You are on page 1of 15

Article can be accessed online at http://www.publishingindia.

com

An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under


the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison with the
Closed-Form Solution of Heston-Nandi
Noureddine Lahouel*, Slaheddine Hellara*

The calculation of option value in the GARCH framework


Abstract
is carried out by using numerical methods, which need
In the option pricing theory, two important approaches have been an important time for application1, necessitating an
developed to evaluate the prices of a European option. The first alternative approach to determine the option value more
approach develops an almost closed-form option pricing formula rapidly. Hanke (1997) proposed an approximation of the
under a specific GARCH process (Heston & Nandi, 2000). The GARCH option valuation model by neural networks. A
second approach develops an analytical approximation for computing concurrent and important approach, proposed by Heston
European option prices with more widespread NGARCH models & Nandi (HN hereafter) (2000)2, consists in developing
(Duan, Gauthier & Simonato, 1999). The analytical approximation a closed-form solution for the European options under
was also developed under GJR-GARCH and EGARCH models by GARCH. This method is based on the characteristic
Duan, Gauthier, Sasseville & Simonato (2006). However, no empirical
function of cumulative returns. Duan, Gauthier &
work was performed to study the comparative performance of these
Simonato (DGS hereafter) (1999)3 proved that the
two formulas (closed-form solution and analytical approximation).
closed-form GARCH option pricing formula proposed by
Also, it is possible to develop an analytical approximation under the
specific GARCH model of Heston & Nandi (2000). In this paper, we HN (2000) is limited by one’s ability to first solve the
have filled up those gaps. We started with the development of an characteristic function of cumulative return analytically.
analytical approximation, for computing European option prices, This work is not possible for any of the more commonly
under Heston-Nandi’s GARCH model. In the second step, we used GARCH specifications4. DGS (1999) developed an
carried out a comparative analysis of the three formulas using CAC analytical approximation to price European call options
40 index returns from 31 December 1987 to 31 December 2013. under the more conventional NGARCH dynamic of

Keywords: GARCH, Option, Pricing, Approximation,


1
Performance, Hedging Among the numerical studies in existence, we quote Duan &
Simonato (1999) and Ritchken & Trevor (1999).
2
JEL Classification: C22, C32, G12, G13. The Heston-Nandi’s affine GARCH process has been used
by several authors, as Christoffersen, Jacobs, Ornthanalai
& Wang (2008), Christoffersen, Dorion, Jacobs & Wang
(2010), and Christoffersen, Jacobs & Ornthanalai (2013),
Introduction 3
among others.
This paper has been extended by Duan, Gauthier, Sasseville
& Simonato (2006) to price European options under two
The family of the GARCH option pricing models has other popular GARCH models, the GJR-GARCH of Glosten,
occupied an important place in the empirical finance. The Jagannathan & Runkle (1993) and the EGARCH of Nelson
success of GARCH models in option valuation is due to the (1991).
4
fact that the option valuation theory is flexible, as it can be The dynamic of the conditional variance used by HN (2000)
is engineered to yield a closed-form solution for option pric-
adapted to any GARCH specification and also the GARCH
ing, whereas a closed-form solution cannot be obtained for
processes are linked up with stochastic volatility models. other conventional GARCH models.

* BESTMOD, Higher Institute of Management, Tunisa - Tunis. Email: lahouelnoureddine@gmail.com


An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 33

Engle & Ng (1993). They used an Edgeworth expansion With: r is the risk-free interest rate, l is the constant price
of the risk-neutral density function of returns to obtain of risk, the shock zt+1 is assumed to be iid N(0, 1) and ht+1
an approximation to the European call option price. is the conditional variance of return on day t+1 which is
DGS used a similar approach to that of Jarrow & Rudd known at the end of day t. Following is the process of ht+1
(1982). The approximate option pricing formula is given by Heston-Nandi;
composed of a term similar to the Black-Scholes model
( ) (2)
2
with the adjustment terms for skewness and kurtosis of ht +1 = w + b ht + a zt - d ht
the standardized cumulative returns. This approximation
is more accurate for the short maturity options, and for the The process of ht+1 captures time variation in the
long maturity options under certain conditions. conditional variance of returns as in Engle (1982) and
Bollerslev (1986), and the parameter d captures the
Up to now, two main interesting questions require to
laverage effect. The so-called leverage effect was earlier
be treated. There is no work performed to compare the
studied by Engle & Ng (1993); as an important feature
empirical performance of the analytical approximation
of equity returns. It captures the negative relationship
and the closed-form formula. An analytical approximation
between shocks to returns and volatility, which results
for European option valuation can be developed under
in a negative skewed distribution of returns. The process
the affine GARCH model of HN (2000). It will also be
of ht+1 is similar to the more conventional NGARCH of
compared to the previous formulas.
Engle & Ng (1993), which is used for option pricing by
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: in the Duan (1995).
second section, we present the affine GARCH model
The risk-neutral dynamics for the GARCH process are
proposed by HN (2000), and the closed-form formula for
given, in HN (2000), by:
call option pricing. In the section three, we develop an
1
analytical approximation formula for European option Rt +1 = r - ht +1 + ht +1ht +1 (3)
pricing under AGARCH, using the same approach as 2
in DGS (1999). The section four studies the numerical
( )
2
ht +1 = w + b ht + a ht - q ht (4)
performance of the proposed approximation formula. The
section five presents the empirical analysis of the asset
where q = d + l + 0.5 measures the skewness of the
returns. The comparative empirical performance, using
risk-neutral distribution, and ht = zt + ( l + 0.5) ht is
data on CAC 40 index, will be discussed in section six.
a standard normal random variable under a locally risk-
In this section, we compare the performance of the new
neutral measure.
analytical formula, in pricing and hedging options, with
that of DGS (1999) and the closed-form formula of HN In the risk-neutralized system, for option pricing, we need
(2000). Finally, it is concluded in the last section. only four relevant parameters namely w, b, a and q. The
volatility process is stationary if p = b + aq2 < 1 and the
The Heston-Nandi’s Framework unconditional variance of the asset return is given by:
h = (w + a ) / (1 - p ) .
The Dynamic of Returns
The Closed-Form Formula for Option Pricing
HN (2000) proposed a very convenient affine GARCH
Under the AGARCH Model
(AGARCH) model for the purpose of option valuation.
The AGARCH model is specifically designed to
In this section we present the option valuation model
yield a closed-form solution for a European option
proposed by HN (2000). The model represents the first
price. In this model the composed conditional return
closed-form solution for options on spot assets whose
Rt +1 = ln ( St +1 / St ) , where St is the underlying asset price
variance follows a GARCH model. The volatility model
at time t, are modeled as:
necessary to determine the option’s price is estimated and
Rt +1 = r + l ht +1 + ht +1 zt +1 (1) implemented solely on the basis of observable data. The

model is operationally similar to the Black & Scholes
34 International Journal of Financial Management Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

(1973) model and includes the stochastic volatility model


the call value. f (ij ) is the conditional characteristic
*
of Heston (1993) as a continuous-time limit. Using daily
data, the prices obtained by HN (2000) are numerically function of the asset price under the risk-neutral measure,
close to the ones obtained by Heston (1993). However, and t is the time remaining for expiration defined as t =
the model of HN (2000) can be more easily implemented T – t.
and tested than the Heston stochastic volatility one.
An Analytical Approximation for Option
Although the solution of HN (2000) is in closed form,
Pricing under the AGARCH Model
coefficients for the generating function must be derived
recursively, working backward from the time to maturity
In this section, we suggest developing an analytical
of the option. Once the generating function is derived, it
approximation formula, similar to that of DGS (1999)
is straightforward to obtain probabilities required for the
and DGSS (2006), when the dynamic of the underlying
call price. This requires numerical integration, but the
asset returns is governed by the AGARCH model of
integral representing the probabilities cannot be derived
HN (2000). However, Jarrow & Rudd (1982) elaborated
analytically. To obtain this only the case p = q = 1 is
a theoretical framework to develop an analytical
analyzed, corresponding to a GARCH (1, 1) process for
approximation formula to valuate options under general
the return variance in the HN (2000) model.
stochastic processes. They presented a technique to
approximate an unknown probability distribution,
The Moment Generating Function
called true probability distribution, with an alternative
known probability distribution, called the approximating
The moment generating function defined by f (j ) = E ÎÈ STj ˘˚
probability distribution. Using a similar approach, we can
can be written as follow:
develop an analytical approximating formula to price a
f (j ) = Stj exp ( At + Bt ht +1 ) (5) European call option under the AGARCH model.

Where: Analytical Approximation Formula for a European


At = At +1 + j r + w Bt +1 - ln (1 - 2a Bt +1 ) (6)
1
Call Option Under AGARCH Process
2
Let rt = ln ( ST St ) , the cumulative return having a mean
(j - d ) 2

mt and a standard deviation st. Let mt = ( rt - mt ) s t the


1
Bt = j ( l + d ) - d 2 + b Bt +1 + (7)
2 2 (1 - 2a Bt +1 )
standardized cumulative returns. The premium, at time t,
The terminal conditions of these coefficients are: of a European call option with strike price K and maturity
AT = BT = 0 T, can be approximated with the following formula:
Ctapprox = C + k 3 A3 + (k 4 - 3) A4 (9)
The Option Pricing Formula

where:
The European call option, with strike price K and maturity
C = St exp ( Ds t ) N (U ) - K exp (- rt ) N (U - s t ) (10)
T, is valuated at time t as:
St s t exp ( Ds t ) ÈÎ(2s t - U ) n(U ) + s t2 N (U ) ˘˚ (11)
1
CtHN = e- rt E ÈÎmax ( ST - K , 0)˘˚ = St P1 - K exp(- rt ) P2 (8) A3 =
3!

1 e- rt • È K f (ij + 1) ˘
( )
- ij *
St s t exp ( Ds t ) È U 2 - 1 - 3s t (U - s t ) n(U ) + s t3 N (U )˘
1
Where P1 = + Ú Re Í ˙ dj and A4 =
2 p St 0 ÍÎ ij 4! Î ˚
˙˚

P2 = + Ú Re Í
- ij *
˙ d j .
1 È 2 ( 3
)
1 1 • È K f (ij ) ˘A4 = 4! St s t exp ( Ds t ) Î U - 1 - 3s t (U - s t ) n(U ) + s t N (U ) ˚
˘
(12)
2 p 0 ÍÎ ij ˙˚

P2 is the risk-neutral probability of the asset price being


greater than K at maturity and P1 defines the delta of
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 35

probability measure, and for all entire k Œ{1, 2, 3, 4} :


mt - rt+ 0.5s t2 ÈÊ S ˆ k ˘ ÈÊ k
with t = T – t, D= et 1 t t ˆ ˘
st Et* ÈÎ rtk ˘˚ = Et* ÍÁ ln T ˜ ˙ = Et* ÍÁ rt - Â ht +i + Â ht +i ht +i ˜ ˙
ÍË St ¯ ˙
Î ˚ ÍÎË 2 i =1 i =1 ¯ ˙
˚
ln( St / K ) + mt + s t2
U= . (13)
st These four moments are naturally specific to a given
n(.) and N(.) denote, respectively, the density and the GARCH process. In Appendix C of DGS (1999), it was
cumulative functions of a standard normal random found to have some general moment formulas that require
variable. The terms k3 and k4 are, respectively, the inputs specific to the GARCH process. In this paper,
skewness and kurtosis of the standardized cumulative the analytical expressions of the moments under the
returns mt under the risk-neutral measure: AGARCH model of HN (2000) are presented in appendix.

k 3 = Et* ÎÈ mt3 ˘˚ and k 4 = Et* ÎÈ mt4 ˘˚ Numerical Study of the Approximation


Where Et* [.] is the expectation under the risk-neutral Formula
probability measure.
To make a numerical analysis, we consider the set of
As shown by the equation (9), the analytical approximation parameters estimations, corresponding to the AGARCH and
formula of the European call option prices is composed the NGARCH models, presented by table 2 in the subsection
by a term (C) similar to the formula of BS (1973) and 5.2. Using these parameters, we obtain a long term variance
two adjustment terms for the skewness and kurtosis of (unconditional variance) equal to 0.000168 for the AGARCH
To make
standardized a numerical
cumulative analysis,
returns. We can wealso
consider the setprocess
note that of parameters estimations,
and 0.000195 corresponding
for the NAGRCH one. to the
in theAGARCH
Black andand model: mmodels,
the NGARCH t = rt - 0presented
.5s t . by table 2 in the subsection 5.2. Using these
2
Scholes
parameters,
Generally, in the we obtain volatility
stochastic a long term variance
context it was:(unconditional variance) equal to 0.000168 for the
rt - 0.5s t2 . process and 0.000195 for the NAGRCHThe
mt > AGARCH one.Typical European Call Option Prices
The application of this analytical
4.1. The Typical European approximation
Call Option requires
Prices To have an idea on the option price given by each approach
knowing the expressions of the first four moments of the as function of moneyness, figure 1 traces the evolution of
cumulative return.
To have an For allon
idea maturity T, underprice
the option the risk-neutral thisapproach
given by each price for different values
as function ofofmoneyness,
the maturity:figure 1
traces the evolution of this price for different values of the maturity:

Figure 1: Evolution of European Call Price, As Function of Moneyness,


Fig. 1:  Evolution of European Callfor Different
Price, ValuesofofMoneyness,
As Function Maturity for Different Values of Maturity

The examination of above Figure allows us to conclude that the European call price is an increasing
function of moneyness and maturity. For a maturity of six months, we compared the call prices
obtained with the three approaches. Under the AGARCH model, both the new analytical
36 International Journal of Financial Management Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

The examination of above Figure allows us to conclude greater than 0.5, there is no difference between the three
that the European call price is an increasing function of calculated prices.
moneyness and maturity. For a maturity of six months,
we compared the call prices obtained with the three Influence of the Volatility of Variance on the
approaches. Under the AGARCH model, both the new Call Option Prices
analytical approximation and the closed-form formula
of (HN2000) give the almost same European call prices We studied the influence of the variance volatility on the
for all categories of moneyness. These two approaches call option price. However, the difference between the
under AGARCH model present a very small difference call option price given by the analytical approximation
compared to that obtained under NGARCH model (the and the one given by the BS formula is represented, as
analytical approximation of DGS), when moneyness a function of moneyness. The constant variance of BS is
is less than 0.5. When the value of the moneyness is replaced by the unconditional variance from the GARCH
parameters.

Figure 2: Comparison with the BS Option Price Formula


Fig. 2:    Comparison with the BS Option Price Formula
In reality, because of the observed volatility skew, the BS model overprices ATM options and under
In prices
reality, deep OTM
because and observed
of the ITM options. For skew,
volatility that reason,
the the trading
under NGARCH is more frequent
process. When formoneyness
ATM options
increases,
BSthan
modelforoverprices
OTM and ITM
ATM options.
options and However,
under pricesthedeep
ATM there
optionsis will have a maximum
no significant time
difference decay5call
between thatoption
OTMleads
andtoITM
the highest
options.value of the
For that options,
reason, compared
the trading is with thatgiven
prices of OTM and ITMmodels.
by different options.We can observe that
more frequent for ATM options than for OTM and ITM the most important difference is obtained when the BS
As aHowever,
options. preliminary remark
the ATM from
options willfigure 2, we can say
have a maximum modelthatis the pricestocomputed
compared under GARCH
the approximation formula under
volatility
time 5
decay thatprocesses
leads to are more realistic
the highest value of than those of the
the options, BS model,
NGARCH for ATM
model. Finally,and
theITM options.
option priceFor
absolute
OTM call
compared with options,
that of OTM the and
moreITM realistic
options.prices are those computed
difference by the
increases analytical
with approximation
maturity for ITM options, but it
under NGARCH process. When moneyness increases, there for
decreases is no
OTM significant difference between
and ATM options.
As call
a preliminary remark from figure 2, we can say that the
option prices given by different models. We can observe that the most important difference is
prices computed
obtained when under
the GARCH
BS model volatility processes
is compared to are
the approximation formula under NGARCH model.
more realistic than those of the BS model, for ATM and Influence of Skewness and Kurtosis on the
Finally, the option price absolute difference increases with maturity for ITM options, but it
ITM options. For OTM call options, the more realistic
decreases for OTM and ATM options.
Option Prices
prices are those computed by the analytical approximation
The analytical approximation formula is similar to the
4.3. Influence of Skewness and Kurtosis on the Option Prices
formula of BS, adjusted by the skewness and the kurtosis
5 The time decay is a ratio that measures the change in option
of cumulative returns. The purpose of this subsection is
Thecaused
price analytical
by the approximation
decrease in time toformula
maturity.is
similar to the formula of BS, adjusted by the skewness and
the kurtosis of cumulative returns. The purpose of this subsection is to study the influence of these
shape parameters on the European call option prices. In figure 3, we represent the difference
between corrected price (by skewness and kurtosis), given by the equation (9), and non-corrected
price or corrected price by skewness, as function of the moneyness and maturity.
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 37

to study the influence of these shape parameters on the the difference between corrected price (by skewness and
European call option prices. In figure 3, we represent kurtosis), given by the equation (9), and non-corrected
price or corrected price by skewness, as function of the
moneyness and maturity.

Figure 3. Influence of the Shape Parameters (Skewness and Kurtosis) on the Call Option Price
Fig. 3.  Influence of the Shape Parameters (Skewness and Kurtosis) on the Call Option Price
When we consider the difference between approximated and non-corrected call option prices,
Whensimilar conclusions
we consider to that deducted
the difference from figure 2 can
between approximated be drawn.Analysis
Empirical This is very logical
of the because
Asset the
Returns
uncorrected price corresponds to the term C
and non-corrected call option prices, similar conclusions of formula (9) which is similar to the BS formula. For
the deducted
to that comparison
frombetween the be
figure 2 can approximated price
drawn. This is veryand The
the corrected
Data price by skewness, the difference
is less
logical important
because but has almost
the uncorrected price the same sign.
corresponds to the
We use data on CAC 40 index daily prices covering
term C of formula (9) which is similar to the BS formula. the period from 12/31/1987 to 12/31/2013. The risk-
For5.
theEmpirical Analysis
comparison between of the Assetprice
the approximated Returns
and free interest rate is set equal to 5% per annum. Table 1
the corrected price by skewness, the difference is less summarizes the principal descriptive statistics of CAC 40
5.1. The
important but Data
has almost the same sign. index returns during the period under study.

We use data on CAC 40 index daily prices covering the period from 12/31/1987 to 12/31/2013. The
Table 1.  Statistics of CAC 40 Index Returns (12/31/1987 – 12/31/2013)
risk-free interest rate is set equal to 5% per annum. Table 1 summarizes the principal descriptive
statistics
Mean of CAC 40 index
Standard returnsSkewness
deviation during the period under study.Q(20)
Kurtosis Q²(20) JB
0.00022 0.01392 -0.04889 7.59007 56.81346 4783.80558 5778.98582
Table 1. Statistics of CAC 40 index returns (12/31/1987 – 12/31/2013)
Mean
Q(20) and Q²(20) Standard deviationof autocorrelation
are the statistics Skewness Kurtosis5.2 TheQ(20)
MaximumQ²(20) JB
Likelihood Estimation
0.00022
Ljung-Box 0.01392
test of order 20 -0.04889
of returns and square 7.59007 56.81346 4783.80558 5778.98582
returns,
respectively. JB is the Jarque-Bera statistic testing the null We use the method of maximum likelihood to estimate
hypothesis considering the model parameters. Table 2 presents parameters
Q(20) and Q²(20) aare normal distribution
the statistics of ofautocorrelation
returns. Ljung-Box test of order 20 of returns and
Thesquare
descriptive analysis results don’t allow affirming that estimates using returns data on the CAC40 for 12/31/1987
returns, respectively. JB is the Jarque-Bera statistic testing the null hypothesis considering a
the normal
empiricaldistribution
distribution of – 12/31/2013. We use a long sample of returns on the
ofthe CAC 40The
returns. index returns is analysis
descriptive results don’t allow affirming that the
CAC40 because it permits a good estimation of GARCH
assimilated to a normal distribution. This conclusion
empirical distribution of the CAC 40 index returnsmodels is is assimilated tobetter
a normal
justified by the values of skewness parameters, than a distribution.
short sample ofThis
data. For
conclusion is justified by the and kurtosis.
values of skewness and the kurtosis.
risk-free interest rate r, the yearly constant rate of 5%
leads to a daily rate of 5/365 = 0.0137%.
5.2. The Maximum Likelihood Estimation

We use the method of maximum likelihood to estimate the model parameters. Table 2 presents
parameters estimates using returns data on the CAC40 for 12/31/1987 – 12/31/2013. We use a long
38 International Journal of Financial Management Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

Table 2.  MLE Estimates and Properties


(Daily returns of CAC40: 12/31/1987 – 12/31/2013)

NGARCH(1,1) AGARCH(1,1)
Parameter Estimate Robust.SE Estimate Robust.SE
1.0403e-02 5.2552e-06 2.6793e-01
l 3.2955e-06 4.2984e-13 2.7926e-01 1.1708e-14
w 8.6967e-01 2.1248e-04 6.7785e-11 1.8672e-04
b 6.2340e-02 9.7260e-05 8.8364e-01 3.6258e-13
a 9.0516e-01 1.1471e-02 4.4560e-06 2.8286e+02
d 1.4205e+02

Ln-likelihood 19759.11 19669.13


Persistence 0.9831 0.9735
Empirical z skewness -0.3584 -0.3049
Model z skewness 0.0000 0.0000
Empirical z kurtosis 5.2497 4.9187
Model z kurtosis 3.0000 3.0000
Average Annual volatility 20.3121 % 19.9126 %
Average volatility of variance 0.6917 0.4324
Average correlation –0.7880 –0.9171

The results reported in Table 2 are comparable with the Empirical Properties of Returns
standard conclusions on GARCH models. The coefficients
α, β and d have approximately the same importance as in To understand more the properties of the two studied
the existing literature. Table 2 also reports the volatility models, we explore various key dynamic properties of the
persistence, deducted from the estimated parameters, in asset returns.
each model. It is important and in accordance with the
literature. The NGARCH model allows us to capture Conditional Volatility
larger variance persistence than its AGARCH counterpart.
The robust standard errors indicate that all the estimated
Here we plot the annualized conditional standard
parameters are significant. These robust standard errors
deviation, as a percentage, for each model, that is,
have the same importance in the two models, except
for the parameters α and d. The positive estimates of l 100 252ht +1 . The parameter values for the underlying
allow to guarantee positive excess log-returns. The Ln- GARCH models are obtained from maximum likelihood
likelihood value (obtained at the minimum of the log- estimations in Table 2.
likelihood function) indicates that non-affine GARCH
model is preferred over the affine GARCH model. The The conditional volatility patterns across the two GARCH
empirical values of skewness and kurtosis of the errors models display similarities. However, we can see periods
of high volatilities followed by periods of low volatilities,
zt , compared to those of the standard normal distribution and vice versa. This phenomenon is called volatility
(0 and 3 respectively), denote that GARCH models can clustering, which is an important stylized fact of asset
capture stylized facts of empirical returns. returns. We can therefore, say that GARCH processes
can adjust well with the empirical asset returns. Figure
4 reveals an important difference among the considered
GARCH processes. The NGARCH appears to display,
sometimes, much more variation in the conditional
volatility than the AGARCH model.
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 39

Figure 4. Annualized conditional volatility and empirical daily returns of CAC 40 index.
Fig. 4:  Annualized Conditional Volatility and Empirical Daily Returns of CAC 40 Index
The conditional volatility patterns across the two GARCH models display similarities. However, we
can see periods of high volatilities followed by periods of low volatilities, and vice versa. This
Conditional Volatility of Variance
phenomenon is called volatility clustering, which is an important
Vart (stylized
ht + 2 ) = afact
2
(
2 +of4dasset
2
)
ht2+1returns.
can therefore, say that GARCH processes can adjust well with the empirical asset returns. Figure 4
(15) We
We plot here the annualized conditional volatility of
reveals an important difference among the considered GARCH
with processes.
the NGARCH The NGARCH appears to
process.
variance using the parameter values of Table 2. However,
display, sometimes, much more variation in the conditional volatility than the AGARCH model.
the future variance ht +2 is stochastic and its probability The annualized conditional volatility of variance as a
5.3.2.is
distribution Conditional volatility
useful for option of variance
valuation. The conditional
percentage, given by 100*252* Vart (ht + 2 ) , is driven
variance of ht +2 can be derived easily, as follows:
We plot here the annualized conditional volatility ofby the a parameter
variance using theinparameter
the AGARCH and
values ofthe NGARCH
Table 2.
However, Vart (the (
) = a variance
ht + 2future2 2
) (14) models.
2 + 4d ht +1ht  2 is stochastic and its probability distribution is useful for option
valuation. The conditional variance of ht  2 can be derived easily, as follows:
under the AGARCH model, and

Vart ht 2    2 2  4 2 ht 1  (14)

under the AGARCH model, and

 
Vart ht  2    2 2  4 2 ht21 (15)
with the NGARCH process.

The annualized conditional volatility of variance as a percentage, given by 100 * 252 * Vart ht  2  ,
is driven by the  parameter in the AGARCH and the NGARCH models.

Figure 5. Annualized conditional volatility of variance.


Fig. 5:  Annualized Conditional Volatility of Variance
Figure 5 demonstrates that the NGARCH model has a larger volatility of variance than its
AGARCH counterpart. Table 2 also reports that10the average annualized conditional volatility of
variance, which is greater in NGARCH framework than in that of AGARCH.
40 International Journal of Financial Management Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

Figure 5 demonstrates that the NGARCH model has a


-2d ht +1
larger volatility of variance than its AGARCH counterpart. Corrt ( Rt +1 , ht + 2 ) = (16)
Table 2 also reports that the average annualized conditional 2 + 4d 2 ht +1
volatility of variance, which is greater in NGARCH
under AGARCH model and
framework than in that of AGARCH.
-2d
Corrt ( Rt +1 , ht + 2 ) = (17)
Conditional Correlation
(
2 1 + 2d 2 )
in NGARCH model.
We here plot the conditional correlation between return at
time t + 1 and its conditional variance at time t + 2, which
is given by:

Figure 6. Conditional correlation between returns and variance.


Fig. 6:  Conditional Correlation between Returns and Variance
These conditional correlations are negative because they are driven by the parameter , which is,
Thesesignificantly positive inare
conditional correlations allnegative
cases. Note thatthey
because the NGARCH model implies a constant conditional
correlation. The AGARCH model instead has the convenient
time-varying measure
conditional of the variance
correlation, term structure
sometimes very for
are driven by the parameter d, which is, significantly maturity T is given by:
closeintoall-1.cases.
positive FromNote
tablethat
2, we
the can say thatmodel
NGARCH the average conditional correlation between return and
conditional
a constantvariance is correlation.
more negative in AGARCH model1 than t
in NGARCH pt ˆ Ê ht +This
Ê 1 - model. 1 - h ˆresult
implies conditional The AGARCH ht = Â E [ ht + s ] = h + Á ˜ ÁË NGARCH (18)
modeldemonstrates that AGARCH
instead has time-varying model correlation,
conditional displays a more pronounced
t s =1 leverage Ëeffect
1 - p ¯than t ˜¯
model.very close to -1. From table 2, we can say that
sometimes
where p denotes the first-order process of stationarity of the
the average conditional correlation between return and
variance (the variance has the first-order weak stationarity
5.4. The
conditional variance
variance term
is more structure
negative in AGARCH model
than in NGARCH model. This result demonstrates that if p < 1). It is given by p = b + a (l + d + 0.5) 2
In this subsection we show graphically
AGARCH model displays a more pronounced leverage an important
in statistical
the AGARCH property model
for the option
of HNpricing. We and
(2000),
effectillustrate
than NGARCHthe variance
model. term structures (VTS) of the studied GARCH2 models using parameters
estimations in table 2. However, the convenient measure p = b of (
+ athe1 +variance
Engle & Ng (1993).
(l + d ) term )
in structure
the NGARCH model of
for maturity
T is given by:
The Variance Term Structure
1  
 1  pThe h  h term structure gives important information
 variance

ht 
E hts   h  
  t 1
about

the model’s
(18)
potential to explain the variation of
 s 1 an important
In this subsection we show graphically  1  p   
statistical property for the option pricing. We illustrate the option prices across maturity.
where
variance termp structures
denotes the first-order
(VTS) processGARCH
of the studied of stationarity of the variance
To compare different (the variance
models, we can hassetthethe
first-
current
models using parameters estimations in table 2. However,    (h , to a0simple
order weak stationarity if p  1 ). It is given by p variance; 2
.5) inmultiple
the AGARCH model
of the long of
run variance
t+1

HN (2000), and p     1  (   ) 2
 in the NGARCH model of Engle & Ng (1993).
The variance term structure gives important information about the model’s potential to explain the
variation of option prices across maturity.
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 41

initial variance and m = 2 to investigate a high (solid line)


(ht +1 = mh ) . In this case the variance term structure
initial variance. In figure 7, we can see clearly that the
relative to the unconditional variance is:
Following Christoffersen, conditional
(2008),variance
we set converges
m  1/ 2 toto investigate
the long-runa variance
Ê 1 - pt ˆ Ê mJacobs,
- 1ˆ Ornthanalai & Wang (unconditional variance) for the two
low
models. Also, figure
h h = +
(dashedt line) initial
Á 1 -variance
Á and (19)
˜ m  2 to investigate a high (solid line) initial variance. In figure 7,
p ˜¯ Ë t ¯
/ 1
Ë 7 shows that the conditional variance converges to its
we can see clearly that the conditional variance converges to the long-run variance (unconditional
unconditional level more quickly in the AGARCH model
Following Christoffersen,
variance) for the two Jacobs,
models.Ornthanalai & Wang
Also, figure 7 shows that the conditional variance converges to its
than in the NGARCH model.
(2008), we set m = 1/2to
unconditional level investigate
more quickly a low
in (dashed line) model than in the NGARCH model.
the AGARCH

Figure 7. Variance term structure.


Fig. 7:  Variance Term Structure

6. Empirical
E mpirical performance
Performance in pricing
in Pricing and and hedging options
price at time t. In fact, the instantaneous knowledge of the
parameter values is difficult for the market operators. For
Hedging Options
To price options using the approaches discussed earlier, we study the performance of each
that, one uses the parameter estimations obtained on the
analytical approximation, developed under affine and non-affine GARCH models, compared to the
previous date. The used underlying asset price is that of the
closed-form
To price formula
options using of HN discussed
the approaches (2000). earlier,
In a first
we step, we examine the price of European call as
6 current date. The calculated option price will be compared
studyfunction of moneyness
the performance of eachand maturity
analytical , using the parameter
approximation, estimations from table 2. The second step
to the one observed at the same time and having the same
studies
developed the static
under affine performance
and non-affineofGARCH
all approaches
models, in maturity.
option valuation. Finally,
The difference, the third
between step presents
expected option price
the dynamical
compared performance
to the closed-form in optional
formula portfolio
of HN (2000). In hedging.
and the correspondent observed one, gives the forecasting
a first step, we examine the price of European call as error of the adopted model. The obtained results are given
6
function
6.1.ofThe
moneyness
option and maturity
pricing , using the parameter
performance in the following table7:
estimations from table 2. The second step studies the
staticInperformance of all approaches
this subsection the main goalin option
is tovaluation.
discuss the modelTableperformance in forecasting
3:  Out-of-sample theErrors
Forecasting option
Finally,
prices. However, we use parametersperformance
the third step presents the dynamical estimated at time t-1 to calculate the option price at time t. In
in optional portfolio
fact, the hedging. knowledge of the parameter values is difficult for the market operators. For
instantaneous < 1 month 1–2 months 2–6 months
that, one uses the parameter estimations obtained on the previous date. The used underlying asset
Average Std. dev Average Std. Average Std.
The price
Optionis that of the
Pricing current date. The calculated option price will be compared to the one
Performance dev observed at
dev
the same time and having the same maturity. The difference, between expected option price and the
NGARCH 0.6573 0.2361 0.5379 0.1403 0.7793 0.0809
correspondent
In this subsection theobserved
main goalone,
is togives thethe
discuss forecasting
model error of the adopted model. The obtained results
AGARCH 0.5321 0.3093 0.4990 0.2324 0.9759 0.2511
7
are given
performance in the following
in forecasting table
the option : However, we
prices.
HN2000 0.5484 0.3151 0.5191 0.2404 0.9925 0.2545
use parameters estimated at time t-1 to calculate the option
BS 0.6569 0.2782 0.6217 0.1894 1.1125 0.1720
6
We studied options with maturity greater than 5 days, and
7
we considered three maturity buckets, of less than 1 month, The results reported in table 3, and represented by figure 8,
between 1 and 2 months and between 2 and 6 months. relate to the at-the-money options.
6
We studied options with maturity greater than 5 days, and we considered three maturity buckets, of less than 1 month,
between 1 and 2 months and between 2 and 6 months.
7
The results reported in table 3, and represented by figure 8, relate to the at-the-money options.
13
NGARCH 0.6573 0.2361 0.5379 0.1403 0.7793 0.0809
AGARCH 0.5321 0.3093 0.4990 0.2324 0.9759 0.2511
HN2000 0.5484 0.3151 0.5191 0.2404 0.9925 0.2545
BS 0.6569 0.2782 0.6217 0.1894 1.1125 0.1720

42 From table 3,Journal


International we denote that the
of Financial best forecasting performance is when the maturity
Management Volume 7isIssue
between one2017
1 January
and two months. The more efficient approach is the AGARCH approximation for the first and the
Fromsecond
table maturity
3, we denote
buckets,that
andthe thebest forecasting
NGARCH maturity for
approximation bucket
the (between 2 and 6bucket
third maturity months). The analytical
(between 2
performance is when the maturity is between one and two approximation under AGARCH
and 6 months). The analytical approximation under AGARCH is better than the closed-form is better than the closed-
months. The more efficient approach is the AGARCH
solution of HN2000. The BS approach is dominatedform solution of HN2000. The BS approach is dominated
by all other methods. The obtained results are
approximation for the first and the second maturity by all other methods. The obtained results are visualized
visualized by the following figure:
buckets, and the NGARCH approximation for the third by the following figure:

Figure 8. Box-plots of option pricing errors.


Fig. 8:  Box-plots of Option Pricing Errors
6.2. The option hedging performance

The Option Hedging


6.2.1. The Performance
hedging strategy Where N (.) is the standard normal cumulative
To evaluate the hedging performance of our new approximated formula, ln(
weSt follow
/ K ) + (the
r + 0approach
.5s t2 )t of
The Hedging Strategy distribution and 1d = .
Duan, Ritchken and Sun (2006). We consider a call option that is to be hedged sover t t n successive
days. At the
To evaluate the date t , theperformance
hedging discrete deltaofhedged results With
our new (hedging
s is errors), over
the implied the n days,
volatility is given
that equates theby:
observed
n
t n
 t  Cthe option price to thetheoretical
 t i 1S t i one at date t.
t  n  Ct   t i 1 S t i  S t i 1   r C 1
approximated formula, we follow approach ofDuan,
Ritchken and Sun (2006). We consider a call option

i 1 that
 i 1
t (20)
For our analytical approximation formula, the hedge ratio
is to Where
be hedged is then successive
 t over delta hedge days.
ratioAtgiven
the date byt,the thevaluation
is derived model at time t . It defines the proportion
as follow:
discrete delta hedged results (hedging errors), over the n
days,ofisunderlying
given by: asset in the replication portfolio. However, the∂delta Ctapproxof a ∂call C
option∂A3 with price∂AC4t is
defined as: n n D approx
∂ C approx
= ∂ C = ∂ A+ k + (k∂4A- 3)
p t = (Ct + n - Ct ) - Â D t +i -1 ( St +i - St +i -1 ) - Â r (Ct - DDt +t i -1St +=
approx t
)
t
∂St + k∂3 St 3 + (k∂4St- 3) 4 ∂ St
3
=
 t   C t /  S t
i -1 ∂S
approx
t ∂ S t ∂ S t ∂ S t (21)
i =1 i =1 ∂Ct exp( Ds ∂C t ) ∂A3 ∂A4K exp(- rt )
n n D tapprox = exp( =
Ds t ) = + Îs3 (∂S) (˘t 4 K
k
È n d + +s k N -d3))˚ - rt )
( exp(
˘ - n (d - s t )
Ct ) - Â D t +i -1 ( St +i In
- Sthe ) - Â r (
t + i -1BS framework, C t - D S
t + ithe
-1 t delta )
+ i -1 hedge ratio is: (20) = ∂
st
S t È
Îs∂
nt (
S d
t ) + t N t( d ) ˚ - ∂ S
s t St
t s n
t (
S d
t - s t)
i =1 i =1
exp( Ds t ) exp( Ds t ) È 2
( ( )
K exp(- rt )
Where Dt is the delta hedge ratio given by the valuation 14 = + kD3s ÈÎnt ()d ) +2s t N (dd )˘˚- -3s t2d + 3s t2 -n1(nd (3-d s ) +t )s˘t3 N (d )˘˚
model at time t. It defines the proportion of underlying
+ k s
3 t
exp(
3!
È
Î
3d
! - 3Îs t d + 3s) s-
t t t 1S n ( d ) + s t ( d )˚
N

( ( ( )
Ds t ) È 23
asset in the replication portfolio. However, the delta of a
call option with price Ct is defined as:
exp( Ds t-) 3È exp(
+ k 3 + (kexp(
+ (k 4 - 33)!
4 D)s
Î
dt2)-È 3s t 3d + Î 34s) - 14snt(d+)3+2(1s-t32Ns(t2d))d˘ +2 4s t3d 2 - d 3 n
stt -
44! s - 4s t + 3(1 - 2s t )d + 4s(23) )
t ˚d - d n ( d ) + s
4! Î t

D t = ∂Ct / ∂St
In the BS framework, the delta hedge ratio is:
(21)
+ (k 4 - 3) (
exp( Ds t ) È
4 ! Î t )
4s 3 - 4s t + 3(1 - 2s t2 )d + 4s t d 2 - d 3 n (d ) + s

(22)
DBSt = N(d1)
exp(   ) 2
- 3)
∂A4  3
3!
 
d  3  d  3 2  1 nd    3 N d  
∂ St
exp(   )
exp(- rt )   4  3   
4 3  4   3(1  2 2 )d  4  d 2  d 3 nd    4 N d 
n (d - s t ) 4!
s t St
For the closed-form solution, HN2000 argued that the delta hedge parameter is given by:
2
t )
- 1 n (d ) + s t3 N (d )˘
˚
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 43
1 e f i  1
 r 
K  i *

+ 3(1 - 2s t2 )d 2 3
)
+ 4s t d - d n (d ) + s t4 N (d )˘˚
HN
t  P1  
2 S t  Re  d
i HN  1 e- rt • È K f (ij + 1) ˘
- ij * (24)
0 D t = P1 = + Ú Í
Re ˙ d j (24)
2 p St 0 ÍÎ ij ˙˚
The evolution of the delta hedge ratio,
For the closed-form solution, HN2000 argued that theas a function of moneyness and maturity, is represented by
The evolution of the delta hedge ratio, as a function of
the following figure:
delta hedge parameter is given by: moneyness and maturity, is represented by the following
figure:

Figure 9: Evolution of the delta hedge ratio given by different models.


Fig. 9:  Evolution of the Delta Hedge Ratio Given by Different Models

From figure 9, we conclude that the delta hedge ratio is an


15 approaches. The hedging results are produced for ATM
increasing (decreasing) function of maturity for OTM (ITM) European call options. The figure shows that the hedging
From figure 9, we conclude that the delta hedge ratio is an increasing (decreasing) function of
options. It tends to have the same value for ATM options,
maturity for OTM (ITM) options. It tends to have the performance,
same value forgiven by the whatever
ATM options, delta hedging
may strategies, is
whatever may bebe the maturityvalue.
the maturity value.TheThe highest
highest value value
of delta forsimilar for all isGARCH
OTM options based
that given by themodels. Only the BS model
BS model,
of delta for OTMwhichoptions
has is
thethat given
lowest by for
value theITM
BS options.
model, Theshowsproposed analyticaldifference
significant approximation
withgives the models. All the
the other
lowestvalue
which has the lowest delta for
hedgeITMratio for OTM
options. options
The and the highest one for ITM options.
proposed GARCH based models produced hedge results better than
analytical approximation gives the lowest delta hedge ratio the BS model. All models produced better hedge results
6.2.2. Out-of-sample hedging performance
for OTM options and the highest one for ITM options. when maturity increases.
Figure 10 shows the box-plots of the hedging errors, using delta hedge values computed by different
Out-of-sample valuation
Hedgingapproaches.
PerformanceThe hedging results are produced for ATM European call options. The figure
shows that the hedging performance, given by the delta hedging strategies, is similar for all
Figure 10 showsGARCH
the box-plots of the
based models. Onlyhedging errors,
the BS model shows significant difference with the other models. All
the GARCH based models produced hedge
using delta hedge values computed by different valuation results better than the BS model. All models produced
better hedge results when maturity increases.

Figure 10. Box-plots of the raw hedging errors.


Fig. 10:  Box-plots of the Raw Hedging Errors
7. Conclusion
In this paper, we developed an analytical approximation formula allowing the valuation of a
European call option under the affine GARCH model of HN2000. In fact, to have this analytical
44 International Journal of Financial Management Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

Conclusion Bollerslev, T. (1986). Generalized auto regressive condi-


tional heteroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics,
31, 307-327.
In this paper, we developed an analytical approximation
formula allowing the valuation of a European call option Christoffersen, P., Dorion, C., Jacobs, K., & Wang, K.,
under the affine GARCH model of HN2000. In fact, to (2010). Volatility components: Affine restrictions
have this analytical option-pricing formula, we used and non-normal innovations. Journal of Business
the general theoretical framework elaborated by Jarrow and Economic Statistics, 28, 483-502.
& Rudd (1982) and applied by DGS1999 to NGARCH Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., & Ornthanalai, C., (2013).
model and by Duan, Gauthier, Sasseville and Simonato GARCH Option Valuation: Theory and Evidence.
(2006) to EGARCH and GJR-GARCH models. This Journal of Derivatives, 21, 8-41.
technique allows to approximate an unknown probability Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., Ornthanalai, C., & Wang,
distribution (true distribution) using an alternative Y. (2008). Option valuation with long-run and short-
distribution (approximating distribution). However, doing run volatility components. Journal of Financial
the approximation of the standardized cumulative return Economics, 90, 272-297.
distribution by the normal distribution, we have managed Duan, J. C. (1995). The GARCH option pricing models.
to establish the analytical approximation of the European Mathematical Finance, 5, 13-32.
call option price under the AGARCH model of HN2000.
Duan, J. C., Gauthier, G., & Simonato, J. G. (1999). An
The confrontation of the proposed analytical formula analytical approximation for the GARCH option
under the affine GARCH model, with the analytical pricing model. Journal of Computational Finance,
approximation under NGARCH and the closed-form 2(4), 75-116.
formula has been carried out using realistic data on CAC Duan, J. C., Gauthier, G., Sasseville, C., & Simonato,
40 index. The results showed that our developed formula J. G. (2006). Approximating the JGR-GARCH
is better than the closed-form solution in option pricing. and EGARCH option pricing models analytically.
Journal of Computational Finance, 9(3).
For the portfolio hedging, using the delta hedging
Duan, J. C., Ritchken, P., & Sun, Z. (2007). Jump Starting
approach of Duan, Ritchken and Sun (2006), this study
GARCH: Pricing Options with Jumps in Returns and
shows that there is no significant difference between the
Volatilities, Working Paper.
GARCH based models.
Duan, J. C., & Simonato, J. G. (1999). American option
Looking forward, following works in this framework are pricing under GARCH by a Markov chain approxi-
likely to be developed. We can quote some subsequent mation, working paper, Hong Kong University of
research prospects: Science and Technology.
• The first development concerns applying the pro- Engle, R. (1982). Auto regressive conditional heteroske-
posed analytical approximation on other type of data. dasticity with estimates of the variance of UK infla-
tion. Econometrica, 50, 987-1008.
• The second direction can concern comparing this
Engle, R., & Ng, V. (1993). Measuring and testing the
new formula with continuous-time models like
impact of news on volatility. Journal of Finance, 48,
Bakshi, Cao & Chen (1997). 1749-1778.
• The third problematic suggests the development of Glosten, L. R., Jagannathan, R., & Runkle, D. E. (1993).
the analytical approximation using non-normal dis- On the relation between the expected value and vola-
tribution of the random variable zt . As an example, tility of the nominal excess return on stocks. Journal
we can reflect to the GED distribution. of Finance, 48, 1779-1801.
Hanke, M. (1997). Neutral network approximation of
References option pricing formulas for analytically intractable
option pricing models. Journal of Computational
Bakshi, G., Cao, C., & Chen, Z. (1997). Empirical perfor- Intelligence in Finance, 5, 20-27.
mance of alternative option pricing models. Journal
Heston S. (1993). A closed-form solution for options with
of Finance, 52, 2003-2049.
stochastic volatility with applications to bond and
Black, F., & Scholes, M. (1973). The pricing of op- currency options. Review of Financial Studies, 6,
tions and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political 327-343.
Economy, 81, 637-654.
Heston, S., & Nandi, S. (2000). A closed-form GARCH
An Analytical Approximation for Option Price under the Affine GARCH Model – A Comparison ... 45

option pricing model. Review of Financial Studies, Nelson, D. (1991). Conditional heteroskedasticity in as-
13, 585-626. set returns: A new approach. Econometrica, 59,
Jarrow, R. A., & Rudd, A. (1982). Approximate option 347-370.
valuation for arbitrary stochastic processes. Journal Ritchken, P., & Trevor R. (1999). Pricing options under
of Financial Economics, 10, 347-369. generalized GARCH and stochastic volatility pro-
Nandi, S. (1996). Pricing and hedging index options un- cesses. Journal of Finance, 54, 377-402.
der stochastic volatility: An empirical examination.
Working paper, Federal Reserve of Atlanta.

Appendix

From equation (4) of the conditional variance, for any positive integers s and t, we can prove that:
Ê1- g t ˆ t
hs +t = w Á ˜ + g t hs + ag t  g - r ys + r -1
Ë 1- g ¯ r =1

2
where: g = b + aq and yt = ht - 2q ht ht .
2 1/ 2

The moments of yt are:


E ( yt ) = 1 ; ( )
E yt2 = 3 + 4q 2 E (ht ) ; ( )
E yt3 = 15 + 36q 2 E ( ht )

As in DGS (1999) and DGSS (2006), some terms in the approximation formula have been dropped because they have
SQ1 SQ 3 SQ 4
negligible effects on the quality of approximation. The dropped terms are (all terms), (all terms), (except
SQ 5
for terms 8 and 12) and (except for terms 2, 3, 6, 7 and 8). The remaining terms are determined from the following
formulas:
w +a
h=
(
∑ E ( hi ) = h + h1 - h g ) i -1
 ; 1- g
2
Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ
∑E ( )
hi2 = Áw Á
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
˜ + g i -1
h1˜
¯
+ 2a w
Á Á
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
˜ + g i -1
h1˜ Á
¯ Ë 1- g ¯
˜

Ê Ê 2 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 1 - g i -1 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ Ê g i -1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ
+ a2 ÁÁ ˜Á
Ë Ë g - 1¯ Ë 1 - g
2
-
1 - g ˜¯
+ 3 + 4q 2
(
h Á )
Ë 1- g 2 ¯
˜ + 4q 2
h1 - h Á (
Ë g - g 2 ¯¯
) ˜˜

3 2
Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ
∑E ( )
hi3 = Áw Á
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
˜ + g i -1
h1 ˜
¯
+ 3a Á w Á
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
˜ + g i -1
h1 ˜ Á
¯ Ë 1- g ¯
˜

Ê Ê 2 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 1 - g i -1 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ
Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ
Á
ˆ Á ÁË g - 1˜¯ ÁË 1 - g 2
-
1 - g ˜¯
+ 3 + q 2
(h Á )
Ë 1- g 2 ¯˜
˜˜
i -1
+ 3a Á w Á ˜ + g h1 ˜ Á
2
˜
Ë Ë 1- g ¯ ¯Á Ê g i -1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ
ÁË (
+ q 2 h1 - h Á ) ˜
˜
Ë g -g 2 ¯ ¯˜
Ê 6 Ê 1 Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g i -1 ˆ 1 Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ ˆ
Á Á Á - ˜ - Á - ˜ ˜ ˜
Á1- g Ë1- g Ë 1- g 1- g ¯ 1- g Ë 1- g 2 1- g ¯¯
2 3
˜
Á ˜
3 Ê Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ Ê g i -1 - g 3i -3 g i -1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ ˜
Á
Ë
( 2
) ( )
Á + 1 - g Á 3 + 4q h ÁË 1 - g 3 - 1 - g 2 ˜¯ + 4q h1 - h ÁË g - g 3 - g - g 2 ˜¯ ˜ ˜
2

¯˜
Á
Á Ê ˆ ˜
Á Ê 3 + 4q 2 h ˆ Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˜
- ˜
Á Á ÁË g 2 - 1 ˜¯ ÁË 1 - g 3 1- g ¯ ˜ ˜
Á ˜
+ a3 Á Á ˜
˜
Á 4q 2 Ê Êg -gi -1 3 i - 3 i
g -g-1 2 i - 2 ˆ Ê1- g 3i - 3
1- g 2 i - 2 ˆ
ˆ ˜ ˜
Á +3 Á +
Á 2 Á h1 - (h Á ) 2
- ˜ + 2a Á 3
- 2 ˜ ˜ ˜
˜
Ê Ê1- g ˆ ˆ Ê Ê1- g ˆ ˆ Ê1- g ˆ
( )
∑ E hi3 = Á w Á ˜
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
+ g i -1h1 ˜ + 3a Á w Á
¯
˜
Ë Ë 1- g ¯
+ g i -1h1 ˜ Á ˜
¯ Ë 1- g ¯
Ê Ê 2 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 1 - g i -1 ˆ Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ
Ê Ê 1 - g i -1 ˆ
Á Á ˜ Á
ˆ Á Ë g - 1¯ Ë 1 - g 2
-
1- g ¯ ˜ + 3 + q 2
h Á
Ë 1- g 2 ¯˜
˜˜ ( )
i -1
+ 3a Á w Á ˜ + g h1 ˜ Á
2
˜
Ë Ë 1- g ¯ ¯Á Ê g i -1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ
46 International Journal of Financial
ÁË
+ q Management
2
h1 - h Á
Ë g -g 2 ¯
( ˜ ) ˜
˜¯
Volume 7 Issue 1 January 2017

Ê 6 Ê 1 Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g i -1 ˆ 1 Ê 1 - g 2i - 2 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˆ ˆ
Á Á 2 Á
- - - ˜ ˜
Á1- g Ë1- g Ë 1- g
3
1 - g ˜¯ 1 - g ÁË 1 - g 2 1 - g ˜¯ ¯ ˜
Á ˜
3 Ê Ê1- g i - i - ˆ i
Êg -g - i - i - i - ˆˆ˜
( ) 1- g g -g
3 3 2 2 1 3 3 1 2 2
Á 2
(
Á + 1 - g Á 3 + 4q h ÁË 1 - g 3 - 1 - g 2 ˜¯ + 4q h1 - h ÁË g - g 3 - g - g 2 ˜¯ ˜ ˜
2
)
Á Ë ¯˜
Á Ê ˆ ˜
Á Ê 3 + 4q 2 h ˆ Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g i -1 ˆ ˜
- ˜
Á Á ÁË g 2 - 1 ˜¯ ÁË 1 - g 3 - g ˜
¯ ˜
Á 1 ˜
+ a3 Á Á ˜
˜
Á q 2 Ê Ê g i -1
- g 3i - 3
g i -1
- g 2i - 2 ˆ Ê - g 3i - 3
- g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ ˜
Á +3 Á +
4
Á Á g 2 -g Ë
Á 1h - h Á
Ë
( )
1- g 2
-
1- g ˜
¯
+ 2 a Á
Ë
1
1- g 3
-
1
1- g 2 ¯¯˜
˜˜
˜ ˜
˜
Á Á ˜ ˜
Á Á 16aq 5 Ê Ê 1 - g 3i -3 1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ Ê g i -1 - g 3i -3 g i -1 - g 2i - 2 ˆ ˆ ˜ ˜
Á ÁÁ + 2 Áh Á - 2 ˜
+ h1 - h Á ( ) - ˜˜ ˜
˜ ˜
Á Ë g - g Ë Ë 1- g 1- g ¯ Ë g -g g -g ¯¯ ¯
3 3 2
˜
Á ˜
Ê 1 - g 3i -3 ˆ Ê g i -1 - g 3i -3 ˆ
Á
( )
Á + 15 + 36q h ÁË 1 - g 3 ˜¯ + 36q h1 - h ÁË g - g 3 ˜¯
Ë
2 2
( ) ˜
˜
¯

( )
∑ E hiphiq hi + j = Èh 1 - g
Î ( j
) - ag j -1 ˘
˚ ( ) (
E hiphiq + g j E hip +1hiq + ag ) j -1 È
Î ( ) (
E hiphiq + 2 - 2q E hip +1/ 2hiq +1 ˘
˚ )
Ê Ê1- g j ˆ 2 Ê 1 - g j ˆ Ê g - g j ˆ 2a 2 Ê g 2 - g 2 j g - g j ˆ 2 j ˆˆ
2Êg -g
2
Áw 2 Á ˜ + 2wa Á ˜ Á ˜ + Á - ˜ + 3a Á ˜˜
Á Ë 1- g ¯ Ë 1- g ¯ Ë g - g 2 ¯ g -1Ë g 2 - g 4 g - g 2 ¯ Ë g 2 - g 4 ¯˜
(
∑ E hip ziq hi2+ j ) =Á
2 2 Ê Ê 2 2j j +1 2j ˆ Êg -g j j + j ˆ
p q
˜ E hi hi ( )
Á 4a q g -g g -g 2 2
g 1
-g ˆ
2
˜
Á + 1 - g Áw Á 2 - 2 3 ˜
+aÁ 2 - 3 4 ˜˜ ˜
Ë Ë g -g g -g ¯ Ë g -g g - g ¯¯
4 4
Ë ¯
Ê Êg j -g 2j ˆ Ê g j +1 - g 2 j ˆ 2 2Êg
j +1
- g 2 j ˆˆ
+ Á 2w Á
Ë Ë 1 - g ˜
¯
+ 2a Á
Ë g - g 2 ˜
¯
+ 4a q Á 2
Ë g - g 3 ˜˜
¯ ¯
E hip +1hiq + g 2 j E hip + 2hiq ( ) ( )
Ê Êg j -g 2j ˆ Ê g j +1 - g 2 j ˆ Ê g j +1 - g 2 j ˆ ˆ
+ Á 2wa Á
Ë Ë g -g ¯2 ˜
+ 2a 2 Á 2
Ë g -g ¯ 3 ˜
+ 4a 3q 2 Á 3
Ë g - g ¯¯ 4 ˜˜
E hiphiq + 2 ( )
( ) ( )
+ 2ag 2 j -1 + 4a 2q 2g 2 j - 2 E hip +1hiq + 2 + a 2g 2 j - 2 E hiphiq + 4 ( )
Ê Êg j -g 2j ˆ Ê g j +1 - g 2 j ˆ 2 2Êg
j +1
- g 2 j ˆˆ
-4aq Á w Á
Ë Ë g - g 2 ˜
¯
+ a Á 2
Ë g - g 3 ˜
¯
+ 2a q Á 3
Ë g - g 4 ˜˜
¯¯
E hip +1 2hiq +1 ( )
( )
-4aqg 2 j -1 E hip +3 2hiq +1 - 4a 2qgg 2 j - 2 E hip +1 2hiq +3 ( )

( ) ( ) ( )
∑ E hiphiq hir+ j him+ j hi + j + k = Èh 1 - g k - ag k -1 ˘ E hiphiq hir+ j him+ j + g k E hiphiq hir++j1him+ j
Î ˚ ( )
+ ag k -1 È
Î ( ) (
E hi hi hi + j hi + j - 2q E hiphiq hir++j1/ 2him++j1 ˘
p q r m+ 2
˚ )

You might also like