You are on page 1of 11

Reconciling Alternative Estimates of the Elasticity of Substitution

Author(s): Ernst R. Berndt


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 58, No. 1 (Feb., 1976), pp. 59-68
Published by: The MIT Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1936009 .
Accessed: 16/08/2013 05:34

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of
Economics and Statistics.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
RECONCILING ALTERNATIVE ESTIMATES OF THE
ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION
Ernst R. Berndt*
I. Introduction and cross-sectional evidence of substitution"
(1969, p. 259).
A large numberof econometricstudieshave In this paper we report results of a rather
focused on possibilities for capital-labor successful attempt to reconcile the differing
substitution in U.S. manufacturing. The evi- estimates of cr. While it may be desirable to
dence, however, indicates substantial disagree- consider separately and systematically the con-
ment over the value of the elasticity of substi- tribution of each of the above hypotheses in
tution (cr). Studies based on cross-sectional reconciling the cr estimates, here we limit our
data provide estimates which are quite close concern to two principal areas: (1) data -we
to unity, but time series studies generally re- attempt to construct time series data on the
port lower estimates. Furthermore, estimates cost of capital services in a more detailed man-
of or seem to vary systematically with the ner than previous researchershave, taking into
choice of functional form: regressions based account real and nominal rates of return, asset
on the marginal product of capital relation prices, depreciation, tax policies, and composi-
generally produce lower estimates of cr than tional changes in aggregate capital between
regressions based on the marginal product of equipment and structures; (2) stochastic spec-
labor relation. A variety of hypotheses have ification -we estimate cr by a two-stage least
been advanced to explain the diversity of re- squares (2SLS) procedure to circumvent the
sults, including cyclical changes in the utiliza- problemof simultaneousequations bias by ordi-
tion of factors (Nerlove, 1967), random mea- nary least squares (OLS). We then compare
surement errors (Leontief, 1964), systematic estimates of a- based on six different functional
variation of input prices with product prices forms, five alternative measures of the rental
(Nerlove, 1967), embodied and disembodied price of capital services, and two estimation
technical change and problems in the measure- methods.
ment of inputs (Griliches, 1967a; Hildebrand Our most sobering result is that estimates
and Liu, 1965), simultaneous equations bias of Cr are extremely sensitive to differences in
(Maddala and Kadane, 1966; Nerlove, 1967), measurement and data construction. In this
serial correlation (Griliches, 1967a), and lagged respect we concur with Nerlove who finds that
adjustment (Griliches, 1967a; Lucas, 1969; "even slight variations in the period or con-
Jorgenson, 1972). In general, empirical studies cepts tend to produce drastically different esti-
attempting to take account of these deficiencies mates of the elasticity" (1967, p. 58). How-
have produced unsatisfactory results. Zvi Gri- ever, with our preferred set of data we obtain
liches, for example, finds that "the labor qual- OLS and 2SLS time series estimates of o-
ity variables . . . contribute little in the elas- which exhibit robustness over a variety of
ticity-of-substitution context" (1967a, p. 296), functional forms and time periods, and are
while R. E. Lucas, Jr. concludes that lagged consistent with the cross-sectional evidence.
adjustment hypotheses "make essentially no
contribution to the reconciling of time series II.
Review of the Literature
Let there be an aggregate production func-
Received for publication March 26, 1974. Revision ac- tion V - V(K,L,X3,X4,.. ., Xm,A) character-
cepted for publication December 30, 1974.
* The helpful comments of L. R. Christensen, M. K. ized by constant returns to scale in the input
Denny, W. Erwin Diewert, Arthur S. Goldberger, Charles quantities, where V is the flow of gross output,
R. Hulten, Dale W. Jorgenson, T. J. Wales, A. D. Wood- K is the flow of services from capital equipment
land, and Paul Zarembka are gratefully acknowledged.
Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the and structures, L is the flow of services from
author. productionand nonproductionlabor, the X's are
[ 59 1

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
60 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
other inputs, and A is an index of technical effi- Zarembka report results in which estimates of
ciency. We assume that any technical change a- based on (1') are generally lower than those
affecting the inputs is Hicks-neutral. This based on (2').
allows us to write V - AH, where A is in- Time series studies have generally provided
terpreted as the index of total factor produc- lower (r estimates than cross-section studies.
tivity and H is the aggregate input function' Robert E. Lucas, Jr. has estimated o- based on
H H(K,L,X3,X4, . . , XM). Further, we
. (2) with a time trend term added; he concludes
assume that K and L are weakly separable from that "the time series estimates are centered in
all other inputs in H, i.e., H - J(F(K,L),X3, the range 0.3 to 0.5" (1969, p. 251). Robert M.
X4, . . ., X,). Like previous researchers, we Coen (1969) has estimated a distributed lag
specify that F can be represented by the CES function based on (1) and finds that his best
form F - (8K-P + (1 - 8)L-P)-'1P in which fit occurs when cr- 0.2. Similar low time series
case , - 1/ (1 + p). Assuming that markets estimates of o- have been obtained by Robert
are competitive, we take logarithms of the mar- Eisner and M. I. Nadiri (1968) based on a dis-
ginal productivity relations, rearrange,and ob- tributed lag variant of (1). The time series
tain results of Lucas, Coen, and Eisner-Nadiri are
In (F/K) a, + crln (PK/P) (1) similar to the cross-sectional evidence of
Dhrymes-Zarembka in that estimates of o-
In (F/L) - a2 + cr n (PL/P), (2)
based on the marginal product of capital rela-
where PK and PL are the input prices of capital tion are generally smaller than estimates based
and labor services, P is the price of aggregate on the marginalproduct of labor relation. G. S.
input F, and the constant terms a, and a2 are Maddala (1965) has estimated oCbased on the
nonlinear combinations of 8 and o. If we sub- ratio of marginal products (3). Although his
tract (1) from (2), we obtain a third equation time series estimates vary considerably, they
independentof F and P: are centered in the range 0.1 to 0.2.
In (K/L) - a3 crln (PK/PL)*
- (3) The finding that time series elasticities are
lower than cross-sectionalestimates is a familiar
Assuming that P is constant across states and one in demandanalysis. Based on lagged adjust-
regions, Zvi Griliches (1967b), Robert Solow
ment models, Lucas has attempted to reconcile
(1964), Paul Zarembka (1970), Paul Za-
the evidence. He finds, however, that the lagged
rembka-Helen Chernicoff (1971), and Phoe-
adjustment hypotheses "make essentially no
bus Dhrymes-Paul Zarembka (1970) have re-
contribution to the reconciling of time series
written (1) and (2) as
and cross-sectional evidence of substitution"
In (PF/K) a', + clnPK, (1') (1969, p. 259). A related finding has been re-
and ported by Griliches (1967a), who compares
In (PF/L) a'2 + o-in PL- (2') successive cross-sections for 1957 and 1958 and
The general conclusionemergingfrom the cross- finds that he must reject the partial adjustment
section studies based on (2') is that "there is model, but cannot reject the serial correlation
no significant evidence that the elasticity of model.
substitution at the two-digit level departs from In the above studies it has been assumed that
unity" (Zarembka, 1970, p. 53) .2 Dhrymes and prices are exogenous. If, in fact, prices are
endogenous, OLS estimation will yield incon-
1 The concept of an aggregate input function was intro- sistent parameter estimates. In our context, the
duced by Robert M. Solow (1957). It has also been em- direction of the bias cannot be determined; see
ployed by Jorgenson and Griliches (1972), Christensen, G. S. Maddala and Joseph B. Kadane (1966).
Jorgenson, and Lau (1973), and Berndt and Christensen
(1973, 1974). Even if both prices and quantities are endog-
2Nerlove (1967, pp. 73-74) has argued that the assump- enous, in small samples it may be desirable
tion of constant P across regions is questionable, for P is
likely to be positively correlated with PK or PL. Failure (1967a), however, has found the bias to be negligible. For
to take account of this when estimating (1') and (2') further discussion of the potential biases using (2'), see
biases the estimated value of o- toward unity. Griliches Lucas (1969, pp. 236-245) and Griliches (1967a).

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION 61
to ignore the simultaneous equations bias and that the R2 based on a simple regression model
estimate the reciprocal regressions from (1), Y = a + ,/X + u is the same as the R2 from
(2) and (3) by OLS: X = 8 + yY + v (R2 here is merelythe squared
ln (PK/P) a4 (1/o-) ln (F/K) (4) sample correlation coefficient between X and
ln (PL/P) (1/o-) ln (F/L) (5)
Y); further, R2 =38"y", where /8" and y" are
a4 +
least squares estimates of /8 and y. Thus, in
ln (PK/PL) a6 -(i/o-) ln (K/L). (6)
our context OLS estimates of o- will always be
Hereafter we denote the estimates of o- based on subject to the inequality relations:
equations ( 1) through (6) by o-r,i 1,.. , 6.
cTl < 04, 2< -5, and 03 < 06, (7)
Since the direction of the possible simulta-
neous equations bias cannot in general be de- because cr1/o-4 R12 R42, o2/or5 R2
termined,Maddala and Kadane have performed R52, and oJ3/'6 = R3- 2 R62, where the sub-
a Monte Carlo study in which they compare script on R2 refers to the squared correlation
small sample properties of 02 and or5.4They coefficientof the equation being estimated.
find that 02 estimates are biased downward, As a matter of historical development,
that the bias is fairly large except when true Dhrymes (1965) reportedthat his results were
values of o- are close to unity, and that 0r5 esti- based on (2'); subsequently Dhrymes and
mates are more robust in the face of simulta- Zarembka (1970) discovered that the Dhrymes
neous equations misspecification.To our knowl- reported results were erroneousand were based
edge, however, cross-section or time series on the "other regression"-the logarithm of
studies estimating o5 have not been reported the wage rate on the logarithm of the output-
in the literature. Maddala (1965) has estimated labor ratio. Dhrymes and Zarembka (1970)
cr3and cr6 from the reciprocal regressions (3) claim to have corrected this error. A puzzling
and (6); his OLS time series estimates of or3 aspect of their correction, however, is that R2
are centered in the range 0.1 to 0.2, while those figures reported by Dhrymes (1965) should
based on o-6 are centered in the range 0.4 to equal the R2 figures from the "corrected" re-
0.6.5 F. W. Bell (1965) has obtained cross- ciprocal regression reported in Dhrymes-
sectional estimates of o-6which in general are Zarembka (1970). This never occurs; in SIC
insignificantly different from unity;6 however, 35, for example, the two R2 figures are 0.2422
his o-6estimates are on average larger than his and 0.0043, while in SIC 37 they are 0.5129
o-2 estimates. and 0.7547. All one can conclude is that the
The above survey suggests that not only do "correction"is incomplete; either one or both
cross-section and time series estimates of oC of these studies must contain additional numer-
differ considerably, but estimates of o- are also ical errors.
sensitive to the equation fitted. It is easy to
show that a systematic variation in o- estimates
is due solely to choice of the equation fitted. III. Data Construction and Sources
In bivariate regressionanalysis it is well known The separationof capital outlay from owner-
utilized assets into price and quantity com-
3 The disturbance terms in (4), (5), and (6) are, of course, ponents is based on the equality in competitive
not the same as those in (1), (2), and (3). For a discussion equilibrium of the acquisition price of an asset
of the potential empirical significance of this problem, see and the discounted value of its services. This
Maddala-Kadane (1966) and Bodkin-Klein (1967).
4 Nerlove (1967) notes that if both prices and quantities equality implies a correspondence between
are subject to random measurement error (or if both are acquisition prices and rental or service prices.
endogenous in some larger system), then a2 and o-5 bracket Following Jorgenson (1974), we assume that
the consistent estimate.
5 The Maddala (1965) results are tabulated in table 7 of
the service flow of a given capital asset declines
Nerlove (1967). geometrically over time. The service price Pt
6Actually, Bell adds In (KIL) to both sides of (6). The obtained from the implied sequence of acquisi-
implicit OLS estimate of C- based on Bell's equation is, of
course, numerically equivalent to the OLS estimate based tion prices, is Pt qt-1rt + qt5 - (qt -qt-1),
on (6) itself. where qt is the acquisition price of the asset, r

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
62 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
the rate of return,and 8 the rate of depreciation. or s over the lifetime of the asset,7 k is the in-
The service price is the sum of the nominal cost vestment tax credit, y is kuze for 1962-1963
of capital, qt-lrt, the current cost of deprecia- and zero all other years, q, and q, are price
tion, qt8, and the cost of capital loss on the indices of new e or s in U.S. manufacturing,8r
value of the asset, -(qt - qt-i). Since the is the nominal after-tax rate of return on cor-
nominal rate of return rt is distinguished from porate property, t is the tax rate on corporate
the real rate of return, r*t, r*t rt- (qt- property, and 8e and As are rates of deprecia-
qt-l)/qt--, the service price is alternatively tion in U.S. manufacturing.9
expressed as the sum of the real cost of capital In order to assess the sensitivity of cr esti-
and the current cost of depreciation. mates to alternative data construction pro-
The presenceof tax policies alters this service cedures, we propose to construct five differing
price. Tax rates on property and income reduce price series for Pe and Ps:
the after-tax rate of return, while investment (a) Set all tax parametersin (8) and (9) to
tax credits and accelerated depreciation allow- zero, the real rate of return to the Moody AAA
ances reduce the net acquisition price of the corporatebond yield,"9and ignore capital gains.
asset. It might be reasonable to assume that at The Moody AAA bond yield has been employed
a particular point in time, effective tax rates as a measure of the cost of capital by Coen
and capital gains are equal across regions or (1968), Evans (1967), and Grunfeld (1960).
states. Over time, however, it seems reasonable (b) Set u and k to their statutory rates, t to
to expect considerablevariation in nominalrates zero, ze and z, to the values computed by
of return, effective tax rates, and capital gains. Christensen-Jorgenson,"the before-tax rate of
The time series studies by Hall and Jorgenson returnr' to be a constant 20%o,but let the after-
(1967, 1969), Coen (1969), and Eisner and tax rate of return vary according to r (1 -
Nadiri (1968) have taken asset prices and rates u)r', and continue to ignore capital gains. The
of depreciationinto account, but tax parameters principal advantage of price series (b) over
have been set to their statutory (rather than (a) is that (b) takes into account statutory tax
effective) rates, capital gains have been ignored, rates. The above relation between before- and
and before-tax real rates of return have been after-tax rates of return has been suggested by
assumed to be constant. Hall and Jorgenson (1967, 1969) and followed
Based on earlier work by Hall and Jorgenson by Coen (1969).
(1967) and Coen (1968), Christensenand Jor- (c) Follow all steps as in (b), except set the
genson (1969) have derived service price for- tax parameters u, k, and t equal to their effec-
mulas for producers' durable equipment (Pe) tive rates.'2 The principal advantage of this
and nonresidential structures (Ps) that take service price over (b) is that (c) takes into
these tax, depreciation, capital gains, and real account effective ratherthan statutory tax rates.
rate of return variables into account. Specifi- (d) Follow all procedures as in (c), except
cally, for the corporate sector in U.S. manu- use as the after-tax rate of return the nominal
facturing 1929-1968, the formulas are after-tax rate of return calculated by Christen-
1 utZet- kt + Yt sen and Jorgenson (1969). The nominal after-
1 Ut 7 The discount rate used in computing ze and zS is 10%,
which is very close to the mean nominal rate of return
4- qet6e - (qet - qe t-) + qettt (8) (9.39) over the 1929-1968 sample period.
8 The source of these data is Grose, et al. (1969); "con-
1utzst
-Ut stant cost 2" deflators are chosen because they represent
Pst 1 - (qs,t- irt + qjt8s an attempt to measure the unit price of output rather
than the unit cost of inputs.
(qst qs,t-1) )+ qsttty (9) 9 These depreciation rates are based on Berndt (1972)
and Berndt-Christensen (1973); 8E = .135 and 8A = .07 1.
where the subscript e refers to producers'dura- 10 The data series on the Moody AAA bond rate is taken
ble equipment, s to nonresidential structures, t from the Economic Report of the President, 1971.
to the time period, u is the corporateprofits tax 11 The data series on u, k, ze and z8 is found in Christen-
sen-Jorgenson (1969), table 5.
rate, ze and z, are the present value of deprecia- 12 These rates are presented in Christensen-Jorgenson
tion deductions on a dollar's investment in e (1969), table 5.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION 63
tax rate of return is computed from national we also construct an aggregate service price
accounting data as property income after taxes based on a fixed weight proceduresuggested by
and depreciation divided by the value of the Coen (1969), P*K .6Pe + .4P8. We construct
aggregate capital stock.'3 The principal advan- aggregate service prices of capital based on the
tage of this service price measureover (c) is that Pe and P8 series (a) and (b) using Coen's pro-
(d) is based on historical nominal after-tax rate cedure; those based on (c), (d), and (e) are
of return data as published in the U.S. National constructed using Tornqvist's (1936) discrete
Income and Product Accounts. Althoughrate of approximation to the continuous Divisia for-
return measures have been employed in numer- mula,
ous studies on investment behaviour, the return ln Pkt - ln P7,t1- i wi-t(ln Pit - InPi,t-)
measures in (a), (b), and (c) above are essen- i - e, s
tially unrelated to the historical national ac- where the weights Wit are arithmetic means of
counting data. the shares in the two periods
(e) Follow proceduresas in (d), but employ Wet = (PetEt/(PetEt + PstSt)), Wst
the real rather than the nominal rate of return -(PstSt/ (PetEt + P,tSt) ) .15
as the cost of capital measure. One possible The aggregate service prices based on series
problem with using such historical national ac-
counting data is that it may yield erratic and P, and P8 (a), (b), (c), (d), and (e) are de-
noted with capital letters A, B, C, D, and E;
volatile rates of return. A priori, it would seem table I summarizes their distinguishing fea-
reasonableto expect producersto look at a more
stable rate of return when deciding upon opti- TABLE 1. - SUMMARY OF ALTERNATIVE PROCEDURES
mal input levels. Over the 1929-1968 period USED TO CONSTRUCT PK

under consideration, the sample means of the


PK Rate of Return Aggregation Procedure
real and nominal rates of return are 6.4% and Index Measure Employed Used to Construct PK
9.3 %; more important, however, the sample Moody AAA corporate Coen's fixed weights
A
variance of the real after-tax rate of return is bond yield; no taxes
only about 30%7as large as that of the nominal B Constant before-tax Coen's fixed weights
after-tax rate of return. Because it is based on rate of return = 20i
historical data, and because the real after-tax statutory tax rates
rate of return is more stable than the nominal C Constant before-tax Divisia index
rate of return = .20;
after-tax rate of return, we prefer service price effective tax rates
measure (e). No doubt some errorsstill remain; D Nominal rate of return Divisia index
for example, producers are not always able to computed from historical
accurately predict the real rate of return even data; effective tax rates
though it is more stable than the nominal return. E Real rate of return com- Divisia index
However, we believe that (e) most accurately puted from historical
data; effective tax rates
measures the actual capital rentals faced by
producers.
Having computed these five alternative ser- tures. A is the index of poorest quallty; B takes
vice price measures of Pe and P8, we must now into account statutory tax rates and corresponds
construct an aggregate service price PE. We closely with the time series data construction
choose to construct our preferred data series by procedures followed by Coen (1969); C em-
employing a discrete approximation to the ploys effective tax rates and Divisia aggregation
Divisia index.'4 For purposes of comparison, methods; D uses as the rate of return measure
the nominal after-tax rate of return computed
13 The property income figure is net of capital gains from the National Income and Product Ac-
from sale of property. For further information regarding
procedures employed in measuring this rate of return, see 15 Measures of E and S are obtained by employing a
Christensen-Jorgenson (1969) and table 7.5, Office of Busi- perpetual inventory method with constant rates of deprecia-
ness Economics (OBE) (1966). tion, using data on investment in constant dollars from the
14Properties of the Divisia index have been discussed by OBE Capital Stock Study (Grose et al., 1969); see Berndt
M. Richter (1966), C. R. Hulten (1973), W. E. Diewert (1972) and Berndt-Christensen (1973) for further informa-
(1974), and Jorgenson-Griliches (1972, pp. 83-84). tion.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
64 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS-
counts; and E, our preferredmeasure, employs behaviour have been concerned with only a
real after-tax rates of return based on the his- subset of capital inputs - equipment.and struc-
torical national accounting data. tures. Other capital inputs like land, inventories,
Correspondingto each of the five alternative and working capital have been ignored. The
service prices, we construct series on K as K= measure of output employed in these studies of
(PetEt + P8tSt)/PKt.'6 Our measure of L is per- equipment,structures,and labor is value added.
sons engaged in U.S. manufacturing;PL is com- This is, of course, an inappropriateprocedure;
puted as compensation to employees in U.S. nominalvalue added will be larger than the sum
manufacturing, adjusted for the earnings of of the costs of equipment,structures,and labor,
proprietors, divided by L."7 because the costs of land, inventories,and work-
We now turn to a discussion of output price ing capital are ignored."9We conclude that for
and quantity indexes. Recall that in our gross two reasons- lack of proportionality among
output production function V = V(K,L,X3,X4, intermediate inputs and omission of certain
... , X,,,A) we assumed the existence of a capital inputs - it would be inappropriate for
weakly separable subfunction F F (K,L). us to use published value added figures as the
The "output" of the subfunction is, of course, measure of the "output" of the subfunction F.
an unobservable variable; the observable out- Robert M. Solow (1957) has suggested an
put is gross output from the production func- alternative method for constructing a measure
tion V. It has been traditionalin productionand of F which is based on a Divisia aggregateinput
investment studies to use as a measure of the index of K and L. Thus, the unobservable"out-
"output"of the subfunction F published series put" of the subfunction F is measured as ag-
on value added, deflated perhaps by some index gregate input. One potential problem with
of Hicks-neutraltechnicalefficiency.Since value Solow's method is that if markets do not adjust
added is constructed as gross output minus in- rapidly, the resulting disequilibriummay iinply
termediate materials, such a value added index that the value of output will not equal the sum
corresponds with F only if all quantities or of the values of the inputs. Such a problem
prices of the intermediate inputs move propor- might be of considerableimportancewith quar-
tionally with output quantity or price. His- terly time series data, but (hopefully) would be
torically such proportionalityhas not occurred; less significant with annual data. In this paper
for example, since until recently the price of we adopt Solow's procedurebecause we believe
energy has risen less rapidly than that of other that with annual data the benefits of not assum-
intermediate inputs, the quantity of energy de- ing proportionalityamong the prices or quanti-
manded has risen more rapidly.'8Thus, propor- ties of the intermediate inputs and the omitted
tionality among intermediate inputs has not capital inputs outweigh the costs of temporary
occurred and the conventional value added in- disequilibriumcaused by lagged adjustment.
dex is an inappropriatemeasure of F. Correspondingwith each of the five alterna-
The concept of value added also serves as a tive aggregate service prices, we construct P,
device for allocating the origins of income to the price of aggregate input F, as a Divisia
services of the primary inputs - all types of price index of PK and PL; F is then constructed
capital and labor inputs. The vast majority of as ((PKK + PLL)/P). This measure of the
empirical studies on production and investment unobservable output F, like that of aggregate
capital services K, obviously depends on the
16For price indexes C, D, and E, PK is computed as a method employed in measuringthe rental price
Divisia index; the quantity index K is therefore an approxi- PK-
20
mate Divisia index. The empirical results reported in section
IV are essentially unchanged when the order is reversed,
i.e., if K is first computed as a Divisia quantity index, and 19 Value added would be perfectly correlated with F
then PK is constructed implicitly as an approximate Divisia only if the prices or quantities of all intermediate inputs
price index. and the omitted capital inputs moved proportionally. This
17 Compensation to employees includes wages, salaries, certainly has not been the case over the 1929-1968 period,
and supplements. For further discussion of these data, see e.g., the price or quantity indexes of land and energy have
Berndt-Christensen (1974) and OBE (1966), tables 6.1 not moved proportionally.
and 6.6. 20 Printouts of the data and constructed variables are
18 For further discussion, see Berndt and Wood (1975). available from the author upon request.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION 65
IV. Empirical Results favorably with those based on C, which indi-
cates that employing effective (rather than
Table 2 presents OLS and 2SLS estimates statutory) tax rates and Divisia (rather than
of Crfor the 1929-1968 time period, based on fixed weight) indexing procedures has only a
six different functional forms and five alterna- limited effect here. An obvious problem with
tive data constructionprocedures.2'Three strik- the OLS estimates based on B and C is their
ing conclusions emerge from table 2: (1) OLS lack of robustness with different functional
time series estimates of o approach unity as forms; for example, the B estimates range from
better methods of data measurement are used; 0.024 to 64.6555 and the C estimates from
(2) 2SLS estimates of Cr are larger than OLS -85.981 to 5.007.
estimates; and (3) alternative 2SLS estimates The pattern of estimates changes dramati-
of Cr based on the six functional forms are cally, however, when rate of return data based
reconciled with each other - all six estimates on the historical.national income and product
fall within the narrow range of 1.148 to 1.245. accounts are employed (procedures D and E).
The OLS estimates of Cr based on A are The variation among alternative OLS estimates
negative. Using data construction procedures is reduced substantially; for D the range is
and functional forms similar to those of Coen 0.441 to 0.707, while for E it is 0.960 to 1.238.
(1969), we obtain a o- estimate based on B OLS estimates based on D in equations 1, 2,
of 0.269 -very close to the 0.2 estimate re- and 3 are larger, while those in equations 4, 5,
ported by him. For functional forms 1, 3, 4, and 6 are smaller in absolute value than the
and 6, the OLS Crestimates based on B compare corresponding OLS estimates based on A, B,
and C data construction procedures. Further-
21 The excluded exogenous variables employed in the
more,when real rate of returndata are employed
2SLS regressions are those used in Berndt and Christensen
(1973, 1974); they are tabulated in the appendix tables of (procedure E), we find that all OLS estimates
(1973). are larger than those based on nominal rates of
TABLE 2. - ALTERNATIVE ESTIrMATES OF 0 FOR TOTAL U.S. MANUFACTURING 1929-1968

Estimation
Procedure: OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS 2SLS
Data
Procedure: A B C D E E
Functional
Form:

1 O*i -.079 .269 .250 .441 .967 1.148


S.E. (.202) (.149) (.156) (.035) (.082) (.098)
R2 .004 .079 .063 .805 .785 .757
D.W. .121 .154 .156 .618 2.162 2.656
2 0(2 -.651 .024 -.020 .604 .960 1.165
S.E. (.242) (.202) (.212) (.041) (.084) (.103)
R2 .161 .001 .001 .854 .776 .740
D.W. .148 .166 .168 .934 2.119 2.668
3 0(3 -.164 .234 .211 .466 .966 1.151
S.E. (.208) (.156) (.163) (.036) (.082) (.098)
R2 .016 .056 .042 .813 .784 .755
D.W. .125 .156 .158 .669 2.160 2.663
4 o4 -19.722 3.412 3.943 .548 1.231 1.233
S.E. (50.493) (1.892) (2.459) (.043) (.103) (.108)
R2 .004 .079 .063 .805 .785 .785
D.W. .036 .058 .048 1.008 2.699 2.699
5 Ur, -4.056 64.655 -85.981 .707 1.238 1.245
S.E. (1.504) (543.74) (915.33) (.046) (.108) (.113)
R2 .161 .001 .001 .854 .776 .775
D.W. .066 .051 .043 1.203 2.705 2.705
6 0e -10.137 4.171 5.007 .573 1.232 1.235
S.E. (12.820) (2.773) (3.869) (.044) (.104) (.108)
R2 .016 .056 .042 .813 .784 .784
D.W. .036 .055 .046 1.044 2.704 2.704
Note: S.E. refers to the estimated standarderror, while D.W. refers to the Durbin-Watson statistic.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
66 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
return (procedureD). Althoughthe E estimates specification may be of considerable impor-
fall on both sides of unity, all six OLS estimates tance, "all econometric results are no better
of C- based on the E procedure are insignifi- than the data that went into them" (Griliches,
cantly different from unity at the 0.025 level 1967a, p. 308). The data used in this study
of significance. Finally, when the OLS method have been constructed with considerable care,
of estimation is replaced by 2SLS, we find that but no doubt some errors still remain. Two po-
all estimates increase to values greater than tential sources of error are particularly worthy
(but insignificantly different from) unity. of further consideration.
It is interesting to note that the Durbin- First, if inputs adjust to their desired levels
Watson statistics generally increase as the qual- only after some time lag, marginal products
ity of the data constructionprocedureimproves. and relative input prices will differ, and markets
An abrupt increase in the D.W. statistic occurs will not be in full equilibrium. The theoretical
when real rather than nominal rates of return justification of our data construction is based
are employed (procedure E instead of D). This on the equilibrium assumption. For example,
suggests that the appropriate "remedy" for the rate of return calculation and the capital
serial correlation here is to construct better rental price measure are based on Euler's
data, ratherthan to employ a more sophisticated theorem and the equality in full competitive
estimation procedure on the inferior data. equilibriumof the acquisition price of an asset
It is also of interest to examine the stability and the discounted value of its services. Thus,
of the C- esti'mates throughout the 1929-1968 the theoretical justification of our data con-
time period. A variety of hypotheses could be struction measures is not strictly valid when
tested. Since substantial data gathering changes lagged adjustment is postulated. To fully ac-
took place in 1947, we choose to test the null count for lagged adjustment, it would be neces-
hypothesis that, based on the E data, the regres- sary to develop theoretical foundations of in-
sion coefficients for the 1929-1946 period are dexing prices, quantities, and marginalproducts
equal to those for the postwar 1947-1968 in disequilibrium markets. It might be con-
period.22We perform a Chow test on each of jectured that our failure to account for lagged
the six functional forms.23 Although point adjustment systematically biases certain of our
estimates of C- from the 1947-1968 period are cr estimates. The direction and magnitude of
slightly less than those from the 1929-1946 such a bias would be difficult to determine un-
period, with our E data the null hypothesis of less the specific form of the lag distribution
parameter equality in the two subperiods can- and the appropriate indexing procedures were
not be rejected. The calculated F-statistics with known. Table 2 suggests that if such a bias
2.36 degrees of freedom are 0.34, 0.28, 0.33, exists, it appears to be neutral with respect
1.64, 2.06, and 1.71 for the OLS regressions to functional form: E estimates of Cr based
based on (1) to (6) respectively, while the com- on the marginal product of capital relation,
parable 2SLS calculated F-statistics are 0.85, the marginal product of labor relation, and the
0.68, 0.84, 1.63, 2.05, and 1.70; the critical ratio of these marginal products (which is in-
value at the 0.05 level of significance is 3.26. dependent of F and P) are all close to one
another.24
Concluding Remarks A second possible source of error worthy of
Frequently, economists are faced with the further consideration is the proper treatment
task of attempting to reconcile inconsistent
24 It might also be conjectured that the cyclical sensitivity
empirical evidence. A common approach is to
of our D and E measures biases the results in favour of
investigate possible errors in functional and these service price formulas. In particular, when capital
stochastic specification. The implication of this gains or "pure profits" are large, investment and employ-
study is that although errors in stochastic ment also tend to be high. Thus, cyclical sensitivity of the
D and E measures would produce larger estimates of o-i
22 A similar hypothesis was tested in Berndt-Christensen and ur2.Although the D measure has a larger sample vari-
(1973, 1974). A discussion of the Bureau of Labor Statistics ance than E, the E index is particularly sensitive to cyclical
data gathering changes is provided in the statistical appendix fluctuations; for example, in periods of prosperity and sub-
of Berndt-Christensen (1974). stantial capital gains, the E service price measure is smaller
23See Johnston (1963), pp. 136-138. than D.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION 67
of non-neutral technical change. Considerable Evans, M. K., "A Study of Industry Investment Deci-
theoretical work still remains to be done on sions," this REVIEW (May 1967), 151-164.
appropriateindexing procedures for inputs and Griliches, Z., "Production Functions in Manufacturing:
Some Preliminary Results," in M. Brown (ed.),
outputs when technical change is not of the The Theory and Empirical Analysis of Production,
simple Hicks or Harrod neutral form. For ex- Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 32 (New York:
ample, input prices in terms of efficiency units, Columbia University Press, 1967a), 275-322.
rates of return to durable inputs, and measures "More on CES Production Functions," this RE-
of value added will be affectedwhen non-neutral VIEW (Nov. 1967b), 608-610.

technical change impingeson primary and inter- Grose, L., T. Rottenberg, and R. Wasson, "New Esti-
mates of Fixed Business Capital in the United
mediate inputs. States," Survey of Current Business (Feb. 1969),
46-52.
REFERENCES Grunfeld, Y., "The Determinants of Corporate Invest-
Bell, F. W., "A Note on the Empirical Estimation of the ment," in A. C. Harberger (ed.), The Demand for
CES Production Function with the use of Capital Durable Goods (Chicago: University of Chicago
Data," this REVIEW (Aug. 1965), 328-330. Press, 1960).
Berndt, E. R., "The Economic Theory of Separability, Hall, R. E., and D. W. Jorgenson, "Tax Policy and In-
Substitution, and Aggregation with an Application vestment Behavior," American Economic Review
to U.S. Manufacturing 1929-1968," unpublished (June 1967), 391-414.
Ph.D. thesis, University of Wisconsin, Madison, "Tax Policy and Investment Behavior: Reply
1972. and Further Results," American Economic Review
Berndt, E. R., and L. R. Christensen, "The Translog (June 1969), 388-401.
Function and the Substitution of Equipment, Struc-
Hildebrand, G. H., and T. C. Liu, Manufacturing Pro-
tures, and Labor in U.S. Manufacturing 1929- duction Functions in the U.S., 1957, Cornell Studies
1968," Journal of Econometrics (Mar. 1973), 81- in Industrial and Labor Relations, no. 15, Ithaca
114.
(1965).
, "Testing for the Existence of a Consistent Ag-
gregate Index of Labor Inputs," American Eco- Hulten, C. R., "Divisia Index Numbers," Econometrica
nomic Review (June 1974), 391-404. (Dec. 1973), 1017-1023.
Berndt, E. R., and D. 0. Wood, "Technology, Prices Johnston, J., Econometric Methods (New York: Mc-
and the Derived Demand for Energy," this REVIEW Graw-Hill, 1963).
(Aug. 1975), 259-268. Jorgenson, D. W., "Investment Behavior and the Pro-
Bodkin, R. G., and L. R. Klein, "Nonlinear Estimation duction Function," The Bell Journal of Economics
of Aggregate Production Functions," this REVIEW and Management Science (Spr. 1972), 220-251.
(Feb. 1967),28-44. "The Economic Theory of Replacement and
Christensen, L. R., and D. W. Jorgenson, "The Mea- Depreciation," in W. Sellekaerts (ed.), Economet-
surement of U.S. Real Capital Input, 1929-67," rics and Economic Theory: Essays in Honor of Jan
Review of Income and Wealth, Series 15 (Dec. Tinbergen (White Plains, N.Y.: International Arts
1969), 293-320. and Sciences Press, 1974).
Christensen, L. R., D. W. Jorgenson, and L. J. Lau, Jorgenson, D. W., and Z. Griliches, "Issues in Growth
"Transcendental Logarithmic Production Fron- Accounting: A Reply to Edward F. Denison," Sur-
tiers," this REVIEW (Feb. 1973), 28-45. vey of Current Business, 52 (May 1972), 65-94.
Coen, R. M., "Effects of Tax Policy on Investment in Leontief, W. W., "An Intemational Comparison of Fac-
Manufacturing,"American Economic Review (May tor Costs and Factor Use," American Economic Re-
1968), 200-211. view (June 1964), 335-345.
,"Tax Policy and Investment Behavior: A Com- Lucas, R. E., Jr., "Labor-Capital Substitution in U.S.
ment," American Economic Review (June 1969), Manufacturing," in A. C. Harberger and M. J.
370-379. Bailey (eds.), The Taxation of Income from Capi-
Dhrymes, P. J., "Some Extensions atid Tests for the tal (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution,
CES Class of Production Functions," this REVIEW 1969), 223-274.
(Nov. 1965), 357-366. Maddala, G. S., "Differential Industry Effects and Dif-
Dhrymes, P. J., and P. Zarembka, "Elasticities of Sub- ferential Factor Effects of Technological Change,"
stitution for Two-Digit Manufacturing Industries: Memo 36, Research Center in Economic Growth,
A Correction," this REVIEW (Feb. 1970), 115-117. Stanford University (Mar. 1965).
Diewert, W. E., "Homogeneous Weak Separability and Maddala, G. S., and J. B. Kadane, "Some Notes on the
Exact Index Numbers," forthcoming, Journal of Estimation of the Constant Elasticity of Substitu-
Econometrics. tion Production Function," this REVIEW (Aug.
Eisner, R., and M. I. Nadiri, "Investment Behavior and 1966), 340-344.
the Neo-Classical Theory," this REVIEW (Aug. Nerlove, M., "Recent Empirical Studies of the CES and
1968), 369-382. Related Production Functions," in M. Brown (ed.),

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
68 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
The Theory and Empirical Analysis of Production, , "Capital, Labor, and Income in Manufacturing,"
Studies in Income and Wealth, 32 (New York: in The Behavior of Income Shares, Studies in In-
Columbia University Press, 1967), 55-122. come and Wealth, vol. 27, (Princeton: Princeton
Office of Business Economics, The National Income and University Press, 1964), 101-128.
Product Accounts of the United States, 1929-1965: Tornqvist, L., "The Bank of Finland's Consumption
A Supplement to the Survey of Current Business Price Index," Bank of Finland Monthly Bulletin,
(Washington, D.C., U.S. Department of Commerce, no. 10 (1936) 1-8.
1966). Zarembka, P., "On the Empirical Relevance of the CES
Richter, M. D., "Invariance Axioms and Economic In- Production Function," this REVIEW (Feb. 1970),
dexes," Econometrica (Oct. 1966), 739-755. 47-53.
Solow, R. M., "Technical Change and the Aggregate Zarembka, P., and H. Chernicoff, "Further Results on
Production Function," this REVIEW(1957), 312- the Empirical Relevance of the CES Production
320. Function," this REVIEw(Feb. 1971), 106-110.

This content downloaded from 147.26.11.80 on Fri, 16 Aug 2013 05:34:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like