You are on page 1of 28

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at:


https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228270025

The Selectiveness of the


Entrepreneurial Process

Article in Journal of Small Business Management · January 2012


DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-627X.2011.00346.x

CITATIONS READS

27 412

3 authors, including:

Rolf Sternberg Heiko Stüber


Leibniz Universität Hann… Friedrich-Alexander-Univ…
131 PUBLICATIONS 2,492 19 PUBLICATIONS 103
CITATIONS CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Rolf Sternberg on 18 December 2016.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Journal of Small Business Management 2012 50(1), pp. 105–131

The Selectiveness of the Entrepreneurial Process


by Udo Brixy, Rolf Sternberg, and Heiko Stüber

jsbm_346 105..131

This paper focuses on the phase before a firm is founded. Based upon cross-
sectional data from the German section of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, the
specific aims of the paper are to shed some light on the selection that takes place
during the entrepreneurial process and to explain empirically the demographic and
cognitive characteristics of (potential) entrepreneurs. The results reveal significant
differences between common determinants of the different phases of the entrepre-
neurial process.

social processes, the entrepreneurial


Introduction process is selective. Selectivity as such is
The characteristics of the venture cre- nothing to worry about as long as its
ation process belong to the most relevant results are, for instance, that the indi-
topics of current nascent entrepreneur- viduals who drop out are those whose
ship (entrepreneurs that are under way ideas and concepts are not sound
to start a firm) research (for an overview enough. However, it is well known that
see Davidsson 2006). There are two main selection can be inefficient or even dis-
reasons why it is important to analyze criminatory. For example, in every
the entrepreneurial process. First, if country, males are more likely to become
potentially successful entrepreneurs entrepreneurs (e.g., Bosma and Levie
drop out at certain thresholds during this 2010). Therefore, the question arises as
process, the achievable number of new to when discrimination or segregation
firms is reduced. Second, like many other takes place: at some threshold during the

Udo Brixy is Senior Researcher in the Department of Regional Labour Markets at the
Institute for Employment Research, Nuremberg, Germany and in the Department of Geography
at the Ludwig-Maximilians University of Munich.
Rolf Sternberg is Full Professor of Economic Geography in the Institute of Economic and
Cultural Geography at the University of Hannover.
Heiko Stüber is Researcher in the Department of Regional Labour Markets and in the
Department of Institutions and Macroeconomic Labour Market Analysis at the Institute for
Employment Research, Nuremberg, Germany, and Ph.D. student at the University of Hohen-
heim, Germany.
Address correspondence to: Udo Brixy, Institute for Employment Research, Regensburger
Str. 104, 90478 Nürnberg, Germany. E-mail: udo.brixy@iab.de.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 105


entrepreneurial process or right at the the phases of the entrepreneurial
beginning of the process. process. In particular, gender and the
Entrepreneurial thresholds are high microenvironment of the (potential)
and the challenges to meet of early founder make a difference. The distinc-
phases are quite different from those of tion between the three aforementioned
later phases when the business is phases is of importance for practitio-
founded (Brush and Manolova 2004). ners, for scholars, and for policymakers.
Analyzing the process of becoming an The latter should, when developing
entrepreneur helps to identify and new government support programs
understand thresholds and gaps that dedicated to start-ups, design programs
might hinder new and promising entre- for latent nascents different from those
preneurs from starting a business and is for nascent entrepreneurs as both popu-
therefore of great practical relevance. lations may react in a specific kind to
Relatively little research has been government policy incentives. Practitio-
published so far that deals with more ners who advise nascents or latent
than one phase of the entrepreneurial nascents should not ignore the different
process. Though later phases of the perceptions and behaviors of both
entrepreneurship process, especially groups if they intend to make real
from nascent entrepreneurship entrepreneurs out of (latent) nascent
onwards, have received increasing entrepreneurs. Finally, scholars in the
attention from empirical researchers in field of empirical entrepreneurship
the recent past (e.g., Davidsson 2006; research may assess it as useful to
Gartner et al. 2004), in particular the analyze potential entrepreneurs during
prenascent phase is still underre- the pre-entry phase not as a homog-
searched. This is astonishing given the enous population but to distinguish, at
policy relevance of knowledge about least, between the three phases consid-
determinants indicating the transition ered in this paper.
from latent nascent entrepreneurship
(very early phase of the entrepreneurial Stages of the
process when an individual starts to Entrepreneurial Process
think about becoming self-employed) to There is no generally accepted defini-
actual entrepreneurship. tion of entrepreneurship in the research
This paper aims to shed light on community. However, at least two prin-
some of these determinants. A specific cipal meanings can be distinguished
objective of the paper is to describe and (Sternberg and Wennekers 2005). First,
explain demographic and cognitive entrepreneurship refers to owning and
characteristics of entrepreneurs and dif- managing a business on one’s own
ferences between entrepreneurs during account and at one’s own risk. Its “prac-
three different phases of the entrepre- titioners” are called entrepreneurs, self-
neurial process: latent nascent entrepre- employed, or business owners. This is
neurship, nascent entrepreneurship, and the occupational notion of entrepreneur-
young entrepreneurship. The data are ship. Within this concept of entrepre-
based upon almost 17,000 cases from neurship, a dynamic perspective focuses
the German data set of the Global on the creation of new businesses,
Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) for the whereas a static perspective relates to
years 2002–2006. The value added to the number of business owners. Second,
the field of entrepreneurship research is entrepreneurship refers to “entrepre-
that several attributes of (potential) neurial behavior” in the sense of seizing
entrepreneurs and their environment an economic opportunity. “Innovator” or
differ statistically significant between “pioneer” may be considered synonyms

106 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


for “entrepreneur” in this sense. This is (2006) used a broad concept of latent
the behavioral notion of entrepreneur- entrepreneurship. It comprises everyone
ship. It has a longer history than the who would, in principle, prefer to be
occupational notion (see Hoselitz 1960). self-employed, whether or not they are
Entrepreneurs in the behavioral sense actually planning to do so. Thus, the
need not be business owners; they may concept can be placed at an early stage
also be “intrapreneurs.” of the discovery phase. Of course, it
For the purposes of this paper, we should be stressed that these phases of
have combined elements of both under- the entrepreneurial process must not to
standings. We understand entrepreneur- be interpreted as absolutely strict: transi-
ship as a combination of some elements tion from one phase to the other is, to a
of behavioral entrepreneurship with degree, fluent and case specific. Never-
aspects of the dynamic perspective of theless, the phases as such are mean-
occupational entrepreneurship, making while accepted at least as stylized facts in
new venture creation the hallmark of entrepreneurship research, although
entrepreneurship (Gartner 1989). Conse- empirically underresearched.
quently, we do not equate self- The concepts used here follow the
employment per se with entrepreneur- GEM methodology (Reynolds et al. 2005)
ship, but the beginning of self- and demand a higher degree of commit-
employment, that is, the start-up. ment with respect to the desire to become
Becoming an entrepreneur is usually self-employed. Latent nascent entrepre-
quite a long process, from the first neurs are adults who are planning to start
thoughts until eventually starting the a business within the next three years.
business. The proportion of people who This is more specific than the concept of
start a firm differs from country to latent entrepreneurship but is neverthe-
country and also varies according to the less still an intention without any evi-
methodological approaches. dence of how concrete this intention
There are not many empirical studies really is. The concept of nascent entrepre-
available that distinguish between entre- neurship is more distinct. An individual is
preneurs in different early phases of the considered a “nascent entrepreneur” if
venture’s history. Though empirical she has taken some action in the past year
work on nascent entrepreneurs alone to create a new business and if she
(see Davidsson 2006; Gartner et al. 2004 expects to own or to share ownership of
for an overview) and young firms alone the firm. Young entrepreneurs, on the
(Falck 2007) has increased enormously other hand, were once nascent entrepre-
in recent years, only few studies have so neurs and have put their start-up idea into
far considered latent nascent entrepre- action in the last three and a half years.
neurs explicitly (Grilo and Irigoyen 2006; With these concepts, it is possible to gain
Grilo and Thurik 2005). a fairly good empirical insight into the
Shane and Venkataraman (2000) and transition from the start-up intention to
Davidsson (2006) distinguish between the actual start-up. A more precise defini-
the discovery phase and the exploitation tion of the three concepts is given in the
phase during the entrepreneurship Data and Method section.
process. Though the former has to do Figure 1 shows the sequence of the
with the very early phases including the entrepreneurial process. The axis shows
origins of the start-up idea, the latter the concepts that have already been used
refers to the tangible actions associated in the literature to measure the number of
with putting this idea into action—for people involved in the particular stage of
example, acquiring resources. Grilo and the process. The idea becomes more and
Thurik (2005) and Grilo and Irigoyen more concrete from left to right and is

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 107


Figure 1
Phases of the Entrepreneurial Process (GEM, Global
Entrepreneurship Monitor)

Discovery process Exploitation Entrepreneurial phase


process

Being committed to Start of business


founding a firm

Latent entrepreneurship Latent nascent Nascent Young


(e.g., Grilo and Irigoyen 2006) entrepreneurship entrepreneurship entrepreneurship
(GEM) (GEM) (GEM)

accompanied by a decreasing number of during the start-up process is based


people involved. As is often the case with upon the distinction made by Sternberg
social processes, it is difficult to give even (2009). He distinguishes between four
a rough estimate of its average duration. categories: the national environment
Some studies (e.g., Reynolds 2007, 2008) (e.g., countrywide laws), the regional
made an effort to identify the date when environment (e.g., gross domestic
someone starts being a nascent entrepre- product [GDP]/capita), the microenvi-
neur. So it is asked when the interviewees ronment (e.g., role models among
first began serious work on the new friends or family), and the characteris-
venture, first thought about becoming tics of the (potential) founder (e.g., age
self-employed, etc. All these questions and gender). As our empirical analysis
share the fundamental idea that a certain is restricted on one country but consid-
point in time is assumed that can be ers regions within this country, the role
remembered by most of the interviewees of the national environment is rather
as the beginning of the process. We doubt modest although it should not be
that this is the case; “serious work,” for ignored. The following argumentation is
example, can be understood in very dif- based upon Wagner and Sternberg
ferent ways. (2004) as well as upon a combination
of Ajzen’s theory of planned behavior
Theoretical Framework— (see Ajzen 1991) and Bhave’s (1994)
The Decision to Start or process model of entrepreneurial
venture creation.
Not to Start a Business Consider a utility-maximizing person
from an Individual who has the choice between paid
Perspective employment and self-employment. This
Our theoretical perspective concern- person will choose the option self-
ing the determinants of new firm for- employment if the discounted expected
mation and of the specific decisions lifetime utility from self-employment

108 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


(DELUS) is higher than that from paid A rational individual will consider
employment (DELUP). each region j (j = 1, . . . ,k) and, given
( DELU iS ) and ( DELU iP ) are determined his individual characteristics, attitudes,
by expected monetary and nonmonetary and microenvironment, compute
returns from self-employment and paid DELU iS and DELU iP for all k regions
employment according to the utility taking the costs of moving to a region
function of the person and the individu- into account. She will choose the region
al’s discount rate. Higher returns lead to with the maximum among these 2k
higher values of DELU. Following the values. Given high monetary and non-
theory of planned behavior, this indi- monetary costs of migration, this often
vidual’s decision in favor of or against means that a person will stay in the
self-employment depends also from region she lives in. The latter is an
three partly interdependent causes: the empirically well-proved assumption not
attitudes toward the behavior (positive only for founders of start-ups in
or negative assessment of the conse- Germany. Entrepreneurship is a particu-
quences of the behavior), the subjective lar regional or local phenomenon
norm (social pressure), and the per- because people usually start businesses
ceived behavioral control that “refers to where they were born, have worked, or
people’s perception of the ease or diffi- already reside (Haug 1995). Therefore,
culty of performing the behavior of inter- a region rather than a nation seems to
est” (Ajzen 1991, p. 183). be a better unit for understanding
It is important to note that all the the most proximate factors affecting
decisions an individual has to make entrepreneurship (cf. Stam 2007). Due
during the entrepreneurial venture to this “geographic inertia” (Sorenson
creation—from opportunity recognition and Audia 2000) and the spatial immo-
to organization creation to exchange bility of most entrepreneurs and their
stage—influence the length and the start-ups (Malecki 1997), such start-
outcome of this process. The entrepre- ups are in theory elements of the
neur receives important strategic and/or regionally endogenous development
operational feedbacks in the sense of potential.
Bhave (1994) not only from potential The expected monetary and nonmon-
customers but also from members of her etary returns from both types of
personal networks, which may change employment, the utility function, and
the implementation of the start-up inten- the discount rate of an individual are
tion significantly. unknown to an observer. Therefore, we
The expected returns from both types cannot test directly whether an indi-
of employment depend on variables vidual or regional characteristic—say,
related to the individual i (demographic age of a person or population density
variables and cognitive ones), summa- in a region—has a positive impact on
rized in the vector xi, and on variables DELU. If, however, DELU iS is greater
related to the region j she lives in, col- than DELU iP, according to the theoreti-
lected in the vector yj: cal framework, a person will choose to
become an entrepreneur, and this deci-
DELU iS = DELU iS ( xi, y j ) and sion is observable. In our empirical
model, we will investigate the influence
DELU iP = DELU iP ( xi, y j ) . (1) of xi and yj on the probability that a
person becomes an entrepreneur at
For the empirical analysis, it is neces- all—either as a latent nascent entrepre-
sary to clearly define the regions (e.g., neur, a nascent entrepreneurs, or as a
via administrative boundaries). young entrepreneur.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 109


less a remarkable variation between
Hypothesis on the males and females remains (see Table a1
Factors that Affect the in the Appendix).
Davidsson (2006) points out that
Selection during the whereas the underrepresentation of
Entrepreneurial Process females among nascent entrepreneurs is
The existing literature on entrepre- very well documented, there is no con-
neurial phases is dominated by sistent evidence of further discrimination
approaches based upon the entrepreneur once they are in the process of becoming
herself. an entrepreneur. The above-mentioned
In recent years, this literature has reasons why women are less likely to try
undergone a fundamental shift away from to found a firm suggest a very early dis-
person-oriented empirical work to crimination or segregation. To gain a
context-related work.1 Even within deeper insight into the differences, sepa-
the person-oriented entrepreneurship rate estimations were conducted for
research, a trend away from pure demo- males and females. Our hypotheses 1
graphic characteristics like gender and and 2 are the following:
age to cognitive, affective, and attitude-
related aspects cannot be overlooked.
H1a: Already latent nascent entrepre-
Freytag and Thurik (2007) give a compre-
neurs are less likely to be female.
hensive overview of approaches that try
to investigate the relationship between
latent and actual entrepreneurship. H1b: The likelihood of being female does
Gender and age are two of the most not differ between nascent entrepre-
popular variables in empirical studies on neurs and young entrepreneurs.
the determinants of the individual deci-
sion as to whether or not to become an As for the age effect, empirical studies
entrepreneur (e.g., Carter and Brush show a clear result: age has a negative or
2004; Reynolds et al. 2004). It is widely curvilinear effect on the probability of
acknowledged that females are less becoming a nascent entrepreneur, with a
likely to be entrepreneurs (see, e.g., clear peak in the group aged between 25
Bosma and Levie 2010). According to and 34 (Bosma and Levie 2010; Delmar
Wagner (2007), this difference is mainly and Davidsson 2000; Reynolds 1997).
caused by their attitudes toward the will- Concerning the age of nascent entrepre-
ingness to take risks. Using GEM data on neurs, it is a stylized fact that 35- to
28 countries, Arenius and Minniti (2005) 44-year-olds are most likely to set up
emphasize that whereas perceptual vari- their own firm (Lévesque and Minniti
ables are important to distinguish 2006). Age is often used as a proxy for
between entrepreneurs and nonentrepre- experience, although the two factors are
neurs, there are only negligible differ- arguably not synonymous. This is none-
ences between entrepreneurs of the two theless common practice as real mea-
sexes. In Germany, the differences sures of experience are scarce. Besides
between entrepreneurs and nonentrepre- the advantage of experience, people
neurs are striking as well, but neverthe- between 35 and 44 often have more

1
Considering, for example, the founder’s networks or the regional environment in which she
lives, see, for example, the comments on the relevance of social proximity for entrepreneurial
activities by Boschma (2005) and Sternberg (2007).

110 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


money at their disposal and therefore preneurs have to be sufficiently skilled in
fewer difficulties in raising capital. On a variety of areas.” This is in line with
the other hand, they tend to be more Davidsson (2006), who states that in
risk-averse than younger people, a fact many studies a positive influence of edu-
that offsets the influence of age and cation can be found for the propensity to
experience (Parker 2004, p. 70). This be a nascent entrepreneur; but that with
leads us to the following hypothesis: regard to making progress in the entre-
preneurial process indicators of specific
H2: Entrepreneurs in all three stages are human capital rather than general
more likely to be younger than 45 human capital are important. Neverthe-
years old. less, although this is certainly true,
highly qualified people often have other
Key factors leading to the successful opportunities on the labor market and
exploitation of venture ideas include spe- are less likely to be “necessity entrepre-
cific and/or general human capital and neurs,” a group that is especially large in
cognitive characteristics, both from a Germany (Brixy, Hundt, and Sternberg
theoretical perspective and from empiri- 2010; Sternberg, Brixy, and Hundt 2007).
cal evidence. In a recent study of nascent Yet Wagner (2008) reports a lower pro-
entrepreneurs in Germany and the Neth- pensity of the highly qualified to be
erlands, Brixy and Hessels (2010) nascent entrepreneurs, relative to
analyze follow-up interviews of nascent medium educational levels.
entrepreneurs one year after the initial However, these results should not be
screening interview. They show that dif- misinterpreted. Though a high educa-
ferent forms of human capital have a tional level may indeed be (statistically)
substantial influence on the start-up unimportant for the successful exploita-
probability of nascent entrepreneurs. tion of venture ideas—this might be due
According to Blanchflower (2000) and to the availability of other more attractive
Blanchflower and Oswald (2007), self- employment opportunities—it does not
employment in the United States and necessarily mean that a good education
Canada is highest at both tails of the is not of advantage for the entrepreneur-
education distribution, whereas in the ial process per se (Davidsson 2006;
United Kingdom the low skilled are less Gimeno et al. 1997).
likely to be self-employed. Results for Thus, the following hypotheses are
Germany show a pattern like that in the proposed:
United Kingdom: nascent entrepreneurs
are more highly educated on average H3a: Medium and high education levels
than the adult population as a whole raise the propensity to be a latent
(Lückgen et al. 2006; Wagner and Stern- nascent entrepreneur.
berg 2004). Parker (2004) points out that
the outcome of variables concerning the H3b: The involvement of highly educated
formal qualification level tends to be individuals decreases during the
positive in cross-section analysis. process.
However, he acknowledges the fact that
the skills that make a successful entre- Examining motivations and percep-
preneur are not necessarily associated tions, Arenius and Minniti (2005) show
with formal qualifications. As Lazear that nascent entrepreneurs, young entre-
(2005, p. 676) points out, entrepreneurs preneurs, and more established entrepre-
are more often the “jack of all trades” neurs are much more likely to respond
type. This means that they need not “nec- affirmatively to questions about percep-
essarily [be] superb at anything, entre- tual variables than respondents who are

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 111


not active in starting or managing a busi- and argues that entrepreneurship is pri-
ness. They also show significant differ- marily a “regional event.”
ences between young entrepreneurs and There is a general problem in relating
nascent entrepreneurs in terms of oppor- regional or macro-evidence to personal
tunity perception (more positive for (micro) decisions. For example, espe-
nascent entrepreneurs), but no differ- cially in Germany becoming unemployed
ences between the entrepreneurial stages is a stimulus to become self-employed
for confidence in one’s skills or fear of (Bergmann and Sternberg 2007; Stern-
failure and knowing other entrepre- berg, Brixy, and Hundt 2007). On the
neurs. Using 2001 GEM data for 18 coun- macroscale, the regional unemployment
tries, Koellinger, Minniti, and Schade rate, however, is more or less an indica-
(2007) confirm this result but show that tor of regional economic performance.
the confidence associated with one’s Therefore, it makes a big difference on
own skills and ability declines as more which scale the variable “unemploy-
experienced entrepreneurs are ment” is considered in the model. In our
considered—thus, differences occur model, we could only use the regional
between the phases of the entrepreneur- unemployment rate, as individual infor-
ial process. Thus, the following hypoth- mation is not asked for in a consistent
eses are proposed: way between different years of GEM.
Rising regional unemployment is
H4: The willingness to trust one’s skills accompanied by declining demand,
and to take risks is higher for entre- which reduces the prospects for newly
preneurs in all three stages compared founded firms. Therefore, we try to
with nonentrepreneurs. exclude this part of the explanation by
also including the development of the
Factors regarding the regional envi- regional GDP per head. That leads us to
ronment gained in importance more the following hypotheses:
recently when scholars tried to explain
an individual’s propensity to start a firm H5a: Growing regional unemployment
or to explain a firm’s growth.2 Most of increases entrepreneurial activity.
these research activities, however, do not
explicitly cover the process character of H5b: A growing GDP per head increases
entrepreneurship but are based upon entrepreneurial activity.
cross-sectional entrepreneurship data
and meso- or even macrolevel data for Data and Method
the independent regional variables (see Ideally, the entrepreneurial process is
Falck 2007; Fritsch, Brixy, and Falck analyzed using panel data. In this case, it
2006 for rare exceptions). The empirical would be possible to analyze the reasons
evidence is clear for most of the regions for attrition between the different stages.
and countries studied: irrespective of dif- This is of particular importance for time-
ferences embodied in the individual variant variables that can change during
herself, there are strong regional impacts the process at the individual level, such
on an individual’s propensity to start a as education. Though we accept Davids-
firm. Feldman (2001) goes even further son’s (2006) argument that panel studies

2
See Audretsch and Fritsch (2002), Bade and Nerlinger (1999), Brixy and Grotz (2007), Falck
(2007), Fritsch and Mueller (2004), Fritsch and Schmude (2006), and Sternberg and Rocha
(2007) on German regions or Acs and Armington (2004), Braunerhjelm and Borgmann (2004),
and Bosma (2009) for regions in other countries.

112 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Table 1
The Number of Interviews of the German Global
Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) (2002–2006) Used in
the Estimations
Total Latent Nascent Nascent Young Nonentrepreneurs
Interviews Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs
Used

2002 8,092 441 257 239 7,155


2003 2,566 303 173 164 1,926
2004 2,020 192 121 141 1,566
2005 2,672 274 175 175 2,048
2006 1,588 143 84 78 1,283
Total 16,938 1,353 810 797 13,978

Data source: Adult Population Survey of the GEM, Germany.

like the Panel Study of Entrepreneurial assembled to facilitate cross-national


Dynamics are generally more appropri- comparisons of the level of national
ate for covering the dynamic process of entrepreneurial activity, by pooling the
entrepreneurship, we think that our data for five successive years, we are
concept is a possible alternative in view able to generate a large micro-data set on
of the lack of panel data for Germany so German entrepreneurship.
far. We use cross-sectional data that are As Table 1 shows, it was possible to
based on different people for each state. use almost 17,000 interviews. We distin-
We are therefore unable to disentangle guish between three different types of
learning and selection effects and have to entrepreneurial activity: latent nascent
assume that there are no or at least only entrepreneurs, nascent entrepreneurs,
minor cohort effects or calendar-time and young entrepreneurs.
effects. However, we are still able to gain Latent nascent entrepreneurs are
valuable empirical insights into the adults (18–64 years old) who are plan-
dynamic aspects of the entrepreneurial ning to start a business within the next
process. three years. This is more specific than
The cross-sectional data of the GEM, the concept of latent entrepreneurship
which have been gathered annually since from Grilo and Irigoyen (2006) but is
1999, allow such analyses for Germany. nevertheless still an intention without
As important variables were defined dif- any evidence of how concrete this inten-
ferently in the early years, we only make tion really is.
use of data collected from 2002 until The concept of nascent entrepreneur-
2006. Every year, a random household ship is more distinct and it is already well
telephone sample is drawn and, using established in the literature (e.g., Davids-
the “last birthday” method, anyone son 2006; Lückgen et al. 2006; Reynolds
between 18 and 64 is interviewed. The et al. 2004). An individual (18–64 years
computer-aided telephone interviews are of age) is considered a “nascent entre-
conducted by a professional survey preneur” on the basis of three conditions
vendor. Although the data have been all of which must be satisfied: first, she

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 113


has done something—taken some new business started by someone else.
action—in the past year to create a new We also excluded intrapreneurs, persons
business; second, she expects to own or who declared to start a business for their
to share ownership of the new firm; and, employer and will not own (part of) the
third, the firm has not yet paid salaries business. Therefore, we tried to avoid
and wages for more than three months. the “holiday makers” trap, as mentioned
Young entrepreneurs, on the other by Davidsson (2006).
hand, were once nascent entrepreneurs Besides the questions that are neces-
and have put their start-up idea into sary to classify the interviewees into the
action in the recent past. They are four groups, the survey includes ques-
defined as follows: in cases where the tions about the basic demography, one
firm already exists and the interviewee is question about the household income,
the owner or part-owner and she has one question about whether the inter-
paid salaries and wages for more than viewees know someone who has started
three months but less than three and a a business in the last two years, one
half years, it is classified as a “new busi- question about how they perceive the
ness” and the individual is classified as a economic situation for setting up a busi-
“young entrepreneur.”3 ness, and one question about the willing-
The states as defined in the GEM are ness to take risks.
obviously nonexclusive, which means We assign available empirical informa-
that a person can be in more than one tion to three groups of indicators: demo-
stage. This is by definition the case with graphic characteristics of the (potential)
latent nascent entrepreneurs and nascent entrepreneur, cognitive characteristics of
entrepreneurs. Nascent entrepreneurs the (potential) entrepreneur, and charac-
who want to found a firm within the next teristics of the region where the (poten-
six months also belong, in principle, to tial) entrepreneur lives. The precise
the group of latent nascent entrepreneurs. information about the independent vari-
The same applies for young entrepre- ables is shown in Table 2. The distribu-
neurs who are already planning their next tion of age, gender, and household
business. Because the estimated multino- income (Tables A2 and A3) as well as the
mial models cannot deal with one person wording of the questions can be found in
being in more than one single state, we the Appendix.
decided that young entrepreneurship is More methodological details on the
considered over nascent entrepreneur- GEM attempt are described by Reynolds
ship and nascent entrepreneurship over et al. (2005). Davidsson (2006) provides
latent nascent entrepreneurship. This a valuable assessment of GEM data for
ranking follows the idea of the growing the purpose of research into nascent
certainty of the three states. The flowchart entrepreneurship.
(Figure 2) gives the exact definition of the
entrepreneurial phases we used in our The Statistical Model
multivariate setting. GEM data are used to estimate multi-
Nonentrepreneurs are persons who nomial probit models for explaining the
state that they never planned or owned a propensity to be a latent nascent entre-
business and never provided funds for a preneur, a nascent entrepreneur, or a

3
In literature based upon GEM data the businesses of these young entrepreneurs are often
called “baby businesses.” As this paper focuses on the individuals (and not their businesses) the
term young entrepreneurs seems to be appropriate. However, the definition is the same for
both terms.

114 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Figure 2
Flowchart for the Assignment of an Exclusive Entrepreneurial State
Wording of the questions for the assignment of a exclusive entrepreneurial state6

q1a: You are, alone or with others, currently the owner of a company you help manage,
self-employed, or selling any goods or services to others.
q1b: Do you personally own all, part, or none of this business?
q1c: What was the first year the founders of the business received wages, profits, or
payments in kind from this business?
q2a: You are, alone or with others, currently trying to start a new business, including any
self-employment or selling any goods or services to others.
q2b: You are, alone or with others, currently trying to start a new business or a new
venture for your employer—an effort that is part of your normal job.
q2c: Over the past 12 months have you done anything to help start a new business, such as
looking for equipment or a location, organizing a start-up team, working on a business
plan, beginning to save money, or any other that would help launch a business?
q2d: Will you personally own all, part, or none of this business?
q2e: Has the new business paid any salaries, wages, or payments in kind, including your
own, for more than three months?
q3a: You are, alone or with others, expecting to start a new business, including any type of
self-employment, within the next three years.
q4a: You are, alone or with others, currently trying to start a new business or a new
venture for your employer—an effort that is part of your normal work.
q4b: You are, alone or with others, currently the owner of a company you help manage,
self-employed, or selling any goods or services to others.
q4c: You have, in the past three years, personally provided funds for a new business
started by someone else, excluding any purchases of stocks or mutual funds.
q4d: You have, in the past 12 month, sold, shut down, discontinued, or quit a business you
owned and managed, any form of self-employed, or selling goods or services to anyone.

6
Our screening for entrepreneurial states differs slightly from the one use by GEM. The GEM
screening is described by Reynolds et al. (2005, pp. 214–215).

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 115


young entrepreneur or not to be neurs right from the start. Nevertheless,
involved in any kind of entrepreneur- the magnitude of the influence of some
ship. We estimated robust standard variables varies considerably across the
errors and included dummies for years three entrepreneurial stages.
(these are not reported in the tables for The probability of a woman being an
better clarity) and clustered for NUTS III entrepreneur is lower at every stage but
regions (NUTS is the abbreviation for the is especially low for latent nascent entre-
French “Nomenclature des Unités Terri- preneurs. Women are still less likely than
toriales de Statistique” [Nomenclature of men to even think about becoming an
Territorial Units for Statistics]. This entrepreneur (H1a). However, in later
geocode standard has been developed by stages the coefficient is lower than at the
the European Union and it shows the beginning of the process. This is a sign
subdivisions of EU countries for statisti- that, once in the process, women tend to
cal purposes).4 All of the interviewees proceed to start a firm more often than
are assigned to a single state: latent men, which confirms the results of
nascent entrepreneurship, nascent entre- Davidsson (2006) as well as Menzies
preneurship, young entrepreneurship, et al. (2006) who also could not find any
or—the large majority—no entrepreneur- differences across gender regarding the
ship at all. characteristics and the length of the
By comparing the results of our esti- start-up process. The likelihood of being
mates for the three entrepreneurial female does hardly differ between
stages, we try to determine whether the nascent entrepreneurs and young entre-
influence of the independent variables preneurs (H1b) confirming the results of
varies at different stages during the entre- Alsos and Ljunggren (1998) that some
preneurial process. For example, educa- gender differences in the entrepreneur-
tion might have no influence on the ship process exist, but not in getting
probability of being interested in starting operational. Our gender-related empiri-
a firm—but could be important for those cal result sheds light on an important
who do actually set up their own firm. new aspect of gender differences and
goes beyond the generally accepted evi-
Results and Discussion dence that men are more often engaged
The results (see Tables 3–5) show that in start-ups than women (see, e.g.,
entrepreneurs at all three stages have a Delmar and Davidsson 2000). The
great deal in common compared with reasons for gender differences before
nonentrepreneurs. However, there are even thinking about becoming an entre-
also considerable differences between the preneur seem not to be related to the real
entrepreneurial phases. This result is in life of entrepreneurs but to the female-
line with the majority of empirical studies specific perceptions of entrepreneurial
comparing (nascent) entrepreneurs with activities (Wagner 2007). The origins of
the general population (see Davidsson these gender-specific attitudes and per-
and Gordon 2009). Many of the differ- ceptions should be searched in far earlier
ences already emerge right at the begin- times of an individual’s life than the con-
ning of the entrepreneurial process. So crete decision in favor or against starting
entrepreneurs differ from nonentrepre- a firm. They are associated with the indi-

4
Because we included two regional variables (development of GDP and unemployment) it is
necessary to relax the assumption of independence within groups. We used stata 10 command:
“mprobit . . . , robust.” To calculate the marginal effects we used the command “mfx compute,
predict (. . .).”

116 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Table 2
List of the Independent Variables
Variables Description and Calculation Source

Demographic Characteristics
Age Dummy with five categories: GEM
1: 18–24 (reference group)
2: 25–34
3: 35–44
4: 45–54
5: 55–64
Gender Dummy (female = 1) GEM
Human Capital
Education Dummy with four categories: GEM
1: lower secondary school
(reference)
2: intermediate secondary school
3: upper secondary school
4: university degree
Income Monthly household income in € GEM
Dummy with four classes:
1: <1,000 (reference)
2: 1,000–2,000
3: 2,000–3,000
4: >3,000
Cognitive Characteristics
Fear of failure* Dummy (high/low) high = 1 GEM
Opportunity recognition* Dummy (yes/no) yes = 1 GEM
Social networks* Dummy (yes/no) yes = 1 GEM
Regional Characteristics
Development of GDP Difference of GDP per capita Federal Statistical
2002–2006 (NUTS III-level) Office
Development of Difference of unemployment rate Statistics of the
unemployment 2002–2006 (NUTS III level) Federal Labour
Agency
Control Variables
Interviewee lives in East or Dummy East = 1
West Germany
Year of observation Dummy for each year GEM

*Exact wording of the questions for the cognitive characteristic variables:


• You know someone personally who started a business in the past two years.
• In the next six month there will be good opportunities for starting a business in
the area where you live.
• Fear of failure would prevent you from starting a business.
GDP, gross domestic product; GEM, Global Entrepreneurship Monitor; NUTS III,
Nomenclature des Unités Territoriales de Statistique.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 117


Table 3

118
Estimates of the Propensity to Be a Latent Nascent Entrepreneur, a Nascent
Entrepreneur, or a Young Entrepreneur (Multinomial Probit Results)
Latent Nascent Nascent Young
Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs

dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z|

Age: (reference: age 18–24)


25–34* -0.008 0.242 0.009 0.122 0.028 0.000
35–44* -0.018 0.001 0.012 0.026 0.025 0.000
45–54* -0.030 0.000 0.004 0.402 0.017 0.014
55–64* -0.057 0.000 -0.020 0.000 -0.014 0.001
Education: (reference: lower secondary school)
Intermediate secondary school* 0.005 0.362 0.006 0.141 -0.004 0.255
Upper secondary school* 0.016 0.012 0.011 0.020 0.007 0.090
University degree* 0.022 0.001 0.013 0.007 0.012 0.008
Monthly income in €: (reference: <1,000)
1,000–2,000* -0.027 0.000 -0.007 0.145 0.001 0.804
2,000–3,000* -0.030 0.000 -0.008 0.083 0.005 0.440
>3,000* -0.025 0.001 -0.006 0.246 0.019 0.004
Gender (reference: male)* -0.018 0.000 -0.011 0.000 -0.013 0.000
Development GDP/pc (ln) 2002–2004 0.611 0.475 -0.763 0.338 -0.713 0.238
Development unemployment 2002–2006 0.970 0.007 0.058 0.817 0.049 0.825
East Germany* 0.008 0.290 0.003 0.531 0.004 0.213
Fear of failure (high = 1)* -0.054 0.000 -0.036 0.000 -0.041 0.000

JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Opportunity recognition (yes = 1)* 0.043 0.000 0.036 0.000 0.020 0.000
Social networks (yes = 1)* 0.062 0.000 0.046 0.000 0.035 0.000

Notes: The estimation method is multinomial probit; standard errors are robust; *dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1 dummies
for years included but not shown for better readability.
Wald chi2: 2,821.29; Number of individuals: 15,286; Count R2: 0.821; e(chi2): 0.000; Number of clusters (NUTS III): 386; Adj. count R2: 0.001.
GDP, gross domestic product; NUTS III, Nomenclature des Unités Territoriales de Statistique; pc, per capita.
Table 4
Females: Estimates of the Propensity to Be a Latent Nascent Entrepreneur, a Nascent
Entrepreneur, or a Young Entrepreneur (Multinomial Probit Results)
Latent Nascent Nascent Entrepreneurs Young Entrepreneurs
Entrepreneurs

dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z|

Age: (reference: age 18–24)


25–34* 0.001 0.893 0.001 0.981 0.039 0.002
35–44* -0.003 0.762 0.009 0.127 0.028 0.002
45–54* -0.017 0.014 0.002 0.734 0.024 0.014
55–64* -0.045 0.000 -0.017 0.000 -0.007 0.198
Education: (reference: lower secondary school)
Intermediate secondary school* 0.006 0.364 0.005 0.241 -0.004 0.232
Upper secondary school* 0.017 0.017 0.008 0.087 0.006 0.177
University degree* 0.021 0.018 0.010 0.074 0.009 0.089
Monthly income in €: (reference: < 1,000)
1,000–2,000* -0.012 0.123 0.000 0.997 -0.003 0.508
2,000–3,000* -0.014 0.057 -0.001 0.879 0.003 0.566
>3,000* -0.007 0.405 -0.002 0.649 0.010 0.134
Development GDP/pc (ln) 2002–2004 -1.077 0.399 -1.176 0.168 -0.074 0.909

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER


Development unemployment 2002–2006 0.951 0.020 0.120 0.662 -0.244 0.272
East Germany* 0.012 0.200 0.001 0.743 -0.009 0.001
Fear of failure (high = 1)* -0.049 0.000 -0.029 0.000 -0.026 0.000
Opportunity recognition (yes = 1)* 0.048 0.000 0.042 0.000 0.016 0.000
Social networks (yes = 1)* 0.052 0.000 0.033 0.000 0.024 0.000

Notes: The estimation method is multinomial probit; standard errors are robust; *dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1 dummies
for years included but not shown for better readability.
Wald chi2: 1,477.62; Number of individuals: 8,024; Count R2: 0.869; e(chi2): 0.000; Number of clusters (NUTS III): 386: Adj. count R2: 0.001.
GDP, gross domestic product; NUTS III, Nomenclature des Unités Territoriales de Statistique; pc, per capita.

119
120
Table 5
Males: Estimates of the Propensity to Be a Latent Nascent Entrepreneur, a Nascent
Entrepreneur, or a Young Entrepreneur (Multinomial Probit Results)
Latent Nascent Nascent Young
Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs

dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z| dy/dx p > |z|

Age: (reference: age 18–24)


25–34* -0.020 0.101 0.020 0.055 0.022 0.043
35–44* -0.039 0.000 0.014 0.122 0.025 0.017
45–54* -0.045 0.000 0.007 0.425 0.014 0.195
55–64* -0.071 0.000 -0.024 0.001 -0.022 0.005
Education: (reference: lower secondary school)
Intermediate secondary school* 0.003 0.733 0.008 0.313 -0.004 0.567
Upper secondary school* 0.014 0.187 0.013 0.110 0.007 0.300
University degree* 0.023 0.049 0.017 0.035 0.015 0.044
Monthly income in €: (reference: <1,000)
1,000–2,000* -0.046 0.000 -0.017 0.028 0.009 0.421
2,000–3,000* -0.050 0.000 -0.019 0.022 0.043 0.701
>3,000* -0.050 0.000 -0.011 0.181 0.030 0.010
Development GDP/pc 2002–2004 2.972 0.073 0.147 0.918 -1.891 0.202
Development unemployment 2002–2006 0.940 0.144 -0.089 0.820 0.518 0.216
East Germany* 0.000 0.982 0.004 0.617 0.005 0.510
Fear of failure (high = 1)* -0.058 0.000 -0.044 0.000 -0.060 0.000

JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Opportunity recognition (yes = 1)* 0.038 0.000 0.032 0.000 0.026 0.000
Social networks (yes = 1)* 0.073 0.000 0.060 0.000 0.049 0.000

Notes: The estimation method is multinomial probit; standard errors are robust; *dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1 dummies
for years included but not shown for better readability.
Wald chi2: 1,423.14; Number of individuals: 7,262; Count R2: 0.770; e(chi2): 0.000; Number of clusters (NUTS III): 384; Adj. count R2: 0.004.
GDP, gross domestic product; NUTS III, Nomenclature des Unités Territoriales de Statistique; pc, per capita.
vidual’s socialization and education in their career, many people think about
very early days, especially during child- becoming self-employed and they are
hood. Thus, theoretical or empirical most likely to actually start a business
models, like ours, just considering the between 24 and 45.
start-up decision of adults by gender are In line with our expectations, medially
not able to detect such early reasons. and highly educated individuals are
Another plausible reason for the fact that more likely to found a business. Interest-
women are less frequently engaged in ingly, the influence of education is
the very early entrepreneurship phases greater for men than for women. Educa-
may be related to the different motiva- tion has the largest effect for latent
tions for starting a firm between men and nascent entrepreneurs, thus right at the
women. Manolova, Brush, and Edelman beginning of the entrepreneurial
(2008) show that men are motivated by process. In other words, highly educated
financial gain, self-realization, and individuals are more likely to found a
autonomy, whereas women, in addition business, but even more likely to just
to the aforementioned motivations, think about being self-employed (H3a).
expect status. Given the fact that the This observation for Germany differs
status of founders (different from the from the situation in Norway where edu-
status of established entrepreneurs) still cation predicts the nascent entrepreneur
is not the best in many countries (see status but not the previous intention to
Bosma and Levie 2010 for the assessment start a firm (see Rotefoss and Kolvereid
of entrepreneurship as a desirable career 2005). The decreasing involvement of
choice in 54 GEM countries), it is reason- highly educated individuals in the
able why women less often try to start process is a sign of selection, as they in
their own firm. particular have attractive alternatives as
The age of latent entrepreneurs differs employees (H3b).
remarkably from that of individuals We included three variables to provide
engaged in later phases of entrepreneur- information about cognitive characteris-
ship. Latent entrepreneurs are particu- tics and attitudes: “fear of failure,”
larly young—from 35 onwards the “opportunity recognition,” and “social
likelihood of being a latent nascent networks.” Each of them has a substantial
entrepreneur is significantly lower than impact, but it differs in size at each entre-
for those aged between 18 and 24. The preneurial stage. The fear that a business
likelihood of being involved in nascent might not be successful is much lower for
entrepreneurship or young entrepre- all stages than it is for nonentrepreneurs
neurship on the other hand is highest for (H4). This confirms the results of Arenius
individuals aged between 25 and 44. This and Minniti (2005). However, we observe
is in line with the results for other non- that confidence grows between latent
German empirical studies that show a nascent entrepreneurship and later
higher engagement in nascent entrepre- phases of the entrepreneurial process. It
neurship for those between 25 and 34 can be assumed that this is partly a selec-
years (see Delmar and Davidsson 2000) tion process, so those with less confi-
and with studies on Germany revealing dence might be more likely to give up
the above-average age of German entre- early. On the other hand, individuals
preneurs compared with other countries might also become more confident as
(Brixy, Hundt, and Sternberg 2010). For their plan becomes more definite. One
all kinds of entrepreneurship, however, remarkable outcome is that women are
the likelihood of being an entrepreneur more optimistic at every stage. As overall
is lowest for those aged 55 and above women are less confident (see Table A1),
(H2). This shows that at the beginning of this looks like a selection effect: a priori

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 121


only very confident women decide to the more concrete the start-up activities
become self-employed. is, the less relevant becomes the impact
The recognition of opportunities is of such role models as the nascent entre-
greater among the latent nascent preneurs have to trust on his own activi-
entrepreneurs and nascent entrepreneurs ties and competencies. During the
and is considerably smaller among entrepreneurship process, the decreasing
young entrepreneurs. Obviously, per- impact of (entrepreneurial) role models
ceived market opportunity is associated may be compensated by the increasing
with the intensity and concreteness of impact of entrepreneurial control belief
start-up activity (see Edelman and and entrepreneurial self-efficacy. Though
Yli-Renko 2007 for a similar argumenta- the concept of entrepreneurial control
tion). This can be interpreted as a kind of belief can directly be related to the
disillusionment as not all of the new theory of planned behavior developed
firms can be expected to fulfill the entre- by Ajzen (1991), Rauch and Frese (2007)
preneurs’ expectations. At the same time, in their meta-analysis have shown the
this might also be a result of a more strong and positive association between
realistic assessment of the real business entrepreneurial behavior and self-
world the young entrepreneurs have efficacy. Both characteristics should be
already been acquainted with, different more common among latent nascents
from the nascents and the latent nascent (than among the general population) and
entrepreneurs. even more common among nascent
The impact of knowing someone per- entrepreneurs.
sonally who has recently started her own With regard to income, it is remark-
business (social networks) declines from able that, when controlling for educa-
stage to stage. Again, this is a sign that tion, those who are planning to become
role models are important for the likeli- self-employed earn less than comparable
hood of considering becoming self- nonentrepreneurs. This is significant for
employed oneself. At later stages of the latent nascent entrepreneurs and—to a
process, more experienced entrepre- lesser degree—for nascent entrepreneurs
neurs or consultants may replace the role too. Whereas those who are already
models. young entrepreneurs have significantly
In the literature, empirical results on more often at least €3,000 at their dis-
the function of role models for the entre- posal per month. Without panel data, it is
preneurial process are contradictory: not possible to ascertain whether this is
though Carter et al. (2003) show that an expression of a selection that favors
nascent entrepreneurs are less motivated those with really profitable concepts or
by role models than the general popula- whether it is actually the effect of becom-
tion, Delmar and Davidsson (2000) ing self-employed.
reveal that those with role models are The relatively low incomes of latent
more likely to engage in entrepreneur- entrepreneurs in particular are an indica-
ship. Both studies, however, do not tion that low incomes drive people to
focus on data for Germany. plan their own businesses. Higher
Of course, knowing (or not knowing) opportunity costs do indeed have a nega-
an entrepreneur can also be interpreted tive influence on the likelihood of
as an indicator for the social embedded- becoming self-employed. However, the
ness of the individual (see Cantner and question as to the reasons for their rela-
Stützer 2010) that may play a pivotal role tively lower income remains unan-
(Davidsson and Honig 2003) during the swered. Obviously, the market for
entrepreneurial process. In that sense, dependent employment does not value
our results seem to be comprehensible: their abilities and qualifications suffi-

122 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


ciently. According to Lazear (2005) and about becoming self-employed rises with
Wagner (2003), employees benefit from declining chances on the labor market.5
being highly specialized, whereas entre- However, it is still questionable if
preneurs have a balanced profile pattern regionally specific determinants of entre-
and do especially well if their qualifica- preneurial activity can be explained suf-
tions are broader, following a “jack of all ficiently precisely by variables
trades” pattern. A further explanation aggregated on regions. As Sternberg and
could be that young people who are Wagner (2005) show with probit analy-
planning to set up a business are more ses of 10 representative German regions,
often still in some form of education, for it is possible to demonstrate the regional
example, writing a thesis or studying for influence on start-up rates in principle,
other qualifications that are not covered but it is not possible to demonstrate the
by the qualification variable. This pre- significant influence of individual
vents them from earning much at the regional determinants. The reason is that
moment, but anticipation would pay off the latter had an actual influence only in
in the future. In regions with growing some, but not sufficient, regions. To
GDP per head, people more often plan prevent erroneous interpretations, there
to set up a firm, but this does not apply is a regional influence, but it is the result
for young entrepreneurs. This, too, could of different (i.e., regionally specific)
be an indication of special selection such causes from one region to the next. A
that entrepreneurs more often give up if summary of the results is shown in
they find attractive alternative employ- Table 6.
ment in their vicinity. The differences are
more pronounced for males than for Conclusions
females. This is presumably a base effect Even though entrepreneurs differ
because of the well-known wage dis- remarkably from nonentrepreneurs in
crimination of females in dependent general, our results give evidence of self-
employment. selection processes and learning pro-
Covering the regional environment cesses during the three entrepreneurial
with only two variables is only a first step phases analyzed. Most of these selections
given the complex nature of a region and were identified just at the beginning of
its numerous potential and interrelated the entrepreneurial process.
influences on entrepreneurial activity. In our empirical model, we included
Entrepreneurship as a “regional event” variables covering three scales: personal
(Feldman 2001) is a rather complicated characteristics, microenvironment, and
phenomenon (see Sternberg 2009 for an the regional environment. The results
overview). From both regional variables, clearly suggest that especially the
development of regional GDP per person microenvironment has a big influence on
and development of the unemployment the desire to become self-employed.
rate, only a rise in regional unemploy- Especially the gender gap is a factor
ment has an influence on the probability where politics is required. Women often
of being a latent nascent entrepreneur. do not even think of becoming self-
Evidently, the likelihood of thinking employed, but those who do decide to

5
The relatively high coefficient of both regional variables should not be misconceived: the
scaling of these variables is quite different from the others (mostly dummies). The beta
coefficient of the mentioned positive overall influence on becoming a latent nascent entrepre-
neur is only 0.009.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 123


Table 6
Major Results of Empirical Research Questions
Hypotheses Latent Nascent Nascent Young
Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs Entrepreneurs

H1a Already latent nascent Support — —


entrepreneurs are less
likely to be female.
H1b The likelihood of being — Support Support
female does not differ
between nascent
entrepreneurs and young
entrepreneurs.
H2 Entrepreneurs in all three Support Support Support
stages are more likely to
be younger than 45 years
old.
H3a Medium and high education Support — —
levels raise the propensity
to be a latent nascent
entrepreneur.
H3b The involvement of highly — Support Support
educated individuals
decreases during the
process.
H4 The willingness to trust Support Support Support
one’s skills and to take
risks is higher for
entrepreneurs in all three
stages compared with
nonentrepreneurs.
H5a Growing regional Support No support No support
unemployment increases
entrepreneurial activity.
H5b A growing GDP per head No support No support No support
increases entrepreneurial
activity.

—: test not possible/not tested; GDP, gross domestic product.

start a firm do so with greater confidence This is substantiated by the very young
than men. Although there are already age of latent nascent entrepreneurs. We
special schemes for supporting start-ups therefore support the idea of introducing
by women, we have the impression that a basic entrepreneurial education as a
these are scheduled too late and that topic at schools (Schröder and Schmitt-
self-employment as an alternative to Rodermund 2006). As our results show,
dependent employment must reach role models are an important stimulus to
women—and men—earlier in their lives. think about becoming an entrepreneur.

124 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Variables reflecting the microenviron- cific populations with different percep-
ment have a very significant influence on tions and behaviors. Entrepreneurship
the decision to become self-employed. scholars may state that potential entre-
First of all, it is a person’s attitude or preneurs during the pre-entry phase are
mindset. Here too, education might help anything else than a homogenous group
to reduce the “fear of failure,” as long as but worth to be separated at least into
this fear is exaggerated, because well- nascents and latent nascents.
informed individuals are better able to Further research should make use of
judge the risks. On the other hand, for panel data to be more able to tackle the
some groups of entrepreneurs with small problem of changing attitudes and dispo-
businesses, it might be worth consider- sition of entrepreneurs during the
ing offering some basic social security. process on the individual level.
A further point is that even though the However, these types of databases are
highly qualified are more likely to start a rather costly and time-consuming, so that
business, there is evidence that they so far only few have been developed
often drop out at an early stage. The (Reynolds 2007; van Gelderen, Thurik,
reasons for this are unclear, but the and Bosma 2005). Others are under
opportunity costs are likely to play a construction (Reynolds and Curtain
role. Given the fact that growth-oriented Forthcoming). The authors are under
entrepreneurship has been high on the way to set up such a database for
agenda of both national and regional Germany, using the screening interviews
policymakers (Fischer and Reuber 2003), of the GEM as a starting point (Brixy and
it is important to identify the reasons Sternberg 2010).
why many highly qualified individuals
drop out of the entrepreneurial process.
Moreover, the conditions of the References
regional labor markets play a role. Rising Acs, Z. J., and C. Armington (2004).
levels of unemployment lead to growing “Employment Growth and Entrepre-
interest in self-employment. This might neurial Activity in Cities,” Regional
be a typically German effect because self- Studies 38(8), 911–927.
employment as a way out of unemploy- Ajzen, I. (1991). “The Theory of Planned
ment is very much promoted. Behaviour,” Organisational Behavior
We interpret our results as a step on and Human Decision Processes 50,
the way to reduce the significant 179–211.
research gap in terms of microdata-based Alsos, G. A., and E. C. Ljunggren (1998).
empirical analyses of the entrepreneurial “Does the Business Start-Up Process
process. The value added to the field of Differ by Gender? A Longitudinal
entrepreneurship research is that several Study of Nascent Entrepreneurs,”
attributes of nascent entrepreneurs as Journal of Enterprising Culture 6(4),
well as latent nascents and their environ- 347–367.
ment differ between some of the phases Arenius, P., and M. Minniti (2005). “Per-
of the entrepreneurial process. In par- ceptual Variables and Nascent Entre-
ticular, this is true for gender and for the preneurship,” Small Business
microenvironment of the (potential) Economics 24(3), 233–247.
founder. Policymakers should consider Audretsch, D. B., and M. Fritsch (2002).
this when they develop new government “Growth Regimes over Time and
support programs dedicated to start-ups Space,” Regional Studies 36(2), 113–
or wannabe start-ups. Practitioners who 124.
advise nascents or latent nascents should Bade, F.-J., and E. Nerlinger (1999).
treat nascents and latent nascents as spe- “Spatial Distribution and Regional

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 125


Economic Impact of New Technology- Brixy, U., and J. Hessels (2010). “Human
Based Firms: Empirical Results for Capital and Start-Up Success of
West-Germany,” in Demography of Nascent Entrepreneurs,” EIM Research
Firms. Spatial Dynamics of Firm Reports H201013, EIM Business and
Behaviour. Eds. J. van Dijk and P. H. Policy Research, Zoetermeer.
Pellenbarg. Utrecht, Groningen: Fac- Brixy, U., C. Hundt, and R. Sternberg
ulteit der Ruimteleijke Wetenschap- (2010). Global Entrepreneurship
pen, Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, 141– Monitor (GEM). Länderbericht Deut-
172. schland 2009. Hannover, Nürnberg:
Bergmann, H., and R. Sternberg (2007). Institute of Economic and Cultural
“The Changing Face of Entrepreneur- Geography, University of Hanover;
ship in Germany,” Small Business Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufs-
Economics 28(2/3), 205–221. forschung der Bundesagentur für
Bhave, M. P. (1994). “A Process Model of Arbeit (IAB).
Entrepreneurial Venture Creation,” Brixy, U., and R. Sternberg (2010).
Journal of Business Venturing 9, 223– “German Panel of Nascent Entrepre-
242. neurs,” in New Business Creation: An
Blanchflower, D. G. (2000). “Self- International Overview. Eds. P. Rey-
Employment in OECD Countries,” nolds and R. T. Curtain. New York:
Labour Economics 7(5), 471–505. Springer, 123–141.
Blanchflower, D. G., and A. J. Oswald Brush, C. G., and T. S. Manolova (2004).
(2007). “What Makes a Young Entre- “Start-Up Problems,” in Handbook of
preneur,” IZA Discussion Paper, 3139. Entrepreneurial Dynamics. Eds. W. B.
Boschma, R. (2005). “Proximity and Gartner, K. G. Shaver, N. M. Carter,
Innovation: A Critical Assessment,” and P. D. Reynolds. Thousand Oaks,
Regional Studies 39(1), 61–74. CA, London, New Delhi: Sage, 273–
Bosma, N. (2009). “The Geography of 284.
Entrepreneurial Activity and Regional Cantner, U., and M. Stützer (2010). “The
Economic Development: Multilevel Use and Effect of Social Capital in
Analyses for Dutch and European New Venture Creation—Solo Entre-
Regions,” Utrecht University (PhD dis- preneurs vs. New Venture Teams,”
sertation). Jena Economic Research Papers,
Bosma, N., and J. Levie (2010). Global 2010–012.
Entrepreneurship Monitor 2009 Carter, N. M., and C. Brush (2004).
Executive Report. Babson College, “Gender,” in Handbook of Entrepre-
Universidad del Desarrollo. London neurial Dynamics: The Process of
Business School, Reykjavík Univer- Business Creation. Eds. W. B. Gartner,
sity: Babson Park, MA, Santiago de K. G. Shaver, N. M. Carter, and P. D.
Chile, Reykjavík, London. Reynolds. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage,
Braunerhjelm, H., and B. Borgmann 12–25.
(2004). “Geographical Concentration, Carter, N. M., W. B. Gartner, K. G.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Shaver, and E. J. Gatewood (2003).
Growth: Evidence from Regional Data “The Career Reasons of Nascent Entre-
in Sweden, 1975–1999,” Regional preneurs,” Journal of Business Ven-
Studies 38(8), 929–948. turing 18(1), 13–39.
Brixy, U., and R. Grotz (2007). “Regional Davidsson, P. (2006). “Nascent Entrepre-
Patterns and Determinants of the neurship: Empirical Studies and
Success of New Firms in Western Developments,” Foundations and
Germany,” Entrepreneurship and Trends in Entrepreneurship 2(1),
Regional Development 19(4), 293–312. 1–76.

126 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Davidsson, P., and S. R. Gordon Fritsch, M., and P. Mueller (2004).
(2009). “Nascent Entrepreneur(Ship) “Effects of New Business Formation
Research: A Review,” QUT Digital on Regional Development over Time,”
Repository: http://eprints.qut.edu.au/ Regional Studies 38(8), 961–975.
19622. Fritsch, M., and J. Schmude, Eds. (2006).
Davidsson, P., and B. Honig (2003). “The Entrepreneurship in the Region. New
Role of Social and Human Capital York: Springer.
among Nascent Entrepreneurs,” Gartner, W. B. (1989). “Some Sugges-
Journal of Business Venturing 18(3), tions for Research on Entrepreneurial
301–331. Traits and Characteristics,” Entrepre-
Delmar, F., and P. Davidsson (2000). neurship: Theory & Practice 14, 27–
“Where Do They Come from? Preva- 37.
lence and Characteristics of Nascent Gartner, W. B., K. G. Shaver, N. M.
Entrepreneurs,” Entrepreneurship Carter, and P. D. Reynolds, Eds.
and Regional Development 12(1), (2004). Handbook of Entrepreneurial
1–23. Dynamics: The Process of Business
Edelman, L. F., and H. Yli-Renko (2010). Creation. Thousand Oaks, CA:
“The Impact of Environment and Sage.
Entrepreneurial Perceptions on Gimeno, J., T. B. Folta, A. C. Cooper, and
Venture Creation Efforts: Bridging the C. Y. Woo (1997). “Survival of the
Discovery and Creation Views of Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human
Entrepreneurship,” Entrepreneurship: Capital and the Persistence of Under-
Theory & Practice 34(5), 833– performing Firms,” Administrative
856. Science Quarterly 42, 750–783.
Falck, O. (2007). Emergence and Sur- Grilo, I., and J. M. Irigoyen (2006).
vival of New Businesses. Heidelberg: “Entrepreneurship in the EU: To Wish
Physica. and Not to Be,” Small Business Eco-
Feldman, M. P. (2001). “The Entrepre- nomics 26, 305–318.
neurial Event Revised: Firm Forma- Grilo, I., and R. Thurik (2005). “Latent
tion in a Regional Context,” Industrial and Actual Entrepreneurship in
and Corporate Change 10(4), 861– Europe and the US: Some Recent
891. Developments,” International Entre-
Fischer, E., and A. R. Reuber (2003). preneurship and Management
“Support for Rapid-Growth Firms: A Journal 1, 441–459.
Comparison of the Views of Founders, Haug, P. (1995). “Formation of Biotech-
Government Policymakers, and nology Firms in the Greater Seattle
Private Sector Resource Providers,” Region: An Empirical Investigation of
Journal of Small Business Manage- Entrepreneurial, Financial, and Educa-
ment 41, 346–365. tional Perspectives,” Environment
Freytag, A., and R. Thurik (2007). “Entre- and Planning A 27, 249–267.
preneurship and Its Determinants in a Hoselitz, B. F. (1960). “The Early History
Cross-Country Setting,” Journal of of Entrepreneurial Theory,” in Essays
Evolutionary Economics 17(2), 117– in Economic Thought: Aristotle to
131. Marshall. Eds. J. J. Spengler and W. R.
Fritsch, M., U. Brixy, and O. Falck (2006). Allen. Chicago, IL: Rand McNally,
“The Effect of Industry, Region and 234–258.
Time on New Business Survival—A Koellinger, P., M. Minniti, and C. Schade
Multi-Dimensional Analysis,” Review (2007). “I Think I Can, I Think I Can,”
of Industrial Organization 28(3), Journal of Economic Psychology
285–306. 28(4), 502–527.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 127


Lazear, E. P. (2005). “Entrepreneurship,” Firms-in-Gestation,” Small Business
Journal of Labor Economics 23(4), Economics 9(5), 449–462.
649–680. ——— (2007). “New Firm Creation in the
Lévesque, M., and M. Minniti (2006). United States—A PSED I Overview,”
“The Effect of Aging on Entrepreneur- Foundations and Trends in Entrepre-
ial Behaviour,” Journal of Business neurship 3(1), 1–150.
Venturing 21(2), 177–194. ——— (2008). “Business Creation in
Lückgen, R., D. Oberschachtsiek, R. the United States: Panel Study of
Sternberg, and J. Wagner (2006). Entrepreneurial Dynamics II Initial
“Nascent Entrepreneurs in German Assessment,” Foundations and
Regions,” in Entrepreneurship in the Trends in Entrepreneurship 4(3), 155–
Region. Eds. M. Fritsch and J. 307.
Schmude. New York: Springer, 7– Reynolds, P. D., N. Bosma, E. Autio, S.
35. Hunt, N. D. Bono, I. Servais, P. Lopez-
Malecki, E. (1997). “Entrepreneurs, Net- Garcia, and N. Chin (2005). “Global
works, and Economic Development: A Entrepreneurship Monitor: Data Col-
Review of Recent Research,” in lection Design and Implementation
Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm 1998–2003,” Small Business Econo-
Emergence and Growth. Ed. J. A. Katz. mies 24(3), 205–231.
Greenwich: JAI Press, 57–118. Reynolds, P. D., N. M. Carter, W. B.
Manolova, T. S., C. G. Brush, and L. F. Gartner, and P. G. Greene (2004).
Edelman (2008). “What Do Women “The Prevalence of Nascent Entrepre-
Entrepreneurs Want?” Strategic neurs in the United States: Evidence
Change Journal 17(3–4), 69–82. from the Panel Study of Entrepreneur-
Menzies, T., M. Diochon, Y. Gasse, and S. ial Dynamics,” Small Business Eco-
Elgie (2006). “A Longitudinal Study of nomics 23(4), 263–284.
the Characteristics, Business Creation Rotefoss, B., and L. Kolvereid (2005).
Process and Outcome Differences of “Aspiring, Nascent and Fledgling
Canadian Female vs. Male Nascent Entrepreneurs: An Investigation of the
Entrepreneurs,” The International Business Start-Up Process,” Entrepre-
Entrepreneurship and Management neurship & Regional Development
Journal 2(4), 441–453. 17(2), 109–127.
Parker, S. S. (2004). The Economics of Schröder, E., and E. Schmitt-Rodermund
Self-Employment and Entrepreneur- (2006). “Crystallizing Enterprising
ship. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer- Interests among Adolescents through
sity Press. a Career Development Program: The
Rauch, A., and M. Frese (2007). “Let’s Put Role of Personality and Family Back-
the Person Back into Entrepreneur- ground,” Journal for Vocational
ship Research: A Meta-Analysis on the Behaviour 69(3), 494–509.
Relationship between Business Shane, S., and S. Venkataraman (2000).
Owners’ Personality Traits, Business “The Promise of Entrepreneurship as
Creation, and Success,” European a Field of Research,” The Academy
Journal of Work and Organizational of Management Review 25(1), 217–
Psychology 16(4), 353–385. 226.
Reynolds, P., and R. T. Curtain, Eds. Sorenson, O., and P. G. Audia (2000).
(2010). New Business Creation: An “The Social Structure of Entrepreneur-
International Overview. New York: ial Activity: Geographic Concentration
Springer. of Footwear Production in the United
Reynolds, P. D. (1997). “Who Starts New States 1940–1989,” American Journal
Firms? Preliminary Explorations of of Sociology 106(2), 424–462.

128 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Stam, E. (2007). “Why Butterflies Don’t Empirical Results of the Regional
Leave; Locational Behavior of Entre- Entrepreneurship Monitor (REM)],”
preneurial Firms,” Economic Geogra- Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsgeographie
phy 83(1), 27–50. 49(3/4), 167–184.
Sternberg, R. (2007). “Entrepreneurship, Sternberg, R., and S. Wennekers (2005).
Proximity and Regional Innovation “Determinants and Effects of New
Systems,” Tijdschrift Voor Econo- Business Creation Using Global Entre-
mische En Sociale Geografie (TESG) preneurship Monitor Data,” Small
98(5), 652–666. Business Economics 24(3), 193–203.
——— (2009). “Regional Dimensions of van Gelderen, M., R. Thurik, and N.
Entrepreneurship,” Foundations and Bosma (2005). “Success and Risk
Trends in Entrepreneurship 5(4), 211– Factors in the Pre-Startup Phase,”
340. Small Business Economics 24, 365–
Sternberg, R., U. Brixy, and C. Hundt 380.
(2007). Global Entrepreneurship Wagner, J. (2003). “Testing Lazear’s Jack-
Monitor (GEM). Länderbericht Deut- of-All-Trades View of Entrepreneur-
schland 2006. Hannover: Institut für ship with German Micro Data,”
Wirtschafts- und Kulturgeographie, Applied Economics Letters 10(11),
Universität Hannover; Nürnberg: Insti- 687–689.
tut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsfors- ——— (2007). “What a Difference a Y
chung der Bundesagentur für Arbeit Makes—Female and Male Nascent
(IAB). Entrepreneurs in Germany,” Small
Sternberg, R., and H. O. Rocha (2007). Business Economics 28(1), 1–21.
“Why Entrepreneurship Is a Regional ——— (2008). “Nascent and Infant Entre-
Event: Theoretical Arguments, Empiri- preneurs in Germany. Evidence from
cal Evidence, and Policy Conse- the Regional Entrepreneurship
quences,” in Entrepreneurship: The Monitor (REM),” in Neue Ansätze der
Engine of Growth, Volume 3: Place. MittelstandsForschung. Eds. J. Merz
Eds. M. P. Rice and T. G. Habbershon. and R. Schulte. Berlin: Lit-Verlag, 395–
Westport, CT: Praeger, 215–238. 411.
Sternberg, R., and J. Wagner (2005). “Zur Wagner, J., and R. Sternberg (2004).
Evidenz Regionaler Determinanten im “Start-Up Activities, Individual Charac-
Kontext Individueller Gründungsak- teristics, and the Regional Milieu:
tivitäten. Empirische Befunde aus dem Lessons for Entrepreneurship Support
Regionalen Entrepreneurship Monitor Policies from German Micro Data,”
(REM) [On the Evidence of Regional Annals of Regional Science 38(2),
Determinants in the Context of Indi- 219–240.
vidual Entrepreneurship Activities.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 129


Appendix

Table A1
Attitudes, Percentage in Favor
Fear of Opportunity Social
Failure1 Recognition2 Networks3

Male Female Male Female Male Female

Latent Nascent Entrepreneurs 28.1 29.8 31.6 30.8 68.1 57.8


Nascent Entrepreneurs 19.9 26.6 36.5 37.8 76.5 65.4
Young Entrepreneurs 14.8 21.6 36.2 27.9 75.7 64.1
Nonentrepreneurs 50.0 59.1 17.7 11.0 38.2 27.0

1
Percentage yes: fear of failure would prevent you from starting a business.
2
Percentage yes: in the next six months there will be good opportunities for starting
a business in the area where you live.
3
Percentage yes: you know someone personally who has started a business in the
past two years.
Data source: Adult Population Survey of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor,
pooled data for Germany 2002–2006, n = 16,938.

Table A2
Distribution of Gender and Age According to the
Four Phases of the Entrepreneurial Process as
Percentages (Unweighted)
Gender Age

Male Female <24 25–34 35–44 45–54 55–64

Latent Nascent 59.8 40.3 20.0 24.3 29.3 17.5 9.0


Entrepreneurs
Nascent Entrepreneurs 62.4 37.6 11.4 22.5 34.2 22.3 9.7
Young Entrepreneurs 64.8 35.2 8.9 24.0 35.6 22.9 8.6
Nonentrepreneurs 42.4 57.6 12.1 15.7 26.8 23.0 22.4

Data source: Adult Population Survey of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor,


pooled data for Germany 2002–2006, n = 16,938.

130 JOURNAL OF SMALL BUSINESS MANAGEMENT


Table A3
Distribution of Household Income According to the
Four Phases of the Entrepreneurial Process in
Percentages (Unweighted)
Monthly Income in €

<1,000 1,000 < 2,000 2,000–3,000 >3,000

Latent Nascent Entrepreneurs 13.0 26.1 26.8 34.1


Nascent Entrepreneurs 9.4 24.9 28.2 37.6
Young Entrepreneurs 5.9 20.5 26.0 47.6
Nonentrepreneurs 10.3 31.8 31.0 26.9

Data source: Adult Population Survey of the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor,


pooled data for Germany 2002–2006, n = 16,938.

BRIXY, STERNBERG, AND STÜBER 131

View publication stats

You might also like