You are on page 1of 10

84 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Corporate Governance Mechanisms:


a plea for less code of good governance
and more market control
Alvaro Cuervo*

This paper provides a critical comparative analysis of corporate governance mechanisms in


market-oriented (Anglo-Saxon) and large shareholder-oriented (Continental European)
systems of corporate governance. Deficiencies in shareholder protection in the legal systems
of both corporate governance systems have been addressed through the use of codes of good
governance, a set of norms that regulate the behaviour and structure of the board of directors.
However, the lower enforceability of norms in Continental Europe limits the applicability of
such codes. Therefore, we argue that in Continental Europe, rather than promoting codes of
good governance, it is necessary to expand market control mechanisms to facilitate the
maximisation of firm value.

Keywords: Corporate governance systems, market for corporate control, codes of good
governance, managerial defence mechanisms, core shareholders

Introduction by large incumbent shareholders or leverage


(Jensen, 1986); and second, mechanisms ex-

T he separation of owners and managers


creates the need for corporate govern-
ance, which comprises mechanisms that en-
ternal to the firm such as the market for
corporate control, the market for managers,
and the market for products and services.
sure efficient decision-making, maximising the However, the use of these mechanisms
value of the firm. Moreover, the expansion of depends on the corporate governance system
capital markets in the 1990s, with increasing prevalent in the country; that is, whether it is
numbers of companies listed, and the global- market-oriented or large-shareholders oriented
isation of investors increase the need for good (Franks and Mayer, 1997; Shleifer and Vishny,
corporate governance mechanisms, as the 1997). Market-oriented systems tend to rely
separation of ownership and control in- more on managerial compensation and the
creases. The broad question that we analyse market for corporate control to solve corpo-
in this paper is: what are the corporate rate governance problems, while large-share-
governance mechanisms that solve or reduce holder oriented systems tend to use control
the problem of the separation of owners and by large incumbent shareholders to align the
managers and facilitate efficient decision- behaviour of managers and owners.
* Address for correspondence: making that optimises the value of the firm? Nevertheless, both systems show limitations
Complutense University of Traditional finance literature has indicated to the efficiency of the mechanisms used to
Madrid, Facultad de Ciencias several mechanisms that help solve corporate solve deficiencies in corporate governance.
Económicas y Empresariales,
Campus de Somosaguas s/n, governance problems (Fama, 1980; Fama and On the one hand, the market for corporate
28223, Madrid, Spain. Tel: Jensen, 1983b; Turnbull, 1997): first, mechan- control is expensive and requires large devi-
34-91-3942505; Fax: 34-91-
3942371; E-mail: acuervo@
isms internal to the firm, such as managerial ations from appropriate behaviour by man-
ccee.ucm.es compensation, the board of directors, control agers in order to function properly, while

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002. 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK
Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002 and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS 85

being subject to further deficiencies in the expand the realm of action of market control
form of anti-takeover measures that protect mechanisms, avoiding managerial defences
incumbent managers (Jensen, 1993). On the and core shareholders, to facilitate the maxi-
other hand, control by large shareholders is misation of the value of the firm in the market.
limited, since these large shareholders seek The rest of the paper is organised as
their private objectives at the expense of follows. In the next section, corporate govern-
minority owners (Barclay and Holderness, ance systems are introduced and the use of
1989; Barclay et al., 1993; Cuervo-Cazurra, 1999). different corporate governance mechanisms
There are other corporate governance me- as part of a system is discussed. Following
chanisms at a higher level that, until recently, this, the legal system and codes of good
have been overlooked in the literature: the governance as alternative corporate govern-
legal system and the codes of good govern- ance mechanisms are presented, and limita-
ance. The legal system, commonly classified tions in the applicability of codes of good
into common law and civil law, establishes governance are reviewed. It is argued that
norms that regulate the behaviour of the firm there is a need to introduce more market
and protect the rights of minority share- mechanisms in the large-shareholder corpo-
holders, offering different levels of protection rate governance systems. Finally, implications
of the rights of minority shareholders (La for future research are discussed.
Porta et al., 1997), and influencing the devel-
opment of capital markets (La Porta et al.,
1997) and the growth of the country (Levine, Corporate governance systems
1999). The codes of good governance, a set of
‘best practice’ recommendations regarding Corporate governance mechanisms vary
the behaviour and structure of the board of across institutional environments (Mayer,
directors (Dalton et al., 1998), act as a sub- 1996). These can be separated into two main
stitute for deficiencies in the protection of systems (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997): large-
minority shareholders in the legal system shareholder control systems, such as those in
(Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazurra, 2000). Germany, France or Spain, and market con-
However, the type of legal system limits the trol systems, such as those in the USA and the
efficiency in the application of the codes of UK. For simplicity, we term the first system
good governance. In common law countries the Continental European system, and the
(in the Anglo-Saxon tradition) judges can second the Anglo-Saxon system.
apply the codes of good governance directly, The large-shareholder control or Conti-
allowing these to become enforceable regu- nental European system is characterised by
lation, whereas in civil law countries (in the the following features: (1) ownership is con-
Continental European tradition) judges can- centrated; banks, companies, and families are
not apply the codes of good governance with large shareholders; (2) control is assumed to
the force of regulation, since the law can only be exercised by large shareholders; (3) the
be developed in parliament. board of directors is controlled by internal
Hence, we argue that in civil law countries directors or external directors linked to large
the codes of good governance can be applied shareholders; (4) capital markets are rela-
formally, following the letter but not the spirit tively illiquid and have limited control ability;
of the law, since they cannot be legally en- (5) there exist implicit contracting and close
forced. In these countries, some companies personal trust relationships among managers;
use the publication or approval of the codes (6) long-term lender–borrower relationships
of good governance in order to adapt them and bank ownership of equity are main-
and establish systems of corporate govern- tained; (7) there is no active market for
ance that go against the spirit of the codes, control; that is, management does not face
developing anti-takeover measures that pro- hostile takeover bids; and (8) banks play a
tect incumbent managers and large share- major role in corporate governance, trough
holders. Moreover, in these countries the equity stakes, proxies given to them by small
authorities require that all takeover plans be investors and bankers’ position on the boards
submitted for approval in order to analyse of firms (Baums, 1993; Kester, 1997).
their impact on competition. This analysis has The market control or Anglo-Saxon system
destroyed the market for corporate control, is characterised by the following features:
since it reduces the surprise impact of the (1) ownership is diffuse except for institu-
takeover and increases governmental inter- tional investors; (2) control is vested in the
vention in the strategy of companies. board of directors, with external directors
Therefore, we contend that rather than playing an important role; (3) capital markets
extending the use of codes of good govern- are very liquid and there is a developed
ance in civil law countries, it is necessary to market for corporate control and takeover

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002 Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002


86 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

market; and (4) there is more defence of the Thus, it is at least as important to understand
ownership rights of shareholders over the the relationship between large controlling
rights of debtholders than in the Continental shareholders and weak minority shareholders
European model; that is, legal protection acts as it is to understand the more commonly
as a substitute for ownership structure (La studied interface between management and
Porta et al., 1997). dispersed shareholders. In several countries,
Neither system is perfect. In the market the median largest voting stake in listed
control system, the reduction in the operation companies is over 50 per cent, suggesting
of the market for corporate control gave rise that voting control by a large blockholder is
to activism by large institutional investors the rule rather than the exception; and in no
(Useem, 1993). In the large-shareholder con- European country studied was the median
trol system, abuses by managers and large largest shareholder small enough to fall
shareholders led to the establishment of codes below the 5 per cent disclosure threshold.
of good corporate governance (Cadbury To illustrate the striking differences in con-
Commission, 1992). centration of voting power among countries,
Although neither system has achieved a consider the size of the largest voting block.
perfect corporate governance system, we con- The median size in percentage of the largest
tend that in the case of the large-shareholder ultimate outside voting block for listed in-
control system, there is a need for more dustrial companies in the US is under 5 per
market control and less use of codes of good cent, and in the UK it is a modest 9.9 per cent,
corporate governance to achieve the ultimate while, at the other extreme, in Germany,
objective of the maximisation of the firm’s Austria and Italy it exceeds 50 per cent, in
value. The Continental European model was the Netherlands it is 43.5 per cent, in Spain it
justified as it evolved in its historical institu- is 34.2 per cent and in France it is 20 per cent
tional framework, where it was useful to deal (Becht and Roell, 1999, p. 1051).
with the hazards associated with information Another characteristic which differentiates
asymmetries, investment in specialised assets, between corporate governance in the Con-
R&D, and long-term investments (Baums, tinental European and Anglo-Saxon systems
1993, p. 180), and the agency problems of is the importance of the fiduciary capital, or
large organisations. However, the desirability institutional investors. In the USA, insti-
of corporate takeover activity and greater tutional investors hold 51.5 per cent of all
operating efficiency in contrast with the long- domestic corporations and 57 per cent of the
term strategies creates the need to revise the outstanding equity of the largest US corpor-
benefits of this system (Kester, 1997, p. 240). ations in 1994 (Hawley and Williams, 1997).
Although, in theory, large shareholders have Many who support the agency model regret
incentives to exercise monitoring (Schleifer the passing of the market for corporate
and Vishny, 1986), there is evidence of a lack control that characterised the 1980s. In that
of control of banks as large shareholders on era, the market was seen as the ultimate
the firm (Zoido, 1998; Cuervo-Cazurra, 1999). mechanism for aligning managers’ actions
Meanwhile, there is other evidence suggest- with owners’ wishes (Hawley and Williams,
ing that there is no relationship between large 1997, pp. 207–8). After the decline in the
shareholders and firm value (Holderness and market for corporate control, owners (insti-
Sheenan, 1998). Moreover, environmental tutional investors primarily) were then forced
changes associated with the opening and in- to turn their attention to: (1) the removal of
tegration of European markets highlight the impediments to the market for corporate
fact that this model is inefficient when the control; (2) the enactment of governance
institutional environment changes (Baums, reforms that give owners more influence on
1993, p. 182; Cuervo and Villalonga, 2000); boards and (3) the development of initiatives
thus, it is recommended that there be a move- to influence the Securities and Exchange
ment towards increasing transparency and Commission and other agencies to adopt
market control. rules that either force institutions to act
One factor that allows differentiation be- aggressively or compel managers to maximise
tween Anglo-Saxon and Continental Euro- long-term shareholder wealth. Now there is a
pean corporate governance systems and new problem: can agents watch agents?
affects the efficiency of corporate governance Sometimes, institutional investors have been
mechanisms, in particular the market for captured by management or exist in a tight
corporate control, is the difference in owner- commercial network of firms. The remaining
ship structure. There is an extraordinarily active institutional investors – primarily pub-
high degree of concentration of shareholder lic pension funds – are relatively free from
voting power in the Continental European corporate pressure, but may be subject to
system relative to the Anglo-Saxon system. strong political pressure. The rise of fiduciary

Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS 87

capitalism with its great concentration of Italy or Spain. Moreover, in the Continental
wealth in the hands of relatively few institu- system, individual investors with shares in
tional investors raises serious concerns about the custody of banks delegate the voting
the monitoring of the monitors (Hawley and rights to the banks. This limits control,
Williams, 1997). communication and collective action of share-
holders since banks, and not the ultimate
Alternative corporate governance shareholders, control the voting rights of the
instruments: institutional investors and shares (Cuervo-Cazurra, 1999; La Porta et al.,
1999).
codes of good governance Finally, there are reasons linked to legal
The reduction in the takeover movement in defences and managerial defences. Although
the 1990s in the Anglo-Saxon system led to the adoption of defensive measures by the
the search for solutions to the limitation on incumbent management team might be illegal
corporate governance mechanisms. With the once a takeover has been announced, as in the
threat of takeover gone, and corporate boards case of Spain, in practice, they have either
powerless or unwilling to act, the manage- previously reformed the firm’s by-laws or
ment of many underperforming companies they will use the Shareholders General Meet-
faced no serious pressure to make reforms ing to make these measures possible. The
necessary to restore profitability. In the opposition of incumbent managers to take-
Anglo-Saxon system, a stronger institutional overs may arise from their receiving compen-
voice could be expected to benefit share- sation above the value of their contribution
holders in a number of ways by prodding to the company, compensation they might
reluctant corporate boards into decisive ac- lose in case of takeover. They may also face
tion. As a consequence, institutional investors limited employment alternatives, or they may
had no choice but to protect their investments have made investments in human capital
by becoming more vocal and active (Pound, specific to the company, investments they
1997); by discouraging empire-building will lose if they leave the firm. Managers’
through acquisitions and thus sharpening opposition to a takeover is manifested in
corporate focus; by persuading management several forms, such as publicising its rejection
to pay out excess capital and dismantle value- of the takeover offer and recommending to
reducing barriers to takeover; and by en- shareholders that they, too, oppose the sale.
couraging management to take a longer view Their opposition may also be expressed in
of the corporate future (Black, 1997). establishment of anti-takeover defences, in-
In the European system, the market for struments that cause delay, make it more
corporate control and the takeover system for expensive or otherwise hinder the takeover
disciplining management did not function operation, which lead to the alternative
efficiently. There are three kinds of reasons management’s withdrawal of the offer.
that explain the limitation in the European A distinctive feature to compensate for the
market for corporate control. First, there are lack of a well-functioning market for corpor-
socio-cultural reasons for this; politicians and ate control in Europe has been the adoption of
managers try to create a climate and a state of codes of good corporate governance. Starting
prevailing opinion against a simple takeover with the Cadbury report in the UK in 1992,
offer that shareholders can accept or reject. In successive countries adopted versions of
this regard, they speak of speculative acquisi- corporate governance norms to improve
tions, hostile attacks, aggression, assaults to corporate governance practices. Norms and
the companies, ‘sharks’ or ‘capitalism without codes of good governance are designed to
soul’. This is highlighted when the takeover is facilitate the establishment of the appropriate
performed by a foreign person or company attitude towards a problem, and the search
(Roe, 1993; Buhmer et al., 1998). for solutions to it. Whereas these codes have
Second, there are reasons linked to the been adopted by most large European corpor-
ownership structure, that is, the weight and ations, their effectiveness in promoting effi-
behaviour of active shareholders, including cient corporate governance has been limited.
institutional investors. Among these, it is Moreover, although the concentrated owner-
important to consider the connection between ship and limited takeover activity of the
the ownership system in Germany and the European system would seem to be more
banking system, the special relationships conducive to longer-term relationships be-
between private and public sectors and the tween the company and its investors, such
cross-shareholdings among companies in concentrated insider ownership can also lead
France, or the high degree of ownership to costly delays in undertaking necessary
concentration in the hands of families, the corrective action, particularly if owners re-
banking system and pyramidal groups in ceive non-monetary benefits from owning

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002 Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002


88 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

and running a business. The existence of core by large shareholders and liquidity, but with
shareholders and the adoption of managerial passive shareholders. The liquidity of mar-
defences that protect both managers and kets has two opposing effects on corporate
incumbent large shareholders have limited governance (Kyle and Vila, 1991). On the one
the efficiency of corporate governance me- hand, it facilitates corporate control, because
chanisms. it allows large shareholders to exit. On the
other hand, liquid markets permit large
shareholders to dispose of shares in the face
Corporate governance in Continental of a drop in price, instead of having to be
Europe: a plea for market control involved in the control of the company. In
mechanisms such a way, ownership dispersion is a pre-
requisite for liquid stock markets, but it
Nowadays, there is a trend towards homo- entails a collective action problem (Becht,
geneity of control systems in the markets, 1999): individual investors have no incentives
with marked movements towards greater to engage in direct monitoring. Empirical
transparency, shareholder empowerment evidence analysing the relationship between
and director oversight in the Anglo-Saxon corporate governance and liquidity indicates
style of corporate governance, and with no a tradeoff between monitoring and liquidity
clear differences among the nations – USA, (Burkart et al., 1997), both in the Anglo-Saxon
UK, Germany, France – in managerial incen- and the Continental European systems.
tives to manage for the short-term or the long- Whereas in the USA many institutional in-
term. Privatisation, the growing presence of vestors deliberately trade-off control against
US investors in Europe and globalisation of liquidity (Coffee, 1991), voting power con-
capital markets are forces propelling initia- centration through blocks had a negative
tives such as more transparent disclosure effect on liquidity in the German and Belgian
standards and raised oversight standards for stock markets (Becht, 1999). Moreover, ‘‘if
boards of directors. Changes in legislation the Netherlands had imposed one-share-one-
facilitate the convergence of corporate gov- vote by law we might have observed con-
ernance systems (Kester, 1996; Berglof, 1997). centrated voting power, concentrated owner-
However, the efficiency of corporate gov- ship and lower levels of liquidity’’ (Becht,
ernance in Continental Europe is limited due 1999, p. 1076).
to the existence of core shareholders and the In Continental Europe, aside from the
adoption of managerial defence mechanisms difficulties faced by corporate governance
that establish barriers to corporate govern- mechanisms to work efficiently, especially in
ance. Only through the adoption of more the market for corporate control, companies
market control measures will corporate gov- actively adopt defensive measures that pro-
ernance improve in Continental Europe. tect not only management, but also large or
core shareholders. These measures, which
introduce restrictions into the market for
Limitations to efficient corporate corporate control, are presented by managers
governance in Continental Europe as necessary for developing stable manage-
The existence of large shareholders in Con- ment of shareholders’ benefits. These man-
tinental Europe has been accompanied by the agerial defensive measures lead to changes in
development of business groups and pyra- by-laws, with the objective of maintaining
midal structures that separate ownership control by means of ‘‘entry barriers’’ that will
from control. By enabling this separation, pyra- limit changes in the control and management
midal groups have facilitated the growth of of the firm.
entrepreneurial projects, and internal capital The behaviour of control shareholders,
markets may have helped deserving projects ‘‘core shareholders’’ or active shareholders
to be financed. However, the perceived risk explains the use of these defence mechanisms.
of expropriation may have imposed severe In most cases, defence mechanisms involve
limits on the overall performance of the system, the defence of minority interests (managers
leading to a dynamic efficiency problem, in and core shareholders), although they are
that the concentration of ownership may have presented as a defence of the general inter-
insufficiently contestable control, hampering ests. Thus proponents of such changes talk of
the efficient selection of controlling agents defences against hostile takeover bids and
(Bianco and Casavola, 1999, p. 1056). external aggression. However, if there is such
Besides the private benefits that are en- hostility, it is against the incumbent manage-
tailed by the presence of large shareholders, ment team and board of directors, certainly
this presence also may result in liquidity not against all the shareholders or the
problems. There is a tradeoff between control company, although this is how it is presented.

Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS 89

At present, empirical evidence suggests that measures (see, for example, Fernández et al.,
managers and control groups use these 1998 for the Spanish market). These findings
defence measures to protect their private show that core investors do not always
interests, rather than to serve the interests of protect all shareholders’ wealth.
shareholders (Jarrell and Poulsen, 1987). This In conclusion, core shareholders may pro-
is a way to maintain control for the manage- vide the benefit of monitoring, but also lead to
ment of the firm who have a small share in less liquid capital markets, the possibility of
the capital and control shareholders who can consumption of perquisites and the achieve-
be compensated through the achievement of ment of voting power that exceeds their cash
their private goals. flow rights. On top of that, they may prevent
Analysis of managerial defence mechan- the existence of an active corporate control
isms and the restrictions of corporate control market that may discipline these large share-
in the market should not be made based on holders, as well as managers, when they do
moral judgments, but on the effects of a not monitor or manage the firm efficiently
system on the creation of value for share- and in the best interests of all shareholders.
holders, the efficiency of the company and the
economy in general. The response to and Solutions to the limitations of the
valuation of these defences that the market Continental European system: not codes
makes will be conditioned by why and when of good governance but market control
they are made. First, defence measures against
a concrete threat in general and preventive
mechanisms
defence measures in general interfere with the The limitations in the European corporate
firm’s ownership structure and, in turn, firm governance system have been addressed
performance. In fact, Cole and Mehran (1998) through the development of codes of good
found that after the anti-takeover provisions governance, a set of ‘‘best practice’’ recom-
expire, insider ownership increases and firm mendations regarding the behaviour and
performance improves significantly. Second, structure of the board of directors (Aguilera
measures established at the outset of the firm and Cuervo-Cazurra, 2000). However, the
might be legal, but one can doubt about their type of legal system limits the efficiency in
compatibility with the by-laws of public the application of the codes of good govern-
firms. This also includes modifications once ance. In common-law countries, or Anglo-
the firm becomes public, which alter rights Saxon countries, which have also adopted the
and the characteristics of shares in ways that codes of good governance, judges can enforce
differ from that which was stated in IPO the use of the codes of good governance
documents (Sánchez Andrés, 1994, p. 37). directly, and these become enforceable regu-
Third measures may depend on the valuation lation once the codes are part of the usual
of the strength of the board of directors, practices of business. Nevertheless, the effec-
although the empirical evidence regarding tiveness of the codes of good governance can
this issue is not conclusive. On the one hand, be questionable. Actually, studies that analyse
Sundaramurthy et al. (1997) find that the per- the wealth effects associated with compliance
ception of the board’s power and the sep- with the Cadbury Report do not find sig-
aration of functions (chairman of the board nificant abnormal returns (Weir and Laing,
and CEO), leads to a less negative reaction 2000). In civil law countries, such as Con-
to this restriction by the market. Similarly, tinental European countries, judges cannot
other studies conclude that the participation enforce the application the codes of good
of external directors limits green-mail pay- governance with the force of regulation. In
ments (Kosnick, 1987) and it supports share- the civil law tradition, laws that guide the
holders’ protection (Kesner and Johnson, behaviour of the firm toward its shareholders
1990). On the other hand, Jarrell and Poulsen can only be developed in the parliaments,
(1987) find a direct relation between the level where practices are codified. The codification
of insider ownership, as well as the presence of new laws that increase the protection of
of certain types of institutional investors, and minority shareholders is possible, but these
the negative wealth effects associated with laws take an inordinate amount of time to
anti-takeover defences. Thus, it is not clear be codified and are not flexible enough to
what the monitoring role played by the board adapt to changing conditions in the corpor-
of directors and core shareholders is when ate governance arena. This characteristic of
the firm decides to adopt defence measures. the legal system results in situations where
Actually, studies conducted in Continental the codes of good governance are applied
European countries, where ownership con- formally following the letter but not the
centration is fairly high, reveal the negative spirit of the law, since they cannot be legally
impact on stock prices of anti-takeover enforced.

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002 Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002


90 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Hence, we argue that rather than extending need fewer morality speeches and less reg-
the use of codes of good governance in civil ulation, constraints that end up harming the
law countries, it is necessary to expand the interests of those they aim to benefit; or, if
realm of action of market control mechan- they are formally complied with, operate in a
isms, avoiding managerial defences and core way that is contrary to the spirit that
shareholders, to facilitate the maximisation of motivated their formulation or enactment
firm value in the market. into law.
Ownership rights are managerial discipline The most effective protection for share-
and stimulus elements. Protection of the holders is to facilitate the exercise of their
rights of shareholders should be centred on rights: access to enough quality information
that simple principle, ‘one share, one vote’, as to evaluate company performance, active
the best guarantee of efficiency. This implies participation in meetings, with stimulation
freedom in the exercise of voting rights, of voting rights and, perhaps, promotion of
access to appropriate information on the per- the culture of the ‘proxy fight’. This might
formance of the company, facilitating the start with institutional investors, whose in-
presentation of proposals to the board of vestment is less mobile since its sale would
directors and the promotion of active mem- affect prices, and who face higher demands
bers of the board of directors to strengthen for a more active role in control. Nevertheless,
its role. The protection of shareholders’ rights as long as institutional investors are part of
benefits the company by attracting investors, the banking system in Continental Europe,
reducing the cost of capital, motivating it is doubtful that they will act as leaders
management by limiting their freedom, and of active shareholders. At this time, the dis-
avoiding the risk of the use of funds in cussion about comparative corporate govern-
unprofitable operations, or outside the control ance, insider versus outsider systems, is still
of the minority shareholders, in search of open (Macey, 1998). The key to resolving it
benefits by reference shareholders. lies not in the existence of institutional in-
Limitations or restrictions to the exercise of vestors with controlling stakes but in the
shareholders’ rights in Continental Europe market for corporate control, which provides
have negative effects, especially since there is a form of continuous monitoring, unlike the
no tradition of proxy fight as there is in the more episodic monitoring of institutional
USA, where shareholders delegate their votes investors. Moreover, it monitors all firms in
to certain people or institutions with the com- the market and not just those in which
mitment of demanding changes in company institutional investors have a significant stake.
management. In Continental Europe, the Hence, all firms are at risk of being taken
widespread delegation of voting in the banks over.
and in the board (chairman) destroys in The literature on corporate governance
practice the board of shareholders’ capacity indicates that the market for corporate control
to be controlled by shareholders. provides for a broader, more effective and
Following this line of thinking, in the more efficient form of monitoring. The litera-
summer of 1995, The Center for European ture also asks why institutional investors
Policy Studies issued a new set of guidelines should get involved in monitoring when they
for corporate governance standards in the could simply diversify their holdings, reduc-
European Union (OEDE, 1998). Among the ing risk. Moreover, it is not at all clear that the
principal recommendations were (Chew, skills required to manage an investment fund
1997, p. 279): (1) one-share one-vote, unless are the same as those required to give good
shareholders approve a dual class structure; advice to firms. If the two sets of skills are
(2) an expansion of shareholders’ voting different – as modern financial theory sug-
rights including the right to vote on the gests – then there are no synergies or scale
election of directors, dividends, capital economies associated with having investors
authorisations and company by-laws; (3) fair actively involved in managing companies.
treatment of minority shareholders in take- Hence, it is necessary to promote the func-
overs; and (4) a greater use of outside direc- tioning of the market for corporate control to
tors capable of exercising independent facilitate the achievement of efficient cor-
oversight. porate governance in the face of core share-
We should place more importance on these holders and managerial defence measures
facts than on formal execution of the good that limit the achievement of maximisation
governance code, if we want to maintain the of firm value.
competitive pressure in all markets, including However, change is not easy. In favour of
the market for corporate control and the the transformation of the Continental Euro-
market for managers. Better market mechan- pean model towards the Anglo-Saxon model
isms and more information are necessary. We we find: (1) the globalisation of markets and

Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS 91

the need to find governance models that be legally enforced. Thus we contend that,
promote efficiency and enable competition rather than extending the use of codes of
in the marketplace; (2) pressures from insti- good governance in civil law countries, it is
tutional investors for change towards the necessary to expand the realm of action of
Anglo-Saxon corporate governance system; market control mechanisms, avoiding man-
and (3) pressure for standardisation of in- agerial defences and core shareholders, to
formation across companies for accessing facilitate the maximisation of firm value in the
international capital markets. Against the market.
movement towards the Anglo-Saxon model The paper has limitations. The discussion
in Continental Europe we find: (1) difficulties has been conducted at a fairly high level of
in changing legal systems and institutions; abstraction; the Anglo-Saxon and Continental
(2) the political power of interest groups, such European systems of corporate governance
as the German lobby, which limited the intro- have been studied as homogeneous systems.
duction of the European Directive on take- However, there are differences across coun-
overs; (3) the culture of the stakeholder model, tries in the two systems that influence the
linked to the Social Democrat ideology prev- particularities of the operation of corporate
alent in Continental Europe; (4) political governance systems. Also, one has to consider
pressure that limits change; and (5) dif- the difficulties involved in comparing and
ferences in development of countries and studying the effectiveness of corporate gov-
markets, which limit homogenisation. ernance structures. The lack of homogenous
databases, the difficulty in identifying truly
independent directors, in measuring voting
Conclusions powers and cash flow rights, and identifying
pyramids, makes this type of research diffi-
Corporate governance serves to create value cult and truly laborious. Moreover, until
in the firm. Corporate governance mechan- recently, the analysis has been centred on the
isms have been devised to facilitate the comparison of market control (Anglo-Saxon)
control of management and groups of power and large shareholder control (Continental
in the firm and facilitate the achievement of European) systems, with little reference to the
maximisation of firm value. However, these alternative systems of the aggregation of
corporate governance mechanisms are far multiple related shareholders that act as one
from perfect. Their efficiency is limited by large shareholder in business group control in
tradeoffs between control of the firm and Asia and Latin America. Further research on
protection of minority shareholders. More- alternative corporate governance systems and
over, institutional differences in the broader their efficiency in control is required.
corporate governance system affect the rela- Despite the differences in corporate gov-
tionship between the shareholder, the board ernance systems, there seems to exist a trend
of directors and managers. The two main towards convergence. This convergence is not
systems of corporate governance, the Anglo- only occurring in developed economies, but
Saxon system of market control, and the Con- also in transition economies, which are
tinental European system of large-shareholder adopting corporate governance mechanisms
control, have developed different ways to re- as they develop their institutions, as well as in
duce the limitations; that is, active institu- developing economies, which face pressure
tional investors in the market control system from international donors for more trans-
and codes of good governance in the large- parent governance systems. This trend toward
shareholder control system. However, an convergence does not imply a movement
analysis of the effectiveness of the Continental towards a single model of corporate govern-
European system in dealing with the en- ance, but a transition towards common guid-
trenchment of managers shows that the large- ing principles of information, transparency
shareholder control system is limited in its and accountability. Variation in national
ability to control core shareholders and contexts, especially in terms of legislation,
managerial defences. institutions the development of capital mar-
Hence, although codes of good governance kets, concentration of ownership and separ-
have been developed in these countries to ation of ownership and control, will sustain
solve corporate governance problems, we differences in corporate governance and con-
argue that rather than using these codes, the trol systems. The degree of convergence
Continental European countries should pro- between models will depend on the political
mote market development. In civil law influence of the interest groups affected, and
countries the codes of good governance can on the political ideology that tries to reenact
be applied formally, following the letter but the stakeholder model in some European
not the spirit of the law, since they cannot countries.

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002 Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002


92 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Acknowledgements Evidence from Texas Banking, Journal of Financial


Economics, 38, 185–210.
This paper was developed while I was a Chew, D. H. (ed.) (1997) Studies in International
Corporate Finance and Governance Systems. New
visiting scholar at New York University.
York: Oxford University Press.
I would like to thank Ingo Walter, Director, Coffee, J. (1991) Liquidity Versus Control: The
and Edward I. Altman, Vice Director of New Institutional Investor as Corporate Monitor,
York University Salomon Center, for their Columbia Law Review, 91, 1277–1388.
invitation and hospitality. The comments of Cohen, R. A. and Meran, H. (1998) The Effect of
the anonymous referee and of Alvaro Cuervo- Changes in Ownership Structure on Perform-
Cazurra of the University of Minnesota and ance: Evidence from the Thrift Industry, Journal
Silvia Gómez Ansón of Universidad de of Financial Economics, 50, 291–317.
Oviedo helped to improve previous versions Cole, R. A. and Mehram, H. (1998) The Effect of
of the paper. All errors remain mine. Changes in Ownership Structure on Perform-
ance: Evidence from the Thrift Industry, Journal
of Financial Economics, 50, 291–317.
Cuervo, A. and Villalonga, B. (2000) Explaining the
References Variance in the Performance Effects of Privatiza-
tion, Academy of Management Review, 25, 581–590.
Aguilera, R. and Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2000) Codes Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (1999) Grandes Accionistas y
of Good Governance Worldwide. Working Paper no. Beneficios Privados: El Caso de Bancos Como
00-105. Illinois: CIBER, University of Illinois at Accionistas de Empresas no Financieras (Large
Urbana Champaign. Shareholders and Private Benefits: The Case of
Barclay, M. J. and Holderness, C. G. (1989) Private Banks as Shareholders of Non-Financial Firms),
Benefits from Control of Public Corporations, Investigaciones Europeas de Dirección y Economı´a de
Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 371–395. la Empresa, 5, 21–44.
Barclay, M. J., Holderness, C. G. and Pontiff, J. Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrund, A. and Johnson, J.
(1993) Private Benefits from Block Ownership (1998) Meta Analytic Reviews of Board Composi-
and Discounts on Closed-End Funds, Journal of tion, Leadership Structure and Financial Perform-
Financial Economics, 33, 293–291. ance, Strategic Management Journal, 19, 269–290.
Baums, T. (1993) Takeover versus institutions in European Corporate Governance Network (1997) Pre-
corporate governance in Germany. In D. D. liminary Report to the European Commission. Brussels:
Prentice and P. R. J. Holland (eds) Contemporary European Corporate Governance Network.
Issues in Corporate Governance. Oxford: Oxford Fama, E. F. (1980) Agency Problems and the
University Press. Theory of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy,
Becht, M. (1999) European Corporate Governance: 88, 288–307.
Trading Off Liquidity Against Control, European Fama, E. F. and Jensen, M. C. (1983a) Agency
Economic Review, 43, 1071–1083. Problems and Residual Claims, Journal of Law
Becht, M. and Roell, A. (1999) Blockholdings in and Economics, 26, 327–349.
Europe: An International Comparison, European Fernández, A. I., Gomez-Anson, S. and Fernandez,
Economic Review, 43, 1049–1056. C. (1998) The effect of board size and com-
Berglof, E. (1997) Reforming Corporate Govern- position on corporate performance. Corporate
ance: Redirecting the European Agenda, Econ- governance. In M. Balling, E. Hennessy and
omic Policy, 24, 91–117. R. O’Brien (eds) Financial Markets and Global
Bianco, M. and Casavola, P. (1999) Italian Corpor- Convergence. Kluwer Academic.
ate Governance: Effects on Financial Structure Franks, J. and Mayer, C. (1997) Corporate Owner-
and Firm Performance, European Economic Re- ship and Control in the U.K., Germany and
view, 43, 1057–1069. France. In D. H. Chew (ed.) Studies in Inter-
Black, B. (1997) Institutional investors and corpo- national Corporate Finance and Governance Systems.
rate governance. In Chew, D. H. (ed.) Studies in New York: Oxford University Press.
International Corporate Finance and Governance Hawley, J. P. and Williams, A. T. (1997) The
Systems. New York: Oxford University Press. Emergence of Fiduciary Capitalism, Corporate
Buhmer, R., Rasheed, A., Rosenstein, J. and Governance, 5, 206–213.
Yoshikawa, T. (1998) Research on corporate Holderness, C. D. and Sheehan, D. P. (1998) The
governance: a comparison of Germany, Japan Role of Majority Shareholders in Publicly Held
and the United States. In J. L. C. Cheng and R. B. Corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, 29,
Peterson (eds) Advances in International Compara- 317–346
tive Management, Vol. 12. Stamford: JAI Press. Jarrell, G. and Poulsen, A. B. (1987) Shark
Burkart, M., Gromb, D. and Panunzi, F. (1997) Repellents and Stock Prices. The Effects of
Large Shareholders, Monitoring and the Value of Antitakeover Amendments since 1980, Journal
the Firm, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 693– of Financial Economics, 19, 127–168.
728. Jensen, M. C. (1986) Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow,
Cadbury Commission (1992) Code of Best Practice: Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, American
Report of the Committee on the Financial Aspects of Economic Review, 76, 323–329.
Corporate Governance. London: Gee and Co. Jensen, M. C. (1993) The Modern Industrial
Canella, A. A., Fraser, D. R. and Lee, D. S. (1995) Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal
Firm Failure and Managerial Labor Markets: Control Systems, Journal of Finance, 48, 831–880.

Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS 93

Kesner, I. F. and Johnson, R. B. (1990) An Sánchez Andrés, A. (1994) Las Cláusulas de


Investigation of the Relationship between Board Blindaje Societario, con Especial Referencia a
Composition and Stockholders Suits, Strategic las Sociedades Cotizadas. (Managerial Defence
Management Journal, 29, 789–799. Mechanisms, with Special Emphasis on Stock
Kester, C. (1996) American and Japanese Corporate Firms), Anales de la Academia Matritense del
Governance: Convergence to Best Practice? In Notariado, 33, 32–53.
S. Berger and R. Dore (eds) National Diversity Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1986) Large Share-
and Global Capitalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Uni- holders and Corporate Control, Journal of Political
versity Press. Economy, 94, 461–489.
Kester, C. (1997) Governance, Contracting, and Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997) A Survey of
Investment Horizons: A Look at Japan and Corporate Governance, Journal of Finance, 52,
Germany. In D. H. Chew (ed.) Studies in Inter- 737–783.
national Corporate Finance and Governance Systems. Sundaramurthy, C., Mahoney, J. M. and Mahoney,
New York: Oxford University Press. J. T. (1997) Board Structure, Antitakeover Provi-
Kosnick, R. D. (1987) Greenmail: A Study of Board sions and Stockholder Wealth, Strategic Manage-
Performance in Corporate Governance, Adminis- ment Journal, 28, 231–245.
trative Science Quarterly, 32, 163–185 Turnbull, S. (1997) Corporate Governance: Its
Kyle, A. S. and Vila, J. L. (1991) Noise Trading and Scope, Concerns and Theories, Corporate Govern-
Takeovers, Rand Journal of Economics, 22, 54–71. ance, 5, 180–205.
La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Useem, M. (1993) Executive Defense. Shareholder
Vishny, R. (1997) Legal Determinants of External Power and Corporate Reorganization. Cambridge,
Finance, Journal of Finance, 3, 1131–1150. MA: Harvard University Press.
La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Weir, C. H. and Laing, D. (2000) The Cadbury
Vishny, R. (1999) Corporate Ownership around Committee and the Governance-Performance Rela-
the World, Journal of Finance, 54, 471–517. tionship: An Empirical Analysis of the Effects of
Levine, V. (1999) Law, Finance, and Economic Cadbury Recommendations on UK Firm Perfor-
Growth, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 8, 8–35. mance. Aberdeen Business School, The Robert
Macey, J. R. (1998) Measuring the Effectiveness of Gordon University, WP.
Different Corporate Governance Systems: To- Zoido, E. (1998) Un Estudio de Participaciones
ward a More Scientific Approach, Journal of Accionariales de los Bancos en Empresas Es-
Applied Corporate Finance, 10, 16–25. pañolas (A Study of Shareholdings of Banks in
Mayer, C. (1996) Corporate Governance, Competition Spanish Firms), Investigaciones Económicas, 22,
and Performance. OECD, Economic Studies, 27. 427–467.
OECD (1998) Corporate Governance: Improving Com-
petitiveness and Access to Capital in Global Markets.
Paris: Organization of Economic Cooperation Alvaro Cuervo is Professor of Business
and Development. Economics at the Complutense University in
Pound, J. (1997) Raiders, Targets, and Politics: The
Madrid. His research interests include cor-
History and Future of American Corporate
Control. In D. H. Chew (ed.) Studies in Inter- porate governance, privatisation and strategic
national Corporate Finance and Governance Systems. management. His current research focuses
New York: Oxford University Press. on the role of the board of directors on the
Roe, M. J. (1993) Some Differences in Corporate corporate governance of the firm and privat-
Structure in Germany, Japan, and the United isation, organisational changes and perform-
States, Yale Law Journal, 102, 1927–2003. ance.

‘‘All too often at the moment company directors feel that they are under a legal duty to put
the short-term interests of shareholders above everything else. What we need is an
approach which allows directors to take a long term view. We intend to amend company
law to allow them to do this.’’

Stephen Byers, currently Minister for Transport, Local Government and the Regions.

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002 Volume 10 Number 2 April 2002

You might also like