You are on page 1of 13

Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Ecosystem Services
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecoser

Understanding the governance of the Payment for Environmental


Services Programme in Costa Rica: A policy process perspective
Jean-François Le Coq a,b,n, Geraldine Froger c, Denis Pesche a, Thomas Legrand d,
Fernando Saenz b
a
CIRAD, UMR ART-Dev, F-34398 Montpellier Cedex 5, France
b
UNA, CINPE, Campus Benjamin Nunez, Lagunilla, Heredia, Costa Rica
c
LEREPS, Université de Toulouse, ENFA, IEP de Toulouse, UT1 Capitole, UT2J, 21 allée de Brienne, 31 000 Toulouse, France
d
UVSQ, Cemotev, 47°bd Vauban, 78047 Guyancourt Cedex, France

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Costa Rica was a pioneer in implementing the concept of ecosystem services through a dedicated policy
Received 10 November 2014 instrument: the Payment for Environmental Services programme (PESP) formalised in February 1996 in
Received in revised form the 4th forestry law. However, the policy process that led to the design of the PESP and its consequences
12 August 2015
for its subsequent governance have never been fully analysed. Our paper aims at answering three
Accepted 1 October 2015
Available online 17 October 2015
questions: why PESP was adopted, what are the factors which enabled the speedy adoption of PESP, and
how does the policy process affect the governance of the programme. Between 2008 and 2012, we in-
Keywords: terviewed 42 key representatives and stakeholders involved in the policy process. We also reviewed
Policy process laws, decrees, and academic and grey literature. We combined the sequential policy cycle model to
Environmental services
identify the sequences of the genesis of the PESP from the problem setting to the decision sequence, and
Interest groups
a cognitive approach to the policy process to identify the internal and external factors that led to its
Governance
Forest conservation genesis. We show that the PESP was rapidly adopted because of the particular domestic context, plus
Costa Rica several internal and exogenous factors. First, deforestation was widely acknowledged and forestry in-
centive instruments already existed as did consolidated forestry organisations and institutions. Second,
compromises were reached between leading actors in a context in which the forestry sector interest
group was the most powerful. Third, public subsidies were banned in the framework of an international
agreement on trade while the international carbon market offered new opportunities. The key elements
of the governance of the Costa Rican PESP, such as its scope, nature and decision structure, reflect the
existing balance of power between interest groups from different sectors (forestry, conservation, agri-
culture) involved in the management of forested areas. We conclude that analysing the policy process is
important to understand PES governance and to promote sound PES development.
& 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction that was institutionalised by the 4th forestry law (#7575) as early
as 1996, i.e., prior to popularisation of the environmental services
Payments for Environmental Services (PES) have received a concept and the first definition of PES schemes (Wunder, 2005). As
great deal of attention as an instrument to support conservation a pioneer case, the Costa Rican PES experience has been thor-
effort (Landell-Mills and Porras, 2002; Wunder, 2005), but the role oughly described (Chomitz et al., 1999; Camacho et al., 2000;
of interplay between actors in the emergence and design of this Castro et al., 2000; Pagiola, 2008) and its results in terms of en-
instrument has been far less studied (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008; vironmental effects or poverty reduction largely assessed (Miranda
Corbera et al., 2009; McAfee and Shapiro, 2010). Costa Rica, con- et al., 2003; Zbinden and Lee, 2005; Sanchez-Azofeifa et al., 2007;
sidered worldwide as a pioneer country for environmental ser- Locatelli et al., 2008; Barton et al., 2009; Daniels et al., 2010;
vices, developed a specific policy instrument: the Payment for Porras, 2010; Pfaff and Robalino, 2012; Robalino and Pfaff, 2013).
Environmental Services Programme (PESP). Whereas in many However, the policy process that led to the emergence of the
countries PES remain local, Costa Rica developed a national system Costa Rican PESP and its consequences for its subsequent gov-
ernance have never been fully analysed. Some authors analysed
n the emergence of PESP as a social and institutional innovation
Correspondence to: CIRAD, ART-Dev, TA C-113, 73 rue Jean-François Breton,
34398 Montpellier Cedex 5, France. Fax: þ 33 4 67 61 44 15 (Camacho et al., 2000; Segura-Bonilla, 2003) arguing that PESP
E-mail address: jflecoq@cirad.fr (J.-F. Le Coq). represented a new way of considering the environment resulting

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2015.10.003
2212-0416/& 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
254 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

Table 1
Key features of PESP and major changes during its implementation from 1997 to 2014. (Source: authors based on Pagiola, 2008; Le Coq et al., 2013; Matulis, 2013; Porras
et al. 2013, and the revision of forestry law #7575 and decrees, and interviews with FONAFIFO administration).

Key features 1997–2001 2002–2006 2007–2014

Scope Forest and forest plantation


Ecosystem services 4 Environmental services: mitigation of greenhouse gas emissions, hydrological services, biodiversity conservation, and scenic beauty
Payment system 3 PES modalities: -forest protection, -re- -Suppression of PES for forest man- 10 PES modalities enabling differentiation of payment ac-
forestation, -forest management agement-Creation of PES for agrofor- cording to the importance of the ES (PES conservation in
estry systems biodiversity hotspots, or water services; PES for pasture re-
generation in Kyoto lands); -Reintroduction of PES for forest
management (2010)
Revalorisation of PES amount for reforestation
Prioritisation of payments according to the location of plots (biological corridor and low development
index) enabling some degree of payment targeting Creation of indigenous PES to enable landholders
with no land title to be incorporated into PES
Management Shared between FONAFIFO (fund raising Operational management concentrated in FONAFIFO, which is in charge of promotion, selection of
system and administration) and SINAC (priority beneficiaries, and administration of the fund SINAC is primarily involved in criteria priority setting and
and selection of beneficiaries) control of deforestation
Development of GIS control and monitoring
Creation of quotas for local forestry organisations
Monitoring and checking contract completion by forest landowners by the forestry regent supervised by Colegio de agronomos (CIA)
Financial and administrative control of the programme by the Contraloria General de la Republica (CGR)
Board of FONAFIFO with 5 members: 3 public, and 2 private representatives nominated by the National Forestry Office (ONF)
Funding system 100% Public funding through an oil tax Oil tax þ international loans and grants Oil tax þ international loans and donations þ private con-
tributions þwater tariff

NB: FONAFIFO: Fondo Nacional de Financiamiento Forestal; SINAC: Sistema Nacional de Área de Conservación; CIA: Colegio de Ingenieros Agrónomos; ONF: Oficina Nacional
Forestal; CGR: Contraloría General de la republica.

from a learning process. On the other hand, Pagiola (2008) high- percentage of fuel tax. In line with the existing forestry incentives
lighted the continuity of the PESP in comparison of previous policy derived from previous laws, the PESP initially consisted in three
instruments to support the Costa Rican forestry sector, and con- PES contracts, so called PES modalities: forest protection, refor-
sidered that the main changes were the justification of the forestry estation, and forest management (Pagiola, 2008; Daniels et al.,
support from the wood industry in the provision of ES, and the 2010) but by 2014, it had evolved into 16 modalities1.
source of funding for this support policy. Fletcher and Breitling PESP underwent changes during its implementation with re-
(2012) argued that PESP is the continuation of public intervention, spect to funding sources, the payment system, and administrative
while Matulis (2013) saw a shift towards a neoliberal policy, and management (Le Coq et al., 2013; Porras et al., 2013), but some key
Brockett and Gottfried (2002) saw the emergence of a hybrid features of PESP governance have remained unchanged since its
regime. inception (Table 1). First, the main funding sources are still public
In this paper, our objective is to thoroughly analyse the policy funds, in particular fuel tax (Blackman and Woodward, 2010), even
process which led to the Costa Rican PESP in order to better un- if the funding sources have been diversified (Matulis, 2013). Sec-
derstand the current governance of the payments for Environ- ond, PESP is an input-based PES (Engel et al., 2008) and its degree
mental Services as an instrument to foster forest conservation. We of commoditisation is low (Muradian et al., 2010), even if the
specifically address the three following questions: Why was PESP prioritisation system for conservation contracts has been en-
selected as a policy instrument in the Costa Rican context? Which hanced to take into account forest potential for biodiversity con-
factors enabled the rapid adoption of PESP? How did the policy servation or for the provision of water services (Le Coq et al.,
process shape the current governance of the PESP? We hypothe- 2013). Moreover, the two main modalities are still “forest protec-
tion”, which is the main modality, and represents the most con-
sised that the rapid adoption of the Costa Rican Payment for En-
tracts and the biggest area affected (89% of total PES area)2, and
vironmental Services Programme (PESP) was due to the specific
“reforestation” which can be undertaken for wood production
context and to a combination of several internal and exogenous
(Lansing, 2013). Third, in terms of PESP management, the legal
factors, and that the main feature of the PES governance reflected
composition of FONAFIFO board has remained unchanged (Ta-
the balance of power between different interest groups involved in
ble 1) as has the control process of landowner contracts through
the policy process.
the private forestry regent and the overall supervision of the PESP
by the National System of the Conservation Area (Sistema Nacional
de Area de Conservacion – SINAC). The monitoring and evaluation
2. Background: brief history of the PESP system is still oriented towards forested areas.

The Costa Rican Payment for Environmental Services Pro-


gramme (PESP) was institutionalised with the 4th forestry law 3. Analytical framework and methodology
(#7575 of 1996). This law established three key components of
PESP (Pagiola, 2008): (1) recognition of the provision by the forest 3.1. Policy process analysis
and tree plantations of four environmental services: mitigation of
greenhouse gas emissions, hydrological services, biodiversity To analyse the emergence and implementation of the PESP, we
conservation, and scenic beauty; (2) a regulatory basis to contract
landowners for the services provided by their forest lands, and 1
FONAFIFO website: http://www.fonafifo.go.cr/psa/modalidades_psa.html –
recognition of the National Fund for Forest Financing (Fondo Na-
Accessed 2014-10-03.
cional de Financiamento Forestal, FONAFIFO) as administrator of the 2
Estimation of the authors based on FONAFIFO statistics for PES between 1997
programme; (3) the definition of a funding mechanism through a and 2011 available in FONAFIFO (2012).
J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265 255

4th forestry
law National PES Programme

1960 1990 1995 1996 1997 2013

(1) agenda (2) policy (3) policy (4) policy (5) policy
setting formulation adoption implementation evaluation

External and internal factors External and internal factors


during policy formulation during policy implementation
and adoption

Context prior
to policy change
Interaction between actors (interest groups)
with different resources
- Interests and cognitive patterns

- Institutions

- Ideas
Policy output :
4th forestry law and governance of the
Payment for Environmental Services Programme

Fig. 1. Analytical framework for the analysis of the policy process applied to the Costa Rican Payment for Environmental Services Programme (PESP), using the “3 I” model
developed by Hall (1997) and Surel (2000) and the five-step sequential model developed by Anderson (1975).

used an analytical framework derived from two complementary dimensions. First, in line with the literature on PES governance
streams of policy process analysis: the sequential model of public structure (Vatn, 2014), and the governance model (Matzdorf et al.,
policies, and a cognitive approach (Fig. 1). 2013), we consider the type of actors involved in the decision
The sequential model of public policies treats the policy process process regarding PES. In particular, as governance differs from
as a succession of sequences. Since the first version of this model government since it involves a different range of actors (private,
(Laswell, 1956), scholars have proposed different ways of breaking community, etc.) from those in the public sector (government), we
down the sequences (Brewer, 1974). Here, we used the five step pay particular attention to the respective role of the state and of
model developed by Anderson (1975) to identify the sequences of non-state actors in the PESP decision process and management.
the policy process of the PESP (Fig. 1): (1) the policy agenda, which Second, we consider the key features that characterise ES gov-
consists in the identification of the problem and raises of aware- ernance between market and hierarchy (Muradian and Rival,
ness of the State, (2) policy formulation, which consists in devel- 2012) and the key characteristics that affect PES results (Sattler
oping a solution to the problem, (3) policy adoption, which is the et al., 2013). Thus we consider (1) the source of funding of PES,
public decision to adopt the solution and develop an action pro- including its origin (state/non state) and nature (compulsory/vo-
gramme, (4) policy implementation, which is the action programme luntary), (2) the type of ES considered, how they are bundled and
implemented by the administrator of the programme, and (5) their degree of commoditization, and (3) the system of payment,
policy evaluation of the results with respect to the objective of the including the mode of payment (input or output-based), type (in-
programme, which may provide feedback for a new cycle of se- kind/in-cash), frequency (one-off, periodical), timing (upfront,
quences leading to a new policy. after ES delivery), and eligibility (horizontal, targeted3). Additional
The cognitive approach overcomes the limits of the sequential attention is paid to the conditionality of PES including technical
model, such as the lack of causal theory, legalistic and top-down and administrative requisites as part of the rule of access to PES.
bias, and oversimplification (Sabatier, 2007). We used two streams
of cognitive approaches to understand the causes of the policy 3.3. Research protocol
changes. To understand the situation prior to PESP adoption
(Fig. 1), we used the “3 I model” (Institutions, Interest and Idea) To capture the governance features of PES and the underlying
developed by Hall (1997) and Surel (2000), who consider that PESP policy process, we combined desk reviews and direct inter-
policy change results from the conjunction of three factors: In- views with stakeholders (Table 2). To identify the different stages
stitutions, Interests, and Ideas. To analyse the policy output, i.e. the of the policy process, we reviewed literature on forest policies and
PESP principles and governance, we used the approach of Has- PESP. We captured PESP governance through a review of the
senteufel (2008): we assumed policy output to be the result of the academic literature and Spanish and English grey literature on the
interaction between the actors who developed strategies accord- PESP, which we complemented with a review of the law, decrees,
ing to their interests and their policy action resources. and manuals of PESP procedures and direct interviews with the
technical staff of FONAFIFO. Based on this information, we re-
3.2. ES and PES governance constructed the initial state and evolution of the different features
of PESP governance.
As part of environmental governance (Lemos and Agrawal,
2006), ES and PES governance can be described through multiple 3
Horizontal PES refers to open to all potential ES providers, while targeted PES
dimensions. To characterise PESP governance we consider two aim either at a specific area or a specific type of providers (Sattler et al., 2013).
256 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

To grasp the conditions of emergence and shape of the project,

Description of governance and timeline of chan-


Summary of debate Timeline of modifications in

Stakeholders' interests and positions regarding


we reviewed the different versions of law projects, and the min-

the text of the law List of stakeholders Stake-


utes of the debate in the legislative process of the 4th forestry law.
Further, between 2008 and 2012, we conducted 42 face-to-face
qualitative interviews with key representatives and stakeholders
Intermediary research products
who were involved in the policy process (see Appendix A for the

holders' interests and positions


list of stakeholders interviewed). We identified the interviewees
using the snowballing method (i.e. the first actors were identified
thanks to their direct involvement in the policy process and were
then asked to identify other actors involved in the process); they

ges in governance
were deputies, civil servants, representatives of organisations, and
scholars. The interviewees were invited to describe their own

governance
trajectory, the role they had played in the emergence and evolu-
Timeline

tion of the PESP, as well as their own perception of the PESP (see
Appendix B for the interview guidelines). From these individual
interviews, we characterised the key factors which explain the
holders involved in adoption of the 4th law
Minutes of debates Interviews with stake-

Law, decree and manual of procedures In-

Face-to-face interviews with stakeholders

adoption of the PESP and its key governance features as set down
in the 4th forestry law. We also recorded their interest in PESP and
their perception of its main governance features and the changes it
involved in PESP implementation

underwent during the implementation phase. By crossing in-


terviews with PESP managers

formation from individual interviews with some grey literature, to


Review of the literature

cross check the statements made by the interviewees, we were


able to characterise the positions, strategies, and resources of the
interest groups involved in the process, and link PESP governance
and PES design
Data sources

to interplay between the stakeholders.

4. Results
Scope PES modality Access condi-

4.1. Context prior to PESP adoption


Internal decision Management

Interest groups Justifications


Institutions Interests Ideas

The context prior to policy formulation and the adoption in


1996 of the 4th forestry law, which included the PESP principles,
was characterised by three key elements: an acknowledged de-
Date of key event

forestation issue and existing forestry policy framework and in-


tions Priority

struments, the consolidated forestry administration and the pri-


Resources
Variables

vate forestry representation of interests, and the emergence of


new ideas regarding forest function and conservation instruments.
Research stages, analytical concepts, variables, data sources and intermediary research products.

4.1.1. Deforestation issue and policy framework


Interplay between actors (Hassenteufel, 2008)
Matzdorf et al., 2013; Vatn, 2014) and char-

Since 1969 and until the creation of the PESP in 1996 (Table 3),
PES Governance (Muradian & Rival , 2012;

Costa Rica had progressively developed a support policy for the


forestry sector characterised by a three pronged strategy, which is
now included in the PESP: reforestation, sustainable forest man-
acteristics (Sattler et al., 2013)

agement, and conservation of existing forest. This policy consisted


Policy cycle (Anderson, 1975)
3 I (Hall, 1997; Surel, 2000)

in supporting forest landowners, from large forestry companies to


small-scale farmers or landowners. Hence after a sharp decrease in
forested area, from 53% of the country in 1961 to 21% in 1987
Analytical concept

(FONAFIFO, 2012), resulting from intense land clearing especially


to develop beef cattle raising, facilitated by land colonisation po-
licies and the expansion of the road network, deforestation began
to slow down in late 1980s due to the combination of socio-eco-
nomic factors, such as the reduction in the price of meat and the
first effects of most recent incentives encouraging reforestation
Analysis of key factors explaining PESP
Characterisation of key features of PES
Analysis of key factors in the adoption

(Calvo-Alvarado et al., 2009). However, in 1996, stakeholders still


governance features and how they
Identification of policy cycle phases

considered deforestation to be an important issue because the first


statistics providing evidence for this reversal were only published
in 1997 after the adoption of the PESP.
and design of the PESP

and how it evolved

4.1.2. Public administration and private organisation of forestry


sector
Research stages

During the period 1969–1995, along with the forest policy


framework, public institutions dealing with forestry and environ-
evolved

mental issues developed, and private representation of the for-


Table 2

estry sector was consolidated.


The public forestry administration, which was almost non-
Table 3
Costa Rican legal forest framework and policy instruments from 1969 until the creation of the PESP (1996) (Sources: our interviews with stakeholders 2008–2012; Camacho et al., 2000).

Year Policy document Policy orientation Policy instrument Mechanism Beneficiary

J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265


1969 First forestry law (#4465) Promote reforestation through forest – – –
plantation
1979 Reforestation law Promote reforestation through forest Income tax reduction Fiscal incentive to compensate for plantation estab- Large companies who pay income tax
plantation lishment and maintenance costs
1986 Second forestry law Promote reforestation through forest Forestry credit certificate (CAF)a Fiscal incentive to compensate for plantation estab- Small and medium enterprises; farmers
(#7032) plantation lishment and maintenance costs
1988 Promote reforestation through forest Forestry credit certificate paid in advance Idem 1986, but paid in advance Small and medium forestry farmers who
plantation (CAFA)b belong to organisations
1988 Promote tree plantation in agro-forestry Forestry development fund (FDF)c Direct support Small and medium scale farmers (even
systems without a land title)
1990 Third forestry law (# 7174) Promote reforestation through forest CAF, CAFA and FDF Direct support Small medium, and large forestry
plantation companies
1992 Reduce deforestation due to wood extrac- Forestry credit certificate for forest man- Direct support) Forest landowners
tion practices agement (CAFMA)d
1995 Conserve existing forest Certificate for forest protectiond Direct support Forest landowners
1996 Fourth forestry law (# Promote reforestation, sustainable man- Payment for Environmental Services Pro- Direct support (Payment for conservation, planta- Forest landowners
7575) agement and conservation gramme (PESP) tion, management of forest)

5: CPB, Certificado de Protección del Bosque.


a
CAF, Certificado de Abono Forestal.
b
CAFA, Certificado de Abono Forestal por Adelantado.
c
FDF, Fondo para el Desarrollo Forestal.
d
CAFMA, Certificado de Abono Forestal por Manejo del Bosque.

257
258 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

International Convention of the environment


External World Trade Organization
Development of international
factors negotiation
mechanisms of compensation

1994: Ratification of 1995 : FMI/CR agreement


Climate Change protocol on a ban on subsidies

Debate on new Adoption


3 Forestry laws of 4th forestry
forestry law projects Reformulation of a
proposal forestry law proposal law
Policy
process (including
ES recognition
1990 1994 1995 and PES principles) February
1996

1994 : New government and Minister of Environment


Internal Event : “from forest to society”
factors
1994 : 3 international conference
on ecological economics

1994 : Creation and strengthening of Costa Rican Chamber of Forestry

Experimental local projects with contractual payment as compensation for forest protection

Fig. 2. Key internal and external factors in the 4th forestry law and the adoption of Payment for Environmental Services (PES) in Costa Rica (1990–1996).

existent in the 1960s, expanded in the 1970s and 1980s along with organisations were created in the 1980s: the Chamber of Reforestation
the implementation of the first and second forestry laws and the Enterprises (Cámara Nacional de Reforestadores – CANAFOR) to defend
creation of the Direction of Forestry (DGF) within the Ministry of the interests of the large forestry enterprises who developed refor-
Agriculture. In 1990, forestry sector institutions gained more au- estation programmes in the 1970s and 1980s; and the National
tonomy and institutional strength in the policy arena thanks to the Chamber of the Wood Industry (Cámara Nacional de la Industria Ma-
creation of the Ministry of Natural Resources Energy and Mine derera – CANAIMA) to represent large-scale saw mills and wood
(Ministry de Recursos Naturales, Energia y Mineria – MIRENEM) processing factories. These two organisations were not close to JU-
which merged the Ministry of Industry, Energy and Mine with NAFORCA because of their different social base and the classical dif-
institutions such as the General Department of Forestry, the ference in the views of large/small structures, business oriented/family
Wildlife Department, and the National Parks Services. Despite oriented activities, and producers/processors opposing economic
these enhancements, the Direction of Forestry was unable to as- interests.
sume proper control over all forestry activities (Brockett and Further, in 1994, with the support of USAID (United States
Gottfried, 2002). Agency for International Development) and the GTZ (Gesellschaft
During the same period, the private forestry interest groups für technische Zusammenarbeit), the Costa Rican Chamber of For-
including small- and large-scale forest owners and their re- estry (Camara Costaricense Forestal – CCF) was created to represent
presentation at local and national levels were gradually con- the whole private forestry sector of Costa Rica. This organisation
solidated. In the 1980s, the General Department of Forestry pro- began with some representatives of forestry and large-scale timber
moted the creation of numerous local forestry organisations as companies who were convinced of the need to unite the sector
interlocutors and intermediaries to facilitate the implementation and introduce more sustainable practices. By promoting agree-
of the forestry policy aimed at smallholders—such as CODEFORSA ment and dialogue among the stakeholders of the forestry sector,
in the northern region, ASIREA in the Caribbean zone, COOPE- the Chamber of Forestry expanded its memberships to include
MADEREROS in the southern zone, the CAC Hojancha in the some local forestry organisations. The Chamber of Forestry began a
northeast region, AGUADEFOR in the Guanacaste region, and dialogue with JUNAFORCA with the aim of achieving a wider re-
FUNDECOR in the central valley region. These organisations were presentation of the forestry sector.
created to provide economic, administrative and technical support
to forestry farmers. They also benefited from support from inter- 4.1.3. Emergence of new ideas on forest and forestry
national cooperation and national public policy (Barrantes, 2009). In the early 1990s, two new ideas about forest and forestry policy
In 1989, the representation of the interest of small and medium and instruments emerged in the public and private forestry, aca-
forestry farmers was strengthened at national level, with the demic, and cooperation sectors. The first idea was to consider forest
creation of the “Peasant forestry national council” (Junta Nacional not only as a producer of a commodity (wood) but also as a provider
Forestal Campesina – JUNAFORCA), which was the result of an in- of a number of valuable services for society. The second idea was
itiative of a number of local forestry organisations, and which that a positive incentive to maintain forest could be an effective way
defends sustainable community management of the forest and to overcome the deforestation issue. In the private forestry sector,
agroforestry. This organisation shared views and interests with large companies and small forestry producers' representatives were
environmentalist organisations and with representatives of small convinced that sustainable practices required public support but
farmers, especially with the National Peasant Platform, which was public funds were increasingly difficult to obtain in the context of
founded at the same time (Mesa Nacional Campesina – MNC). national budget deficits, stabilisation policies and structural adjust-
Regarding the interests of forestry companies, two representative ment plans (De Camino et al., 2000). On one hand, organisations of
J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265 259

small forestry landowners with more conservationist views, such as

Favourable to conservation, not


Favourable to management, re-
Favourable to agroforestry PES
AGUADEFOR and CAC Hojancha, were questioning the logic of public
support for the forestry sector: “why give incentives to cut and plant

forestation, agroforestry
trees, instead of protecting the existing forest?” On the other hand,

Favourable to PES on
with the reduction in forested area, representatives of the wood

to management
industry were preoccupied with the sustainability of their own

Not favourable
PES modalities
activity.

agroforestry
In the academic sector, scientific studies in the 1960s were
oriented toward the inventory of natural resources to characterise
forest biodiversity. But, in the 1990s, new disciplines emerged
such as environmental and ecological economics. Many studies
assessed the economic benefits of national parks and natural re-

Favourable
sources, in order to demonstrate the importance of nature for

Sources of
funding
society. In the early 1990s, the first economic valuation of the
Monteverde reserve located in north-western Costa Rica was car-


ried out by Tropical Science Centre (TSC) with the support of
USAID, the World Wildlife Fund, the Nature Conservancy and
World Resources Institute (Echeverría et al., 1995). From 1993 on,
in the framework of the Collaborative Research in Environmental

Institutional
governance

Favourable
Economics and Development programme, an initiative by the In-

Objectives and positions of main interest groups with respect to forestry issues in 1995 in Costa Rica (Sources: our interviews with stakeholders 2008–2012).
ternational Institute for Environment and Development (IIED) and
the Institute for Environmental Studies (IVM), the TSC undertook


Main objectives and interests related Position in the debate on the future 4th forestry law
numerous economic valuations of the environment (Rojas and
Aylward, 2003). In a complementary way, from 1993 to 1997, a

Recognition of PSE
project named “Economic Incentives for Watershed Protection”
was implemented in collaboration with the TSC and the Master’s

(Favourable)
mechanism

Favourable

Favourable

Favourable
Programme in Economic Policy of the Costa Rican National Uni-
versity. It consisted in 24 sub-studies and benefited from inputs
from a research team of 18 economists and natural scientists, and


led to the dissemination of a series of working papers. Meanwhile,

Recognition of ES provi-
Costa Rican scholars with relations with American scholars in-
creased their own skills in the economic valuation of the en-
sion by the forest
vironment. In 1994, the third International Conference of Ecolo-
gical Economics brought a large number of international scientists

(Favourable)
Mesa Nacional Campesina Develop agriculture and agroforestry Favourable

Favourable

Favourable
to Costa Rica (Costanza et al., 1996). This conference strengthened
this discipline in Costa Rica and raised the awareness of policy
makers and of society about the value of natural resources and

ecosystems, especially forested areas.


Sustain forestry activity (production

Sustain forestry activity (as income


Land use extension for agriculture

generation for local communities)


In the cooperation sector, new mechanisms to promote forest

Maintain biodiversity and natural


for local income diversification

protection and sustainable management practices were being ex-


perimented in the late 1980s and early 1990s at local scale, two
examples being the Boscosa project by the foundation Neotropica
of timber for industry)

in the Osa Peninsula (Southern region) (Campos Arce 1991; Gott-


fried et al., 1994), and the Foresta project (1989–1996) funded by
to forest issues

USAID and implemented by FUNDECOR in the central valley


ecosystems

(USAID, 1996). These projects empirically tested the very first ap-
plication of the principle of contractual payment for conservation.
This principle was included in the set of forestry instruments in
1995 with the creation of a “Certificate for Forest Protection”
(Table 3) which rapidly achieved success (FONAFIFO, 2005).
Costa Rican Chamber of
National Chamber of
Leading professional

4.2. The adoption of PESP, key factors and groups of actors


UPA Nacional
organisations

JUNAFORCA
Agriculture

The definition and adoption of the key principles of the PSEP


Forestry

took place within a short period (1995–1996) which corresponded


FECON

to the policy formulation and adoption sequences of the 4th for-


estry law adopted in February 1996 (Fig. 1). We identified the key
Large forestry company, the

internal and external factors that led to the rapid formulation and
Large farms (businesses)

adoption of this law and the interplays between the groups of


Small farms (peasants)

Ecologists associations
Small forestry farmers

–no opinion expressed.

actors in the decision process which led to the creation of the PESP.
Conservation sector
Agricultural sector

timber industry
Forestry sector
Interest group

4.2.1. Key internal and external factors in the policy formulation


In the early 1990s, three key factors encouraged the formula-
tion and rapid adoption of the 4th forestry law (Fig. 2).
Table 4

The first factor was external: the increasing importance of en-


vironmental issues on the international agenda. For the leaders of
260 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

the forestry sector, especially the Chamber of Forestry and some sector interest groups had access to major resources and alliances
local organisations including FUNDECOR, the ratification of the to defend their point of view (Table 4). First, they had strong in-
Climate Change and Biodiversity Convention in 1992 was an op- stitutional and political resources thanks to their alliance with the
portunity to finance the support required by the forestry sector. Ministry of Environment. This Ministry was part of the main-
This opportunity was strengthened by the ratification of the Cli- stream of the National Liberation Party which had just won the
mate Change Protocol by the government of Costa Rica in 19944. elections and had a majority in the national assembly. Second, the
This government initiative, which was supported by the forestry forestry sector had strong organisational resources. The Chamber
sector, was rapidly exploited. Then, in 1995, the Office of joint of Forestry, which played a leading role in the dialogue process
implementation (“Oficina Costaricense de Implementacion Con- and benefited from international cooperation, also benefited from
junta” – OCIC) was created to formulate carbon compensation strong leadership and technical capacities at that time. The for-
projects. The opportunity to finance forest policy for forest ser- estry sector enjoyed strong and broad representativeness, as it
vices, in particular carbon sequestration, was promising. represented both large companies and small landowners located
The second factor was endogenous and political. In 1994, José throughout the country. Third, these interest groups benefited
Maria Figueres Olsen, who had used the environmental issue as an from academic support since their proposal was in line with the
important electoral-campaign theme, was elected president. He views of many scholars in Costa Rica.
nominated a new Minister of Environment, Rene Castro, who was The conservationist interest groups had been increasing in
a member of a network of American scholars specialised in en- importance since the mid-1980s. Many local environmentalist
vironmental economics and of the national network of scholars associations and NGOs, which, in 1989, were grouped together in
and forestry organisations. The Minister of Environment was the FECON network, denounced local environmental issues. This
looking for a new way to conceptualise the benefits of the forest in network had connections with some civil servants at the Ministry
order to justify the need to support forestry. In 1994, the Minister of Environment, but their conflicting position limited the extent of
organised a large conference “From forest to society” with politi- their institutional alliances. Politically, even if a small fraction of
cians, scholars, and actors from the forestry sector, where he the National Platform of Peasants (MNC) shared some of their
publicly introduced the notion of environmental services and the ideas, no clear alliance was formed between deputies and re-
need to pay for these services (Costa Rica. Presidencia de la Re- presentative of the conservationist movement. The conserva-
pública, 1994). tionists had good academic support from biologists and ecologists
The third and key factor came from the international scene and who were losing their audience in the local scientific debate faced
external actors. It was the ban on subsidies to productive sectors with the rise of ecological and environmental economics. Despite
following an agreement between the Ministry of Finance, the support from international NGOs, their financial resources were
limited. Ultimately, favourable public opinion was their main re-
President of Costa Rica, and the International Monetary Fund in
source, since Costa Rican citizens had become interested in their
the framework of World Trade Organisation negotiation (De Ca-
natural resources through mass media campaigns.
mino et al., 2000; Brockett and Gottfried, 2002). This ban threa-
Interest groups in the agricultural sector were traditionally the
tened existing incentives and gave the formulation and the
main opponents of forest conservation since their economic de-
adoption sequences of the future 4th forestry law a sense of ur-
velopment depended on land colonisation. However, they were
gency. The Ministry of Environment exploited environmental ser-
poorly invested in the forestry agenda negotiation, because of an
vices and paying for them as a new way of legitimising support for
economic crisis (with falling meat and coffee prices), and an in-
the forestry sector, switching from public subsidy incentives to a
stitutional crisis with the reform of agricultural public adminis-
market-based instrument rhetoric.
tration and a reduction of public support (Lansing, 2013). In ad-
dition, their representation was not united as there were strong
4.2.2. The interest groups around forest issue and their resources
opposition to the agricultural agenda between representatives of
We identified three main interest groups with divergent views
large-scale companies and those of small famers. In addition, the
of the forest issue, the forestry law and instruments in 1995
small farmers were divided among themselves, which further
(Table 4): (1) the forestry sector groups comprising the large for-
sapped their power.
estry companies and the wood industry represented mainly by the
In addition to the three main interests groups described above,
Chamber of Forestry (CCF), and the small-scale forestry farmer
it is worth noting that indigenous groups, who collectively manage
landowners represented by the JUNAFORCA; (2) the conservationist
large extents of forest in their territories, were poorly integrated in
group mainly represented by the Costa Rican federation of con-
the forestry law policy process. Indigenous territories have only
servationists (FECON); and (3) the agricultural sector groups com-
benefitted from the PESP since 2002 thanks to the creation of
posed of large-scale farmers represented by the National Chamber Agroforestry PES contract in 2002 following the mobilisation of
of Agriculture (CNA) and some interprofessional bodies such as the indigenous and small holder groups (Rosa et al., 2004).
agro-industrial sugarcane league (LAICA), and the small and med-
ium-scale farmers and peasants who in the mid-1990s, were re- 4.2.3. From 1995 to February 1996: the political negotiation process
presented by two main organisations, the National Syndicate of before the adoption of the 4th forestry law and the PESP
small and medium agricultural producers (UPA Nacional) and the In the early 1990s, a proposal for a new forestry law was dis-
National Platform of Peasants (MNC). cussed in the national assembly but a consensus was not reached
In 1995–1996, while the formulation and adoption of the for- (Brockett and Gottfried, 2002). In the new political context of
estry law and the design of the PESP was underway, the forestry 1995, three forestry law proposals were introduced one after an-
other, each supporting different views. The first proposal, made by
4
In addition, Costa Rica was already committed to conservation at national the Ministry of Environment, had the support of the private for-
level with the development of national parks and conservation areas (Evans, 1999) estry sector (especially the Chamber of Forestry) and favoured a
as well as at international level with the ratification of multiple international productive strategy. The second proposal, called “Cut only what
conventions including the convention on the Protection of Flora, Fauna and Natural has been planted” (Cortar únicamente lo que ha sido plantado –
Scenic Beauty in the Countries of the Americas (1940), the Convention on Inter-
national Trade of Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES – 1975), the
CULPA) was submitted by a deputy belonging to a minority frac-
Convention on Wetlands (RAMSAR – 1975) or the Convention on Biological Di- tion of the majority party in the assembly, which supported a
versity (CBD – 1992). more conservationist strategy, as it proposed to ban the
J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265 261

exploitation of natural forest. A third proposal was introduced by forest management modality was abandoned between 2003 and
the Committee of the National Assembly in charge of the in- 2009 following denunciation by conservation groups, but was re-
struction of this law, which aimed to reconcile the previous views. activated under pressure from groups supporting productive for-
Finally, faced with the emergence of an incentive system for estry (Le Coq et al., 2013; Porras et al., 2013). Indeed, even if
forestry activities, a compromise was found and formalised in the groups interested in productive forestry argue for the develop-
4th forestry law. The ideas of ES provision by forest and wood ment of a reforestation and forest management modality, these
plantations, as well as the principle of PES (earmarked oil tax and a modalities represent a minor part of the budget compared with
management role for FONAFIFO), were introduced in the final conservation contracts, which represent 89% of the total area un-
version of the law, as a justification for supporting forest produc- der PES contracts (FONAFIFO, 2012). The predominance of the
tion and the conservation of forest on private land, as well as conservation contract can be explained by different factors. First,
promising mechanisms to finance forestry incentives. The main conservation PES contracts have been considered by the produc-
point under discussion was the prohibition of land use change for tive forestry interests as a compensation for the prohibition of land
forested areas. This ban on deforestation was not in the interest of use change laid down in the forestry law, and are thus not opposed
the agricultural sector as it would limit agricultural growth. It was to this modality (Le Coq et al., 2012). Second, demand for refor-
not in the interest of the forestry sector, as it restricted their rights estation (as well as for forest management) PES is limited due to
on private property. However, the forestry sector representatives technical and economic constraints (Locatelli et al., 2008 ; Navarro
finally accepted it, as it was part of the compromise required to get and Bermúdez, 2013). Third, the demand for conservation PES is
the law accepted. Moreover, the ban was balanced by the creation high – even higher than the funds available (Pagiola, 2008; Ma-
of PESP to maintain forestry incentives. tulis, 2013), as it calls for limited investment. Fourth, the aware-
ness of the Costa Rican population of environment issues has been
increasing thanks to information distributed at different levels
5. Discussion (academic, institutions, professionals, mass media) on global
warming and biodiversity depletion, creating a “conservation
In this section, we discuss how the policy process and the in- culture” in the country, within which cutting trees (from natural
terplay between interest groups make it possible to understand forest, but even on reforested plots) has become unpopular,
the extent and pace of change that the adoption of the PESP re- thereby limiting the social acceptance of expanding such activities
presents, the respective roles of international and national factors, (ONF, personal communication 2012). The other changes concern
as well as of scientific information in the design of the PESP, and the diversification and differentiation of conservation PES (Porras
the key elements of PESP governance. We then draw some con- et al., 2013) to increase its efficiency, the refinement of the selec-
clusions regarding the analysis of the policy process to help un- tion procedure for conservation PES to ensure more transparency,
derstand PES diversity and to support PES emergence in contexts and the setting of quotas for forestry intermediary organisations
that prevail in other countries. (Matulis, 2013; Bosselmann and Lund, 2013) to strengthen their
support for the programme and to facilitate access by small-
5.1. Policy process: pace and extent of change holders. Finally, some changes also occurred in the administration
of PESP. The civil servants status of FONAFIFO was adjusted to fit
The rapid pace of the policy process leading to PESP adoption the public administration law following the request the Contraloria
reflected the sense of urgency created by external threats, such as General de la Republica (Fonafifo, pers. com. 2012), which made it
the ban on public subsidies to productive sectors in the framework possible to claim legitimacy vis-à-vis public procedure. The func-
of the World Trade Organisation negotiation, to the sustainability tion of FONAFIFO was extended to include the selection of PESP
of existing forestry incentives. This particular combination in time beneficiaries (Robalino et al., 2011) at the expense of SINAC office,
led to a specific policy window (Kingdon, 1995; Zahariadis, 2007) in order to make the process of recruitment of PES beneficiaries
that was evidenced in different countries by the increased use of more efficient. Nevertheless, the SINAC, which represents the in-
the ES concept (Le Coq et al., 2012), as one of the factors enabling terest of biodiversity, still plays an important role, as it continues
the promotion of ES (Swallow et al., 2010). to participate in the definition of the priority criteria for PES al-
Although the PESP has been considered as a policy innovation, location, and gives priority to forest areas located in protected
in fact, the change in practices it represents was limited (Pagiola, areas and biological corridors.
2008; Fletcher and Breitling, 2012). PESP, as a continuation of
previous instruments, i.e., forest credit certificates, can be inter- 5.2. Influence of international actors
preted as the result of the primacy of the forestry interests groups
in the policy process whose interest was in maintaining existing The genesis of PESP is an example of indirect and diffuse in-
instruments. This continuity is embedded in a long term trajectory ternational influence in which domestic interest groups domi-
of conservation commitments of Costa Rica (Evans, 1999) and is nated the process, although external organisations could have
consistent with the path dependency observed in the changes in acquired a dominant position in policy making through financial
environmental policies in other countries (Froger and Méral, support or normative argumentation (Bernauer and Gampfer,
2012). 2013). Indeed, international conservation NGOs were not directly
Actually, most of the changes occurred in the implementation involved in the genesis of the PESP, whereas in many countries
sequence of the programme (i.e. after 1997) due both to the they have played a crucial role in the establishment of PES
change in the balance of power and resources between interest (Wunder and Albán, 2008; Hrabanski et al., 2013). International
groups (Le Coq et al., 2013) and to the “learn by doing” process cooperation actors were not directly involved in the design of the
(Porras et al., 2013). These changes did not alter the core govern- PESP, although they are directly involved in many other PES ex-
ance feature of PESP (scope, input-based nature of payment, periments (Swallow et al., 2010). In Costa Rica, they facilitated
structure of decision) (Table 1) but they did help reinforce the good conditions by supporting a technical consensus in the for-
legitimacy of the programme, which is a key factor for PES sus- estry sector (Brockett and Gottfried, 2002), and facilitated the
tainably (Corbera et al., 2007). Changes occurred regarding PES creation of the representative platform for the private forestry
modalities. A PES modality for agroforestry system was included in sector. They also contributed by supporting two projects, Boscosa
2003 to incorporate smallholder farmers in the programme. The and Reforesta, which were used as references for the national PES.
262 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

The indirect influence of external actors was important in the forestry sector representatives, one from the wood industry and one
overarching environment of PESP design. Indeed, in the 1990s, small forestry landowner, both designated by the National Forestry
international actors, such as International Monetary Fund and the Office (ONF, Oficina Nacional Forestal). The FONAFIFO management
World Bank, supported a more neoliberal orientation of policies in board does not include representatives of conservation organisa-
Costa Rica (Fletcher and Breitling, 2012). tions even though they are part of the ONF, as their representation
Although the PESP design and its governance features derived in the ONF is limited. The participation of indigenous re-
more from internal debate led by domestic interest groups than presentatives in the board is not laid down by the 4th law, even
from international normative debate, the influence of interna- though they manage 10% of the national forest area and have been
tional actors and norms became more direct and more rigorous receiving 20% of annual payments since 2008 (Molina Murillo et al.,
during the implementation sequence. This is illustrated by three 2014). Likewise, local authorities are not represented in the decision
events: (1) the integration of funding from international co- structure of PESP, in contrast to other PES, such as the PINFOR
operation in the PESP since 2001 with the Ecomercado Project programme (Programa de Incentivos Forestales) in Guatemala (Bos-
funded by the World Bank and Global Environmental Fund (Pa- colo et al., 2010) or watershed PES, such as the Pimampiro muni-
giola, 2008); (2) the creation of the “regeneration modality” in cipal watershed-protection scheme and the PROFAFOR carbon-se-
2004 to benefit from the specific condition set by the Kyoto pro- questration programme in Ecuador (Wunder and Albán, 2008).
tocol (Le Coq et al., 2013); and (3) the current REDD þ negotiation In the end, the design of the PESP was basically limited to a
process (Rosendal and Schei, 2014). International actors including negotiation within the forestry sector, whereas the broad partici-
the World Bank have been influential in the integration of prior- pation of stakeholders is considered to be a key factor in en-
itisation criteria with respect to the poverty index and the inclu- vironmental governance (Newig and Fritsch, 2009). This explains
sion of a specific indigenous PES modality (Fonafifo staff, personal the efficiency of the design process and the board’s reactivity in
communication; 2012). the face of threats and opportunities arising from international
factors. On the other hand, it limited the participation of certain
5.3. The policy process explains PES governance features actors who are important for the provision of ES today, namely the
indigenous population, and for the funding of ES, tourism. The
Three specific key features of the PESP discussed in the litera- tourism sector has been identified as a beneficiary of ES for scenic
ture can be understood by examining the PESP policy process: the beauty (Castro et al., 2000) but never directly participates in PESP
scope, the input-based payment associated with limited commo- funding. For instance, entry fees to national parks are used to fund
dification, and the structure of decision making. park administration, but not the PESP. However, tourism activities
The scope of the PESP includes the forest ecosystem and the such as car rentals support the PESP through the acquisition of a
whole rural landscape. As it originated in the forestry sector, the certificate for environmental services (CSA) to compensate for
PESP did not intend to preserve a specific service, e.g. a hydraulic their carbon emissions.
oriented PES (Kosoy et al., 2007; Quintero et al., 2009), which can Finally, the continued state-centred emphasis on the manage-
cover all the land uses in a watershed. The forestry law states the ment and funding of the PESP contrasts with the user-funding PES
recognition of ES from a forest and from tree plantations, which model that has been promoted in the PES literature, in which
mainly concern exotic species (Baltodano, 2007). This scope re- private international and national funding sources are considered
flects the view of the forest as productive, which is supported by likely to be more sustainable (Engel et al., 2008). The Costa Rican
the private forestry sector. The forestry law also deregulated for- PES programme shows that financial sustainability can derive from
estry plantations, eliminating any need for permits for harvesting, sustained commitment of the State supported in dialogue with
transporting, industrialising, or exporting plantation timber representative forestry groups and not from commitments by
(Brockett and Gottfried, 2002), which also supports forestry private funders. Indeed, although the fuel tax included in the
groups’ interests. The legal scope of the PESP justifies support for forestry law was considered as a jumpstart, and it was envisioned
plantation, although this has been denounced by the conservation that carbon-abatement trading would provide significant funding
groups who defend the restoration of the forest ecosystem (Bal- to the programme (Castro et al., 2000; Sage and Sanchez, 2002;
todano, 2007). It also justifies payment to support the adoption of Sanchez-Azofeifa et al., 2007); the PESP failed to be financed by
sustainable forest management, which has also been denounced the international carbon market as it did not include the principle
by conservation groups (Le Coq et al., 2013). of additionality in its design, but a principle of compensation for
The input-based payment (Engel et al., 2008) and the low reduction of land use rights (Legrand et al., 2013). To compensate
commodification (Muradian et al., 2010) of the PESP result from for this shortfall, the continuing role of State in funding the pro-
three characteristics of the policy process and the interplay be- gramme has been crucial, as it provides the core funding through
tween actors: (1) the rapid pace of the policy sequence, as it was fuel tax allocation and additional funding by negotiating interna-
easier to maintain the input-based payment of the previous for- tional loans and the creation of water tariffs. The latter could be
estry incentives than to create a more complex output-based considered as an introduction of neoliberal logic (Matulis, 2013)
payment; (2) the willingness of the forestry interest groups to but is still a non-voluntary contribution of ES users where public
justify the forest incentive, not the provision of a specific ecosys- involvement plays a key role (Pagiola, 2008).
tem service, like the Mexican PES programmes, which are oriented
toward water services (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008), or carbon and
biodiversity (Corbera et al., 2009); and (3) the conception and 6. Conclusion
justification of PES as a compensation for the ban on changes in
forest land use (Legrand et al., 2013), not for the remuneration of Understanding the genesis of the Payment for Environmental
the provision of specific ES. Accordingly, the monitoring process of Services programme in Costa Rica (PESP) allowed us to explain key
the PESP has been focussed on forested area and not on ES pro- elements of its governance, including its scope, nature, and deci-
vision, even though the overall objective of the PESP should be ES sion making structure.
provision and not forest conservation per se (Contraloria General We showed that the PESP, which was adopted in 1996, was
de la Republica, 2011). formalised to legitimise the previous forest incentive and to get
The PESP structure of decision is controlled by forestry-oriented round the international agreement on the ban of public subsidies to
entities. The FONAFIFO management board includes two private productive sectors in the framework of World Trade Organisation
J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265 263

negotiations. The rapid institutionalisation of the PESP through the contexts. A policy process analysis should be used to complement
adoption of the 4th forestry law in 1996 relied on the conjunction of feasibility studies in PES promotion initiatives, which are often
four prior enabling conditions as well as on international and do- based on a normative conception of PES. First, identifying stake-
mestic conditions. The set of the four prior enabling conditions holders' interests and policy window may help institutionalise PES
comprised: (1) a clearly defined and widely acknowledged defor- schemes. Second, understanding the interplay between actors may
estation issue; (2) the existence of specific public administration
help to design and implement legitimate PES in a given context
and incentive programmes; (3) consolidated organisations re-
(Corbera et al., 2007; Gross-Camp et al., 2012). Third, analysis of
presenting the interests of forestry stakeholders; and (4) new ideas
the policy process may help better understand and overcome in-
about the representation of the forest and support schemes. In
addition, in the mid-1990s, international conditions both threa- herent difficulties in PES design and implementation such as the
tened the funding of existing instruments, and created opportu- limited willingness of the private sector to invest in PES, the lim-
nities for new funding of this instrument. At the same time, do- ited efficiency or equity of PES, and the conjunction of multiple
mestic conditions pushed the PESP forward, thanks to newly elec- objectives (Wunder et al., 2008; Muradian et al., 2010). To con-
ted elites who were members of international ecological economics clude, whereas most PES design processes emphasised ES valua-
networks and a powerful interest group in the forestry sector. tion and the identification of ES demand and funding mechanisms,
From the Costa Rican experience, we believe that the main is- the Costa Rican experience shows that a great deal of attention
sue for PES design and implementation is the ability to achieve a should be paid to the policy process and to the interplay between
compromise among interest groups with divergent views of nat- actors. Strengthening organisations that are representative of the
ural resources. A strong leading group and good relationship be- ES offer and creating dialogue between divergent interest groups
tween public and private representatives are keys to achieving
involved in the management of natural resources are keys to the
institutionalisation and legitimacy of the PES which are key con-
successful design of sustainable PES.
ditions for their sustainability. In Costa Rica, no strong organised
groups were opposed to forest conservation. Conversely, in many
tropical countries, agricultural or wood extraction lobbies are still
Acknowledgements
strong and may limit adoption or implementation of a PES pro-
gramme strictly oriented towards conservation. Searching for a
This research was funded by the French National Agency of
compromise including tree plantation for production as well as
forest conservation could be a way to increase the social support of Research (ANR-08-STRA-13). We acknowledge the support of
the interest groups for conservation and PES programmes. SERENA (Environmental Services and Rural Space Uses) project
While Costa Rica is considered as a world reference for PES, we and Cécile Fovet-Rabot for useful comments on previous versions
argue that insufficient attention has been paid to the PESP policy of the manuscript. The views expressed and any errors remain our
process when drawing lessons for the development of PES in other own responsibility.

Appendix A.

Key representatives and stakeholders interviewed on the subject of the PESP policy process (42 face-to-face qualitative interviews;
2008-2012; Costa Rica).

(Number of interviewees as a function of their origin) Total

Civil servants FONAFIFO (5); SINAC (3); CIA(2); MAG (2) 12


Forestry sector organisations ONF (2), CCF (3), JUNAFORCA (1), Fundecor (3), Codeforsa (1), private enterprise (1) 11
Conservationist organizations Fecon (1), Asoprofleifas (2), others (4) 7
Agricultural organisations MNC (1), UPA Nacional (1), UNAG (1), Other (3) 6
Politicians ex minister (1), ex deputies (3) 4
Academics UNA (3), UCR (2), TEC (1), CATIE (3), other (3) 12
Total 42

List of acronyms:

FONAFIFO Fondo Nacional de Financiamiento Forestal UCR Universidad de Costa Rica


SINAC Sistema Nacional de Área de Conservación TEC Tecnológico de Costa Rica
CIA Colegio de Ingenieros Agrónomos CATIE Centro Agronómico Tropical de Investigación y de
MAG Ministerio de Agricultura y Ganadería Enseñanza
ONF Oficina Nacional Forestal
CCF Cámara Costarricense Forestal
JUNAFORCA Junta Nacional Forestal Campesina
FECON Costa Rican federation of conservationists Appendix B.
MNC Mesa Nacional Campesina
UPA Nacional National Syndicate of small and medium-scale Interview guideline
agricultural producers
UNA Universidad Nacional de Costa Rica 1. The interviewee presents him/herself
264 J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265

The interviewee is invited to briefly present his/her curriculum vitae, including training, and job experience to enable the interviewer to
grasp the interviewee's main role and functions in public or private organisations, and his/her role in the PESP policy process.
2. Analysis of the main decisions made during the PESP policy process and their outputs

A list of changes in governance decisions to be analysed with the interviewees was drawn up (based on our desk review and pre-
liminary interviews with FONAFIFO civil servants).
These decisions concerned the emergence of the PESP and the decision process embedded in the 4th law, on the one hand, and changes
in governance features during the implementation phase of the PESP, on the other hand.
It specifically concerned the choice regarding

1. The content of the 4th forestry law (ban on changes in land use, etc.) and the specific articles regarding PES (scope and definition of ES,
management and funding source);
2. The choice of PES modalities, the level of payment per modality, the decision on budget allocation among the modalities, modes of
access and conditions (prerequisites), prioritisation criteria, funding sources and PES management (including composition of the FO-
NAFIFO board, the monitoring and control process)
For each decision identified, depending on the interviewee's background, the following issues were discussed:
3. How and why was this decision taken?
4. What was the context of the decisions (external, internal factors, etc.)?
5. Who were the main actors involved in the decision?
6. What were the positions, arguments, resources, and the strategy of the different stakeholders?
7. How was the final decision taken? Based on which criteria and justification?

References

Anderson, J., 1975. Public Policy-Making. Holt, Rinehart and Winston, New York. Modelo Costarricense de Desarrollo en Alianza con la Naturaleza. EUNED, San
Baltodano, J., 2007. Bosque, cobertura y uso forestal. Décimo tercer informe estado Jose.
de la nación en desarrollo humano sostenible, Costa Rica. 〈http://www.estado Costanza, R., Segura, O., Martinez-Alier, J., 1996. Getting down to earth: practical
nacion.or.cr/Info2007/Ponencias/Armonia/Bosque-recursosforestales.pdf〉 (Re- applications of ecological economics. Island Press, Washington DC, United States
visado por última vez 13.08.09). Daniels, A.E., Bagstad, K., Esposito, V., Moulaert, A., Rodriguez, C.M., 2010. Under-
Barrantes, A., 2009. La organización del sector forestal en Costa Rica. Ambientico standing the impacts of Costa Rica's PES: are we asking the right questions?
186, 3–5. Ecol. Econ. 69, 2116–2126.
Barton, D.N., Faith, D.P., Rusch, G.M., Acevedo, H., Paniagua, L., Castro, M., 2009. De Camino, R., Segura, O., Arias, L.G., Perez, I., 2000. Costa Rica: Forest Strategy and
Environmental service payments: evaluating biodiversity conservation trade- the Evolution of Land Use. The World Bank (OED), Washington.
offs and cost-efficiency in the Osa Conservation Area, Costa Rica. J. Environ. Echeverría, J., Hanrahan, M., Solórzano, R., 1995. Valuation of non-priced amenities
Manag. 90, 901–911. provided by the biological resources within the Monteverde Cloud Forest Pre-
Bernauer, T., Gampfer, R., 2013. Effects of civil society involvement on popular le- serve, Costa Rica. Ecol. Econ. 13, 43–52.
gitimacy of global environmental governance. Global Environmental Change 23, Engel, S., Pagiola, S., Wunder, S., 2008. Designing payments for environmental ser-
439–449. vices in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecol. Econ. 65, 663–674.
Blackman, A., Woodward, R.T., 2010. User financing in a national payments for en- Evans, S., 1999. The Green Republic: A Conservation History of Costa Rica. University
vironmental services program: Costa Rican hydropower. Ecol. Econ. 69, of Texas Press, Texas, United States.
1626–1638. Fletcher, R., Breitling, J., 2012. Market mechanism or subsidy in disguise? Governing
Boscolo, M., Dijk, K.V., Savenije, H., 2010. Financing sustainable small-scale forestry: payment for environmental services in Costa Rica. Geoforum 43, 402–411.
lessons from developing national forest financing strategies in Latin America. FONAFIFO, 2005. FONAFIFO Over a Decade of Action. MINAET, San Jose.
Forests 1, 230–249. FONAFIFO, 2012. Costa Rica Tropical forests: A Motor for Green Growth. Río þ20
Bosselmann, A.S., Lund, J.F., 2013. Do intermediary institutions promote inclusive- The future we want. MINAET–FONAFIFO, San Jose.
ness in PES programs? The case of Costa Rica. Geoforum 49, 50–60. Froger, G., Méral, P., 2012. Towards an institutional and historical analysis of en-
Brewer, G.D., 1974. The policy sciences emerge: to nurture and structure a discipline. vironmental policy in madagascar. Environ. Policy Gov. 22, 369–380.
Policy Sci. 5, 239–244. Gottfried, R.R., Brockett, C.D., Davis, W.C., 1994. Models of sustainable development
Brockett, C.D., Gottfried, R.R., 2002. State policies and the preservation of forest and forest resource management in Costa Rica. Ecol. Econ. 9, 107–120.
cover: lessons from contrasting public-policy regimes in Costa Rica. Lat. Am. Res. Gross-Camp, N.D., Martin, A., McGuire, S., Kebede, B., Munyarukaza, J., 2012. Pay-
Rev. 37, 7–40. ments for ecosystem services in an African protected area: exploring issues of
Calvo-Alvarado, J., McLennan, B., Sánchez-Azofeifa, A., Garvin, T., 2009. Deforesta- legitimacy, fairness, equity and effectiveness. Oryx 46, 24–33.
tion and forest restoration in Guanacaste, Costa Rica: putting conservation po- Hall, P.A., 1997. The role of Interests, Institutions, and Ideas in the Comparative
licies in context. For. Ecol. Manag. 258, 931–940. Political Economy of Industrialized Nations. In: Lichbach, Mark, Zuckerman,
Camacho, M.A., Segura, O., Reyes, V., Aguilar, A., 2000. Pago Por Servicio Ambientales Alan (Eds.), Comparative Politics. Rationality, Culture, and Structure. Cambridge
en Costa Rica Preparatory Report of the Prisma-ford Fund Ation Proyect "Pago University Press, Cambridge, pp. 174–207.
Por Servicios Ambientales en Latin America". San Jose, p. 65. Hassenteufel, P., 2008. Sociologie Politique: l'action Publique. Armand Colin, Paris.
Campos Arce, J.J., 1991. The Boscosa Project: Case Study of Sustainable Natural Re- Hrabanski, M., Bidaud, C., Le Coq, J.-F., Méral, P., 2013. Environmental NGOs, policy
source Management in the Osa Peninsula, Costa Rica. Fundación Neotrópica, entrepreneurs of market-based instruments for ecosystem services? A com-
Costa Rica. parison of Costa Rica, Madagascar and France. For. Policy Econ. 37, 124–132.
Castro, R., Tattenbach, F., Gamez, L., Olson, N., 2000. The Costa Rican experience with Kingdon, J.W., 1995. Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies. Longman, New York.
market instruments to mitigate climate change and conserve biodiversity. En- Kosoy, N., Martinez-Tuna, M., Muradian, R., Martinez-Alier, J., 2007. Payments for
viron. Monit. Assess. 61, 75–92. environmental services in watersheds: Insights from a comparative study of
Chomitz, K.M., Brenes, E., Constantino, L., 1999. Financing environmental services: three cases in Central America. Ecol. Econ. 61, 446–455.
the Costa Rican experience and its implications. Sci. Total Environ. 240, 157–169. Landell-Mills, N., Porras, I.T., 2002. Silver bullet or fools’ gold? A global review of
Contraloria General de la Republica, 2011. Informe Acerca de Los Efectos del Pro- markets for forest environmental services and their impact on the poor. IIED,
grama Pago Por Servicios Ambientales (PSA) Implementado Por el Estado London.
Costarricense. San Jose. Lansing, D.M., 2013. Understanding linkages between ecosystem service payments,
Corbera, E., Brown, K., Adger, W.N., 2007. The equity and legitimacy of markets for forest plantations, and export agriculture. Geoforum 47, 103–112.
ecosystem services. Dev.and Chang. 38, 587–613. Laswell, H., 1956. The Decision Process. 7 Categories of Functional Analysis. Uni-
Corbera, E., Soberanis, C.G., Brown, K., 2009. Institutional dimensions of Payments versity of Maryland Press, College Park.
for Ecosystem Services: an analysis of Mexico's carbon forestry programme. Le Coq, J.-F., Froger, G., Legrand, T., Pesche, D., Saenz-Segura, F., 2013. The govern-
Ecol. Econ. 68, 743–761. ance of Costa Rica's programme of payments for environmental services: A
Costa Rica. Presidencia de la República, 1994. Del Bosque a la Sociedad: un Nuevo stakeholder's perspective. In: Muradian, R., Rival, L. (Eds.), Governing the
J.-F. Le Coq et al. / Ecosystem Services 16 (2015) 253–265 265

Provision of Ecosystem Services. Springer, Dordrecht, pp. 237–257 [Pays-Bas]. Robalino, J., Pfaff, A., 2013. Ecopayments and deforestation in Costa Rica: a na-
Le Coq, J.-F., Pesche, D., Legrand, T., Froger, G., Saenz-Segura, F., 2012. La mise en tionwide analysis of PSA’s initial years. Land Econ. 89, 432–448.
politique des services environnementaux : la genèse du programme de paie- Robalino, J., Pfaff, A., Villalobos, L., 2011. Assessing impacts of institutional design of
ments pour services environnementaux au Costa Rica. VertigO 12, 25. Payments for Environmental Services. The Costa Rican experience. In: Declerck,
Legrand, T., Froger, G., Le Coq, J.-F., 2013. Institutional performance of Payments for Rapidel, Beer, Le. Coq (Eds.), Ecosystem Services From Agriculture and Agro-
Environmental Services: an analysis of the Costa Rican Program. For. Pol- forestry. Measurement and Payment. Earthscan, London, pp. 305–318.
icy Econ. 37, 115–123. Lemos, M.C., Agrawal, A., 2006. Environmental governance. Annu. Rev. Environ.
Locatelli, B., Rojas, V., Salinas, Z., 2008. Impacts of payments for environmental Resour. 31, 297–325.
services on local development in northern Costa Rica: a fuzzy multi-criteria Rojas M., Aylward B., What are we learning from markets for environmental ser-
analysis. For. Policy Econ. 10, 275–285. vices? A review and critique of the literature, Markets for Environmental Ser-
Matulis, B.S., 2013. The narrowing gap between vision and execution: neoliber- vices Series, 2003. IIED, London, 102 p.
alization of PES in Costa Rica. Geoforum 44, 253–260. Rosa, H., Kandel, S., Dimas, L., 2004. Compensation for environmental services and
Matzdorf, B., Sattler, C., Engel, S., 2013. Institutional frameworks and governance rural communities: lessons from the Americas 1. International Forestry Review
structures of PES schemes. For. Policy Econ. 37, 57–64. 6, 187–194.
McAfee, K., Shapiro, E.N., 2010. Payments for ecosystem services in Mexico: nature, Rosendal, G.K., Schei, P.J., 2014. How may REDDþ affect the practical, legal and
neoliberalism, social movements, and the state. Ann. Assoc. Am. Geogr. 100, institutional framework for ‘Payment for ecosystem services’ in Costa Rica?
579–599. Ecosyst. Serv. 9, 75–82.
Miranda, M., Porras, I.T., Moreno, M.L., 2003. The Social Impacts of Payments for Sabatier, P.A. (Ed.), 2007. Theories of the Policy Process, 2nd ed. Westwiew Press,
Environmental Services in Costa Rica. A Quantitative Field Survey and Analysis Boulder, San Fransisco, Oxford.
of the Virilla Watershed. International Institute for Environment and Devel- Sage, L., Sanchez, O., 2002. Evolucion esperada para el mercado de pago de servicios
opment (IIED), London. ambientales en Costa Rica. Revista Forestal Centroamericana 37, 72–73.
Molina Murillo, S.A., Pérez Castillo, J.P., Herrera Ugalde, M.E., 2014. Assessment of Sanchez-Azofeifa, G.A., Pfaff, A., Robalino, J.A., Boomhower, J.P., 2007. Costa Rica's
environmental payments on indigenous territories: the case of Cabecar-Tala- payment for environmental services program: intention, implementation, and
manca, Costa Rica. Ecosyst. Serv. 8, 35–43. impact. Conserv. Biol. 21, 1165–1173.
Muñoz-Piña, C., Guevara, A., Torres, J.M., Braña, J., 2008. Paying for the hydrological Sattler, C., Trampnau, S., Schomers, S., Meyer, C., Matzdorf, B., 2013. Multi-classifi-
services of Mexico's forests: analysis, negotiations and results. Ecol. Econ. 65, cation of payments for ecosystem services: How do classification characteristics
725–736. relate to overall PES success? Ecosyst. Serv. 6, 31–45.
Muradian, R., Corbera, E., Pascual, U., Kosoy, N., May, P.H., 2010. Reconciling theory Segura-Bonilla, O., 2003. Competitiveness, systems of innovation and the learning
and practice: an alternative conceptual framework for understanding payments economy: the forest sector in Costa Rica. For. Policy Econ. 5, 373–384.
for environmental services. Ecol. Econ. 69, 1202–1208. Surel, Y., 2000. The role of cognitive and normative frames in policy-making. J. Eur.
Muradian, R., Rival, L., 2012. Between markets and hierarchies: the challenge of Public Policy 7, 495–512.
governing ecosystem services. Ecosyst. Serv. 1, 93–100. Swallow, Leimona, B., Yatich, B., Velarde, S., T., 2010. The conditions for functional
Navarro, G.A., Bermúdez, G., 2013. Análisis económico del impacto de las re- mechanisms of compensation and reward for environmental services. Ecol. Soc.
stricciones técnicas y legales sobre la rentabilidad del manejo bosques natur- 15, 6.
ales y su competitividad respecto a otros usos de la tierra en Costa Rica. USAID, 1996. Forestry and the Environment: Costa Rica Case Study. USAID, Wa-
Newig, J., Fritsch, O., 2009. Environmental governance: participatory, multi-level – shington DC, PN-ABS-531.
and effective? Environ. Policy Gov. 19, 197–214. Vatn, A., 2014. Markets in environmental governance—from theory to practice. Ecol.
Pagiola, S., 2008. Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica. Ecol. Econ. 65, Econ. 105, 97–105.
712–724. Wunder, S., 2005. Payment for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts. CI-
Pfaff, A., Robalino, J., 2012. Protecting forests, biodiversity, and the climate: pre- FOR, Occasional Paper n°42. Bogor, p. 24.
dicting policy impact to improve policy choice. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 28, Wunder, S., Albán, M., 2008. Decentralized payments for environmental services:
164–179. the cases of Pimampiro and PROFAFOR in Ecuador. Ecol. Econ. 65, 685–698.
Porras, I., 2010. Fair and Green?: Social Impacts of Payments for Environmental Wunder, S., Engel, S., Pagiola, S., 2008. Taking stock: a comparative analysis of
Services in Costa Rica. IIED, London. payments for environmental services programs in developed and developing
Porras, I., Barton, D.N., Miranda, M., Chacón-Cascante, A., 2013. Learning from 20 countries. Ecol. Econ. 65, 834–852.
years of payments for ecosystem services in Costa Rica. IIED. 〈http://pubs. iied. Zahariadis, N., 2007. The multiple streams framework: structure, limitations, pro-
org/16514IIED. html〉 (accessed 17.12.12). spects. In: Sabatier, P. (Ed.), Theories of the Policy Process. Westvview Pres,
Quintero, M., Wunder, S., Estrada, R.D., 2009. For services rendered? Modeling Cambridge, pp. 65–92.
hydrology and livelihoods in Andean payments for environmental services Zbinden, S., Lee, D.R., 2005. Paying for environmental services: an analysis of par-
schemes. For. Ecol. Manag. 258, 1871–1880. ticipation in Costa Rica's PSA Program. World Dev. 33, 255–272.

You might also like