You are on page 1of 8

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2009, 99:2, 261–267

http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.99.2.261

MACROECONOMIC NARRATIVES
FROM AFRICA AND THE DIASPORA†

Institutions versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands

By Peter Blair Henry and Conrad Miller*

A long line of work emphasizes the correla- origins enables researchers to estimate the causal
tion between institutions and economic perfor- impact of property rights on long-run economic
mance (Adam Smith 1776; W. Arthur Lewis outcomes. Differences in the legal tradition that
1955; Douglass C. North 1990). Rich countries countries inherited from their colonial masters
have laws that provide incentives to engage in also have a long-run impact on economic out-
productive economic activity. Investors rely on comes. Countries with English common law ori-
secure property rights, facilitating investment in gins provide investors with stronger protection
human and physical capital; government power and are less prone to government ownership and
is balanced and restricted by an independent regulation than countries with civil law origins
judiciary; contracts are enforced effectively, (Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes,
supporting private economic transactions. and Andrei Shleifer 2008). In turn, common law
Recent research moves from correlation to countries have greater financial development,
causation by observing that countries whose less corruption, smaller informal economies,
colonizers established strong property rights and lower unemployment.
hundreds of years ago have, on average, much Case studies seem to suggest that institutions
higher levels of income today than countries also exert a causal influence on economic out-
whose colonizers did not (Daron Acemoglu, comes over periods of time somewhat shorter
Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson 2001). than the centuries-long span emphasized by
Since a country’s colonial origin—literally the colonial and legal origins literature. For
determined centuries ago—can in no meaning- instance, following the Armistice of 1953, Korea
ful way be said to be caused by its present-day broke into two separate nations with similar lev-
level of income, the nature of countries’ colonial els of income, almost identical ethnic and cul-
tural makeup, but starkly different institutional
arrangements of the economy. North Korea

resorted to central planning while South Korea
Discussant: William A. Darity, Jr., Duke University. relied on property rights and markets (with a
* Henry: Graduate School of Business, Stanford Uni­ healthy dose of state intervention). More than 50
versity, Stanford, CA 94305–5015, Brookings Institution, years later South Korea’s income per capita is
and National Bureau of Economic Research (e-mail: more than ten times as large as North Korea’s.
pbhenry@stanford.edu); Miller: Department of Economics,
Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305 (e-mail: The divergence of the East and West German
ccmiller@stanford.edu). Henry gratefully acknowledges economies following the partition of Germany
financial support from the John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn after World War II ostensibly provides another
Faculty Fellowship, the Stanford Institute for Economic piece of evidence in favor of the view that insti-
Policy Research, the Stanford Center for International
Development, and the Freeman Spogli Institute. Miller
tutions play the dominant role.
gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Mellon While institutions undoubtedly affect eco-
Mays Undergraduate Fellowship. We thank Jonathan nomic outcomes, the macroeconomic policies
Bendor, Sir Courtney Blackman, Renee Bowen, Eleanor that governments choose to implement may
Brown, Cecilia Conrad, William A. Darity Jr., Kevin Davis, exert just as much influence on the trajectory
Chad Jones, John Rapley, Tracy Robinson, Paul Romer,
members of the Caribbean Policy Research Institute, and of their economies as the broader institutional
seminar participants at Brookings, MIT, and Stanford for framework within which those policy decisions
very helpful comments and discussions. take place. As a matter of arithmetic, long-run
261
262 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2009

1.2

Natural log of index of real GDP per capita 1

0.8

Barbados
0.6 Jamaica

0.4

0.2

0
60
62
64
66
68
70
72
74
76
78
80
82

84
86

19 8
90

92
94
96
98
00
02
8
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19

19
19
19

19
19
19
19
20
20
Year

Figure 1. Standards of Living in Barbados and Jamaica Diverge after Independence

income levels are the sum of a series of short- Figure 1 plots the natural logarithm of an
and medium-run growth rates that are heavily index of real GDP per capita (measured in US
influenced by fiscal, monetary, and exchange dollars) in Barbados and Jamaica from 1960
rate policy (to name a few). This article demon- through 2002. By construction, the value of the
strates the relevance of the point by examining index is one in 1960 so that the natural log of
a very different kind of policy experiment from the index is zero in 1960. While Barbados has
the ones in the existing literature on institutions not exactly experienced a growth miracle, its
and growth. economy performed reasonably well over the
In contrast to the examples of North and South 42-year period and substantially better than
Korea and East and West Germany, we examine Jamaica’s. To be exact, by 2002, the natural log
a pair of countries—Barbados and Jamaica— of the index is 0.917 for Barbados and 0.356 for
whose income levels diverge over a 40-year Jamaica, so that the average growth rate of real
stretch in spite of no obvious differences in the GDP per capita for Barbados over the entire
institutional arrangements of their economies at sample is 2.2 percent per year (0.917 divided
the beginning of the observation period. by 42) versus 0.8 percent per year for Jamaica
(0.356 divided by 42).
I.  Standards of Living in Barbados and Jamaica One particularly striking feature of Figure 1
is the sharp decline in Jamaica’s standard of liv-
Barbados and Jamaica are both former British ing that sets in after 1972. Of course, the first oil
colonies, small island economies, and predomi- price shock in 1973 precipitated a general slow-
nantly inhabited by the descendants of Africans down in world economic growth, but the central
who were brought to the Caribbean to cultivate point (laid out in more detail later in the paper)
sugar. As former British colonies, Barbados and is that growth in Jamaica slowed more dramati-
Jamaica inherited almost identical political, cally than it did in Barbados. While Jamaica’s
economic, and legal institutions: Westminster economy contracted at a rate of 2.3 percent per
Parliamentary democracy, constitutional protec- year from 1972 to 1987, Barbados, whose econ-
tion of property rights, and legal systems rooted omy has a similar structure (see Table 1) and was
in English common law. Yet, as Figure 1 demon- subject to the same external shocks, grew by 1.2
strates, the standard of living in the two countries percent per year. In other words, for a 15-year
diverged in the roughly 40-year period following period income per head in Barbados grew by 3.5
their independence from Great Britain. percentage points faster than it did in Jamaica.
VOL. 99 NO. 2 Institutions Versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands 263

Table 1—Barbados and Jamaica Have Similar Economies

Barbados Jamaica
Exports as percent GDP 58.4 50.0
Imports as percent GDP 68.6 60.7
Agriculture as percent GDP 3.7 5.7
Industry as percent GDP 18.0 33.1
Services as percent GDP 78.3 61.2
Population 300,000 2,700,000
Area (square miles) 166 4,244

Turning from growth rates to levels gives a 85 percent of the populations of Barbados and
tangible sense of the impact of these growth-rate Jamaica. Slavery was abolished in the British
differentials on long-run standards of ­living. In West Indies in 1834, and following World War
1960 real GDP per capita was $3,395 in Barbados I the region began a process of “constitutional
and $2,208 in Jamaica. In 2002 Barbados’s decolonization” that led the islands down a grad-
GDP per capita was $8,434 while Jamaica’s ual, if difficult, path toward greater self-govern-
was $3,165. The $1,187 income gap that existed ment (Trevor Munroe 1972). Reporting on his
between Barbados and Jamaica around the time visit to the region in 1922, Major E. F. L. Wood,
of independence now stands at $5,269 dollars. Britain’s Under Secretary of State for Colonies
Put another way, the income gap between the wrote:
two countries now exceeds Jamaica’s level of
GDP per capita. “The whole history of the African popula-
Since their initial conditions were similar at tion of the West Indies inevitably drives
the time of independence, it stretches credulity them towards representational institu-
to argue that Barbados and Jamaica diverged tions fashioned after the British Model.
because of differences in colonial origins, legal Transplanted by the slave trade or other
origins, geography, or some other exogenous circumstances to foreign soil, losing in the
feature of their economies. We argue below process their social system, language and
that the explanation for the divergence lies not traditions. … Small wonder if they look for
with differences in institutions but differences political growth to be the only course and
in macroeconomic policy. pattern that they know, and aspire to share
in what has been the particularly British
gift of representational institutions”
II.  Institutions (Wood 1921).
Jamaica won its independence from Britain in
1962, Barbados in 1966. At the time they became Three subsequent empirical observations
sovereign nations, both countries possessed the demonstrate the accuracy of Wood’s predic-
two institutional characteristics that the litera- tion that the British West Indies (Barbados and
ture identifies as critical to long-run prosperity: Jamaica in particular) were destined to establish
strong constitutional protection of private prop- institutions that mirrored the mother country.
erty and English common law. A brief review of First, as sovereign nations, both Barbados
the islands’ colonial histories verifies the state- and Jamaica organized their governments as
ment in the preceding sentence. parliamentary democracies in the Westminster-
The English settled Barbados in 1627 and Whitehall tradition (Anthony Payne 1993).
wrested Jamaica from the Spanish in 1655. Since independence, Barbados and Jamaica
Both islands entered the modern era as planta- have maintained two-party political systems
tion economies that produced sugar and other and consistently held free and fair elections with
agricultural commodities using slave labor (Eric no unconstitutional transfers of power. While
Williams 1970). By the end of the eighteenth sporadic violence often accompanies elections
century, African slaves comprised more than in Jamaica, neither Barbados nor Jamaica has
264 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2009

suffered a coup or civil war, and both countries For most of their histories, both countries shared
have a free and vocal press. Four postindepen- the Judicial Committee of the Privy Council in
dence elections in Jamaica resulted in the ­ruling England as their highest court of appeals.
party peacefully turning over power to the Because Barbados and Jamaica possess simi-
opposition. Three such transitions occurred in lar economic institutions and legal systems, nei-
Barbados. ther the property-rights nor legal-origins theory
Second, the constitutions of Barbados and of long-run income determination can explain
Jamaica explicitly protect private property. The their postindependence divergence. Although
joint parliamentary committee that drafted the institutional structures of Barbados and
Jamaica’s constitution was chaired by Norman Jamaica are very close, the same cannot be said
Manley—a lawyer, Rhodes Scholar, and father of their approaches to macroeconomic policy.
of the nation’s future prime minister. Discussing
the constitution in front of Jamaica’s House of III.  Macroeconomic Policies
Parliament on 23 January 1962, Manley says:
When Jamaica gained independence in 1962
“We have put into this constitution a clause the Jamaican Labor Party (JLP) held a parlia-
which provides that property may not be, mentary majority. For the next ten years the JLP
in effect, arbitrarily acquired. Property remained in power and GDP per capita grew at a
is protected in that it can only be taken rate of 5.4 percent per year, with the lion’s share
under a law which has been passed. And of growth stemming from two principal sources:
when so taken, it must be taken in accor-
dance with the terms of that law. What the strong US growth in the 1960s created a robust
law provides for compensation, you must export market for Jamaican bauxite; and rising
get. …[I]t is of the highest importance for a incomes in North America boosted growth in
country like Jamaica to let the world know Jamaica’s tourism industry.
that…people can come here to invest… But all was not well. In classic Dutch Disease
fully protected by the laws of the land…” fashion, growth in the bauxite sector drove up
(Manley 1962, 306). the relative price of nontradeables, reducing
the competitiveness of Jamaica’s agricultural
Barbados, which attained full independence sector and precipitating an exodus of workers
four years after Jamaica, adopted a constitu- from the countryside to the cities (Carl Stone
tion with an effectively identical coverage of and Stanislaw Wellisz 1993). Because of strong
private property. Both constitutions assert that unions, wages in other sectors did not adjust
property cannot be compulsorily acquired downward to absorb the excess labor released
except under written law that describes a pro- from agriculture (Caribbean Policy Research
cedure for determining and providing compen- Institute 2005). Consequently, during its first
sation and grants claimants the right of appeal decade of independence Jamaica experienced
to a court (Chapter 3, Section 16, of Barbadian the odd combination of strong growth coupled
Constitution; Chapter 3, Section 18, of Jamaican with an unemployment rate that rose from 13
Constitution). The constitutions also delineate percent in 1962 to 23.2 percent in 1972.
similar sets of exceptions to this clause, such as Rising unemployment, income inequality,
cases where property is acquired in satisfaction and the attendant societal tensions proved too
of a tax, property is in a condition dangerous to much for the JLP at the ballot box. In 1972 the
the health of others, or property is acquired to People’s National Party (PNP) rose to power
pay debt of the insolvent. under the leadership of Prime Minister Michael
Third, Barbados and Jamaica adopted legal Manley (son of Norman) and the promise of
systems based on English common law (Rose- “democratic socialism.” The two cornerstones of
Marie Antoine 1999). Describing the essence of democratic socialism and the PNP’s economic
this adoption to the Philadelphia Bar Association policies were “self-reliance” and “social jus-
in 1967, Manley says: “As to the law, we took over tice.” Self-reliance translated as extensive state
the English common law holus bolus. But what intervention in the economy. The PNP nation-
was more important we took over the structure alized companies, erected import barriers, and
and machinery which England built up for the imposed strict exchange controls (R. DeLisle
administration of justice” (Manley 1967, 340). Worrell 1987). Social justice meant income
VOL. 99 NO. 2 Institutions Versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands 265

Table 2—Economic Policy and Performance in Barbados and Jamaica Diverge after
1973

Barbados Jamaica
1966–1972 1973–1980 1962–1972 1973–1980
Growth rate of GDP per capita 6.0   2.7 4.2 −4.3
Fiscal deficit, percentage of GDP 2.7   5.3 2.3 15.5
Inflation 6.0 14.8 4.4 23.0

redistribution through job creation programs, was down to 2.9 percent. Since much of defi-
housing development schemes, and subsidies on cit financing comes from the central bank, by
basic food items. extension, Barbados also ran a tighter monetary
Whatever merits the PNP’s economic program ship than Jamaica. Table 2 summarizes the
may have had, it was expensive. Government net result of the difference in macroeconomic
spending rose from 23 percent of GDP in 1972 policy in Barbados and Jamaica over the two
to 45 percent in 1978. Revenue did not keep pace periods.
with the rise in expenditure. From 1962 through
1972 Jamaica’s average fiscal deficit was 2.3 IV.  Exchange Rate Policies
percent of GDP (see Table 2). In contrast, from
1973 to 1980 the average fiscal deficit was 15.5 In 1975 Barbados pegged its currency to the
percent of GDP! The PNP financed much of US dollar at a parity of B$2: US$1. The parity
the deficit by borrowing directly from the Bank came under threat when Barbados suffered a
of Jamaica. Predictably, inflation rose. From deep recession in the early 1990s and real GDP
1962 to 1972 inflation averaged 4.4 percent per per capita contracted by 5.1 percent per year
year. By 1980 inflation was 27 percent per year, from 1989 to 1992. In the midst of the crisis
investment had collapsed (to 14 percent of GDP in 1991, Barbados entered formal negotiations
down from 26 percent in 1972), and the PNP with the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
was voted out of power. to request financial assistance. Among other
Because Jamaica’s reversal of fortune coin- things, the IMF recommended devaluation to
cided with the oil price shock of 1973 and the stimulate production and return the economy to
onset of worldwide stagflation, it is tempting full employment. Deeply attached to the stabil-
to blame the country’s downward spiral on ity of their currency, the Barbadians resisted the
external events. While many have done so (see recommendation. Instead of devaluing, the gov-
Manley 1987), even a cursory comparison with ernment began a set of negotiations with employ-
Barbados makes it difficult for an objective ers, unions, and workers that culminated with a
observer to embrace that conclusion. tripartite protocol on wages and prices in 1993.
The inflation rate in Barbados also spiked Under the 1993 Wage and Price Protocol,
in the early 1970s, hitting a peak of 39 percent workers and unions assented to a one-time cut in
in 1975, but Barbados’s policy response to the real wages of about 9 percent and agreed to keep
external shocks that precipitated the spike could their demands for future pay raises in line with
not have been more different from Jamaica’s. increases in productivity. Firms promised to
First of all, Barbados avoided nationalization, moderate their price increases, the government
kept state ownership to a minimum, and adopted maintained the parity of the currency, and all
an outward-looking growth strategy (Courtney parties agreed to the creation of a national pro-
Blackman 2006, 390). Second, instead of tak- ductivity board to provide better data on which
ing an accommodative stance that delayed the to base future negotiations.
inevitable retrenchment needed to adjust to To be sure, the protocol involved costly
higher energy prices, policymakers in Barbados bargaining. When negotiations began, public
kept government spending under control. While demonstrations broke out and the government’s
the fiscal deficit in Barbados did climb to 7.7 wage-cut proposal was challenged in court, all
percent of GDP in 1973, by 1978 that number the way up to the Privy Council (Alvin Wint
266 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2009

2004, ch. 3). Nevertheless, the center held. in the global economy. On the contrary, we
The fall in real wages helped restore exter- think that important general lessons lie at the
nal competitiveness and profitability, thereby heart of this Caribbean parable. Recent work
achieving the same result as a devaluation but focuses on the very long-run effects of insti-
without the risk of triggering an inflationary tutions to the point of exclusion of almost all
spiral. The economy recovered quickly. From other factors. But the macroeconomic deci-
1993 to 2000 GDP per capita grew by 2.7 per- sions of governments can exert just as much
cent per year. influence on the trajectory of the economy
Unlike Barbados, Jamaica devalued its cur- as the institutional ­f ramework within which
rency several times between 1975 and 2002. those decisions take place. Countries have no
From this fact, many observers draw the spe- control over their geographic location, colo-
cious conclusion that the difference in exchange nial heritage, or legal origin, but they do have
rate policy accounts for Barbados’s superior agency over the policies that they implement.
economic performance1. But Barbados’s fixed Of particular importance for small open econ-
exchange rate did not cause its economy to omies (i.e., most countries in the world) is the
outperform Jamaica’s. Rather, the proximate response of policy to macroeconomic shocks
source of Barbados’ superior performance was such as a fall in the terms of trade. Pedestrian
a set of growth-facilitating policies—monetary as it may seem, changes in policy, even those
restraint, fiscal discipline, openness to trade, that do not have a permanent effect on growth
and ultimately wage cuts to restore competi- rates of GDP per capita, can have a significant
tive unit labor costs—that had the side effect impact on a country’s standard of living within
of enabling the monetary authority to maintain a single generation.
the exchange-rate parity without losing external
competitiveness. In contrast, Jamaica’s policies
were never consistent with maintaining commit- REFERENCES
ment to any parity the government might have
wanted to adopt. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James
The differences in exchange rate policy do, A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins
however, raise an important issue. Faced with a of Comparative Development: An Empirical
scenario like that of Barbados in 1991, would Investigation.” American Economic Review,
Jamaica be able to achieve the social consen- 91(5): 1369–1401.
sus needed to adopt the measures required to Antoine, Rose-Marie. 1999. Commonwealth
avoid a competitive devaluation? As stated in Caribbean Law and Legal Systems. London:
the previous paragraph, we think the Jamaican Cavendish Publishers.
record speaks for itself. Answering the deeper Blackman, Courtney. 2006. The Practice of Eco-
question—why do some democratic societies nomic Management: A Caribbean Perspec-
(of which Barbados is just one example) manage tive. Kingston: Ian Randle Publishers.
to reach constructive policy compromises while Caribbean Policy Research Institute. 2005. Taking
others (such as Jamaica) do not?—remains an Responsibility: The Jamaican Economy Since
important research challenge.2 Independence. http://www.takingresponsibil-
ity.org/.
V.  Conclusion La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and
Andrei Shleifer. 2008. “The Economic Conse-
It may be tempting for readers to regard this quences of Legal Origins.” Journal of Eco-
paper as a quaint tale of two exotic islands nomic Literature, 46(2): 285–332.
better known for their beaches, music, and Lewis, W. Arthur. 1955. The Theory of Economic
Olympic sprinters than their significance Growth. Homewood, Illinois: Unwyn Hyman.
Manley, Michael. 1987. Up the Down Escalator:
1
Development and the International Economy: A
Hon. Edward Seaga, “The Caribbean Single Market: Jamaican Case Study. London: Andre Deutsch.
Beneficial Path or Wayward Journey,” Jamaica Observer,
February 10, 2006. Manley, Norman Washington. 1962. “The Inde-
2
See Donald Robotham (1998) for clues about answers pendence Constitution.” In Norman Washington
to this question for Barbados and Jamaica. Manley and the New Jamaica: Selected
VOL. 99 NO. 2 Institutions Versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands 267

Speeches and Writings 1938–68, ed. Rex Net- the Western World, Encyclopedia Brittanica.
tleford, 1971. London: Longman Caribbean. Stone, Carl, and Stanislaw Wellisz. 1993.
Munroe, Trevor. 1972. The Politics of Decoloni- “Jamaica.” In The Political Economy of Pov-
zation: Jamaica, 1944–1962. Jamaica: Univer- erty, Equity, and Growth: Five Small Open
sity of the West Indies Institute of Social and Economies, ed. Ronald Findlay and Stanislaw
Economic Research. Wellisz, 140–218. New York: Oxford Univer-
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institu- sity Press.
tional Change, and Economic Performance. Williams, Eric. 1970. From Columbus to Cas-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. tor: The History of the Caribbean 1492–1969.
Payne, Anthony. 1993. “Westminster Adapted: New York: Random House.
The Political Order of the Commonwealth Wint, Alvin. 2003. Competitiveness in Small
Caribbean.” In Democracy in the Caribbean: Developing Economies: Insights from the
Political Economic, and Social Perspectives, Caribbean. Kingston: University of the West
ed. Jorgé I. Dominguez, Robert A. Pastor, and Indies Press.
R. DeLisle Worrell. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Wood, Hon. E. F. L., M.P. 1921. Report of a Visit
University Press. to Certain West Indian Colonies and to Brit-
Robotham, Donald. 1998. “Transnationalism in ish Guiana, as cited in Anthony Payne (op. cit.)
the Caribbean: Formal and Informal.” Ameri- 1993, 58–59.
can Ethnologist, 25(2): 307–21. Worrell, R. DeLisle. 1987. Small Island Econo-
Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature mies: Structure and Performance in the Eng-
and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. In lish Speaking Caribbean Since 1970. New
Mortimer Adler (ed.), 2005, Great Books of York: Praeger.
This article has been cited by:

1. Thomas Gall, Paolo Masella. 2011. Markets and jungles. Journal of Economic Growth . [CrossRef]
2. Thorvaldur Gylfason, Eduard Hochreiter. 2011. Growing Together: Croatia and Latvia.
Comparative Economic Studies 53:2, 165-197. [CrossRef]
3. Randall Morck, Bernard Yeung. 2011. Economics, History, and Causation. Business History
Review 85:01, 39-63. [CrossRef]

You might also like