You are on page 1of 90

RESEARCH REPORT

Occupational change and


wage inequality:
European Jobs Monitor 2017
Occupational change and
wage inequality:
European Jobs Monitor 2017

European Foundation
for the Improvement of
Living and Working
Conditions
When citing this report, please use the following wording:
Eurofound (2017), Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017, Publications Office of the
European Union, Luxembourg.

Authors: Enrique Fernández-Macías and John Hurley (Eurofound); and José María Arranz-Muñoz (Universidad de
Alcalá)
Research manager: Enrique Fernández-Macías
Eurofound project: European Jobs Monitor
Acknowledgements: The authors would like to thank Andrea Garnero, Stephen Kampelmann, Brian Nolan,
Luis Ortiz, François Rycx, Andrea Salvatori, as well as Eurofound colleagues and members of the Advisory Committee
for Labour Market Change for their very useful input to earlier versions of this report.

Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union


Print: ISBN: 978-92-897-1581-2 ISSN: 2363-0825 doi:10.2806/989106 TJ-AN-17-101-EN-C
Web: ISBN: 978-92-897-1580-5 ISSN: 2363-0833 doi:10.2806/332137 TJ-AN-17-101-EN-N
© European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, 2017
For rights of translation or reproduction, applications should be made to the Director, European Foundation
for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, Wyattville Road, Loughlinstown, Dublin D18 KP65, Ireland.
The European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (Eurofound) is a tripartite
European Union Agency, whose role is to provide knowledge in the area of social, employment and work-related
policies. Eurofound was established in 1975 by Council Regulation (EEC) No. 1365/75 to contribute to the planning
and design of better living and working conditions in Europe.
European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions
Telephone: (+353 1) 204 31 00
Email: information@eurofound.europa.eu
Web: www.eurofound.europa.eu

Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European Union.
Freephone number*: 00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11
*Certain mobile telephone operators do not allow access to 00 800 numbers or these calls may be billed.
Printed in Luxembourg
Cover image: © Shutterstock
Contents

Executive summary 1

Part 1: Shifts in the employment structure 3

1 Labour market context 5


Jobs-based approach: Methodology 8

2 Employment shifts in the EU, 2011–2016 11


Variety of patterns across Member States 12
Recovering labour markets 15
Growing and declining jobs 17

3 Patterns of employment change by sector, employment status and worker characteristics 21


Developments by broad sector: The service transition 21
Atypical employment growing across the wage distribution 24
Core employment share stabilising 25
Growing male share of part-time work 27
Non-natives dominate new employment in lower-paid jobs 27
Summary 29

Part 2: Wage inequality from an occupational perspective 31

4 Background and methodology 33


Methodology 34

5 Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution 37


Initial considerations and theoretical arguments 37
Occupations and wage inequalities: An initial overview 39
Analysing the economic arguments 41
Analysing the sociological arguments 43
Summary 49

6 Occupational wage differentials across European institutional models 51


Varieties of capitalism and occupational wage structures 51
A discussion of country differences 52
Conclusion 55

7 Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality in Europe 57


Introduction 57
Analysis of the role of occupations in the recent evolution of wage inequality 58
Conclusion 63

8 Conclusions 65

Bibliography 67

Annexes 71
Annex 1: Shifts in employment composition 71
Annex 2: Handling of data breaks 72
Annex 3: Comparing employment shifts using different job quality measures 73
Annex 4: Categorisation of the service sector 75
Annex 5: Member State shares of employment in top 12 jobs 76
Annex 6: Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality over three decades 77
Annex 7: Detailed examination of occupations and wage inequality in Spain 80

iii
Country codes
AT Austria FI Finland NL Netherlands
BE Belgium FR France PL Poland
BG Bulgaria HR Croatia PT Portugal
CY Cyprus HU Hungary RO Romania
CZ Czech Republic IE Ireland SE Sweden
DE Germany IT Italy SI Slovenia
DK Denmark LU Luxembourg SK Slovakia
EE Estonia LT Lithuania UK United Kingdom
EL Greece LV Latvia
ES Spain MT Malta

iv
Executive summary
The jobs-based approach was pioneered in the 1990s in
Introduction the USA by Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz and then
During 2016, employment in the EU finally returned to refined by Erik Olin Wright and Rachel Dwyer. The
the same level as before the global financial crisis. The particular question that this earlier American work
recovery that began in 2013 has resulted in the net addressed – was job growth being achieved at the
creation of eight million new jobs. Most of this net new expense of job quality? – has become more nuanced
employment has been created in services, but there has over time. The jobs-based approach has, in particular,
also been a marked rebound in manufacturing been used to assess the extent to which employment
employment, with around 1.5 million new jobs. structures in developed economies are polarising,
This, the sixth annual European Jobs Monitor report, leading to a ‘shrinking’ of mid-paid jobs, or upgrading as
looks in more detail at recent shifts (from the second the supply of highly qualified workers increases. To the
quarter (Q2) of 2011 to 2016 Q2) in employment at extent that employment in some labour markets
Member State and aggregate EU levels. Part 1 of the appears to be polarising, this research also connects
report applies a ‘jobs-based approach’ to describe with broader concerns about increasing inequality.
employment shifts quantitatively (how many jobs were
created or destroyed and in what sectors) and Key findings
qualitatively (what kinds of jobs they were, primarily in
terms of average hourly pay). Part 2, a more analytical Shifts in employment, 2011–2016
section, discusses the role that occupations play in
£ There were eight million more people at work in
structuring European wage inequality, and to what
2016 Q2 in the EU compared with three years
extent the observed patterns of job polarisation and
previously. Employment growth since 2013 has
upgrading have contributed to wage inequality trends
been only modestly skewed towards well-paid jobs.
in the last decade.
There has been robust growth in low-paid and mid-
paid jobs as well, consistent with a
Policy context consumption-led recovery.
£ Over a longer time frame (going back to the late
The EU’s Europe 2020 strategy for smart, sustainable
1990s), higher-paid jobs have continued to grow
and inclusive growth includes a commitment to
faster relative to those in the rest of the wage
fostering high levels of employment and productivity.
distribution. This has been the case in recessionary
This implies a renewed focus on the goals of the earlier
and non-recessionary periods alike.
Lisbon Agenda, ‘more and better jobs’. More jobs are
needed to address the problem of unacceptably high £ More than 7 out of 10 jobs in the EU are now in
unemployment rates. But Europe also needs better and services, a sector that alone has added over 8
more productive jobs if it is to succeed once again in million jobs in the EU since 2011. Recent service
improving living standards for its citizens in an sector employment growth has been
expanding, integrated global economy. The European asymmetrically polarised, with greater gains in jobs
Commission’s 2012 Employment Package (‘Towards a at the top and bottom of the wage distribution.
job-rich recovery’) identifies some sectors in which £ There has also been an increase of 1.5 million in the
employment growth is considered most likely: health manufacturing employment headcount since 2013.
services, information and communications technology, Most of this increase has been in engineering,
and personal and household services, as well as the professional and management jobs in the top wage
promising if hard-to-define category of ‘green jobs’. The quintile and not in more traditional, blue collar
jobs-based approach adopted in this report provides production roles. Proportionately, the EU13
up-to-date data about employment levels and job countries (those that have joined the EU since 2004)
quality in growing and declining sectors and have been the main beneficiaries of net new
occupations. manufacturing employment.

1
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

£ In many of the faster-growing large jobs, the share £ Although there are wide differences across Europe
of older workers has increased significantly, in the levels of wage inequality, occupations
suggesting that extended working lives and later provide a remarkably similar backbone to the
retirement are as important in explaining recent distribution of wages in all countries. The
employment growth as any resurgence of labour distribution of variance in wages between and
market dynamism. within occupations and the hierarchy of
occupational wages (which occupations pay more
Occupational change and wage inequality and which pay less) are essentially the same across
£ Occupations play an important role in the all countries. The actual differences between the
structuring of wage inequality in Europe. This is wages paid by occupations and the extent to which
partly because occupations mediate the effect on they are grouped in broad classes or linked to
wage inequality of other factors such as human differences in human capital are aspects that do
capital, social class and segregation by gender or vary across countries.
age. But occupations have their own effect on wage £ Despite the deepening and generalisation of job
inequality, too, probably as a result of specific polarisation in Europe in the aftermath of the Great
mechanisms such as occupational licensing, Recession, occupational dynamics did not drive
credentialing or apprenticeship systems. wage inequality developments in the last decade.
Changes in the distribution of wages within
occupations were much more consequential for
overall wage inequality trends than changes in the
wages paid by the different occupations or changes
in the occupational structure.

2
Part 1:
Shifts in the employment structure
1 Labour market context
In 2016, somewhat later than in other developed particularly steep contraction of 2008–2013. Secondly,
economies, employment levels in the EU recovered all the recovery has, as recent Commission analysis
the net losses experienced since the global financial indicates, been strongly consumption-led rather than
crisis. Just over 223 million people were in work in the fuelled by export or investment. This has led to
EU in 2008; 223.6 million were in work in 2016.1 At the ‘stronger job creation in the services sector, which is
post-crisis trough in 2013, the number was just over more labour intensive and more reactive to the
215.5 million. dynamics of consumption’ (European Commission,
2016, p. 1). Such employment growth is also likely to
Recessions based on banking crises are steeper, and
have been less productivity-enhancing, which would, in
recovery from them takes longer. Reinhart and Rogoff
part, explain relatively tepid output growth. It is
(2009) estimated that recovery – measured as the
important in this regard to highlight that the analysis in
restoration of gross domestic product (GDP) per head to
this report is based on a headcount approach; given
pre-crisis levels – takes over 7 years following a financial
declines in average hours worked and the increasing
crisis, compared with 4.5 years after a ‘normal’
share of part-time employment, the total number of
recession. GDP per head in the EU as a whole had
hours worked by EU workers was still nearly 2% lower in
returned to 2008 levels in 2015.2 Using aggregate EU
2016 Q2 compared to 2008 Q2.
employment headcount as a labour market indicator
leads to broadly similar conclusions. It has taken 7–8 The recent boost in employment levels is reflected in
years to get back to a pre-crisis level. higher levels of labour market participation, higher
employment rates and declining unemployment rates.
There has nonetheless been sustained employment
Demographic factors, however, no longer offer the
growth since the second quarter (Q2) of 2013, which has
boost to employment levels that they once did. Since
been broadly shared across Member States. The EU
2010, the working age population in the EU has begun
added some 8 million net new jobs between 2013 Q2
to contract at an annual average of 0.15% after rising at
and 2016 Q2, of which 3.8 million were created between
an annual average of 0.32% between 2000 and 2010. In
2015 Q2 and 2016 Q2. Even though the aggregate
Germany, the combination of sustained labour demand
employment headcount in the EU has been restored to
and contracting supply has contributed to a very tight
the pre-crisis level, the composition of employment has
labour market (the unemployment rate fell to 4% in
altered significantly over the last eight years. This report
2016 Q3).
seeks to describe these changes and then to use the
‘jobs-based approach’ to add further detail on how Given a very similar stock of EU employment headcount
shifts in employment (for example, by country, sector, in 2008 and 2016, it is an obvious but nonetheless
gender, working time or contractual status) are shared interesting exercise to compare what has changed over
across the wage or job quality distribution. the crisis and post-crisis periods. Periods of crisis in
particular are associated with rapid shifts in
In some respects, the gathering momentum of job
employment composition as some sectors and
creation in recent years is unexpected; net employment
occupations are disproportionately impacted by the
expansion of 1.7% per annum – as recorded between
selective nature of job destruction during downturns.
2015 Q2 and 2016 Q2 – results normally from above-par
This was clearly the case in 2008–2010 when the
output growth. But real EU output growth has only
manufacturing and construction sectors together
intermittently, and then very marginally, passed above
accounted for all the net employment declines suffered
2% over a long period, going back to 2008. Why has
in the earliest and severest years of the crisis. As Figure 1
employment growth surpassed output growth? Two
confirms, the employment shares of construction and
possible explanations can be advanced. Firstly, just as
manufacturing remain much reduced in nearly every
employers hoard labour at the onset of a recession, they
Member State, notwithstanding three years of
may hesitate to hire at the onset of a recovery until such
employment growth. The primary sector (agriculture
time as they consider it established. From this
and mining principally) also represents a declining
perspective, much of the recent job growth arises, for
share of employment in most countries – rapidly
example, from deferred hiring decisions or from delayed
declining in the case of Croatia, Poland, Portugal,
recovery in cyclical sectors strongly affected by the
Romania and Slovenia.

1 EU-LFS data for France since 2014 include employment in overseas departments (départements d’outre-mer, DOM), amounting to over 500,000 people. To
ensure compatibility over time, DOM employment has been excluded in all analysis in this report.

2 In the 19 Member States of the euro zone (EA19) and the 15 Member States that joined before 2004 (EU15), the recovery has taken even longer; 2016 data
should, when available, indicate full recovery.

5
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 1: Percentage point change in composition of employment, by Member State and main sector
(2008 Q2–2016 Q2), and service sector employment share, by Member State (2016 Q2)

10 100
8 90
6 80
4 70
Percentage points

2 60
0 50 %
-2 40
-4 30
-6 20
-8 10
-10 0

Primary Manufacturing Construcon Services Services share (right-hand axis)

Note: The percentage point change in composition of employment is plotted on the left-hand axis, and the percentage of service sector
employment is plotted on the right-hand axis.
Source: EU-LFS (authors’ calculations)

The counterpart of these declines has been the jobs in recent years, employment remains 8% below its
increased share of service sector employment in all pre-crisis level.
Member States. Services now account for 71% of EU
The construction sector is one that is typically
employment. In some Member States (Austria, Germany
considered more cyclically sensitive – employment
and Hungary), the shift to services has been quite
tends to grow in upturns and decline in downturns –
modest (less than 2.25 percentage points), but in 13
and more labour intensive, but the evidence of recent
Member States, the shift has been notably sharper
years is surprising for different reasons. Firstly, the
(more than 5 percentage points). These can be roughly
contracting employment share of construction appears
divided into two groups. In the first group are those
to be a common pattern across nearly all Member
Member States, already indicated above, where the
States, notwithstanding how differently the crisis
main recomposition of employment has been away
affected individual Member States, in terms of both the
from the relatively large primary sector to the service
severity of output declines and the core role played by
sector. In the second group – which includes the Baltic
construction in these declines in some countries such as
states, Cyprus, Ireland and Spain – sharp employment
Ireland, Latvia and Spain. Secondly, employment in the
falls in the manufacturing and construction sectors
sector has recovered even more slowly post-2013 than
explain in large part the increasing services share of
has been the case in manufacturing. The resumption of
employment.
economic growth has not, so far, been accompanied by
Manufacturing employment has been in secular decline the rebound in construction sector employment that
in advanced economies for over 40 years as a result of might have been expected. There were nearly 20%
the twin influences of technological innovation (capital fewer (3.7 million) construction sector jobs in the EU in
replacing labour) and trade (globalisation and the 2016 compared to 2008. What explains this contraction?
replacement of domestic labour by foreign labour). This Clearly one factor was the over-exuberant and, in
secular decline has tended to manifest itself as stable retrospect, unsustainable growth of the sector in the
employment levels in periods of economic growth, pre-crisis years in some countries. The construction
followed by sharp contractions in downturns. That employment share rose to nearly double its long-term
historical pattern has been repeated, to some extent, average in countries such as Ireland and Spain. Much of
over the last eight years. The manufacturing sector in the subsequent job loss was a reversion to the mean.
the EU employed 41.1 million people in 2008 Q2, 36.2
million in 2013 Q2 and 37.7 million in 2016 Q2; so while
there has been some recovery of lost manufacturing

6
Labour market context

Table 1: Labour market indicators, EU

2016 Change 2008–2016


EU (%) (percentage points)
Employment rate (20–64-year-olds) 71.1 0.6
Gender employment gap 8.1 -2.5
Part-time share of employment 20.5 2.3
Older worker (55+ years) share of employment 18.6 4.6
High-skilled white collar worker share of employment* 41.0 1.8

* ‘High-skilled white collar worker’ refers to International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO) main groups 1, 2 and 3 (managers,
professionals and associate professionals). Change data for this indicator are for 2011–2016 only due to a classification break.
Note: For full national data, see Annex 1.
Source: EU-LFS (authors’ calculations)

But the generality of the decline in construction In addition to the already noted increasing share of
employment across countries also suggests other employment in the service sector, the main changes
factors may be in play. Perhaps there is a more identified are:
technological explanation, based on increasing capital
£ an increasing share of older workers, arising from
investment and decreasing labour intensiveness in the
the compound effects of declining youth
sector. Other possible factors include: demographic
participation and employment, reduced early
trends, notably declining rates of population growth;
withdrawal possibilities and later retirement;
decreasing levels of public investment, including
expenditure on public housing; and the declining £ an increasing incidence of part-time work, arising
affordability of housing for the cohort of household- from a significant replacement of (mainly male) full-
forming age. time employment by new part-time employment
(shared more or less evenly by gender);
The workforce has changed across a number of other
£ a declining gender employment gap;
dimensions as well. Table 1 presents the most
important shifts in workforce composition – in the sense £ an increasing share of employment in white collar
that similar changes are likely to have occurred in all, or occupations requiring generally high skill levels
a very large majority, of Member States. (managers, professionals and associate
professionals), reflecting both patterns of labour
demand skewed towards services and higher skills
and the ‘natural’ upgrading of the workforce as older
workers retire and younger cohorts, with higher
average qualifications, enter the labour market.

Figure 2: Employment rates of 20–64-year-olds, by Member State, 2008 Q2–2016 Q2

85

80

75

70
%
65

60

55

50

2008 Q2 Minimum 2008–2016 2016 Q2

Source: EU-LFS (Eurostat website)

7
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

However, the starting point for this study is the shifting


composition of employment by country within the EU
Jobs-based approach:
(Figure 2). The crisis and post-crisis periods have been Methodology
experienced very differently across the labour markets The approach in Part 1 of the report is to focus on:
of Member States. In two larger Member States, whose
labour market performance has, in living memory, seen £ how the structure of employment in Europe has
each labelled as the ‘sick man of Europe’, nearly five changed in recent years (2011 Q2–2016 Q2 3);
million net new jobs were created between 2008 Q2 and £ what implications this has had for aggregate
2016 Q2. Labour markets in both Germany (+2.9 million) employment quality;
and the UK (+2 million) recovered early from the crisis £ how the compositional changes already indicated
and account for the lion’s share of net new jobs in the (for example, increasing part-time or a higher share
EU. Both have met and comfortably surpassed the EU of women in the workforce) have contributed to
target of a 75% employment rate. They share this these changes.
achievement with a number of other northern and
central European Member States including the Czech To do this, the ‘job’ is taken as the unit of analysis.
Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Lithuania, the Netherlands A ‘job’ is defined here as a given occupation in a given
and Sweden. sector – such as a customer service worker in the retail
sector or a health professional (doctor) in the health
Accentuating the geographical shift of employment sector. This is an intuitively attractive definition and
from south to north is the still largely unrepaired corresponds to what people would consider when
destruction of employment in many southern Member describing their job, or to how an employer advertises a
States. Spain has shed more than 2.3 million jobs over new job opening.
the same period, while Greece and Romania have both
shed over 900,000 jobs and Portugal over 500,000. In the This definition is useful for both theoretical and
case of Greece, Portugal and Spain, the severity of the empirical reasons. The two concepts of occupation and
crisis and the consequences of the policies undertaken sector correspond to two fundamental dimensions of
to confront it explain much of the job attrition. In the the division of labour within and across organisations.
case of Romania, the net job loss appears to have as The sectoral classification designates the horizontal
much a demographic as an economic basis. In common distribution of economic activities within a country
with some other eastern European Member States – across organisations generating different products and
Bulgaria, Latvia and Lithuania – as well as Portugal, the services. The occupational classification provides an
overall population has declined, and a disproportionate implicit hierarchy of within-organisation roles – senior
share of that contraction has been among people of managers, line managers, professionals, associate
working age, indicative of significant net emigration. professionals, production staff and so on. Established
international classifications, such as ISCO (for
While the divergences noted above are stark, and occupation) and the Statistical Classification of
particularly so within the euro zone Member States, the Economic Activities in the European Community (NACE)
most recent period of employment growth since 2013 (for sector), mean that it is relatively easy to
has seen some sustained recovery in most of the operationalise the jobs-based approach using the
Member States whose labour markets suffered most standard labour market data sources, such as the EU
during the crisis period. Employment levels have risen Labour Force Survey (EU-LFS). This provides a highly
faster in Spain in the period 2013 Q2–2016 Q2 (+6.6% detailed disaggregation of the workforce in each
increase) compared with the EU as a whole (+3.7%). This country based on commonly applied occupational and
has also been the case for Ireland (+7.8%), Greece sectoral classifications to ensure international
(+4.7%) and Portugal (+4%) as well as for Estonia and comparability.
Lithuania, where the crisis began earlier and the
recovery is more established. As Figure 2 confirms, The jobs-based approach requires not only the
employment rates in each of these countries rose definition of a job in an intuitive, conceptually coherent
substantially from their post-crisis minima. For some and empirically practical way but also some means of
countries, notably Greece and Spain, these are just the evaluating these jobs in relation to their quality. The
first steps towards the normalisation of labour markets. job-wage has been the main proxy of job quality in
Most of the jobs lost in these two countries during 2008– much jobs-based analysis, originating in the work of
2013 have not been recovered, and unemployment Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz in the 1990s (CEA, 1996)
rates remain high (23% and 19% respectively, 2016 Q4). and subsequently refined by Erik Olin Wright and Rachel

3 In most of the charts of Part 1, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2 is the time frame used. Revision of the ISCO classification in 2010–2011 to ISCO-08 means that figures
relating to earlier periods are based on job rankings using the older ISCO-88 classification. Occasionally, shorthand reference in the text is made to
2011–2013 and 2013–2016; unless otherwise noted, figures are based on second-quarter data from the relevant year.

8
Labour market context

Dwyer (2003) and others. The analysis that follows relies level is also provided using education- and job-quality-
mainly on a wage-based measure to rank jobs, but some based rankings for comparison (see Annex 3).
overview of recent employment shifts at EU aggregate

Box 1: Methodological note on the jobs-based approach


The main, simplified steps of the jobs-based approach are as follows:
1. Using the standard international classifications of occupation (ISCO-08) and sector (NACE Rev 2.0) at two-
digit level, a matrix of jobs is created in each country. Each job is an occupation in a sector. In total, there are
43 two-digit occupations and 88 two-digit sectors, which generate 3,784 job cells. In practice, many of the
theoretical job cells do not contain employment; there are unlikely to be many skilled agricultural workers in
financial services, for example. The country total of job cells with employment varies between around 400
and just over 2,000 and is largely determined by country size and labour force survey sample size. The bigger
the workforce, the greater the variety of possible job combinations that can be identified using LFS data.
2. The jobs in each country are ranked based on some ranking criterion, mainly the mean hourly wage. The job-
wage rankings for each country used in this report are based on combining data from the EU-LFS annual data
files for 2011–2014 and aggregated data from the Structure of Earnings Survey (SES) for 2010. These sources
allowed the creation of country job-wage rankings for the 28 Member States.
3. Jobs were allocated to quintiles in each country based on the job-wage ranking for that country. The best-
paid jobs are assigned to quintile 5, the lowest-paid to quintile 1. Each quintile in each country should
represent as close as possible to 20% of employment in the starting period – in other words, jobs are
assigned to quintiles based on their employment weights. From this point on, the job-to-quintile assignments
remain fixed for each country so that, in all of the charts that follow in Part 1 of this report, a given quintile in
a given country (however broken down) always refers to employment data in a specific group of jobs
exclusive to that quintile. For presentation purposes, the focus then is shifted to the change in the stock of
employment at quintile level during a given period in each country (for example, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2).
Figure 3 illustrates in simplified format the three steps outlined above, using some of the top-paid and lowest-
paid jobs that employ large numbers at EU level as examples. (While the jobs are correctly assigned in terms of EU
quintile, the individual job-wage ranks, 1–4 and 1,105–1,108, are for illustrative purposes only.)

Figure 3: Job rankings and quintile assignments carried out for each country

Rank Sector Occupation


1 Financial services Corporate managers
2 Legal/accounting activities Other professionals
3 Education Teaching professionals
4 Human health activities Life science and health professionals
... ...
... ...
1,105 Agriculture Skilled agricultural/fishery workers
1,106 Services to buildings Sales/services elementary occupations
1,107 Education Sales/services elementary occupations
1,108 Food manufacture Craft workers

Quintile 1 Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 Quintile 5


Low-paid 20% Mid-low-paid Mid-paid Mid-high-paid High-paid 20%

9
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

4. Net employment change between starting and concluding periods (in people employed) for each quintile in
each country is summed to establish whether net job growth has been concentrated in the top, middle or
bottom of the employment structure. This generates a series of charts similar to Figure 4. Except where
otherwise indicated, all charts in the report describe net employment change by quintile for the indicated
country or for the EU as a whole. The EU aggregate charts are based on applying a common EU job-wage
ranking (based on the weighted average of the standardised national job-wage rankings).
The resulting quintile charts give a simple, graphical representation of the extent of employment change in a
given period, as well as an indication of how that change has been distributed across jobs with different pay.
(A similar classification of jobs can be carried out using job-holders’ skills or a broad-based, multidimensional
indicator of job quality as a ranking criterion – see Annex 3.) Figure 4, for example, illustrates employment change
for the EU28 during 2011 Q2–2016 Q2 using the job-wage quintiles. The figure should be read from the leftmost
bar cluster (quintile 1, representing the lowest-paid jobs) to the rightmost cluster (quintile 5, representing the
highest-paid jobs). Net employment change is represented on the vertical axis, generally in thousands but
sometimes in annual percentage change. The dominant feature of the chart is the addition of around 3.9 million
well-paid (top-quintile) jobs over the period.

Figure 4: Net employment change (in thousands) by job-wage quintile, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2

4,000

3,000

2,000

1,000

0
Low-paid Mid-low-paid Mid-paid Mid-high-paid High-paid

Note: EU27 (Luxembourg data omitted); Q2 data in each year.


Source: EU-LFS (authors’ calculations)

This method also offers further possibilities of breaking down these net employment changes by such categories
as gender, employment or professional status, or working time category (full time or part time), which are used
later in Part 1. For a more extensive description of the data processing involved, see Annex 3. Further background
documentation includes Eurofound (2008b), as well as extensive material in the annexes of previous European
Jobs Monitor (EJM) annual reports – see Eurofound (2008a, 2011, 2013, 2014, 2015b) – where the same jobs-based
approach was used.
For the jobs-based approach to characterise employment shifts accurately, an important condition is that the
ordinal ranking of a job – whether that ranking is based on hourly wage, educational level of the job-holder or
some broader index of job quality – remains stable over the period covered. In practice, there is a high level of
correlation of job-based rankings over time – health professionals in the health sector tend to be in the top
quintile and cleaners and helpers in the services to buildings sector tend to be in the bottom quintile in most
periods – and across countries.

10
2 Employment shifts in the EU,
2011–2016
This chapter uses the jobs-based approach to describe As the figure illustrates, new employment since 2013
employment developments by job-wage quintile has been more evenly spread across the wage
primarily during the period from 2011 Q2 to 2016 Q2. distribution, with only a mild skew towards the top
Overall trends in the EU are looked at first, with the quintile. Employment grew in each of the job-wage
varying patterns of change in the individual Member quintiles during 2013–2016. As aggregate economic and
States then described. It goes on to examine the labour market performance has begun to normalise
individual jobs contributing to the shifting patterns at (since 2013), the sharpened employment polarisation
EU level. observed during the period of employment contraction
has given way to more balanced growth during 2013–
The five-year period between 2011 Q2 and 2016 Q2
2016. Overall, aggregate growth continues to be
divides naturally into two periods. The earlier period of
modestly upgrading, and the relative performance by
employment decline coincides with the second, so-
quintile remains similar before and after 2013, and
called ‘double-dip’, recession following the global
indeed going back to the late 1990s – employment
financial crisis and covers the period 2011 Q2– 2013 Q2
growth has been consistently strongest in the top
in this report’s analysis. This is broadly also the period
quintile, followed by the lowest and mid-high quintiles
of the sovereign debt crisis, tightening budgetary
and with weakest growth in the middle and mid-low
supervision and contracting public budgets. Some 1.2
quintiles.
million job losses were added to the 5 million previously
lost during the global financial crisis period (2008– Employment continued to grow in well-paid, high-
2010). As already noted, 2013 Q2 marks a turning point, skilled jobs in the top quintile throughout 2008–2013,
and the most recent three-year period has seen some although at a more modest pace than in the long period
significant employment growth, with approximately of employment expansion that preceded the 2008
eight million net new jobs created in the EU. Figure 5 global financial crisis. Bottom-quintile employment also
shows employment shifts by wage quintile for the EU as tended to be more resilient than that in the middle
a whole for 2011–2013 and 2013–2016 as well as for quintiles, suffering relatively modest losses.
earlier periods based on previous EJM analyses.

Figure 5: Employment change (% per annum) by job-wage quintile, EU,* 1998–2016

1998–2007 2008–2010 2011–2013 2013–2016

2 2 2 2

0 0 0 0

-2 -2 -2 -2

-4 -4 -4 -4

* Different EU country aggregates and periodisations due to data availability as follows: 1998–2007, EU23 (no data for Cyprus, Malta, Poland or
Romania), based on annual EU-LFS data; 2008–2010, EU27 (no data for Croatia); 2011–2016, EU27 (data for Luxembourg omitted).
Note: For all periods from 2008, figures are based on Q2 data in each year, extracted from EU-LFS in November 2016, and may differ slightly from
previously reported figures due to data revisions.
Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

11
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

The consistent feature of employment shifts over all routine clerical and manufacturing or production jobs).
periods is the relative outperformance of the top These happen to predominate in the middle of the wage
quintile. Well-paid jobs have added employment even distribution in developed economies (Autor et al, 2006).
during the peak crisis period (2008–2010) and Less-routine jobs – for instance, personal services at the
contribute disproportionately in all periods to overall bottom of the wage distribution, such as hairdressers or
employment growth. A secondary recurring pattern restaurant workers, and knowledge-intensive
across the four periods is the relative weakness of professional services at the top, such as lawyers or
employment growth in the mid-low and middle medical doctors – are less easy to automate and
quintiles, though the resulting pattern of employment therefore less vulnerable to replacement.
polarisation was clearest during the recessionary period
A sometimes complementary, sometimes distinctive,
and has been much attenuated in the most recent
explanation emphasises the role of international trade
period (2013–2016). In summary, while one can certainly
and its differential effects on the employment structure.
make a case that employment polarisation has occurred
The less-routine jobs indicated above involve services
in each of the four periods covered, the dominant shift
that generally have to be carried out in person or in a
has been one of employment upgrading favouring
particular place. Offshoring them or performing them
growth in well-paid jobs.
remotely is often not feasible. They may, additionally,
be subject to specific national occupational licensing
Variety of patterns across frameworks, particularly, for example, higher-skilled
occupations in the health or professional services
Member States sectors. For these reasons, such jobs enjoy some
Until recently, the debate about shifts in the protection from the threats of both technological and
employment structure in developed economies was trade displacement. More routine administrative,
largely focused on two main patterns of change – clerical or manufacturing jobs may not benefit to the
upgrading and polarisation. Each has its own same extent from these protections and are, as a result,
supporting narrative – ‘skill-biased technological more vulnerable to displacement.
change’ in the case of upgrading and ‘routine-biased While the academic literature on structural shifts in
technological change’ in the case of polarisation. employment in developed market economies tends to
Upgrading shifts should lead to a linear improvement in give more weight to technological change as the main
employment structure, with the greatest employment determinant of shifts (Goos et al, 2009), there has also
growth in high-paid (or high-skilled) jobs and the been important recent analysis that emphasises the role
weakest growth in low-paid (or low-skilled) jobs, with of import competition from China, for example, in the
middling growth in the middle. With polarisation, the rapid decline of American manufacturing employment,
main difference is that the relative positions of the especially after China’s entry into the World Trade
middle and bottom of the job distribution are swapped: Organization in 2001 (Autor et al, 2016). More generally,
employment growth is weakest in the middle and the decline of developed-world employment in
relatively stronger at both ends of the job-wage manufacturing sectors clearly arises out of a
distribution, leading to a ‘shrinking’ or ‘hollowed’ combination of competition from low-cost economies
middle. (trade) and technology, with trade arguably the more
important factor in, for example, traditionally labour-
In both accounts (skill-biased technological change and intensive sectors relying on basic skills, such as textiles
routine-biased technological change), the principal and clothing.
driver of employment change is technology, and its
principal effect is to increase the demand for skilled Previous EJM annual reports have drawn attention to
labour in developed economies at the expense of less- other important factors likely to have a bearing on the
skilled labour. Higher skills levels endow those who changing shape of employment in advanced market
possess these skills with the capacities to utilise and economies, whose importance is often overlooked.
master new technologies. This should enhance their These factors are discussed briefly next.
individual productivity. But while technology tends to
complement those with higher skills, it is more likely to Role of the state as employer
substitute those with lower skills, whose job tasks are In terms of direct impact on the employment structure,
more easily replaceable by machines. perhaps the most important policy dimension relates to
the state’s role as an employer. In most Member States,
The main explanation of the differences in the two
the state accounts directly or indirectly for between
accounts relates to where in the wage distribution – at
15% and 35% of employment. In sectors such as health,
the bottom or in the middle – those jobs most
education and public administration, policy decisions –
susceptible to technological displacement lie.
whether to reduce or expand public expenditure on
Exponents of routine-biased technological change claim
such services – have a very direct bearing on the shape
that the most vulnerable jobs are routine jobs with a
of overall employment shifts, especially as labour
high share of easily codifiable tasks (for example,

12
Employment shifts in the EU, 2011–2016

demand in these sectors tends to be biased towards four European countries showing how the evolution of
higher skills. In the period of peak austerity (2010–2013), the employment structure (in terms similar to those
there was a very clear shift in employment growth from used in the EJM – so in terms of the distribution of net
public to private services and a notable contraction (of new employment across the wage structure) was closely
over one million jobs or 6% of employment), in correlated with the evolution of skills supply.
particular, in public administration employment in the
Increasing labour mobility and migration: Migration
EU (Eurofound, 2014).
and cross-border labour mobility generate new forms of
labour supply in the destination countries. Intra-EU
Labour supply
labour mobility has, for example, increased, and some
The orthodox labour economics explanations of 12% of the EU labour force were born in a Member State
changing job structure (skill- or routine-biased other than the one where they reside and work. The
technological change, or trade/globalisation) are absolute level of intra-EU migrant labour (using those
demand-side explanations indicating why demand for employed workers born in a country other than the
specific types of labour, jobs and tasks in developed reporting country as a proxy) has increased from
economies is being altered by the impacts of new 5.7 million people in 2008 to 7.3 million in 2016, but this
technologies, computerisation or international figure is still lower than the number of workers of
competition. But, partly in response to these changes, non-EU origin working in the Member States
the quality and quantity of labour being supplied to (13 million).4 Migrant labour tends, especially initially,
employers is changing rapidly. It is reasonable to expect to work in lower-paid jobs, regardless of the
that the availability of new types of worker affects the qualifications of the job-seeker or job-holder. Between
job creation decisions of employers. Three particular 2011 and 2015, non-native employment increased in
dimensions of the change in labour supply are each of the lower four quintiles in the EU, with the
especially worth noting: increased female participation strongest growth in the lowest quintile (Eurofound,
in the labour market, educational upgrading, and 2016a, p. 11), while it decreased in each of the same
increasing labour mobility and migration. Why and how quintiles for native workers. Similarly, migrant inflows
are these changes related to changes in the have been the most important component of low-paid
employment structure? employment growth in the UK (1991–2008) and in the
Increased female participation: Women and men tend USA during the 1990s, contributing to the polarised
to work in different types of jobs. For this reason, the patterns of employment growth in both countries
majority of men and women work in sectors that are (Wright and Dwyer, 2003; Oesch, 2015).
either predominantly male (for example, construction
or manufacturing) or predominantly female (for Labour market regulation
example, personal care or education). The increase in Employment protection legislation and minimum wage
female jobs can be seen particularly in the growth of the legislation are particularly likely to affect the demand
‘care economy’ (Dwyer, 2013) as many care activities for lower-paid jobs (Fernández-Macías, 2012a; Oesch,
previously provided informally within families have 2013). Employment deregulation has been a common
been formalised in paid jobs. These include many of the policy response to joblessness among the low-skilled
sectors (such as health and residential care) with the following the OECD jobs study recommendations
highest employment growth rates in developed (OECD, 1994), and this may have contributed to
economies over the last two generations and where, boosting employment growth in lower-paid sectors.
due to demographic shifts, demand is forecast to
continue expanding. Labour taxation
Educational upgrading: Higher-skilled workers can Most labour tax codes are progressive to some extent,
perform a broader variety of tasks and jobs. One of the with lighter tax burdens on lower-paid workers. This
Europe 2020 strategic objectives is to raise the may boost the supply of such workers – and possibly
proportion of 30–34-year-olds with a third-level degree demand for them, to the extent that low income tax is
or equivalent qualification to 40% by 2020. In 2015, the accompanied by reduced levels of employer payroll or
share was already 38.7%, up from 23.6% in 2002 social security contributions. Additional tax-based
(Eurostat, 2016). The availability of a sharply rising share incentives – such as working tax credits – operate in a
of highly qualified workers responds to employer similar way, implicitly subsidising lower-paid
demands for specific types of labour but also induces employment.
fresh demand itself. Oesch (2013) presented data from

4 This excludes Germany, where LFS data on the nationality or origin of respondents do not enable differentiation between EU and non-EU migrant
workers.

13
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Collective representation (2007) highlighted that patterns of employment


Different modes of collective representation or levels of polarisation in the UK were regionally differentiated and
union coverage may also play a role, particularly in their much sharper, for example, in London than in the rest of
potential to mitigate the raw impact of market forces on the UK.
decisions affecting employment. In practice, it has not
Inequality and consumption spillovers
been easy to demonstrate empirically such effects
(Eurofound, 2014). In earlier work, Nellas and Olivieri Growing income inequality, related to the
(2012) developed a model of labour demand responses disproportionate share of growth accruing to larger
to technological change where the inclusion of metropolitan areas, may also have a role in the
collective bargaining parameters was able to account changing distribution of employment across
for the substantial differences in the growth of the occupations, notably via consumption spillover effects.
employment share of low-paid work between 1988 and Increasing demand from time-poor, income-rich
2004 in the USA (where it increased) and European workers generates fresh employment in low-skilled
countries (where it was stable). Their conclusion was services (such as in restaurants, households and
that higher union coverage impedes the destruction of cleaning or laundry services). Mazzolari and Ragusa
mid-paid jobs and thereby labour supply to lower-paid (2013) estimated that ‘this channel may explain one-
jobs. This can result in higher unemployment, as in their third of the growth of [US] employment of non-college
model. It could also induce other more positive workers in low-skill services in the 1990s’.
outcomes, however. A specific counter-example is
Sweden, which over many decades has had a
Stages of economic development
consistently upgrading employment structure While there are common trends in the employment
(Eurofound, 2015a), high employment and low structure in developed countries (principally
unemployment as well as high levels of collective occupational upskilling and the service transition), not
representation. all countries are at the same stage of development.
Processes of catch-up and convergence mean that some
Welfare regimes countries may experience much swifter bouts of
Unemployment benefit systems indirectly establish sectoral or occupational transformation than others in a
reservation wage levels and may thus alter the demand given period. Within the EU, the share of employment in
for labour, again primarily for jobs at the bottom of the agriculture, for example, declined in 2016 to just over
wage structure. Active labour market policy is also 1% in the UK from 1.6% in 2000, while in Poland over
salient as supported employment for job-seekers is the same period, it declined from 19% to 10%.
more likely to be in lower-paid jobs. More generally,
welfare regimes channel the development of particular
Stages of the business cycle
types of job in different ways, with the state, the market Recessions are generally periods of accelerated job
or the family assuming greater importance in, for destruction that affect sectoral employment
example, the provision of lower-paid interpersonal differentially. All of the net employment losses in the EU
services in, respectively, social democratic, liberal or between 2008 and 2010 were accounted for by just two
conservative welfare regimes (Esping-Andersen, 1990). sectors – manufacturing and construction. Jaimovich
This has impacts on the cost and volume of formal paid and Siu (2012) made a related point when they
employment in these (increasingly important) services demonstrated that recent employment polarisation in
and thereby on the evolution of employment shares the USA is largely explained by the concentrated
(Oesch, 2015). destruction of routine, mid-paying jobs that occurs
during recessions. The jobs that disappear do not
Metropolitan concentration subsequently reappear during jobless recoveries. They
Well-paid jobs are increasingly likely to be found in also point out that, in the USA at least, not all of this job
larger cities. This is reflected in patterns of regional and destruction was concentrated in manufacturing and
international mobility in which the overwhelmingly construction – which they describe as ‘cyclically
favoured destinations are capital cities or larger sensitive goods-producing sectors’ – and that it was
metropolitan areas. The two NUTS 5 regions with the routine occupations in these and many service sectors
greatest inflows of residents who had moved from that accounted for the recessionary job attrition.
another country in the preceding year were London
(197,000) and Paris (94,000) (Eurostat, 2015). Kaplanis

5 Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics – a geographical nomenclature subdividing the territory of the EU into regions.

14
Employment shifts in the EU, 2011–2016

Levels of economic growth expect much variation between countries. As the next
Employment upgrading is likely to accompany stronger section indicates, this is what is found for the period
output growth, to the extent that a growing share of 2011–2016 and what earlier EJM analysis has
more productive workers should lead to greater output documented going back to the mid-1990s.
(everything else being equal). This theoretical
prediction was supported by empirical evidence from Recovering labour markets
an application of the jobs-based approach to recent
employment data from the EU and six developed The employment recovery post-2013 is now well
economies (Eurofound, 2015a). Employment shifts were established, with eight million net new jobs created
much more likely to be upgrading in countries across the EU. In Figure 6, this is evident in the
experiencing periods of higher growth, for example in predominance of positive employment growth by
Australia (2001–2010), China (2005–2010), Russia (2000– quintile and country in the 2013–2016 period (orange)
2008) and South Korea (2001–2008), while employment compared with the earlier period of 2011–2013 (blue),
polarisation was more characteristic of countries the period of double-dip recession.
experiencing weaker growth (the EU, the USA and Japan At EU aggregate level, net employment gains after 2013
during various recent periods). have been more broadly shared across the quintiles,
though with a customary skew to higher-paid jobs.
Modes of economic development Around 2.7 million of the net job creation since 2013 has
The varieties of capitalism literature list some of the been in well-paid, top-quintile jobs, but there have also
factors already cited as associated with either side of its been gains of between 830,000 and 1.6 million jobs in
core differentiation between liberal market economies each of the remaining quintiles. During 2011–2013,
(such as the UK and the USA) and coordinated market employment contracted in all quintiles except the top
economies (such as Germany, Japan and Sweden). Each quintile. Employment growth has, in effect, spread
generates distinctive forms of comparative advantage down the wage distribution during the recovery,
favouring the development of specific sector consistent with a consumption-led recovery raising
specialisations – manufacturing in the case of demand in particular for lower-level, non-tradeable
coordinated market economies and services, services in most recent years (European Commission,
information technology and new technology in the case 2016).
of liberal market economies (Hall and Soskice, 2001).
This is clearly observed in some Member States –
The literature on the ‘service transition’ also assimilates
Austria, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Hungary,
similar distinctions to explain why countries are
Lithuania, the Netherlands and the UK. It is also a
converging at different speeds on a higher share of
pattern observed in several of those Member States
service activities in overall employment and output
where the recession hit hardest. For Cyprus, Greece and
(Wren, 2013).
Spain and, to a lesser extent, Ireland, significant
Some of the above can be considered drivers of change contraction of employment persisted after the peak
(for example, the role of the state as employer), while crisis years (2008–2010) right through until 2013. This
many of the others are contextual factors – welfare job loss tended to have a strong concentration in mid-
regimes and rate or stage of economic growth – that paying jobs, attributable in substantial part to a
influence the contours of employment change, making continuation of the rapid contraction of manufacturing
them, for example, more obviously upgrading or more and construction sector employment that had occurred
obviously polarising. Crucially, these drivers and in 2008–2010. Since 2013, each of these countries has
contextual factors vary significantly between countries experienced employment growth above the EU average.
and across time, even among a subset of relatively These gains have tended to occur in the middle
homogenous, developed western European EU Member quintiles, but with the bulk of the gains occurring
States (Eurofound, 2015a). For these reasons, even if somewhat further down the wage distribution. This
aggregate EU employment displays some consistency in suggests that while some of the gains may result from
its shifts over time, notably as regards the persistent rebounds in the strongly recession-affected sectors,
outperformance of top-quintile jobs in employment much of the net new employment created most recently
growth and relative decline of mid-paid jobs, one would is in different, lower-paid jobs. This is most clearly the
case in Ireland.

15
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 6: Employment change (in thousands) by job-wage quintile, Member States, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2

Austria Belgium Bulgaria Croaa Cyprus Czech Republic


100 50 40 50 10
100
20
50 0 0
50
0 0
0 -50 -10 0
-20
-50 -50 -40 -100 -20 -50

Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece


50 30 20 200 600 100

20 100
0 400 0
0 10 0
-20 200 -100
0 -100
-50 -10 -40 -200 0 -200

Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Malta


40 25 30 6
150 300
150 20
20 3
100
0 0 10
50 0 0
-150 0

0 -20 -300 -25 -10 -3

Netherlands Poland Portugal Romania Slovakia Slovenia


80 300 200 200 60
60 200 20
100
100 0 40
40
0 0
20 0
-100 -200 20
0 -100
-200
-20 -300 -200 -400 0 -20

Spain Sweden UK EU
500 150 600 3,000

100 400 2,000

0 50 200 1,000

0 0 0

-500 -50 -200 -1,000

2011–2013 2013–2016

Notes: Data for Germany are for 2012 Q2–2016 Q2; data for the Netherlands and Slovakia are not available for 2011 Q2–2013 Q2. See Annex 2 for
treatment of data breaks in France, Germany, the Netherlands and Slovakia. Luxembourg is excluded for data reasons.
Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

There is clearly no dominant pattern of employment to 2012–2013, and where associated employment
shift over the two periods covered, as might be inferred destruction was concentrated in mid-paying jobs
also from the divergent labour market performances of (Greece, Portugal and Spain). As already indicated, the
Member States over recent years. The aggregate EU recent rebound of employment in some of these
pattern is upgrading with some polarisation. Member States (Greece and Spain) has tended also to
occur in mid-paying or mid-low-paying jobs, leading to
Those more populous Member States with significant
distinctive ‘growth in the middle’ employment shifts.
positive employment growth in recent years each
demonstrate clear upgrading patterns – Germany, A small number of Member States show downgrading
Poland and the UK. Around 60% of top-quintile patterns of employment shift since 2013, with greater
employment growth in the EU since 2013 occurred in growth occurring at the bottom of the wage
these three Member States; they also accounted for distribution. Hungary, Ireland, Latvia and the
around half of total net employment growth. Other Netherlands are the clearest examples of this, while in
unambiguously upgrading countries included Sweden Italy and Malta, employment growth has been strongest
(2011–2016) and Portugal (2013–2016). throughout 2011–2016 in the lowest-paying jobs.
In Belgium, employment growth was polarised in both Downgrading patterns of employment growth have also
periods (2011–2013 and 2013–2016), occurring only in been observed in the US labour market recently, with
the top and bottom wage quintiles. In Austria, the Czech relatively stronger growth in the lower part of the wage
Republic, Denmark and Romania, recent (post-2013) distribution in the period 1999–2012, accompanied by
growth has been polarised, whereas the most clear relatively stagnant growth in the middle and top of the
examples of employment polarisation in the 2011–2013 wage distribution (Autor, 2015, p. 20). More generally, in
period arose in those countries that experienced the the longer term, jobs-based patterns of employment
sharpest recessions in the wake of the global financial change in the USA have tended to shift from
crisis, where the recessionary impacts persisted through unequivocally positive upgrading (in the 1960s) to more

16
Employment shifts in the EU, 2011–2016

polarised patterns each decade until the 1990s (Wright Eurofound, 2015a), is that there has been a variety of
and Dwyer, 2003). This is obviously a development that different employment shift patterns in different
warrants monitoring, all the more so as none of the countries.
more orthodox, demand-based theoretical accounts of
how developed economy labour markets are changing
offers an explanation for such observed downgrading. It Growing and declining jobs
is worth recalling also that earlier diagnoses of The quintile charts compress a lot of data in order to
employment polarisation related first to the USA (Autor convey graphically the main employment shift patterns.
et al, 2003) before emerging in relation to the UK (Goos They do not, however, identify the individual jobs
and Manning, 2007) and other EU Member States (Goos (again, as defined in this study’s application of the jobs-
et al, 2009); the USA can be a harbinger of developments based approach, occupations in sectors at two-digit
in other developed market economies including the EU. level of detail using the ISCO and NACE classifications)
Thus far, a similar pattern can be observed only in a that contribute to the overall pattern. Depending on the
small number of Member States and over a shorter 3–5 country, each quintile encompasses between 80 and
year time frame. Aggregate employment shifts in the EU 300 plus jobs. In practice, a small number of large-
continue to be skewed towards top-quintile growth, employing jobs account for a very large share of
albeit with a strengthening since 2013 of growth in employment. It is shifts in the employment headcount
lower-paid employment. in these jobs that contribute most to the observed
In many countries, employment shifts do not conform patterns of change in the quintile charts. Table 2 lists, in
to any obvious pattern, are irregular or are some hybrid sequence, the top 12 jobs in terms of employment in the
of the four patterns already indicated. This is partly due EU as well as those large-employing jobs (employing
to the short time frame covered. Structural changes more than 600,000 people in the EU28 in 2016, n = 57)
generally take longer than three or five years to become with the fastest rates of growth or contraction in 2011–
apparent. But a second general conclusion based on 2016. Details are also included of the composition of
Figure 6, supported by previous jobs-based analysis employment in these jobs by gender, age and share of
carried out over longer time frames (Oesch, 2013; part-timers.

Table 2: Top 12 jobs by employment (2016 Q2) and top 12 fastest-growing and fastest-declining
large-employing jobs (2011 Q2–2016 Q2), EU

Largest-employing jobs Employment Employment composition (%) Job quintile


Average
2016 annual % Age 55+ Age <30
Occupation Sector (millions) growth Female years years Part time W E JQ
Sales workers Retail trade 12.2 0.3 70 14 29 34 1 2 3
Teaching professionals Education 9.8 0.6 71 21 12 22 5 5 5
Skilled agricultural workers Crop and animal 6.2 -2.6  36 32 13 17 2 1 2
production, etc.
Health professionals Human health activities 4.9 2.0 70  24 14 22 5 5 4
Personal services workers Food and beverage service 4.4 2.7 53 9 41 35 1 2 1
activities
Drivers and mobile plant Land transport and 4.1 0.1 5  23 10 8 3 2 1
operators transport via pipelines
Building and related trades Specialised construction 4.0 -2.2 2 15  19 7 2 2 2
workers activities
Health associate Human health activities 3.8 0.5 82  16 22 28 4 4 3
professionals
Business and administration Public administration and 3.1 -0.2 60 22 11 16 4 4 5
associate professionals defence
Building and related trades Construction of buildings 2.3 -1.3 1 15  15 5 3 1 1
workers
Cleaners and helpers Services to buildings, etc. 2.2 2.9 78  23 12 64 1 1 1
Personal services workers Other personal service 2.1 2.1 85 12  28 32 1 3 3
activities

17
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Fastest-growing large-employing jobs Employment Employment composition (%) Job quintile


Average
2016 annual % Age 55+ Age <30
Occupation Sector (millions) growth Female years years Part time W E JQ
ICT professionals Computer programming, 1.6 7.0  15 8 21 7 5 5 5
consultancy, etc.
Legal, social and cultural Education 1.0 6.1  79 16 27 46 3 4 3
associate professionals
Drivers and mobile plant Warehousing and support 0.6 5.8 4  20  15 5 3 2 1
operators activities
Business and administration Activities of head offices; 0.7 4.6 44  22 13  18 5 5 5
professionals management consultancies
Health associate professionals Residential care activities 0.6 4.5  84  19  23  35 2 4 3
Food preparation assistants Food and beverage service 1.1 3.8  59 11 41 53 1 1 1
activities
Legal, social and cultural Legal and accounting 1.1 3.2  47  19 11 9 5 5 5
professionals activities
Stationary plant and Manufacture of food 0.8 3.2 42  14 22  8 2 1 1
machine operators products
Business and administration Financial service activities 0.7 3.1 49 9 19 8 5 5 5
professionals (excluding insurance)
Personal care workers Residential care activities 2.0 3.1 87  20  22  40 2 3 3
Cleaners and helpers Services to buildings and 2.2 2.9 78  23 12 64 1 1 1
landscape activities
Personal services workers Accommodation 0.9 2.8  56 15 31 26 2 2 2

Fastest-declining large-employing jobs Employment Employment composition (%) Job quintile


Average
2016 annual % Age 55+ Age <30
Occupation Sector (millions) growth Female years years Part time W E JQ
Hospitality, retail and other Food and beverage service 0.9 -2.8 40 19 15 7 3 3 3
services managers activities
Metal, machinery and Manufacture of fabricated 1.6 -2.8 4 18 21 4 3 2 1
related trades workers metal products
Skilled agricultural workers Crop and animal 6.2 -2.6  36 32 13 17 2 1 2
production, etc.
Hospitality, retail and other Retail trade 0.7 -2.6  49 16 15 6 4 3 4
services managers
Customer services clerks Financial service activities 0.9 -2.2 63  16  24  22 4 4 4
(excluding insurance)
Building and related trades Specialised construction 4.0 -2.2 2 15  19 7 2 2 2
workers activities
General and keyboard Public administration and 1.3 -2.2 74  26 9 19 3 3 4
clerks defence
Cleaners and helpers Education 0.6 -1.8 87  32 4  34 1 1 2
Cleaners and helpers Activities of households as 1.4 -1.7 95  26  7 68 1 1 1
employers
Sales workers Wholesale trade 1.0 -1.6 43 15 20 18 3 3 4
Building and related trades Construction of buildings 2.3 -1.3 1 15  15 5 3 1 1
workers
Agricultural labourers Crop and animal 1.3 -1.0  33  18 23  28 1 1 1
production, etc.

Notes: EU28, 2016 Q2 data for top 12 jobs by employment; also for employment composition estimates. For individual Member State shares of
employment for each of the top 12 jobs, see Annex 5. Figures for average percentage growth per annum are based on the average yearly growth
rate for different EU aggregates due to data breaks in certain countries, as follows: 2013–2016, EU26 (no data for France or Luxembourg);
2012–2013, EU24 (no data for France, Luxembourg, Slovakia or the Netherlands); 2011–2012, EU23 (no data for France, Luxembourg, Slovakia,
the Netherlands or Germany). Red arrows indicate declining share by at least 2 percentage points; green arrows indicate increasing share by at
least 2 percentage points (over period 2013–2016, EU26 (no data for France or Luxembourg)). Job quintiles: W = wage, E = education, JQ = job
quality (see Eurofound 2013 annexes for details of construction).
Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

18
Employment shifts in the EU, 2011–2016

The top 12 jobs account for over a quarter (26%) of all categories with fastest growth. In general,
employment in the EU, with the two biggest jobs – retail developments in both the fastest-growing and fastest-
sector sales workers and education sector teaching contracting jobs are likely to contribute more to
professionals – accounting for 1 in 10 jobs. Employment employment polarisation. Ten of the fastest-growing
has grown modestly in these two predominantly female jobs are in the low-paid, mid-low-paid or top-paid
jobs, the former in the lowest job-wage quintile and the quintiles, while the fastest-contracting jobs are in the
latter in the highest. Of the other largest-employing middle of the wage distribution.
jobs, the biggest contractions in headcount were in
The fastest-growing jobs are, however, growing faster
skilled agricultural workers (-2.6% per annum) as well as
than the fastest-declining jobs are contracting; the
two construction sector jobs. However, more jobs were
annual growth rate of personal services workers in
growing than contracting in the top 12 list (8 versus 4),
accommodation (12th in the fastest-growing jobs list) is
and more of these jobs were growing relatively fast
of the same magnitude (2.8% per annum) as the rate of
(more than 2% per annum) than declining relatively
contraction of the fastest-declining jobs (hospitality
fast.
managers in food and beverages and trade workers in
The greatest employment growth was recorded in three fabricated metal products production).
low-paid jobs: cleaners and helpers in the services to
In terms of job composition, as already indicated, the
building sector; personal services workers in food and
main aggregate shifts are the increasing share of
beverages; and personal services workers in other
employment accounted by female workers, older
personal services activities. These jobs account for
workers and part-timers. Among the top-growing and
much of the recent bottom-quintile employment
top-declining jobs, the most obvious compositional
growth. They are typical, basic-skilled service jobs, that
change is the increasing share of older workers,
are hard to automate and where the service is provided
especially in the fastest-growing jobs. This suggests that
directly in person. They are also predominantly female-
older workers in these jobs are remaining longer in work
employing jobs, with a high share of part-timers.
and retiring later. Some fast-growing, predominantly
In the two lists of relatively fastest-growing and fastest- female jobs are becoming less female (for example,
contracting large jobs, one can see that the archetypal health associate professionals in residential care), while
modern digital economy job – ICT professional in the very male-dominated job of ICT professionals in
computer programming – is the fastest-growing job computer programming is attracting a growing share of
(+7% per annum). There are four well-paid, top-wage- women. Finally, it is interesting to see that in four of the
quintile jobs in the fastest-growing list but none in the top-growing jobs, the share of part-timers is declining.
fastest-declining list. One manifestation of increased demand may have been
the conversion of existing part-time positions to full-
While these top-growing jobs contribute to employment
time positions as the employment recovery has
upgrading, they do so only modestly, given their
strengthened. If this is the case, some share of the part-
relatively low employment headcount. There are 1.6
time pool in such jobs may be functioning as a labour
million ICT professionals in computer programming and
reserve.
fewer still in the other top-quintile professional job

19
3 Patterns of employment change
by sector, employment status
and worker characteristics
In this chapter, employment change is broken down in which it is harder to increase productivity. And even
into its components in terms of major sectoral the application of the formidable advances in
aggregations, employment status and worker information technology to services sector work
characteristics. The objective is to show how the broad processes has brought about relatively modest
outlines of employment change identified in the quintile improvements in output. As Nobel Laureate economist
charts intersect with other dimensions of labour market Robert Solow has observed, ‘we see computers
development, such as the increasing share of services in everywhere except in the productivity statistics’.
total employment, the rapid recent growth in part-time
This may, however, be about to change. Recent
work and the increasing share of female employment.
developments in education (for example, massive open
online courses), telemedicine, domestic robots and
Developments by broad sector: driverless transport suggest that the application of
technology may revolutionise the provision of services
The service transition that have traditionally been provided personally. This
Over many generations in developed market could augur declining labour demand in some high-
economies, employment has tended to decline in employing service sectors. But for the moment, this is
primary sectors (agriculture and mining) and secondary not occurring in developed-economy labour markets. In
sectors (manufacturing), with a corresponding increase structural terms, employment headcount is continuing
in the share in tertiary, service sectors. This has to grow, especially in services, even as the working age
occurred largely as a result of differential rates of population has begun to contract post-2010.
productivity growth. The application of successive The long-term secular shift to services employment
waves of productivity-enhancing and labour-saving tended to pick up pace during the post-2008 economic
technology in farming and in production has automated crises as the negative employment impacts of the crises
many processes and allowed greater output to be fell disproportionately on non-service sectors. Despite
generated with fewer and fewer workers. Many service the aggregate net loss of 7.5 million jobs in the EU in the
activities are labour intensive and do not have the same period 2008–2013, the service sector actually grew
potential productivity improvements because they employment during the period (+0.25% per annum).
involve tasks that are hard to automate and that Manufacturing and construction alone accounted for
continue to require direct human intervention – think, the net destruction of 8.6 million jobs during 2008–2013.
for example, of a haircut, the preparation of a meal or Since the employment recovery in 2013, the average
an examination by a doctor. Employment needs in growth rate in services employment has been 1.6%.
modern economies are therefore increasingly satisfied
by a growing service sector. Over 70% of EU Figure 7 highlights again the pivot in terms of
employment is now in services, and in the most service- employment performance from the earlier post-
intensive countries such as Luxembourg or in large recession period (2011–2013) and the employment
metropolitan areas such as greater London or the Île- recovery (2013–2016). Only the top quintile grew
de-France, the figure is between 80% and 90%. employment in 2011–2013; there has been growth in all
quintiles since 2013, and the bulk of new employment
Many of the consequences of ‘unbalanced’ sectoral has been in the service sector, which has been – relative
growth were first identified in the 1960s (Baumol, 1967; to earlier periods – quite evenly distributed across the
see Nordhaus, 2006 for a more recent assessment). job-wage distribution.
These included decreasing relative costs and
employment in technologically progressive sectors such The same year – 2013 – marks a point of inflection for
as manufacturing, and increasing relative costs and the other broad sectors presented. Employment losses
employment in ‘technologically stagnant’ service in the primary sector – agriculture and the mining and
sectors. ‘Baumol’s cost disease’ is probably an extractive industries – have actually increased post-
important factor in declining rates of output growth and 2013 even as the recovery has strengthened. These
in predictions of ‘secular stagnation’ in developed losses have been in low-paid agricultural jobs almost
market economies. The composition of paid exclusively and with a strong concentration in a smaller
employment has increasingly shifted to sectors and jobs number of Member States that have comparatively

21
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 7: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile and broad sector, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2

2011–2013 2013–2016

2,500 2,500

1,500 1,500

500 500

-500 -500

-1,500 -1,500

Services Construcon Manufacturing and ulies Primary sector

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

large agricultural workforces, such as Croatia, Greece, growing manufacturing jobs are in professional,
Poland, Portugal and Romania. associate professional or managerial grade
occupations, with the strongest growth in machinery
As regards the construction and manufacturing sectors,
and equipment production and motor vehicle
even if the majority of post-crisis employment losses
production. Employment levels of science and
occurred during the earlier ‘peak crisis’ period 2008–
engineering professionals in motor vehicle
2010 (not shown), both sectors continued to shed
manufacturing (NACE 29), for example, have been rising
employment through to 2013. In contrast, there has
by 7% per annum since 2013. At the same time, there
been positive growth since 2013 in both sectors, very
has also been growth in traditional blue collar
marginally so in construction, but much more robustly
production roles such as stationary plant and
in manufacturing, where the annual employment
machinery operators and assemblers, again in the
growth rate since 2013 has been only slightly lower than
faster-growing machinery and motor vehicle production
in services (1.4% versus 1.6%). In both sectors, net new
sectors.
employment has been skewed to better-paid jobs.
Manufacturing employment in the EU has not only been
In manufacturing, this has arisen in part from a
changing qualitatively but also has been shifting
recomposition of employment towards higher-skilled
geographically. Figure 8 focuses on manufacturing
professional roles. Manufacturing employment is
employment shifts and differentiates between the ‘old’
upgrading: the employment lost mainly in mid-paying
EU15 Member States and the primarily eastern
jobs up to 2013 is being replaced by higher-skilled and
European Member States that joined the EU after 2004
higher-paying employment. Eight of the top 10 fastest-
(the EU13).

22
Patterns of employment change by sector, employment status and worker characteristics

Figure 8: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile in manufacturing, EU15 and EU13,
2011 Q2–2016 Q2

2011–2013 2013–2016

500 500

0 0

-500 -500

EU15 EU13 EU15 EU13

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

Most employment losses in the earlier 2011–2013 period explanation is consistent with patterns of employment
were recorded in the EU15. During the recovery, around gains and losses arising from restructuring activity
60% of the net 1.5 million new manufacturing jobs captured by the European Restructuring Monitor in
created in the EU have been in the EU13, even though recent years (Eurofound, 2017), especially in the two
these countries account for just over a quarter of the manufacturing subsectors that have contributed most
total EU manufacturing workforce. It is also worth to the recent manufacturing ‘renaissance’ – the motor
noting that the growth in EU15 manufacturing vehicle production and machinery and equipment
employment has been mainly in high-paid jobs, while production sectors.
that in the EU13 has been more evenly distributed
The contribution of manufacturing to overall
across the top four quintiles, with a skew towards mid-
employment growth pales beside that of the service
paid jobs. One likely explanation is that some
sectors. These have added over eight million new jobs
‘traditional’ blue collar, mid-paying manufacturing jobs
since 2011, the majority of the job gains occurring after
– of the type that were cut in the older Member States
2013. Consistent with a consumption-led recovery, a
with a higher GDP during the recession – have relocated
large share of this new employment has come in less-
eastwards following the recovery, as primarily western
knowledge-intensive services 6 – jobs such as personal
European companies take advantage of lower labour
care workers or service workers in the food and
costs in the eastern European Member States. Such an
beverages sector. These account for most of the growth

6 This breakdown relies on the Eurostat aggregation of service sectors into knowledge-intensive services (KIS) and less-knowledge-intensive services (LKIS).
As there is no specific question in the EU-LFS regarding the public or private status of the respondent’s employer, it is not possible to estimate accurately
the respective shares of public and private sector services employment. To make the distinction in this report, the KIS category has been further broken
down into public and private service components. Public KIS comprises the following NACE sector categories: public administration; social security and
defence; education; and human health activities. Private KIS comprises all remaining knowledge-intensive services (see Annex 4 for a full list). It should be
noted that, as a significant minority of workers in the health and education sectors are in fact private sector employees, the public KIS category is an
imprecise proxy of public sector employment.

23
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

in the bottom two quintiles in Figure 9. There has also


been a reprise of growth in the predominantly public
Atypical employment growing
sector knowledge-intensive service employment, across the wage distribution
notably in the top quintile, as public spending One effect of the 2008–2013 crises was to reduce the
restrictions were relaxed after 2013. As noted in Table 2, share of European workers in full-time permanent
employment growth has been particularly strong in the dependent employment. This traditional status –
category of health professionals. Knowledge-intensive henceforth referred to as ‘core employment’ status in
services in the private sector – including media, ICT, this report – described 58.2% of EU workers in 2016 Q2
consulting, legal and accounting services as well as (compared with 59.5% in 2009). In particular, there was
financial services – account for around half of the a steady expansion of part-time work even as the
growth in well-paid, top-quintile jobs but only modestly numbers of those in full-time work decreased. As the
for growth in the other quintiles. All four of the top- recovery in EU labour markets has broadened since
quintile fastest-growing large jobs (see Table 2) fall into 2013, a (very modestly) growing share of net new
this category, including that of ICT professionals in employment has been in core employment status. This
computer programming and consultancy. is consistent with greater confidence among employers
as economic conditions and prospects have improved.
Figure 9: Employment shifts (in thousands) by
job-wage quintile in services, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2 Member State labour markets show a great diversity in
terms of the shares of core employment and of the
distribution of non-core employment between those
3,000 who are self-employed, on temporary contracts,
working part-time or some combination of these
categories. For example, just over one in three Dutch
workers has core employment status; this country’s
very particular experiment in flexibilised working time
has resulted in there being more part-timers than full-
2,000
time workers. In recent years, an increasing number of
self-employed workers in the Netherlands has added
another vector of destandardisation. While most
western European EU15 Member States have shares of
core employment close to the EU28 average
1,000 (±5 percentage points), the percentages tend to be
much higher in the EU13 countries (70%–85% in most
cases),7 although here, too, they are in decline. The
incidence of part-time work in particular tends to be
much lower in eastern European Member States.
0
Private KIS LKIS Public KIS In summary, the main vector of destandardisation has
been the increasing share of part-time employment.8
Note: KIS = knowledge-intensive services; LKIS = less-knowledge- At aggregate EU level, shares of temporary work and
intensive services.
Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors' calculations) self-employed are not much changed since 2008.

7 Poland is the exception with its very high share of temporary workers.

8 This analysis relies on the LFS’s main variables capturing employment status. These differentiate between full-time and part-time work (ftpt), self-
employment and dependent employee status (stapro), and between those dependent employees with a permanent contract and those with a temporary
one. However, a weakness can be noted in any analysis of ‘atypicality’ or employment destandardisation that relies on these distinctions. It is increasingly
obvious that some emerging forms of employment relationship (for example, online platform workers, on-call workers or those working zero-hours
contracts in the UK) are not directly identifiable using the available LFS variables. Many online platform workers are likely to be part time, but it is only
now in some cases that labour law is being called on to arbitrate whether, for example, a taxi driver operating on a particular taxi-service platform is self-
employed or an employee of the platform provider. Even where such distinctions may have acquired legal clarity, an additional complication with the LFS
data – as with all surveys – is that it is based on individual survey responses, and respondents in similar situations may report differently on their own
status.

24
Patterns of employment change by sector, employment status and worker characteristics

accounted for the majority of job losses, there was also


Core employment share a broadly shared decline in temporary employment
stabilising (usually the most vulnerable category in a downturn)
Figure 10 breaks down recent EU employment growth and also of self-employment in mid-paid and mid-low-
by job-wage quintile for core workers (those on full-time paid jobs (mainly in agriculture and likely to be
permanent contracts) and various forms of ‘atypical’ structural).
worker 9 (those who work part time or on full-time After 2013, as labour market conditions improved, the
temporary contracts or who are full-time self- share of core employment has stabilised. Core
employed). The analysis compares the period of employment status has been the category accounting
ongoing job loss (2011–2013) with the recovery period for the biggest share of employment growth in each of
(2013–2016); the reference category is core workers the quintiles, though only in well-paid, top-quintile jobs
(represented by a dark blue bar in Figure 10). The two does it account for the majority of net new employment.
periods are quite different, not only in terms of the sign Part-time employment continues to grow across the
of the employment shifts, but also in the shifts by wage distribution, and there has been an across-the-
employment status. board increase in temporary employment – a customary
The period 2011–2013 saw a destandardisation of labour market response in conditions of recovery. While
employment. This was a continuation of developments self-employment accounts for only a small share of net
previously observed in 2008–2010 (Eurofound, 2011). new employment, it is interesting to see that this is very
The main elements of this were a net decrease of full- clearly skewed towards high-paying jobs such as
time employment in all except the top quintile, partly professionals in the health, education, and legal and
compensated for by an increase in part-time accounting services as well as in the fast-growing
employment in all quintiles. While core employment category of ICT professionals.

Figure 10: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile and employment status, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2

2011–2013 2013–2016

2,500 2,500

1,500 1,500

500 500

-500 -500

-1,500 -1,500

Permanent, full me Self-employed, full me Temporary, full me Part me

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

9 Family workers are omitted from the description of employment shifts by core/non-core employment status; these accounted for just over 1% of the total
EU workforce (2.46 million people) in 2016 and are in decline.

25
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 11: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile in core and non-standard forms of work,
selected Member States, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2
Finland Spain
20 200

0 0

-20 -200

-40 -400

UK Sweden
1,000 200

800
150

600
100
400

50
200

0
0

-200 -50

Permanent, full me Self-employed, full me Temporary, full me Part me

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

Trends in temporary employment and core Different manifestations of these developments can be
employment outside the top quintile have tended to be seen in Figure 11 in four Member States with quite
sensitive to the business cycle. The more obviously different recent economic and labour market
structural trends are the growth of part-time performance.
employment and core employment in the top quintile;
In Finland and Spain, where there was a net destruction
this has been consistent through periods of
of employment in 2011–2016, most of the job loss has
employment contraction and expansion alike. Similar
been in core employment while there have been some
conclusions can also be drawn based on earlier EJM
countervailing gains in atypical work – predominantly
analyses looking at the pre-crisis period (1998–2007)
part-time work in Spain and self-employment in
and the peak crisis period (2008–2010) (Eurofound,
Finland. In contrast, where workforces have been
2011, 2013). Part-time employment levels have grown
growing, these gains have either been primarily in core
consistently since 2008, even in periods of steep
employment status in higher-paid jobs – as in Sweden –
recession, while full-time employment has tended to
or have been shared between core and atypical
grow only in periods of relatively higher growth.
employment – as in the UK, where increasing self-
employment, in particular, has contributed to growth at
the top.10

10 Indeed, the rapid rise of self-employment in the UK – from around 4 million workers in 2011 to 4.8 million in 2016 – is the main factor behind the rise of
self-employment in the EU overall.

26
Patterns of employment change by sector, employment status and worker characteristics

Figure 12: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile and full-time and part-time status, according to
gender, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2

Men Women

1,500 1,500

1,000 1,000

500 500

0 0

-500 -500

Full me Part me Full me Part me

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

Last year’s EJM analysis concluded that the core quintile. Part-time employment has also grown very
employment relationship – with its customary benefits in significantly for men over recent years, but this growth
terms of greater contractual security, career has been strongest in low-paid service jobs, including
advancement possibilities and full-time earning capacity many jobs which, to date, have been mainly female-
– was increasingly the privilege of those in well-paid jobs employing, such as retail sales assistants and personal
(Eurofound, 2016a). The addition of one year of services workers in the food and beverages sector.
reasonably vigorous employment growth has largely
One potential explanation is that male workers who lost
qualified this conclusion. Core employment has
their jobs in the manufacturing and construction sectors
accounted for much of the recent growth across the wage
during the crises have subsequently taken up generally
distribution, although still with an upgrading skew
lower-paying service jobs. While such a hypothesis is
towards higher-paid jobs. And atypical employment is
not possible to test using cross-sectional data, Salvatori
tending to grow across the wage distribution and not just
observed in relation to the UK labour market that ‘the
in lower-paid jobs, as atypical employment forms such as
decline in middling occupations is entirely accounted
part-time work and self-employment appear to be
for by non-graduates, who have both decreased in
‘normalising’ even in higher-skilled, higher-paying jobs.
numbers and seen their employment become more
concentrated at the bottom’ (2015, p. 12).
Growing male share of part-time
work Non-natives dominate new
At first glance, it may be surprising that net new part- employment in lower-paid jobs
time employment – in both periods – is so evenly spread
Just over 27 million workers in the EU (12% of the total)
across the job-wage quintiles. Part-time work is
were born in countries other than the countries in which
associated with a wage penalty, and part-time
they work. Since the majority of this subgroup was born
employment is skewed towards the lower quintiles. The
in non-EU countries, a minority is mobile EU workers
main explanatory factor is gender, as Figure 12
taking advantage of the freedom of movement that EU
illustrates. This covers the whole period from 2011 to
citizens enjoy to settle and work in other Member
2016 and breaks down employment shifts by gender
States. The mobile/migrant worker population has
and full-time versus part-time status. There are
increased by over three million since 2011 and thus
increasing numbers of part-time professionals,
accounts for just less than half of net employment
particularly in the health and education sectors, and, in
growth over the last five years, although, as the recovery
line with the overall gender share of employment in
has become more established in 2015–2016, the share
these sectors, these are primarily female jobs. These
of net new employment held by natives has risen
have supported the growth in part-time work in the top
sharply.

27
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 13: Employment shifts by job-wage quintile As can been seen from Figure 13, most of the net
and country of birth, EU, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2 employment growth in the bottom three quintiles in the
EU is accounted for by non-natives. In these low-paid
4,000 and mid-paid jobs, native employment has either
increased only marginally (first quintile) or has
contracted. Meanwhile, natives have been the main
beneficiary of the more resilient employment growth in
better-paid jobs and especially in top-quintile jobs. At
aggregate EU level, therefore, developments in native
2,000 employment tend to be more upgrading while those in
non-native employment contribute to employment
polarisation by bolstering growth at either end of the
wage distribution.
Around half of the growth of migrant employment is
0 accounted for by Germany where, for historical reasons,
the LFS does not record the different categories of the
country of birth variable but instead assigns all
respondents not born in Germany to a ‘No answer’
category. This category has grown by some 1.2 million
since 2011 and is likely to comprise a high share of non-
-2,000 EU migrants, given the nature of recent immigrant flows
Reporng country EU13 non-nave to Germany. The other big increases in non-native
EU15 non-nave Non-EU employment were for EU13 non-nationals, which now
account for the majority of EU mobile workers, and non-
No answer
EU nationals. Each of these groups grew by around one
Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations) million workers. The numbers of mobile EU workers

Figure 14: Employment shifts (in thousands) by job-wage quintile and country of birth, selected Member
States, 2011 Q2–2016 Q2
Denmark Sweden UK
100 200 1,000

80 150

60 100

40 50 500

20 0

0 -50

-20 -100 0

Italy Ireland Spain


100 100
500

80
0
300
60

40 -100
100

20
-200
-100
0

-20 -300
-300

Reporng country EU13 non-nave EU15 non-nave Non-EU No answer

Source: EU-LFS, SES (authors’ calculations)

28
Patterns of employment change by sector, employment status and worker characteristics

from EU15 Member States were relatively stable, contribute to growth at the top of the wage distribution,
increasing by around 200,000 over the five-year period. where high demand for certain professional
As has been the case for over a decade, intra-EU labour qualifications is met by supply from internationally
mobility flows have been predominantly east–west, mobile workers. For example, non-natives accounted
from countries with lower GDP per head to countries for a majority of the employment increase in the fastest-
with higher GDP per head, but these EU13 mobile growing, well-paid (top-quintile) job in the UK, that of
workers are more likely to be working in lower-paid jobs ICT professionals in computer programming. Native
compared with their EU15 counterparts. employment shifts in these countries have also been
strongly upgrading with nearly all of the net gains
The non-native working population is highly
concentrated in the top two quintiles.
concentrated in older Member States; it accounts for
only a marginal share of employment in eastern In Italy, where most employment growth has been in
European Member States such as Bulgaria, the Czech low-paid jobs, it is non-natives that have largely
Republic, Hungary, Romania and Slovakia. But 15% of accounted for this growth, and they have also been an
workers in Austria, Cyprus, Germany, Ireland, important factor in growing low-wage employment in
Luxembourg, Sweden and the UK are non-natives. Ireland. The travails of the Spanish labour market have
affected both natives and non-natives alike, notably
In all large host countries except Spain, there has been
non-EU workers – mainly those from other Spanish-
an increase in the levels of non-native employment. On
speaking countries that arrived to work in the pre-crisis
the top row of Figure 14, the patterns of native and non-
boom and who subsequently have either become
native employment growth in Denmark, Sweden and
unemployed or left the country. But as employment
the UK are similar to those observed in the EU as a
levels have increased in Spain so too has its non-EU
whole (Figure 13); non-natives account for most or all of
non-native working population – by some 230,000 since
the growth in the lower three wage quintiles but also
2014.

Summary
£ During 2013–2016, employment levels in the EU have exhibited their first sustained increase since the global
financial crisis. There were eight million more people at work in 2016 Q2 compared with three years
previously, and newer jobs are increasingly likely to be full time rather than part time.
£ The resumption of employment growth since 2013 has been manifested in particular in increasing shares of
new employment in low-paid and mid-paid jobs.
£ Over a longer time frame (going back to the late 1990s), higher-paid jobs have continued to show the fastest
employment growth relative to those in the rest of the wage distribution in both recessionary and non-
recessionary periods.
£ There continues to be a variety of patterns of employment shift across Member States. During 2011 Q2–2016
Q2, some countries exhibited one of the two main patterns of employment shift identified in the literature –
upgrading or polarisation; for example, Sweden was clearly upgrading while Belgium was clearly polarising.
Other countries, such as Hungary, Ireland and Italy, exhibited downgrading shifts, where relative
employment growth was strongest in low-paid jobs. As employment has recovered since 2013 in countries
such as Greece and Spain, where it had previously fallen sharply, much of the fresh growth has been in mid-
paying jobs – where most jobs were destroyed during the recession.
£ More than 7 out of 10 jobs in the EU are now in services (71%); the service sector alone has added over 8
million jobs in the EU since 2011. Recent service sector employment growth has been asymmetrically
polarised, with greater gains in the bottom and top quintiles relative to the middle. The predominantly state-
funded sectors of education and health have made an increasing contribution to top-quintile employment
growth, consistent with less-constrained public finances.
£ There has been an increase of manufacturing employment headcount by 1.5 million since 2013. Most of this
increase has been in top-quintile engineering, professional and management jobs and not in more
traditional, blue collar production roles. EU13 countries have been the main beneficiaries of net new
manufacturing employment.
£ The large-employing job with the fastest rate of growth (7%) is that of ICT professionals in computer
programming, a job occupied by relatively young and high-skilled workers. It is predominantly male but with
an increasing female share of employment (15%).

29
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

£ In the majority of other faster-growing large jobs, the share of older workers has increased significantly (by
over two percentage points since 2011), suggesting that extended working lives and later retirement are an
important factor in explaining recent employment growth.
£ As the recovery has strengthened, the standard or ‘core’ employment relationship – full-time, dependent
employment with a permanent contract – has accounted for much of the recent growth across the wage
distribution but with a skew towards well-paid jobs. At the same time, there is some evidence that atypical
employment forms such as part-time work and self-employment are becoming more prevalent even in
higher-skilled, higher-paying jobs.

30
Part 2:
Wage inequality from an
occupational perspective
4 Background and methodology
It is well established that wage inequalities have been However, whether the two phenomena are related in
growing in many advanced economies in the past two any significant way is an empirical question, and
or three decades, although there are important nothing should be assumed without solid evidence.
exceptions and differences in terms of the extent and There could be both job polarisation (or upgrading) and
timing of the change across countries. The clearest and growing wage inequality without any significant link
most intense expansion of wage inequalities took place between the two phenomena. That could be the case if
in the USA and the UK in the 1980s (OECD, 2011), the distribution of wages within occupations had
extending in a generally more moderate form to many changed significantly in recent years; those changes
European countries in the 1990s and 2000s (with some could be much more consequential for wage inequality
noteworthy exceptions such as France). than any change in the occupational structure. In fact,
some recent influential studies on inequality trends
A separate but related debate has focused on the
would point in this direction (Piketty, 2014). In many
phenomenon of job polarisation in the same countries
cases, growing inequality is largely the result of a
over the same period. According to many analysts
concentration of earnings at the very top of the wage
(Autor et al, 2006; Goos et al, 2009), recent technological
distribution – the top 1% or even 0.1%. However, it
change and international trade have biased labour
seems unlikely that this development is significantly
demand against mid-skilled workers, polarising the
linked to broad occupational dynamics. Behind this
occupational structures of advanced economies. Others
increasing concentration of earnings at the very top of
(Oesch and Rodriguez Menes, 2011; Fernández-Macías,
the distribution would be institutional changes such as
2012a) have argued that job polarisation is not so
financial deregulation and destandardisation of
pervasive across developed economies; nor is it
employment (Saez, 2015), phenomena that seem more
primarily driven by market forces but by changes in
plausibly linked to growing within-occupation (or
labour supply, institutional processes of labour market
occupation-independent) inequality than to between-
deregulation and destandardisation of employment
occupation inequality. But again, this is an empirical
contracts. However, both sides would agree that labour
question that must be discussed with figures, which this
demand in recent years has been biased towards
report aims to do.
particular types of occupations, producing either job
polarisation or occupational upgrading. What does the existing literature say about the role
played by occupations in explaining growing inequality?
It seems more than possible that increasing wage
There have been significant contributions on this from
inequality and occupational restructuring could be
economics and sociology. In mainstream economics,
somehow related. In particular, it seems reasonable to
occupations have traditionally played a secondary role
think that an upward or polarised bias in labour
as explanatory factors, with skills differentials being the
demand could have contributed to increasing wage
prime explanation for wage inequality. But recent
inequality (although not necessarily as its main cause).
economic analysis of the labour market effects of
Even if the average wages paid by occupations and the
computerisation has assigned occupations a much
distribution of wages within occupations remained
more central role. Since computers have a different
stable, a process of occupational polarisation would
effect on the demand for different types of tasks,
increase wage inequality by expanding the proportion
occupations (understood as bundles of tasks) are a key
of workers with low and high wages relative to those in
mediating factor in the effect of recent technological
the middle (in contrast, occupational upgrading would
change on labour markets (Autor, 2013). On the other
compositionally reduce wage inequality by reducing the
hand, in sociological research, occupations (understood
relative share of low-paid work). Furthermore, a
as positions within the division of labour in society)
consistently uneven demand for labour in occupations
have always been considered one of the main
across different skill levels would tend to affect
determinants of the distribution of earnings and life
occupational wages in biased ways. All other things
chances (Weeden, 2002). There is some controversy as
being equal, a polarised labour demand would reduce
to whether occupations are becoming more or less
wage inequality in the bottom half of the distribution
important as drivers of wage inequality and, more
(since the wages of those at the very bottom would
specifically, whether they are behind the recent
increase with demand, relative to those in the middle),
increases in inequalities previously mentioned. Some
while increasing it at the top half. Occupational
scholars argue they are (Mouw and Kalleberg, 2010;
upgrading would lead to a relative increase in the wages
Acemoglu and Autor, 2011), while others argue the
of the highest-paid occupations, thus contributing to
opposite (Kim and Sakamoto, 2008; Mishel et al, 2013).
wage inequality even more directly.

33
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

The analysis that follows uses EU data on wages and within the hierarchy and skill structure of their
occupational structures to contribute to this debate organisations.
from a comparative European perspective.
The division of labour along the vertical and horizontal
£ First, it evaluates to what extent wages are a dimensions, in practical terms, means that in most
significant explanatory factor for wage inequalities, cases, the unit of analysis will be a specific occupation
using some of the main arguments from the social within a specific sector (an occupation-by-sector
sciences debate to orient the analysis. combination: for instance, a secretary within the
£ Second, taking advantage of the fact that this study construction sector). In the first part of this report, this
covers nine European countries with rather unit of analysis is called a ‘job’, but in the current part,
different institutional and economic structures, it the term ‘occupation’ or ‘detailed occupation’ is used
focuses on differences in the role played by interchangeably with ‘job’, for the following reasons.
occupations in the distribution of wages across £ Empirically, occupations are the main structuring
different institutional families. factor for most of the aspects of work and
£ Finally, a time dimension is introduced, looking at employment that have been investigated over the
changes in the importance of occupational wages years (see Eurofound, 2013 and Eurofound, 2016a
during the recent recession. for analyses of job quality and tasks, respectively).
£ Conceptually, occupation as defined above
(coherent bundles of tasks that require specific
Methodology skills and correspond to positions in the division of
To the authors’ knowledge, there are no previous labour) encompasses both dimensions of the
studies of the role played by occupations in recent wage division of labour (conventionally called occupation
inequality trends covering such a wide range and and sector).
diverse set of countries. The main reason is probably
In fact, ISCO incorporates sector distinctions at all levels
the formidable methodological difficulties involved in
(for instance, at the one-digit level, there are different
such a comparison. To do this kind of analysis, data
groups for agricultural, manufacturing and services
sources covering many countries and periods are
workers). Previous EJM work relied on the combined
needed, including adequate and comparable measures
classification of ISCO and NACE because the level of
of the two main variables of interest – occupations and
detail of ISCO that was available in EU-level data (two-
wages. In strict terms, there is no single international
digit level, corresponding to 23 categories) was not
dataset that fulfils all these criteria, which means that it
enough for the type of analysis intended. In practice,
is necessary to construct the analysis using different
ISCO at the three-digit level provides a level of
sources and to be flexible in the operationalisation. This
granularity that is equivalent to the combination of
section provides some details on the main concepts
ISCO and NACE at the two-digit level.
used for the analysis and their measurement, discussing
the limitations of the data sources used and how they In the current analysis, the level of detail of the
have been dealt with. occupational classification used will depend on the
possibilities afforded by the data at hand, as explained
Occupations: Concept and classifications later. For international comparisons, the ideal level of
Occupations are defined here as ‘coherent bundles of detail of occupations would be ISCO at three digits or
tasks that require specific skills, corresponding to ISCO at two digits combined with NACE at two digits.
different positions within the division of labour in This level of detail should generate a sufficient internal
society’ (Fernández-Macías, 2012b). The division of homogeneity within each job and external
labour refers to the breakdown of economic processes heterogeneity between them for the purposes of this
into different tasks to be performed by specialised study, while retaining international comparability
workers (leading to enormous gains in efficiency but (beyond three digits, the comparability of categories in
also increasing structural complexity), which in ISCO across countries is problematic; see Elias, 1997). In
contemporary market economies is coordinated by two some cases, however, ISCO will have to be used at the
different mechanisms: markets and hierarchies. Markets two-digit level only or combined with NACE at the one-
coordinate the division of labour between companies digit level (or even ISCO one-digit level by NACE
(horizontal division of labour), while hierarchies one-digit level). In those cases, some of the
coordinate the division of labour within companies heterogeneity between jobs at the detailed level will
(vertical division of labour). The conventional appear as heterogeneity within jobs at the aggregate
classifications of sector and occupation correspond to level. Since this type of flexibility in the definition of
the horizontal and vertical division of labour, occupation is necessary to carry out the intended
respectively. Sectors classify companies and workers analysis, one can only address it by being careful in its
operating in different markets, while occupations interpretation and explicitly discussing this problem
classify workers according to the position they occupy whenever necessary.

34
Background and methodology

When using data from the SES, occupations will be based on payroll data (rather than on workers’
defined as the combination of ISCO at two-digit level responses). The sample is representative of both
and NACE at one-digit level, with a further breakdown of enterprises and workers in the sectors covered and in
some categories (in practice very close to the standard companies of different sizes.
two-digit by two-digit classification of jobs normally
The main advantage of the SES for the purpose of this
used in the EJM). In the case of the European Union
study is that it is a survey aimed explicitly at measuring
Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC),
wages with a high degree of detail. What this means is
occupations will be defined by combining ISCO at two-
that the target variable of wages can be constructed in a
digit level and NACE at the one-digit level – thus with a
relatively direct and precise way. The sample is very big
higher level of aggregation than in the standard EJM
in most countries, which allows for a detailed
approach.
breakdown of wages by occupations. It also provides
reasonably detailed classifications of occupation (ISCO
Wage: Concept and measurement
at two-digit level) and sector (NACE at one-digit level
The second key variable in this report is the wage, with some further breakdown of large categories such
defined as the gross hourly remuneration of the work of as manufacturing, which in practice makes it similar to
employees. In other words, the focus is on the two-digit level).
compensation of labour, not the earnings of employees;
hourly wages, not monthly or annual labour income. Its main disadvantage is the limited and inconsistent
Monthly or annual labour earnings are strongly affected coverage of the economy in different countries. Small
by issues such as working time and employment companies and public sector organisations are covered
stability, which are not directly related to occupational in only some countries, and, unfortunately, the
differences (even though they may themselves be microdata for public use do not allow the construction
unevenly distributed by occupations, their effect on of a consistent dataset in terms of coverage across
wages is of a different nature). countries, unless all companies with fewer than 50
employees are eliminated from the sample, which is
As in the case of occupations, the actual obviously too restrictive. So, in practice, some countries
operationalisation of this concept in the analysis will include companies with fewer than 10 employees and
have to be adapted depending on the characteristics of some do not. Another problem with the SES is that it
the different sources. The SES uses strictly defined cannot be used for analysing the change over time in
hourly wages for employees, obtained at the the effect of occupations on wages, because only three
establishment level (so the information is provided by waves are available and the classifications and coverage
managers rather than the workers themselves). In the change in each wave.
case of EU-SILC, an approximation to hourly wages is
used, obtained by dividing annual labour income in the EU-SILC is used for the analysis of change in the effect of
year before the survey by the number of months occupations on wage inequality between 2005 and
worked, taking into account whether the workers were 2014. EU-SILC is a cross-sectional and longitudinal
full time or part time and adjusting for people with more database on income, poverty, social exclusion and living
than one job (for more details on this measure, see conditions in the EU, coordinated by Eurostat, with data
Eurofound, 2015b). So in practice, with EU-SILC, a drawn from different sources at national level. It is
measure of full-time-equivalent wages is used rather representative of all private households and their
than hourly wages, which should be equivalent even if current members residing in the territory of the
not identical. countries at the time of data collection. A key advantage
of EU-SILC for the purposes of this study is that it
Data sources provides consistent cross-sectional data on wages and
The 2010 SES is used to make a static analysis of the role occupations for the period 2005–2014. Furthermore, it
played by occupations in wage inequality in Europe. The provides complete coverage of the economy.
SES has been conducted every four years since 2002 and However, EU-SILC provides only an approximate
collects harmonised data on wages in enterprises with measure of wages (which has to be computed on the
more than 10 employees in all sectors except basis of annual labour earnings information). Sector is
agriculture, fishing, public administration, education, only available at the one-digit level (occupation is
health and community, and social services. The available at two digits). The sample size is considerably
inclusion of small enterprises and the above-mentioned smaller than that of the SES, which complicates the
sectors is optional for the participating countries, and, detailed decomposition of the distribution of wages by
in fact, many of them opted for such comprehensive occupations.
coverage in the last edition of the survey (2010).
Although the actual method for collecting the
information can differ considerably across countries
(between specific surveys and administrative registers),
in all cases it is collected at the company level and

35
5 Static analysis of the role of
occupations in determining the
wage distribution
vary across occupations depending only on the amount
Initial considerations and of human capital they require; the fact that different
theoretical arguments occupations involve performing very different types of
As mentioned in the previous chapter, occupations have tasks and therefore require qualitatively different skills
traditionally played a secondary role as explanatory is not part of this argument.
factors in mainstream economics. In economics A third and more recent argument assigns occupations
textbooks, wages primarily reflect productivity a prominent role, associated with differences in the
differentials between individuals, and occupations are types of tasks they involve. Technological change can
hardly mentioned (Mankiw, 2012, pp. 397–412). But have a different effect on different types of task input
even from a mainstream economics approach, there are into the production process, being complementary to
reasons to believe that occupations could be associated some but substitutive to others. Since different
with wage differentials without playing a direct role in occupations involve different types of tasks, this could
wage determination. lead to systematic wage differentials between
occupations that cannot be reduced to differences in
Economic perspective the stock of human capital. More specifically,
First, occupations may be associated with arguments from this perspective have posited that
compensating wage differentials. As Adam Smith recent technological change tends to depress labour
famously argued in The Wealth of Nations, if some jobs demand for occupations that involve higher levels of
involve performing very disagreeable or dangerous routine, which tend to be in the middle of the skills
tasks, they should be more highly compensated, all else continuum (Acemoglu and Autor, 2011). So it is
being equal (Smith, [1776] 1976, p. 117). Since different important to note that, despite remaining within
occupations obviously involve different levels of mainstream economics, the tasks approach does assign
hardship and hazard, this factor could create systematic a prominent role to occupations, at least to the extent
between-job wage differentials. Empirical evidence, that the types of tasks carried out are one of the main
however, suggests that this factor plays a very marginal defining characteristics of occupations (tasks cannot
role in explaining overall wage inequality; it seems to be exist on their own, they have to be coherently bundled
important only in some extreme cases (Muñoz de into actual occupations; see Autor, 2013; Eurofound,
Bustillo et al, 2011, pp. 42–45). 2016a).
Second, occupations may be associated with Sociological perspective
differences in the amount of human capital. Human
capital refers to accumulated knowledge and In contrast, occupations have always played a central
experience that makes individuals more productive and explanatory role in the sociological and institutional
therefore likely to receive higher wages (Becker, 1993). economics traditions. From these perspectives,
Since different occupations typically require different occupations are understood as highly differentiated and
amounts of human capital, it could be associated with specialised positions within the complex division of
systematic wage differentials. Two observations ought labour in modern societies, associated with different
to be made about this argument. First, it implies that cultures and lifestyles, and differential access to
occupations do not play a role on their own; they just economic resources and life chances. The key
group workers with a similar stock of human capital. mechanism linking occupations and the distribution of
Therefore, if one could control for human capital, wage wages (and economic inequality in general) is Weber’s
differentials between occupations should disappear. notion of social closure: ‘social groups formed around
Second, this theory can provide only a one-dimensional positions in the technical division of labour create social
explanation of occupational wage differentials (linked and legal barriers that restrict access to resources and
to skill levels), since its focus is on the amount and not opportunities to a limited circle of eligibles’ (Weeden,
the type of human capital. In other words, wages would 2002, p. 57). Some specific mechanisms and strategies
of occupational closure from this perspective include

37
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

licensing, credentialing,11 certification, unionisation and under- or over-representation of some social groups in
representation by associations. These strategies would specific occupations. This may affect the status and
allow some occupations to generate rents, that is, social power associated with the occupations and may
payments attached to positions independently of the end up reinforcing the inequality that initially generated
level of effort or productivity of the people occupying the segregation, further expanding occupational wage
those positions (Weeden, 2002, p. 58), leading to the differentials. As in the case of human capital, this
observed occupational wage differentials. argument assigns occupations a mediating role in the
structuring of wages, and therefore it should (at least
Measuring the effect of these mechanisms of
partly) disappear if one could eliminate the effect
occupational closure would require systematic
caused by the underlying segregation factors.
information on institutional differences that is not
available at EU level, so it is beyond the scope of this Another important qualification is that the role of
report (for an example of this approach comparing two occupations in structuring economic outcomes
specific countries, see Kampelmann and Rycx, 2013 and depends on other attributes of the socioeconomic
Bol and Weeden, 2014). However, they provide a system, such as industrial relations or labour regulation.
plausible explanation for occupational wage For instance, in some countries unions are craft-based
differentials that cannot be directly linked to differences while in others they represent the interests of the
in human capital, compensation for working conditions working class as a whole; in the latter, occupations may
or routine task content. be less important for the distribution of wages than in
the former. Some of the mechanisms of occupational
Other strands of the sociological literature provide
closure previously mentioned (apprenticeship systems
important qualifications to the centrality of occupations
or occupational licensing) are very different across
in the structuring of wage inequalities.
countries, which can also lead to systematic differences
In many sociological traditions, social class rather than in the effect of occupations on wages. So, even if
occupation is the central structuring factor of economic occupations are expected to play a significant role in
outcomes. In general terms, social class can be structuring wage inequality in most developed
understood as broad groups of socioeconomic economies, the importance of such a role is likely to
stratification, defined by their position in relations of vary. In the particular case of Europe, this variation can
exploitation, authority relations, employment contracts be expected to be associated with the well-known
or other factors (Erikson and Goldthorpe, 1992; Wright, institutional families (welfare regimes, varieties of
1997; and, for a more recent proposal, see Oesch, 2006). capitalism). These differences will be explored in some
In practical terms, social classes are often constructed detail in Chapter 6.
by aggregating from occupational classifications,
Finally, some recent studies on the evolution of
although secondary variables such as authority in
inequalities would suggest that the role of occupations
production are sometimes also used (Wright, 1997). In
in determining wage inequality may be declining.
other words, social classes can be often understood as
According to the thinking of Atkinson et al (2011), the
aggregated occupations, or occupations as very
recent surge in income and wage inequality, particularly
disaggregated classes: this is an argument made explicit
in the economies of the USA and the UK, results from
in the neo-Durkheimian approach of David Grusky, who
the ‘retreat of institutions developed during the New
conceptualises occupations as microclasses (Grusky
Deal and World War II – such as progressive tax policies,
and Galescu, 2005). In order to explain a particular
powerful unions, corporate provision of health and
phenomenon such as growing wage inequality, the
retirement benefits, and changing social norms
comparison of developments at the aggregate level of
regarding pay inequality’ (Saez, 2015, p. 5). These
big classes and at the detailed level of microclasses can
factors are either unrelated to occupational differences
reveal different dynamics and underlying mechanisms
or would tend to undermine some of the institutional
(for an example, see Weeden et al, 2007).
mechanisms behind them, and therefore would make
Other theories have argued that occupations play a between-occupation differentials account for a
mediating role for the effect of separate social declining share of overall wage inequality. This
stratification factors such as gender or race, via the argument contrasts particularly with the previously
mechanism of occupational segregation (Tomaskovic- discussed idea of task-biased technological change as a
Devey, 1993; Grimshaw and Rubery, 1997). Differential key factor behind growing inequalities. The role of
(culturally and socially constrained) preferences and occupations in recent wage inequality trends in Europe
labour market discrimination can produce a systematic will be discussed in detail in Chapter 7.

11 The process of formally accrediting competences in a defined area of practice to confirm that a person is fit to practise in that area.

38
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

group component will be large. If they are not, most of


Occupations and wage the variation in wages will take place within the groups,
inequalities: An initial overview and the within component will dominate.
How much wage inequality is associated with According to this approach and using data from the
occupational differentials in a European context? In 2010 SES, between-job differentials account for around
common with many previous studies on this issue (for 50% of the total variance in log wages (wages
instance, Acemoglu and Autor, 2011; Mouw and transformed into logarithms) (and consequently,
Kalleberg, 2010), one can try answering this question by within-job variability would account for the other half),
using a variance decomposition approach. The total with some differences across countries, from 42% in
variance of wages in a country can be split into two Germany to 53% in Poland (Table 3, Column 6). This
components when the data are grouped by percentage of variance explained refers to the most
occupations: detailed occupational level, which in the EJM is called a
£ the variance that results from between-group ‘job’ and corresponds to two-digit occupations
differentials; combined with two-digit sectors (the number of these
jobs also varies across countries, between 450 and 650).
£ the variance that results from within-group The most important component for the distribution of
variability. wages in such a definition of jobs is actually occupation
If the groups (in this case, occupations or jobs) play an as measured by ISCO: even with the 36 categories of
important role in structuring inequality, the between- ISCO at two digits, one can already explain most of the

Table 3: Impact of occupations on wage inequalities: Results of analyses

ANOVA decompositions – % variance in log wages explained by between-group differentials


according to:
3. ISCO only 4. NACE only 5. ISCO + 6. Jobs 7. Jobs, excl. 8. Jobs, 8b. Jobs,
1. No.of 2. No. of (36 (19 NACE, no (ISCO x small wages not wages < top
observations jobs categories) categories) interaction NACE) companies logged 1%
France 187,177 444 40.96 7.94 43.21 45.32 43.69 18.11 44.77
Germany 1,745,189 652 34.84 9.03 38.01 41.67 44.32 38.88 47.13
Italy 264,506 514 41.34 13.84 42.91 47.39 50.59 41.46 47.39
Netherlands 158,004 493 37.46 15.12 40.1 42.54 42.93 29.13 42.19
Poland 629,176 590 46.98 15.77 50.2 52.93 54.11 36.34 49.44
Romania 233,877 574 39.52 10.81 45.48 48.91 53.14 35.15 42.81
Spain 205,132 484 37.42 11.61 40.29 43.48 48.98 31.55 42.58
Sweden 270,491 473 41.62 7.85 43.97 47.24 48.18 32.48 43.47
UK 167,467 470 45.99 12.07 48.72 51.12 54.6 12.04 41.7

Inequality indices (wages not logged) Human capital approach, log wages
9. Variance
explained by a 14. Variance 15. Wages net from
model with 12. Theil 13. Between explained by a model education and
sociodemographic between jobs/total with education and tenure, variance
variables 10. Gini 11. Theil jobs Theil tenure explained by jobs
France 42.25 27.28 16.25 6.93 42.68 25.38 29.43
Germany 56.25 32.68 19.00 9.16 48.19 41.03 25.33
Italy 43.02 28.66 15.16 7.58 50.01 33.67 20.65
Netherlands 53.47 29.40 16.19 6.52 40.28 42.9 14.8
Poland 45.57 35.27 23.01 12.07 52.46 35.25 25.35
Romania 40.98 39.02 29.74 15.14 50.92 28.49 28.44
Spain 47.99 29.58 16.07 6.98 43.41 36.4 19.68
Sweden 31.79 18.91 7.98 3.68 46.13 11.56 41.97
UK 35.5 36.83 30.85 12.69 41.11 16.39 37.75

Notes: The model in Column 9 includes the variables gender, age, education, tenure, part-time, temporary contract (except Sweden), company
size, company ownership, collective bargaining (except Sweden) and region. ANOVA = analysis of variance. Small companies (Column 7) are
those with fewer than 50 employees.
Source: SES 2010 (authors’ analysis)

39
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

variance shown by the full range of 450+ jobs (see later). What the comparison between Columns 8 and 6
Column 3). However, NACE and the combination of shows is that, while occupations play a significant role
NACE and ISCO also add significantly to the explanatory in the distribution of the majority of wages, they play a
power of this model (they add another 20% of variance marginal role in the distribution of a minority of very
explained, see Table 3, Columns 4 and 5), so the large wages. That is why not logging wages mostly adds
detailed definition of occupations, or jobs, can be to within-job inequality (if all the super-high wages were
kept.12 concentrated in a few occupations, not logging wages
could even make between-occupation differentials
In other words, occupations play a significant role in the
more important). This can be confirmed by yet another
structuring of wage inequality in Europe. In order to
approach (shown in Column 8b), in which wages are not
evaluate the significance of this result, it is useful to
logged but the top 1% of the distribution is excluded:
compare it with a different variance decomposition
the variance explained by occupations in this
model, in this case using 10 key socioeconomic
‘truncated’ wage distribution is similar to the variance
variables as predictors (including gender, age,
explained when wages are transformed to logarithms.
education, tenure, company ownership and others, with
Hence, occupations play a very significant role in
no interactions). As Column 9 of Table 3 shows, the
structuring the majority of wages, but they cannot
variance explained by such a model is comparable to
explain the distribution of some very large values. This
the variance explained by the ‘jobs’ classification –
on its own suggests that occupational differences may
again, with some differences across countries.
not be driving the recent surge in inequality in some
Wages are known to have a log-normal distribution: advanced economies, at least to the extent that such a
strongly asymmetric and skewed to the right because of surge is associated with developments at the very top of
a high concentration of values below the mean, which is the wage distribution.
usually inflated by some very large values. Transforming
However, there are very important differences across
them to logarithms generally makes the distribution
European countries in this respect. In France and the
more normal (more symmetrical, less skewed by very
UK, the variance explained by occupation drops more
high values) and therefore more tractable to
precipitously when wages are not logged (they fall to
econometric modelling, which is why it is routinely
18% and 12%, respectively, from around 50%), whereas
performed in economics. This approach is followed in
in Germany and Italy the decrease is quite small (just
most of this analysis, as shown in Table 3. However, it is
3%–6%, to around 40%). These differences can result
important to note that transforming wages into
from two factors:
logarithms has a very significant effect on the
distribution of wages, making it ‘less unequal’, for £ the importance of those very high wages in the
obvious reasons: the logarithmic transformation overall distribution of wages (which would be
compresses the distribution, with an increasing effect highest in France and the UK);
on very large values. To evaluate the effect of such £ the extent to which those very high wages are
transformation, a variance decomposition of wages by linked to occupational differences (for instance,
jobs where wages have not been logged has also been there are also outliers in Germany and Italy, but
included (see Column 8). It can immediately be seen they seem to be better predicted by occupations).
that the variance explained by between-job differentials
is significantly reduced in most cases. This means that Table 3 also includes an alternative approach to
there are some very large values of wages whose evaluate the impact of occupations on the distribution
occurrence cannot be linked to occupational of wages, in this case using the Theil index instead of a
differences. decomposition of variance. The Theil index can also be
broken down into a between-group and a within-group
This is not a technical point, but a very significant result component, but has the advantage of additionally
for the purposes of this analysis, particularly so for providing an overall assessment of the level of
cross-country comparisons. As is well-known, the inequality in a distribution. The Gini index is also
existence of some very high values is a key attribute of included for this purpose since it is the most well-known
the distribution of wages (and income) in advanced measure (Table 3, Column 10). In this case, wages are
economies; according to recent research, it is one of the not logged.
drivers behind increasing inequalities (a point discussed

12 Table 3 (Column 7) also includes the results for a sample in which small companies have been eliminated from all countries. This makes the results more
comparable across countries by removing the previously mentioned problem of the SES having inconsistent samples for small companies in different
countries. The results are very similar, generally increasing the share of variance explained by jobs (which ranges from 43% to nearly 55%) and slightly
reducing the cross-country variation.

40
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

The highest levels of wage inequality are observed in The results clearly show that compensation for bad
Poland, Romania and the UK and the lowest in Sweden. working conditions is not a significant factor shaping
The overall level of wage inequality does not seem to be between-job wage differentials. In fact, between-job
related to the importance of occupations/jobs in wage differentials tend to be positively correlated with
explaining it: for instance, the amount of wage job quality: jobs with bad working conditions tend to
inequality explained by between-job differentials is also have lower wages and vice versa. This can be seen
similar in countries with high and low overall levels of in the overall job quality index (with correlations above
inequality. This point is discussed later in connection 0.6 in all the countries covered) and in the dimensions
with country patterns. For now, it is important to note of intrinsic quality of work and employment quality. The
that the Theil and the variance decomposition approach correlation with health and safety is also positive, but
provide a very similar overall assessment of the role of less strong. And in the case of work–life balance, there is
occupations/jobs in the distribution of wages (they essentially no correlation, positive or negative, reflected
would account for 40%–50%), although the specific in the lowess regression line, suggesting a mild negative
position of individual countries varies slightly in both association in some countries. The aspect of work–life
approaches. balance, therefore, is the only one where there could be
a very weak case for compensating differentials in some
occupations, but even in that case, the fact that there is
Analysing the economic no significant association does suggest that
arguments compensation plays no significant role whatsoever.

The oldest economic argument to explain occupational So working conditions and wages tend to correlate
wages is probably the theory of compensating rather than compensate for each other, which may
differentials, advanced by Adam Smith more than 200 suggest that both depend on some third variable.
years ago. As mentioned above, empirical evidence is Perhaps that variable is human capital and the
not very supportive of this theory, at least in terms of associated productivity differentials, as suggested by
the overall distribution of income (though it may work another economic hypothesis reviewed earlier. Can that
in some particular cases). However, one can try to hypothesis be also tested with these data? Human
evaluate it empirically from an occupational capital cannot be directly observed or measured, but it
perspective: are between-job wage differentials related is frequently proxied by education and work experience
to differences in the conditions of work? More (Mincer, 1974). Following such an approach, Column 14
specifically: do higher occupational wages compensate of Table 3 shows the variance of log wages that can be
for bad conditions? explained by a model with education and tenure as
predictors.13 Despite its simplicity, this model accounts
Figure 15 shows the relationship between the for a significant amount of the total variance of wages
conditions of work in different occupations and their (again, there are differences across countries, but in
average wage for the nine European countries studied. most countries, it is above 30%), although it is well
The vertical axis represents the average log wage. The below the results for occupations or jobs.
horizontal axis represents the average value on a 0–1
normalised scale for a composite index of job quality However, the most important result is shown in Column
(based on the proposal by Muñoz de Bustillo et al, 2011; 15 of Table 3, where log wages are expressed net of the
see also Eurofound, 2013) and its four higher-level effect of education and tenure (in technical terms, using
dimensions: intrinsic quality of work, quality of the residual from the predicted values of the model
employment conditions, health and safety conditions shown in Column 14), and the variance decomposition
and work–life balance. Each job (occupation–sector is repeated by job using this new variable. A wage net of
combination) is represented as a dot in the charts (the differences in the stock of human capital is just the
size of the dot being proportional to the employment observed wage of a person minus the average wage for
share of the job). A lowess (locally weighted scatterplot all workers with the same level of human capital (the
smoothing) regression line to represent the shape of the same education and years of tenure). If detailed
association is superimposed, and the Pearson occupations or jobs were predictors of wage inequality
correlation coefficient is shown. only because they are associated with different stocks
of human capital, they would not be able to explain any
of the differences observed in wages when expressed
net of human capital differences. Column 15 of Table 3

13 In the SES, the only education variable that can be used for international comparisons is one based on educational attainment, with three categories (low,
medium and high), which were included as dummies in the model. Work experience was included as years of tenure, a continuous variable (a quadratic
term was also included to allow for non-linearity).

41
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 15: Relationship between working conditions in different occupations and their average wage, nine
Member States
Index of job quality Intrinsic quality of work Quality of employment conditions Health and safety conditions Work-life balance

corr: 0.60 corr: 0.69 corr: 0.66 corr: 0.35 corr: 0.16

Germany

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.61 corr: 0.73 corr: 0.77 corr: 0.28 corr: 0.14

Spain

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.73 corr: 0.82 corr: 0.71 corr: 0.54 corr: 0.10

France

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.68 corr: 0.70 corr: 0.70 corr: 0.45 corr: 0.29

Italy

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.70 corr: 0.78 corr: 0.79 corr: 0.39 corr: 0.14

Netherlands

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.71 corr: 0.78 corr: 0.77 corr: 0.44 corr: 0.28

Poland

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.65 corr: 0.73 corr: 0.74 corr: 0.39 corr: 0.16

Romania

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.58 corr: 0.69 corr: 0.60 corr: 0.41 corr: -0.02

Sweden

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

corr: 0.74 corr: 0.82 corr: 0.76 corr: 0.45 corr: 0.16

UK

0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1 0 .2 5 .5 .7 5 1

Source: European Working Conditions Survey for working conditions and SES 2010 for wages (authors’ analysis)

42
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

shows that is not the case; although the share of occupations may be also part of the story, although not
variance explained decreases in all countries, between- a very significant one. It should also be noted that
job differentials still account for a significant share of routine task content, particularly in its repetitiveness
the inequality between wages net of differences in dimension (the one most plausibly linked to
human capital (from 42% in Sweden to 15% in the occupational wage differentials, according to Figure 16),
Netherlands). Therefore, although human capital is strongly correlated with the skills required by the
differences explain part of the role played by different jobs (see Fernández-Macías and Hurley, 2016
occupations in the distribution of wages, they are only for a detailed discussion). In other words, the routine-
part of the story. In terms of their effect on the biased technological change argument would not add
distribution of wages, occupations are not just groups of much to the earlier more robust finding about the role
workers with similar levels of human capital. played by differences in the stock of human capital. If
Occupational wage differentials cannot be reduced to one controls for the average educational level of jobs,
differences in education and tenure. the role played by routine or repetitiveness becomes
much less important.
A related argument suggests that the type, rather than
the level, of human capital required to perform the
different jobs may be a key determinant of between- Analysing the sociological
occupation wage inequalities. The routine-biased
technological change hypothesis argues that arguments
technological change depresses demand for The evidence presented so far seems, in principle, more
occupations that require a high level of routine task in line with the sociological than the economic tradition.
content, and one should therefore expect those Occupations play a significant role in shaping wage
occupations to have lower wages than the rest. inequality and not just by grouping workers with similar
Expressed in more general terms, wage levels could be levels of human capital. The fact that occupations still
negatively associated with the degree of routine account for a significant part of the variance of wages
involved in each occupation.14 Figure 16 shows the net of human capital suggests that occupation-specific
correlation between an index of routine tasks at work mechanisms (such as occupational closure) may be at
calculated at the job level (the one presented in the EJM play.
2016 annual report; see Eurofound, 2016a for more
details) and the average wage of each job, with jobs In fact, one could even reinterpret the previously
shown as dots proportional to employment in size, a discussed evidence on the role of human capital (in
lowess regression line and Pearson’s correlation particular, education) in a different way. The observed
coefficient (the same representation used earlier in association between levels of education and
Figure 15). occupational wage differentials may be the result of
credentialism and occupational closure, rather than
According to these results, there is no clear correlation productivity differentials. Some occupational groups
between the overall level of routine of jobs and their may try to artificially inflate educational requirements
wage levels, and certainly not a negative association. If as a way to restrict new entrants and increase their
the index of routine tasks is broken down into its two bargaining power, a process which could also generate
subcomponents, repetitiveness and standardisation the observed association between education and
(Eurofound, 2016b), it can be seen that this lack of occupational wage differentials. The data used for this
correlation conceals two opposite associations for the study does not allow this to be clarified, but an
lower-level indicators. The degree of repetitiveness in ambiguity in the interpretation of the results on the role
the job is negatively associated with wages, whereas the of human capital differences must at least be
degree of standardisation is positively associated, acknowledged in explaining occupational wage
though to a much lower extent. This suggests that the differentials.
extent (and type) of routine task content of the different

14 This is a very simplified version of the argument of routine-biased technological change, for two reasons. First, the argument refers to change in wage
levels rather than the wage differentials observed at any point in time. Second, it does not replace but complements the human capital argument: the
level of routine would constitute a secondary axis of wage inequality, additional to the traditional axis of skills (thus, highly routine occupations would
tend to be in the middle of the wage distribution, rather than the bottom). A detailed discussion of this argument is beyond the scope of this report (see
Acemoglu and Autor, 2011 and Mishel et al, 2013), but the simple analysis presented in this report is still useful because, after decades of computerisation,
the predicted decline in wages of routine occupations should already be reflected in actually lower wages. In addition, recent empirical evidence suggests
that routine tasks and skill level are very strongly correlated, forming a common axis in terms of occupational differences rather than two different ones
(see Fernández-Macías and Hurley, 2016).

43
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 16: Relationship between level of routine in jobs and their average wages, nine Member States
Index of routine tasks Repetitiveness Standardisation

corr: -0.13 corr: -0.50 corr: 0.28


4 4 4

3 3 3
Germany 2 2 2

1 1 1
0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.12 corr: -0.54 corr: 0.33


5 5 5

4 4 4

3 3 3
France
2 2 2

1 1 1

0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.15 corr: -0.51 corr: 0.28


4 4 4

3 3 3
Netherlands
2 2 2

1 1 1

0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.16 corr: -0.46 corr: 0.19


2.5 2.5 2.5
2 2 2
1.5 1.5 1.5
Romania 1 1 1
.5 .5 .5
0 0 0

0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.11 corr: -0.52 corr: 0.32


5 5 5

4 4 4

UK 3 3 3

2 2 2

1 1 1
0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.09 corr: -0.51 corr: 0.34


5 5 5

4 4 4

Spain 3 3 3

2 2 2

1 1 1
0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.33 corr: -0.47 corr: -0.06


5 5 5

4 4 4
Italy 3 3 3

2 2 2

1 1 1
0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: -0.27 corr: -0.58 corr: 0.13


3 3 3
2.5 2.5 2.5
2 2 2
Poland 1.5 1.5 1.5
1 1 1
.5 .5 .5
0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

corr: 0.01 corr: -0.36 corr: 0.34


4.5 4.5 4.5

4 4 4
Sweden 3.5 3.5 3.5

3 3 3

2.5 2.5 2.5

0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1 0 .25 .5 .75 1

Source: European Working Conditions Survey for level of routine and SES 2010 for wages (authors’ analysis)

44
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

However, one can try to test some of the sociological Figure 17 shows a visual decomposition of the total
arguments discussed earlier, in particular whether the variance of log wages in each country into three
observed occupational differentials are less important components:
than broader class distinctions. Occupations have
£ the variance resulting from between-class
always played a very important role in class theory:
differentials (‘explained between classes’, shown in
they are the backbone of the two most influential
blue);
contemporary class schemes (those of E. O. Wright and
J. Goldthorpe), although both also rely on other £ the variance resulting from between-job
variables (employment status, managerial and differentials within each of the five classes
supervisory roles). But the full list of occupations or jobs (‘explained between jobs within classes’, in orange);
would be, from this perspective, unnecessarily detailed £ the residual inequality that exists within jobs, also
for the analysis of most social phenomena (such as the distributed across the five classes (‘not explained,
wage distribution), as well as lacking in some important by classes’, in green).
dimensions of social power within productive
It is striking that the five very simple and crude pseudo-
organisations (such as capital ownership or supervisory
classes account in all countries for a significant amount
position). In empirical terms, this argument would imply
of the variance explained by jobs. As usual, there is
that a much smaller set of categories (classes) would be
cross-country variation, but in all countries the
able to account for most of the observed inequality in
differences between the five classes account for more
wages.
than half of the variance explained by jobs, and in most
Unfortunately, the SES data used here do not include countries for more than two-thirds. But the five simple
the self-employed nor any information on the classes also provide a very interesting additional piece
managerial or supervisory roles of employees (beyond of information: the extent of wage inequality within
what is implicit in ISCO); this means a full test of this each one of them also differs quite significantly, both
hypothesis cannot be tested with the data. However, a between and within jobs. In most countries, the most
crude approximation to the Goldthorpe scheme can be unequal class is the higher service one (the exceptions
constructed (which is in practice quite close, though not being Germany and the Netherlands), whereas the
identical, to a reaggregation of occupations into one- classes more internally homogeneous in terms of wages
digit ISCO codes), assigning two-digit ISCO codes to are skilled and unskilled manual workers everywhere.
each of five categories:
So even with this very crude approach, the social class
£ higher service class (professionals, administrators, argument seems quite compelling. Five very broad
managers and high-grade technicians); classes defined by the type of employment relationship
£ lower service class (technicians and lower-grade and skill level can already account for a significant
professionals); proportion of the variance explained by a very detailed
list of jobs (between 450 and 650). At least for some
£ routine non-manual workers (routine
purposes, one could argue on the basis of parsimony
administration, commerce and other service
that the simple class scheme should be used rather than
workers);
the long list of occupations. Furthermore (although this
£ skilled manual workers; is only speculation) it seems likely that, if the classes
£ semi-skilled and unskilled manual workers. could have been built properly, the results would have
The Goldthorpe proposal differentiates social classes been even more significant.
according to two principles: first, the ownership of the However, as in the case of the human capital argument,
means of production; and second, the nature of the the full list of occupations/jobs still adds a significant
employment relationship (Erikson and Goldthorpe, amount of explanatory power to this analysis, so it is
1992). The first principle is almost entirely missing in empirically justified to keep using them. Because of the
this crude five-class classification, but the second limitations of the data (the impossibility of building
(mainly aimed at distinguishing those employees with a proper classes), it cannot confidently be said that a
labour contract from employees with service detailed occupational approach is superior to a simpler
relationships, as well as differentiating skill levels) is class scheme to explain the observed wage inequalities.
reasonably well covered. But it can be said that the full classification of
occupations works better with the data and tools
available: as was argued earlier in the case of human
capital, classes are (a significant) part of the story but
not all of it.

45
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

The final argument to be evaluated refers to self-selection may be at play too). The most important
occupational segregation as an explanation for occupational segregation factors mentioned in the
occupational wage differentials. As with human capital, literature are gender, ethnicity or migrant origin, and, to
in this argument occupations are not the source of the a lesser extent, age. Unfortunately, the SES does not
differentials but a mediating factor for an external provide information on the ethnicity or migrant origin of
mechanism, in this case discrimination linked to respondents, so that important factor cannot be
sociodemographic characteristics (though other covered. However, data on gender and age are available,
mechanisms such as culturally or socially mediated so this argument can at least partially be evaluated.

Figure 17: Class versus job decomposition of wage inequality, nine Member States

France Germany
Not explained, by classes Explained between classes Not explained, by classes Explained between classes

Routine non-manual Lower service

Higher service Lower service Explained between jobs within classes

Explained between jobs within classes Lower service


Lower
service Higher Unskilled
Routine S service manual
Skilled Unskilled non- k
manual Higher service Unskilled manual Higher service Skilled manual Routine non-manual Skilled manual
Routine non-manual Unskilled manual manual manual il

Italy Netherlands
Not explained, by classes Explained between classes Not explained, by classes Explained between classes

Routine non-manual Higher service

Routine non-manual Higher service

Explained between jobs within classes


Explained between jobs within classes
Unskilled
manual Higher
Lower service
Routine service Skilled
manual Skil
Unskilled Skilled Higher non- Unskilled Lower led
Lower service manual manual service manual Skilled manual Lower service Unskilled manual Farm Routine non-manual manual service ma

Poland Romania
Not explained, by classes Explained between classes Not explained, by classes Explained between classes

Higher service

Unskilled
Higher service manual

Unskilled manual Lower service Explained between jobs within classes


Explained between jobs within classes
Routine non-
manual
Routine
non- Skilled
Lower
Unskilled manual manual
Unskilled Skilled servi-
Routine non-manual Skilled manual Higher service manual Lower service Routine non-manual Lower service Skilled manual Higher service manual manual ce

46
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

Spain Sweden
Not explained, by classes Explained between classes Not explained, by classes Explained between classes

Higher service
Higher service Lower service

Explained between jobs within classes

Lower
Explained between jobs within classes service
Unskilled
Unskilled manual manual Routine non-manual
Unskilled
manual
Routine
Higher non- Lower Skilled Skilled Routine Skil
non- led
Routine non-manual Skilled manual service manual service manual Lower service Unskilled manual manual Higher service manual ma

UK
Not explained, by classes Explained between classes

Higher service

Lower service
Explained between jobs within classes

Unskilled Skilled Unskilled Lower


Routine
manual manual service
Routine non-manual manual Higher service non-manual

Source: SES 2010 (authors’ analysis)

Figure 18 shows a decomposition of the total log wage occupations are the result of differences in pay by
variance explained by jobs (the same previously shown gender and age (and differences in the gender and age
in Column 6 of Table 3) for different sets of explanatory composition of jobs, that is, segregation), eliminating
variables. The approach is similar to the one used them from the picture (expressing wages net of their
earlier for evaluating the human capital argument: fit a compositional effect) would leave very small residual
multivariate regression equation using different between-job differentials. As Figure 18 shows, according
explanatory variables, and then see whether the to this approach, gender and age segregation only
variance of the residual is linked to occupations/jobs. In account for a significant share of occupational wage
this case, the approach is generalised by adding more differentials in the Netherlands (more than one-quarter)
and more variables to the model, starting with gender and to a lesser extent in Sweden and the UK. It is
and age, then adding education, then employment important to note that this does not mean that there is
attributes (tenure, part-time and temporary status), no occupational segregation or indeed wage
then company-level variables (establishment size, discrimination in the other countries; what it means is
ownership and collective agreement) and finally region. that gender and age do not play such a significant role
By comparing (subtracting) the variance explained by in occupational wage differentials. It is very unfortunate
jobs for wages computed net of the factors of each of that information on ethnicity or migrant origin is
those successive models to the variance explained for unavailable (which would probably explain some of the
the original wage variable, the role they play (if any) can occupational wage differentials in some countries), but
be evaluated in the observed between-job wage it seems unlikely that adding it would change the
differentials. overall picture very significantly. So, again, segregation
is part of the story, although in this case a smaller part
The first variables modelled are gender and age, and
and not even in all countries. The structuring role that
their impact on between-job wage differentials can be
occupations play in wage inequalities is not mainly the
interpreted as evidence of (gender and age)
result of segregation mechanisms.
segregation. If most of the differences in wages between

47
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 18: Decomposition of the total log wage variance explained by jobs for different sets of explanatory
variables, nine Member States
60

50

40

30

20

10

0
Germany Netherlands Spain France Sweden Italy Romania UK Poland

-10

Gender and age Plus educaon


Plus tenure, part-me and temporary status Plus establishment size, ownership and collecve agreement
Plus region Residual inequality explained by job

Source: SES 2010 (authors’ analysis)

The addition of education and other factors in Figure 18 variables included in Figure 18 is often crude and, in
allows a rough estimate to be made of the ‘pure’ some cases, even inconsistent across countries in the
explanatory power of occupation/job with respect to SES (for instance, establishment variables and regions
wage inequality (the segment labelled ‘residual are not strictly comparable). These inconsistencies may
inequality explained by job’). It is significant in all partly explain some of the observed differences in
countries, but there are very wide differences, from just Figure 18, but it is impossible to know to what extent.
under 25% in the Netherlands to nearly 60% in Sweden Secondly, understanding education as a variable
and the UK. It is tempting to interpret this residual as an exogenous to occupation in this context is problematic
indication of the effect of the main factor that could not because it is explicitly used as a criterion to differentiate
be empirically tested with the data, that of occupational levels. This makes it logically impossible
occupational closure (and mechanisms such as to disentangle the effect of occupation on the
occupational licensing, credentialing, certification, distribution of wages from the effect of education, at
unionisation and representation by associations). least in the simple way shown in Figure 18. Educational
However, the authors would caution against such differences (or more precisely, differences in
interpretation. Firstly, the measurement level of the key educational requirements) are a crucial aspect of the
occupational classification itself.

48
Static analysis of the role of occupations in determining the wage distribution

Summary
This first empirical section can be summarised with the following points.
£ Detailed occupations or jobs account for a significant part of wage inequality in Europe: between 40% and
50% in the countries studied here.
£ Human capital differences are part of the reason why occupations account for such a significant amount of
wage inequality, but not all. Occupations matter for wage inequality even if human capital differences are
controlled for.
£ Broad occupational classes defined by the nature of their employment contract and skill level can account
for a significant part of the explanatory power of occupations on wage inequality, though not all of it.
£ Occupational segregation by gender and age is also part of the reason why occupations structure a
significant amount of wage inequality, but only in some European countries.
Overall, occupations seem to play an important role on their own that cannot be (entirely) reduced to other
factors such as human capital, classes or segregation. Although the data used did not enable the direct evaluation
of the role of occupational closure mechanisms, they remain a plausible explanation for some of the observed
variance in wages that is linked to occupations but cannot be explained away by other factors.

49
6 Occupational wage differentials
across European institutional
models
can be moved across companies and industries. As a
Varieties of capitalism and result, the distribution of wages in LMEs tends to be
occupational wage structures more unequal and less structured by industries or
The main empirical observation made in Chapter 5 was sectors than in CMEs.
that occupations are an important structuring factor of It seems plausible that the distinction between LMEs
wage inequalities in all the European countries studied. and CMEs would also have implications for the role of
However, there were differences between countries in occupations in structuring wage inequality. Although
some important details with respect to how overall wage inequality is lower in CMEs, the higher level
occupations structured wage inequalities. For instance, of coordination in wage bargaining, generally at
in some countries, there were big outliers in the industry level, could be expected to make within-
distribution of wages that seemed unrelated to the occupation (or industry) wages more homogeneous and
occupational structure. The extent to which between-occupation (or industry) wages more
occupational wage differentials could be explained by heterogeneous, thus making occupational differentials
the composition of jobs by gender, age or education more important for the distribution of wages.
varied significantly across countries, as did the Furthermore, the higher specificity of skills in CMEs
significance of broadly defined social classes in the could reinforce occupational boundaries. As a result,
structuring of occupational wage inequalities. one could expect lower wage inequality in CMEs but a
Is it possible to make sense of those country more important structuring role for occupations,
differences? Can the countries be somehow grouped in whereas LMEs would produce higher levels of inequality
different categories or models with respect to how in overall terms, but primarily within rather than across
occupations structure wage inequality? And perhaps occupational boundaries (making occupations less
most importantly, can those patterns and country relevant for wage inequality).
groupings be related to different socioeconomic However, the relevance of this approach for the
models, as identified by the recent political economy purposes of the current analysis is limited by its
literature on varieties of European capitalism? generality. In this study’s small sample of nine European
Literature on the varieties of capitalism distinguishes countries, there is only one clear case of an LME (the
two distinct types of advanced capitalist economies, UK), with all the others being variations of the CME
liberal market economies (LME) and coordinated model. And there are reasons to believe that the
market economies (CME), according to the predominant variations within the CME model are indeed substantial
ways in which companies coordinate with each other and likely to produce very different results in terms of
and other actors in five different spheres – industrial the structuring role of occupations in the distribution of
relations, vocational training and education, corporate wages. The degree of centralisation and coverage of
governance, inter-company relations, and relations with collective bargaining in CMEs varies considerably across
employees (Hall and Soskice, 2001, p. 8). In LMEs, the Europe (European Commission, 2009), as well as union
main forms of coordination are competitive markets strategies and even ideological orientation; for instance,
and hierarchies, while in CMEs, companies rely more on in Sweden, unions have traditionally pursued a national
non-market forms of coordination. These different strategy of wage compression, explicitly aimed at
forms of coordination produce different outcomes in reducing the gaps between high-paid and low-paid
terms of wage distribution (Rueda and Pontusson, occupations and sectors, whereas in other countries,
2000). Wage-bargaining structures and skills systems wage bargaining is considerably less coordinated across
are key mechanisms in this respect. Whereas in CMEs industries and less explicitly egalitarian. The role of
union density tends to be high and wage bargaining unions and collective bargaining in wage determination
relatively centralised and coordinated at the industry or is also changing in different ways and at different rates
national level, in LMEs the social partners are less across CMEs; in Germany, for instance, collective
organised, and bargaining takes place primarily at bargaining coverage has declined significantly since the
company level. In CMEs, workers tend to have specific 1990s, which has contributed quite clearly to growing
skills tied to the company or industry where they work, wage inequality and to a widening gap between
while in LMEs, they tend to have more general skills that unionised and non-unionised industries and

51
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

occupations (Dustmann et al, 2009). The systems of simultaneously) and then comparing it with each
vocational training and education also vary quite individual occupational wage distribution.
significantly between different CMEs; whereas in
Finally, a detailed analysis of the relative distance
Germany, apprenticeship systems are highly developed
between the average wages of a set of specific
(with the significant participation of unions and
occupations in each country is added, as well as
occupational associations) and likely to reinforce the
between occupational quintiles.
role of occupations in structuring wage inequality
(Bol and Weeden, 2014; see also Kampelmann and Rycx,
2013), in other CMEs, apprenticeship systems hardly A discussion of country
exist.
differences
Furthermore, the occupational closure approach
emphasises the importance of specific institutional All the results are summarised in Table 4. The nine
settings such as occupational licensing or credentialing countries analysed here (representing different
that are difficult to associate clearly with the very broad European institutional families) have been more or less
distinction of LME versus CME. For instance, sorted in the table by their overall level of wage
occupational licensing plays a very important role in the inequality, shown in the first row of results using the
LMEs of the UK and the USA, but also in CMEs such as Gini index. The most unequal wage distribution is that
Denmark, Italy and Spain (Kleiner, 2015). of Romania, closely followed by the UK and Poland,
then southern Europe (Italy and Spain), continental
In short, it is difficult to make specific hypotheses about Europe (France, Germany and the Netherlands), and
how occupational wage differentials should vary across finally the lowest level of wage inequality by far of
European institutional families. At most, countries that Sweden. Germany is something of an outlier, since its
are institutionally similar can be expected to be also level of wage inequality puts it closer to the UK or
similar in this respect, and distinct from the rest. eastern Europe than to the continental countries.15
Perhaps one could even advance the hypothesis that However, it is left in that position to facilitate the
Sweden and the UK (as perhaps the most distinct cases comparison with countries that are institutionally
of the CME and LME models, respectively) should similar.
produce the most clearly different results, with the
other countries and models somewhere between. In the UK
following pages, the role of occupations in structuring In the UK, the second most unequal country in Table 4,
wage inequality is analysed systematically in the sample occupational differences account for more than half of
of nine European countries, looking for patterns and all the inequality in log wages (see Row 2a). This would
similarities, and trying to link them to the patterns of contradict some of the arguments stated earlier,
overall inequality and to broad institutional differences. although there is an important qualification: as
To do this, this study first re-evaluates some of the main discussed in Chapter 5, in the UK, occupations matter
findings discussed in Chapter 5, in particular: for wage inequality only if wages are logged. If raw
wages are used as the dependent variable, the share of
£ the levels of overall wage inequality; variance explained by detailed occupations (all the
£ the variance of wages that can be explained by combinations of occupation and sector at the two-digit
occupational differentials; level) is remarkably low, at 12.1% (Table 4, Row 2b). The
£ the link between occupational differentials and importance of some very large wages, and their
human capital, age, gender and social classes. apparent independence from the occupational
structure, is something peculiar to the UK – only in
Secondly, some extra analysis focuses specifically on
France can a similar phenomenon be observed, but to a
country differences. The similarity of occupational
lesser extent.
structures is evaluated across Europe, constructing with
a principal components analysis a hypothetical EU-level Rows 6a and 6b of Table 4 show another peculiar aspect
occupational wage distribution (the one that is most of the UK occupational wage structure. A principal
correlated with all national wage structures components analysis of occupational wages was
performed for the nine European countries shown in the

15 Recent literature argues that the German model has taken a dualisation path in recent years, which has led to a significant expansion of labour market
inequalities (Thelen, 2012). But dualisation involves an increasing divide between the conditions of work and employment of insiders and outsiders, not a
generalised flexibilisation of the labour market. Therefore, the German model remains different from the liberal regime of the UK. Dualisation can be seen
as an inegalitarian version of the CME model. The effect of dualisation on the structuring role of occupations in wage inequality will depend on whether
the boundaries between insiders and outsiders cut across occupations or are associated with different occupational categories.

52
Occupational wage differentials across European institutional models

Table 4: Summary of country differences


Sweden France Germany Netherlands Italy Spain Poland Romania UK
1. Overall wage inequality (Gini) 18.91 27.28 32.68 29.40 28.66 29.58 35.27 39.02 36.83
2a. Variance of log wages explained by job 47.24 45.32 41.67 42.54 47.39 43.48 52.93 48.91 51.12
2b. Variance of wages (not logged) 32.48 18.11 38.88 29.13 41.46 31.55 36.34 35.15 12.07
explained by job
2c. Difference 2a - 2b 14.76 27.21 2.79 13.41 5.93 11.93 16.59 13.76 39.05
3a. Variance of log wages explained by 11.56 25.38 41.03 42.90 33.67 36.40 35.25 28.49 16.39
educaon + tenure
3b. Variance of log wages net of human 41.97 29.43 25.33 14.80 20.65 19.68 25.35 28.44 37.75
capital explained by job
4a. Variance of log wages explained by five 25.56 33.77 24.41 29.27 34.47 30.73 36.24 26.95 39.68
broad classes
4b. Variance within jobs in upper service 1.53 1.40 1.03 1.00 1.64 1.46 1.35 1.61 1.59
class versus empirical share
4c. Same, for skilled and unskilled working 0.50 0.78 0.89 0.92 0.67 0.71 0.72 0.68 0.58
class
5. Effect of control by gender and age in 5.23 0.80 1.90 12.87 1.70 0.18 0.25 0.41 6.34
variance explained by job
6a. Uniqueness in occupaonal wages 0.18 0.11 0.13 0.16 0.17 0.11 0.18 0.14 0.08
logged (PCF)
6b. Uniqueness in occupaonal wages not 0.14 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.22 0.12 0.20 0.18 0.20
logged (PCF)
7a. Relave differences between job-wage 1.22 1.34 1.54 1.64 1.40 1.33 1.59 1.81 1.70
quinles: quinle 3/quinle 1
7b. Relave differences between job-wage 1.60 1.94 2.04 1.69 1.93 1.92 2.30 2.25 2.16
quinles: quinle 5/quinle 3
8. Differences between quinles within Low Mid Low Low Mid Mid Mid High High
inequality
9. Percentage difference between wage of
cleaners in business services and wage of:
9a. Sales workers in retail 23% 21% 31% 0% 33% 2% 29% 35% 8%
9b. Building and related trades workers in 41% 23% 47% 62% 45% 19% 47% 57% 109%
construcon
9c. Metal and machine trades workers in 30% 36% 72% 42% 43% 47% 76% 94% 73%
metal manufacturing
9d. Business administraon associated 90% 94% 230% 102% 181% 107% 166% 204% 216%
professionals in private business services
9e. Health professionals in health and 74% 160% 253% 153% 362% 185% 159% 203% 215%
social services
Notes: Shading from light to dark highlights low to high values per row. PCF = principal component factor.
Source: SES 2010 (authors’ analysis)

table. This statistical procedure generates a new well-paid in one country, it tends to be very well-paid in
variable (factor) that is a linear combination of the other countries too. But by looking at the correlation (or
occupational wages of all nine countries and can lack of it) between the occupational wages of each
therefore be understood as a kind of latent pan- country and the generated factor, one can also get an
European wage structure, since it assigns to each ‘job’ a idea of how peculiar each wage structure is: this is the
value that is closest to the observed values of wages of coefficient of ‘uniqueness’ reported in Rows 6a and 6b
all countries simultaneously. In other words, this factor for wages and log wages. Looking at the results for the
is a newly constructed variable that summarises most UK, it can be seen that it goes from being one of the
efficiently the distribution of occupational wages in all most ‘unique’ countries in terms of its occupational
countries. The factor accounts for 84% and 86% of the (raw) wages to being one of the least ‘unique’ when the
observed variability in occupational wages and log wages are logged. If one disregards (or rescales) the
wages, respectively. This, on its own, means that there values of some large outliers, the UK wage distribution
is a remarkable consistency in occupational wages is very similar to that of any European country; if one
across European countries: when a particular job is very does not, the UK becomes very idiosyncratic.

53
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Rows 7, 8 and 9 in Table 4 provide a further glimpse into Another surprising similarity between Sweden and the
the peculiarities of occupational wages in the UK. The UK is that human capital differences seem less
relative distance between occupational wages in the UK important in both countries for explaining occupational
is very large, as could be expected considering the very wage differentials than in other countries. Row 3a of
high levels of general inequality. For instance, the Table 4 shows the variance explained by a model with
occupations/jobs in the middle quintile are 1.7 times education and tenure (a simple Mincer equation), which
higher, on average, than those in the first quintile (Row is lowest in these two countries as well. The result for
7a); and those in the top quintile are 2.16 times larger Sweden is consistent with previous estimates such as
than in the middle quintile (Row 7b): only in eastern those of Badescu et al (2011), while the result for the UK
Europe are those differentials slightly bigger. Looking at seems a bit low though not implausible. But the
specific jobs (Rows 9a–9e), one can see that the important thing is that in these two countries,
between-job differentials in the UK are, on average, occupation accounts for a large share of the variation of
larger (even if there may be specific cases of jobs with wages net of human capital differences (the residual of
much larger differentials in particular countries, such as the Mincer equation’s fitted values), suggesting that
health professionals in Italy). A final interesting occupational wage differentials are less explained by
peculiarity of the UK is that the five broadly defined broad human capital differences than in other
social classes constructed in Chapter 5 account for the countries. So contrary to expectations, and despite their
largest proportion of overall wage variance in any big differences in terms of wage inequality and actual
country (four-fifths of the total variance explained by occupational wage differentials (big in the UK, small in
detailed jobs can be explained by just five broadly Sweden), the role played by occupations in structuring
defined social classes). wage inequality seems equally important in both
countries.
So the UK comes out as a very unequal labour market
with large occupational wage differentials, strongly
Poland and Romania
related to broad occupational classes, and an
occupational wage hierarchy similar to that of the rest Besides the UK, Poland and Romania have high levels of
of Europe except for the (very important) existence of a wage inequality. As shown by Rows 7a–7b and 9a–9e of
small minority of very large wages seemingly unrelated Table 4, occupational wage differentials are as large or
to occupations. even larger than in the UK. And, as shown by Rows 2a–
2c, occupations account for a very significant share of
Sweden overall wage inequality, irrespective of whether wages
are logged or not (which means that big outliers are not
At the other extreme of the table is Sweden, which is in
so important in these wage distributions and that their
many aspects the polar opposite of the UK. In Sweden,
occurrence is better predicted by occupation). One can
overall wage inequality is very low, as are occupational
also see that the Polish occupational wage structure is
differentials. The wages of the middle quintile in
one of the most peculiar in Europe (Rows 7a–7b).
Sweden are only 1.2 times those of the bottom quintile,
and the wages of the top quintile only 1.6 times those of
Italy and Spain
the middle. On average, business administration
associate professionals earn only 90% more than Italy and Spain have middling levels of wage inequality
cleaners in business services, and health professionals and mid-low levels of occupational wage differentials
only 74% more. The five broad social classes account for (see Rows 7a–7b and 9a–9e in Table 4). However, even
a smaller share of overall wage inequality than in any though Italian occupational wages are not very unequal,
other country except Germany, and the degree of there are some very large outliers such as health
residual within-job inequality is similarly low in all five professionals (who earn almost four times as much as
quintiles. cleaners in business services). The Italian occupational
structure is, in fact, the most peculiar of all of Europe,
But even though wage inequality is generally smaller, with some jobs occupying very different positions in the
the role played by occupations in structuring it is wage structure than in other European countries (as
actually high, almost as high as in the UK (occupational shown by the uniqueness statistic of factor analysis in
wages account for 47% of the variance of log wages and Rows 7a–7b). As for the role played by occupations in
32% if wages are not logged). It is important to note that the wage distribution, the ANOVA results of Rows 2a–2c
this does not mean that wage differentials between show moderate values for Spain and high values for
occupations are as high in Sweden as in the UK: as can Italy, irrespective of whether wages are logged or not.
be seen by comparing the values in Rows 7a–7b and 9a–
9e of Table 4, they are much smaller in Sweden. But France, Germany and the Netherlands
wage inequality being generally smaller, it is similarly The group of three continental European countries is
structured by occupations in both countries (again, with the most diverse. Germany has relatively high levels of
the important qualification of the distorting incidence wage inequality and France relatively low, with the
of very large wages in the UK, a phenomenon that is not Netherlands somewhere in the middle. The wage
observed in Sweden).

54
Occupational wage differentials across European institutional models

differentials between occupations are quite high in clearly different outcomes in terms of inequality levels,
Germany, among the highest in the sample of nine according to this analysis, but the same results shows
countries (Rows 7a–7b and 9a–9e in Table 4), whereas in no significant differences in the role played by
the Netherlands occupational wage inequality is high occupations in structuring wage inequality.
only in the lowest half of the distribution (as shown in
A second striking finding concerns the similarity of
Row 7a). An interesting peculiarity of the Netherlands is
occupational hierarchies in Europe despite the large
that it shows the clearest evidence of segregation by
differences in the actual wages associated with the
gender and age as a driver of occupational wage
same occupations in different countries. A principal
differentials (controlling for gender and age reduced the
components analysis enables the construction of a
variance explained by occupation by nearly one-third;
hypothetical or latent EU-level occupational wage
see Row 5 in Table 4), probably linked to the very high
hierarchy (a linear combination of all occupational wage
incidence of part-time employment.
hierarchies, constructed according to their observed
The role played by occupations in wage inequality is correlations) that could, on its own, account for nearly
also quite diverse in the group of continental European 90% of all the information contained in all the country-
countries. It is relatively high in France and relatively level observed occupational wages. In other words, if
low in Germany and the Netherlands. Not logging wages occupation A is better paid than occupation B in one
changes the picture quite significantly in France European country, it is very likely to be also better paid
(because of the incidence of wage outliers and their in all the other countries. This does not mean that the
strong contribution to within-occupation inequality), relative (or absolute) difference between the average
but very little in Germany. In Germany and the wages of those two occupations is also the same across
Netherlands, the five big occupational classes account countries: the actual wage differentials will vary
for a small proportion of overall inequality, and wage considerably, as overall wage inequality itself.
inequality within working class occupations is
What these findings suggest is that behind all European
particularly high. In Germany and the Netherlands also,
wage distributions, there is a very similar underlying
human capital differences account for a very significant
occupational backbone. Different institutional
part of occupational wage inequalities, more than in
frameworks may produce different levels of wage
any other country.
inequality overall, but they do not alter the backbone
itself. They may stretch it or compress it (thus increasing
Conclusion or decreasing overall wage inequality), but the sorting
of different occupations in a hierarchy will remain
This chapter has tried to identify systematic differences essentially untouched, as well as the distribution of the
between European countries in the way occupations additional inequality between and within those
structure wage inequality and to link those differences occupations. The striking similarity of this occupational
with European institutional variations. backbone across different European countries and
Perhaps the most significant result is the high level of institutional families suggests that it is the result of
similarity across all countries, rather than the more fundamental features of economic systems, which
differences. In the nine European countries analysed in are shared by all similarly developed economies. In the
the previous pages, occupations account for a similar authors’ view, what this backbone may reflect is the
level of overall wage inequality, between 40% and 50%. underlying similarity in the technical division of labour
It is useful to contrast this with the variation in the level and level of technological development of European
of wage inequality itself: as measured by the Gini index, economies. Even if different European countries have
the most unequal country (Romania) has more than different economic structures, institutional frameworks
double the value of the least unequal (Sweden). What and cultural values, their underlying economic
this means is that, independently of how unequal the processes and organisations share some key features to
distribution of wages is in each country, the proportion the extent that they are similarly developed and
of such inequality that occurs within occupations is organised in a technical sense. Among those similar
roughly the same everywhere (between 50% and 60%), features are the division of labour and the broad range
as well as the proportion of inequality that results from of technologies available for economic processes; these
occupational wage differentials (the remaining 40%– shared features would produce the underlying
50%). It is also surprising that the big differences in backbone to European occupational wages.
wage-setting mechanisms and institutions (coordinated But although the underlying similarities in occupational
by markets or collective agreements, with different wages are striking and suggestive, they are not perfect.
levels of centralisation and coverage, or with different There are also some significant differences across
systems of occupational licensing, credentialing and countries, especially in some of the details and
apprenticeship) do not produce significant differences associated factors. Can they be linked to varieties of
in the extent to which occupations shape the different European capitalism?
wage distributions. Again, these differences produce

55
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Occupational wage differentials (the relative differences Another interesting finding is the wide differences in the
between the average wages associated with different share of occupational wages that can be explained by
occupations) as such do vary across countries as much differences between five broadly defined social classes.
as wage inequality itself and can be easily linked to In Italy, Poland and the UK, this value is remarkably high
European institutional families. The differences (close to 40%), suggesting that, to a large extent, the
between highest- and lowest-paid occupations are structuring role of occupations in wages reflects
largest in the UK and eastern Europe, smallest in broader processes of social stratification rather than
Sweden, and with different gradations across occupation-specific processes of wage differentiation.
continental and southern European countries. But this In other words, broadly defined occupational classes
is hardly a new or exciting finding since occupational (and their associated mechanisms of differentiation) are
wage differentials just reproduce the European considerably more important in those countries than
distribution of wage inequality. The fact that other European countries. In Germany and Sweden, in
occupations explain a similar level of wage inequality in contrast, these broadly defined classes are considerably
all countries, and that wage hierarchies are very similar, less important factors of wage structuration.
implies that the variation in occupational wage
Overall, the attempt to identify groups of European
differentials will be almost identical to the variation in
countries where occupations structure wage
wage inequality itself.
inequalities in similar ways, and to link them to
Some of the differences in the association between institutional variations in economic coordination, has
occupational wage differentials and other variables are been unsuccessful. Clear groups of countries could not
more interesting, although not always easy to explain or be found, nor could a clear link between the effect of
link to institutional frameworks. The link between occupations on the distribution of wages and the broad
human capital and occupational wage differentials is institutional frameworks. However, the reasons for this
smaller in the two polar extremes of European wage failure are themselves interesting findings that suggest
inequality and the most different ‘varieties of European further possibilities for research. First, very significant
capitalism’: Sweden and the UK. Conversely, the differences could not be found because there seems to
strongest association between occupational wages and be a similar underlying structure of occupational wages
human capital as measured by education and across Europe in terms of the distribution of inequality
experience is observed in continental and southern between and within occupations, and in terms of the
Europe. Despite their differences in other respects, implicit hierarchy of average occupational wages.
Sweden and the UK do share a similar orientation in Second, the differences found seemed related to
their educational systems towards general rather than aspects of their institutional framework that are
specific skills development, in contrast with continental specifically linked to occupations and do not necessarily
and southern European systems, where credentialing, vary according to broadly defined variations or
apprenticeship, vocational training and other features institutional families (such as the orientation of
of the educational system tend to produce more specific educational and vocational training systems or the
skills in workers. These differences may explain some of relevance of broadly defined social classes).
the observed differences in the link between
occupational wages and human capital in the different
countries.

56
7 Occupations and the evolution of
wage inequality in Europe
between occupations. For instance, the sociologists Kim
Introduction and Sakamoto (2008) studied the period between 1983
Occupations clearly play an important role in and 2002 in the USA, finding no evidence of an
structuring wage inequality. But did they also play an increasing role for occupations in wage inequality. The
important role in the recent evolution of wage economists Mishel et al (2013), in an explicit rebuttal of
inequality levels? As previously mentioned, in many the findings of Acemoglu and Autor (using the same
countries (though not all and to different extents) wage data but with a different operationalisation), found only
inequality has increased in recent decades. Was this evidence of an increasing role of occupations in
development driven by widening occupational wage explaining US wage inequality between 1979 and 1994,
differentials, or did these remain broadly stable? Or did with a significant decline afterwards.
they actually become less important in recent years, as
Despite using similar approaches and the same data
a result of a widening of wage inequality within rather
sources, the contrast between the findings of these
than between occupations?
different studies is striking. Even within the group of
There are some recent studies relevant to this matter, studies defending an increasing role for occupations,
mostly for the USA and the UK to the authors’ there are important contradictions. For instance, Mouw
knowledge, coming from both sociology and and Kalleberg (2010) found a decreasing role of
economics. But the results are often contradictory in occupations in wage inequality for the period 1983–
their findings, despite analysing similar periods and 1992, in contrast to Weeden et al (2007) and Acemoglu
even using the same data. Some conclude that and Autor (2011). Why are the results of different studies
widening occupational wage differentials and the so inconsistent, and which should be believed?
changing occupational composition of employment (job
These inconsistencies are probably the result of the
polarisation) account to a significant extent for the
methodological challenges of assessing the role of
growing inequality in wages in the USA and the UK in
occupations in wage inequality over long periods of
the 1980s and 1990s. For instance, Weeden et al (2007)
time. Occupational classifications are updated every
found that most of the growth of wage inequality in the
few years (in the USA, they were introduced in 1977,
USA between 1973 and 2005 took place between rather
changed in the late 1990s and changed again in 2010),
than within occupations. In fact, according to these
and the comparability of results before and after those
sociologists, most of this expansion took place between
changes is highly problematic. The updating of
broadly defined occupational classes rather than at the
occupational codes is necessary because technical
level of detailed occupations. Mouw and Kalleberg
change and the unfolding of the division of labour
(2010) found that between-occupation changes
renders them obsolete. But then to the extent that it is
explained two-thirds of the increase in wage inequality
better adapted to the new realities of work, an updated
in the USA between 1992 and 2008, although they
classification should produce more internally consistent
cautioned that at least 23% of this change could be due
occupations and therefore should increase the share of
to a change in occupational codes over that period. The
variance in wages explained. Even if it may be possible
same authors found, however, that between 1983 and
to estimate this reclassification effect in the short run
1992, most of the increase in wage inequalities took
(for instance, Mouw and Kalleberg, 2010 attribute
place within rather than between occupations. The
almost one-third of the increase in wage variance
economists Acemoglu and Autor (2011) used a variance
explained by occupations in the USA in the 1990s to this
decomposition approach to argue that broadly defined
effect), the comparability of occupational codes in the
occupations (10 categories) became significantly more
long run remains problematic and the results very
important as explanatory factors for wage inequality
sensitive to small methodological decisions on how
between 1979 and 2009, compared with other factors
occupations are treated for long-term analysis.
such as education. For the UK, Williams (2013) reported
similar findings, with occupations accounting for an A more general methodological problem is the
increasing share of the variance in wages between 1975 increasing importance of very large outliers in the
and 2008; again, most of this increase being related to distribution of wages. A recent and very influential
broadly defined occupational groups or classes. strand of the literature on income and earnings
distribution has argued that the recent increase in
But in both sociology and economics, other studies
inequality is mostly the result of a massive expansion of
contest these findings and claim that most of the
labour income for those at the very top of the
expansion of inequalities took place within rather than
distribution (the top 1% or top 0.1%; see Piketty, 2014,

57
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

especially Chapter 9; also OECD, 2011). This


development, according to the same literature, is very
Analysis of the role of
poorly captured in standard government surveys on occupations in the recent
income and wages such as the US Current Population
Survey (Atkinson et al, 2011), as a result of under-
evolution of wage inequality
reporting, sparse data, non-contact or refusals by top Before starting the analysis with EU-SILC data, it is
earners (to uncover these trends in top labour earnings, necessary to briefly mention some limitations of this
these studies used administrative registers and tax data source, which are mostly related to the data used
return data instead). Since most of the studies on and the period covered. First, EU-SILC aims to measure
occupational wages use surveys, they may miss a income rather than wages, providing only an
significant part of the growth in wage inequality. This approximate measure of the latter that must be
problem may be compounded by the common practice constructed under weighty assumptions and can
of using log wages rather than monetary wages as the conceal some of the real variation of wages while
variable whose variance is to be explained. As seen introducing some variation unrelated to wages. Second,
earlier in the case of the UK, logging wages can increase the sample size is relatively small (a few thousand
dramatically the share of variance explained by cases), which is particularly problematic when the goal
occupations if there are very large outliers, but it makes is to evaluate how the variance is distributed between
the interpretation problematic if large outliers are a and across a very large number of groups (detailed
feature and not a bug of the distribution. Among the occupations or jobs). Third, although occupation is
previously mentioned studies, the one that finds less measured at the two-digit level, sector is only measured
evidence of a growing role for between-occupation at the one-digit level (even slightly more aggregated, in
differentials (Kim and Sakamoto, 2008) uses dollar fact), which may not yield a sufficient level of
wages rather than log wages as the dependent variable. granularity to the approach taken here. Finally, the
period 2005–2014 is too short for making an evaluation
Of course, some of these methodological problems will
of the long-term contribution of occupational trends on
affect this study, too, but they will be addressed as
wage inequality, with any analysis likely to be biased by
explicitly as possible; in the case of changing
cyclical developments.
classifications, by trying to explicitly discuss the
potential effect of breaks and, in the case of big outliers, How have those limitations been dealt with? With
looking at wages both logged and in euros for respect to the measure of wages and the sample, the
comparison. The problem of missing the top wage results of EU-SILC are compared with those obtained
earners is a more intractable one, because the authors earlier with the SES (see previous chapters), which is a
do not know of any administrative data source that much better survey for the purposes of this analysis (it
includes reliable information on occupation. has a very large sample and a good measure of wages)
despite being available in practice for just one year.
Before embarking on a data analysis, it is important to
With respect to the classification variables, previous
clarify the ways in which occupations could affect the
chapters have already shown that occupation at the
evolution of wage inequality. The first and most obvious
two-digit level already captures most of the variation of
effect would be via occupational wage differentials: if
the more detailed occupation-by-sector combination.
the differences between the average wages of
But since this study is mostly interested in evaluating
occupations become larger over time, they would drive
trends rather than making a precise assessment of the
up overall wage inequality even if within each
importance of occupations at any point in time, this
occupation the distribution of wages would remain
should not be a big problem. And finally, even if only a
stable. Second, occupations could also affect wage
short period of time can be looked at, it is a period of
inequality compositionally; even if average wages across
particularly intense occupational change in terms of
occupations and wage inequality within occupations
employment, which should allow a broad evaluation of
remain stable, wage inequality could increase if
whether this change has affected inequality. This short-
employment expanded in high-paid and low-paid
term analysis is complemented, however, with some
occupations relative to the middle. That is how the well-
exploratory medium-term results using the Luxembourg
known phenomenon of job polarisation could have led
Income Study (see Annex 6). In Annex 7, a similar
to an expansion of wage inequalities. Finally, overall
analysis is presented using a national-level dataset with
inequality could also expand if employment in the most
a much larger sample, the Spanish Continuous Sample
internally unequal occupations grew faster than in the
of Working Life. The results are very consistent with the
most internally homogeneous. For instance,
ones presented here using EU-SILC.
deindustrialisation can produce that effect because the
distribution of wages in services tends to be more ANOVA test
unequal than in manufacturing.
The analysis begins with a breakdown of the variance
approach, which in Chapter 5 established that detailed

58
Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality in Europe

occupations account for between 40% and 50% of the inequality.17 However, it seems a picture of either
total variance in wages. Now the same approach can be stability or growth, with only one clear case of a decline
used to evaluate whether the structuring role played by in the share of wage variance explained by occupations
occupations in the distribution of wages has changed in (France). There are three countries where the variance
recent years. This is shown in Figures 19 and 20, for raw accounted for by occupations clearly and significantly
and logged wages, respectively, for nine European increased over the period: Finland, Poland and Spain. In
countries between 2005 and 2014.16 It is important to Germany and Italy, the trend also suggests an increase,
compare the values produced by EU-SILC with the but much slighter (and potentially reversible). In the
values provided previously using the SES, which is a Netherlands and the UK, the figures show a lot of
more adequate source. As could be expected because of volatility, which in the case of the Netherlands may be
the limitations previously discussed, the values are linked to the business cycle but in the UK just looks very
generally around 10 percentage points lower with inconsistent (especially when wages are not logged).
EU-SILC than with SES, but otherwise the picture Romania shows a more stable pattern, perhaps also
painted by both sources seems reasonably consistent. with some cyclicality since it first consistently declines
And again, the main objective of this chapter is to and then marginally increases. Finally, as already
evaluate the trend rather than to establish the mentioned, France is the only case of a more or less
importance of occupations in structuring wage clear decline (though again with some volatility).
inequality.
So bearing in mind all the limitations previously stated,
Figures 19 and 20 paint a quite diverse and somewhat the data suggest a stable or slightly increasing role of
volatile picture of the recent change in the role played occupational wage differentials in structuring wage
by occupations in structuring European wage inequality in Europe during the past decade. This

Figure 19: Share of variance explained by job and occupation, wages not logged

Germany Spain Finland

.4
.3
.2
.1

France Italy Netherlands

.4
Variance explained

.3
.2
.1

Poland Romania UK

.4
.3
.2
.1
2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015

Job Occupation
Note: Breaks in the classifications are indicated by the two vertical dotted lines: the first refers to the change in sector (NACE) and the second to
the change in occupation (ISCO).
Source: EU-SILC (authors’ analysis)

16 The countries shown are the same as those analysed in Chapter 5 using SES data, except that Finland has replaced Sweden. The reason is that the
Swedish results using EU-SILC seem problematic for occupations, with a much lower share of variance explained for no obvious reason. Since SES data
are much more adequate for the purposes of this study, it was decided to replace Sweden in this chapter with Finland as another representative of the
northern European social democratic economies.

17 The breaks in the NACE and ISCO classifications in Figures 19 and 20 are in some cases associated with discontinuities in the trend that should therefore
be ignored in the analysis. The clearest case is Spain, with big jumps around the classification breaks.

59
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure 20: Share of variance explained by job and occupation, wages logged

Germany Spain Finland

.4
.35
.3
.25
.2

France Italy Netherlands


Variance explained

.4
.35
.3
.25
.2

Poland Romania UK
.4
.35
.3
.25
.2

2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015

Job Occupation
Note: Breaks in the classifications are indicated by the two vertical dotted lines: the first refers to the change in sector (NACE) and the second to
the change in occupation (ISCO).
Source: EU-SILC (authors’ analysis)

impression is reinforced if one focuses on the period reflect the overall level of inequality in the country,
after the onset of the crisis (around 2008), when in some which is not directly shown in the figure but can be
cases there is a change in the trend. inferred), plus the share that the between component
represents over the total Theil (the ‘explained’ indicator,
Theil index test which has a similar interpretation to the variance
That does not necessarily mean that occupations have explained by occupations and which can be used to
been driving wage inequality developments in recent evaluate the role they play in structuring wage
years. A Theil index decomposition can help to clarify inequality).
this, a tool that was also used for the static analysis in The explained indicator shown in Figure 21 (the dashed
Chapter 5. The Theil index itself is a measure of the line) paints a very similar picture to the ANOVA
degree of inequality in a distribution, which can be previously discussed. But the evolution of inequality
directly compared across countries and over time. It can between and within occupations can now be looked at
be broken down by any grouping variable such as as well, and it suggests a rather different interpretation.
job/occupation, into a within component (an It is the within component that drives change in the
aggregation of the level of wage inequality that exists overall level of inequality in most cases, even when the
within occupations) and a between component (the share of inequality that is directly linked to occupational
extent of wage inequality that results from differences differentials tends to grow. The reason is, simply, that
between the average wages of different occupations). the between component tends to be very stable; and
Figure 21 shows the yearly evolution of the within and when it changes, it tends to move in parallel with the
between components of Theil (added, they would evolution of the within component.

60
Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality in Europe

Figure 21: Theil decomposition of wage inequality by detailed occupations (jobs)

Germany Spain Finland


.3 .4
.2 .35
.3
.1 .25
0 .2

France Italy Netherlands


Theil decomposition

.3 .4
.2 .35
.3
.1 .25
0 .2

Poland Romania UK
.3 .4
.2 .35
.3
.1 .25
0 .2

2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015

Within Between Explained


Notes: The vertical dotted line indicates a break in the occupational classification. The ‘Explained’ indicator is plotted on the right-hand axis.
Source: EU-SILC (authors’ analysis)

In Finland and Poland, where the increase in the role In order to conclude that occupational dynamics are
played by occupations in the ANOVA was clearer driving wage inequality trends, one should see the
(a result confirmed with the Theil approach), it is a between component changing more significantly than
significant decline in the within component of wage the within component; however, the exact opposite is
inequality that makes the explanatory power of found. A possible objection to this argument is that the
occupations grow (a denominator effect). So, within component may be just more sensitive to
paradoxically, occupations become more important not measurement errors and random noise, while the
because occupational wage differentials grow, but between component (which derives from a comparison
because they remain relatively stable in the face of a of occupation averages) could just be more stable.
generalised decline of wage inequality (which takes Perhaps a long-term analysis would reveal the changes
place mostly within occupations). in the within component to be insignificant, whereas
steady developments in the between component would
The picture is similar in Germany and Italy, although
become more significant over time. Without looking at
with much more stability in both the between and
long-term data, it is difficult to discuss such an
within components. In Romania, both the between and
objection. In some countries, it seems plausible that the
within components clearly declined over the period,
within development just reflects cyclical developments
with only a marginal increase in the importance of the
or even pure statistical noise (this seems a plausible
former in the very last year. And, in France, the only case
case in the UK). But just by looking at the results, the
where the variance explained by occupations
objection does not seem to apply to other countries,
consistently declined, the within component actually
where trends seem similarly consistent in the between
increased over the period while the between
and within components of Theil, and the overall trend is
component remained stable or slightly declined. The
more clear. This objection would also imply that the
apparently cyclical development in the Netherlands is
short-term evolution of wage inequality picked up in
again driven by within-occupation changes, as is the
Figure 21 would itself be too volatile or cyclical, even
volatility of the UK (with between-occupation shifts
though it is reasonably consistent with other recent
being more stable). Even in Spain, where the between
studies.
component seemed to increase more clearly
(particularly between 2008 and 2009), it runs in parallel
with the evolution of within-occupation inequality, and
therefore cannot be said to drive the overall evolution.

61
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

A dynamic decomposition of Theil’s L index analysis). The compositional change is particularly


For a final test of whether occupations are driving wage important for the purposes of this analysis, because it is
inequality trends in Europe, another decomposable how the widely discussed patterns of job polarisation
inequality index of the Theil (or Generalised Entropy) and upgrading could contribute to inequality trends.
family is used: the Mean Log Deviation or Theil’s L index. The results of this dynamic breakdown are displayed in
The advantage of this alternative index is that its Figure 22. They show that, at least for the short period
evolution (change in L) by subgroups can be easily and the nine countries studied here, it is changes in
broken down into the following components: wage inequality within jobs/occupations that drive
£ change in L resulting from changes in within overall inequality, not changes in occupational wage
subgroup inequalities (a); differentials (component d) or in occupational
employment shares (components b and c). The
£ change in L resulting from changes in the subgroup particularly small contribution of occupational shares to
population shares – this can be further the overall developments of wage inequality should be
differentiated in effect of subgroup population noted. This is important because it suggests that the
share shifts through the within L component (b) and widely discussed phenomena of job polarisation and
the effect of subgroup population share shifts upgrading (or any other compositional change) had at
through the between L component (c); most a very marginal contribution to wage inequality
£ change in L resulting from changes in the subgroup developments in the countries and period covered. It is
means (d). wage inequality within occupations that changed most
The four components add to overall change in L: (increasing or decreasing, cyclically or consistently) over
ΔL = a + b + c + d (Mookherjee and Shorrocks, 1982). The the period, with a smaller but, in some countries,
benefits of this approach are that the effect of the significant role of occupational wage differentials (such
different components is quantified (rather than inferred as Romania or Spain and perhaps Finland), but hardly
from the observation of trends), and it allows the impact any role whatsoever for the effect of changing
of compositional change to be evaluated explicitly occupational shares.
(again, this effect was only implicit in the previous

Figure 22: Dynamic Theil breakdown of wage (not logged) inequality, contribution of occupational
differentials and shares

Germany Spain Finland


.03 .02
.06
.01
.02 .04 0
.01 .02 -.01
0 -.02
0
Dynamic Theil decomposition

France Italy Netherlands


.04 0 .06

.02 -.005 .04

0 -.01 .02

-.02 -.015 0

Poland Romania UK
.01 0 .02
0 -.005 0
-.01 -.01
-.02
-.02 -.015
-.03 -.02 -.04
2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015 2005 2010 2015

Within Share within Share between Between

Source: EU-SILC (authors’ analysis)

62
Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality in Europe

reclassifications are needed every few years: the


Conclusion changing nature of work is continuously eroding the fit
All the analysis in this report suffers from significant between the occupational codes and the jobs that
constraints related to the limitations of the data actually exist, introducing an element of variation in
available for EU-level comparative analysis on the wages and other attributes of jobs that is unrelated to
distribution of wages by occupations. Those constraints occupational dynamics in strict terms. Second, as
were particularly restrictive in this final section, and mentioned earlier, the period studied is short but
they limit considerably the scope of the conclusions particularly eventful. As discussed in previous EJM
that can be extracted. What can be said is that, for the reports (see, in particular, Eurofound, 2013; and for a
period and countries studied, occupational dynamics similar argument for the USA, see Jaimovich and Siu,
have played only a marginal role in the development of 2012), the intensity of structural change in European
wage inequality; within-occupation changes were a labour markets in the aftermath of the Great Recession
much more important driver of the observed trends in was striking. Not only the intensity of structural change
wage inequality between 2005 and 2014. This does not but also its nature (a generalisation of a negative job
mean that occupations became a less important polarisation pattern, with intense destruction of mid-
structuring factor for the wage distribution in the paid jobs in many countries) should make the effect of
countries analysed; in most cases, their structuring role occupational dynamics on wage inequality particularly
remained stable, even increasing in some cases as a strong in this period. And yet no significant impact was
result of a decline in within-occupation wage inequality. found. This would suggest that changes in occupational
Although the short period covered obviously limits the structures (phenomena such as job polarisation or
scope of these observations, they can still make a upgrading) are unlikely to have significant implications
relevant contribution to the debate, for two reasons. on their own for the evolution of wage inequality.
First, because the previously mentioned problems in the Changes in occupational wages, on the other hand, did
comparability of occupational classifications in the long play a small but significant role, which perhaps in longer
run may suggest looking at short-term periods instead. periods can become more important for inequality
It is important to emphasise that the time comparability trends. Unfortunately, studying these longer-term
problem is not only about the occupational trends from a comparative European perspective is
reclassifications themselves, but also about the reason currently hampered by the lack of suitable data.

63
8 Conclusions
Understanding the link between occupations and wage Second, the role played by occupations in the
inequality is necessary for understanding how the structuring of wage inequality has some strikingly
division of labour and technological change affect the consistent attributes in all European countries,
life chances of workers and provide an underlying irrespective of the overall levels of inequality or
structure for the distribution of economic resources in institutional frameworks. It seems that the occupational
society. In a context of increasing earnings inequality structure provides a unifying backbone to European
and accelerating technological change, this seems wage distributions, with occupational wages
particularly important. And yet existing research on this accounting for a very similar share of overall wage
issue is limited, sometimes contradictory and lacking an inequality in all countries and occupational hierarchies
international perspective. being very similar despite wide differences in wage
inequality levels. The backbone is the same, but it is
Part 2 of this report tries to contribute to a better
more or less stretched in the different countries
understanding of the role that occupations play in the
according to the overall level of wage inequality, itself
structuring of wage inequality from a European
associated with institutional differences in bargaining
comparative perspective, studying recent data for nine
and educational systems, among other factors. Some
European countries. Although this exercise has been
further significant differences were found in other
constrained by methodological problems imposed by
aspects of the occupational wage distribution, such as
the lack of suitable data, it produced some interesting
the distorting role played by very large outliers in the UK
results, whose significance is amplified by the wider
distribution and the aggregation of occupational wage
scope of the analysis compared with previous studies.
differentials in bigger occupational classes (much
Those results can be synthesised in three main
smaller in Germany and Sweden than in the UK, for
conclusions.
instance).
First, occupations play an important role in the
Finally, despite the important role played by
structuring of wage inequality in all the European
occupations in structuring wage inequality and the
countries studied, an importance that can be quantified
significant changes in the occupational structure that
as 40%–50% of the total variance in wages being
took place in Europe in the aftermath of the Great
directly the result of occupational differences. These
Recession, occupational dynamics did not drive
differences are themselves partly explained by
developments in wage inequality in the last decade in
systematic differences in the stock of human capital of
the nine European countries studied. Most of the
workers in the different occupations, but only partly.
changes in wage inequality between 2005 and 2014
Although, at present, it is impossible to test it directly
were the result of changes in the distribution of wages
with EU-level data, an even more significant part of
within occupations, with changes between occupations
occupational wage differentials seems to be associated
playing a much less important role and changes in the
with occupation-specific mechanisms of wage
occupational structure (job polarisation) playing a very
differentiation, such as occupational closure. On the
marginal one. Although the period studied is short, it
other hand and particularly in some countries, such as
was particularly intense in terms of occupational
the UK, occupational wage differentials seem to be
restructuring, so it seems unlikely that compositional
strongly structured by broader mechanisms of social
changes such as job polarisation or upgrading could be
class differentiation, not limited to human capital either
a significant driver of wage inequality in the long term.
but to other factors such as the nature of employment
relations or power in labour markets. In some countries
(such as the Netherlands), occupational wage
differentials are also linked to mechanisms of
occupational segregation by gender, age or other
sociodemographic factors.

65
Bibliography
All Eurofound publications are available at www.eurofound.europa.eu

Acemoglu, D. and Autor, D. H. (2011), ‘Skills, tasks and Bol, T. and Weeden, K. A. (2014), ‘Occupational closure
technologies: Implications for employment and and wage inequality in Germany and the United
earnings’, in Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. E. (eds.), Kingdom’, European Sociological Review, Vol. 31, No. 3,
Handbook of labor economics, Volume 4B, Elsevier, pp. 354–369.
Amsterdam, pp. 1043–1171.
CEA (Council of Economic Advisers with the U.S.
Arranz, J. M. and García-Serrano, C. (2011), ‘Are the Department of Labor) (1996), Job creation and
MCVL tax data useful? Ideas for mining’, Hacienda employment opportunities: The United States labor
Pública Española, Vol. 199, No. 4, pp. 151–186. market, 1993–1996, Office of the Chief Economist,
Washington, DC.
Arranz, J. M. and García-Serrano, C. (2014), ‘How green
was my valley: Earnings differentials and the changing Dustmann, C., Ludsteck, J. and Schönberg, U. (2009),
distribution of wages in Spain, 2005-2010’, International ‘Revisiting the German wage structure’, Quarterly
Journal of Manpower, Vol. 35, No. 7, pp. 1059–1087. Journal of Economics, Vol. 124, No. 2, pp. 843–881.
Atkinson, A. B., Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2011), ‘Top Dwyer, R. E. (2013), ‘The care economy? Gender,
incomes in the long run of history’, Journal of Economic economic restructuring, and job polarization in the US
Literature, Vol. 49, No. 1, pp. 3–71. labor market’, American Sociological Review, Vol. 78,
No. 3, pp. 390–416.
Autor, D. H. (2013), The ‘task approach’ to labor markets:
An overview, NBER Working Paper No. 18711, National Elias, P. (1997), ‘Social class and the standard
Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. occupational classification’, in Rose, D. and O’Reilly, K.
(eds.), Constructing classes: Towards a new social
Autor, D. H. (2015), ‘Why are there still so many jobs?
classification for the UK, Economic and Social Research
The history and future of workplace automation’,
Council, Swindon, UK.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 29, No. 3,
pp. 3–30. Erikson, R. and Goldthorpe, J. H. (1992), The constant
flux: A study of class mobility in industrial societies,
Autor, D. H., Levy, F. and Murnane, R. J. (2003), ‘The skill
Oxford University Press, USA.
content of recent technological change: An empirical
exploration’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118, Esping-Andersen, G. (1990), The three worlds of welfare
No. 4, pp. 1279–1333. capitalism, Polity Press, Cambridge.
Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F. and Kearney, M. S. (2006), ‘The Eurofound (2008a), ERM report 2008 – More and better
polarization of the U.S. labor market’, American jobs: Patterns of employment expansion in Europe,
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 96, No. 2, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.
pp. 189–194.
Eurofound (2008b), Recent changes in the jobs structure
Autor, D. H., Dorn, D. and Hanson, G. H. (2016), ‘The of the EU: Technical report, Dublin.
China shock: Learning from labor-market adjustment to
Eurofound (2011), Shifts in the job structure in Europe
large changes in trade’, Annual Review of Economics,
during the Great Recession, Publications Office of the
Vol. 8, pp. 205–240.
European Union, Luxembourg.
Badescu, M., D’Hombres, B. and Villalba, E. (2011),
Eurofound (2013), Employment polarisation and job
Returns to education in European countries – evidence
quality in the crisis: European Jobs Monitor 2013,
from the European Community Statistics on Income and
Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.
Living Conditions (EU-SILC), Publications Office of the
European Union, Luxembourg. Eurofound (2014), Drivers of recent job polarisation and
upgrading in Europe: European Jobs Monitor 2014,
Baumol, W. J. (1967), ‘Macroeconomics of unbalanced
Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.
growth: The anatomy of urban crisis’, American
Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 415–426. Eurofound (2015a), Recent developments in the
distribution of wages in Europe, Publications Office of
Becker, G. S. (1993), ‘Human capital revisited’, in Human
the European Union, Luxembourg.
capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis with special
reference to education, 3rd edition, University of
Chicago Press, Chicago and London, pp. 15–28.

67
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Eurofound (2015b), Upgrading or polarisation? Long- Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (eds.) (2001), Varieties of
term and global shifts in the employment structure: capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative
European Jobs Monitor 2015, Publications Office of the advantage, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
European Union, Luxembourg.
Jaimovich, N. and Siu, H. E. (2012), The trend is the cycle:
Eurofound (2016a), What do Europeans do at work? Job polarization and jobless recoveries, NBER Working
A task-based analysis: European Jobs Monitor 2016, Paper No. 18334, National Bureau of Economic
Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg. Research, Cambridge, MA.
Eurofound (2016b), ERM annual report 2015: Job creation Kampelmann, S. and Rycx, F. (2013), ‘Does institutional
in SMEs, Publications Office of the European Union, diversity account for pay rules in Germany and
Luxembourg. Belgium?’, Socio-Economic Review, Vol. 11, No. 1,
pp. 131–157.
Eurofound (2017), ERM annual report 2016: Globalisation
slowdown? Recent evidence of offshoring and reshoring Kaplanis, I. (2007), The geography of employment
in Europe, Publications Office of the European Union, polarisation in Britain, Department of Geography and
Luxembourg. Environment, London School of Economics, London.
European Commission (2009), Industrial relations in Kim, C. and Sakamoto, A. (2008), ‘The rise of intra-
Europe 2008, Publications Office of the European Union, occupational wage inequality in the United States, 1983
Luxembourg. to 2002’, American Sociological Review, Vol. 73, No. 1,
pp. 129–157.
European Commission (2016), Labour market and wage
developments in Europe, Publications Office of the Kleiner, M. M. (2015), Reforming occupational licensing
European Union, Luxembourg. policies, The Hamilton Project, Washington, DC.
Eurostat (2015), People in the EU, statistics on Mankiw, G. (2012), Principles of economics, 6th edition,
geographic mobility, web page, accessed 31 January South-Western Cengage Learning, Mason, Ohio.
2017.
Mazzolari, F. and Ragusa, G. (2013), ‘Spillovers from
Eurostat (2016), Europe 2020 indicators – education, high-skill consumption to low-skill labor markets’,
web page, accessed 31 January 2017. Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 95, No. 1,
pp. 74–86.
Fernández-Macías, E. (2012a), ‘Job polarization in
Europe? Changes in the employment structure and job Mincer, J. A. (1974), Schooling, experience, and earnings,
quality’, Work and Occupations, Vol. 39, No. 2, NBER Books, Cambridge, MA.
pp. 157–182.
Mishel, L., Shierholz, H. and Schmitt, J. (2013), Don’t
Fernández-Macías, E. (2012b), ‘Patterns of employment blame the robots: Assessing the job polarization
expansion in Europe, 1995–2007’, in Fernández-Macías, explanation of increasing wage inequality, Economic
E., Hurley, J. and Storrie, D. (eds.), Transformation of the Policy Institute working paper, EPI, Washington, DC.
employment structure in the EU and USA, 1995–2007,
Mookherjee, D. and Shorrocks, A. (1982), ‘A
Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 26–51.
decomposition analysis of the trend in UK income
Fernández-Macías, E. and Hurley, J. (2016), ‘Routine- inequality’, Economic Journal, Vol. 92, No. 368,
biased technical change and job polarization in Europe’, pp. 886–902.
Socio-Economic Review, doi: 10.1093/ser/mww016.
Mouw, T. and Kalleberg, A. L. (2010), ‘Occupations and
Goos, M. and Manning, A. (2007), ‘Lousy and lovely jobs: the structure of wage inequality in the United States,
The rising polarization of work in Britain’, Review of 1980s to 2000s’, American Sociological Review, Vol. 75,
Economics and Statistics, Vol. 89, No. 1, pp. 118–133. No. 3, pp. 402–431.
Goos, M., Manning, A. and Salomons, A. (2009), ‘Job Muñoz de Bustillo, R., Fernández-Macías, E., Antón, J. I.
polarization in Europe’, AEA Papers and Proceedings, and Esteve, F. (2011), Measuring more than money: The
Vol. 99, No. 2, pp. 58–63. social economics of job quality, Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham.
Grimshaw, D. and Rubery, J. (1997), The concentration of
women’s employment and relative occupational pay: Nellas, V. and Olivieri, E. (2012), The change of job
A statistical framework for comparative analysis, OECD opportunities: The role of computerization and
Publishing, Paris. institutions, Quaderni DSE Working Paper No. 804,
Department of Science and Economics, Bologna, Italy.
Grusky, D. B. and Galescu, G. (2005), ‘Foundations of a
neo-Durkheimian class analysis’, in Wright, E. O. (ed.), Nordhaus, W. D. (2006), Baumol’s diseases:
Approaches to class analysis, Cambridge University A macroeconomic perspective, NBER Working Paper
Press, Cambridge, pp. 51–81. No. 12218, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA.

68
Bibliography

OECD (1994), The OECD jobs study, OECD Publishing, Salvatori, A. (2015), The anatomy of job polarisation in
Paris. the UK, IZA Discussion Paper No. 9193, Institute for the
Study of Labour, Bonn.
OECD (2011), Divided we stand: Why inequality keeps
rising, OECD Publishing, Paris. Smith, A. (1776), An inquiry into the nature and causes of
the wealth of nations, Skinner, A. S. and Campbell, R. H.
Oesch, D. (2006), Redrawing the class map: Stratification
(eds.), reprinted (1976) by Clarendon Press, Oxford.
and institutions in Britain, Germany, Sweden and
Switzerland, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, UK. Thelen, K. (2012), ‘Varieties of capitalism: Trajectories of
liberalization and the new politics of social solidarity’,
Oesch, D. (2013), Occupational change in Europe: How
Annual Review of Political Science, Vol. 15, pp. 137–159.
technology and education transform the job structure,
Oxford University Press, Oxford. Tomaskovic-Devey, D. (1993), Gender and racial
inequality at work: The sources and consequences of job
Oesch, D. (2015), ‘Welfare regimes and change in the
segregation, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.
employment structure: Britain, Denmark and Germany
since 1990’, Journal of European Social Policy, Vol. 25, Weeden, K. A. (2002), ‘Why do some occupations pay
No. 1, pp. 94–110. more than others? Social closure and earnings
inequality in the United States’, American Journal of
Oesch, D. and Rodriguez Menes, J. (2011), ‘Upgrading or
Sociology, Vol. 108, No. 1, pp. 55–101.
polarization? Occupational change in Britain, Germany,
Spain and Switzerland, 1990–2008’, Socio-Economic Weeden, K. A., Kim, Y. M., Di Carlo, M. and Grusky, D. B.
Review, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 503–531. (2007), ‘Social class and earnings inequality’, American
Behavioral Scientist, Vol. 50, No. 5, pp. 702–736.
Piketty, T. (2014), Capital in the twenty-first century,
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Williams, M. (2013), ‘Occupations and British wage
MA. inequality, 1970s–2000s’, European Sociological Review,
Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 841–857.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. (2009), This time is
different. Eight centuries of financial folly, Princeton Wren, A. (ed.) (2013), The political economy of the service
University, Princeton, NJ. transition, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Rueda, D. and Pontusson, J. (2000), ‘Wage inequality Wright, E. O. (1997), Class counts: Comparative studies in
and varieties of capitalism’, World Politics, Vol. 52, No. 3, class analysis, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
pp. 350–383.
Wright, E. O. and Dwyer, R. E. (2003), ‘The patterns of job
Saez, E. (2015), Striking it richer: The evolution of top expansions in the United States: A comparison of the
incomes in the United States, University of California, 1960s and 1990s’, Socio-Economic Review, Vol. 1,
Berkeley, CA. pp. 289–325.

69
Annexes
Annex 1: Shifts in employment composition
Table A1: Indicators of shifting composition of employment, 2008–2016

Employment rate Gender employment Older workers High-skilled white


Indicator Employment (20–64-year-olds) gap Part-time workers (55 years and older) collar workers
Change Change Change Change Change Change
Country 2008–2016 2016 2008–2016 2016 2008–2016 2016 2008–2016 2016 2008–2016 2016 2011–2016
% % % % % % % % % % %
Austria 5.1 74.9 0.6 6.1 -2.8 28.8 5.1 14.6 4.0 40.7 3.2
Belgium 3.2 67.3 -0.5 8.3 -2.5 25.1 2.5 15.3 5.1 44.8 1.3
Bulgaria -10.0 68.0 -2.5 6.0 -0.4 2.3 -0.1 19.8 4.6 31.8 1.2
Croatia -8.8 62.1 -3.2 7.4 -4.9 7.0 -1.1 16.1 2.2 35.5 5.7
Cyprus -3.5 69.8 -7.3 3.3 -7.5 14.1 6.3 15.9 0.6 35.0 1.5
Czech Republic 2.5 76.5 4.0 11.9 -2.2 6.7 1.8 17.9 2.6 37.6 0.8
Denmark -0.2 77.7 -2.2 5.5 -1.2 28.4 4.0 20.1 3.5 45.0 1.8
Estonia 0.3 77.7 0.6 1.0 -1.4 11.0 4.5 23.0 4.9 46.0 3.0
Finland -3.8 73.9 -2.7 4.0 -0.3 16.1 3.2 21.0 3.0 45.3 2.5
France 0.4 70.2 -0.5 3.5 -2.1 18.9 1.9 16.6 5.0 45.5 1.5
Germany 7.5 78.5 4.8 6.5 -2.8 28.1 1.9 22.1 6.8 44.4 1.5
Greece -20.2 56.6 -10.1 15.7 -5.1 9.8 4.3 14.8 1.1 30.2 0.7
Hungary 13.0 71.4 10.0 8.6 -0.6 5.3 0.7 16.4 5.3 34.2 -1.5
Ireland -6.2 70.0 -2.9 8.3 -4.3 22.9 4.4 17.6 4.4 40.6 0.8
Italy -1.4 62.1 -1.2 16.2 -3.5 18.7 4.0 19.3 6.9 35.9 0.5
Latvia -16.3 73.5 -2.9 -1.9 -2.7 8.7 2.1 21.7 3.5 39.6 0.8
Lithuania -4.5 75.4 3.0 -2.4 -4.4 8.5 2.0 21.7 6.8 42.2 -0.4
Luxembourg 24.3 70.4 0.9 10.5 -3.8 19.5 3.1 10.5 1.0 57.4 2.2
Malta 21.2 69.5 10.0 22.4 -9.6 15.0 3.5 15.0 3.9 40.2 1.6
Netherlands -2.0 77.0 -1.9 7.6 -1.6 50.6 3.4 19.0 4.8 46.8 0.2
Poland 3.1 69.1 4.4 9.9 -0.5 6.9 -1.4 16.7 6.1 37.6 3.7
Portugal -10.6 70.5 -3.0 2.7 -3.6 11.9 -0.4 20.5 1.6 35.7 6.4
Romania -10.2 66.6 1.3 13.8 3.7 8.8 -1.3 17.2 0.9 22.8 0.6
Slovenia -7.1 70.6 -2.3 7.3 -1.7 9.8 0.8 13.7 2.9 42.1 -1.3
Slovakia 3.6 69.9 1.6 11.0 -0.9 6.1 3.8 15.2 5.4 31.2 -0.2
Spain -11.4 63.7 -5.5 9.0 -6.8 15.3 3.5 16.0 4.4 33.2 1.1
Sweden 6.7 81.5 0.7 4.2 -1.2 25.8 -1.2 21.1 0.2 51.7 5.5
UK 6.9 77.6 2.2 6.6 -1.1 26.8 1.6 19.0 2.3 48.8 2.0
EU 0.3 71.1 0.6 8.1 -2.5 20.5 2.3 18.6 4.6 41.0 1.8

Note: High-skilled white collar workers are those in ISCO main groups 1–3 (managers, professionals and associate professionals). Values are
colour coded by column; highest values are green, middle values are yellow and lowest values are red.
Source: EU-LFS (authors’ calculations)

71
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Annex 2: Handling of data breaks


Table A2 describes how major classification breaks were
handled in the analysis.

Country Nature of break Year and quarter Impact Solution


France ISCO occupational 2013 Q1 Some reassignment of Aggregate ISCO two-digit to one-
classification break employment across ISCO digit for ISCO two-digit categories
categories – mainly obvious at 10–54 for all quarters covered.
two-digit level.
Germany ISCO occupational 2012 Q1 Significant reassignment of Use 2012 Q2 to 2016 Q2 data for
classification break employment across ISCO all German charts, omitting the
categories, at one- and two-digit first year.
levels of detail.
Netherlands ISCO occupational 2013 Q1 Some reassignment of Use 2013 Q2 to 2016 Q2 data for
and Slovakia classification break employment across ISCO all Dutch and Slovakian charts,
categories – mainly obvious at omitting the first two years.
two-digit level.

Eurostat identified breaks for other Member States in and Slovakia to 2011 Q2 using the aggregate
different quarters for the core variables (ISCO and employment shift observed, thus preserving the
NACE) as well as for employment estimates. However, structure of employment observed in 2012 in Germany
adjustments were made only in the above cases as they and 2013 in the Netherlands and Slovakia. The
involved obviously artificial and large shifts in assumption, therefore, is that the composition of
employment share by occupation. Luxembourg was employment by jobs did not change in Germany in
dropped in the analysis due to very significant variation 2011–2012 or in the Netherlands and Slovakia in 2011–
in employment share estimates from year to year, so all 2013; only the levels of employment changed. For the
EU aggregates are for the EU27 rather than the EU28. EU27 aggregates in the breakdown charts (for example,
gender, full-time or part-time), the missing data for
For the EU27 aggregate figures for 2011 Q2, the missing Germany, the Netherlands and Slovakia are generated
data for Germany, the Netherlands and Slovakia are using a similar backcasting, but also taking into account
accounted for by backcasting from 2012 Q2 in the case observed changes in employment for the categories of
of Germany and 2013 Q2 in the case of the Netherlands the breakdown variable(s).

72
Annexes

Annex 3: Comparing employment shifts using different job quality measures


Most of the analysis in this and previous EJM annual During 2011–2013, as Figure A1 highlights, the job-wage
reports has concentrated on the job-wage as the ranking tended to generate more polarised patterns of
primary ranking criterion. Wages are clearly an employment change (greater relative growth at the
important dimension of quality of work and have the edges, less in the middle) than the other two ranking
additional advantages of being reasonably well criteria. Net employment destruction was concentrated
measured and highly correlated with other relevant in mid-paid and mid-low-paid jobs. Employment shifts
dimensions of job quality. The use of mean or median in terms of the education and job quality rankings were,
job (or occupation) wage as the basic ranking criterion however, clearly upgrading with greatest net
has also been the common approach of much of the employment destruction progressively from the bottom
employment polarisation literature (see Goos and quintile upwards.
Manning, 2007).
At the same time, there are some obvious points of
But there are other proxies of job quality and Figures A1 similarity between the three charts reflecting the high
and A2 make use of two different measures to rank correlation (r > 0.7) between the different measures of
‘jobs’ (as always using the jobs-based method, these are job quality used to rank jobs. The top quintile is growing
defined as specific occupations in specific sectors that fastest regardless of the ranking criterion, and
are then assigned to five quintiles of employment). The employment growth is relatively weaker in the lower
first is the average educational level of the job-holder in quintiles.
a job. The second is based on dimensions of job quality
The reason for the (modest) differences between the
more broadly considered – including contractual
three measures is that a substantial proportion of jobs
stability, work autonomy, working time flexibility,
in the middle of the wage distribution have a relative
development opportunities and risk exposure – and
wage premium (a higher relative position in terms of
relies on answers to 38 questions in Eurofound’s fifth
wages than education or non-pecuniary job quality
EWCS. This is called a ‘non-pecuniary job quality’
attributes), and these jobs were responsible for a large
ranking as it deliberately omits wage income data in
share of overall job destruction during and after the
order to avoid overlapping with the existing, principal
global financial crisis. Two illustrative examples can be
job-wage ranking. Data are shown for two periods:
seen in the list of large-employing jobs with the fastest
Figure A1 for the late crisis period of contracting
rates of employment decline (see Table 2). The first is
employment (2011 Q2 to 2013 Q2) and Figure A2 for the
that of building and related trades workers in the
recovery (2013 Q2 to 2016 Q2).
construction of buildings sector, which is in the third

Figure A1: Employment change (% per annum), by wage, education and job quality quintile, EU,* 2011 Q2–
2013 Q2

Wage Education Job quality


2 2 2

0 0 0

-2 -2 -2

* EU27 (excluding Luxembourg)


Notes: Q2 data in each year. Data adjusted for breaks in France, Germany, the Netherlands and Slovakia as indicated in Annex 2. Due to data
limitations, job quality rankings could be generated only for jobs accounting for around 90% of EU employment.
Source: EU-LFS, SES, fifth EWCS (authors’ calculations)

73
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure A2: Employment change (% per annum), by wage, education and job quality quintile, EU,* 2013 Q2–
2016 Q2

Wage Education Job quality


4 4 4

2 2 2

0 0 0

* EU27 (excluding Luxembourg)


Notes: Q2 data in each year. Data adjusted for breaks in France, Germany, the Netherlands and Slovakia as indicated in Annex 2. Due to data
limitations, job quality rankings could be generated only for jobs accounting for around 90% of EU employment.
Source: EU-LFS, SES, fifth EWCS (authors’ calculations)

quintile as measured by wages but in the bottom employment growth has been much more broadly
quintile as measured by educational attainment or spread across the distribution for each measure, and
broader job quality. The second is that of metal and this has tended to mute some of the patterns previously
machinery trade workers in the manufacture of observed. What were clearly polarising shifts by job-
fabricated metal products, which is in the third, middle wage ranking are only very mildly polarised after 2013.
wage quintile but in the second education quintile and The pattern has been one of upgrading in terms of job-
in the bottom quintile as measured by broader job education ranking, but again less sharply than before
quality. It was precisely such, primarily male, jobs in the and with relatively fast growth in jobs in the second
construction and manufacturing sectors that accounted quintile. Finally, in terms of broader job quality, the
for most of the net job destruction in 2011–2013 (and, pattern observed post-2013 is quite distinctive from
previously, from the onset of the crisis in 2008). that of the earlier period, with strong employment
growth in the bottom quintile – the reverse of what had
The above suggests that the different characterisations
occurred previously.
of employment shift, based on the three proxies of job
quality, arise in large part for sector-specific and In part, there has been some employment rebound in
business cycle reasons over quite a short time period the types of jobs that contracted during the extended
(2008–2013). However, similar findings have also been crisis period, for example the largely male jobs of drivers
identified in developed economies over longer time and mobile plant operators in warehousing were among
frames. Based on a jobs-based analysis of the pre-crisis the fastest-growing jobs (see Table 2). More generally,
period (1990–2008) in five European countries, Oesch these types of jobs have not continued to incur the
(2013) noted that ‘the employment drop in the lower- declines that took place during the crisis. In addition,
middle and middle quintiles concerns comparatively many of the fastest-growing large-employing jobs have
well-paid working-class jobs’. In similar fashion, the jobs been in lower-level services. Jobs such as cleaners and
that were disproportionately affected by employment helpers in services to buildings, and personal services
loss during and after the crisis were male, blue collar, workers and food preparation assistants in food and
primarily mid-paying jobs that do not require high levels beverages have contributed much to employment
of formal education. growth during the recovery, but are ranked in the
bottom quintile by most of the ranking measures.
During the recovery period (2013–2016), each quintile
has recorded employment growth according to all three Nonetheless, the one persistent and probably structural
of the rankings (Figure A2). As previously, the greatest trend has been for ‘good’ jobs to grow faster than
growth occurred in the top quintile in each (between 2% poorer-quality jobs – regardless of the measure used to
and 2.5% per year). What has changed is that assess the quality of the jobs.

74
Annexes

Annex 4: Categorisation of the service sector

Table A3: Knowledge-based services aggregation: Breakdown by NACE Rev. 2 two-digit sector code
Private knowledge-intensive 50 to 51 Water transport, Air transport
services
58 Publishing activities
59 to 63 Motion picture, video and television programme production, sound recording and music
publishing activities, Programming and broadcasting activities, Telecommunications, Computer
programming, consultancy and related activities, Information service activities
64 to 66 Financial and insurance activities (section K)
69 to 71 Legal and accounting activities, Activities of head offices; management consultancy activities,
Architectural and engineering activities; technical testing and analysis
72 Scientific research and development
73 to 74 Advertising and market research, Other professional, scientific and technical activities
75 Veterinary activities
78 Employment activities
80 Security and investigation activities
90 to 93 Arts, entertainment and recreation (section R)
Public knowledge-intensive 84 Public administration and defence, compulsory social security (section O)
services
85 Education (section P)
86 to 88 Human health and social work activities (section Q)
Less-knowledge-intensive 45 to 47 Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles (section G)
services
49 Land transport and transport via pipelines
52 Warehousing and support activities for transportation
53 Postal and courier activities
55 to 56 Accommodation and food service activities (Section I)
68 Real estate activities
77 Rental and leasing activities
79 Travel agency, tour operator reservation service and related activities
81 Services to buildings and landscape activities
82 Office administrative, office support and other business support activities
95 Repair of computers and personal and household goods
94 Activities of membership organisations
96 Other personal service activities
97 to 99 Activities of households as employers of domestic personnel; Undifferentiated goods and
services-producing activities of private households for own use (section T), Activities of extraterritorial
organisations and bodies (section U)

Source: Eurostat; Eurostat indicators on high-tech industry and knowledge-intensive services, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/cache/metadata/Annexes/htec_esms_an3.pdf

75
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Annex 5: Member State shares of employment in top 12 jobs

Table A4: Top 12 employing jobs at EU level by % of employment, 2016 Q2


Occupation Sector EU AT BE BG CY CZ DE DK EE ES FI FR EL HR HU

Sales workers Retail trade 5.4 5.6 4.3 8.7 7.4 5.3 4.8 5.8 4.5 7.3 4.8 4.0 9.7 6.5 5.7

Teaching professionals Education 4.4 4.5 5.6 3.7 6.1 4.2 3.2 5.4 4.9 5.2 4.3 4.3 6.7 5.1 4.3

Agricultural workers Crop and animal 2.8 3.8 0.5 3.5 1.9 0.8 0.7 1.3 1.0 1.6 2.7 2.3 11.2 4.9 2.2
production, etc.
Health professionals Human health 2.2 1.3 3.4 2.2 2.5 2.1 2.0 3.3 1.4 2.8 1.3 1.8 2.3 1.4 0.7
activities
Personal service workers Food and beverage 2.0 2.3 1.4 2.9 2.8 1.9 1.3 1.6 1.2 5.1 1.5 1.3 5.2 3.6 2.0
services
Drivers/mobile plant Land transport etc 1.8 1.3 1.6 3.3 1.2 2.5 0.7 1.5 3.1 2.3 2.6 2.0 2.0 1.8 2.4
operators
Building workers Specialised 1.8 2.3 2.3 0.6 1.5 2.7 1.8 2.3 1.1 1.5 1.5 2.2 1.6 1.4 1.6
construction
Health associate professionals Human health 1.7 2.5 1.3 0.2 0.2 1.2 3.6 0.6 1.5 0.6 3.5 2.1 1.4 2.5 1.8
activities
Business and administration Public administration 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.0 1.1 1.6 2.8 0.9 1.1 0.7 0.8 1.3 0.6 1.1 1.9
associate professionals
Building workers Construction of 1.0 0.7 1.0 2.0 1.8 0.8 0.5 0.2 2.7 1.2 1.8 0.2 0.8 1.1 1.3
buildings
Cleaners and helpers Services to buildings 1.0 0.9 1.7 0.2 1.0 0.4 1.1 0.9 0.4 2.0 1.2 0.9 0.5 0.6 0.4

Personal service workers Other personal service 0.9 1.2 0.9 0.7 1.9 0.9 0.9 0.4 0.8 1.2 0.7 0.8 0.8 1.3 1.1
activities
Total share of employment in top 12 employing jobs 26.4 27.7 25.2 29.2 29.5 24.5 23.2 24.2 23.8 31.7 26.7 23.1 42.8 31.3 25.5

Occupation Sector IE IT LT LU LV MT NL PL PT RO SE SI SK UK

Sales workers Retail trade 5.6 6.2 5.6 1.7 5.7 6.8 4.8 7.0 5.5 6.0 3.8 5.7 6.2 4.6

Teaching professionals Education 4.4 5.0 5.4 6.1 5.0 4.9 4.1 4.5 4.9 3.1 6.6 6.2 4.1 4.5

Agricultural workers Crop and animal 4.3 2.0 4.9 0.6 2.2 0.8 1.2 8.5 1.8 19.2 0.9 2.9 0.6 0.4
production, etc.
Health professionals Human health 3.3 1.3 2.8 2.2 1.2 2.2 2.4 2.4 2.3 1.6 3.4 2.1 0.8 3.3
activities
Personal service workers Food and beverage 1.7 3.0 1.1 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.8 0.9 2.1 1.6 1.0 2.4 2.2 1.2
services
Drivers/mobile plant Land transport etc 2.1 1.6 2.9 1.4 3.2 0.9 1.3 3.0 1.6 3.2 2.1 1.8 3.0 1.6
operators
Building workers Specialised 1.9 2.1 1.2 1.3 0.4 1.6 1.2 2.0 0.9 0.7 1.8 1.5 2.0 1.8
construction
Health associate professionals Human health 0.5 2.3 0.6 0.7 0.7 1.1 1.5 0.5 0.5 1.0 0.6 1.6 2.2 0.6
activities
Business and administration Public administration 1.5 0.5 1.0 2.5 1.5 1.2 1.0 1.6 1.0 0.5 1.2 0.7 1.6 1.1
associate professionals
Building workers Construction of 0.8 1.4 1.9 0.8 2.5 1.1 0.8 1.5 2.0 3.3 1.0 0.3 1.8 0.9
buildings
Cleaners and helpers Services to buildings 0.9 1.4 0.8 1.1 0.2 0.8 0.9 0.6 0.6 0.3 0.8 0.7 0.2 0.9

Personal service workers Other personal service 1.3 1.2 0.9 0.9 1.2 1.0 0.9 0.7 1.2 0.6 0.5 0.7 0.7 0.9
activities
Total share of employment in top 12 employing jobs 28.2 27.8 29.1 20.9 25.3 23.7 21.7 33.1 24.5 41.0 23.7 26.7 25.3 21.8

76
Annexes

Annex 6: Occupations and the evolution of wage inequality over three


decades
This annex includes a tentative analysis of changes in using EU-SILC. Both datasets show an increasing role of
wage inequality across occupations and countries over occupational wage differentials in structuring wage
the last three decades using the Luxembourg Income inequality in Finland, Germany (only when wages are
Study (LIS) database.18 This database is the largest logged) and Spain in the most recent period and a
available database of harmonised income microdata decline in the share of wage variance explained by
collected by multiple countries over a period of occupations in Denmark and France. In the Netherlands,
decades. It provides household and person-level data the trends seem to be inconsistent, with a high degree
on market and government income, demography, of volatility. But the most interesting aspect of Figures
employment and expenditures from countries in A3 and A4 is that they also show the previous trends.
Europe, North America, Latin America, Africa, Asia and The increase in the role played by occupations in
Australia since 1965. Although the measures of wages structuring wage inequality observed in Germany and
and occupation in the LIS are problematic for the Spain seems to extend to previous decades, too; the
purposes of this analysis, even more so than EU-SILC, same happens with France in the opposite direction,
they can be used for an approximation of longer-term with a clear long-term decrease. The only case in which
trends using the same methods presented in Part 2.19 the long-term trend seems at odds with the most recent
The variance decomposition approach previously used period is Finland, where the long-term trend is one of
for the EU-SILC and SES datasets is reproduced here to decline, contrasting with the most recent period. The
evaluate whether the structuring role played by results for Denmark and the Netherlands seem
occupations in the distribution of wages changed in six problematic, for different reasons. In the case of the
European countries across the last two or three Netherlands, the high volatility suggests data problems,
decades, according to the LIS database. The results are making it impossible to identify any clear trend. In the
shown in Figures A3 and A4 for raw and logged wages case of Denmark, there is surprising inconsistency
for Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, the between the lines for occupation only and the lines for
Netherlands and Spain from 1984 to 2013. As might be the combination of occupation and sector (Job).
expected because of the higher level of aggregation of Whereas occupation only accounts for a growing share
the occupation and sector variables used (one-digit of wage inequality over the period, the combination of
level), the share of wage variance explained by occupation and sector shows a clear decline over time.
occupations and sectors is around 10% lower in the LIS This, which happens only in Denmark, implies that the
than in EU-SILC for the common period of analysis effect of sector on wage inequality shrank very
(2005–2013), between 30%–40% of the total. significantly over the period. Although it is theoretically
possible, this effect seems implausibly large and may
The patterns for the last decade according to LIS are
reflect problems in the classification of sector.
reasonably consistent with those previously discussed

18 Further information about the LIS database is available at http://www.lisdatacenter.org/

19 For the measure of wages, the LIS variable PILE (personal paid employment income) is used, which cannot be adjusted by hours of work because it has
many missing values and countries. ISCO and NACE are both measured at the one-digit level. In some countries and years, there is a higher level of detail,
but it is impossible to provide consistent trend analysis beyond one digit.

77
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Figure A3: Share of variance explained by job and occupation, wages not logged, six Member States
Germany Denmark Spain
.4

.3

.2

.1

Finland France Netherlands


.4

.3

.2

.1

0
1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

Occupation Job
Source: LIS database (authors’ analysis)

Figure A4: Share of variance explained by job and occupation, wages logged, six Member States
Germany Denmark Spain

.4

.3

.2

.1

Finland France Netherlands

.4

.3

.2

.1

0
1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

Occupation Job
Source: LIS database (authors’ analysis)

78
Annexes

Figure A5: Theil decomposition of paid employment income by occupation, six Member States
Germany Denmark Spain
.3 .5

.4
.2
.3

.2
.1
.1

0 0

Finland France Netherlands


.3 .5

.4
.2
.3

.2
.1
.1

0 0
1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

Within Between Explained


Note: The ‘Explained’ indicator is plotted on the right-hand axis.
Source: LIS database (authors’ analysis)

Figure A5 illustrates a Theil index decomposition inequality actually declines until 2010, whereas
approach. As with earlier in the report, the Theil index between-job inequality remains stable or even
(itself an indicator of wage inequality) is broken down increases slightly. In Germany, although within-job and
into a within and a between component, also displaying between-job inequality develop similarly, the latter
the share that the between component represents in grows faster than the former. Consequently, in both
the total Theil (‘explained’). This ‘explained Theil’ cases, according to this approximation using LIS data,
indicator is comparable to the trends in the variance occupational wages contributed positively to growing
explained shown in Figures A3 and A4. As already wage inequalities. In France, the exact opposite is
discussed in the report, Figure A5 shows that the observed after 1989, with declining between-job
between-jobs component of wage inequality is much inequality and expanding within-job inequality (in the
more stable than inequality within jobs. If between-jobs 1980s, occupational wage differentials also grew in
differentials were driving wage inequality France, according to this approach). In the three
developments, the between-component should be remaining countries, there are large shifts, suggesting
growing while the within-component should remain data problems again, but overall the between-job
stable or decline. There are two cases where this component is more stable or runs in parallel to within-
happens more or less consistently over the period: job inequalities, indicating that it did not play a
Germany and Spain. In Spain, within-job wage significant role in overall developments.

79
Occupational change and wage inequality: European Jobs Monitor 2017

Annex 7: Detailed examination of occupations and wage inequality


in Spain
The analysis that follows endeavours to contrast the Column 5; by occupation and sector (not combined), in
findings of this report with those obtained using a Column 6; and by jobs (the combination of occupation
national-level register dataset from Spain, the and sector), in Column 7.
Continuous Sample of Working Life (Muestra Continua
Table A5 shows that, as already discussed in the report,
de Vidas Laborales, MCVL). The MCVL is an
occupation is a very important factor structuring wage
administrative dataset built upon the computerised
inequality, more so than sector, accounting for 20%–
records of the Spanish Social Security, the Continuous
30% of total wage inequality in the years shown.
Municipal Register and the tax data of the National
Second, although occupation is more important,
Revenue Agency. Since 2004, this database has provided
crossing it with sector (generating the base
annual information on more than one million people
classification of ‘jobs’) contributes significantly to the
who have had some kind of work relationship with the
explanatory power of the classification. Between-jobs
Social Security, regardless of the duration or the nature
wage differentials account for 40%–45% of the total
of the relationship (for further details about this
variance in log daily wages, increasing until 2011 and
dataset, see Arranz and García-Serrano, 2011 and 2014).
decreasing afterwards. The percentage of variance
Table A5 presents a variance decomposition approach explained by jobs in wage inequality is 44% in 2010, very
(of log daily wages in real terms, with base 2011) for similar to the value of 40% estimated earlier using SES
Spain to explain wage inequality by differences between data for Spain. The small differences could be due to the
and within jobs during the last decade. This table is measure used in the databases for wages: daily wages in
similar to Table 3 in Chapter 5 (constructed using the the MCVL and wage per hour in the SES.
SES 2010 dataset). Column 1 contains the year, Column
There is a very significant drop in the share of variance
2 contains the number of observations (individuals)
explained by jobs between 2011 and 2012, which is very
available each year in this dataset, and Column 3
probably a statistical artefact, a result of a change in the
contains the number of jobs that corresponds to one-
classification of occupations. Discounting such obvious
digit occupation level 20 combined with one-digit sector
discontinuity, the general trend is one of remarkable
level (16 categories of NACE). The number of these jobs
stability, especially if one considers how complex this
varies between 193 and 206 over the period 2005–2014.
period was in terms of labour market developments,
The percentage of variance of log daily wages explained
first with very fast employment creation until 2008, then
by occupation only is in Column 4; by sector, in
with a massive expansion of unemployment. These

Table A5: Impact of occupation on (logged) wage inequality

% of variance of log daily wages explained by: Human capital approach


9.Wages net of
6. Job 8.Variance explained education and tenure,
2. No.of 3. No. of 4. Occupation 5. NACE category + by a model with variance explained by
1. Year observations jobs only only NACE 7. Jobs education and tenure jobs
2005 571,687 204 27.2 21.4 39.0 40.7 14.6 29.5
2006 594,780 206 26.8 20.0 37.9 39.7 15.1 27.9
2007 615,374 202 26.8 19.7 37.6 39.4 12.9 29.3
2008 617,846 200 27.4 21.2 38.8 40.5 15.0 27.8
2009 589,555 200 29.1 25.9 41.8 43.5 17.2 29.0
2010 576,550 198 29.7 27.1 42.8 44.5 18.0 29.1
2011 567,423 195 29.6 26.5 42.1 43.8 18.0 28.4
2012 519,144 197 21.5 10.6 28.5 30.2 15.9 18.0
2013 508,605 193 21.3 10.9 28.5 30.2 16.3 17.6
2014 516,092 194 20.9 10.6 28.0 29.8 16.4 17.1

Source: MCVL, 2005–2014

20 The occupational classification of MCVL is similar but not identical to ISCO at one-digit level. There are 10 categories: 1. Engineers and graduates;
2. Technical engineers and other skilled workers; 3. Chief and departmental heads; 4. Other semi-skilled workers; 5. Skilled clerks; 6. Auxiliary workers;
7. Semi-skilled clerks; 8. Skilled labourers; 9. Semi-skilled labourers; 10. Unskilled labourers.

80
Annexes

results are roughly consistent (though with small (approximately two or three times lower). The variance
differences in magnitudes) to those detected with the decomposition analysis by job is repeated using a
EU-SILC and LIS databases for Spain. variable net of the effect of education and tenure 21 in
Column 9. Although the share of variance explained
In a further analysis, the human capital approach
decreases in all years, between-job differentials still
(a hypothesis reviewed previously with SES data) was
account for a significant share of the wage inequality
tested, and results are shown in Columns 8 and 9. First,
between wages net of differences in human capital
Column 8 shows the share of the variance of log wages
(28%–29% in 2005–2011 and 17%–18% in 2012–2014).
that can be explained by a model using education and
As discussed in Chapter 5, human capital differences
tenure as predictors. This approach accounts for a
explain part of the role played by occupations, but wage
significant amount of the total wage variance over the
differentials cannot be reduced to differences in human
period, although it is far below the results for jobs
capital.

21 The residuals from the predicted values of the model shown in Column 8 (as described in Chapter 5, Table 3 for the SES dataset).

81
EF1710EN
TJ-AN-17-001-EN-N
In 2016, somewhat later than in other developed
economies, the EU recovered all the net
employment losses sustained since the global
financial crisis. Employment growth since 2013 has
been only modestly skewed towards well-paid
jobs; growth has been robust in low-paid and
mid-paid jobs too. Newer jobs are increasingly
likely to be full time rather than part time. Part 1 of
this sixth annual European Jobs Monitor report
takes a detailed look at shifts in employment at
Member State and EU levels from 2011 Q2 to 2016
Q2. Part 2 examines the role that occupations play
in structuring European wage inequality. It finds
that occupations have their own effect on wage
inequality as well as mediating other factors such
as human capital and social class. It also finds that
occupational dynamics did not drive wage
inequality developments in the last decade, a
period of intense structural change in European
labour markets.

The European Foundation for the Improvement of


Living and Working Conditions (Eurofound) is a
tripartite European Union Agency, whose role is
to provide knowledge in the area of social,
employment and work-related policies.
Eurofound was established in 1975 by Council
Regulation (EEC) No. 1365/75, to contribute to the
planning and design of better living and working
conditions in Europe.

ISBN: 978-92-897-1580-5
doi:10.2806/332137

You might also like