You are on page 1of 10

® Academy of Management Journal

1999, Vol. 42, No. 4, 420-428.

RESEARCH NOTES

GETTING MORE THAN YOU PAY FOR:


ORGANIZATIONAL CITIZENSHIP BEHAVIOR AND
PAY-FOR-PEJIFORMANCE PLANS
JOHN R. DECKOP
ROBERT MANGEL
Temple University

CAROL C. CIRKA
Neumann College

Economic control frameworks such as agency theory start with the assumption that
employee and employer interests naturally diverge, whereas alternative control frame-
works imply that employee and employer interests are often aligned. Integrating these
literatures, we hypothesized that value alignment moderates the impact of pay for
performance on extrarole behaviors. Our study of employees in the utility industry
supported this hypothesis. Pay for performance had a negative impact on extrarole
hehaviors for employees low in value alignment but not for employees high in value
alignment.

A paradox of social organization is that human behaviors (George & Jones, 1997; Morrison, 1996;
variability must be reduced to ensure predictable Wright, George, Farnsworth, & McMahan, 1993).
role performance, yet spontaneous and innovative One critical form of extrarole behavior is organi-
activity that goes beyond role requirements must zational citizenship behavior (OGB). OGB is em-
still be encouraged (Katz, 1964). There has been ployee behavior that goes above and beyond the
extensive research on how to design organizational call of duty, that is discretionary and not explicitly
control systems to accomplish the objective of en- recognized by the employing organization's formal
suring predictable and reliable role performance reward system, and that contributes to organiza-
(e.g., Eisenhardt, 1989; Govindarajan & Fisher, tional effectiveness (Organ, 1988; Smith, Organ, &
1990; Johnson & Gill, 1993). There has also been Near, 1983). OGB is desirable from an organiza-
significant research on the construct of extrarole tional point of view because such behavior is
behavior and its importance to the effective func- thought to increase available resources and de-
tioning of organizations (e.g., Podsakoff & MacKen- crease the need for more formal and costly mecha-
zie, 1997). There has been a lack of research, how- nisms of control (Organ, 1988; Podsakoff & Mac-
ever, on the intersection of control systems and Kenzie, 1997). If an organization's control system
extrarole behavior, the point at which the critical reduces OGB, the ironic and unfortunate effect is
paradox identified by Katz occurs. that the organization may have to invest in other
A pay-for-performance plan, in which compen- forms of control in order to encourage spontaneous
sation is linked to employee performance, is one and innovative activity.
form of organizational control, as it motivates em- We suggest that the degree to which the interests
ployees to devote effort to in-role performance by of employees and their organizations are aligned is
controlling their behaviors, outputs, or both (Oliver a key factor in understanding the impact of control
& Anderson, 1995). However, a potential downside systems on OGB. In this research note, we draw on
of pay for performance is that it may also discour- multiple theoretical frameworks to explain why the
age employees from engaging in behaviors not degree of interest alignment moderates the impact
linked to monetary rewards, including extrarole of pay for performance on OGB.

CONTROL THEORY AND PERFORMANCE PAY


We wish to thank Gary Blau, Alison Konrad, and John
McClendon for their helpful comments on drafts of this Economics-based control theories offer frame-
work. works for understanding the exchange between em-
420
1999 Deckop, Mangel, and Cirka 421

ployees and organizations. Agency theory, for ex- wise, natural inclination will result in noncooper-
ample, addresses the issues that arise in ah agency ative behavior and unfavorable transactions.
relationship, in which one party (the principal) Other research on control theory, however, has
delegates work to another (the agent). Most agency not been based on the assumption that the goals of
theory models rest on the assumption that the prin- employer and employee diverge. Ouchi (1980)
cipal and the agent have diverging goals and that it drew on the transactional cost economics frame-
is often expensive for the principal to monitor the work but relaxed the assumption of goal incongru-
behavior of the agent, given the information asym- ence. He argued that the degree of goal incongru-
metries between the two (e.g., Eisenhardt, 1989; ence varied from cases of total divergence to cases
Fama, 1980). In an agency situation, the principal of little or no deviation between the goals of an
basically can choose to provide some form of out- organization and an employee. Ouchi's perspective
put-based contingent reward to align the agent's suggests that firms can proactively manage their
interests with its own or to invest in mechanisms to selection and socialization practices so that em-
monitor the behavior of the agent (Eisenhardt, ployee interests are aligned with the firms'. These
1989). The relative efficiency of each control option so-called clan forms of organization thus have little
is dependent upon levels of outcome uncertainty, need for formal mechanisms to mediate the ex-
risk aversion, the costs of monitoring behavior, and change between individual and organization, be-
other related variables. cause the employee's natural (or socialized) incli-
Most agency theory research has focused on the nation is to behave in ways that are consistent with
GEOs of organizations as agents (Barkema & Gomez- the organization's objectives.
Mejia, 1998), though more recently, strategic com- Other theoretical perspectives are consistent
pensation research has examined the principle- with and extend the clan control perspective. Blau
agent relation for employees below the GEO level (1964) distinguished social from economic ex-
(e.g., Eisenhardt, 1989; Gomez-Mejia & Balkin, change relationships in organizations. Economic
1992; Milkovich, Gerhart, & Hannon, 1991; Stroh, exchange relationships involve tangible, often
Brett, Baumann, & Reilly, 1996). Lower-level em- short-term, contractual relations with a clear quid
ployees, unlike GEOs, have little opportunity to pro quo component, much akin to an output con-
affect key firm performance indicators. As a result, trol system. Social exchange is based on trust be-
many firms base pay increments, awarded as merit tween the parties and does not require an immedi-
pay, on subjective assessments of employee behav- ate quid pro quo. In a social exchange relationship,
ior (Eisenhardt, 1988). trust allows for temporary or perceived asymme-
Whether pay-for-performance systems are based tries between inducements and contributions, and
on behavioral monitoring or output control, the the relationship itself has value. This valuing of the
goal of these plans is to encourage employees to . relationship allows one party to put the interests of
maximize their individual performance, or in-role the other party ahead of his or her own.
effort. A possible by-product, however, may be a The notion that the relationship between em-
reduction in the effort devoted to OGB. By clearly ployer and employee can be far more than a tradi-
specifying behaviors and outputs that will be re- tional economic exchange has been developed fur-
warded, organizations risk discouraging behaviors ther in related lines of research. Van Dyne, Graham,
that will not be explicitly rewarded (Morrison, and Dienesch suggested that when the relationship
1996). This argument has been supported in an between an employee and an organization is char-
experimental context. Wright and colleagues (1993) acterized by a system of shared values, organiza-
found that subjects given difficult goals and incen- tional identification, and trust, it may become a
tives for task completion exhibited relatively low covenantal relationship that lies outside the ex-
levels of spontaneous helping behavior. change framework and involves "intrinsically mo-
This tension between rewarding individual per- tivated effort rather than earning something or get-
formance and maintaining OGB is assumed to re- ting somewhere" (1994: 768). Similarly, Fox and
sult from divergence in the interests of principal Hamilton (1994), Davis and coauthors (1997), and
and agent. Agency theorists and proponents of re- others have conceptualized managers as stewards,
lated theories, such as transactional cost economics as opposed to agents. Stewardship theory, devel-
(Williamson, 1981), have usually assumed that the oped in part as a counterpoint to agency theory,
interests of the parties involved in employment defines situations in which managers are inotivated
transactions are not aligned (Davis, Schoorman, & by organizational rather than individual goals be-
Donaldson, 1997). Hence, a formal control sys- cause their interests are aligned with those of the
tem—such as pay for performance—is needed to owners (principals) of the organization (Davis et al.,
mediate transactions between the parties; other- 1997).
422 Academy of Management Journal August

In summary, several theoretical perspectives de- tionship between the performance-pay link and
scribe a type of control system that is premised on OGB as follows:
the alignment of values between employer and em-
ployee. In such a value-based control system, OGB Hypothesis la. At low levels of value commit-
would not necessarily represent a cost to employ- ment, there will be a negative relationship
ees. To the extent that goals are aligned, employees between the strength of the performance-pay
may feel that they'are helping themselves as they link and organizational citizenship behavior
engage in OGB, even though they do not expect (OCB).
direct, organizational rewards for this behavior. To Hypothesis lb. At high levels of value commit-
the extent that these perspectives apply, we would ment, there will be no relationship between the
not expect support for an agency/transactional cost strength of the performance-pay link and OCB.
economics prediction that the stronger the link be-
tween pay and performance, the less an employee
is likely to engage in OGB. METHODS
Design of the Study
Eight large, investor-owned gas and electric pub-
Control Interaction
lic utilities from across the United States partici-
The preceding discussion suggests that the effect pated in our survey. The utility industry was a
of pay for performance on OGB depends on the particularly attractive context for this study, in that
broader employment relationship and, more specif- many utilities are modifying their control systems
ically, on the extent of interest alignment. Gonsis- to incorporate more transactional forms of control,
tent with agency theory predictions, our argument including pay-for-performance plans.
is that when interests are not aligned, a strong The survey was administered in 1992 to workers
performance-pay link is the main employment ex- in similar jobs in the eight participating companies.
change between employer and employee. Pay for The utility companies identified an average of 13
performance will likely motivate employees to fo- benchmark jobs per company that would be com-
cus on their in-role behavior and to avoid behaviors parable to each other in the outside labor market.
such as OGB that are not rewarded. The jobs ranged from craft and clerical positions to
However, when the values of individuals are supervisory and lower-level managerial work. Al-
tightly aligned with those of the organization, the though the johs were not necessarily unique to
employment exchange is social rather than eco- utilities, it was possible that the industry context
nomic, and OGB may not be perceived as a cost. For might exert some effect on the results of this study,
such value-aligned employees, we predict that pay potentially limiting the generalizability of results.
for performance will not exert a significantly neg- Utilities tend to be larger and more hierarchical
ative effect on OGB. than other organizations and, as quasi-public enti-
To assess the validity of these cirguments using ties, they may be subject to different political forces
individual-level data, it is necessary to translate the than private sector organizations. Employees in the
construct of a value-based control system to the majority of jobs in the survey were covered by
level of employee attitude. The construct of value union contracts.
commitment is useful in this regard. Mayer and Respondents included workers and their imme-
Schoorman (1992), building on previous research diate supervisors. One supervisor was chosen at
(Angle & Perry, 1981; Porter, Steers, Mowday, & random from each company for each benchmark
Boulian, 1974) defined value commitment as "a job. The supervisors were asked to select, at ran-
belief in and acceptance of organizational goals and dom, up to 10 subordinates (most supervised
values and a willingness to exert considerable ef- fewer) and to report on OGB for each employee.
fort on behalf of the organization" (Mayer & Schoor- Supervisors with more than 10 subordinates were
man, 1992: 673). Thus, value commitment repre- asked to list their employees alphabetically, then
sents the degree to which employee and employer select every other one until 10 were chosen. We
values are aligned, and it is equivalent to the ob- then surveyed the employees selected by the super-
jective of a value-based control system. It has also visors (N = 660) about job attitudes, work organi-
been linked conceptually to OGB in previous re- zation, and other variables. A total of 512 usable
search (Davis et al., 1997; Mayer & Schoorman, employee responses were obtained. We were able
1992). to match 340 of these "listwise" with the responses
In summary, we suggest that the level of em- of the supervisors; not all of these employees were
ployee value commitment will moderate the rela- covered by pay-for-performance plans. Our final
1999 Deckop, Mangel, and Cirka 423

primary subsample consisted of 146 employees existence and scope of a pay-for-performance plan
working under some form of pay-for-performance (Lawler, 1980). Also, employees' attentiveness to
plan (individual-, group-, facility-, or company- such communication is likely to vary. Hence, some
based). Gomparisons of this primary subsample of employees may misperceive the strength of the per-
146 to all survey respondents on demographic vari- formance-pay link in their organizations and may
ables indicated that the subsample was representa- act on their perceptions rather than on reality. Gon-
tive in terms of age (42.38 versus 42.06 years), sistent with this idea, research on employee own-
tenure with the company (15.39 versus 15.20 ership has found that employees' perceived influ-
years), and gender (75 percent versus 76 percent ence is a more important explanatory variable than
men), though subsample members were more actual ownership (Buchko, 1993) and that an organ-
highly educated (x = 4.23 vs. 3.70, p < .05).^ This ization's ability to accurately communicate about
difference in education is probably due to the fact an ownership plan is a significant factor in its suc-
that employees covered by pay-for-performance cess (Klein, 1987).
plans are generally likely to be in higher-level jobs, Value alignment. A six-item scale from the Por-
which require more education. ter et al. (1974) Organizational Gommitment Ques-
tionnaire (OGQ) was used to measure value com-
Measures mitment. We identified these items through a
principal factor analysis using "varimax" rotation
Organizational citizenship behavior. For each of a 12-item version of the OGQ, which was in-
of the employees, supervisors filled out a 9-item cluded in the survey. The factor analysis produced
version of the Podsakoff and MacKenzie (1989) Or- two factors with eigenvalues greater than one. We
ganizational Gitizenship Behavior Scale. The ques- labeled these factors "value commitment" and
tions included 3 from each of the scale's three "continuance commitment." Six of the items
dimensions, altruism, sportsmanship, and consci- loaded more heavily on the value commitment fac-
entiousness. Practical constraints made it impossi- tor, and these items constituted our scale. Angle
ble to use the entire OGB scale. This study reports and Perry (1981) and Mayer and Schoorman (1992)
results from data collected as part of a larger survey also factor-analyzed the OGQ, obtained two factor
on human resource practices in the utility industry. solutions, and applied similar labels to the factors.
In its full form, the Podsakoff and MacKenzie scale It should be noted that although we applied the
would have required up to 240 responses (24 items label "value commitment" to this factor, other re-
times ten subordinates) from each supervisor, who searchers (e.g., Dunham, Grube, & Gastefieda, 1994)
also had several other scales to complete. Re- have argued that the OGQ more closely measures
sponses on this and all other scales in the study affective commitment, defined as employees' emo-
were on a five-point Likert-type format with an- tional attachment to, identification with, and in-
chors from 1, "strongly disagree," to 5, "strongly volvement in their employing organization (Allen
agree." (Please contact the first author for a list of & Meyer, 1990). Mayer and Schoorman (1998) also
the items used in this study.) The OGB scale was stated that Angle and Perry's (1981) value commit-
completed by the employees' supervisors; the fol- ment dimension reflected "a positive, affective ori-
lowing scales were completed by employees. entation to the organization" (Mayer & Schoorman,
Performance-pay link. We developed a three- 1998: 16). A difference between value and affective
item- scale for this survey to measure the degree to commitment is that the latter implies emotional
which employees perceived a strong link between attachment. Since it seems reasonable to assume
their performance and pay. The scale items were that value alignment will produce emotional at-
"Increased productivity means higher pay for em- tachment, the degree to which our measure of value
ployees," "My individual performance actually has commitment reflected an affective orientation
little impact on any incentive pay award" (reverse- should not have significantly affected our results or
coded), and "My performance actually has little conclusions.
impact on my salary" (reverse-coded). The per- Control variables. Four control variables were
ceived link between pay and performance is more included: a measure of procedural justice, and de-
relevant to this study than the actual link in that mographic information related to employee gender,
organizations and units within organizations may age, and education. Previous research has asserted
vary in their ability to effectively communicate the the role of procedural justice as a necessary condi-
tion for a social exchange relationship, and hence
OGB, to occur (Moorman, 1991; Organ, 1988). Pro-
^ For the coding of education level, see "Control vari- cedural justice has also been shown to be positively
ables," below. related to value commitment (Organ & Ryan, 1995).
424 Academy of Management Journal August

Though procedural justice does not directly relate assess whether the effect of the performance-pay
to our theorizing about control systems' relation to link on OCB varied with the level of employee
value commitment and its consequences for behav- value commitment, as predicted. With the effects of
ior in the context of a pay-for-performance system, the performance-pay link and value commitment
procedural justice was a necessary control variable. entered, along with the control variables, we added
Employees low in value commitment may be more the interaction of the performance-pay link and
likely to possess negative perceptions of the fair- value commitment. The significance level of that
ness of organizational procedures, particularly a coefficient represented a test of whether the addi-
pay-for-performance system. If we had not con- tion of the interaction term contributed a statisti-
trolled for procedural justice in our analyses, our cally significant increment to R^ (Aiken & West,
estimates of the effect of value commitment could 1991).
have reflected procedural justice effects as well. To The results shown in Table 2 are consistent with
measure procedural justice, we followed the the moderation effect implied by our hypotheses.
method used by Moorman (1991) and developed a The first column reports results without the mod-
seven-item scale that reflected the rules of proce- erator specified; the second column includes the
dural justice developed by Leventhal (1980) and moderator. Results show a statistically significant
Leventhal, Karuza, and Fry (1980). (p < .01) interaction between the performance-pay
Employee gender, age, and education were in- link and value commitment. Comparisons between
cluded because all could be related to employee columns indicate that the addition of the interac-
attitudes (Tsui, Pearce, Porter, & Tripoli, 1997) such tion term resulted in a significant increase in fl^
as value commitment, as well as to OCB. Education [p < .01). These results imply that the effect of the
was coded on a six-point scale ranging from "some performance-pay link on OCB is influenced by the
high school" (1) to "graduate training" (6). value commitment of employees.
The subsample of nonunion employees was too To further explore the interaction, we calcu-
small to warrant separate analyses; no significant lated regression coefficients for the performance-
differences were found in OCB, value commitment, pay link effect at several levels of value commit-
and the performance-pay link between unionized ment (e.g., Aiken & West, 1991; Cohen & Cohen,
and nonunionized employees. 1983). Calculations were made at one standard
deviation below the mean of value commitment,
^vhich represents low^ value conunitment; one
RESULTS
standard deviation above the mean, which repre-
Table 1 contains means, standard deviations, cor- sents high value commitment; and at the mean of
relations, and reliability levels of the study vari- value commitment.
ables. Scale reliabilities all exceeded the cutoff of At low value commitment, the slope estimate of
.70 suggested by Nunnally (1978). the performance-pay link is -1.07 + .25 (3.48) =
We tested our study's hypotheses using moder- -.20 [t = -2.28, p < .05). At high value commit-
ated regression analysis (Aiken & West, 1991). The ment, the slope is -1.07 + .25 (4.76) = .12 [t =
specification of the interaction term enabled us to 1.46, p > .10), and at the mean, the slope is -1.07 +

TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics, Pearson Correlations, and Reliabilities
Variable Mean s.d.

1, OCB 3.86 0.67 (.88)


2, Performance-pay link 3.26 0.92 .08 (.71)
3. Value commitment 4.12 0.64 .28** .30** (.82)
4 Value commitment X 13.59 4.84 .21* .91** .65**
performance-pay link
5, Procedural justice 3.23 0.80 .23** .27** .29** .33** (.90)
6, Age 42.38 8.80 -.09 .02 .11 .06 .13
7, Education 4.23 1.45 .08 -.10 -.05 -.09 -.06 -.12
8. Gender'' 1.24 0.43 .01 .12 .13 .15 .09 -.14 -.30*

° N = 146; coefficient alphas appear on the diagonal.


'' Coding: 1 = man, 2 = woman.
* p < .05
** p < .01
1999 Deckop, Mangel, and Cirka 425

TABLE 2
Results of Regression Analysis for
Without With
Independent Variable Interaction Interaction Sample of 340

Intercept 2.67** (.52) 5.99** (.51) 3.23** (.50)


Value commitment 0.27** (.09) -0.52^ (.31) -0.00 (.12)
Performance-pay link -0.02 (.06) -1.07** (.39) -0.31** (.18)
Value commitment X performance-pay link 0.25** (.09) 0.08* (.04)
Procedural justice 0.15* (.07) 0.15* (.07) 0.13** (.04)
Age -0.01^ (.00) -O.Ol'^ (.00) -0.00 (.00)
Education 0.04 (.04) 0.03 (.04) 0.06* (.02)
Gender -0.05 (.13) -0.07 (.13) 0.03 (.08)

.13 .17 .13


Adjusted R^ .09 .13 .12
F. 3.52** 4.17** 7.30**
N 146 146 340

' Values are unstandardized coefficients; standard errors are in parentheses.


"^p < .10
*p < .05
**p < .01

.25 (4.12) = -.04. The results show a significant, DISCUSSION


negative effect of pay for performance on OCB for
The results of this study provide hoth negative
low value commitment, a marginally significant,
and positive evidence regarding the effects of he-
positive effect of pay for performance on OCB for
havioral and output control systems in organiza-
high value commitment, and no effect of pay for
tions. On the negative side, for employees low in
performance on OCB at the mean.
value commitment a pay-for-performance system
In summary, the results presented in Tahle 2 and appears to he a disincentive for engaging in OCB.
the supplemental tests described ahove support our The stronger they perceive the performance-pay
hypotheses. As predicted hy Hypothesis la, for em- link to be, the less likely they are to engage in
ployees low in value commitment, the stronger the organizational citizenship behavior. This result,
performance-pay link, the less they will engage in which is consistent with agency and transactional
OCB. For individuals high in value commitment, cost economics predictions, represents a downside
we obtained a statistically insignificant coefficient to the use of behavioral and output control systems
estimate, a finding supporting Hypothesis Ih. not previously identified in field research.
We also conducted, for comparison purposes, an The positive evidence is that pay-for-perfor-
analysis that utilized the full sample of 340. This mance plans do not appear to discourage OCB for
sample included individuals who reported on the value-committed employees. This result is consis-
survey that they were not covered hy a pay-for- tent with previous research on control systems in
performance plan. Results from the sample of 340, which a conflict of interests between employer and
shown in Tahle 2, are similar to those for the sam- employee has not heen assumed, and it further sug-
ple of 146. Though effect sizes are somewhat gests that most agency/transactional cost economics
smaller, the interaction hetween the performance- models are limited in their applicability and may
pay link and value commitment is positive and need to be modified to account for convergent inter-
statistically significant [p < .05), which again sup- ests. In fact, agency models can be constructed to
ports the argument that the effect of the perfor- reflect convergent interests, though in practice most
mance-pay link on OCB depends on the value com- are not (Albanese, Dacin, & Harris, 1997).
mitment of employees. Interestingly, we obtained a fairly sizable, posi-
Consistent with previous research (Organ & tive estimate for the performance-pay link for val-
Ryan, 1995), procedural justice was a significant ue-aligned employees that was marginally statisti-
predictor of OCB. The age of an employee had a cally significant in a one-tailed test. A positive
negative and marginally significant effect on OCB. effect of pay-for-performance on OCB is potentially
The gender and education of the employee failed to compatible with what Tsui and her colleagues
exert a statistically significant effect. (1997) termed a "mutual investment" approach to
426 Academy of Management Journal August

the employee-organization relationship. Mutual in- the pay-for-perfofmance link when value commit-
vestment in their study was indicated, in part, by ment was low. If we were able to obtain a more
the existence of a unit-based pay-for-performance accurate measure of OCB, we would expect to ob-
plan. Tsui and coauthors found that organizations serve an even stronger negative relation between
that adopted a mutual investment approach expe- pay for performance and OCB for those employees
rienced more employee OCB. This finding suggests who are less value-committed.
that value-aligned employees may view pay for per- Future research that addresses the interaction of
formance less as a short-term quid pro quo and different control systems within and across organi-
more as an element of a broad, long-term social zations would he valuable, as organizations con-
exchange relationship. These employees may view tinue to alter the nature of their relationships with
pay for performance as an investment on the part of employees. The utility industry presents an espe-
the organization, and they respond with OCB. cially good context for exploring the issues of in-
Results of this study also present interesting teracting control systems. Utilities have historically
implications for research into antecedents of OCB. been heavily regulated, very paternalistic, and
The lack of a negative relationship between the heavily unionized (as was our sample). Now, they
performance-pay link and OCB for value-aligned are moving toward more transactional forms of con-
employees suggests that OCB is not necessarily a trol, in which the focus is on enhancing individual
cost to employees. If this is true, exchange-based and organizational performance in order to adapt to
theories may be limited in their ability to explain deregulation and increased competition.
OCB. Though there is persuasive evidence that
With respect to the unionized part of the work-
OCB is an outcome consistent with a social ex-
force in particular, this movement toward transac-
change relationship, results of this study are also
tional control manifests itself in a move to various
consistent with previous research that has identi-
forms of pay for performance. From an agency per-
fied nonexchange explanations of OCB. For exam-
spective, pay for performance attempts to align em-
ple, Pearce and Cregerson (1991) found that altru-
ployer and employee interests. Many group incen-
ism in the form of felt responsihility predicted
tive systems also entail increased employee
extrarole behaviors, and Van Dyne and colleagues
participation in decision making (Lawler & Jenkins,
(1994) found that extrarole behaviors resulted from
1992). These evolving forms of workforce gover-
a covenantal relationship between employee and
nance challenge the notion that union and manage-
employer, a relationship that, like altruism, tran-
ment necessarily have conflicting interests in all
scended exchange. In these studies, altruism and
areas of the employment relationship. The assump-
intrinsic motivation were suggested as probable an-
tion of conflicting interests has historically under-
tecedents of OCB. In future studies, researchers
lain industrial relations theory (Kaufmann, 1993;
should consider further theoretical and empirical
Kochan, 1980). In the same way, it provides an
assessment of the place of motivational antecedents
underpinning for economic theories of control sys-
in the nomological net of OCB. A focus at the level
tems, such as the agency/transactional cost eco-
of motivation may help explain the conditions un-
nomics perspective. As industrial relations theory
der which employees transcend an exchange rela-
evolves, newer models that incorporate elements
tionship with their employers.
such as trust (Fox, 1974) and social exchange (Ma-
A limitation of any study involving OCB is honey & Watson, 1993) reflect convergent interests,
whether the measure used is valid. As has heen as do perspectives such as input-, clan-, and value-
argued (e.g., Morrison, 1994; Robinson & Morrison, based control in the control theory literature.
1995), individual differences and contextual fac- The utility industry exemplifies a more general
tors may determine whether a behavior measured trend in the United States. In recent decades, the
hy an OCB scale is in fact an extrarole behavior. For employment relationship has heen moving away
example, as Eastman (1994) pointed out, what for from long-term, bureaucratic forms in which em-
some employees may be citizenship behavior for ployees are tightly tied to organizations. In con-
others may be an attempt to ingratiate themselves trast, we observe more flexible arrangements, in
to employers or supervisors. Civen this limitation, which employees are less firmly attached to given
our results may represent a conservative test of organizations and there is more emphasis placed
Hypothesis la. To the extent that the hehaviors we on immediate, short-term employee performance
measured in our OCB scale were in fact in-role (Kanter, 1989; Pfeffer & Baron, 1988; Useem, 1993).
behaviors, the less we would expect to find a neg- Organizations with histories of long-term employ-
ative relationship between the strength of the pay- ment relationships, in which social or value-hased
for-performance link and our measurement of OCB. control was an important component of the overall
Yet we did find a negative effect for the strength of control systems, are increasingly implementing
1999 Deckop, Mangel, and Cirka 427

performance-based incentive systems. To the ex- Fox, A. 1974. Reyond contract: Work, power, and trust
tent that value-based control systems are eroding relations. London: Farber & Farber.
in such organizations, other methods of fostering Fox, M. A., & Hamilton, R. T. 1994. Ownership and
organizational citizenship hehavior may need to be diversification: Agency theory or stewardship the-
identified as the shift to transactional forms of con- ory. Journal of Management Studies, 31: 69-81.
trol discourages good citizenship. George, J. M., & Jones, G. R. 1997. Organizational spontane-
ity in context. Human Performance, 10: 153-170.
Gomez-Mejia, L. R., & Balkin, D. B. 1992. Determinants of
REFERENCES faculty pay: An agency theory perspective. Academy
of Management Journal, 35: 921-955.
Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. 1991. Multiple regression:
Testing and interpreting interactions. Newbury Govindarajan, V., & Fisher, J. 1990. Strategy, control sys-
Park, CA; Sage. tems, and resource sharing: Effects on business-unit
performance. Academy of Management Journal,
Albanese, R., Dacin, M. T., & Harris, I. C. 1997. Agents as 33: 259-285.
stewards. Academy of Management Review, 22:
609-611. Johnson, P., & Gill, J. 1993. Management control and
organizational behaviour. London: Chapman.
Allen, N. J., & Meyer, J. P. 1990. The measurement and
antecedents of affective, continuance and normative Kanter, R. M. 1989. The new mafiagerial work. Harvard
commitment to the organization. Journal of Occu- Rusiness Review, 67(6): 85-92.
pational Psychology, 63: 1-18. Katz, D. 1964. The motivational bases of organizational
Angle, H. L., & Perry, J. L. 1981. An empirical assessment behavior. Rehavioral Science, 9: 131-146.
of organizational commitment and organizational ef- Kaufmann, B. E. 1993. The origins and evolution of the
fectiveness. Administrative Science Quarterly, 26: field of industrial relations in the United States.
1-14. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Barkema, H. G., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. 1998. Managerial Klein, K. L. 1987. Employee stock ownership and em-
compensation and firm performance: A general re- ployee attitudes: A test of three models. Journal of
search framework. Academy of Management Jour- Applied Psychology, 72: 319-332.
nal, 41: 135-145.
Kochan, T. A. 1980. Collective bargaining and indus-
Blau, P. M. 1964. Exchange and power in social life. trial relations: From theory to practice. Home-
New York: Wiley. wood, IL: Irwin.
Buchko, A. A. 1993. The effects of employee ownership Lawler, E. E. 1980. Pay and organizational development.
on employee attitudes: An integrated causal model Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
and path analysis. Journal of Management Studies,
30: 633-658. Lawler, E. E., & Jenkins, G. D. 1992. Strategic reward
systems. In M. D. Dunnette & L. M. Hough (Eds.),
Cohen, J., & Cohen, P. 1983. Applied multiple regres- Handbook of industrial and organizational psy-
sion/correlation analysis for the behavioral sci- chology (2nd ed.), vol. 3: 1009-1055. Palo Alto, GA:
ences (2nd ed.). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Gonsulting Psychologists Press.
Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. 1997.
Leventhal, G. S. 1980. What should be done with equity
Toward a stewardship theory of management. Acad-
theory? New approaches to the study of fairness in
emy of Management Review, 22: 20-47.
social relationships. In K. S. Gergen, M. S. Green-
Dunham, R. B., Grube, J. A., & Castaneda, M. B. 1994. berg, & R. H. Willis (Eds.), Social exchange: Ad-
Organizational commitment: The utility of an inte- vances in theory and research: 27-55. New York:
grated definition. Journal of Applied Psychology, Plenum.
79: 370-380.
Leventhal, G. S., Karuza, J., & Fry, W. R. 1980. Beyond
Eastman, K. 1994. In the eyes of the beholder: An attri- fairness: A theory of allocation preferences. In G.
butional approach to ingratiation and organizational Mikula (Ed.), Justice and social interaction: 167-
citizenship behavior. Academy of Management 218. New York: Springer-Verlag.
Journal, 37: 1379-1391.
Mahoney, T. A., & Watson, M. R. 1993. Evolving modes
Eisenhardt, K. M. 1988. Agency- and institutional-theory of workforce governance: An evaluation. In B. E.
explanations: The case of retail sales compensation. Kaufmann & M. M. Kleiner (Eds.), Employee repre-
Academy of Management Journal, 31: 488-511. sentation: Alternatives and future directions: 135-
Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and 168. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations Research As-
review. Academy of Management Review, 14: 57-74. sociation.
Fama, E. F. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the Mayer, R. G., & Schoorman, F. D. 1998. Differentiating
firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88: 288-298. antecedents of organizational commitment: A test of
428 Academy of Management Journal August

March and Simon's model. Journal of Organiza- Porter, L. W., Steers, R. M., Mowday, R. T., & Boulian,
tional Rehavior, 19: 15-28. P. V. 1974. Organizational commitment, job satisfac-
Mayer, R. G., & Schoorman, F. D. 1992. Predicting par- tion, and turnover among psychiatric technicians.
ticipation and production outcomes through a two- Journal of Applied Psychology, 5: 603-609.
dimensional model of organizational commitment. Robinson, S. L., & Morrison, E. W. 1995. Psychological
Academy of Management Journal, 35: 671-684. contracts and OGB: The effect of unfilled obligations
Milkovich, G. M., Gerhart, B., & Hannon, J. 1991. The on civic virtue behavior. Journal of Organizational
effects of research and development intensity on Rehavior, 16: 289-298.
managerial compensation in large organizations. Smith, G. A., Organ, D. W., & Near, J. P. 1983. Organiza-
Journal of High Technology Management Re- tional citizenship behavior: Its nature and anteced-
search, 2: 133-150. ents. Journal of Applied Psychology, 68: 653-663.
Moorman, R. H. 1991. Relationship between organiza- Stroh, L. K., Brett, J. M., Baumann, J. P., & Reilly, A. H.
tional justice and organizational citizenship behav- 1996. Agency theory and variable pay compensation
iors: Do fairness perceptions influence employee cit- strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 39:
izenship? Journal of Applied Psychology, 76: 845- 751-767.
855.
Tsui, A. S., Pearce, J. L., Porter, L. W., & Tripoli, A. M.
Morrison, E. W. 1994. Role definitions and organiza- 1997. Alternative approaches to the employee-organ-
tional citizenship behavior: The importance of the ization relationship: Does investment in employees
employee's perspective. Academy of Management pay off? Academy of Management Journal, 40:
Journal, 37: 1543-1567. 1089-1121.
Morrison, E. W. 1996. Organizational citizenship behavior Useem, M. 1993. Executive defense: Shareholder
as a critical link between HRM practices and service power and corporate organization. Gambridge,
quality. Human Resource Management, 35: 493-512. MA: Harvard University Press.
Nunnally, J. G. 1978. Psychometric theory. New York: Van Dyne, L., Graham, J. G., & Dienesch, R. M. 1994.
McGraw-Hill. Organizational citizenship behavior: Gonstruct re-
Oliver, R. L., & Anderson, E. 1995. Behavior- and out- definition, operationalization, and validation. Acad-
come-based sales control systems: Evidence and emy of Management Journal, 37: 765-802.
consequences of pure-form and hybrid governance. Williamson, O. E. 1981. The economics of organization:
Journal of Personal Selling and Sales Manage- The transaction cost approach. American Journal of
ment, 4(Fall): 1-15. Sociology, 87: 548-577.
Organ, D. W. 1988. Organizational citizenship behav- Wright, P. M., George, J. M., Farnsworth, S. R., &
ior: The good soldier syndrome. Lexington, MA: McMahan, G. G. 1993. Productivity and extra-role
Lexington Books. behavior: The effects of goals and incentives on
Organ, D. W., & Ryan, K. 1995. A meta-analytic review of spontaneous helping. Journal of Applied Psychol-
attitudinal and dispositional predictors of organiza- ogy, 78: 374-381.
tional citizenship behavior. Personnel Psychology,
48: 776-801. John R. Deckop is an associate professor of human re-
source administration at the Fox School of Business and
Ouchi, W. G. 1980. Markets, bureaucracies, and clans. Management, Temple University. He received his Ph.D.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 129-141. in industrial relations from the University of Minnesota.
Pearce, J. L., & Gregersen, H. B. 1991. Task interdepen- His research interests include the effects of pay systems
dence and extrarole behavior: A test of mediating on employee motivation and behavior, especially extra-
effects of felt responsibility. Journal of Applied Psy- role behavior.
chology, 76: 838-844.
Robert Mangel is an assistant professor of human re-
Pfeffer, J., & Baron, J. 1988. Taking the workers back out: source administration at the Fox School of Business and
Recent trends in the structuring of employment. In Management, Temple University. He received his Ph.D.
B. M. Staw & L. L. Gummings (Eds.), Research in from the Wharton School of the University of Pennsyl-
organizational behavior, vol. 10: 257-303. Green- vania. His current research interests include individual
wich, GT: JAI Press. and group incentive systems, employee participation,
Podsakoff, P. M., & MacKenzie, S. B. 1989. A second work-family initiatives, and work-technology interfaces.
generation measure of organizational citizenship
Carol G. Cirka is a doctoral candidate in the Fox School
behavior. Working paper, Indiana University,
of Business and Management at Temple University and
Bloomington.
an assistant professor of management at Neumann Gol-
Podsakoff, P. M., & MacKenzie, S. B. 1997. Impact of lege. She received her M.B.A. from the University of
organizational citizenship behavior on organiza- Pittsburgh. Her doctoral work examines the effects of
tional performance: A review and suggestions for management controls on psychological empowerment
future research. Human Performance, 10: 133-152. and proactive employee behaviors.

You might also like