You are on page 1of 16

Time-inconsistent Preferences

and Consumer Self-Control


STEPHEN J. HOCH
GEORGE F. LOEWENSTEIN”

Why do consumers sometimes act against thair own better judgment. engaging
in behavior thai is often regretted after the fact and that would have beBn
rejected with adequate Jorethought? More generally, how do consumers
attempt to maintain selI•controI in the (ace of time-inconsistent preferences? D
This article addresses con- sumer impatience by developing a decision-theoretic o
model based on reference poims. The model explains how and why consumers w
expeñence sudden increases in desire for a product. increases that can result in nl
the temporary overriding of long- term preferences. Tactics lhat consumers oa
use to control their own behavior are also discussed, Consumer seifmontrol de
iS framed as a struggle between two psy- chological lorces. desire and d
willpower. Finally, two general classes of self-controi strategies are descnbed fro
those that direL;tly reduce desire. and those that overcome desire through m
willpower. htt
ps
://
ac
ad
The same person will vary in his mood, e
being at one t ime impatient, and greedy model. Consumers decide whether to make a mi
for present enjo ymc nl; while at a not he r purchase, and which purchase to make, by weighing c.
his mind dwells on ltte futu re. and hc is the costs and benefits of alternatives. The terminology ou
used to describe these decisions—“trade-offs,” p.
willing to posipone all enjoyments that can
co
convc niently be made to wait. Sometimes “attributes,” “choices,” “decision rules”—reveals a m/
he is in a mood to care little for anything particular view of behd vjor. Consumers are seen as jcr
else: soiiieti mes he is like the chil d ren dispassionate in- formation processors. evaluating /ar
who pick the pt u ms o ut of their puddi ng ticl
to cat them at once, somei i mcs like ihose
alternatives in a boundedly rational fashion and
e/
who put them aside to be eaten last. effortlessly imple- menti rig decisions (Bett man 17
[Marshall 1 890, p. 100) 1979). I ndeed. m uch purchase behavior is probably /4/
Who among us has never been gu iJiy of well described by these utilitarian terms. But, as 49
being u nable to deny himself lhe momen- suggested in the earlier ob- ser nations of Marshall and 2/
tary enjoy mc ni of thut 1 uscious dcsscrt or Bfi h m-Bawerk, a more complete understanding of 17
the fragrant Havana thai the doctor or- 97
consumer hehavior m ust recognize that people are
dered us to La rgo? And that in spite of 24
influenced both by long-term rational concerns and by 3
kn owing pe rfcrtl y we l1 that it is going to
more short-ierm emotional factors. by
bring an aggravation of our ail ment which
su bseq ucn1 unbiased appraisal will rec- Holbrook, O’Shaugh nessy, and Bell ( 1990) write, gu
“Recent approaches to consumer research have tended es
ognize as being far more u n pleasant than
to regard corisu mer behavior as a mode of reasoned t
the renu nciatio n of that iri fling enjoy- on
ment. [Biihm-Bawerk ( 1898) 1959, p. 269] action or as a repository of emotional reactions . 09

I n marketing, the dominant paradigm used to de-


scribe consumer behavior is ltte rational choice
[but] a one-Sided focus on either aspect by itself—ac-
tions or reactions—provides a distorted view of the
consumption experience.” We agree. There is a clear
O

Stephen J. Hcch professor of marketing and behavioral science


need to examine the interaction between rational and
and Georg r. Loewc nstein is associate profcsso r of hcha vio ral sci- hedonic motives—between what Albert H irschman
ence, both ai the Center for Dccisio n R cscarch. Graduate School ( 1977) called the “interests” and the “passions” and
of Busi ness, U niversii y of Chicago, i 10 i E. 5 8th St.. Chicago, I L what Abelson ( 1963) labeled “cold” and “hot” cog-
60637. Both authors contributed equally to the w rising of this paper. nition. Although each perspective adequately
This work was supported in part by the Beatrice Companies, I nc.,
Faculty Research Fu nd at the Graduate School of Business, U ni- describes a wide range of consumer behaviors, neither
versity of Chicago, a National Science Fo undalion grant #SES- alone can provide a complete account. One reason that
891075 5 to S.J.H ., and bt' grants from they Russell Sage Foundation little progress has been made in integrating the
and the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation to G.F.L.
rational with the hedonic is an incompatibility in
vocabulary. Typ- icall y, the rational side has been
492 modeled formally

<c 1991 oy JOt4 RNn I. OF CONSUMER RESEARCH, Inc. e Vol. l7 e March l99t
All n$tMs l<served. fXt9T3 30 I /9 I /1704-OXI4$tI2.X

CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL
493
while the hedonic side has bcen described more qual-
itatively. One way to lie the cognitive to the emotional We propose a m odel to explain consumer impatience
is to place them in a framework with a com mon lan- and the circumstances under which it will occur. Spe-
guage. cifically. the model addresses the question of how and
We do not intend to provide a com plete model of why consumers experience “sudden, often powerful
the interplay betwecn cognition and emotion. Our in- urge(s) to buy something immediately” (Rook 1987)
terests here are narrower and our efforts m ore modest. that can in vol ve temporary overriding of long-term
We oifer an eco nomic-psyc hological model that seeks preferences. Next, we discuss tactics that consumers
io integrate ihe rational and emotional forces influ- use to control I heir own behavior and to avoid time-
encing consumer self-control. Although consumers are inconsistency. We organize our discussion around a two-
often even handed in their balancing of present and factor modcl or behavior, where the battle for self-
future benefits and costs, certain situations can induce control is conceptualized as a struggle between the two
extreme impatience. At such times, buying assu mcs a psychological forces o1’ desire and willpower. We dis-
more hedonic character (H irsch man and Holbrook
tinguish t wo classes of self-control strategies: (a) those D
1982), one better characterized by sudden increascs in
ihal attempt to directly reduce desire, and (h) those o
desire accompanied by inner conflict and attem pts to w
lhat seek to ovcrcome desire through a variety of will-
control one’s own behavior. Shi1’ts in time perspective nl
power tactics.
of this type have becn labeled “myopic” or “time-in- oa
Before continuing, it is important to place this work de
consistent” by economists (Strotz 19561 and “impul-
in proper perspective. First, we assume that consumers d
sive” by psychologists (A inslie 1975). Self-control, as
do i ndeed have long-term preferences. We do not ad- fro
we defi ne it, consists of efforts on lhe part of’ the con- m
vocate (or require) the extreme position of some econ-
sumer to avoid or resist behaving in such an inconsis- htt
omists, who argue that tastes are stable and essentially
tent man ner. ps
constant across all consumers, Rather we assume that ://
TIME-I NCONSISTENCY consu m ers have I eng-terms goals that, in turn, guide ac
A time-inconsistent choice is one thal would not their preferences (M iller, Galanter. and Pribram 1960). ad
Second, we assu me that passionate behavior can be e
have been made if it had been contemplaled from a mi
removed, dispassionate perspcctivc: it represents a modeled. We retain the essential cost-benefit orien- c.
transient alteration in lastes, not a permanent reeval- tation of the utilitarian perspective, bui m odify it to ou
nation of an alternative due to receipt nf new infor- incorporate the emotional reactions excluded from p.
mation (cf. Stigler and Becker 1977). Time-inconsis- most economic models. Finally, our approach is most co
releva nt to contemporary Western consu mers, where m/
tent behavior is of special interest to economists jcr
because of its significance for macroeconomic policy possessions play an indirect role in defining individ- /ar
(Kydland and Prescott 1977) and sari rigs behavior ually bascd identities, and less relevant to more tra- ticl
(Thaler and Shefrin l9fi 1). Psychologists have been ditional societies, where group identity is the guiding e/
concerned mainly with the connection between im- force behind self-concept (Belk 1984). 17
/4/
pulsi vity and dieting, addiclion, and other self-regu- 49
lation problems. The ability to delay gratihcation has A RE FERENCE-POINT MODEL 2/
been studied extensively in developmental and clinical OF DESI RE 17
97
settings (M ischel 1974).
Time-inconsistcncy raises inn po rtant q uestions W hy do people sometimes act incOn5istently over 24
time engaging in behavior that would have been re- 3
about consumcr sovereignty (Slrotz 1956). Are im- by
patience-driven decisions as legitimate (normative) as jecte‹l if contem plated in adva nce and that may be gu
the even handed preferences that are usually assu med regretted after the fact? This question has puzzled gen- es
to reign? Is there no arguing with t astcs, as erations of social scicntists. One view, espoused by t
economists often assert? The consensus of social Marshall ( 1 890) in the openi rig quote, is thai time- on
inconsistent behavior arises from unpredictable 09
scientists, and apparently of consumers them set yes, O
is that time-in- consistent preferences are not as changes in moods and tastes (also see Bass 1974). I n
legitimate as their more farsighted counterparts. a modern rendition of this view, Winston ( 19801 pro-
Consumers ialk about being driven to buy something posed an econ omic model of tmpulsivity in which a
against their own better judgment, and, as a result, we decision maker randomly vacillates between two sets
com monly observe at- tempts by consumers to of preferences, one myopic and the other farsighted.
control their own behavior, to avoid or resist episodes Winston descrilres a variety of strategies that people
can employ to maximize expected utility in the face
of extreme impatience. Popular magazines aid
of inconsistent preference fluctuations. This economic
consumers in control efforts by offering elaborate
model of impulsivity has two shortcomings. First, it
instructions on how to fight the “urge to splurge” and
placcs time-inconsistent preferences on an equal foot-
avoid “binge buying” ( fimr 1987).
ing with temporally consistent preferences. But im-
This article begins with a discussion ef consumer patience is not simply the random manifestation of an
time preference and the causes of time-inconsistency. alternate and equally valid preference ordering; rather,
494 ing impulsively, consumers often view their own de-
cision making as distorted (Rook 1987). Second, the
it i3 a m omentary and involuntary departure from the random-preference model fails to shed light on the ba-
consumer’s dominant preferences. Even while behav- sic qucstion of when and why m yopic preferences
come into play. JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
An alternative and better-k nown cx planation of im-
patience (Ainslie 1975; Strotz 1956) is based on lhe FIGURE 1
economic concept of discounting. According to t his
view, people are disproportionately attracted to im- ADAPTATION ANO THE VALUE OF CONSUI\1PTION
mediatel y available rewards. When two rewards (e.g. , Sati slactio n
the pleasure of a cigarctte and thc plcasu re ot good
health) are both substantially delayed, the individual
is able to make a rational trade-off between them ,
However, when one reward (the cigarette, in this ex-
ample) is imminent, it exerts a disproportionate at-
traction. The discounting perspective is accurate as
far as it goes, but it leaves basic questions unanswered.
Why are certain types of goods (e.g.. dessert) associated
with impulsivity and not others (e.g., gasoline)? Dis-
counting also fails to explain why other factors, such D
o
as physical proximity. are com mt›nly associated with w
time-inconsistency. nl
Although recognizing the i mporlance of ti me (as oa
well as other dimensions of pro ximit y), our model of de
impatience differs from the eco nomic discounting d
fro
perspective. We believe that time-inconsistent pref- m
erences arc due to suddcn i ncreascs in desire brought htt
o n by a shift in the consumer's reference point. Ref- ps
erence-point shifts can be precipiialed by any number ://
of factors (e.g.. physical proximity in a store), causing ac
ad
the consumer to partially adapt to I he notion of owning e
or consuming the product. After a reference point mi
shifts, consumers not only attach positi ve utility to t he c.
object itseir(what o ne might call a standing or existing ou
desire before the reference-point shi ft). but they also p.
Tversky’s ( 1979) prospect theory and more recently co
attach negative utility to fai lurc to consu me the object. m/
Failure to purchase implies more than the forgone applied lo consu mer choice (Thaler 19SO, 1985) and jcr
pleasure fro m consu m ption; the individual actuall v intertemporal choice (Loewenstein 1988). The value /ar
feels deprived, This deprivation is a psychological state function represents the consumer’s satisfaction level ticl
of need analogous to physi ological states of need exclusive of any costs (the j -axis) as a function of a e/
(which can range from h unger and thi rst to addiction). discrete outcome levcl (purchasc or nonpurchase) rel- 17
ative io some refcrencc point. The reference poini is /4/
49
Reference Points and Deprlvation located wherc the value function intersects the .v-axis. 2/
The concept of a reference point, or adaptation level, T he val ue fu nction is assu mcd to be steeper for neg- 17
has a long history in psychology. Reference points play ative departures (losses) than for positive departures 97
a central role in research on perception (Helson 1964), (gainsl from the rcferc ncc point (Bell 1982, 1985; 24
Fish burn 197 7; Kah neman and Tversk y 1979). 3
satisfaction with achicvcment (Lewin et al. 1944), dis- by
tributive justice (Walster, Bcrscheid, and Walster Consider a good that would yield a vaI uc of N, if it gu
19 73), saving behavior (Duesenberr y 1949), and lifc were purchased. The no-adaptation value function, es
satisfaction (Brick man, Coaies, and Janoff-Bulman rcpresented by the lighter line lfiat goes through the t
1978). The reference point reflects the fact that people origi n, is d rawn such that the purchase of the good on
yields D , and nonpurchasc yields zero. This no-ad- 09
are less concerned with absolute attainments than with O
aptation function depicts thc case of a consumer who
attainments relative io some psychologically relevant
would dcrive salisfaction from owning an object (Erased
comparison point.
on long-term needs) bu1 who has not adapted to the
Figure 1 illustrates the effect of a refcrence-point
notion of possessing it. Wiih no adaptation, the stecpl y
shift using a framcwork introduced in Kah neman and
sloped negative region of the value function is not rel-
evant.
The value function’s usefulness lies in showing what
happens whgn the consumer partially adapts to pos-
session of 1 hc good. The partial adaptation casc is de-
picted by the bold-line value function. As com pared
with the no-adaptatio n situation. thc zero point of the
value function has movcd to the right, signifying that
the consumer is now in an intermediate state between
CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL stead results in deprivatio n (the distance bet wccn the
origin and where the bold value function intersects the
owning and not owning the prod uci. Failing to make -axis). Now, overall desire for the product is repre-
the purchase is no longer affectively neutral, but in- sented by the distance +2 ( e., the utility resulting from
consumption coupled wilh the rclief ensuing from not 495
feeling deprived).
In both the no-adaptation and adaptation cases. we
define desire D and D2l as the difference between expectations about the future or the consumption level
owning and nor ohm ng the object. The graphic de- of a referent individual or group (Austin 1977; Gurr
pictio n of desire D) in Figure 1 can be written in 1970; W alster et at. 1973). Falling below onc’s refcr-
equation form. ence point or adaptation level, whether biological or
psychological, can lead to feelings of deprivation and
D — o(P — r) + g(r — 0), (1) provides lhe moi ination to improve one’s relative po-
sition.
where a is the slope of the value function in the positive
region, fl is its slope in lhe negaii ve region, and r is the
E ynam it E’ff‹•ei.‹ vf R eference- Pnint Shi fts. Al-
consumer’s level of adaplalion between purchase (N)
though the rcferencc-point shift depicted in Figure 1
and nonpurchase (0). The value N is normalized so
provides a mec han ism for the motive force behind
that a P iS equal to the consumer’s no-adaptation level
time-inconsistency, it is a stat ie conception. Most de-
of desire for the good D .
cisions madc in the present have hedonic consequences D
As long as fi > n, an increase in r will raise D. o
that extend over time. If desire is not t ransient, the
Desire represc nts the consu mc r*s levcl of w
loss depicted on the value fu nction will understate the
motivation to pos- sess the object; in the no- nl
deprivation anticipai cd or cxperienced by the con- oa
adaptation case, it is based solely on a standing
su mer while consumption is delayed. The deprivation de
preference for ihe iiem. Because the consumer views d
induced by a reference point shift is not instantaneous,
the purchase as hypothetical, fail- ure to purchase fro
but may linger. Thus. the relevant loss must take into
does not result in deprivation (the consu mer m
account thc lc ngt h of time during which the consumer htt
possesses nothing and, so. loses nothing). The consu
feels deprived. Figure 2s depicts the choice between ps
mer will buy lhe product whenever desire exceeds the
an in ferior, inn mediate object and a superior, delayed ://
costs (both economic and psychic) of pur- chase. ac
object under conditions of partial adaptation. The
Deprivation, induced by partial adaptation. in- ad
smaller rectangle in Figure 2 represents the utility de- e
tensifies desire and the motivation to purchase
rived from consuming a smaller immediate reward; mi
because
the larger rectangle depicts lhe utility derived from a c.
> Nt . The consumer who partially adapts ha5 al- larger delayed reward. The area marked “deprivation ou
ready had a taste and may drcad the pain of having to p.
forgo further tastes. Similarly, the bait-and-switch vic- from waiting” represents the negative utiJ ity experi- co
tim, who anticipates making a purchase but fi nds the enced while waiting for the larger delayed reward. The m/
item out of stock, will feel deprived and may feel com- delayed reward could be a concrete object (e.g., a car) jcr
or something more ahstract (e.g., long-term health /ar
pelled to purchase a substitute item to mitigate the ticl
immediate frustratio n. benefits). As Figure 2s shows, the more deprived one
e/
Divergent social science research points to the feels while waiting, the greater is the incentive to con- 17
pow- erful incentive value of negative departures sume quickly so as to terminate the stream of negative /4/
from a ref- erence level. Research on a nima I utility. 49
In certain cases, thc consumer may be aware that 2/
learning has dist in- guished three types of incentives: 17
reward, punishment, and frustrative non reward. desk re for an object is transient and may opt for the 97
Frustrati ve nonreward oc- curs “when we fail to delayed option, k now ing that the deprivation will be 24
reinforce a response that has previously been short-lived. This situation is depicted in Figure 2b, 3
reinforced” (Skinner 1950, p. 203). There is evidencc with time, depri vation from waiting decreases. Often by
de- privation decreases with time because the gu
that frustrativ e n on reward has greater incentive es
value than either reward or punish- ment (Amsel consumer moves on to other activities. Reduced t
1958; Wagner 19 5 9). For example, the powerful attention to thc object of desire can result in a leftward on
motivating effect of intermittent reinforce- ment can shift of the reference point back toward the non 09
be explained in terms of the frustration brought on by purchase zero point in Figure I . An example of O
nonreinforced trials (Amsel 1962). Re- search on decreasing depriva- tion over lime can arise in eating
social un rest also provides evidence for the behavior. Some peo- ple have learned ihat, even if
significance of negati vc departures from reference they remain ravenous after a big meal, they should
lev- els. Most theories assume that discontent results delay the decision to order dessert. The reason is that
from a negative discrepancy between current changes in osmotic pressure in the stomach and blood
position and some reference value, whethcr the sugar that accompany eating, and reduce feelings of
reference value is hunger, do not occur immedi- ately (Guyton 1971).
Within 20 minutes, however, the pain of abstinence
usually fades. In other cases, desire may intensify
over t i me, a situation illustrated in Fig- ure 2r,
Again, physical appetites provide a context for
under5tanding such phenomena: feelings of hunger
and thirst lypically intensify if left unsatisfied. This
495 CHOICE BETWEEN IMMEDIATE AND DELAYED CONSUMPTION
ta) C a n s tant d e p rl v ali o n
JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

ity. For example, consumers asked to discuss recent


impulse purchases (Rook and Hocli 1985) repeatedly
commented on the difficulty of deferring consum Ation.
“It gnaws at me until I buy it.” “The feeling staris
when 1 see something . . it comes on very quickly
and is a persistent nagging.” Thc deprivation experi-
enced by the consumer is, thus, analogous to a mild
addiclion. Addiction is a com plex phenomenon with
m ultiple stages, progressions, and in fi uences (Marlatt
et at. 198d). Bul some research suggests that the ad-
dict’s powerful urge to consume is not so much a search
fo r plcasure (addictive substances lose hedonic potency
with prolonged usc) as a flig ht from pain, the pain of
not consu ming (Sil vcrstein 1976; Solomon and
(b) T ran s i ent d e p riva t i a n
Corbit 1974).
I n su m, we believe that lime-inconsistent prefer-
ences are i nduced by reference-point shifts in which
consumers adapt to possession of not-yet-purchased
items. When reference points shi fl, the consumer’s de-
sire for the nonpurchascd object increases. More im-
portantly, the consu mer desires to purchase or con-
surnc the object as quickly as possible so as to terminate
the stream of deprivation. I n the next section, we dis-
cuss en viron mental faci ors that can lead to
reference- point shi fts and prom ole impulsivity.

Proximity-induced Impatience
l n gencral, refcrcnce-point shifts arc induced by a
process of accom m odation or adaptation. People ex-
posed to a persistcnt sensory stim ulus (c.g.. a noise or
smell) adapt to lhat slim ulus to the point at which they
are no longer aware of il: they are sensitive only to d
cviations from the adapted-to-stimul us level. Re-
garding co nsu mcr behavior, reference-point shifts are
caused by the consumer’s adapting to possession of a
good that has not been purchased. There are many
mechanisms that can cause such adaptation (a right-
ward shift of t he reference point in Fig. 1 ), All of the
mechanisms involve increasing lhe consu mcr's prox-
imity to thc good along somc dimension.
Ph vsi‹'al Nro. Uni/r. Perhaps the most potent in-
duccr of reference-point shifts is ph ysical proximity.
The effect cif physical proximity on impulsivity has
becn well documented in experiments on delay of
grat ifi cation by M ischcl ( 1974). In a typical experi-
may he one reason why ph ysical appetites are such ment, children are placed in a room and taught that
potent instigators of impulsivity: they just do not go they can quickly summon the experimenter by ringing
away. a beIL They arc then givcn a choice between an im-
The pain associated with not buying is a recurring mediate inferior reward (e.g.. a single marshmallow)
theme in consumers’ accounts of their own inn pulsiv- or a delayed superior reward (two marsh mallows). I f
ihe child is able to wait for the experimenter to return
without ringing the bell, s/he obtains thc superior
item. I mpulsivity is measured by how long the subject
writs before ringing the be1L In an early experiment,
Mischcl and Gruscc ( 1967) examined the cffeci of the
visiblc presence of thc rcward on willingness to wait;
when eit her the immediate or delayed reward was in
view,
CONSUMER BELF-CONTROL ing the object in view leads to a rcferc rice-point shift that
increases deprivation and makes waiting more dif- ficult.
subjects were less willing to delay. It appears that plac- A variety of marketing practices ma y induce a ref-
erence-point shift by increasing physical and sensory 497
pToximity. Much advertising shows the product in use,
increasing proximity by vividly simulating the cxpe-
rience (Macl nnis and Pricc 1987. Wclls 1987). Distilled fcrrcd the more lemporally proximate toy (75 percent),
spirits ads opi for simple “boitle, glass. and ice” de- whether faced with a one-wcek (b2 percent) or lh ree-
pictions to help consumers visuahze the ex perience. min ute (68 percent) delay in receiving the other toy.
Marketers also use atmospherics t K otlcr 197 3— 1974; L oewcnstein ( 1990) examined the effects or temporal
Nord and Peter 1980) to provide the senses wilh a hint proxi m ity by manipulating the interval that high
of the real experience. For example, Mrs. Field’s sch ool sophom ores anticipated waiting before receiv-
Cookies has successfull y overcome high rcnts by ing a reward objecL Subjects either expected an early
pu mping chocolate-chip cookie odor into the heavy If- (e.g., four weeks) or a late delivery (e.g.. eight weeks)
trafficked corridors o1 A mcrican shopping malls. of a $7 gift certificate from a local record store. After
Sometimes marketers actually gi ve thc consumer a a two-week delay, subjects were given a choice between
taste through sampling. Scratch and -sniff perfume $7 at the early date or $8.50 if they delayed until the
samples are accompanied by product order forms. fare date. Subjects expecting an early delivery were less
Publishers who send books and magazines into the I ikely to wait than lhose expecting a later delivery (42 D
home with the cxplicit assurance that they can be re- percent vs. b4 pcrcenl). Apparently. subjects adapted to o
turned if they are not wan led may also shift Jhe con- t hei r anticipated delivery dates, and those subjects who w
felt rem porally closer to the reward were more nl
sumer’s reference point (Thaler 1980), as may’ sellers oa
of Oriental rugs who encouragc customers to borrow impatient than those who felt tcmporally farther away. de
rugs to “see how they look in your home.” Clearly Some marke ling efforts may increase impatience by scl d
there are otten unanticipated transaction costs asso- ling inn mine nt opportunit y, reminding the con- su fro
ciated with product return. howcvcr. it is also the case mer that the prod uct is “yours for the asking” or “only a m
phonc call away.” Pizza-delivery services that give a so htt
that parting with a book that has graced one’s coffee ps
tablc. or a rug that has cnhanccd thc atmosphere of bsiantial discou nt if the pizza is not delivered within 3t) ://
minutes ntit only are guaranteeing a warm. nonsoggy ac
one’s living room. is more dt the ul t than turning away
from the same book or rug displayed with cou ntlcss product. but are also playing on the time element in a ad
others in ihc rctail outlct (K nctsch. Thaler, and domain where impatience tends to be particularly e
severe. The di 5count raises the credibility of the claim mi
Kah neman 1987). c.
and offsets any anticipated impatience once the pizza is ou
Temporal Pro.’irnii\!. Earlier theoretical accounts ordered. since late delivery confers Signifi cant p.
of impulsivity (A inslie 1975: Strot z 1956) focused economiC Savings. Many direct-response ad co
on only one dimension of proximity, proximity in vcrtisemcnls are accompanied hy a toll-free hot line m/
time. allowing inn mediatc ordering. Direct-mail catal og jcr
/ar
companies not only feature toll-free n umbers with 24- ticl
hour order-taking operators, they also provide ihe e/
pption of next-day express deli ver y for an extra fee. 17
Television-bascd marketers of carpeting offer next-day, /4/
in-home viewing of samples and 2—3-day dcli vcry 49
2/
thereaftcr. 17
I n the animal-learning literature, it is well known that So ’ill C.’oinporison. A third factor that appears 97
the more immediate a reward, the greater is its rein- c apable of inducing a refcrence-point shift is social 24
forcing val ue (Chung and Herrnsicin 1967). Hence. com parison. People faced with an adverse social com- the 3
by
inn mediate availability of a reward will tend to in- parison want what their more tortunaie peers aJ ready gu
crease the desire for ii. Research on lime preference possess, and they do not want to wait. For example, es
suggests that increasing temporal proximity not o nl y sociological rcsearch (Easlerlin 1974: Merton 1968; t
increases desirability. but also increases impatience. Stouffer et al. 1949) suggcsts that pcople or" all income on
Willingness to delay gratification in exchange for levels tend lo compare themsel ves with others who are 09
O
greater rewards decreases as consumption ot›jects be- slightly betlcr off lhan they are. Festingcr ( 1954) argucd
come irn mingnt (A inslie and Hacndel 19 h 3; Benzion, lhut people prefer to compare themselves to “superior”
Rapoport, and Yagil 1987). The increase in impatience’ others, for both informational and status reasons (cf. is
duc in part to nonexponent ial discounting (A inslie Brickman and Bul man 1977). A reference-point shift
1975), hut it is also exacerbated by a temporally in- induced by social comparison increases proximity and
duced reference-point 5hift (Loewenstein 1988). may reduce willingneS5 to delay consumption. Related
I n four experimcnts with five- to seven-year-old research on coaCtion cffects has found that people
children, Irwin, Armitt, and Simon ( 1943) examined consume more food in the presence of others who are
preference for im mediate- and delayed-choice objects. al5o consuming (Zajonc 1968). Terkel ( 1970) provides
Children were shown two toys. one to bc received inn- anecdotal e 'idence that. during the Great Depression.
mediatcly and one later; preferences for the two toys there was an upswing in gambling on horses and num-
were measured. The children overwhelmingly prc- bcrs in this cxample. thc relevant reference point may
498 Loewenstein ( 1990) experimentally demonstrated the
effect of social comparison on impulsi vil y. Fifth- graders
have been previous income levels (i.e., an example of who won a moderate prize ($4) in a competi- tion against
intraindividual social comparison and its ePect on im- opponents who won a larger prize ($8) displayed greater
pulsivity). inn patience than subjects who won the same moderatc
prize but whose opponents won a smaller prize ($ 2). JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
Losers were willing to give up more than winners to get
the reward inn mediately (450 vs. I 2e). Losers also
requi red a larger premium than win- ners ror enduring a The ability to maintain self-control and successfully
further delay (534 vs. 23c). If losers use their lucky peers implement long-run decisions depends on the relative
as a consumption standard and partially adapt to what strength of the opposing forces of desire and willpower.
lhey might have gotten if they had won, then the The consumer’s conflict is portrayed in Figure 3. The
reference-point m odel or desire pre- dicts greater consumer can rest at any placc on the diagram. The
feelings of deprivation and impatience for losers than x- and J'-coordinates represent current levels of desire
for winners. and willpower. In Figure 3s, the consumer begins with
Advertising based on modeling and identificalion a standing lcvel of desirc for a product, D . To illus-
with prototypical product users (Peter and Olson trate, imagine a consu mer who has prcviously decided
1987) may induce reference-point shifts through on a long-term course of action, weight control, and
social com- parison. A n cxam ple is VA LS-inspired vows not to eat desserts. At D , willpower is greater
ad yen ising (e.g., American Express) that targets than de5ire, so the consumer does no1 want to pur-
emulators, who model much of their behavior after the chase. If, however. the consu mer were to come into
more materially successful achievers (Hot man 1984). direct contact Uh a previously rejected alternative
Although iden- tification with a product user (e.g., by being confronted by the dessert cart after a
undoubtedly increases desire by increasing the slope lavish meal), the increased proximity might boost de-
of the value function on the gain side, our analysis sire and move the consumer righ tward to D› . With a
suggests that identification may also encourage large enough increase in desire, the consumer can cross
buying through a rightward shift of the consumer’s over the “buy li ne” to ltte point where desire now
reference point. Of course, the strength of the dominates willpower. At this point, there is a need for
reference-point shift will depend on the level of self-control. A time-inconsistent purchase will result
identification with the product user (Krebs 1975). u nless the co nsumer can quickly move back above the
dashed diagonal.
Figure 3b sh ows that there are several ways that
SELF-CONTROL: THE CONFLICT the consumer can respond. First, s/he may buy, and
BETWEEN DESIRE AND pos- sibly consume, the product immediately in an
WILLPOWER attempt to sate the desire; in such cases the co nsumer
never moves from N, . Purchases of this kind may
Consumers are not passive victims of their own
occur with the minimu m conscious deliberation
fluctuating preferences. Those who have experienced
charactcristic of automatic or mindless behavior (
rime-inconsistency and its consequences (e.g., the re-
Langer, Blank, and Chanowitz 197d; Langer and I
gret associated with closets full of unworn clothes or
mber 1980; Weinberg and Goltwold 1982), or the
embarrassing product returns) are likely to develop
pure reaction with little or no cognition (Holbrook et
se!f-control strategies for imposing consistency on
al. 1990). Alternatively, consumers may experience an
their own behavior. I n this articlc. we frame the self-
“interrupt” (Bett man 1979; Simon 1967) that alerts
coMrol problem as a psychological conflict between
them to the need for cognitive deliberation. Interrupts
desire (the initiating hedonic force previously
can assume many forms. Consu mcrs may recognize that
discussed} and willpower (strategies used to
they are in a situation in which they prcviously made
overcome desire).
purchases that were regretted (e.g., in a fancy clothing
Two-factor models of behavior have been an store right after payday). Thc act of pa ying fo r the
integral part of many accounts of self-control (Freud
ilcm may also act as a n interrupt. Even desirc itsel f
191 1 ; James 1890: McIntosh 1969; Winston 1980).
may serve as an in- terru pl: loo su d den an increase
In psy- choanalytic theory, the conflict is represented
in desire may lead consumers to be suspicious of their
as an oscillation between primary process thinking
motives.
(the id or pleasure principle), which is impulse-driven, The desire-willpower framework illustrated in Fig-
largely irrational, and seeks immediate gratification at ure 3b ma kes it clear that Ihere arc two distinct forms
any and all costs, and secondary process thinking (ihe that self-control attempts can take: desire-based and
ego or réality principle), which is patient. logical, and willpower-based. First, consumers may attempt to di-
has the will to postpone gratification in lhe ser vice of rectly reduce desire (a direct movement to the left) by
future long-run gains or goals (Hilgard 1962). physically or psychologically reducing proximity to the
product. Alternatively, consumers may attempt to
overpower desire (an u pward movement) by relying
on a variety of willpower strategies. Willpower at-
tern pts will be succes rul to the extent that consumers
can nor oifer persuasive rationalizations (a downward
movement) thai might legitimate a time-inconsistent
prefercnce.
Before moving on, it is important to note that con-
sumer self-control, however, need not be as reactive
CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL 49'7

FIGURE 3

DESIRE-WILLPOWER MODEL OF SELF-CONTROL


( a) TIme-inca nsistent preference induced by prox imity ( b) 8 fra legies for ma in ie in in g set f-com rot

W i I I powe r

D
o
w
nl
oa
de
d
fro
m
Desire Desire htt
ps
://
ac
as suggested in the desk re- ind uced, interrupt vie w. Although standard models of dccision making take ad
There are other rcaso ns people might want to reg ulatc e
tastes as fixed and inx'ariant, there has been some work
their inn mediate consumption hehavior. In his discus- mi
on the sclf-manipulation of preferences. Most rele vant c.
sion of modern hedo nism. Campbell ( 1957) offers a
to our rcfercnce point m odel is the literature on as- ou
m uch more proactive conception of selt-control. For
piration level. AT though aspiration lcvel sometimes is p.
Campbell, m uch pleasure is sought vja emotional co
considered as cx ogenously specified, much of the lit-
stimulation (imagination. window shopping) to create m/
erature h‹is rccognix.ed that individuals have some
a necessary level ot novelty. Drawing on earlier work jcr
abilit y to control their own aspiralions. Downward /ar
by Scitovsk y ( 1976), Campbell offers a conccption manipulations of aspirations may serve to reduce the
of self-control that could be labcled “pleasure ticl
frustration arising from failure to meet goals (Festingcr e/
manage- ment.” Consumers cngagcd in p[easurc managc 1942). Likewise, people may inflate their aspirations 17
ment recognize (at least implicitly) that there is a to increase their motivation lcvel (Frank 194 I ). In our /4/
trade-off between comt“ort and pleasure. Scitovsky framework. people manipulate lheir reference points 49
defi ned comfort as residing at an optimal state of 2/
to maintain consist ency in their own behavior. Like a 17
arousal. He argued that comfort i n itself is not surge protector on a computer, the goal of such efforts 97
pleasurable: pleasure is generated during the process of is to neulralize transient shi fts in desire that are caused 24
getting to the com- fortable state (eithcr incrcasing or by sudden increases in proximity. This scction outlines 3
decreasing arousal to thc optimal level). Pleasure threc self-control tactics (avoidance, postponement by
manage menl in vol pcs self-imposcd periods of deprivat gu
and distraction, and substitution} that reduce desire es
io n to inc re asc futurc pleasure, It demands consumer b y undoing refcrence-point shifts. Each tactic inn plies t
foresight. requiring a consumer worldly enough to a lcftward movement in Figure 3. on
appreciate George Ber- nard Shaw’s obser v ation t hat 09
“There are lwo tragcdies in life. One is not to get your Ai'‹ iJunt’e. Clearly, the best way for consumers to O
heart’s desire. The other is to gai n it.” Everyone avoid time-inconsistent behavior is to eschew situa-
engages in pleasure manage- ment to some degree. Not lions in which they are likely to cxperience increases
eat ing bet ween m cals so as to better enjoy din ner, in desire for previously rcjectcd alternatives. Avoid-
and taking a 10-kilometer run so as to experience lhe ance prccludes physical or sensory proximity and, thus,
pleasurc of slopping, are ex- amples of defcrring prevents a proximity-induced shift in a reference stan-
short-term gains for the promise of long-term dard. The importancc of" avoidance is well-known to
pleasure. Pleasure management is a fas- cinating form those who have given up alcohol or drugs (although
of sell’-control that deserves more study. there is some controversial clinical evidence that al-
coholics and addicts may be able to consume in m od-
Desire Reduction eralion: Polich, Armor. and Braiker 19S l ). Recogniz-
One way in which consumers can maintain self- ing that their resolve could lapse under the wrong
control is by manipulaling Ihcir own reference points. circumstances, recovering alcoholics and addicts
nften
500 served. Rook and Hoch (1985) found that consumers
employed a variety of distancing strategies based on
avoid bars and parties where alcohol or drugs are avoidance, such as: “You’ve got to walk away—as soon
as I feel an impulse, I immediately leave the area,” JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
and “I steer clear of record stores whcn I can’t afford
it.” Schifter and Ajzen ( I 9S5) found that women were
more successful in losing weight when they had de- pean uts or potato chips. The purpose of this tactic lfi
veloped a fairly detailed plan of action to deal with to provide sufficient immediate satisfaction to endure
the unanticipated difficulties of dieting. the deprivatio n associated with waiting, perhaps si-
m ull aneously distracting oneself from the original de-
Po.st pon‹'ment and Dislruc lion, Postponement sired object. Low-calorie foods (e.g., light and nonal-
means putting off a choice until some ruture date, an coholic beverages and high-fiber breads that fill you
effective st rategy against transient desires (Fig. 2b). up but not out) are positioned as wholesome substitutes
Many consumgrs devise post ponement rules, such as: for the real thing. Specialty shops and galleries selling
“Never buy a car on the first visit to the dealership,” expensi ve antiques or artwork also offer relatively in-
or “Always consult my spouse before making a major expensive baubles and gewgaws that can be purchased
purchase.” After a consu mer leaves i he showroom or to sale desires for more imposing objects.
department store, his or her desires, which had seemed The effectiveness of substitution is uncertain. Sev-
firm ly entrenched. often recede. Rook ( 1987) found eral fi ndings from the delay-of-gratification paradigm D
that the most difficult moments in a n impulsive-buyi rig suggest that it can backfi re (Yates and Mischel 1979). o
situation occur inn mediately after the i mpulse to con- Although substitution may momentarily distract the w
sume is first felt. Consumcrs believed that the intense consumer from the more desirable object, the delayed nl
desire would subside by itself if they could only resist oa
object may come back into focus. I mpatience may in- de
it for a little while. Recognizing that impulsivity may lensify when 1he small reward is no longer available. d
be cultivated by high-pressure sales t actics, nu mcrous Moreover a “lesser evil” substitute may not always be fro
states have th ree- to seven-day cooling-off periods an improvement over the focal object of desire, as wit- m
during which a consu mer can reconsider and nullify nessed by people who continue to sm oke in order to htt
a purchase. Postponement, howevcr, does not work ps
avoid weight gain ( K lesges ct al. 1989). ://
for all people. N isbett and Kanouse ( 1968) found that, ac
although there was a positive relation between un- ad
planned inn pulse buying and number of hours of food Willpower e
deprivation for normal-weight individuals, there was The second factor influenci ng self-control is will- mi
no relation for obesc consumers. I n fact, obese con- c.
power. Willpower refers to the diverse tactics that peo- ou
sumers purchased even mo re when they had just eaten, ple use to overcome, rather than to reduce, lheir own p.
suggesting the possibility of an eating-begets-ealing impatience. The idea of pvercoming desires is inimical co
mechanism. to lhe rational choice perspective, which assumes thai m/
Distraction has proved to be one of ihe most suc- people try to satisfy, raihcr than to ovcrcome, desires. jcr
cessful means of postponing. Whereas attention to the /ar
The use of willpower tactics implies the existence of ticl
delayed-goal object increases the pain associated with multiple, quasi-independent centers of motivation e/
waiting, distraction reduces the frustration and arousal wilhin individuals (or m ultiple selves [Elster 1977]). 17
that accompanies the typical waiting period, I n literature and the fine arts. self-conflict is often /4/
effcclively reducing the magnitude of the shaded portrayed as the soul caught between the devil’s im- 49
areas in Figure precarious and an angel’s moral ex hortations. I ntra- 2/
2. Work by Mischel and his colleagues has dc mon- 17
personal conhict is a recurring theme in consumers’ 97
strated that self-distraction is an effective way tor chil- self-reports of impulse purchases (Rook 1957; Rook 24
dren to maintain self-imposed delays of desired goal and Hoch 1985). To capture the introspective expe- 3
objects (other than avoidance). 1 n two sets of experi- rience of intrapersonal conflict, theorctical frameworks by
ments, subjects were i nstructed to distract themselves gu
of inter personal conflict have been used to model the es
while waiting (Mischel and Ebbesen 1970) or to cog- struggle between multiple set ves. Ga me theory, the t
niti vely transform the inn mediate rewards (e.g., by problem of collective actio n, and principal agent the- on
thinking of the marsh mallows as liltle White clouds; ory ha ve all been translated into intrapersonal terms. 09
Mischel, Ebbesen, and Zeiss 197 2). Both distraction Schelling (1978) and, more recently, A inslie ( 1985) O
and cognitive transformation increased willingness to view intrapersonal conflict as a repeated two-person
wait. game, an “intimate contest for self-command”
Subsiif ulion. Substitution involves offering oneself (Schelling 1984) between two selves, one myopic and
a small but immediate reward for successfully resisting the of her farsighted. For example, there is the self
a larger impulse. For instance, as a snack, a dieter may (dominant right after smoking a cigarette) who wants
substitute a piece of celery for the much more satisfying to quit smoking and the self who wants “just one
more.” There is the self who wants to rise early (and
sets the alarm clock accordingly) and the self who re-
jects the previous night’s resolve in favor of sleeping
i ri. Willpower. in this context, can be viewed as t he
efforts of the farsighted self to constrain the behavior
of the m yopic sclf. Elster (1977) views intertemporal
CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL that social equilibrium can unwind as the result of in-
dividual defections, inn pulsi ve acts by earlier situated
choice as a problem of collective action between a se- selves (e.g., smoking a cigarette) can lead to an ever-
quence of temporally situated selves. In the same way expanding series of defections. Thaler and Shefrin
( 198 I) apply a theoretical framework adopted from
principal agent theory in Eco no mice to understand in- 50 1
trapersonal conflict. In their model, an a temporal, far-
sighted planner (the principal) attempts to regulate the
behavior of temporally situated, shortsighted doers (the Per 'ornm // m en/ Precommit ment involves any
agents). device through which consumers impose constraints
Sjoberg ( 1980; Sjdberg and Jnhnson 1978) views on, or n ltcr inrenti yes for, future behavior. A classic
willpower as a form of high-quality deliberation re- example of precommitment was Ulysses’ instructions
quiring cognitive effort. “To have a strong will means lo his crew t o bind him to the mast so that he could
being able to stick to an initial well-balanced decision hear thc Sirens without jumping overboard to his
under various forms of pressure” (Sjiiberg and death: his crew stuffed wax in their ears so that they
could sarely sail the boat (Elster 1977). Wiring one’s
Johnson 1978, p. 1 50). Volitional breakdowns occur
jaw shut as a means of losing weight and taking the
under the influence of strong moods or desires, when
d rug Antabuse io discourage future drinking arc mod-
“some en- ergy which otherwisc would have been
ern examples of precom mitment through self-binding,
available for the cognitive system is lost.. . . The
as are ltte less extreme cases of placing the alarm clock
withdrawal of energy first affects more sop h isticared
across the room (Schelling 1978) and leaving one’s D
cognii ive mech- anisms leaving the more primitive c re dit cards and chec kbook at h ome when going shop- o
ones. This may leave the door open for a corrupt, ping. “Side bets” (Becker 1960) are also often included w
twisted, and shortsighted reasoning which generates in the precommit ment category. Side bets are contracts nl
excuses for changing the initial decision” (p. 1 5 1). that com mii consumers to a course of action in which oa
Sjoberg and Joh nson tested their theoretical future rewards are irrevocably tied io the ability to
de
perspective by repeatedly interviewing smokers who d
avoid more inn mediate satisfactions. fro
attempted to quit. As predicted, reversion to smoking
Precom mitment is usually assumed to operate by m
gencrally occurred at ti mes of extreme stress; su brute force. The individual either eliminates the option htt
bjects who resumed smoking identified cog- nitive of consu ming or imposes sue h extreme penalties on ps
distortions of reality that occurred prior to re- impulsive behav›or ihai the costs outstrip the benefits.
://
sumption of smoking. ac
However, if credible, precommitment may also have ad
In what follows, we classify all of lhe i nterpcrsonal an impact th rough its effect on desire and impatience. e
strategies ihal people can apply intrapersonal ly under Knowing that one will not have the option to consume mi
the category of “willpower.” People can attempt to in the future can rcducc desire. For example, addicts c.
regulate their own behavior (by erecting constraints ou
surer le5s withdrawal pain when deloxifying in an es- p.
or altering incentives) in the same way that they at- tablishment that has a reputation for incorruptibility co
tempt to regulate others' behavior. I ust as indi idtials (SChelling 1984). m/
may attempt to use reason and argu ment to persuade Precommit mcnt has received much attention, es- jcr
an other perso n io adopt their pcrspecti ve, t hey may /ar
pecially in recent economic analyses of self-control
apply analogous persuasion tactics to themselves. (Elster 1977: Strotz 1956; Thaler and Shefrin 198 1 ).
ticl
Willpower tactics diffcr from desire-reduction tactics e/
It remains an obvious enigma for the standard time 17
in an important way. Willpower is a force that opposes discounti rig view. Despite the abundance of literature /4/
desire. Pure will power inn plies an u pward move in the on the subject. the prevalence of precommit ment in 49
desire-will power model in Figure 3. Exercise of will- aiding day-lo-day consumer self-control is unclear. 2/
power need not change the level of‘dcsire experienced Precommitment strategies are often difficult or costly
17
by the individual, although it can decrease, or inad- 97
to initiate and are of limited effectiveness. Consumers 24
vertently increase, the intensity of a desirc in certain are adept at constructing easily revocable side bets, 3
cases. inventing rationales for why a current purchase is a by
Willpower-based strategies include all attempts by valid exception to the rule. Even individual retirement gu
consumers to enumerate and make salient the costs of accounts, pensions, and trusts have provisions for early
es
t
satisfying time-inconsistent preferences. There are wiihd rawal. on
economic costs, based on an assessment of the ability 09
to pay, and psychic costs, such as guilt and regret. We Ec'onomi Cr›sr A ’s‹'ssmeni. When consumers are O
also discuss consu mer rationalizations thai might un- asked what types of self-control devices they use to
dermine the effectiveness of particular willpower resist impulsive buying, conscious consideration of the
st rntegies. purchase’s economic coSt5 iS often the first tactic men-
tioned (Rook and Hoch 1985). Self-control based on
cost-benefit considerations is not always easy. While
desire is proximate and vivid, economic consequences
usually are remote and di fficuli to define (Hirschman
1977). Ten dollars spent now results in a minute de-
crease in savings, or an insignificant increase in dcbt,
and is quickly lost in the complex flow of income and
purchases (Joh n SOfl, Kotlikoff, and Samuelson 1987).
There is little relation between an isolated expenditure
302 se[f- heI p groups for compulsive shoppers (e.g.,
Spender- tenders; see O’G ui n n and Faber 1959) have
today and the ability t o make a speci hc purchase in Iound that, when mak ing purchases, profligate
the future; this may be especiall y true in households spenders sometimes relied on a “just-charge-it” logic:
where the spender is not ihe bill payer. Sr udies of appar- ently, they were are able to succcssfull y
divorce the pleasures of purchase from the economic
JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
realii ies of paymc nt.
Consumers may make numerous rationalizations
(some provided by salespeople who have read personal I he deve1 opment cif frustra4 ion (deprivation)
sell ing man ual s) t hal sabotage their attem pts at ra- tolcrance. Hence, he viewed idcalion about delayed
tional cost assessment: most notable are feelings of rewards as, in cifert, a substitution tactic where i he
entitlement. Entitlement represents t he quintessential intermediate rewards are psychic rather lhan material.
Yuppie theme—“you work hard, so you deserve lo Time binding and other typcs of internal reinforcers
play hard.” As the theme was expressed on a recent bus- have becn the subject of m uch study, particularly in
stop advertisement for women’s designer clothes, “Beiny developmental research on delay of gratification (see
it all is hard work; havink it all makes u p for it.” Mischel [1974] for a sum mary). When waiting for a
Splurging is acceptable because a penance has been paid gnal object is involuntary (i.e., an extcrnall y imposed
in advance or will be in the near future. The V delay thal cannot be overcome), time binding has been
ALS-inspired achiever ads rely on the entitlement theme. dem onstrated to be an effective st ratcgy to reduce
as exemplified by a print ad sh o wing two ex- hausted frustration (M iller and K.arniol 1976). However, when
racquet ball players as backd rop to the copy: “He works the situati on in vo1x•es a self-i m posed delay of gratih- D
as hard as hc plays. And he drinks Johnnie Walker.” A cation (arguat›1y the most com mon situation in con- o
su mer behavior), experimental research overwhelm- w
recurrent lheme in consumers’ discussions of why they nl
engage in recreational shopping and im- pulse buying is ingly dem onstrates that time binding does not work oa
that it relieves feelings of depression (Bellenger and well. Mischel et al. ( 1972) found that instructing sub- de
Korgaonkar 1980). Entitlement offers t he consu mer jects to thin k about delayed rewards while waiting for d
the argument that “you do not deserve to feel them made subjects less willing to delay gratification. fro
A n increasing unwillingness to delay gratification is m
miserable; buy it and cheer yoursc If u p.” En- iitlement htt
sometimes is supplemented with a “greed- is-good” especially like1 y when delayed-reward objects are sim- ps
rationale. During the G ildcd Age ( I 860- 1900), some ilar to immediate-reward objects (e.g., both are con- ://
social commentators argued that con- spicuous sum m at o ry objects; Misc hcl and Baker 1975). ac
consumption offered positive benefits by en- couraging What accou rrts for ltte limited efi’ectiveness of ad
time binding (as opposed to pleasure management, e
seir-help behavior in thc middle class, a class that was mi
fueled by the social emulation motive (Muson 1951 ). which docs seem to be effective)? One reason may be c.
Entitlcmcnt may provide on ex’en more potent ra- that virtually all delay-of-gratification research has ou
tionalization for purchasc when it is coupled with so- used child subjects. a population with limited. if any, p.
cial Com parison, w hich, as mentioned earlier, can plca- surc-managc ment intuition or st ills. A n other co
cre- ate impatience by increasing proximity to the possi- bility is ihat, even though focusing on the m/
delayed ob- ject makes the benefits associated wilh jcr
product. The basic argument here is that, not only do /ar
you de- serve to be compensated ror your good deeds waiting more salient, it may also inad vcrtently ticl
or hard- ships, but, in addition, since “everybody else increase proximity. which, in t urn, activates des ire e/
is doing it, you ought to jump on the bandwagon as and incrcases inn pa- tience. Thin king about how 17
well. This attitude would result in a shift toward thc good dessert will taste to avoid overcal ing appct izers /4/
may actually increase cur- rent hunger pangs. thereby 49
bottom right- hand corner of Figurc 3fi. Since the 2/
movement is per- pendicular to the buy line, such increasing the likelihood of‘ time-inconsistent 17
rationalizai ions may consumption (R uderman 1986). However. t ime 97
dramatically increase impai ience and thc propensity binding may be more effective in prac- lice than is 24
for time-inconsistent behavior. indicatcd by empirical research. Time binding has 3
been sl udied in situations in which subjects have had by
gu
Time Binding. In addition to thinking about the to rcact to a desirable stimulus. It may be that time es
negative consequences of consuming, consumers may binding docs not work as well as a reactive self- t
also toe us on I he positive benefits of delay, a tactic control strategy in rcspondi rig to sudden increases in on
known as “time binding” (Jones and Gerard 1967). desire, even though it does work as a proactive form 09
Freud ( 191 1) believed that the ability to cathect images of‘ pleasure management. O
of desired but delayed gratifications was necessary for Bundling ‹¿/’ C’n sis. Another tactic for increasing
the salience of purchase costs is to bundle a series of
otherwise isolated actions (A inslie 1975). Through
bundling. impulsi ve transgressions become inseparable
(as in a formal budget); thc influence of the transgres-
sions is felt in other areas, such as thc postponement
of more important and needed purchases. The old ad-
age “calories add up” is an explicit form of bundling.
Rather than myopically view lhe eating of an ice-cream
cone as an isolated act, a dieter may attempt to reframe
it as the hrsl in an endless string of self-control vio-
lations. By bundling eating of the current cone with
CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL calories a day for t he foreseeable future, with obesily as
the inevitable outcome. to aid consu mcrs in bu n- dling,
eating of future cones, lhe consumer may view the costs public-ser vice television ads show piled-up car- tons of
of the cone not as 250 calories, but as an extra 250 cigarettes with the yearly cost of smoking pull- ing on
center-screen. Similarl y, the E nviro n mental 503
Protection Agency requires automobile and consu mer
appliance manufacturers to display a sticker 5t £ttiRg
average yearly fuel costs. Apparen ily having these cx- authorities available, higher a ulhority can take the
penses exprcssed as a lum p su m mak cs them more real form of tal king to oneself or related forms of self-rc-
and consequential to consumers’ future well-being. in forcement (Mischel ct al. 1972). Relying on higher
It should be noted that actions can be u nbundled as authority. however, can be a risky strategy. When
well as bundled. I nslead of bii nd I ing i m puls ive acts, transgressions occur, as is likely to happen occasion-
consumers can just as easily treat such episodes as iso- ally, instead of continuing to struggle for self-control,
lated even is, rationalizing their behavior with logic individuals may view themselves as lost causes and
such as “just one won"t hurt” or “a liitle is nor that abandon all further restraint. Research on dieting
bad for you.” Mar kelers, also, may reframe the eco- (Loewc 1982) has found that binging behavior is
nomic cost of a purchase into smal lcr, more palatable often precipitated by reference to an “already-blown-
units. “Pennies a day” represents onc example of such it” logic.
reframing through unbu nd ling. Cred it-card broch urcs Rezr‹•t arid G mill. I n additio n to the material costs
that state the cost of maintaini rig a deirit ba lance as associated with time-inconsistent purchases, there are D
o
the mini m u m monthly payment, rather t han as I he also psychic costs (O"Guinn and Faber 1989). Research w
interest cost, similarly focus attention on the small size on decision making under uncertainty (e.g., All ais’s nl
of payments: these brochures di verl attention from the paradox) has found that people avoid actions that they oa
more distant problem of how long the payments will anticipate regretting (Bell 1982). Consumers may also de
last. Consumers ma y also attem pt to redefi nc purchases anticipate future gu ilt and shame. I m pulsive purchase d
so that they appear time-co nsistcnt. Sales promotions fro
behavior may conflict with basic mo rals and val ues,
m
can provide a basis for rationalization by raising the signaling hedonism, materialism. or selfishness (Belk htt
spectcr that it would be shortsightcd not to make the 1982. 1985). Consumers may worry about the con- ps
purchase. A food firm’s recent direct- mail offc r shows spicuousncss (Mason 198 I ) or fear the embarrassment ://
a large full-color picture a n fanc y dessert with the thal may accompa n y scc mingly frivolous purchases. ac
headline, “Would you throw away a ?"R EN Dobosh The embarrassment need not be public, as witnessed ad
e
Torte worth $1 1.95?” The offer increases desire by by consumers’ feel ings of immaturity when looking mi
shifting the consumer’s reference point (i.e., not or- into a closer fi lled wilh infrequently worn shoes and c.
dering results in a loss) and also pro• ides a means for clothing. ou
rationalizing other catalog purchases. Realtors are wcll- A rccc nt automobile ad, recognizing that guilt can p.
versed in highlighting the u niquc characteristics of a co
reduce the probability of purchase, offered explicit m/
ho use and warning that if one does not make an offer “it countervailing arguments. lt read, “To anyone who jcr
may get snapped up.” thin ks a Mercedes-Benz S-Class is self-indulgent, a /ar
brief lesson in self-prescrvai ion .” A detailed pictorial ticl
Hi pher N of/i riiJ'. Consumers may also invoke higher- e/
and verbal enumeration of the product’s safety features
orde r principles, or religious doctrine, in their efforts to 17
followed. The ad ended with the tag line, “the only
resist impulsivity. Appealing to higher au- thority is /4/
luxury sedan that can offer the luxury of being rated 49
similar to cost bund ling in that the costs as- sociated with
‘the safest car in A me rica’ two ycars running.” Finally, 2/
succumbing to a momentary desire arc treated as global in
i n many cases, recognition of futurc psychic cosis may 17
nature. Violations that could be considered as not hing mo 97
diminish desire in the short run. For example, antic-
re tha n a sin glc lapse are re- cast as significant 24
ipuled rcgre Is about not practicing safe sex may directly
transgressions aga inst ‹inc’s beliefs and values. Negative decrease one’s current desire. Willpower-inducing guilt
3
consequc nccs cannot be local- ized. The ba8tS of self- by
accompanied by desire-reducing fear may be one of gu
control in the higher-authority situation involves strict the most effective self-control devices since it tnoves es
adherence to rules and regu- lations. Any momentary thc consumer away from the buy line (perpendicular t
violation, no matter how small in isolation, represents a toward thc upper left-hand corner of Figurc 3l as rap- on
serious breach. idly as possible. 09
Higher authorities take a number of forms, both in- O
ternal and external. The consu mcr may pray for
strength, rely on peer grou ps, or treai the tempting of
CONCLUSIONS
self-control as a challenge. When there are no I n this article we have attempted to explain how
external consumers maintain self-control in the face of time-
inconsistent preferenccs. We have conceptualized
consumer self-control as a struggle between the two
psychological forces of desire and willpower.
Our desire-willpower model borrows heavily from
previous two-factor theories or self-control.
However, the model is also unique in several regards.
Firsl, using
a decision-lheorelic analysis of reference points, it
pr vides an explicit mechanism for sudden increases
504 inconsistent behavior. Second, whereas previous two-
factor models have tended to 1 u m p all self-control
in desire. Specifically, it shows how a nonproblematic at- tempts into one broad category, wc are able to draw
standing desire can turn into one that fosters time- clear distinctions between desi re-based, will power-
based, and combination stralegies. In particular, the JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
model recognizes that self-control is influenced not
only by environment at factors that in0uence
proximity and desire but also by the ability of tinguish between the different motives for unplanned
consumers to ex- ecute their own desk re- and purchasing. Stern ( 1962) developed four conceptually
distinct categories of inn pulse buying: reminder, sug-
willpower-hased strategies. The desire-willpower
geslion, plan ned, and pure. It is clear that not all im-
framework offers testable pre- dictions concerning
pulse buying represents ti me-inconsistent be havior,
time-i nconsistcnc y a nd self-con- trol, many of which
but lime-inconsistency and consumer self-control are
are supported by the existing lit- erature. Additional
closely linked to “truly impulsive buying, the novelty
iests of the model could in volve increasing desire by
or escape purchases which break the normal buying
using proximity to induce refer- ence-poini shifis, and
pattern” (Slern 1962). Our approach is compatible
ihen examining the effects of the different desire- a nd
with the narrower focus of Rook ( 1987, p. 19 I ). who
willpowc r-based strategies on subjects’ ability to defi ned tmp ulse buying as occurring “when a con-
delay consumption. Self-control strategies could be su mer experiences a sudden, often powerful and per-
provided through explicit instruc- ti on. It won Id also sistent urge to buy sonnet hing inn mediatel y. The im-
be interest ing to in vestigale ihe ef- fects of different pulse Io buy is hedonically complex and may stimulate
forms of rationalization on self-con- trol; however. emotional conflict. Also, i mpulsc buying is prone to
this type of research is not easy to do. Al mosi all of occur with diminished regard for its consequences.”
the work in the delay-of-gratification paradigm We feel that the bcst way to make progress in under-
(Mischel 1974) has used very young subjects who standing impulse buying is to be specific about the be-
have not been well socialized to the need for self- havior in question. Our framework may help in this
control. On the other hand, most adult consumers al- regard.
ready have well-developed repertoires of seir-control O ur econom ic-psy chological model of con sumer
tactics, especially when they are placed in situations self-control stands at the intersection of two broad
in which they know that they are being evaluated. current s in consu mer behavior research. One
Therefore. adults may not require experimenter in- perspcc- tive views decision making as ralional and
structions to maintain self-control. dispassion- ate; the other views it as visceral and
lt would also be inieresling to examine how self- emotional. Th us, the desire-wit 1 power framework
control evolves over a family life cycle in which dis- provides an ideal ar- ena for examining the interaction
posable-income levels and family expc nd it ures are between rational and hedonic motives. These two
typically negatively correlated. Because of m ultiple types of psychological processes are normally com
decision makers, the study of self-control would in- part mentalized into sep- arate literal ures. Although
volve both intra- and interpersonal con fi ict. Savings each perspective adequately describes a side range of
behavior is another i mportant research application. consu mer behaviors, neither alone can provide an
Saving is the mi rror inn age of consumption. Although adequate account of the entirc decision-making
it has rcceivcd plcnty of attention from economists,
process. Emotional factors are re- flected in the
savings behavior has been neglected by consu mer re-
reference-point model of deprivation and desire.
searchers (cf, Katona 1975). For reasons that are not
Cognitive factors are reflected in the delibera- tion
understood by economists, the U niled States currently
and self-control strategies that consumers utilize. A c
has one of the lowest savings rates among ind ustrial- hange in ciI her desi re or willpower can cause the
ized countries. Since consumer self-control underlies consumer to s hift over the buy line, resulting in a pur-
the national savings rate (Shefrin and Thaler 1988), a chase. Moreover. we have cited numerous cases in
better understanding of consu mer set f-control at the w hich emotions in 0uence cognit ivc factors (e.g., desire
micro level could increase our understanding of motivating a rationalization of the negative consc-
saving and its determinants. quinces of a purchase) and vice versa (e.g., cost anal-
Our work also bears on impulsc-buying behavior. ysis reducing a desire). Although concepiually
Although the term “impulse buying” has been around dislinci, the psychological faclors of desire and
for over forty years. few theoretical or empirical ad- willpower are by no means independent of one
vances have been made. Parr of the problem is that another.
people have used a single term. “impulse buying,” to
refer to a wide range o(processes that cause
consumers to make unplanned purchases. Global
terminology may obscure m ore than it ill uminates.
In t ry ing to dis- REFERENCES
Abelson. Roberl P. (1963), “Computer Sim ulatio n of ‘ £tot’
Cognition.” in C’vinpti Ier Sirn ulation r› Persr»ta/ifj', ed.
S. Tom kins and S. Messick, New York: Wiley.
A inslie, George (1975}. “Specious Reward: A Behavioral
Theo ry of I m pulsi veness and I mpulsc Control.” Ps y-
eah o Ing i‹ u1 Bit llel in, 82 (4), 46.3-509.
( 1985). “Beyond M icrocconomics: Conflict among
I nlerests in a M ultipl c Self as a Determinant of Value,”
CONSUMER SELF-CONTROL bridge U nivarsity Press.
and Varda Haendel ( 1983). “The Motives of W ill,” in
if J‹›/pg/r A s per I s ri/ z1/ci›fir›/ o nd n my; .1 h ti i c, cd. E.
in 'Eli ‹• .Minh iylr S‹•lf. ed. Jon E lsicr, Cam hridgc: Cam-
Goti heil ct at., Springfield. I L: Thomas, 1 19- 1.39.
A msel, A bram ( 1958), “The Role of L rustrati›’e Non reward
in N on con lin uous Reward Sit uations,” #i r ho/‹izi‹ al
505
Bull i i n, 55 (2), 102 — 1.19.
( 19621, “Frustrativc N onreward in Partial Rcin- ‹›l .I to.s‹'.s . I o n‹›i ii., cd. P.A. David and M.W. Reder,
fc›rcement and Discrimination Lear ning: Some Recc nt New York: Academic Press.
H istory and a Theoretical Fxieusr on,” Ps;‹’h‹›/‹izi‹ a/ Elster. J on ( 1977). é. I i-.i v‹•. unJ flu.• Sir‹•n.s, New York: Cam-
R‹• 'i‹ , 69 (4). 306—3 28. bridge Min iversily Press.
A us tin. Wi lli am ( 19 7 7), “Equity Tlicor y and Social Com- Fcsti nger, Leon { 1942 ). “Wish, Expecl at ion a nd G ro up
parison Processes.” in S‹›c'/o/ L'‹›mpori.r‹›n 6r‹›rr.‹z‹’ . ed. Standards as L aclors In flue ncing Le vel of A spi ratio n ,”
Jerry M. Suls and R icha‹d L. Miller, Washingt‹›n, DC: mourns1 r//’. 1JiJfr‹ d .Sii‹‘iof P.i r‹lioloy ', 37, 1 54—200.
Hemisphere, 279—306. ( 1954). “A Tlieor y of Social Comparison Processes.” I-
Bass. Fran k M. ( 1 V74), “The Stochastic Thcoty or PrcLer- f i«nun £ t•lu I i on.\. 7 (2). 1.1.7 — 1 0.
ertces and Brand S itc hing.” J‹›liriial ‹›f,\furkt’/ind R '- Fishbu rn, Pelc r ( 1977), “Mean• Risk Analysis with Risk As-
.›'‹°orc/7, 1.1 (Fghruary), I —20. soci:ited wilh Below-Target Retu rns.” Am eri‹ un fi‹'‹›-
Becker, Howard S. ( I 960)„ “N‹›tes ‹›n Ihe Concept of Com- ni›in /r’ fii'i i«t , b7 (2 ), I I 6— 1.26.
mitment,” J i»c’ri‹an ./‹›ui GUI ‹›I .Y‹ 6/’‹›/‹›y , 6d, 3 2—4fi. Frau k, J. D ( 194.1 ), “Reccnl Stud ics of the Level of Aspi-
Belk, Russell W. ( 1984}, “Cultural and Historical Differences raii‹sn,” Ns I r /i ›/‹tpit'u/ Ali//‹•f in, 38. 2.1 h—2 26.
D
in Concepts of Sel I and T heir Effects on A itiludes ion ard Free d, Sigm un d I [ 19.1.1 ] 1959), “For m ulalions rcgarding
o
Having and Giv i ng.” in .4 ‹fi n ni i's in fi’run i iim‹'r fi r - the Two Princi pies of Mc ntal Fu ncliout rig,” in C w
st•ur‹‘h, Vol. 1.1 . ed. Thomas Min near. Prox'o, U I’: As- ‹›f/‹’c'feff f'o/›c'rs. Vol. 4, New York: Basi c, I 3-2 1. nl
sociation for Consumer Research, 753-7f›0. G urr. Ted R. ( 1970), 11 /i r tf‹'ii ft‹'ñe/, Princeton, NJ: oa
t 1985), “Material ism: Trait A spcct s of Livi ng in a I•rinccton U nivarsity P rose. de
M atcrial World,” Joui’nnl rJ L.‹›n. ii m‹•i H ‹'.i thu rt h. 1. 2 Ciu yton, Arth ur C. [ 197.1 ), fo,‹t‹’ fiiiiriun Uh v. uil‹ig . Normul d
(December). 2d 5 —28tL I“iiii‹ init ‹i /iJ .Wr‹'/we i tin ‹ ‹›/ D‹'f‹ ns‹'. Phi ladcl phi a: fro
Bell. David F. ( 19521, “Regret in C›ccision Ma king under Sanders. m
U nccrtai ntj.” 63 yrrul ion.s H e.s ‹•or‹’1i, 3G S ). 96.1 —9S 1 . H elson. Harrv ( 1964). I dop/arii›n-/ ‹ v‹'/ 7’/ie‹›rJ', New York: htt
Har per & Row. ps
( 1983), “DiSappoiM ment in Decision Makin g u nder
14 ilga rd. E rncsl R. ( 1962), “I mpu Jsive versus Realistic ://
U nccrtainty,” D¿ac'ru/i‹7ii.› A e.irai“‹'ñ, 3? t I ), I -2 7. ac
Bellcnger. Danny M. find P, R. Korgaonk;tr ( 19SO}. “Profiling Thin kin g: A n Examination of lhe Distinct ion between
ad
the Recreational Shopper,” J‹›time1 ‹›f! R‹'toilin p, S6 ( 3). Primary and Secondary Processes in Though t,” N.sJ -
e
77 —92. -//‹›f it/‹’ ! flir//z•frn, 5.9 (6), 477—48 8. mi
8enz ion. Uri, A mnon R;ipo port. and Joscp h Yagit ( 1989). ti irsch man, Albert C›. ( 1977), ’f’/i‹ Nuss'i‹›n,s a nd the c.
in/‹•r‹•‹f,c P clit! ‹’o1.1 ryiiinr•n i ; /r»- (“npiyzifism ou
hc•(nrc• It s 1‘riwnyh, P ri nccion. NJ Princeton University p.
Press. co
H i rscli man. EU zube I h C’. and Morr is B. H olbroo k ( 19S21, m/
“H cdonic Con su m ption: E m crgi ng Cone cpls. M el hods jcr
and l'ropositi on s.” Ji›wiio I of .ilarL ct ing, 46 (Sum mcr), '? /ar
2 — I (11 . ticl
Holbroo k. Morris B.. John O’Shaughncssy, and Stephen Bell e/
17
t 19.90 . “Actions and Rcaci ions in lhc Consumption
/4/
“Discount Rates 1nté rrcd Decisions: A n E hperi- E x pencncc: Thc Complc mcntar y Roles of R casons and
49
mental Stud v,” .lfzinoyeiricof .'›r i «oz r. 3.5 ( 3), 2 70—2 Emotio ns in €“onsu mcr Behavior,” in R r›'‹ ore I in C“on- 2/
h4. Betl ma n, I amcs R. ( 1979 ), I n Sri/‹try glint ?’rr›‹ e.‘.i trip .s mini i- d‹•Ji i rir›r. cd. E li zabct h C. H irschman, G ree n- 17
1’h‹•- rr,r oJ‘ C‹›nii‹m r C/i i‹'‹', Reading. MA: Addison - WCS- wich. CT: JA1. 97
ley. Idol man. Rebecca 11. 1.1984 J. “A Val ucs and Li fcsi yles Per- 24
Bohm- Bawer k. Eugcn vo n I [1 h98 I ** )- ‘*F!!*! and In- spccli ve on 11 u m 0 n Be havior.” i n P‹•rs vnul thu lut•.s 3
/rrr•it, Vol. 2, South Holland. I L. Libcrtaria n . an d C no.s iim‹ i P.› r‹ b‹›/r›pj , ed. R . E. Pitis. J r., and A. R by
Bric k ma n, Phi I I ip and Run nic Jan of flu 1 man ( 1977). . Wot›d st de, Le x ington . MA: Lcxi ngton . gu
“Pleasure and Pain in Social Comparison,” in Macie I Irw i n, From cis W„ L an nic M . Ar mitl. and Charles W. Si m es
C‹›m ›o ri. on Nrc›r-c•.i'sc i, ed. Jerry M. Suls and Ric hard on ( 19 4 3). “S tud ies i n Object-Prefcrc nccs. I. The E ffcct t
L. M iller, Washington , DC: H emisphcre. 149- I hñ. of Fenn pural Pro ximit v.” J‹›iirn ul of £’. /ic'rimc•a/o/ P.s on
t'- r J‹if‹ jir. 3.3 ( 1 ). fi4-7 2. 09
, Da n Coates. a nd Ro n nie Ja noff-B u1man ( 1978).
O
“lottery Wi n ners and A cci dent V ici i m s: Is 13appincss Jam es. Will iam ( I h90). Tito’ Prin‹'i/›l '.‹ ‹›I /'.‹i‘‹ h‹›In¿i-, New
Relative?” ,la urita I r›J I’ers’‹›oo/i/ r puff Arm /‹Jf Nsj’c/ii›/‹ip Yt›zk: I I r›lt, k inchart & Winston.
I’ 36 (3), 917-927. Juh nson. Stephen. Lawn ncc K‹›tlikofL, and W i1tiam Sam-
Campbell, Cal in ( 19b 7). The fi‹›r›to›inc ñ’i/ii‹ motel //i r .Sp/r// uelson ( 1987). “tun PcopIr Campuse* An E xperimcntal
‹›.f.modern L"‹ n.s iimt r/.v n, Lo ndon: Basil Bl ac k ell. Tesl of‘the Lily Cyclc Consumption Model.” paper pre-
Chung, Shin- Ho and R ic hard J. H cr nstci n ( I 9fi*), “Choice sen led ut I he N B E R Research Program on Economic
and Delay of Rein furcement.” Journo 1 of! tlw F..‘y‹ ri - FI uct uai to us.
J ones. kd• ard and Harcild B. Gerard ( 1967), “rn‹ndo/ir›n.s
Duesenberry, James ( 19 49). int»rir, ,Sn ring. onf/ the /'ñ‹'‹»‘r of .Eni io/ /’.› i c /i«/‹›yr, New York: Wiley.
of €"‹ n.‹timc'r B‹ yu vioi’, t“s mbridge. MA: Har ard Kah nema n, Daniel and A « ’r ersk y ( 197S), “Prospect
Uni- versity Press. Theory: A n Anal ysis of Decision under Risk,” ñ‹’r›n‹i-
Easterl in, R.A. ( 1974), “Does E con omic Grow'ih ] mpro ve lii i ii’/r o, 47 (2). 36.3 — 39.1.
the Human Lot? Some Empirical Lvidence,” in Nai ion› KoiC R’o. GcolgC I *115 1. Ps)'‹’hologic’ul Emu vm res, A
mster- dam: E hex ivr.
506 Weighi, and Their Effects on Sm oking Behavior: A Com
prrhensi ve Review of the Literature,” I’s y‹-li‹›lop- i‹-al
Bullet in, 106 (2), 204—23 1.
Klesges, Robert C., Andrew W. Meyers, Lisa M. K lesges,
and Marie E. La Vasque ( 1989). “Smo king, Body Knetsch , Jack L., Richard Thaler, and Daniel Kah neman
( t 987), “Reluctance to Trade: An Experimental Refu-
tation of ihe Coase Theorem,” working paper, Graduate JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH
5chool of Business, Corne11 D niversity, Ii haca, NY,
14853.
Kotler, Phillip ( 1973- 197 4), “Atmospherics as a Mischel, Walter ( 1974), “Processes in Delay of Gralitica-
Marketing lion,” i n Add anr ve in I.’xyerim mm 1 Si›cui1 Psyt’holog
Tool,” Journal of Rrt ai li rig, 49 (Winter), 4fl—64. y, VoL 7, ed. D. Berkow itz. New York: Academic. 249—
Krebs, Dennis ( 1973), “Empathy and Altruism,” Journs1 rif 292.
Perrys‹i lit y and .T‹›‹ ml I’s vch oMg y. 32 (6). 1 134— 1 1 and Na ney Baker ( 1975), “Cognitive Appraisals and
46. Transformations in Delay Behavior,” .h›urnal vf Pcr-
sunnfiiJ' und Son ial Ps5 ’liolog y. 31 (2). 254-26 1.
and Ebhe B. Ebbesen t 1970), “Attention in Delay of
G rat i ficat ion,” Joiir nal o( Pier.en nulit y and Soria I
Ps y- chilled›', 16 (2), 329— 337.
, Ebbe B. Ebbesen, and A ntonette R. Zciss ( 1972),
“Cognitiv c a nd Attc ntional Mechanisms i n Delay of
Gralificat ion,” Jout nal r›/ P‹ re ronfiiJ' onal .Socu’al
1•.‹ - ’h‹›loy; . 2 1 (2), 204—2 18. D
K y dla nd, Finn and Ed ward P rescoti (1977), “R ulus rather and Joa n Grusec ( 19 67), “Waiting for Rewards a nd o
than Discrei ion: The I nconsistency of Optimal Plans,” Punish menls: Effects of Time and Probability on w
Joiirnttl uf Polil incl I.°ci›n‹›rn y, 85, 473—49 2. Cho’ice,” Journa/ o] Prrsunali t y and Sucial Psycholoy nl
Langer. Ellen, A . Blank, and B. Chan owilz ( 19 7g), “T he v, 5 ( I ), 24-3 I . oa
Mind less ness of Ostensibly Thoughtful Action: The Nisbctl, Richard E, as d David E. Kano use ( 1968), “Obesity. de
Role of Placebic I n formation in 1ntcrncrsonal I nier- H unger, and Supermarket Shop ping Behavior.” I’ro- d
action.” Jr›«rnnf ‹aJ f'cr.sonafi/J' onJ So‹‘inl i « d/rips, American Psychological Association A n nual fro
N.tJ'c0o/r›gJ', 36, 6 35-642. Con mention. m
and L. I mber ( 1980). “The Role of M indlessness in htt
No rd. Walter R. and J. Paul Peter ( I 9d0), “A Behavior ps
the Perception of Deviance,” Joii ryal vf Pvr.s‘‹›nalii y Modificali on Perspective on Marketing,” Journal ‹›f
and Svci‹il P› y‹holog y. 38, 360—36 7 ://
Market in g, 44 (Spring). 36—47, ac
Lewin, Kurt, Tamara Dembo, Leon Fcslinger, and Pauline O’Gti in n. Thomas C. and Ronald J. Faber ( 1989), “Com- ad
Sears ( 1944), “Level s of’ Aspi rai ion.” in Per.trans/ifj' pul sive Buy i ng: A Phc nome n ological Explorati on ,” e
und Belui vi'or Dis‘order.s, ed. J. Me V. i-I unl, New Joii rnul ‹;/' Con.vurn‹•r R‹•.s‹•u rch. 1 6 (Scptem ber), 1 mi
York: Ron- ald. 333—37 g. 47 — 157. c.
Loewe. M.G. ( I 9fl 2), “The Rolc of Anticipated Deprivation Peter, J. Paul and Jerry C“. Olson ( 1987), £: on.burner Zrcha ou
in Overeating.” A Edit iiv‹• Bc•ho vi mrs. 7, 10.3— 1 1 2, vier.’ p.
L oewenslein, George F. ( l988), ‘“Frames uf Mind in I nter- co
.MarLc'i ing .Siralc•{• y Per.sp‹ cii ver. , H omewood, IL:
temporal Choice,” Manug mvnt S‹’ic'n‹’‹'. 34 (2), 200— m/
214. Irwin. Polich, J.M., D.J. A rm or, and H.B. Braiker 1198 I ), jcr
( 1990), “Reference Points in 1ntertemporal Choice,” Th • C‹»‹r ‹' o/ Il‹ cm›/i.inn. f’‹›or Scar.‹ ofrr /?‹•nrrnrni, New /ar
wo rk ing paper, Center for Decision Research, Univer- York! Wilry. ticl
Rook. Den nis W. ( 19 fl 7). “The Buying I mpulse.” lv u rnal e/
sity of Chicago, Chicago. I L 606 37. vf L.’on›‘um er Resettrt’li, 1 4 (September), l 89— 199. 17
and Stephen J. Hoch ( 19SS), “Consuming Impulses,” /4/
Macl n nis, Deborah J. and Linda t.. Price (1987), “The Role 49
of [ magery in I n formation Processing: Review and Ex- in ldrnncrs in €’onsumt•r Re. ‹•or‹/i, Vol. 12, ed. Eliz-
abeth C. H i rsch man and Morris B. Holbrook, Pro vo, 2/
tensions,” Joti rnul /C‘‹›a› wn vr Re earn h, 1 3 (March), 17
473-49 l . U T: Associai ion for Consumer Research, 23—27.
97
Marlutl, G. A lan, Joh n S. Bacr, Dene is M. Don ovan. and R uderman, Alice J. ( 1986). “dietary Restra in1: A Ther›rct- 24
Daniel R. K ivla han ( 198 S). “Addict ivc Be haviors: Ical and Empirical Review," P.sy‹hol‹iyi‹:al Rtillel in. 99 3
Etiology and Trcatmc nt,” Ann ual R rrf‹'iv' ( P. y‹’Iiolvg (2). 247—262. by
'. 39, 2 23—25 2. Sc helling. Thomas ( 19 78). “Egonomics. or lhc Art nf Self- gu
Marshall, Alfred ( 1 S90). Print idle.i ‹›f‘ f?coiiomic‘.s, 1st Management,” km‹grit un Err›nomic Revit•i‹ I'apers and es
ed., London: Macmillan. Prof edings, b8 (May). 1 34— 1 39. t
( 1920), Prin‹’iples oJ‘ I.‹’unomi‹ .i, 8th ed., Lo ndon: ( 1984), “The 1 climate Contest for ski r-command,” on
in C’h‹ii‹e and Con.«•qtit'nc‹•, Cambridge, MA: Harvard 09
Macmillan. O
Mason, Roger S. ( 198 I ), Consyi‹’uous C’‹›n.s eruption. A U niversit y Press, 57 —82.
ited y D/‘ ñ.Té’ep/ lunol €’‹ n sum •r £te/i avi‹›r , Schit‘ter, Debora h E. and Icek Ajzen ( 1985), “Intention,
Westmead, England: Gower. Perceived Control. and Weight Loss: An Application of
McI ntosh, Donal d ( 1969), The I’oun Lai i‹ins ‹›J‘/ftimas So- the Theory of Planned Behavior,” Journal of Per.ii›nalii ¿
c'ie/y, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. and Soci‘nl P.› y‹'liolozv. 49 (3), 843-85 I .
Merton, Robert K. ( 1968), .Arm/oil Theor y and Serra I St Scitov sk y, Tibor [ 1976), Thr Jo yle.s.s ñc ‹ni‹imJ. H n Ing
ruC- ui r y rule Huma n Satis Luc’l ion, New York: Oxford
f are, New York: M acmillan. University Press.
Miller, Dale T. and Rachel Kar mol ( 1976), “The Role of Shefrin. Hersh M. and Richard H. Thaler ( 1988), “The Be-
Rewards in Eeternally and Self-imposed Delay of Grat- havioral Life-Cycle H ypothcsis,” /icr›n‹»x/t‘ Inpuirt.. 26.
ification,” Jutirnal i›] Per.s vnalil y• and So‘ial P. 609-643.
(ycholog v. 33 t5), 594—600. 5il verstein, B. ( 1976), “A n Addiction Explanation of Ciga-
Miller. George, Eugene Galanter. and Karl Pribrarn (1960), rette- induced Relaxation,” unpublished dissertation.
Plans and ih‹ Sr ruck urt t›j Beha›'i it r, New Yo rk: Hott, Columbia University, New York. NY 10027.
Rinehart & Winston.
CONSUMER SELF—CONTROL Controls of Cognition,” N.iJ'r'J‹›fng/‹.'of ftevfew, 74, 23— 39.
Sjoberg, Len nari ( 1 9d 0). “V o1it ional P roblc ms in Carry ing
Simon, Herbert A. ( 1967), “Mai ivatinnal and Emoi ional Through a Di fficull Occision.” A‹’l o 1’.‹ !cholo¿i‹:a, 43, I
23-l 32. 507
and Tommy Joh nso n ( 19 78), “Trying lo Give Up
Smoking: A Study of V‹ilitional Breakdow ns,” Addr c live
B haiii›r.s', 3. 149- 1.6.4, Consum c r Choicc,” It›urnal oj Econom i‹’ Beha•'ior ond
Skin ncr, B.F. ( 19 SG). “Are Thcories of Learning Necessary?” Oryan iza ti un, 1 ( 1 }. 39-60.
fsycfi‹›/‹›gi‹'n/ Sri u•iv. 57, 193—2 1 6. ( 19851. “Mental A ccou n1ing and Consumer Choice,”
A/n rim trip .S‹ ir•nc‹', 4 (3), l 99—2 1 4.
Solomon, R.l. and J.D. Corbil ( 1974), “An Opponc n i Pro-
and Hersh m. s her i» ( i s i ), “An Economic Theory
cess Theory of Moti valion.” N m‹•ri‹‘an Ec io ›mi‹ tr-
of Set f-Cont rod.” Bourn o/ o./ P‹›lii i’‹’o1 ñc‹inrim r, 59
y rat, 68 (6l, i 2—24.
(2). 392—4 10.
Stern. Hawk ins ( 19621, “The Signihcancc of I mpulsc Buying Tim e (I 987). “Fightin g the U rge to Splu rgc,” December
Today,” Journal ‹*{,Wp rkUI i ny, 26 (April). 59-62. 14. Wagner. Alan ( 1959). “The Role of Reinforcement and
Stigler, George J. and Gary S. Becker ( 1977), “De G ustibus Non reinfr›rcement in an ‘Apparent Frustration Effect,’ ”
Non Est Disputandu m,” .4/n ric'iin I.c‘onom/‹' fi‹'i'i‹'w, J‹:iirnal of Ex perunenial P.s t /i‹if‹›gi', 57, 130— 136.
8.9 (2), 76-90. Walster, Elai ne. E. Bcrscheid, and G.W. Walster ( 1973).
Stouffer, S.A., E.A. Sue h man, L.C. De Vin ne y, S.A. Star, "New Directions in Eq uit y R cscarch,” Journal o/ Per-
and s‹inulil; un J Svq ial I•.i ycholi›g , 25, t 5—.1 173.
R.M. Will iams ( 19 49), The . I tnt'i’iran Snldi rr.’ Ad ii ‘t- Wcinberg, Peter and Wol fga ng Gottwold ( 1982). “I mpulsi ve D
ment during ArrtiV Li[e, Vol. 1, Princelon. NJ. Princeton Consumer Bu vi n g as a Rcsuli of E moi ions,” Journul ol o
U ni versity Press. Bii.si n‹ s.s R •.ecu r 'h. 1. 0 (March), 43—57, w
Slrotr, Robert H . ( I 95h1, “M yopia and Inco nsist c ncy in nl
Wells, Will iam D. ( 1987), “Lectures and Dramas,” in C‹›y-
Dynamic U tilitv Maxim izatio n,” R‹ vi ‹ i›’ of’ oa
n ir/v‹ nu dA JLve'l i ’e Re.i-pr›n›’e /‹i 1 di'c•rli s ing, ed. Pat
.$io‹fir.s. 2.3 (2). 1.65 — 180. de
Caf- ferata and A lice Tybo ut, Lex ington, MA: Heath. d
Winston, Gordon C. ( 1980), “Addiction and Backsliding: fro
A Theory of Com pulsivc Consu mption,” .hmmal of m
F.crior›mir’ B‹'huv inr and Organ ical izin. I , 295—324. htt
Yaies, Brian T. and Wa licr M ischcl ( 1979), “Young Chil- ps
d ren's Prcfcrrcd Attentional Strategies for Dela y ing ://
G rati fication.” Joni na I ri/’ Pier.s c'nalit t’ und Swi ft1 P.s ac
v- c-li‹›I‹›y) , 37 t2), 286—3fT(J. ad
Terkel. Si uds ( 19 70). Ha rd “I"iinc.•. .4 n II ral Hi.sinr ’ o[ ter Zajonc, Robert B. (1 968}. “Social Facilitation.” in Grouy e
Gr‹•o/ D‹•pre.i.sion, New York: Pa nthcon. K5'n emit .s, ed. Dorwin Cart wrigh t and Alvin Zander. mi
Thaler, Richard H . ( 1980), “Towurd a Positive Thcor j of New Y ork: lfarpcr & Row. c.
ou
p.
co
m/
jcr
/ar
ticl
e/
17
/4/
49
2/
17
97
24
3
by
gu
es
t
on
09
O

You might also like