You are on page 1of 11

Regional Studies

ISSN: 0034-3404 (Print) 1360-0591 (Online) Journal homepage: http://rsa.tandfonline.com/loi/cres20

Creativity support policies as a means of


development policy for the global South? A critical
appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report
2013

Rolf Sternberg

To cite this article: Rolf Sternberg (2017) Creativity support policies as a means of development
policy for the global South? A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013,
Regional Studies, 51:2, 336-345, DOI: 10.1080/00343404.2016.1174844

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2016.1174844

Published online: 02 Jun 2016.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 93

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://rsa.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cres20

Download by: [Technische Informationsbibliothek (TIB)] Date: 09 February 2017, At: 03:01
REGIONAL STUDIES, 2017
VOL. 51, NO. 2, 336–345
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2016.1174844

POLICY DEBATES

Creativity support policies as a means of development policy for


the global South? A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative
Economy Report 2013
Rolf Sternberg

ABSTRACT
Creativity support policies as a means of development policy for the global South? A critical appraisal of the UNESCO
Creative Economy Report 2013. Regional Studies. Cultural segments of the economy have long been the popular
targets of policy-makers intending to promote the economy. The United Nations Creative Economy Report intends to
harness the creative economy for goals of economic development policy to the benefit of developing countries. This
paper demonstrates that the idea of the creative economy, understood as a development policy tool, has several
serious theoretical–conceptual weaknesses. Popularity does not mean the policy tools are or will be successful. For
that reason, and with all due respect to the strengths of this concept, they should be subject to critical analysis in
each individual case.
KEYWORDS
creative economy; creative class; development policy; developing countries

摘要
支持创造力的政策作为全球南方的发展政策工具?对联合国教科文组织 2013 年创意经济报告的批判性评价, Regional
Studies. 经济的文化部分,长期以来作为期盼提升经济的政策制定者所针对的大众目标。联合国的《创意经济报告》,
企图驾驭创意经济,旨在促进能够嘉惠发展中国家的经济发展政策。本文显示,理解为发展政策工具的创意经济之概
念,具有若干严重的理论—概念弱点。普及并不表示政策工具是成功的、抑或将会成功。为了上述原因,以及为了此
一概念效力的冒昧直言,它们应该在每个单独案例中受到批判性地分析。
关键词
创意经济;创意阶级;发展政策;发展中国家

RÉSUMÉ
Des politiques en faveur du soutien de la créativité comme outil de la politique de développement dans les pays du Sud?
Une évaluation critique du Rapport sur l’économie créative 2013 de l’UNESCO. Regional Studies. Depuis longtemps les
secteurs culturels de l’économie sont des cibles très appréciées de la part des décideurs politiques qui envisagent de
promouvoir l’économie. Le Rapport sur l’économie créative de l’Onu cherche à exploiter l’économie créative pour
réaliser des objectifs en matière de politique de développement économique au profit des pays en voie de
développement. Cet article démontre que la notion d’économie créative, que l’on entend ici comme outil de la
politique de développement, fait preuve de plusieurs graves lacunes à la fois théoriques et conceptuelles. La popularité
ne veut pas dire que les outils de politique réussissent ou réussiront. Pour cette raison, et compte tenu des forces de
cette notion, on devrait les soumettre à l’analyse critique au cas par cas.
MOTS-CLÉS
économie créative; classe créative; politique de développement; pays en voie de développement

CONTACT
sternberg@wigeo.uni-hannover.de
Institute of Economic and Cultural Geography, University of Hannover, Schneiderberg 50, Hannover D-30167, Germany.

© 2016 Regional Studies Association


A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013 337

ZUSAMMENFASSUNG
Politiken zur Unterstützung der Kreativität als Mittel der Entwicklungspolitik für den globalen Süden? Eine kritische
Bewertung des Berichts über die Kreativwirtschaft 2013 der UNESCO. Regional Studies. Die kulturellen Segmente der
Wirtschaft sind schon seit langem beliebte Ziele von Politikern zur Förderung der Wirtschaft. Im Bericht über die
Kreativwirtschaft der UN wird versucht, die Kreativwirtschaft für die Ziele der Politik zur Wirtschaftsentwicklung in
Entwicklungsländern zu nutzen. In diesem Beitrag wird nachgewiesen, dass die Idee der Kreativwirtschaft als Instrument
der Entwicklungspolitik mehrere schwere theoretisch-konzeptionelle Schwächen aufweist. Eine Beliebtheit bedeutet
nicht, dass die politischen Instrumente erfolgreich sind oder sein werden. Aus diesem Grund sollten sie – bei allem
gebührenden Respekt vor den Stärken dieses Konzepts – in jedem Einzelfall einer kritischen Analyse unterzogen werden.
SCHLÜSSELWÖRTER
Kreativwirtschaft; kreative Klasse; Entwicklungspolitik; Entwicklungsländer

RESUMEN
¿Políticas para apoyar la creatividad como medio de las políticas de desarrollo para los países del hemisferio sur? Valoración
crítica del informe sobre la economía creativa 2013 de la UNESCO. Regional Studies. Los segmentos culturales de la economía
son desde hace tiempo objetivos populares de los responsables políticos a la hora de fomentar la economía. La finalidad del
informe sobre la economía creativa de Naciones Unidas es sacar partido de la economía creativa para los objetivos de la
política de desarrollo económico en países en desarrollo. En este artículo se demuestra que la idea de la economía
creativa, entendida como una herramienta de política de desarrollo, tiene varias graves deficiencias teórico-conceptuales.
El hecho de que las herramientas políticas sean populares no significa que tengan o vayan a tener éxito. Por este motivo,
y con el debido respeto a los puntos fuertes de este concepto, deberían estar sujetas a análisis críticos en cada caso individual.
PALABRAS CLAVES
economía creativa; clase creativa; política de desarrollo; países en desarrollo

JEL E, E6, E69, O, O1, O18, R5, R58


HISTORY Received September 2014; in revised form April 2016

WHY CREATIVITY IS (STILL) HIGH ON THE 2006; Sternberg, 2012; Storper & Scott, 2009) as well as
POLICY AGENDA his uncritical application of the concept in public policies
(Galloway & Dunlop, 2007).
Creative and/or cultural segments of the economy have But this sometimes harsh criticism from the academic
long been the most popular targets of policy-makers world has not so far done anything to hurt the popularity
intending to promote the economy of their respective of Florida’s ideas within the policy world, partly because
region, particularly since the advent of Florida’s (2004, there is only a small overlap between the academic world
2005) perfectly marketed idea of the ‘creative class’ and and the policy world, in other words policy-makers are
the creative economy it supposedly characterizes. Florida’s often either not aware of or do not understand such aca-
argumentation that the members of the creative class are demic criticism. In addition, economic policies to support
decisive initiators of economic growth, particularly in (lar- creativity need not necessarily be limited to Florida’s
ger) cities, is the subject of hefty criticism from scholars of interpretation of creativity as there are many other under-
various academic fields (e.g., Krätke, 2011; Peck, 2005). standings of creative economy, such as Throsby’s (2008)
Some of his expert colleagues on the economics side, for concentric circles model of creative and cultural industries.
example, consider the level of innovative thinking in Flor- Supporting a creative economy, however it may be defined,
ida’s theories to be rather limited, as two of his three ‘T’s has become an important objective of economic and cul-
(technology, talent, tolerance) could easily be replaced by tural policy, which have become increasingly strategically
human capital and their impact on the economic growth linked in recent years. This is true at all spatial levels of pol-
of cities had long been known (cf., e.g., Glaeser, 2005; icy interventions: at the local level of individual cities, just
cf. also Marrocu & Paci, 2012). Criticism is even stronger as at the regional level, such as for city regions or federal
from some economic geographers, who take issue in par- states, right up to the level of complete countries or supra-
ticular with the lack of transferability of Florida’s empirical national groups of countries like the European Union. For
findings, which are based solely on US. regions, the lack of example, in Germany almost all cities each of the 16 federal
causal correlation between the number of members of the states have developed their own strategies and policy
creative class and economic growth, the missing empirical instruments to support their creative economy. Most of
evidence of soft location factors such as openness and tol- these federal state programmes are oriented towards the
erance as factors that shape migration decisions and desti- nomenclature recently developed for the whole of Germany
nation choices for example, and numerous other actual or and based on the classification of industries put forward by
putative shortcomings (e.g., Alfken, 2015; Markusen, Söndermann (2012).

REGIONAL STUDIES
338 Rolf Sternberg

There are now attempts to support the creative econ- countries. That this initiative is emanating from a globally
omy even at the global level. The Creative Economy Report active institution such as the UN is only logical. One inten-
2013, Special Edition, from the United Nations (2013) fol- tion of this paper is to demonstrate that the creative econ-
lows two earlier reports by the United Nations (UN) that omy as a development policy tool not only has strengths,
contain an initial, empirical global survey of creative econ- but also serious theoretical–conceptual weaknesses. Popu-
omies in (selected) developing countries (United Nations, larity does not mean the policy tools are or will be success-
2008, 2010). It is important to emphasize that the popular- ful. For that reason, and with all due respect to the
ity of these programmes is not a short-term fad; rather, it strengths of this concept, they should be subject to critical
has been observable worldwide for around a decade. analysis in each individual case.
There is currently no foreseeable end to this popularity.
This cannot be because there are already many positive THE UNESCO CREATIVE ECONOMY
ex-post evaluations of creative economy support policies. REPORT 2013: PHILOSOPHY, METHOD,
On the contrary, there are very few respectable evaluations RESULTS AND POLICY SUGGESTIONS
that are oriented towards evaluation criteria and methods
recognized in the academic world (Jayne, 2005). The Creative Economy Report 2013 was jointly published by
Why these programmes are so popular among policy- the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP)
makers, even in comparison with supposed panaceas of and the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cul-
economic development policies from earlier times, such tural Organization (UNESCO). The two earlier creative
as high-tech industries (in the 1980s) or regional–sectoral economy reports published in 2008 and 2010 demon-
clusters (in the 1990s) (see also Sternberg, 2012)? First, strated that the creative economy is among the most rapidly
these programmes are relatively cost-effective compared growing sectors of the world economy and has great poten-
with other policy options. In most cases, they do not tial for transformative countries’ economies in terms of
require any expensive infrastructure, because soft locational income generation, job creation and export earnings.
factors, rather than hard, are more considered to have a The authors see the creative economy as an important
positive influence on creative economies. Second, the and to date underexploited opportunity for further develop-
label ‘creative’ has almost exclusively positive connotations, ment in developing countries. The focus of the report is
particularly when linked with culture, as it often is in sup- therefore primarily limited to these countries. The report
port policies to the benefit of creative economies. Some- interprets the creative economy ‘in humanistic terms –
times, the creative economy is even put on an equal i.e., creativity as an embodied, lived quality informing a
footing with the cultural economy, in contrast to Florida diverse range of industries and activities’ (p. 154). The
(2004). Also, culture has forever been a term with positive key question of the report, therefore, is ‘how to capture
implications and therefore ideally suited to policy pro- the vibrancy and scale of creative economies beyond econ-
grammes that are to be financed by the tax payer, particu- omic indicators’ (p. 16). The report outlines various path-
larly as investments in culture may also entail long-term ways to development through cultural and creative
economic development effects (Falck, Fritsch, & Heblich, industries and expects significant results in terms of inclus-
2011). Third, a creative economy policy strategy is very easy ive social and economic development. The authors empha-
to relate to older and, in some cases, still popular target size that the best of these pathways are to be found at the
groups of policy-makers, such as entrepreneurs, new sub-national level in cities and regions.
firms, or clusters – which is why such terms are to be
found in all creative economy support programmes. Entre- Contents
preneurs and entrepreneurship per se inherently entail a The report starts with arguments stressing the relevance of
high degree of creativity, as an entrepreneur cannot succeed spatial clustering and agglomeration, the dichotomy of for-
without creativity and entrepreneurship is an important mal and informal, or the implication for inequality of the
conduit for the (economic) creativity of firms and regions, creative economy, as well as the definitions and terminol-
for example (Krauss & Sternberg, 2014). The idea of ogy that are used. Chapter 2 examines the role of the
regional–sectoral clusters is based on the concept that local level in fostering creative economies, with a dedicated
spatial proximity facilitates networking and linkages focus on the role of cities. The rather heterogeneous chap-
between economic actors of the same or related industries. ter 3 explores three non-economic ways in which creativity
The creative economy, which is more commonly located in and culture contribute to development: via cultural
large cities, has better chances of development in such clus- expression, via cultural heritage, and via urban planning
ters, and vice versa: The chances of a cluster developing and architecture. Chapter 4 provides a panoply of local
within the creative economy is greater when the creative creativity in many different local settings in Africa, the
economy reaches a certain minimum size. Arab States, Asia and the Pacific, and Latin America and
These correlations between entrepreneurship and clus- the Caribbean, based upon case studies. In Chapter 5 the
ters on the one hand and the creative economy on the other critical factors are taken into account when designing a pol-
also play an important role in the Creative Economy Report icy for local creative economy development (e.g., financing
of the UN (2013) to be discussed in this article. The report or intermediaries and institutions). Chapter 6 proposes a
intends to harness the creative economy for goals of econ- range of qualitative and quantitative indicators of effective-
omic development policy, i.e., to the benefit of developing ness and success for use by local policy-makers by

REGIONAL STUDIES
A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013 339

differentiating between economic, social, environmental All the same, one important economic factor is among the
and cultural outcomes. Chapter 7 analyses aspects of the major challenges in the creative economy development
UN as a strategic partner of local creative development across the global South: financing. Other critical factors
initiatives. The assessment is based upon initiatives carried of creative economy development at the local level are the
out under the aegis of the UNESCO International Fund lack of human capacities and infrastructure. While stressing
for Cultural Diversity (IFCD) and the UNDP-Spain Mil- the creative economy’s important empowering dimensions
lennium Development Goals Achievement Fund (MDG- (e.g., cultural work can complement the maintenance of
F) Thematic Window on Culture and Development. The traditions and participation in community decision-mak-
eighth and concluding chapter summarizes the lessons ing), the value of promoting participation in the cultural
learned, and proposes ten policy recommendations. and creative industries is considered independent from
economic benefits.

Definitions and methods Policy recommendations


Florida’s understanding of the term ‘creative economy’ is Ten policy keystones are recommended (pp. 155ff.):
discussed in the report, but not applied. Instead, cultural
industries are considered ‘as a positive label. This referred . Recognize that the creative economy also generates non-
to forms of cultural production and consumption that monetary value.
have at their core a symbolic or expressive element’ . Make culture a driver and enabler of economic, social
(p. 20). A clear differentiation between creative industries and environmental development.
and cultural industries or cultural economy is not made. . Reveal opportunities through mapping local assets of the
The report incorporates a method mix of quantitative creative economy.
and qualitative attempts. The latter predominate clearly, . Strengthen the evidence base through rigorous data
as many case studies of individual initiatives, programmes collection.
or industries from a large variety of different countries . Investigate the connections between the informal and
and sub-national regions are a characteristic feature of formal sectors.
this report. Of an equally qualitative nature is the first port- . Analyse the critical success factors that contribute to for-
folio analysis of the impact of initiatives funded through the ging new pathways for local creative economy
UNDP-Spain Millennium Development Goals Achieve- development.
ment Fund Thematic Window on Culture and Develop- . Invest in sustainable creative enterprise development
ment and the UNESCO International Fund for Cultural across the value chain.
Diversity in which techniques of text analytics are used, . Invest in local capacity-building to empower creators
but not explained further. Quantitative data, taken and cultural entrepreneurs, government officials and pri-
among other sources from the two earlier creative economy vate sector companies.
reports, complement the qualitatively gained data. . Engage in South–South cooperation to facilitate pro-
ductive mutual learning.
. Mainstream culture into local economic and social
Results development programmes.
According to the report, the creative economy is now one
of the most rapidly growing sectors of the world economy.
World trade of creative goods and services totalled a record THE MAIN STRENGTHS
US$$624 billion in 2011, more than doubling between
2002 and 2011. The average annual growth rate of exports Local sources of creativity
of creative goods was 12.1% during the same period in The report emphasizes at several points the importance of
developing countries and therefore higher than for the local sources for the emergence, valorization, effect and dis-
rest of the world. tribution of creativity. This is scientifically plausible and of
Among the key lessons learned is that ‘local creative considerable political relevance. As economic geographers,
economies are highly diverse and multifaceted’ (p. 154), in contrast to some economists (Friedman, 2005), correctly
which is why there are no ‘one size fits all’ solutions. In emphasize, the local environment is becoming more
addition to these economic implications, the report empha- important for economic, social and ecological processes,
sizes in particular the non-monetary impact and the non- i.e., for what characterizes sustainable development, not
economic effects of the creative economy for the develop- despite ongoing globalization, but because of it (e.g., Rodrí-
ment of local areas in the global South. The report argues guez-Pose & Crescenzi, 2008). This apparent paradox is
reflected in the empirical finding that in an era of globali-
that successful cultural and creative industries are not just zation, the local/regional level (not the nation-state) is
those that maximize exports, or generate significant royalties gaining significance, for example for firms’ decision on
or wages. They may and should do both, but neither of these where to locate, but also for people’s migration decisions.
outcomes is either a necessary or a sufficient condition for For the economic, cultural and social implications of the
human wellbeing. emergence of creativity, this means, for example, that
(p. 154) local links to the domestic environment of the (potentially)

REGIONAL STUDIES
340 Rolf Sternberg

creative person have a decisive influence on the nature and Case studies of ‘cultural regions’
scope of that person’s creativity. Up to a certain point, A second strength of the report lies in the 38 case studies of
therefore, creativity is a reflection of the local environment ‘cultural regions’ of various different countries, continents
where the person lives. Or lived: Migrants who lived a long and cultural environments, as spread around as an addition
time in a region other than their current region may very to the text in the form of boxes, primarily in chapter 4. Case
well take some of the influences from the sending region studies from Africa, the Arab States, and the Asia-Pacific
to the receiving region and then, in a mix of old and new region are also presented on approximately the same scale
cultural influences, use them to generate creativity in the as well as, to a slightly lesser extent, case studies from
new region. This kind of local links may generate Latin America and the Caribbean. The emphasis of this
location-specific creativity that only exists at this one part of the report is on the ‘development of capacities, con-
place. This makes it possible to create precisely those sym- tent and consumption for and by local and regional audi-
bolic values that more and more consumers of products ences and their productive engagement with the cultural
worldwide are looking for). and creative industries’ (p. 53). Particularly as there is a
Similar to the emergence and distribution of new lack of internationally comparable data on (cultural) crea-
knowledge, the emergence and distribution of creativity tivity at the local level, the presentation of as many case
therefore also clearly has local sources. A further parallel studies as possible is an important asset of this report.
to new knowledge is that creativity primarily emerges and Although they do not claim to be representative these
spreads through social relationships between people. case studies illustrate in an impressive manner the great var-
Despite new information and communication technologies iety of cultural creativity at various places in the developing
which at least technically make it easier to overcome geo- world. Heterogeneity is a feature not only of the case studies
graphical distance, face-to-face contacts remain important in the developing countries overall, but also of each of the
when it comes to creativity. And these face-to-face contacts four world regions observed. One example: What do the
are, and remain, dependent on spatial proximity. The impressive Nairobi GoDown Arts Centre (box 4.2, p. 58)
emphasis on regional–sectoral clusters in the report argues and the entrepreneurship model (‘Maaya’) of the Festival
in a very similar manner. sur le Niger (box 4.1, pp. 55f.) have in common apart
The emphasis on local sources of creative economy has from the fact that they are (rather successful) case studies
consequences for policy interventions. As the report under- from the same world region, ‘Africa’? Not much. The
standably focuses locally on cities, support policies should report emphasizes that it presents ‘selective case studies’,
primarily concentrate on cities and use/develop instruments but unfortunately without stating the selection criteria.
with locally specific effect. This is a clear rebuttal of one-
size-fits-all policies and calls for a certain degree of creativ- Indicators and measurement section
ity among policy-makers themselves, however: they cannot The greatest strength of the report in my view is the largely
simply imitate what has already been successfully successful attempt to make a contribution to the empirical
implemented elsewhere. documentation of the scope and therefore of the relevance
The focus on cities is also plausible because the growth of the creative economy in developing countries at the local
of cities continues unabated worldwide and the number of level. Chapter 6 deals with indicators and measurement
people living in cities, globally, now exceeds the number and the related (very big) problems. This is a mammoth
living outside cities. In developing countries in particular, task: The definitions of creative economy differ between
the percentage of people living in cities is increasing at a local regions of the same or even of various countries
disproportionately high rate, in both absolute and relative even more than at the country level. Often they are lacking
terms. The report gives appropriately detailed attention entirely. Linked with this is the problem of the lack of data
to the work of Allen Scott (Scott, 2006, 2010), who with the comparability necessary for policy support pro-
emphasizes the increase in significance as well as the chan- grammes, for example.
ged role of (large) cities for creativity and cultural econom- This makes chapter 6 highly relevant for creative econ-
ies. Even without entirely sharing the report’s overly omy support policies:
optimistic tone when it states that cities and city-regions How are we to identify the specific dimensions of the cultural
on every continent are now emerging as major economic
and creative industries that should be the focus of investment
and cultural motors (p. 33), it is undisputed that cities
and measure the sorts of economic and social impacts that
(and not their hinterlands or rural areas) will in future be might be expected? […] Hence, indicators will be suggested
greater sources of cultural creativity than in the past.
that will assist in illuminating them for the benefit of city
Urbanization economies, that are so important for a
mayors, urban planning officials, etc.
creative economy, can also only be generated in (larger) (p. 123)
cities. This also applies in a lesser form to localization econ-
omies, without which the clusters of creative sectors as Policy-makers need clear, empirical evidence, indicators,
emphasized in the report would scarcely be able to emerge. and output measures in order to decide which projects,
One point which comes up a little short in the report initiatives, local regions or individuals should receive support
should at least be mentioned, however, and that is that and which should not. Culture and creativity may be rather
local may also mean rural – and rural areas are still home soft and intangible constructs, but when it’s a question of
to hundreds of millions of people in developing countries! public support and funding, hard facts are needed.

REGIONAL STUDIES
A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013 341

It makes a lot of sense always to ask the local (or reference to the definition by Cunningham, Banks, and Potts
regional or national) planners and policy-makers four cat- (2008, p. 17) of a creative economy ‘as a complex system that
egories of questions recommended in the report: derives its ‘economic value’ from the facilitation of economic
evolution – a system that manufactures attention, complexity,
. What are our capacities to support the arts and culture in identity and adaptation though the primary resource of crea-
their contribution to sustainable development? tivity’ (p. 21). As necessary as it is to define this term that is
. What is our potential? Do we have any particular strength so difficult to delineate in a few words, such definitions are
in the cultural area that can be used to fix existing pro- all the more unsuitable when they are to be used for the pur-
blems or to create new development opportunities? poses of empirical documentation of the creative economy in a
. What are the areas in which serious problems might be specific region/city. An economy without creativity is difficult
addressed through cultural industry development? to imagine. The association with culture narrows it down
. What will be the indicators of success? This question somewhat, but also expands it in other respects. What this
addresses the monitoring and evaluation processes, i.e., means for empirical research on creative economies is that
how the outcomes of a project or an initiative may be the assignment of specific firms, industries, cities or regions
defined and measured. to a creative economy is at least partially arbitrary and random
– and therefore easy to manipulate. With such a broad defi-
The report then presents a list of resources that help estimate nition it is relatively easy to define every firm, industry, city
the chances of success of any given political measure. Differ- or country as creative.
entiation according to creative workforce, creative The six alternative ‘classification systems for the cultural
businesses, cultural institutions, heritage buildings and and creative industries’ listed in the report do not solve this
sites, and intangible cultural heritage (each with around 10 problem, as the authors do not make a clear decision for one
indicators) is very helpful, even if it is not always consistent. (or other) of these classification systems; they simply list them.
Subsequently, slightly fewer, but still sufficient, indicators of
the capacities of a creative economy are cited, broken down The assumed culture–creativity nexus
into government participation, private sector participation, The second weakness is the close link between culture and
social capital/civic society, education/training in arts and cul- creativity, as becomes clear in the definition of the creative
ture, and media and communications. Finally, the outcomes economy. As understandable as it is to emphasize cultural
of a creative economy support policy/a respective project/ identity as an important addition to purely economically
initiative are classified and assigned indicators. The three- interpreted development in developing countries, when a
category classification corresponds to the classic understand- report on creative economy (sic!) primarily interprets crea-
ing of sustainability (economic, social, environmental), com- tive as cultural and largely ignores the economically relevant
plemented by the cultural dimension, which the report aspects of creativity (e.g., research and development, tech-
considers superordinate to the other three dimensions. nological innovations), the economic element of the ‘crea-
The 30 or so indicators for each of these four dimensions tive economy’ is not adequately taken into consideration.
generate in their entirety a multifaceted picture of potential This shortcoming is not trivial: In a globalized economy
outcomes. This chapter is doubtless of great use as an aid with – at least according to the preference of multinational
to orientation for members of the creative economy and pol- firms – increasingly homogenous needs and global markets,
icy-makers/local planners. it is important to note that cultural creativity is most defi-
nitely not always economically relevant and, in turn, econ-
THE MAIN WEAKNESSES omically relevant creativity is only cultural in nature in (a
small) part. The authors were aware of that, as a restriction
Is it possible for an economy to be non- to the cultural dimension of creativity is intended.
creative?
Any scientific consideration of creativity and creative Understanding of ‘development’ (when
economy must deal with the issue of the definition of economic growth is not meant)
terms – not an easy matter for each of the many academic It is common sense in economics and economic geography
disciplines this concerns (for psychology, see Sternberg & that the development of cities, regions, countries, and
Lubart, 1991; for economic geography in connection with groups of countries is not the same as (economic) growth.
creative regions, see Andersson, 1985). The authors of the While economic growth just means a quantitative increase
report were also aware of this, which is why they spent sev- of economic measures (e.g., gross domestic product
eral pages discussing alternative understandings of key terms (GDP)/capita, average personal income, employment),
such as creative economy, cultural industries, and creative development also has a qualitative dimension, i.e., quanti-
industries. Unfortunately, in most cases, such discussion is tative and qualitative growth Two aspects of the report are
as far as it goes and no operationalized decision is taken as questionable in this respect. First, too little attention is paid
to what a creative economy in particular is and how it to the at least statistical, but partially also causal correlation
could be documented empirically at the local level. Instead, between growth and development, including the spatial
the authors repeatedly emphasize a very broad (but not pre- perspective (e.g., the 2009 World Development Report
cisely defined) understanding that focuses on a culture-based entitled ‘reshaping economic geography’; The World
interpretation of creative economy. Symptomatic of this is the Bank, 2009). Development requires a certain amount of

REGIONAL STUDIES
342 Rolf Sternberg

quantitative economic growth, for the characteristics of of the creative class concept that jobs follow people as
qualitative growth, which are correctly considered impor- these creative people migrate according to soft locational
tant, are easier to achieve in wealthy than in less wealthy factors (such as cultural amenities) and therefore towards
countries, regions and cities. If the inequality of personal large cities is not always correct (Alfken, 2015). Rather,
income, one of the most important aspects of qualitative migration motives do heavily depend on the respective
(economic) growth, is taken into consideration, then the life course stage and for many of the latter the intention
statistical correlation between the level of economic devel- of the creative class members to move to a large city with
opment and economic inequality is not linear, but an opportunities in the creative class sector is not very wide-
inverted ‘U’-shape or is not existing at all, which also spread (see also Borén & Young, 2013). In rural areas,
applies to sub-national regions (McCann, 2013). Unfortu- however, the situation is often different as the absence of
nately, the report constantly emphasizes but not empirically urban amenities might be considered a substantial push
demonstrates that cultural values are more important for factor for out-migration. In fact, McGranahan and
the development of a region than pure economic growth. Wojan (2007) find that in rural US regions natural and
Policy support of culture costs money – which developed outdoor amenities and education opportunities foster the
countries have (in particular some prosperous cities within employment rates of the creative class. Several empirical
such countries). This is most likely not the case for the studies using the rich Swedish data on interregional
majority of the developing countries addressed in the migration reveal that members of the creative class are
report. I agree entirely that neither more spatially mobile than the rest of the employ-
ment sector nor are amenity-related migration motives
development cannot be limited to growth of gross domestic pro- really important (but social relations and occupational fac-
duct (GDP), but must also embrace the opportunity to choose a tors are), other than expected by Florida (Niedomysl &
full, satisfying, valuable and valued way of living together, the Hansen, 2010). Migration of creative people from rural
flourishing of human existence in all its forms and as a whole. areas or smaller cities towards large urban agglomerations
(p. 16) (and hubs of the globalized cultural industry) lessens the
potential for those regions to attract and retain creative
But: not limited to GDP growth does not mean without and innovative people so that this migration loss of periph-
GDP growth! On the contrary, GDP growth with a certain eral urban regions can obviously not been repositioned as
level of economic development is what enables the financing cultural gain (Bennett, 2010). As a consequence one should
of culture and respective policies in the first place. This does be quite careful when assuming that the supposed spatially
not mean that poor, developing countries have no culture or mobile creative class completely moves into the cultural/
creativity, but the economic outcomes expected of creative creative hot spots of a developing country in the Global
economies in those countries in the course of a development South – just because of the agglomeration of cultural indus-
strategy are limited and these countries are less likely to be tries. Empirical studies using quantitative techniques also
able to afford effective support policies (which cost money) find little evidence for amenity-related factors influencing
for such creative economies. In times of intense globalization the growth rates of regional artist populations (Alfken,
and the continuing triumphal march of capitalist economies Broekel, & Sternberg, 2015).
worldwide, it would be naïve to believe that a general focus
on cultural values would bring the development of the global Local development versus catching up of the
South forward significantly. global South
Tellingly, several of the numerous case studies in the This argument is closely linked with the one described
report do not originate from current developing countries, above. The report suggests in several places that successful
but from emerging countries such as China and India, in local creative economies in developing countries could con-
some cases even from developed countries such as the tribute to helping the countries in question and therefore
Netherlands. the global South as a whole in its catch-up process relative
to emerging economies and developed countries. This
Creative people do not always migrate as view, too, is naïve and overly optimistic. There can be no
Florida wishes us to believe doubt that the local focus of creative economies makes
An important argument of the respective literature says that sense as its takes into consideration and promotes at the
members of the creative class are spatially highly mobile same time the emergence of (regionally) specific creativity.
and that they are attracted by places characterized by Under favourable conditions, this may also lead to moder-
large communities of other creative class members. If this ate local economic growth and to local economic develop-
would be the case, creative industries and cultural economy ment. Indeed there is some empirical evidence for the idea
could indeed be considered a panacea for some of the econ- that culture and creative industries contribute a great deal
omic problems (of cities) in the Global South. However, to qualitative development and to quantitative economic
empirical evidence, different from Florida’s own work growth in terms of income and employment (Bandarin,
(restricted to US regions), supporting this argumentation Hosagrahar, & Sailer Albernaz, 2011). But: in the medium
is scarce (e.g., Wojan, Lambert, & McGranahan, 2007). term at least, this will not lead to a significant catch-up of
Results from qualitative research among designers and this local region relative to other regions/cities in the same
advertizers in Germany show that Florida’s simple logic countries. The same applies to developing countries overall

REGIONAL STUDIES
A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013 343

and their catch-up relative to the global North. In addition, economy needs urban agglomeration effects to be able to
the latter has a strongly growing creative economy of its contribute to the existence and growth of creativity. This
own which is far stronger in absolute terms than the crea- is also demonstrated most convincingly by the report in
tive economy of the global South where the average size of chapter 2. These urban agglomerations are also the econ-
most firms in this sector is very small (Barrowclough & omically strongest regions in the country, however, which
Kozul-Wright, 2008). There is currently little at the global means when the local creative economy is strong, it con-
level to suggest that in the creative economy, which will no tributes to the further economic growth of what is already
doubt continue to grow in the future, the disparities the strongest urban region – and in doing so typically
between developing countries (excluding China and increases the interregional disparities. Second, in principle,
India, which are no longer developing countries) on the creative economies can and should of course also develop
one hand and developed economies and emerging econom- and grow in rural regions, too, in order at least potentially
ies on the other will become smaller. If anything, the oppo- to reduce the interregional disparities between urban and
site should be expected! This is even more relevant as the rural regions. But this tends to be rather rare for reasons
report uses a country classification that overrates the share already mentioned and will only happen to a lesser extent
of developing countries in terms of exporting creative than in urban agglomerations although some potentials
goods (see the critical comments and constructive advices exist in rural regions as well (e.g., Bennett, 2010).
in De Beukelaer, 2014). Neglecting economic aspects of creative economies (to
the benefit of the cultural perspective) also has a negative
Not every city has got what it takes to be a effect in the report as regards the reduction of interregional
‘creative economy’ economic disparities. If a reduction of interregional econ-
The focus on local resources of creative economies is one of omic disparities within developing countries were to be
the strengths of the report. But it would negligent to believe possible through creative economies at all, it would have
that every city had the same chances of becoming a creative to (also) be achieved thanks to economic effects. But econ-
economy or to develop a successful public policy to support a omic effects are much undervalued in the report and
creative economy. Urbanization and/or localization econ- instead some naïve hope raised of being able to catch up
omies mostly connected with cities, are without doubt a based solely on culturally driven development. There is
necessary condition for the emergence of a creative economy another reason why this is naïve, not just because
as both Florida’s creative class hypothesis argues. These ‘decision-making and resource allocation within the com-
urbanization and localization economies are not a sufficient munity economy are seldom free from the politics of per-
condition, however: not every city is (equally) creative (e.g., sonal gain and a communitarian ethos is not always easy
Mossig, 2011; Alfken et al., 2015). The mistake some scho- to maintain’ (p. 16): with respect to Maslow’s (1954) theory
lars and policy-makers made with other once popular, sup- of human needs and Hofstede’s (1984) critique one can
posed panaceas of local development policies (such as argue that in a developing country, in contrast to developed
clusters and high-tech parks, see Sternberg, 2012) should countries, the primary expectations of citizens are very
not be repeated here, because the simple fact is that cities much centred around the satisfaction of their basic needs,
vary considerably. With a view to local policy-makers, it is i.e., a wealthy environment and personal gain.
worth repeating an old mantra of local economic develop-
ment policy which is also connoted with urban agglomera- Can the experiences of cities in developed
tion and is now popular in developing countries, too: the countries (in terms of the creative economy) be
promotion of sectoral–regional clusters of related industries. applied to cities in developing countries?
Here, too, empirical research very quickly found that a suc- Empirically and scientifically documented experiences with
cessful cluster is neither a sufficient nor a necessary con- creative economy support policies come, by their very
dition for an economically successful region; there are nature, primarily from developed countries where they
several economically successful cities and regions that did were first practiced and researched (see also EU OMC,
not or do not have this kind of sectoral–regional cluster 2012). It is understandable, but also negligent, to want to
(Sternberg, 2010). It can only be hoped that these erroneous transfer these experiences from totally different environ-
conclusions are not repeated in the global support for crea- ments to cities in developing countries. The institutional
tive economies, in particular in cities in the global South environment differs considerably between cities in devel-
that is already underway. oped countries and cities in developing countries – in favour
of the former. Since in a globalized world, however, the
Reducing sub-national spatial inequalities by creative economies in cities of developed and developing
supporting the creative economy? countries do not (and cannot) act in isolation of one another,
A characteristic feature of many developing countries is the but are – at least for some products of the cultural/creative
large spatial economic disparities between the sub-national industries such as internet-based new media products and
regions (e.g., The World Bank, 2009). A typical situation is services – in competition with one another, this institutional
the dominance of one primate city. The report gives the disadvantage of cities in developing countries can have a
impression that local creative economies and their pro- negative impact on them. They have to try and find their
motion with public policies could reduce these disparities. own path, adjusted to their own local conditions, and not
That is rather improbable for two reasons. First, a creative try to push their way onto the global market too fast.

REGIONAL STUDIES
344 Rolf Sternberg

There is another aspect, too. The report emphasizes that be, but it was sometimes because of the policy interventions
demand in developing countries is not primarily for the basic and sometimes despite them. A causal link was and is rare,
needs to be satisfied by industrialization, but for higher- but not impossible.
value, cultural products and services. I dispute that. The The report contains a long list of critical success factors
majority of countries in the global South want to catch up for development interventions, most of which (at least in
economically. Some formerly developing countries have part) could only be achieved by government policies. To
already achieved that and are therefore now emerging econ- mention just some of the most important ones: financing;
omies such as China, Brazil, or India. They achieved this on a intermediaries and institutions; transnational connections
grand scale through industrialization, in other words with an and flows technical and entrepreneurial leadership. But this
internationally competitive manufacturing sector, a globally is beyond policy-makers in many developing countries, too.
(still) growing share of the global economy, which is partially
relocating to developing countries and emerging economies. CONCLUSIONS
There is still a great need in these two groups of countries to
catch up in terms of totally mundane (admittedly modern) The report is an important and necessary complement to
manufacturing and service products that to a considerable the two previous creative economy reports published by
extent are related to the satisfaction of basic needs. But this the UN in 2008 and 2010 which primarily presented quan-
also includes access to financeable individual means of trans- titative data on creative goods (trade data in particular) at
port, i.e., there are still millions of people who, for example, the country level, which reduced a relevant data gap at
want to buy their first car as soon as they are financially in a the time of publication. The special edition report dis-
position to do so as the recent decades in China have shown. cussed in this article represents a significant step forward,
That these – more or less – basic needs are satisfied is a matter as it emphasizes the local level with a clear focus on devel-
of course for most people in most developed countries, but oping countries. The report gives lots of helpful tips for
not in many developing countries. Despite justified warnings local planners and policy-makers intending to support the
from the global North of the ecological consequences, people local creative economy. These include the numerous
in the global South will want to satisfy these basic needs examples of initiatives from very different parts of the
(first). Only then will they look to satisfy their cultural world and different cultural areas. This portrayal is the
needs – as in earlier times in the global North, too, following first of its kind. The presentation and argumentation of
Maslow’s idea of human needs and Hofstede’s important cri- the indicators for documenting a creative economy may
tique regarding the cultural (and thus country-specific) also be of great practical use.
differences concerning the hierarchy of these needs. The On the other hand, it is necessary to warn local decision
local economies in the developing countries are gaining makers against taking too seriously the sometimes overly
more and more global influence in the satisfaction of these optimistic hopes of economic effects of a solely culturally
basic needs and can generate a great deal of added value interpreted creative economy. It is true that the old devel-
that, in total , will be more important for development and opment interventions paradigm to the benefit of develop-
growth than the cultural creative economy. ing countries was excessively economically oriented in its
argumentation. But the UN report gives vehement and
The policy side: more local creativity due to one-sided preference to the other extreme: without the
‘development interventions’? economy, development of the ‘creative economy’ (sic!) can-
The report expresses the overly optimistic expectation that not work. Development as qualitative economic growth
public or private agents could create a local creative econ- first (but not exclusively) requires quantitative economic
omy through their ‘development interventions’, more seen growth, which should admittedly give greater consideration
from a demand-side perspective being very different from to criteria of ecological, social and cultural sustainability
the traditional supply-side interventions during the pre- than was the case in earlier times.
internet era (see also Flew & Cunningham, 2010). The
report was published by an important policy organization, DISCLOSURE STATEMENT
which is why this goal is understandable. But of course
this does not mean that this is a realistic goal. I am more No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.
sceptical. As has been argued in more detail elsewhere
(Sternberg, 2012), policy-makers in regions and cities of
the global North eagerly backed the ‘creative economy’ SUPPLEMENTAL DATA
horse that Florida had very successfully let loose. Florida’s
creative economy saw a repeat in those countries of what Supplemental data for this article can be accessed at http://
Michael Porter had practiced equally successfully 15 years 10.1080/00343404.2016.1174844
before with his ‘horse’ – cluster and cluster policies. All
these policy interventions were only ever successful at a
very few locations in the Global North that had/have the REFERENCES
necessary locational characteristics – but they were never
successful in all cities (Sternberg, 2010). The effects Alfken, C. (2015). Ich will nicht nach Berlin! – Life course analysis of
intended by the policy-makers sometimes did come to interregional migration behaviour of people from the field of

REGIONAL STUDIES
A critical appraisal of the UNESCO Creative Economy Report 2013 345

design and advertising. Environment and Planning A, 47, 2187– Marrocu, E., & Paci, R. (2012). Education or creativity: What mat-
2203. doi:10.1177/0308518X15599287 ters most for economic performance? Economic Geography, 88,
Alfken, C., Broekel, T., & Sternberg, R. (2015). Factors explaining 369–401. doi:10.1111/j.1944-8287.2012.01161.x
the spatial agglomeration of the creative class: Empirical evidence Maslow, A. H. (1954). Motivation and personality. New York: Harper
for German artists. European Planning Studies, 23, 2438–2463. & Row.
doi:10.1080/09654313.2014.979767 McCann, P. (2013). Modern urban and regional economics (2nd ed.).
Andersson, A. E. (1985). Creativity and regional development. Papers of Oxford: Oxford University Press.
the Regional Science Association, 56, 5–20. doi:10.1007/BF01887900 McGranahan, D., & Wojan, T. (2007). Recasting the creative class to
Bandarin, F., Hosagrahar, J., & Sailer Albernaz, F. (2011). Why examine growth processes in rural and urban counties. Regional
development needs culture. Journal of Cultural Heritage Studies, 41, 197–216. doi:10.1080/00343400600928285
Management and Sustainable Development, 1, 15–25. doi:org/10. Mossig, I. (2011). Regional employment growth in the cultural and
1108/20441261111129906 creative industries in Germany 2003–2008. European Planning
Barrowclough, D., & Kozul-Wright, Z. (Eds.). (2008). Creative Studies, 19, 967–990. doi:10.1080/09654313.2011.568807
industries and developing countries. London: Routledge. Niedomysl, T., & Hansen, H. K. (2010). What matters more for the
Bennett, D. (2010). Creative migration: A Western Australian case decision to move?: Jobs versus amenities. Environment and
study of creative artists. Australian Geographer, 41, 117–128. Planning A, 42, 1636–1649. doi:10.1068/a42432
doi:10.1080/00049180903535626 Peck, J. (2005). Struggling with the creative class. International
Borén, T., & Young, C. (2013). The migration dynamics of the ‘crea- Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 29, 740–770. doi:10.
tive class’: Evidence from a study of artists in Stockholm, Sweden. 1111/j.1468-2427.2005.00620.x
Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 103, 195–210. Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Crescenzi, R. (2008). Mountains in a flat
doi:10.1080/00045608.2011.628263 world: Why proximity still matters for the location of economic
Cunningham, S., Banks, J., & Potts, J. (2008). Cultural economy: The activity. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 1,
shape of the field. In H. Anheier & Y. R. Isar (Eds.), The cultural 371–388. doi:10.1093/cjres/rsn011
economy. The Cultures and Globalization Series 2 (pp. 15–26). Scott, A. (2006). Creative cities: Conceptual issues and policy questions.
London: SAGE. Journal of Urban Affairs, 28, 1–17. doi:10.1111/j/0735-2166.
De Beukelaer, C. (2014). Creative industries in ‘developing’ countries: 2006.00256.x.
Questioning country classifications in the UNCTAD Creative Scott, A. (2010). Jobs or amenities? Destination choices of migrant
Economy Reports. Cultural Trends, 23, 232–251. doi:10.1080/ engineers in the USA. Papers in Regional Science, 89, 43–63.
09548963.2014.912043 doi:10.1111/j.1435-5957.2009.00263.x
European Union Open Method of Coordination. (2012). Expert Söndermann, M. (2012). Kurzanleitung zur Erstellung einer statis-
group on cultural and creative industries. Policy handbook on how tischen Datengrundlage für die Kulturwirtschaft. Statistische
to strategically use the EU support programmes, including Anpassung der Kultur- und Kreativwirtschaft in Deutschland.
Structural Funds, to foster the potential of culture for local, regional Retrieved from http://www.kulturwirtschaft.de/wp-content/
and national development and the spill-over effects on the wider econ- uploads/2011/01/Kurzanleitung-KKW_20120124.pdf
omy? Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/culture/library/ Sternberg, R. (2010). Neither planned nor by chance: How
publications/cci-policy-handbook_en.pdf knowledge-intensive clusters emerge. In D. Fornahl, S. Henn,
Falck, O., Fritsch, M., & Heblich, S. (2011). The phantom of the & M.-P. Menzel (Eds.), Emerging clusters. Theoretical, empirical
opera: Cultural amenities, human capital and regional economic and political perspectives on the initial stage of cluster evolution
growth. Labour Economics, 18, 755–766. doi:10.1016/j.labeco. (pp. 295–323). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
2011.06.004 Sternberg, R. (2012). Learning from the Past? Why ‘creative indus-
Flew, T., & Cunningham, S. (2010). Creative industries after the first tries’ can hardly be created by local/regional government policies.
decade of debate. Information Society, 26, 113–123. doi:10.1080/ Die Erde, 143, 293–317.
01972240903562753 Sternberg, R. J., & Lubart, T. I. (1991). An investment theory of
Florida, R. (2004). The rise of the creative class. And how it’s transform- creativity and its development. Human Development, 34, 1–31.
ing work, leisure, community and everyday life. New York: Basic. doi:10.1159/000277029
Florida, R. (2005). Cities and the creative class. New York: Routledge. Storper, M., & Scott, A. J. (2009). Rethinking human capital, crea-
Friedman, T. (2005). The world is flat. New York: Farrar, Straus & tivity and urban growth. Economic Geography, 9, 47–167.
Giroux. The World Bank. (2009). Reshaping economic geography. The
Galloway, S., & Dunlop, S. (2007). A critique of definitions of cultural World Development Report 2009. Washington, DC: World
and creative industries in public policy. International Journal of Bank.
Cultural Policy, 13, 17–31. doi:10.1080/10286630701201657 Throsby, D. (2008). Modelling the cultural industries. International
Glaeser, E. L. (2005). Review of Richard Florida’s ‘the rise of the Journal of Cultural Policy, 14, 217–232. doi:10.1080/
creative class’. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35, 593– 10286630802281772
596. doi:10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2005.01.005 United Nations. (2008). Creative economy report. The challenge of asses-
Hofstede, G. (1984). The cultural relativity of the quality of life con- sing the creative economy: Towards informed policy making. Geneva
cept. Academy of Management Review, 9, 389–398. and New York: United Nations. Retrieved from http://www.
Jayne, M. (2005). Creative industries: The regional dimension? unctad.org/creativeeconomy
Environment and Planning C, 23, 537–556. doi:10.1068/c0453 United Nations. (2010). Creative economy report 2010. Creative econ-
Krätke, S. (2011). The creative capital of cities: Interactive knowledge cre- omy: A feasible development option. Geneva and New York: United
ation and the urbanization economies of innovation. Chichester: Wiley. Nations. Retrieved from http://www.unctad.org/creative-
Krauss, G., & Sternberg, R. (2014). Introduction: On the relation- economy
ship between entrepreneurship and creativity. In R. Sternberg United Nations. (2013). Creative economy report 2013 special edition.
& G. Krauss (Eds.), Handbook of research on entrepreneurship Paris: UNDP/UNESCO.
and creativity (pp. 1–20). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Wojan, T. R., Lambert, D. M., & McGranahan, D. A. (2007).
Markusen, A. (2006). Urban development and the politics of a crea- Emoting with their feet: Bohemian attraction to creative milieu.
tive class: Evidence from a study of artists. Environment and Journal of Economic Geography, 7, 711–736. doi:10.1093/jeg/
Planning A, 38, 1921–1940. doi:10.1068/a38179 lbm029

REGIONAL STUDIES

You might also like