You are on page 1of 12

Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

Persuasion knowledge and consumer reactions to pricing tactics


David M. Hardesty a,1 , William O. Bearden b,2 , Jay P. Carlson c,∗
a University of Kentucky, Gatton College of Business & Economics, Lexington, KY 40506, United States
b University of South Carolina, Moore School of Business, Columbia, SC 29208, United States
c School of Management, Union Graduate College of Union University, Schenectady, NY 12308, United States

Accepted 30 June 2006

Abstract

The current research investigates consumer knowledge of the pricing tactics that marketers frequently employ and the effects of that
knowledge on responses to various price offers. In the research, a series of studies were conducted to develop and validate a knowledge
measure designed to assess pricing tactic persuasion knowledge (PTPK). Consistent with the persuasion knowledge model, individuals with
higher levels of PTPK were shown to have more knowledge-related thoughts regarding pricing tactic information than those with low levels of
PTPK. Additionally, pricing tactic persuasion knowledge was shown to be more predictive of consumer choices regarding quantity surcharge
offers and purchase interest evaluations following exposure to tensile claim offers (e.g., “Save up to 50 percent Off”) than several competing
constructs.
© 2007 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Consumer knowledge; Quantity surcharge; Persuasion knowledge model

Prior research has examined marketers’ reasons for suggests that what consumers know about how and why
employing different pricing tactics (e.g., Monroe 2003; Tellis marketers determine prices and price changes can affect con-
1986), as well as consumers’ responses to individual tactics, sumers’ perceptions of price fairness. As Campbell (1999, p.
such as comparative price claims (e.g., Blair et al. 2002), 198) argues, knowledge regarding selling tactics of marketers
everyday-low pricing (Darke and Chung 2005), pennies-a- can influence consumer responses to marketing stimuli such
day (Gourville 1998), and price matching (Kukar-Kinney as prices, price presentation, and price advertising.
and Walters 2003). Interestingly, the extant literature has not Second, studies based upon attribution theory, in which
investigated directly consumer knowledge of marketers’ pric- consistency and distinctiveness of pricing tactics have been
ing tactics, nor has it attempted to assess how this knowledge varied experimentally, support the premise that consumers
may affect consumers’ responses to such tactics. possess knowledge schemata that they use to evaluate price
Several theoretical perspectives that involve assumptions promotions and that they hold these beliefs with varying lev-
regarding underlying consumer knowledge of pricing tactics els of confidence (Lichtenstein and Bearden 1986, 1989). In a
attempt to explain consumers’ reactions to marketers’ offers. similar vein, Mela and Urbany (1996) found, based on a series
First, studies of price-fairness judgments implicitly assume of in-depth interviews, that consumers often make inferences
that consumers know something about price-setting strate- about seller behavior regarding price promotions, and that
gies (cf. Campbell 1999; Bolton et al. 2003). This research long-term patterns of price promotions can affect consumer
learning. Researchers have also investigated the varying per-
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 518 388 6738; fax: +1 518 388 6754. sonal tendencies of individuals to be aware of prices, and
E-mail addresses: david.hardesty@uky.edu (D.M. Hardesty), to have pricing knowledge. For example, some consumers
bbearden@moore.sc.edu (W.O. Bearden), carlsonj@union.edu
exhibit price mavenism, that is, “the degree to which an indi-
(J.P. Carlson).
1 Tel.: +1 859 257 9419; fax: +1 859 257 3577. vidual is a source of price information regarding products
2 Tel.: +1 803 777 4914; fax: +1 803 777 6876. and places to find low prices and responds to other con-

0022-4359/$ – see front matter © 2007 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2006.06.003
200 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

sumers’ requests for information” (Lichtenstein et al. 1993). ing general measures of persuasion knowledge confidence
Importantly, all of these theoretical perspectives suggest that (Bearden et al. 2001) or individual traits not necessarily spe-
consumers develop pricing tactic persuasion knowledge as a cific to price such as need for cognition (Petty and Cacioppo
result of their marketplace interactions, but research has yet 1981).
to directly study such knowledge (e.g., how such knowledge To investigate the ability of pricing tactic persuasion
might affect consumer responses to price offers). knowledge to moderate consumer phenomena, we first devel-
Using the parlance of persuasion knowledge (cf. Friestad oped a valid and reliable scale. Toward that objective, the
and Wright 1994), marketers (i.e., agents) create exchanges marketing literature was reviewed to identify the many tac-
in part by persuading consumers (i.e., targets) via specific tics that compose the domain of our subsequent objective
strategies for generating favorable perceptions regarding their knowledge measure. Table 1 depicts definitions from the
brands, stores, and offerings. One domain in which con- extant literature for each pricing tactic. Other selling tactics
sumers develop persuasion knowledge is in their beliefs categorized under consumer sales promotion such as rebate
regarding the tactics that marketers use to set and pro- restrictions, buy-one-get-one-free offers, and coupons were
mote prices. For example, marketers promote appeals such excluded.
as “Just $1.09 per issue for a 1-year subscription to
Sports Illustrated,” in attempts to persuade consumers that
the offerings are desirable. Similarly, marketers employ Measuring pricing tactic persuasion knowledge
claims like “Always low prices, always Wal-Mart,” so that
not only prices appear attractive, but also the marketers Consistent with prior measure development procedures,
themselves. we began by specifying the domain of pricing tactic persua-
Consumer pricing tactic persuasion knowledge consid- sion knowledge and then creating an initial pool of items
ers the marketer (e.g., the manufacturer, advertiser, retailer) based on the pricing literature and open-ended responses
to be the agent of persuasion, the consumer to be the from a large sample of consumers. Next, expert judges
target of persuasion, and the pricing tactic to reflect the assessed the content validity of the items in two phases.
persuasion attempt. Consumers learn to recognize that pric- Then, using methods consistent with test development the-
ing tactics include a range of holistic message themes ory (Crocker and Algina 1986), the final measurement items
(e.g., everyday-low-pricing), specific message elements (e.g., were selected. The operational measure of pricing tactic per-
external reference prices), and/or abstract configurations of suasion knowledge (PTPK) proposed to study the effects of
message elements (e.g., image pricing) (cf. Friestad and varying levels of consumer knowledge is a seventeen-item,
Wright 1994, p. 4). Pricing tactic persuasion knowledge rep- true–false objective index comprised of formative indica-
resents a form of domain-specific knowledge gained through tors (cf. Moorman et al. 2004).1 The measure represents
experience. a global assessment (Haynes et al. 1995) of knowledge
Consistent with the underlying premises of the PKM, our across different tactics that comprise the content domain
research focuses on consumer knowledge of pricing tactics of PTPK. We also provide evidence regarding test–retest
and the extent to which variance in this knowledge mod- reliability, convergent validity, and known-group validity
erates consumers’ reactions to influence attempts. As such, of the knowledge index. After providing evidence of reli-
our research addresses what Friestad and Wright (1994, p. ability and validity, we conducted Study 1 to assess the
2) cited as an important shortcoming in the extant consumer correspondence of open-ended consumer thought data with
behavior literature: the fact that researchers have infrequently PTPK. Finally, Study 2 and Study 3 investigate the impact
studied persuasion knowledge as a moderator of persuasion that PTPK has on two different pricing-related marketer
influence. tactics.
The main objectives, then, of the current research are
to develop and validate an index of pricing tactic persua- Domain specification and item development
sion knowledge and to investigate pricing tactic persuasion
knowledge as it moderates consumer responses to market- In order to generate an initial pool of items, two sources
place persuasion efforts. Pricing tactics include marketers’ were used: (1) a review of the relevant academic and trade lit-
efforts to generate favorable price perceptions regarding their erature, and (2) an open-ended elicitation of adult consumers.
brands, stores, and offerings. As such, the measure devel- The review of the marketing literature yielded a preliminary
oped here is similar to the advertising and personal selling set of 23 pricing tactics. In addition, 441 adult consumers
persuasion knowledge measures developed by Boush et al. of mixed age (M = 34 years) and gender (51 percent female)
(1994) and Campbell and Kirmani (2000), respectively, but
adds to this prior research by investigating consumers’ per-
1 The selection of a true–false format was based on both past literature and
suasion knowledge regarding marketers’ tactics related to
the need to balance knowledge assessment with scale response demands.
pricing. Moreover, the current context-specific pricing tac- The true–false measure is consistent with prior knowledge measures such
tic persuasion knowledge measure should be more predictive as Moorman et al. (2004) nutrition knowledge scale that included seven
of consumer responses to marketer pricing tactics than exist- true–false items.
D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210 201

Table 1
Pricing tactic definitions
Pricing tactic Definition
(1) Captive pricinga The core product is priced low and complementary items (e.g., accessories, supplies, spare parts) are priced
with a high premium (Noble and Gruca 1999, p. 438)
(2) Customary pricing When a retailer sets prices for a good or service and seeks to maintain those prices over an extended period of
time (Dunne et al. 2002, p. 377)
(3) Customer value pricinga Pricing one version of a product at very competitive levels while also offering fewer features than are available
on other versions (Noble and Gruca 1999, p. 438)
(4) Everyday-low-pricinga The seller sets a constant, everyday price with no (or very infrequent) temporary price promotions (Monroe
2003, p. 497)
(5) Image pricinga A firm brings out an identical version of its current product with a different name (or model number) and a
higher price in an attempt to signal quality (Tellis 1986, p. 156)
(6) Invoice ERP’sa The price the dealer pays the factory for an individual product (http://www.drivingtoday.com/features/
archive/invoice pricing/)
(7) Loss leader pricinga Featuring items priced below cost or at relatively low prices to attract customers to the seller’s place of business
(Monroe 2003, p. 639)
(8) Manufacturer’s suggested retail pricesa The seller presents the price offered by comparing it with a higher price suggested (listed) by the manufacturer
(Della et al. 1981, p. 416)
(9) Multiple unit pricing When consumers are exposed to multiple-unit prices instead of single-unit prices (e.g., “On sale – 6 cans for
$3 vs. “On sale – 50 cents”) (Wansink et al. 1998, p. 73)
(10) Nine-ending pricing The practice of setting prices just below a round number (Stiving and Winer 1997, p. 57)
(11) No haggle pricinga Prices are non-negotiable (Cason et al. 2003)
(12) No interest offersa When companies charge no interest in financing a purchase in order to stimulate early purchase (Kotler and
Keller 2006, p. 453).
(13) Partitioned pricinga Dividing a product’s price into two mandatory parts rather than charging a combined, all-inclusive price (Morwitz
et al. 1998, p. 453)
(14) Penetration pricinga Using low prices as a wedge to get into mass markets early (Monroe 2003, p. 382)
(15) Pennies-a-daya The temporal reframing of the cost of a product from an aggregate one-time expense to a series of small ongoing
expenses (Gourville 1998, p. 395)
(16) Premium pricing A firm exploits consumer heterogeneity in demand for a product by offering a superior version of that product
and charging a high (profitable price) for it (Tellis 1986, p. 155)
(17) Price bundlinga The sale of two or more separate products in a package at a discount, without any integration of the products.
(Stremersch and Tellis 2002, p. 56)
(18) Price discrimination When a company sells a product or service at two or more prices that do not reflect a proportional difference in
costs (Kotler and Keller 2006, p. 453)
(19) Price matching An offer to match the lowest price available in the market (Srivastava and Lurie 2001, p. 296)
(20) Price signalinga A higher price set by a firm may signal better quality (Nagle and Holden 2002, p. 91)
(21) Price skimminga The pricing method of attempting to first reach buyers who are willing to purchase at a high price before
marketing to more price-sensitive customers (Monroe 2003, p. 642)
(22) Prices charged by competitors The seller provides the comparison price charged by a competitor along with the seller’s actual price (Berkowitz
and Walton 1980, p. 350)
(23) Prices previously charged The seller compares an advertised price with the seller’s former (higher) price (Biswas and Blair 1991, p. 1)
(24) Random discountinga Discounting price in a manner that should be undiscernible or “random” to uninformed consumers and infrequent
so that these consumers do not get lucky too often (Tellis 1986, p. 150)
(25) Seasonal pricing Price reductions for merchandise or services out of season (Kotler and Keller 2006, p. 452)
(26) Tensile price claimsa Promoting a line of merchandise at different sale prices and not specifying the exact level of reduction for any
one particular product (Biswas and Burton 1993, p. 217)
(27) Two-part pricing Involves two separate charges that consumers must pay to consume a service (Tellis 1986, p. 157).
a Item included in final seventeen-item PTPK index.

were asked to complete an open-ended elicitation task. As tactics. Selected responses from this “why” inquiry were
part of this task, each respondent was asked to list and edited and employed subsequently as false statements for our
describe pricing tactics that marketers use to generate favor- true–false items. Correct statements associated with the items
able price perceptions regarding their brands, stores, and were based upon descriptive definitions from the extant pric-
offerings. Two judges coded the responses, and the inter- ing literature, which describe the various tactics (e.g., Monroe
rater reliability was 0.95. Based on these responses, three 2003; Nagle and Holden 2002; Noble and Gruca 1999; Tellis
additional tactics were added to the item pool (no haggle 1986). An “I don’t know” response option was included to
pricing, seasonal pricing, and penetration pricing), expand- inhibit forced-response guessing.
ing the set to 26. To aid in creating items for each tactic, As depicted in the Appendix A, we created an example
the 441 adults were each further asked to describe why they for each pricing tactic to include with the items compris-
thought marketers employ the elicited tactics. Each respon- ing the knowledge measure, so that participants could base
dent was asked to evaluate a subset of two or three specific their responses on understandable marketplace exemplars.
202 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

Some examples involved general claims (e.g., “Always low Table 2


prices at store XYZ”), while others incorporated specific Item assessment results
prices. We conducted two pretests including both students PTPK scale item Indices of Point biserial
and adult consumers to determine prices to be used in the discrimination correlations
examples that included prices. These pretests yielded quite Captive pricing 0.24 0.37
similar median values for price estimates, and these val- Customer value pricing 0.36 0.42
Everyday-low-pricing 0.36 0.39
ues were used as the price specifications in several of our Image pricing 0.45 0.43
examples. Invoice ERP’s 0.47 0.44
Loss leader pricing 0.53 0.38
Content validity MSRP’s 0.27 0.32
Multiple-unit pricing 0.27 0.20a
Nine-ending pricing 0.13b 0.23a
To evaluate how well the 26 identified tactics represented No haggle pricing 0.32 0.34
the domain of inquiry, two procedures were employed. First, No interest offers 0.46 0.41
twelve marketing PhDs and five retail managers were pro- Partitioned pricing 0.59 0.50
vided with an overall conceptual definition and then asked Penetration pricing 0.36 0.42
to rate how representative each tactic was of the pricing tac- Pennies-a-day 0.35 0.40
Premium pricing −0.06b 0.02a
tics employed by marketers. We used a three-point scale. Price bundling 0.27 0.39
3: clearly representative, 2: somewhat representative, and Price discrimination 0.15b 0.19a
1: not representative at all (Zaichkowsky 1985). Individ- Price matching 0.09b 0.24a
ual tactics were retained if the judges, on average, rated Price signaling 0.35 0.32
the tactic as at least somewhat representative. Two tac- Price skimming 0.31 0.30
Prices charged by competitors 0.09b 0.21a
tics failed (two-part pricing and customary pricing); 24 Prices previously charged −0.03b 0.00a
were retained. The seventeen judges were asked to suggest Random discounting 0.64 0.47
other marketplace tactics that should be included. Based Seasonal pricing 0.12b 0.32
then on these responses, price discrimination was added, Tensile price claims 0.48 0.30
bringing the total to 25. Other tactics mentioned by the Note. Bold items are included in the seventeen-item PTPK index.
a Deleted based on point biserial correlation cutoff of 0.30.
judges were either B2B-related or overlapped with our initial
b Deleted based on index of discrimination cutoff of 0.20.
set.
In a further effort to enhance the content validity of the
remaining twenty-five items, nineteen additional experts (i.e., unbalanced items can be as reliable as multiple-choice for-
marketing faculty) were asked to evaluate the statements mats and offer the advantage of brevity (Clark and Watson
used to frame the individual items. The judges were asked 1995).2
to rate how appropriate each statement was for assessing Following tabulation of correct and incorrect responses,
pricing tactic persuasion knowledge. 3: completely appro- item indices of discrimination and point biserial correlations
priate, 2: somewhat appropriate and 1: not at all appropriate were assessed for each item (Crocker and Algina 1986) and
(cf. Netemeyer et al. 1995). All statements were rated, on are shown in Table 2. These criteria ensured that the items
average, as at least somewhat appropriate and were carried included in the knowledge index distinguished between high
forward. and low knowledge individuals (i.e., indices of discrimina-
tion) and correlated with the overall index (i.e., point biserial
Item discrimination assessment and measure purification correlations). Items failing to satisfy the cutoff criteria for
either the index of discrimination or the point biserial corre-
Student interviewers from a large Midwestern university lation were deleted.
collected data for course credit from 42 non-student adults As suggested by Crocker and Algina (1986, p. 315), the
using procedures similar to those described by Mick (1996). index of discrimination for an item should be above 0.20
These data were used to evaluate the ability of the items to be retained. As shown in Table 2, seven items failed to
(1) to distinguish between consumers with high and low satisfy this cutoff and were deleted. Next, the point bise-
knowledge and (2) to correlate with the overall scale. Respon- rial correlations for each of the remaining eighteen items
dents averaged 37 years of age; 56 percent were female. were evaluated. We retained only items whose point biserial
To detect differences in knowledge, it was critical to select
items for the final knowledge measure that captured vari- 2 The discrete nature of the items comprising the objective knowledge mea-

ability. Items with little variability have little discriminatory sure, as well as the formative nature of the items, precluded factor analysis
power, correlate weakly to other items in the measure, and can in efforts to address dimensionality. However, preliminary cluster analyses
produce unstable correlation results (cf. Clark and Watson and item response theory failed to support stable sub-dimensions within
the set of seventeen items used to form the proposed knowledge measure.
1995, pp. 312–315). As such, items are undesirable if all or Moreover, reanalysis of the data that comprise our subsequent studies, using
mostly all respondents answer them correctly or incorrectly. knowledge measures based on subsets of items with similar content, also did
Importantly, true–false measures that do not contain highly not support a multi-dimensional or higher order measurement approach.
D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210 203

correlations were two standard errors above zero (Crocker by undergraduate students at a Southeastern U.S. univer-
and Algina 1986, √ p. 324). This
√ standard error criterion is sity. Respondents averaged 39 years of age; 64 percent were
approximated as 1/ N − 1(1/ 41 = 0.15). Thus, for an item female. In the test–retest study, respondents first answered
to be considered adequately correlated with the overall mea- the seventeen items (PRL reliability estimate = 0.94), then
sure, item point biserial correlations had to be 0.30 or larger, responded to the same items a month later (PRL reliabil-
a criterion that resulted in the removal of one additional ity estimate = 0.96). A significant positive correlation of 0.72
item. (p < .01) between time periods one and two provided addi-
After evaluating all items using both of these indices, the tional support for the reliability of the index. Interestingly,
seventeen items presented in the Appendix were selected. The test–retest estimates are seldom, if ever, reported for measures
item indices of discrimination ranged from 0.24 to 0.64 and of objective knowledge. However, evidence of test–retest reli-
averaged 0.40. Additionally, the point biserial correlations for ability is particularly important given the formative nature of
the items ranged from 0.30 to 0.50 and averaged 0.39. These the knowledge items (MacKenzie 2003).
indices suggest that the retained items effectively distinguish In a further effort to assess the validity of PTPK, responses
between consumers with high or low knowledge. Also, the to a four-item measure of advertising persuasion knowledge,
retained pricing tactics were similar to the few items that were adapted from Boush et al. (1994), were also assessed in the
eliminated, which suggests minimal loss of domain represen- initial test–retest phase. It was hypothesized that advertising
tation (MacKenzie 2003). For example, MSRPs (retained) persuasion knowledge would be positively related to PTPK
are similar to reference prices framed in terms of competi- because both represent aspects of general consumer per-
tor prices (deleted) and prices previously charged (deleted). suasion knowledge. As expected, the advertising persuasion
Likewise, price signaling (retained) is similar to premium knowledge measure was positively correlated with PTPK
pricing (deleted). (r = .27, p < .01), suggesting that the advertising and pricing
For the resulting seventeen-item index, composite knowl- tactic knowledge domains are related, but distinct.
edge scores were computed as the sum of the number of
correct responses, that is, 1: correct; 0: otherwise. Coeffi-
cient alpha and KR20 are not reported as these reliability Known group differences
estimates are inappropriate when indicators are formative
(MacKenzie 2003; Moorman et al. 2004). Instead, reliability Responses to the knowledge items were also collected
for the proposed objective measure was assessed using the from an additional sample of 44 tenth graders from a Mid-
proportional reduction in loss (PRL) measure developed by western high school. Respondents averaged 16 years of age;
Rust and Cooil (1994). Since the PRL reliability measure is 46 percent were female. The PRL reliability estimate for
a direct extension of Cronbach’s alpha, it is evaluated sim- PTPK was 0.77. Evidence of known group validity was pro-
ilarly to coefficient alpha with values above 0.70 implying vided by comparing the tenth grade students’ mean scores
adequate reliability. For the data collected for scale purifi- (n = 44) with the adult samples collected previously in our
cation, the PRL reliability estimate is 0.95, supporting the item development effort (n = 42) and test–retest assessment
initial reliability of the PTPK measure. In addition, the rec- (n = 71) for both time periods. Adult consumers should have
ommendations of Diamantopoulos and Winklhofer (2001) higher knowledge scores than young consumers as persua-
were also used to investigate the quality of the formative sion knowledge develops over time with greater exposure
PTPK measure. In this analysis, the latent variable, objec- to persuasion episodes, and because it becomes more valu-
tive knowledge, was used as the dependent variable and each able to consumers in a larger number of everyday tasks
item as independent variables. Subsequent multiple regres- and goals when more diverse and subtle persuasion tactics
sion analysis suggested minimum multicollinearity among are encountered (Boush et al. 1994; Friestad and Wright
the items (maximum VIF = 3.03, less than the recommended 1994). Consistent with these expectations, the tenth-grade
cutoff of 10) (Neter et al. 1996, p. 387). Thus, significant sample averaged fewer correct responses than the general
redundancy does not appear among the seventeen formative adult samples. Specifically, the mean for the high school
items (Diamantopoulos and Winklhofer 2001, p. 272).3 respondents was 8.61, while the means for the adult sam-
ples were 11.14 (item development), 11.54 (time period one
Test–retest reliability and additional evidence test–retest), and 11.85 (time period two test–retest), respec-
tively (all p’s < .01).4
A further study was conducted to assess the test–retest
reliability of the knowledge measure. In this study, the sam-
ple was comprised of 71 non-student respondents, recruited
4 Comparison of two subgroups within another sample not reported here

also enabled an additional test of known group validity. Specifically, 69 adult


3 For the remainder of the data used in this paper, all VIFs were less than respondents were asked whether or not they had prior retail work experience.
the maximum of 3.03 found for the measure purification data suggesting that Additional known group validity support was found in that those respondents
there was little redundancy across the seventeen items of PTPK in any of the with retail experience had higher knowledge levels (M = 12.24) than those
data employed. without retail experience (M = 10.60, t67 = 2.38; p < .01).
204 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

Further validation of the pricing knowledge measure determined whether each respondent generated knowledge-
related thoughts for each tactic. Reactions were coded as
In the next section, we describe three studies that were knowledge-related thoughts for the surcharge stimuli if par-
conducted to further validate the PTPK scale. In Study 1, ticipants commented on the sizes of the prices-per-oz. For
empirical evidence supports the prediction that individuals the tensile claims stimuli, reactions were labeled knowledge-
with higher levels of pricing tactic knowledge are more likely related thoughts if participants indicated that some of the
to have knowledge-related thoughts than those with lower products might not be 50 percent off. The inter-rater relia-
levels of pricing tactic knowledge. Next, Study 2 contributes bility for this coding was 0.84. Differences were resolved by
to the retailing literature by demonstrating the ability of PTPK discussion.
to moderate consumer responses to quantity surcharge offers
(Sprott et al. 2003). Finally, Study 3 investigates the ability Results
of PTPK to moderate consumer responses to tensile price Of individuals with high levels of PTPK (based on
claim offers and rules out additional potential alternative a median split), 60 percent generated knowledge-related
explanations not addressed in the first two studies. thoughts for the tensile claim tactic whereas only 42 percent
According to the PKM, consumers can elaborate upon (χ2 (1) = 4.16, p < .05) of those with low levels of PTPK had
the message tactics included in persuasion attempts, and knowledge-related thoughts. Similarly, 67 percent of those
these elaborations include the assessment of prior knowl- with high levels of PTPK had knowledge-related thoughts
edge (Ahluwalia and Burnkrant 2004, p. 27). As such, PTPK on the quantity surcharge information, whereas only 49
is expected to moderate the impact of marketers’ persua- percent (χ2 (1) = 5.10, p < .05) of those with low levels of
sion attempts. Low-knowledge individuals are less likely PTPK had knowledge-related thoughts. These two assess-
to have knowledge-related thoughts regarding pricing-tactic ments of consumer open-ended thought data support the
information. In contrast, high-knowledge individuals are notion that those with higher levels of PTPK are more likely to
more likely to have knowledge-related thoughts regarding have knowledge-related thoughts regarding tensile claim and
pricing-tactic information and to effectively process persua- quantity surcharge information than those with lower PTPK.
sion attempts (Petty and Cacioppo 1981). Moreover, high For the tensile price claim stimuli, a significant positive cor-
knowledge individuals should be less likely to be persuaded relation was observed between knowledge-related thoughts
by pricing-persuasion appeals. This expectation is also con- and PTPK (r = .21, p < .01). Likewise, results indicated a
sistent with the assertion made by Compeau and Grewal significant positive correlation between knowledge-related
(1998) regarding the greater potential for less knowledge- thoughts on quantity surcharge information and PTPK
able individuals to be deceived by marketplace offers. Thus, (r = .27, p < .01). All of these results provide support for H1a.
and as a guide to studies 1–3, we predict: In the next study, the predictive validity of the PTPK scale is
assessed relative to several competing measures in an attempt
to further validate the scale.
H1. As compared with consumers with lower levels of
pricing tactic persuasion knowledge, consumers with higher
Study 2: quantity surcharges
levels of pricing tactic persuasion knowledge (a) will have
more knowledge-related thoughts regarding pricing tactic
In an effort to investigate consumer knowledge as it mod-
information, (b) will be less impacted by quantity surcharge
erates individuals’ reactions to marketplace phenomena, we
persuasion attempts, and (c) will be less impacted by tensile
conducted a study involving quantity surcharge offers. This
price claim offers.
study investigates the effects on a choice-dependent variable
involving quantity surcharge offers, a recently investigated
Study 1: knowledge-related thoughts tactic that is not included in the PTPK measure. Knowl-
edge was measured one week earlier in a separate phase from
Method subsequent experimental tests of the surcharge stimuli.
We exposed 252 undergraduate students to the surcharge Surcharge offers occur when large packages are priced
stimuli used later as part of Study 2 and to a tensile price higher per unit than small packages of the same brand (Sprott
claim offer (“Save up to 50 percent off”) employed later et al. 2003). Marketers may not necessarily be trying to
in Study 3. The surcharge stimuli included a 40-oz bot- deceive consumers, but they are often affected nonetheless
tle of well-known ketchup for $2.99 ($0.075 per oz) and (Manning et al. 1998; Sprott et al. 2003). Sprott et al. (2003, p.
a 32-oz bottle priced at $1.69 ($0.053 per oz). After read- 34) note that, “in general, consumers expect different sizes of
ing each set of stimuli, participants were asked to describe a brand to be priced in a quantity-discount fashion, such that
their reactions to the offers. Then, respondents completed a brand’s larger packages cost less per unit than do smaller
the PTPK items. Pricing tactic persuasion knowledge was packages.” Likewise, Wansink (1996) showed that many con-
assessed after respondents were exposed to the surcharge and sumers believe larger packages have lower unit costs. The
tensile claim scenarios to minimize the potential for demand expectation guiding Study 2 is that individuals scoring high
bias (cf. Wheeler et al. 2005). Two independent coders then in PTPK will be less likely to choose an item with a quantity
D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210 205

surcharge than low knowledge respondents. Several compet-


ing variables were also assessed in an effort to investigate the
relative explanatory power of pricing persuasion knowledge.

Method
Data were collected across two time periods from 176
undergraduate students who received extra course credit
for their participation. Of the respondents, 49 percent were
female. In time period one, respondents completed the
knowledge items and an eighteen-item measure of need
for cognition (Cacioppo et al. 1984). One week later, we
employed a three-group (no surcharge, n = 61; small sur-
charge, n = 55; large surcharge, n = 60) between-subjects
design. Using stimuli consistent with Manning et al. (1998),
participants were asked to consider offers for 32 and 40-oz
bottles of “well-known” ketchup. Like study 1, and based Fig. 1. Knowledge by quantity surcharge interaction: Study 2.
on an evaluation of marketplace prices, the 40-oz bottle of
ketchup was priced at $2.99 ($0.075 per oz) across all con- The ability of the price knowledge measure to moderate
ditions. The no-surcharge condition priced the 32-oz bottle the quantity surcharge level-choice relationship was evalu-
at $2.39 with a unit price of $0.075 per oz. The small- ated by analyzing participants’ choices using logit analysis.
surcharge condition priced the 32-oz bottle at $2.09 with a Choice was coded “0” if a participant chose the 32-oz ketchup
unit price of $0.065 (a 15.4 percent surcharge for the 40-oz and “1” if the participant chose the 40-oz. Subjects who chose
bottle). The large-surcharge condition priced the 32-oz bottle not to purchase either bottle were excluded from the analyses.
at $1.69 with a $0.053 unit price (a 41.5 percent surcharge Two dummy variables were created and included as indepen-
for the 40-oz bottle). After viewing one of these ketchup dent variables along with PTPK and the interactions between
offers, participants responded to a choice measure which each dummy variable and PTPK. A significant interaction
asked “If you were in the scenario described on the previ- of surcharge condition with knowledge was observed as pre-
ous page, which package size would you buy?” Respondents dicted for the comparison between the large surcharge condi-
chose either to purchase the 32-oz bottle (the smaller size) tion and the no surcharge condition (β = −0.38, p = .07). For
of ketchup, purchase the 40-oz bottle (the larger size) of ease of explication, a high/low PTPK median split variable
ketchup, or to purchase neither bottle of ketchup. Then, the was coded “0” for low knowledge and “1” for high knowl-
study participants completed a five-item price consciousness edge. Fig. 1 displays the percentage of participants selecting
scale (Lichtenstein et al. 1993), a six-item general persuasion the surcharged product across surcharge conditions. When
knowledge confidence measure (Bearden et al. 2001), and a there was no surcharge, 69 percent of respondents with both
five-item sale-proneness scale (Lichtenstein et al. 1993), as low and high knowledge chose the larger item. In contrast,
well as manipulation check and demographic questions. when large surcharges were present, low knowledge individ-
uals selected the surcharged item 26 percent of the time, while
Results those with higher knowledge chose the surcharged item only
Two items were used to check the manipulation of the 10 percent of the time. These findings are consistent with
quantity surcharge. Respondents indicated the difference in the expected moderating role of PTPK. The slopes for the
cost-per-oz between the two offers by answering the follow- small surcharge versus no surcharge condition did not differ
ing questions: “The difference in cost-per-oz between the between high and low PTPK groups (β = −0.11, p = .57).
two bottles of ketchup presented was 1: a little to 7: a lot Lastly, these analyses were repeated using the competing
and 1: not considerable to 7: considerable.” Analysis of this measures as potential moderators. Results of these addi-
two-item manipulation check measure (r = 0.77) revealed that tional analyses indicated that price consciousness (β = −0.09,
the manipulation was successful (F2, 154 = 25.38, p < .01). All p = .16), persuasion knowledge confidence (β = 0.12, p = .22),
pairwise comparisons across the three surcharge conditions sale proneness (β = −0.04, p = .60), and need for cognition
(no, low, high surcharge) were significant (p < .05). Moreover, (β = −0.04, p = .29) failed to moderate the surcharge – choice
and in tests of potential crossover effects, the manipula- relationship for the large surcharge condition versus the no
tion check results were non-significant for the PTPK levels surcharge condition. In addition, none of these competing
(p > .10) and the interaction between PTPK and the surcharge measures moderated the surcharge-choice relationship for the
levels (p > .10). The coefficient alpha estimates of reliability small surcharge condition versus the no surcharge condition
for the need for cognition, price consciousness, persuasion (all p’s > .48). These follow-up analyses, when coupled with
knowledge confidence, and sale proneness measures were the knowledge results, suggest that PTPK impacts behavior
0.85, 0.83, 0.78, and 0.81, respectively. The PRL reliability in response to a frequently encountered marketplace-pricing
estimate for PTPK was 0.87. phenomenon, while other related measures do not.
206 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

While the results of Study 2 are encouraging, two alter- advertising offer, participants completed the seventeen-item
native explanations may have been operative. First, the knowledge measure, a five-item task engagement measure
respondents’ level of engagement in the task of answering (e.g., “I was motivated to answer the questions included in
the PTPK items may be consistent with the results. To assess the PTPK scale.”), and the eighteen-item need for cognition
this alternative, a five-item measure of task engagement is scale (Cacioppo and Petty 1982).
included in Study 3 regarding tensile claim offers. A second After a 30-min filler task was completed, participants
potential alternative explanation is that a person’s cognitive reacted to either a sale claim (i.e., “Save 50 percent off”)
skill level is consistent with the PTPK results. In an effort or a tensile price claim offer (i.e., “Save up to 50 percent
to investigate this alternative, participants self-reported ACT off”) for Nike running shoes. After viewing the advertising
scores, a test similar to the SAT, were assessed in Study 3 as information, participants responded to a single-item pur-
a proxy for cognitive skill. Thus, Study 3 was conducted to chase interest measure, labeled 0: Not Very Interested and
assess a larger number of potential alternative explanations, 10: Very Interested. Next, respondents completed a single-
including task engagement and cognitive skills, as well as to item manipulation check measure which asked “How was
demonstrate the moderating ability of PTPK in responses to the sale on Nike running shoes stated?” Response options
tensile price claim offers. Moreover, other competing mea- included “Save 50 percent Off,” “Save up to 50 percent
sures (e.g., advertising persuasion knowledge, advertising Off,” and “I don’t remember.” Then, respondents indicated
skepticism, and value consciousness) were included in an their overall attitude toward Nike running shoes on a single-
expanded effort to assess the relative predictive validity of item measure ranging from 0: Very Undesirable to 10:
PTPK and to investigate other alternative explanations. Very Desirable. Next, respondents completed potential alter-
native explanation measures including the five-item price
Study 3: tensile price claims consciousness scale (Lichtenstein et al. 1993), the six-item
persuasion knowledge confidence scale (Bearden et al. 2001),
In a final effort to investigate consumer knowledge as the five-item sale proneness measure (Lichtenstein et al.
it moderates individuals’ reactions to marketplace phenom- 1993), the nine-item advertising skepticism scale (Obermiller
ena, we conducted a third study involving tensile price claim and Spangenberg 1998), the seven-item value consciousness
offers. Prior research has argued that vague wording in ten- scale (Lichtenstein et al. 1993), and the four-item advertis-
sile price claims (e.g., “Save up to 50 percent off”) causes ing persuasion knowledge measure adapted from Boush et al.
consumers to perceive that the advertised offers are ambigu- (1994). Finally, respondents indicated their gender and ACT
ous (Mobley et al. 1988, p. 273). In particular, Biswas and scores.
Burton (1993) demonstrated that tensile price claims pro-
viding the maximum amount of savings (e.g., “Save up to 50 Results
percent off”) raise consumer price expectations considerably. Analysis of the manipulation check measure revealed that
Overall, prior results suggest that tensile price claims are par- the manipulation was successful (χ2 (2) = 142.04, p < .01).
ticularly influential when the maximum amount of potential The coefficient alpha estimates of reliability were 0.90, 0.88,
savings is stated. 0.67, 0.80, 0.75, 0.91, and 0.79 for the task engagement, need
As part of Study 3, and in addition to the present for cognition, price consciousness, persuasion knowledge
knowledge index, an expanded set of alternative moderat- confidence, sale proneness, advertising skepticism, and value
ing variables was assessed to investigate PTPK’s explanatory consciousness measures, respectively. The PRL reliability
power vis-à-vis other constructs. In addition to the constructs estimates for PTPK and the Boush et al. (1994) advertising
included in Study 2, study participants also responded to persuasion knowledge measure were 0.90 and 0.72, respec-
measures of value consciousness (Lichtenstein et al. 1993), tively.
advertising persuasion knowledge (Boush et al. 1994), adver- The ability of the price knowledge measure to moder-
tising skepticism (Obermiller and Spangenberg 1998), task ate the tensile price claim-purchase interest relationship was
engagement, and ACT performance. Measures of these addi- evaluated by using regression analysis. In the analysis, a
tional constructs were included as they arguably represent significant interaction of tensile price claim condition with
alternative explanations to knowledge effects, due to either knowledge was observed as predicted (β = −0.25, p < .01).5
their similarity to PTPK or their potential impact on infor- For ease of explication, a high/low PTPK median split vari-
mation elaboration. able was coded “0” for low knowledge and “1” for high
knowledge. Fig. 2 displays the mean interest levels across
Method tensile claim conditions and pricing tactic knowledge levels.
Data were collected from 241 undergraduate students who When there was no tensile claim offer, respondents with high
received extra course credit for their participation. Fifty-one knowledge were more interested in the offer (M = 5.76) than
percent of respondents were female. Similar to study 2, and those with low knowledge (M = 5.33; t117 = 1.37, p < .10).
in an effort to inhibit demand effects, knowledge was mea-
sured in an earlier phase from subsequent experimental tests 5 Similar significant results were found when those respondents who

of the tensile price claim stimuli. Prior to responding to an missed the manipulation check item were removed.
D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210 207

as a competency like other essential aspects of life. Simi-


larly, Mick (2003) argues that consumer knowledge remains
important as individuals must be ever skillful in the myriad
contexts of marketing in daily life.
The overall objectives of the present research were to
develop and validate a reliable index to assess consumers’
knowledge regarding pricing tactics and to understand the
role of persuasion knowledge as a moderator of consumer
reactions to surcharge offers. As part of the index develop-
ment effort, a true–false measure was proposed and tested.
Based on both indices of discrimination and point biserial
correlation results, as well as results of our other devel-
opment efforts, the knowledge measure was found to be
reliable and suggested that consumers differ in their knowl-
edge regarding pricing tactics. Briefly, our studies reveal that,
Fig. 2. Knowledge by tensile price claim interaction: Study 3.
as predicted, less-knowledgeable consumers are more sus-
In contrast, when a tensile price claim was offered, low ceptible to surcharge and tensile claim offers and to making
knowledge individuals were significantly more interested suboptimal decisions. Study 1 provided further validation
(M = 5.05) in the offer than those with high knowledge for the PTPK scale by showing that consumers had more
(M = 4.57, t120 = 1.42, p < .10). These findings then are con- knowledge-related thoughts regarding pricing tactic informa-
sistent with the expected moderating role of PTPK and tion than those with low levels of PTPK. Importantly, Studies
H1c. 2 and 3 underscore the importance of consumer pricing tac-
Lastly, the competing measures were investigated in a tic persuasion knowledge. Specifically, greater pricing-tactic
series of similar analyses in an attempt to test for alterna- persuasion knowledge was shown to lessen the impact asso-
tive explanations for the results. These analyses indicated ciated with large quantity surcharges (no knowledge effect
that advertising persuasion knowledge (β = −0.03, p = .91), was found for small quantity surcharges) and tensile claim
need for cognition (β = 0.00, p = .76), price conscious- offers.
ness (β = 0.03 p = .37), persuasion knowledge confidence The present research not only enhances our understanding
(β = −0.06, p = .19), advertising skepticism (β = −0.01, of consumer persuasion knowledge and consumer reactions
p = .81), value consciousness (β = 0.00, p = .91), sale prone- to marketers’ tactics, it also has public policy implications.
ness (β = 0.10, p = .99), task engagement (β = 0.03, p = .37), Policy makers may feel that if knowledge differences affect
and cognitive skill (i.e., ACT scores) (β = −0.03, p = .64) consumer acquisition, comprehension, and interpretation of
failed to moderate the tensile claim offer – interest in price tactics, it might be necessary to limit misleading impres-
the purchase offer relationship. These follow-up analyses, sions (Compeau and Grewal 1998). Grewal et al. (1998) argue
when coupled with the PTPK results, suggest that PTPK that buyers who have less knowledge in terms of prices and
again moderates responses to a frequently encountered products have greater potential for being deceived. The cur-
marketplace-pricing phenomenon, while other measures do rent research supports the PKM arguments that persuasion
not. knowledge indeed can enhance consumer decision-making.
Our findings underscore the need to monitor promo-
tional communications to limit the potential for marketers to
Discussion deceive vulnerable consumers and to search for methods to
enhance how consumers interpret and use marketplace infor-
Consumers’ persuasion knowledge and its effects on con- mation. Like earlier efforts to improve consumers’ use of unit
sumer behavior have recently received significant research price information, it could be worthwhile to provide educa-
attention (e.g., Friestad and Wright 1994, 1995; Wright tion, especially in areas where the population is relatively
2002). Our literature review suggests that, while substantial less educated (Aaker and Ford 1983). For example, programs
research attention has been given to consumer responses to might help consumers recognize the persuasive techniques
individual pricing tactics, minimal research has investigated agents use (Boush et al. 1994), as enlightened consumers are
consumers’ persuasion knowledge regarding marketers’ pric- more able to exert greater control in response to persuasion
ing tactics and the effects of that knowledge on consumer attempts (Friestad and Wright 1994; Pechmann et al. 2003).
responses to various marketplace offers. As such, the research
presented here extends the typical focus of consumer research
to market-level knowledge reflecting beliefs about market- Limitations and future research
place dynamics (e.g., Bolton et al. 2003, p. 489; Wright 2002).
The present research is also consistent with Wright (2002) Caveats are warranted regarding certain limitations of this
assertion that researchers should treat consumer knowledge research. First, pretests of prices will be needed to periodi-
208 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

cally update the proposed knowledge measure. For instance, have conducted an initial experiment and the results sug-
in the random discounting item, the example included current gest that individuals with calibrated pricing tactic persuasion
prices for orange juice. In a few years, perhaps these prices knowledge are less impacted by the presence versus absence
will warrant revision. Second, items might also need to be of manufacturer suggested retail prices than miscalibrated
added as new pricing tactics are implemented or deleted as individuals. One final area that warrants consideration is the
tactics become infrequent. Third, the studies were all con- study of pricing persuasion tactics that may lead to consumers
ducted in a lab setting. Certainly, knowledge effects may be being better off if they are persuaded by the pricing tactic.
more pronounced when marketing tactics are encountered In our surcharge study, consumers are worse off if they pur-
in more realistic shopping environments. Finally, PTPK was chase the surcharged item. However, if a tactic like loss leader
measured prior to being exposed to the scenarios in Studies 2 pricing results in high knowledge individuals purchasing the
and 3 and there might be a threat of demand effects. However, loss leader product while avoiding buying other higher priced
in Study 2, a 1-week separation was included and a filler task products, the persuasion episode aids the high-knowledge
was employed in Study 3. consumer. Studies investigating these positive persuasion
Future research is warranted studying the extent to which attempts could be quite interesting.7
marketplace knowledge differences affect the inferences con-
sumers make in arriving at judgments of the fairness of prices
paid (cf. Bolton et al. 2003). Moreover, higher knowledge Acknowledgments
may help consumers be less susceptible to other tactics, par-
titioned pricing (Morwitz et al. 1998)6 , pennies-a-day pricing The first author (David M. Hardesty) received a James
(Gourville 1998) and moderate other signaling effects as W. McLamore summer research grant from the University of
described by Kirmani and Rao (2000). In addition, the role Miami for this research. The authors would like to thank Meg
of prior knowledge regarding consumer generalizations of Campbell, Allan Chen, Kristin Diehl, Kelly Haws, Tatiana
pricing-related message claims to other non-promoted prod- Levit, Joe Urbany, and Stacy Wood for their helpful com-
ucts remains uncertain. Future research might also consider ments and direction.
the use of disclosure statements, as well as the development
of methods for enhancing consumer abilities to process and
understand marketplace information. Appendix A. Pricing tactic persuasion knowledge
Researchers have recently provided evidence that cogni- (true/false/do not know)
tive capacity and motivation affect consumer utilization of
persuasion knowledge (Campbell and Kirmani 2000). Future 1. Captive pricing—“$3.00 for a non-disposable, easy-grip
research should investigate how cognitive capacity con- razor, and $10.00 for a package of eight replacement
straints and motivational deficiencies affect consumers’ use razor blades.” Captive pricing is used by marketers in
of marketplace knowledge when encountering marketplace order to take advantage of the fact that, eventually,
offers. Another area of concern involves the determinants of consumers will need to purchase the high-priced replace-
PTPK and how this knowledge is obtained. Carlson et al. ment components if they want to continue using the
(2007) recently found that age, need for cognition, experi- product. TRUE
ence, and a best friend’s perceived knowledge are related to 2. Customer value pricing—“$0.79 for a hamburger on the
objective PTPK and/or subjective PTPK. Future researchers value menu at a fast-food restaurant chain.” Customer
could investigate the effect of additional factors such as fre- value pricing is used by marketers to attract consumers
quency of marketer use and propensity to search and evaluate who seek low prices to the marketer’s store. TRUE
persuasive messages on PTPK, as those factors have been 3. Everyday-low-pricing—“Always low prices at store
found to affect price knowledge in prior research (Estelami XYZ.” Everyday-low-pricing is used by marketers so
and De Maeyer 2004; Vanhuele and Dreze 2002). Another that they will be perceived as having really low prices on
issue that warrants additional research involves the extent to some items and higher prices on others. FALSE
which consumer persuasion knowledge extends across sub- 4. Image pricing—“$100.00 for a brand of wine (‘Brand
domains. In this research, the correlation in the test–retest X’). The same wine is currently sold for $20.00 a bot-
study between advertising persuasion knowledge and pricing tle under the name ‘Brand Z’.” Image pricing is used by
tactic persuasion knowledge was 0.27. These findings pro- marketers in order to have a higher-priced version of a
vide some evidence that knowledge levels for sub-domains product available for consumers who view higher-priced
of consumer persuasion knowledge may vary. goods as having higher quality, and a lower-priced ver-
Another interesting area for future research is pricing tac- sion of the same product available for consumers who
tic knowledge calibration (Alba and Hutchinson 2000). We strongly desire lower prices. TRUE
5. Invoice external reference prices—“2002
automobile–$500 over invoice.” Invoice external
6 Data from two other studies suggest that higher levels of PTPK are

associated with less vulnerability to partitioned pricing (Morwitz et al. 1998). 7 We thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.
D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210 209

reference prices are used by marketers to persuade 17. Tensile price claims—“Products X, Y, and Z: Up to 50
consumers to seek out complete price information for a percent off.” Tensile price claims are used by marketers
product. FALSE in order to take advantage of consumers who may inad-
6. Loss leader pricing—“Box of a dozen ‘Grade A’ eggs for vertently perceive most or all products to be discounted
$0.80.” Loss leader pricing is used by marketers to get by the stated amount (i.e., 50 percent off). TRUE
consumers to not only purchase the low-priced item but
also other regularly priced items within the store. TRUE
7. MSRP’s (Manufacturer’s Suggested Retail Prices)—“A References
new 19 in. color television (with remote control): MSRP
$300, Sale Price $200” MSRP’s are used by marketers in Aaker, David A. and Gary T. Ford (1983). “Unit Pricing 10 Years Later: A
efforts to cause consumers to perceive that the sale price Replication,” Journal of Marketing, 47 (1) 118–122.
looks attractive. TRUE Ahluwalia, Rohini and Robert E. Burnkrant (2004). “Answering Questions
about Questions: A Persuasion Knowledge Perspective for Understand-
8. No haggle pricing—“All automobiles for sale at the low-
ing the Effects of Rhetorical Questions,” Journal of Consumer Research,
est price possible–no haggling!” No haggle pricing is 31 (June) 26–42.
used by marketers in order to convince buyers that nego- Alba, Joseph W. and J. Wesley Hutchinson (2000). “Knowledge Calibration:
tiations will be fair. FALSE What Consumers Know and What They Think They Know,” Journal of
9. No interest pricing offers—“Buy a dining room set today Consumer Research, 27 (September) 123–156.
Bearden, William O., David M. Hardesty and Randall L. Rose (2001).
and pay no interest for twelve months.” No interest pric-
“Consumer Self-Confidence: Refinements in Conceptualization and
ing offers are used by marketers to persuade consumers Measurement,” Journal of Consumer Research, 28 (June) 121–
that the price has been reduced. FALSE 134.
10. Partitioned pricing—“$30.00 for a button-up, 100 Berkowitz, Eric N. and John R. Walton (1980). “Contextual Influences
percent cotton long-sleeve shirt, plus $5.00 ship- on Consumer Price Responses: An Experimental Analysis,” Journal of
Marketing Research, 17 (August) 349–358.
ping and handling.” Partitioned pricing is used
Biswas, Abhijit and Edward A. Blair (1991). “Contextual Effects of Refer-
by marketers to persuade consumers that the mar- ence Prices in Retail Advertisements,” Journal of Marketing, 55 (July)
keter is offering an attractive shipping and handling 1–12.
rate. FALSE Biswas, Abhijit and Scot Burton (1993). “Consumer Perceptions of Ten-
11. Penetration pricing—“A four-pack of a new brand of sile Price Claims in Advertisements: An Assessment of Claim Types
Across Different Discount Levels,” Journal of the Academy of Marketing
batteries–$2.00.” Penetration pricing is used by mar-
Science, 21 (3) 217–229.
keters so that, by setting prices low, consumers will be Blair, Edward A., Judy Harris and Kent B. Monroe (2002). “Effects of
encouraged to try the product. TRUE Shopping Information on Consumers’ Responses to Comparative Price
12. Pennies-a-day or XXX-per-day—“Just $1.00 per issue Claims,” Journal of Retailing, 78 (3) 175–181.
for a 1-year subscription to sports magazine XYZ.” Bolton, Lisa E., Luk Warlop and Joseph W. Alba (2003). “Consumer Percep-
tions of Price (Un)fairness,” Journal of Consumer Research, 29 (March)
Pennies-a-day or XXX-per-day is used by marketers to
474–491.
provide price information in the most understandable Boush, David M., Marian Friestad and Gregory M. Rose (1994).
format to consumers. FALSE “Adolescent Skepticism toward TV Advertising and Knowledge of
13. Price bundling—“Computer having a 1.1 GHz proces- Advertiser Tactics,” Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (June) 165–
sor and 128 MB memory and laserjet printer for $1100.” 175.
Cacioppo, John T. and Richard E. Petty (1982). “The Need for Cognition,”
Price bundling is used by marketers in order to increase
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 42 (1) 116–131.
revenue over what would have been obtained had the Cacioppo, John T., Richard E. Petty and Chuan F. Kao (1984). “The Efficient
products been priced separately. TRUE Assessment of Need for Cognition,” Journal of Personality Assessment,
14. Price signaling—“A new pair of running 48 (3) 306–307.
shoes–$140.00.” Price signaling is used by mar- Campbell, Margaret C. (1999). “Perceptions of Price Unfairness:
Antecedents and Consequences,” Journal of Marketing Research, 36
keters since consumers may make quality judgments
(May) 187–199.
for products or services based on price (i.e., high Campbell, Margaret C. and Amna Kirmani (2000). “Consumers’ Use of Per-
price = high quality, low price = low quality). TRUE suasion Knowledge: The Effects of Accessibility and Cognitive Capacity
15. Price skimming—“Brand new product—videophone on Perceptions of an Influence Agent,” Journal of Consumer Research,
$500.” Price skimming is used by marketers to appeal 27 (June) 69–83.
Carlson, Jay P., William O. Bearden and David M. Hardesty (2007). “Influ-
to consumers who are willing to pay a high price for a
ences on What Consumers Know and What They Think They Know
new product. TRUE Regarding Marketer Pricing Tactics,” Psychology & Marketing, 24 (2)
16. Random discounting—“A brand of orange juice’s (64 oz. 117–142.
or 1/2 gallon) price over a four-week time period was as Cason, Timothy N., Daniel Friedman and Garrett H. Milam (2003).
follows: Week 1 $2.50, Week 2 $2.50, Week 3 $1.50, “Bargaining Versus Posted Price Competition in Consumer Mar-
kets,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21 (February)
Week 4 $2.50.” Random discounting is used to obtain
223–252.
sales from both consumers who carefully search for low Clark, Lee A. and David Watson (1995). “Constructing Validity: Basic
prices and consumers who do not check prices carefully. Issues in Objective Scale Development,” Psychological Assessment, 7
TRUE (3) 309–319.
210 D.M. Hardesty et al. / Journal of Retailing 83 (2, 2007) 199–210

Compeau, Larry D. and Dhruv Grewal (1998). “Comparative Price Adver- Mobley, Mary F., William O. Bearden and Jesse E. Teel (1988). “An Inves-
tising: An Integrative Review,” Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, tigation of Individual Responses to Tensile Price Claims,” Journal of
17 (2) 257–273. Consumer Research, 15 (September) 273–279.
Crocker, Linda and James Algina (1986). Introduction to Classical and Monroe, Kent B. (2003). Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions, 3rd ed. New
Modern Test Theory, Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt, Brace, and Jovanovich. York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Darke, Peter R. and Cindy M.Y. Chung (2005). “Effects of Pricing and Moorman, Christine, Kristin Diehl, David Brinberg and Blair Kidwell
Promotion on Consumer Perceptions: It Depends on How You Frame (2004). “Subjective Knowledge, Search Locations, and Consumer
It,” Journal of Retailing, 81 (1) 35–47. Choice,” Journal of Consumer Research, 31 (December) 673–680.
Della, Bitta, J. Albert, Kent B. Monroe and John M. McGinnis (1981). “Con- Morwitz, Vicki G., Eric A. Greenleaf and Eric J. Johnson (1998). “Divide
sumer Perceptions of Comparative Price Advertisements,” Journal of and Prosper: Consumers’ Reactions to Partitioned Prices,” Journal of
Marketing Research, 18 (November) 416–427. Marketing Research, 35 (November) 453–463.
Diamantopoulos, Adamantios and Heidi M. Winklhofer (2001). “Index Nagle, Thomas T. and Reed K. Holden (2002). The Strategy and Tactics of
Construction With Formative Indicators: An Alternative to Scale Devel- Pricing: A Guide to Profitable Decision Making, 3rd ed. Upper Saddle
opment,” Journal of Marketing Research, 38 (May) 269–277. River, NY: Prentice Hall.
Dunne, Patrick M., Robert F. Lusch and David A. Griffith (2002). Retailing, Neter, John, Michael H. Kutner, Christopher J. Nachtsheim and William
4th ed. Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt, Inc.. Wasserman (1996). Applied Linear Statistical Models, 4th ed. Chicago:
Estelami, Hooman and Peter De Maeyer (2004). “Product Category Deter- Irwin.
minants of Price Knowledge for Durable Consumer Goods,” Journal of Netemeyer, Richard G., Scot Burton and Donald R. Lichtenstein (1995).
Retailing, 80 (2) 129–137. “Trait Aspects of Vanity: Measurement and Relevance to Consumer
Friestad, Marian and Peter Wright (1994). “The Persuasion Knowledge Behavior,” Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (4) 612–626.
Model: How People Cope with Persuasion Attempts,” Journal of Con- Noble, Peter M. and Thomas S. Gruca (1999). “Industrial Pricing: Theory
sumer Research, 21 (June) 1–31. and Managerial Practice,” Marketing Science, 18 (3) 435–454.
Friestad, Marian and Peter Wright (1995). “Persuasion Knowledge: Lay Obermiller, Carl and Eric R. Spangenberg (1998). “Development of a Scale
People’s and Researchers’ Beliefs about the Psychology of Advertising,” to Measure Consumer Skepticism toward Advertising,” Journal of Con-
Journal of Consumer Research, 22 (June) 62–74. sumer Psychology, 7 (2) 159–186.
Gourville, John T. (1998). “Pennies-a-Day: The Effect of Temporal Refram- Pechmann, Cornelia, Guangzhi Zhao, Marvin E. Goldberg and Ellen T.
ing on Transaction Evaluation,” Journal of Consumer Research, 24 Reibling (2003). “What to Convey in Antismoking Advertisements for
(March) 395–408. Adolescents: The Use of Protection Motivation Theory to Identify Effec-
Grewal, Dhruv, Kent B. Monroe and R. Krishnan (1998). “The Effects tive Message Themes,” Journal of Marketing, 67 (April) 1–18.
of Price-Comparison Advertising on Buyers’ Perceptions of Acquisi- Petty, Richard E. and John T. Cacioppo (1981). Attitudes and Persuasion:
tion Value, Transaction Value, and Behavioral Intentions,” Journal of Classic and Contemporary Approaches, Dubuque, IA: Wm. C. Brown
Marketing, 62 (April) 46–59. Company Publishers.
Haynes, Stephen N., David C.S. Richard and Edward S. Kubany (1995). Rust, Roland T. and Bruce Cooil (1994). “Reliability Measures for Qualita-
“Content Validity in Psychological Assessment: A Functional Approach tive Data: Theory and Implications,” Journal of Marketing Research, 31
to Concepts and Methods,” Psychological Assessment, 7 (3) 238–247. (February) 1–14.
Kirmani, Amna and Akshay R. Rao (2000). “No Pain, No Gain: A Critical Sprott, David E., Kenneth C. Manning and Anthony D. Miyazaki (2003).
Review of the Literature on Signaling Unobservable Product Quality,” “Grocery Price Setting and Quantity Surcharges,” Journal of Marketing,
Journal of Marketing, 64 (April) 66–79. 67 (July) 34–46.
Kotler, Philip. and Kevin L. Keller (2006). Marketing Management, 12th ed. Srivastava, Joydeep and Nicholas Lurie (2001). “A Consumer Perspective
Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall. on Price-Matching Refund Policies: Effect on Price Perceptions and
Kukar-Kinney, Monica. and Rockney G. Walters (2003). “Consumer Per- Search Behavior,” Journal of Consumer Research, 28 (September) 296–
ceptions of Refund Depth and Competitive Scope in Price-Matching 307.
Guarantees: Effects on Store Patronage,” Journal of Retailing, 79 (3) Stiving, Mark and Russell S. Winer (1997). “An Empirical Analysis of Price
153–160. Endings with Scanner Data,” Journal of Consumer Research, 24 (June)
Lichtenstein, Donald R. and William O. Bearden (1986). “Measurement and 57–67.
Structure of Kelly’s Covariance Theory,” Journal of Consumer Research, Stremersch, Stefan and Gerard J. Tellis (2002). “Strategic Bundling of Prod-
13 (September) 290–296. ucts and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing,” Journal of Marketing,
Lichtenstein, Donald R. and William O. Bearden (1989). “Contextual Influ- 66 (January) 55–72.
ences on Perceptions of Merchant-Supplied Reference Prices,” Journal Tellis, Gerard J. (1986). “Beyond The Many Faces of Price: An Integration
of Consumer Research, 16 (June) 55–66. of Pricing Strategies,” Journal of Marketing, 50 (October) 146–160.
Lichtenstein, Donald R., Nancy.M. Ridgway and Richard.G. Netemeyer Vanhuele, Marc and Xavier Dreze (2002). “Measuring the Price Knowledge
(1993). “Price Perceptions and Consumer Shopping Behavior: A Field Shoppers Bring to the Store,” Journal of Marketing, 66 (October) 72–85.
Study,” Journal of Marketing Research, 30 (May) 234–245. Wansink, Brian (1996). “Can Package Size Accelerate Usage Volume?,”
MacKenzie, Scott B. (2003). “The Dangers of Poor Construct Conceptual- Journal of Marketing, 60 (July) 1–14.
ization,” Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 31 (3) 323–326. Wansink, Brian, Robert J. Kent and Stephen J. Hoch (1998). “An Anchor-
Manning, Kenneth C., David E. Sprott and Anthony D. Miyazaki (1998). ing and Adjustment Model of Purchase Quantity Decisions,” Journal of
“Consumer Response to Quantity Surcharges: Implications for Retail Marketing Research, 35 (February) 71–81.
Price Setters,” Journal of Retailing, 74 (3) 373–399. Wheeler, Christian S., Richard E. Petty and George Y. Bizer (2005). “Self-
Mela, Carl F. and Joel E. Urbany (1996). “Consumer Beliefs about Retail Schema Matching and Attitude Change: Situational and Dispositional
Prices and Promotions,” K. P. Kaufman, G. John and Lynch (Eds.), Determinants of Message Elaboration,” Journal of Consumer Research,
Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 23, Provo, UT: Association for 31 (March) 787–797.
Consumer Research., 78. Wright, Peter (2002). “Marketplace Metacognition and Social Intelligence,”
Mick, David Glen (1996). “Are Studies of Dark Side Variables Confounded Journal of Consumer Research, 29 (March) 677–682.
by Socially Desirable Responding? The Case of Materialism,” Journal Zaichkowsky, Judith Lynne (1985). “Measuring the Involvement Construct,”
of Consumer Research, 23 (September) 106–119. Journal of Consumer Research, 12 (December) 341–352.
Mick, David Glen (2003). “Appreciation, Advice, and Some Aspirations for http://www.drivingtoday.com/features/archive/invoice pricing/
Consumer Research,” Journal of Consumer Research, 29 (March).

You might also like