask: What is austerity? And is 
austerity really the way to fix an economy? 

What the IMF is doing to Pakistan, the EU has already done to Greece, and from that 
episode many academics and policy-makers have drawn important lessons which are 
applicable to Pakistan today. The overriding consensus in the academic (if not in the 
policy) circles now is that austerity for a macroeconomy is fundamentally illogical. 
Belt-tightening works for households and for individuals, but for an economy overall, 
belt-tightening means that I will get fewer haircuts, and so the barber has less to pay 
the baker, who has less to pay the mechanic, and so forth. Put another way, the ripples 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


13 
 

of economic stagnation emanate through the macroeconomy when all agents hold 
back their consumption and slow the velocity of money circulation. 

The devastation in Greece illustrates this vividly. From a society whose members three 
decades ago nearly all owned their own homes, had virtually no debt, and led 
autonomous economic lives, two problems arose. First, Greece’s elite began to 
binge-borrow to fund lavish lifestyles at the exchequer’s expense (like ours); and 
second, only 4 percent of the public paid any taxes (that is sadly still much better than 
in Pakistan). So a similar situation to what Pakistan has begun to face in fact emerged 
earlier in Greece, and culminated in an economic collapse by 2010-2011, after which 
the EU imposed austerity measures across society so that workers, pensioners, civil 
servants, private businesses, and civil society overall fell into a hellish morass from 
which they have yet to recover. 

Today, 25 percent of the working population of Greece does not have a job, while 
household incomes have shrunk by nearly one-third, and one in every three 
businesses has gone bankrupt. Horrifyingly for an OECD developed country, about 14 
percent of Greece's children remain malnourished, and one-quarter of the nation’s 
children live in poverty. Starvation has been a frighteningly regular occurrence (9 
percent of children lack a daily, protein-based meal), with people rummaging through 
the rubbish bins of local supermarkets looking for scraps to bring home to the family. 

Teachers, in fact, have reported cases in which students have turned up at school 
eating nothing more than rice and stale rusks for months at a time. The teachers 
themselves haven’t received their proper (full) salaries in years. Pensions have been 
cut 13 times since 2009, and this has left many families with dramatically less income, 
deprived of even the bare essentials in many cases. 

Because of this, the most vibrant Nazi-party in Europe is in fact in Greece; a violent 
political movement known as the Golden Dawn. For the more than 50,000 Pakistanis, 
not to mention other visible minorities living in Greece, the Golden Dawn has been a 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


14 
 

vicious nightmare with regular attacks against migrants, a convenient scapegoat for 
the desperate Greeks unable to confront the actual perpetrators of their tyranny who 
reside in Brussels and Frankfurt. 

In the case of the IMF, the most seething irony is that its own reports since 2016 have 
come to frame austerity as the wrong approach to economic reforms, and the IMF 
itself now believes that it massively understated the damage that spending cuts inflict 
on a weak economy. As an IMF report by economists Ostry, Loungani and Furceri 
admits in economist-speak, “episodes of fiscal consolidation have been followed, on 
average, by drops rather than by expansions in output. On average, a consolidation of 
1% of GDP increases the long-term unemployment rate by 0.6 percentage points.” 

Countries that have refused externally-imposed austerity have in fact recovered faster 
after crises. Portugal and Ireland are clear examples of this, and their economies 
bounced back by deliberately refusing to tow the austerity line, in stark contrast to 
Greece. The United States itself has used massive counter-cyclical stimuli in times of 
crisis: after 9/11, Bush encouraged Americans to raise consumer spending to help civic 
morale; and Obama authorized nearly $1 trillion dollars through the Troubled Asset 
Relief Program (TARP) to grapple with the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. During that 
period, Australia gave AUD$1500 to each household to spend immediately, and other 
countries such as Japan also adopted measures that would be considered the opposite 
of any austerity diktat. 

However, it has been forcefully argued that Pakistan had no choice but to go to the 
IMF. Assuming that is correct, and recognizing the limitations posed by a public of 19+ 
crores that refuses to shoulder its fiscal responsibility to the country, then Pakistan 
must adeptly manage the impositions of austerity: just getting enough through for the 
IMF board to sign-off on the bailout, and just going easy enough on the people that the 
recent price hikes, tax jumps, and currency devaluation do not further compress at 
least the 20 lakh that do contribute fiscally to society. This narrow band of society is 
facing the disproportionate brunt of taxation measures, which is a double-punishment 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


15 
 

and an incentive that runs counter to the government’s asset-amnesty schemes, since 
it nudges non-filers to remain outside the fiscal net for fear of ever-greater squeezes.  

The strong-arming by the IMF ultimately seeks to end the black-economy lifestyle that 
an informal and illiterate mass has settled into, and for that they deserve credit. But 
the actual notion of austerity must be more critically examined, as it will lay a 
disproportionate burden on those who are not culpable (tax filers), while lowering the 
general growth trajectory of the country. In sum, given that : (1) the IMF itself does not 
buy into this politicized argument of austerity, (2) the IMF constitutes one of the main 
pillars for economic violence against developing countries, and (3) economies that 
have refused to allow austerity imposition have done much better; we should be wary 
of sticking to an austerity-budgeting culture for too long.   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


16 
 

Watchdog or Lapdog? 
Usman W. Chohan 

The FATF and its mirror-body APG have begun to tighten the noose around Pakistan, 
and their most recently revealed report card (The Mutual Evaluation Report, MER), 
presents a mixed opinion about the steps Pakistan has taken since its grey-listing last 
year. In its own words, “competent authorities have varying levels of understanding of 
the country’s money-laundering and terror-financing risks, and the private sector has 
a mixed understanding of risks.” 

On one hand, it finds that important steps have been taken, and many 
recommendations have at least been partially fulfilled. But on the other hand, it notes 
that much still needs to be done, and a major impediment is that key institutions do 
not comprehend either the gravity of the situation or nuances around the key 
concepts. In other words, according to the APG, many of Pakistan’s institutions seem 
unfit or inept, given the magnitude of challenge. 

Much of the mutual evaluation report is based on rich datasets displaying how 
economic activity is undertaken in the country. If anything, the 228-page MER serves 
as a useful guide to gleaning just how complex economic life is in the country, and how 
daunting the task of regularizing it has become. 

That said, much recent exploration, including my own [1], highlights the glaring 
shortcomings of the FATF as a self-styled watchdog for international economies. One 
of the most pertinent arguments (among several others) against the FATF’s practices is 
just how much they have deviated from the body’s original goals at its inception in 
1989. A recent example, known informally as the “Russian Laundromat,” illustrates this 
perfectly. 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


17 
 

To start, it should be noted that the FATF was originally conceived in anticipation of a 
massive outflow of wealth from the dissolution of the USSR. The former Soviet Union 
held all material assets with the state as a public trust, thereby abolishing private 
ownership of the means of production. 

Following the chaos of dissolution, the fear both within and beyond the former USSR’s 
borders was that self-styled Mafioso oligarchs would use physical violence and 
disarray to siphon funds formerly held in the public trust to personal accounts in 
offshore jurisdictions. 

The purpose of the FATF was largely confined to monitoring the flows of funds from 
that side of the fizzling Iron Curtain during a period of upheaval. It was only after 9/11 
that the guns became squarely-pointed at Muslim countries, since it was ever so 
convenient for the powers-that-be to conflate the term “Muslim” with “terrorist” 
exclusively; and Muslims worldwide have been living with the consequences ever 
since. 

However, in serving the political interests of targeting specific (mostly Muslim) 


countries with grey and black lists instead of keeping a focus on the transfer of black 
money in societies in upheaval, the FATF became more of a political lapdog and less of 
a serious watchdog. The FATF and its mirror-bodies thus lost the plot with regards to 
the oligarchs who nabbed up considerable wealth in the tumult of economic transition 
in the former USSR republics. 

As a result, not only have Mafiosos managed to move considerable amounts of wealth 
out of Russia and her sister republics, but also that Western banks with their 
finely-suited and (at best) amoral “financial experts” have acted as henchmen and 
abettors to that process. 

One of the most notorious incidents is the “Russian Laundromat” scheme, which 
involved the mass-scale laundering of money from Russia, Moldova, and several other 
countries, to the tune of between $20-80 ​billion​ dollars. It is in fact still not clear just 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


18 
 

how much dirty money was moved out through the Laundromat scheme, but the 
numbers dwarf anything remotely possible in the smaller and largely de-dollarized 
economy such as Pakistan’s. 

What is clear, however, is that the swanky Western banks had their corrupt hands 
deeply sullied by deliberate involvement in this syndicate. The most prestigious bank 
within the most prestigious financial center on the European mainland, the Deutsche 
Bank for Frankfurt, Germany had its pockets 175 ​million​ Euros deep in the Laundromat 
scheme. This is in addition to the Danske Bank scandal in which Deutsche Bank was 
again implicated, which has worth more than 160 ​billion ​Euros, mostly of Russian 
provenance. 

Deutsche was not alone; Citibank, HSBC, Danske, and countless other banks from 
ostensibly responsible financial jurisdictions were awash with dirty money which they 
appear to have been more than happy to deal in over a prolonged harvest of black 
money. And where was the FATF in all of this? Nowhere in sight. 

Indeed it was not the FATF which uncovered any of these issues, since it was too busy 
trying to financially disembowel smaller economies such as Pakistan’s. Rather, it was 
civil society organizations, such as the journalists at the Organized Crime and 
Corruption Reporting Project (OCCRP), which exposed the magnitude of the Russian 
Laundomat money-laundering scheme. 

The FATF totally missed the mark on this incident, a fact that is disappointing given 
that this was its singular mission before its politicization by countries such as the US 
and India began. In the FATF’s parlance, a “mutual evaluation” of the FATF would be 
totally dismal for failing to stem rampant money-laundering and terrorist-financing 
from the specific jurisdictions it was designed to monitor. 

It is worth noting that the APG’s most recent MER of Pakistan goes as far as to say, on 
its very first page, that the APG and the FATF are “non-political bodies.” This is a 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


19 
 

notion they have begun to stress in recent publications, given that a more critical view 
of these watchdogs is now becoming not just more evident, but also necessary. 

The FATF and its mirror-bodies continue to go around bashing smaller economies 
willy-nilly, while missing out on the elephant in the room which is capitalism’s bane of 
tax havens stashing ill-gotten wealth from the developing world, not least from former 
USSR republics, much to the glee in the crooked smiles of so-called “responsible” 
Western jurisdictions. 

It is high time countries such as Pakistan “mutually evaluate” the FATF itself, and 
emphasize that it is in fact the FATF that needs to “do more.” This, naturally, will 
involve the FATF acting as more of a watchdog and less of a lapdog. 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


20 
 

The Disquiet in People’s Lives 


Usman W. Chohan 

Here is what the reporters are saying: the people have come on to the streets, 
expressing their rage through marching, chanting, rioting, confronting the police, 
demanding an end to the current government’s corruption, and above all, and end to 
the austerity policies imposed by the IMF. The reporters say that “the city” has become 
a ground-zero for public agitation, and unanimous cries for an end to the tyranny of 
the IMF. 

Which city are the reporters referring to: Santiago, Chile? Beirut, Lebanon? Quito, 
Ecuador? Port-au-Prince, Haiti? Algiers, Algeria? Baghdad, Iraq? Tegucigalpa, 
Honduras? 

They are in fact referring to ​all of them​. 

A tide of discontent has now swept cities across the developing world, with [mostly 
young] people taking to the streets and mobilizing against the harsh realities of 
subjugation through economic instruments and policies that are either directly 
imposed or abetted by IMF. 

The ​wretched of the earth​, as the philosopher Fanon called them, today articulate their 
contempt for brutal austerity policies though civil disobedience. Security forces are 
struggling to dismount the public pressure, and many leaders are finding their careers 
on the line. 

We are seeing the results of the public agitation in many ways. In Ecuador, the 
government has rescinded the austerity bill that the government had promulgated 
under the IMF’s auspices. In Chile, the President has fired his entire cabinet and 
promised all sorts of changes, but the million people on Santiago’s street want his 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


21 
 

head and nothing less. In Lebanon, every major street is blockaded and Beirut is in 
gridlock until the President and PM both resign. 

The triggers, as usual, were trivial measures that were part of an austerity program. A 
small metro ticket hike in Chile, a tobacco and “Whatsapp tax” proposal in Lebanon, 
and some of other tax hike or public spending cut elsewhere. Yet the conflagrations 
grow wider and are being observed in great similitude around the world. 

It is in fact a “humanitarian crisis” that the IMF wreaks upon the wretched of the 
earth, and that term is not being used lightly. The current head of the United Nations, 
Antonio Guterres, actually expressed his vocal opposition to the IMF’s policies at the 
fund’s most recent meeting, reproaching the IMF for the miseries that its policies have 
wrought on the poor on the world. 

Guteres urged world leaders “to listen to the real problems of real people,” and later 
told reporters that “disquiet in peoples’ lives” has sparked demonstrations around the 
world from the Middle East to Europe, Africa, Asia, Latin America and the Caribbean. 

In other words, the man who usually speaks out for war crimes and breaches of the 
Geneva Convention articulated his concern about what the IMF does. In a sense, that is 
a very accurate message to send to the IMF. Their policies engender “structural 
violence” which tyrannizes the disenfranchised without firing a shot. 

“Even where people are not protesting, they are hurting and want to be heard,” he told 
the IMF. This is pertinent for us to observe in the international uprising, because the 
very same policies have been imposed on Pakistan. The IMF swooped in early this year 
to throw down the gauntlet, for a paltry sum of $6 billion dollars, in exchange for 
heavy structural changes that are very unlikely to be addressed in so short a span. 

There is indeed a concentration of protesting elements in the capital at this time, but a 
careful negotiation process and active engagement has meant that, for the moment, 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


22 
 

Pakistan looks nothing like other countries that otherwise seem economically much 
better off but are caught up in whirlwinds of agitation. 

In the meantime, inflation is rising, job losses mounting, and a growing number of 
people (albeit proportionately still small, thankfully) are reporting an overall 
dissatisfaction with life. This is the disquiet that Guterres has warned the IMF of as a 
generalizable experience of the third world. 

Indeed, there is too large a disquiet pervades people’s lives, and the sorts of spending 
cuts and austerity drives the IMF exacts from poor countries, often for paltry sum of 
lending in return, exemplifies the problems that not just our country, but the world 
must contend with. 

   

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


23 
 

References  
1. Ahamed, L. (2014). ​Money and Tough Love: On Tour with the IMF L ​ ondon: Visual 
Editions. 
2. Ahmed, J., & Chohan, U. W. (2019, March 30). The Faulty Logic of the FATF (Part 
1).​ The Daily Times​. 
3. Alford, J., & O’Flynn, J. (2009). Making Sense of Public Value: Concepts, 
Critiques and Emergent Meanings. ​International Journal of Public 
Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 171-191. 
4. Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2005). IMF programs: Who is chosen and what are the 
effects?. ​Journal of Monetary Economics, 52​(7), 1245-1269. 
5. Beck Jorgensen, T., & Vrangbaek, K. (2011). Value Dynamics: Towards a 
Framework for Analyzing Public Value Changes. ​International Journal of Public 
Administration, 34(​ 8), 486-496. 
6. Becker, J. (2017). In the Yugoslav mirror: The EU disintegration crisis. 
Globalizations, 14​(6), 840-850. 
7. Benington, J. (2009). Creating the Public In Order To Create Public Value? 
International Journal of Public Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 232-249. 
8. Benington, J., & Moore, M. (2010). ​Public Value: Theory and Practice​. Basingstoke, 
UK: Palgrave MacMillan. 
9. Benington, J., & Turbitt, I. (2007). Policing the Drumcree Demonstrations in 
Northern Ireland: Testing Leadership Theory in Practice. ​Leadership, 3(​ 4), 
371-395. 
10. Blustein, P. (2003). ​The Chastening: Inside the crisis that rocked the global financial 
system and humbled the IMF. .​ Washington, DC: PublicAffairs. 
11. Blustein, P. (2006). ​And the Money Kept Rolling In (and Out) Wall Street, the IMF, 
and the Bankrupting of Argentina. .​ Washington, DC: Public Affairs. 
12. Chohan, U.W. (2016) The Panama Papers and Tax Morality. 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2759418 
13. Chohan, U.W. (2017f). The Decentralized Autonomous Organization and 
Governance Issues. 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3082055  
14. Chohan, U.W. (2017g). The Double Spending Problem and Cryptocurrencies.   
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3090174 
15. Chohan, U.W. (2017h). “Charters of Budget Honesty”. In Farazmand, A. (ed.). 
Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, and Governance. 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


24 
 

16. Chohan, U.W. (2017h). “Pension Fund Regulation and Governance”. In 
Farazmand, A. (ed.). Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, 
and Governance.   
17. Chohan, U.W. (2017i). “Budget Reform and Political Reform”. In Farazmand, A. 
(ed.). ​Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, and Governance. 
18. Chohan, U.W. (2017j). “Public Value: Bureaucrats vs Politicians”. In Farazmand, 
A. (ed.). ​Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, and 
Governance. 
19. Chohan, U. W. (2017k). Universal Basic Income: A Review. 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3013634 
20. Chohan, U.W. (2017l). Independent Budget Offices and the 
Politics–Administration Dichotomy. ​International Journal of Public 
Administration. 4​ 1 (12), 1009-1017 
21. Chohan, U.W. (2017m). What is a Charter of Budget Honesty? The Case of 
Australia. ​Canadian Parliamentary Review. 4​ 0(1), 11-15. 
22. Chohan, U.W. (2017n). Qu’est-ce qu’une charte d'honnêteté budgetaire? Le cas 
d’Australie. ​Revue Parlementaire Canadienne. ​40(1), 11-15. 
23. Chohan, U.W. (2017o). The Presidentialisation Thesis and Parliamentary Budget 
Offices. ​Parliamentary Affairs. ​70(2), 361-376. 
24. Chohan, U.W. (2017p). “Public Value as Rhetoric: A Budgeting Approach.” 
International Journal of Public Administration. 4​ 1 (15), 1217-1227. 
25. Chohan, U. W. (2018a). What is One Belt One Road? A Surplus Recycling 
Mechanism Approach. In Chaise, J. and Gorski, J. (eds.). The Belt and Road 
Initiative . Brill Nihjoff: Netherlands. 
26. Chohan, U. W. (2018b). The Political Economy of OBOR and the Global Economic 
Center of Gravity. In Chaise, J. and Gorski, J. (eds.). The Belt and Road Initiative . 
Brill Nihjoff: Netherlands. 
27. Chohan, U.W. (2018c). The Roles of Independent Legislative Fiscal Institutions: A 
Multidisciplinary Analysis. UNSW, Canberra, Australia.  
28. Chohan, U.W. (2019a). Public Value and Budgeting: International Perspectives: 
Routledge. 
29. Chohan, U.W. (2019b). Book Review Synthesis: Mobilizing Insights from Three 
Books. SAGE Publications. 
30. Chohan, U.W. (2019c). Documentary Research: Positing Innovations in a 
National Budgeting Process. SAGE Publications. 
31. Chohan, U.W. (2019d). Comparative Case Studies: Contrasting Two Budget 
Institutions. SAGE Publications Ltd 
32. Chohan, U.W. (2019e). A Green New Deal: Discursive Review and Appraisal. 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3347494 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


25 
 

33. Chohan, U.W. (2019f). Initial Coin Offerings (ICOs): Risks, Regulation, and 
Accountability. ​Cryptocurrencies and Mechanisms of Exchange. S ​ pringer. 
34. Chohan, U.W. (2019g). Are Cryptocurrencies Truly Trustless? ​Cryptocurrencies 
and Mechanisms of Exchange. ​Springer. 
35. Chohan, U.W. (2019h). Are Stable Coins Stable? 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3326823 
36. Chohan, U.W. (2019m). The Limits to Blockchain? Scaling vs. Decentralization. 
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3338560 
37. Chohan, U.W. (2019r). The FATF in the Global Financial Architecture: Challenges 
and Implications. CASS Working Papers on Economics & National Affairs, 
EC001UC (2019). ​https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3362167 
38. Chohan, U.W, and Jacobs, K. (2017a). Public Value in Politics: A Legislative 
Budget Office Approach. ​International Journal of Public Administration​. 40 (12), 
1063-1073. 
39. Chohan, U.W, and Jacobs, K. (2017b). Public value as rhetoric: a budgeting 
approach. ​International Journal of Public Administration. 4​ 1 (15), 1217-1227 
40. Decourt, R.F.; Chohan, U.W.; Perugini, M.L. (2017). “Bitcoin returns and the 
Monday Effect.” ​Conference Proceedings of the 14th Convibra: Administração 
(Brazil).​ November. 
http://www.convibra.com.br/upload/paper/2017/33/2017_33_14675.pdf 
41. Constable, S., Passmore, E., & Coats, D. (2008). ​Public Value and Local 
Accountability in the NHS. .​ Retrieved from London: 
42. Danaher, K. (2011). ​10 Reasons to Abolish the IMF & World Bank.​ London: Seven 
Stories Press. 
43. Douglas, S., & Meijer, A. (2016). Transparency and Public Value: Analyzing the 
Transparency Practices and Value Creation of Public Utilities. ​International 
Journal of Public Administration, 39​(12), 940-951. 
44. Dresner, D. (2012). The irony of global economic governance: The system 
worked. . ​Tufts University Papers: Fletcher School of Law & Diplomacy. 
45. Fritz-Krockow, B., & Ramlogan, P. (2007). ​International Monetary Fund 
Handbook: functions, policies, and operations.​ Washington, DC: IMF. 
46. Künneth, W., & Beyerhaus, P. (1975). ​Reich Gottes oder Weltgemeinschaft: Die 
Berliner Ökumene-Erklärung zur utopischen Vision des Weltkirchenrates.​ Berlin: 
Bad Liebenzell: Verlag der Liebenzeller Mission. 
47. Lee, S. (2002). The international monetary fund. ​New Political Economy, 7(​ 2), 
283-298. 
48. Lowndes, V., Pratchett, L., & Stoker, G. (2006). Local Political Participation: The 
Impact of Rules-in-use. ​Public Administration, 84(​ 3), 539-561. 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


26 
 

49. Margalit, Y. (2012). Lost in globalization: International economic integration and 


the sources of popular discontent. ​International Studies Quarterly, 56(​ 3), 
484-500. 
50. Meynhardt, T. (2009). Public Value Inside: What is Public Value Creation? 
International Journal of Public Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 192-219. 
51. Momani, B. (2007). IMF staff: Missing link in fund reform proposals. ​The Review 
of International Organizations, 2(​ 1), 39-57. 
52. Moore, M. (1994). Public Value as the Focus of Strategy. ​Australian Journal of 
Public Administration, 53(​ 3), 296-303. 
53. Moore, M. (1995). ​Creating Public Value: Strategic Management in Government.​  
Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 
54. Moore, M. (2003). ​The Public Value Scorecard. A Rejoinder and an Alternative to 
“Strategic Performance Measurement and Management in Non-Profit 
Organizations” by Robert Kaplan, .​ Retrieved from 
55. Moore, M. (2014). Public value accounting: Establishing the philosophical basis. 
Public Administration Review, 74​, 465-477. 
56. Moore, M., & Donahue, J. (2012). ​Ports in a Storm: Public Management in a 
Turbulent World​. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. 
57. Moore, M., & Khagram, S. (2004). ​On Creating Public Value: What Business Might 
Learn from Government about Strategic Management.​ Retrieved from Cambridge: 
58. Moosa, I. A., & Moosa, N. (2019a). The Effects of IMF Operations on Social 
Expenditure. In ​Eliminating the IMF ​(pp. 111-134). Cham.: Palgrave Macmillan. 
59. Moosa, I. A., & Moosa, N. (2019b). The IMF as an Instigator of Riots and Civil 
Unrest. In ​Eliminating the IMF (​ pp. 89-110). Cham.: Palgrave Macmillan. 
60. Moosa, I. A., & Moosa, N. (2019c). Keep, Reform or Abolish? In ​Eliminating the 
IMF (​ pp. 135-163). Cham.: Palgrave Macmillan. 
61. Nadash, P., Miller, E. A., Jones, D. K., Gusmano, M. K., & Rosenbaum, S. (2018). A 
series of unfortunate events: implications of Republican efforts to repeal and 
replace the affordable care act for older adults. ​Journal of aging & social policy., 
30​(3-4), 259-281. 
62. Oakley, K., Naylor, R., & Lee, D. (2006). ​Giving Them What They Want: 
Constructing the 'Public' in Public Value.​ London: BOP Consulting. 
63. Patomäki, H. (2017). Will the EU disintegrate? What does the likely possibility of 
disintegration tell about the future of the world? ​Globalizations, 14​(1), 168-177. 
64. Payer, C. (1975). ​The Debt Trap: The International Monetary Fund and the Third 
World ​(Vol. 376). New York: NYU Press. 
65. Peet, R. (2009). ​Unholy trinity: the IMF, World Bank and WTO.​ London: Zed 
Books. 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


27 
 

66. Rapkin, D. P., & Strand, J. R. (2006). Reforming the IMF's weighted voting 
system. ​World Economy, 29(​ 3), 305-324. 
67. Saldinger, A. (2019, 12 March). US budget slashes global development funding, 
stresses burden sharing.​ Devex.​  
68. Samaratunge, R., & Wijewardena, N. (2009). The Changing Nature of Public 
Value in Developing Countries. ​International Journal of Public Administration, 
32(​ 3-4), 313-327. 
69. Spano, A. (2009). Public Value Creation and Management Control Systems. 
International Journal of Public Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 328-348. 
70. Stiglitz, J., & Pike, R. M. (2004). Globalization and its Discontents. ​Canadian 
Journal of Sociology, 29(​ 2), 321-340. 
71. Stoker, G. (2006). Public Value Management: A New Narrative for Networked 
Governance? . ​American Review of Public Administration, 36(​ 1), 41-57. 
72. Stone, R. (2003). ​Lending Credibility: The International Monetary Fund and the 
Post-Communist Transition.​ Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 
73. Talbot, C. (2009). Public Value—The Next “Big Thing” in Public Management? 
International Journal of Public Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 167-170. 
74. van der Waal, Z., & van Hout, E. T. (2009). Is Public Value Pluralism Paramount? 
The Intrinsic Multiplicity and Hybridity of Public Values. ​International Journal 
of Public Administration Review, 32​(3-4), 220-231. 
75. Varoufakis, Y. (2016). ​And the Weak Suffer What they Must? Europe's Crisis and 
America's Future.​ New York: Nation Books. 
76. Vreeland, J. R. (2003). ​The IMF and economic development. ​. Cambridge: 
Cambridge University Press. 
77. Wallis, J. (2010). A tale of two leaders: leadership and cultural change at the New 
Zealand treasury. ​Australian Journal of Public Administration, 69​(1), 22-33. 
78. Wallis, J., & Gregory, R. (2009). Leadership, Accountability and Public Value: 
Resolving a Problem in “New Governance”? . ​International Journal of Public 
Administration, 32(​ 3-4), 250-273. 
79. Wanna, J., & Rhodes, R. (2007). The Limits to Public Value, or Rescuing 
Responsible Government from the Platonic Gardens.​ Australian Journal of 
Public Administration, 66​(4), 406-421. 
80. Widmaier, W. (2014). From Bretton Woods to the global financial crisis: Popular 
politics, paradigmatic debates, and the construction of crises. ​Review of Social 
Economy, 72(​ 2), 233-252. 
81. Woods, N. (2003). Order, Justice, the IMF, and the World Bank. . In J. L. G. A. H. 
Rosemary Foot (Ed.), ​Order and Justice in International Relations:​ Oxford 
University Press 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331


28 
 

82. Woods, N. (2014). ​The globalizers: the IMF, the World Bank, and their borrowers:​  
Cornell University Press. 
83. Zakaria, F. (1997). The rise of illiberal democracy. ​Foreign Affairs, 76(​ 22). 

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514331

You might also like