You are on page 1of 77

Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market

Daron Acemoglu

Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 40, No. 1. (Mar., 2002), pp. 7-72.

Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28200203%2940%3A1%3C7%3ATCIATL%3E2.0.CO%3B2-P

Journal of Economic Literature is currently published by American Economic Association.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained
prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in
the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/journals/aea.html.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic
journals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers,
and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community take
advantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org
Tue Oct 30 14:10:14 2007
Journal of Economic Literature
Val. XL (Marcla 2002), pp. 7-72

Technical Change, Inequality,


and the Labor Market

1. Introduction the 90th percentile of the wage distri-


bution earned 266 percent more than a
1.1 Motivation worker at the 10th percentile. By 1995
What are the implications of techni- this number had risen to 366 percent
cal change for the labor market? How (author's calculations from March CPS
does new technology affect the distri- data). Many commentators see a direct
bution of wages and income? Is tech- causal relationship between technologi-
nology responsible for the changes in cal changes and these radical shifts in
the wage structure observed in many the distribution of wages taking place in
advanced economies since the 1970s? the U.S. economy. T h e title of Alan
The recent consensus is that techni- Krueger's (1993) influential paper on
cal change favors more skilled workers, computers and inequality summarizes
replaces tasks previously performed by this view: "How Computers Have
the unskilled, and exacerbates inequal- Changed the Wage Structure." Jeremy
ity. This view is shaped largely by the Greenwood and Mehmet Yorukoglu
experience of the past several decades, (1997, p. 87) similarly give a succinct
which witnessed both major changes in statement:
technology, including the rapid spread Setting up, and operating, new technolo-
of computers in workplaces and in our gies often involves acquiring and processing
lives, and a sharp increase in wage in- information. Skill facilitates this adoption
process. Therefore, times of rapid technologi-
equality. I n the United States, for ex- cal advancement should be associated with a
ample, the college premium-the wages rise in the return to skill.
of college graduates relative to the wages
of high-school graduates-increased by They further argue that we are now
over 25 percent between 1979 and in the midst of a "Third Industrial Revo-
1995. Overall earnings inequality also lution," fueled by advances in informa-
increased sharply. In 1971, a worker at tion technology, and that this revolu-
tion is responsible for the increase in
Massachusetts Institute of Technology. I thank inequality (as does Francesco Caselli
Alexis Leon for excellent research assistance and
Joshua Angrist, David Autor, Olivier Blanchard, 1999, in a paper entitled "Technological
Lawrence Katz, Olner Moav, Tohn McMillan, Revolutions").
Lawrence Mishel, Donald ~ o r r i s d n Lee
, Ohanian, T h e view that technological develop-
Steve Pischke, Thomas Lemieux, Gianluca Vio-
lante, Bas ter Weel, and two anonymous referees ments favor skilled workers also receives
for comments. support from accounts of earlier
8 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

episodes. For example, there were already the idea that technological advances fa-
signs of significant technology-skill vor more skilled workers is a twentieth-
complementarity in the 1910s. Claudia century phenomenon. In nineteenth-
Goldin and Lawrence Katz (1998) argue century Britain, skilled artisans
that the spread of batch and continuous- destroyed weaving, spinning, and
process methods of production in- threshing machines during the Luddite
creased the demand for skills. They and Captain Swing riots, in the belief
add, ". . . the switch to electricity from that the new machines would make
steam and water-power energy sources their skills redundant. They were right:
was reinforcing because it reduced the the artisan shop was replaced by the
demand for unskilled manual workers factory and later by interchangeable
in many hauling, conveying, and assem- parts and the assembly line (e.g., John
bly tasks" (p. 695). Over this period, James and Jonathan Skinner 1985;
capital-intensive industries increased Goldin and Katz 1998). Products pre-
the demand for skills considerably (see viously manufactured by skilled artisans
Goldin and Katz 1998, table 3), and the started to be produced in factories by
scope of these industries expanded with workers with relatively few skills, and
the sharp fall in the price of electricity many previously complex tasks were
(see, for example, Arthur Woolf 1984, simplified, reducing the demand for
p. 178). The rapid increase in the im- skilled workers.2 Joel Mokyr (1990, p.
portance of white-collar and clerical oc- 137) describes this process vividly:
cupations gave another boost to the de- First in firearms, then in clocks, pumps,
mand for skills. Generalizing from the locks, mechanical reapers, typewriters, sew-
experience of the 1920s, Harry Jerome ing machines, and eventually in engines and
(1934, p. 402) argued that ". . . in the bicycles, interchangeable parts technology
proved superior and replaced the skilled
future . . . there is considerable reason
artisans working with chisel and file.
to believe that the effect of further
[mechanization] will be to raise the
"n the absence of detailed econometric evi-
average skill required." dence, it is difficult to eneralize from the histori-
The early twentieth-century evidence cal examples and concfude that technical change
was so powerful that Zvi Griliches was definitely skill-replacing during the nine-
teenth century. Still, the only econometric evi-
(1969) suggested capital and skills are dence that I am aware of supports this view. Usin
intrinsically complementary. Richard the 1850 Census of Manufacturers, James an8
Nelson and Edmund Phelps (1967), Skinner (1985) find that there was more ra id sub-
stitution of capital for skilled workers t&n un-
Finis Welch (1970), Theodore Schultz skilled workers. I t can also be ar ued that techni-
(1975), and Jan Tinbergen (1975) also cal change always increases t%e demand for
argued that technological developments "skills," and the artisans who were hurt as a result
of new technolo y were not "skilled" since they
increase the demand for skills. Events lacked the flexi%ility to adapt to the required
since then support this notion. Personal changes. This argument is not totally convincing,
computers, computer-assisted produc- since the artisans earned considerably more than
other laborers (for example, James and Skinner
tion techniques, and robotics appear to 1985 report over 60 percent wage differentials for
complement skilled workers, replacing building and printing workers relative to laborers
many labor-intensive tasks. In this light, in the 1850s). So the artisans possessed skills that
were being rewarded by the market, and the stan-
it is perhaps natural to view the in- dardization of the production process destroyed
crease in inequality over the past sev- these rewards. On the other hand, it has to be
eral decades as a direct consequence of noted that many of the skill-replacing technologies
of the nineteenth century ma have also increased
technical change. the demand for engineers andmanagers (see, e.g.,
Although the consensus is now broad, Goldin and Katz 1998).
Acernoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 9

Interchangeable parts were in fact very an acceleration in skill bias during the
much designed to be skill-replacing past few decades appears to be the main
(unskill-biased). Eli Whitney, a pioneer cause of the increase in inequality.
of interchangeable parts, described the We can understand the behavior of
objective of this technology as: technical change by recognizing that
the development and use of technol-
. . . to substitute correct and effective op-
erations of machinery for the skill of the art-
ogy is, at least in part, a response to
ist which is acquired only by long practice profit incentives.3 When developing
and experience; a species of skill which is not skill-biased techniques is more profit-
possessed in this country to any considerable able, new technology will tend to be
extent. . . . (quoted in H . J. Habakkuk 1962, skill-biased. I suggest that the early
p. 22)
nineteenth century was characterized
The experience of the nineteenth and by skill-replacing developments be-
early twentieth centuries led Harry cause the increased supply of unskilled
Braverman (1974) and Stephen Marglin workers in the English cities (resulting
(1974) to argue that technical change from migration from rural areas and
was "deski1ling"-a major purpose of from Ireland) made the introduction
technical change was to expand the divi- of these technologies profitable. In
sion of labor and simplify tasks pre- contrast, the twentieth century has
viously performed by artisans by break- been characterized by skill-biased
ing them into smaller, less skill-requiring technical change because the rapid in-
pieces. Braverman (1974, p. 113), for ex- crease in the supply of skilled workers
ample, suggested that the first principle has induced the development of skill-
of management and production tech- conlplementary tech~lologies.The re-
niques of the period was "dissociation of cent acceleration in skill-biased tech-
the labor process from skills of the work- nical change is in turn likely to have
ers. The labor process is to be rendered been a response to the rapid increase
independent of craft, tradition, and the in the supply of skills during the past
workers' knowIedge." several decades. However, I also argue
A longer view therefore suggests that that despite the acceleration in skill
technological advances may not have bias, we are most likely not in the
always increased the demand for skills. midst of a "technological revolution";
In fact, most early nineteenth-century what has changed is not necessarily
innovations appear to have replaced the overall rate of progress, but the
skilled workers and expanded tasks per- types of technologies that are being
formed by the unskilled. But then, why developed.
have technological advances been skill-
biased in the twentieth century? And, 3 Precedents of this approach include Jacob
are technological changes the major cause Schmookler (1966), who emphasized demand pidl
and the extent of the market as key determinants
of the recent increase in inequality? of innovations; the endogenous growth theory,
This essay attempts to answer these e.g., Paul Romer (1990), Gene Grosslnan and El-
questions. It has two main theses: hanan Helpman (1991), and Philippe Aghion and
Peter Howitt (1992); the induced innovation the-
ory, including Syed Ahlnad (1965), Charles Ken-
The behavior of wages and returns to nedy (1964), Paul Samuelson (1970), Yujiro
schooling indicates that technical Hayami and Vernon Ruttan (1970), and Paul
change has been skill-biased during the David (1975); and recent work including my own,
Acernoglu (1998, 1999b, 2000), Acelnoglu and
past sixty years and probably for most Fabrizio Zilibotti (1999), and Michael Kiley
of the twentieth century. Furthermore, (1999).
10 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Finally, I conjecture that recent tech- creases in within-group (residual) in-


nological developments are likely to have equality-i.e., increases in inequality
affected the organization of the labor among observationally equivalent
market-including the way firms are workers-account for much of this
organized, labor market policies, and rise.
the form of labor market "institutionsn- 4. Average wages have stagnated and
and may have had a large effect on the wages of low-skill workers have fallen
structure of wages through this channel. in real terms since 1970.
In the processof developing this ar-
I argue that technical change over the
gument, this essay sets out a simple
theoretical framework in which inequal- past sixty years, or even over the past
ity and returns to skills are determined century, has been skill-biased. This con-
by supply and demand forces (technol- clusion follows from fact 1 above: in the
ogy).4 Using this framework as a unify- absence of substantial skill bias in tech-
ing device, I critically survey many of nology, the large increase in the supply
the theories that explain the recent in- of skilled workers would have depressed
crease in inequality by technological the skill premium. In 1970, Welch (1970,
factors and discuss how various pieces p. 36) reached the same conclusion, and
of evidence can be interpreted within
I
argued:
this framework. With the phenomenal rise in average edu-
cation, why have rates of return failed to
1.2 Summary of tlae Argument decline? . . .
I t is obvious that changes have occurred to
I begin with a roadmap of the argu- prevent the decline in returns to acquiring
ment. Since the effect of new technol- education that would normally accompany a
rise in average educational level. Presumably,
ogy on the distribution of wages in the these changes have resulted in growth in de-
recent past is central to the focus here, mand for . . . education . . . sufficient to ab-
I organize this essay around a number sorb t h e increased supply with constant or
of salient facts from the post-war U.S. rising returns.
economy.5 Briefly, these facts are:
The thirty years after Welch wrote these
1. The past sixty years have seen a large words witnessed a much more rapid in-
increase in the supply of more educated crease in the supply of education and a
workers, while returns to education sharp increase in the returns to more
have risen. skilled workers, suggesting that skill-
2. Returns to education fell during the biased changes in technology continued
1970s, when there was a very sharp throughout the postwar period.
increase in the supply of educated And yet, if technical change has been
workers. Returns to education then skill-biased throughout the recent past,
began a steep rise during the 1980s. why did inequality increase during the
3. Overall wage inequality rose sharply past thirty years, but not before? There
beginning in the early 1970s. In- are at least two possible answers to this
question. The first, which I call the
4Precedents of the supply and demand ap- steady-demand hypothesis, maintains that
proach include, among others, Gary Becker
(1964), Finis Welch (1970), and Jan Tinbergen demand for skills increases at a constant
11975). pace, so changes in inequality must be
5 1 limit the discussion of the major trends to explained by the pace of the increase in
the U.S. economy because of space constraints and
also because there is notably more research to the supply of skills. According to this
build upon. hypothesis, inequality (returns to skills)
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, a n d t h e L a b o r Market 11

was relatively stable before the 1970s, ior of entrepreneurs driven by a variety
because the rate of skill accumulation of nonprofit motives. Demand for skills
in the U.S. economy was as rapid increased faster during the past thirty
as the constant pace of skill-biased years, this approach would maintain,
technical change (e.g., Katz and Kevin because of a teclanological revolution led
Murphy 1992; Murphy, Craig Riddell, by the microchip, personal computers,
and Paul Romer 1998; David Card and and the internet.6 New technologies of
Thomas Lemieux 2000). The recent in- the early nineteenth century were skill-
crease in inequality is then explained, replacing (unskill-biased) because the
not by a major technological change, technological frontier then only en-
but by a decline in the growth rate of abled the invention of skill-replacing
the supply of skills. The second possible techniques.
answer comes from the acceleration hy- Nevertheless, there are several prob-
potlaesis, which maintains that there has lems with this approach. First, although
been an acceleration in skill bias begin- a number of papers, including Green-
ning in the 1970s or the 1980s. Accord- wood and Yorukoglu (1997), Andres
ing to this hypothesis, there is a dis- Hornstein and Krusell (1997), and Ga-
continuity in the growth rate of the lor and Moav (2000), show that rapid
demand for skills. The most popular technical change may lead to slower to-
version of this hypothesis claims that tal factor productivity (TFP) growth,
there has been a notable acceleration in the slow rates of TFP and output
the skill bias of technology, driven by growth of the past several decades are
advances in information technology, or difficult to reconcile with a technologi-
perhaps a "Third Industrial Revolution." cal revolution during this time period.
So was there an acceleration in skill Second, demand for skills appears to
bias? This question is difficult to an- have accelerated starting in the late
swer, as we lack direct measures of the 1970s, precisely when the supply of
degree of skill bias. To tackle this ques- skills increased very rapidly. Exogenous
tion, one therefore needs to look at a technology theories do not explain the
variety of evidence often pointing in timing of this acceleration.7
different directions. I conclude below 6See, among others, Krueger (1993), Eli Ber-
that skill-biased technical change is man, John Bound, and Griliches (1994), and David
likely to have accelerated over the past Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) for evidence that
several decades. This conclusion is the rapid spread of computers has increased the
demand for skills. See Per Krusell, Lee Ohanian,
based on the sharp increase in overall Victor Rios-Rull, and Giovanni Violante (2000),
inequality starting in the 1970s and on Oded Galor and Daniel Tsiddon (1997), Green-
the fact that returns to schooling rose wood and Yorukoglu (1997), Aghion and Howitt
(1998, ch. 9), Caselli (1999), Galor and Olner
over the past thirty years despite the Moav (2000), Violante (2000), Yonna Rubinstein
unusually rapid increase in the supply and Tsiddon (1999), Aghion, Howitt, and Violante
of educated workers. (2000), and Eric Gould, Moav, and Bruce Wein-
berg (2000) for models in which ra id technical
Why did the demand for skills accel- f
change increases the demand for ski1 s and causes
erate over this ~ e r i o d ?And why has a rise in inequality.
new technology favored more skilled 7Naturally, supply and demand ma 7 have
moved together because supply responded to de-
workers throughout the twentieth cen- mand. I argue below that the large increase in the
tury, but not during the nineteenth cen- supply of educated workers was not in anticipation
tury? One approach would view tech- of, or in response to, high returns, but driven by a
variety of other factors. More generally, I often
nology as exogenous, stemming from focus on the effect of the supply of skills on tech-
advances in science or from the behav- nology not because I view supply as exogenous,
12 Journal of Economic Literature, Vok. XL (March 2002)

An alternative theory maintains in- acceleration in skill bias could cause a


stead that new technologies are endoge- TFP slowdown because it creates an
nous and respond to incentives. It was imbalance in the composition of R&D.
the large increase in the supply of This approach also provides a possi-
skilled workers, this approach claims, ble explanation for the skill-replacing
that induced the acceleration in the de- techi~ical change of the early nine-
mand for skills. When skill-biased tech- teenth century. The emergence of the
niques are more profitable, firms will most skill-replacing technologies of the
have greater incentives to develop and past two hundred years, the factory sys-
adopt such techniques. A key determi- tem, coincided with a large change in
nant of the profitability of new tech- relative supplies. This time, there was a
nologies is their market size; machines large migration of unskilled workers
that can be sold in greater numbers will froin villages and Ireland to English cit-
be more profitable. Jacob Schmookler ies (see, for example, Habakkuk 1962;
(1966), in his pioneering study, Inven- Paul Bairoch 1988; or Jeffrey Williain-
tion and Economic Growth, placed son 1990). This increase in the "reserve
great emphasis on market size. He ar- army of unskilled workers," slightly
gued that (p. 206) "invention is largely paraphrasing Karl Marx, created profit
an economic activity which, like other opportunities for firnls to exploit by in-
economic activities, is pursued for gain; troducing technologies that could be
. . . expected gain varies with expected used with unskilled workers. In fact,
sales of goods embodying the inven- contemporary historians considered the
tion." This reasoning implies that ma- incentive to replace skilled artisans by
chines complementary to skilled work- unskilled laborers to be a major objec-
ers will be more profitable to develop tive of technological improvements of
when there are inore skilled workers the period. Ure, a historial1 in the
to use them. New technologies have first half of the nineteenth century,
become more skill-biased throughout describes these incentives as follows:
most of the twentieth century because I t is, in fact, the constant aim and tendency
the supply of skilled workers has grown of every improvement in machinery to super-
steadily. This perspective also suggests sede human labor altogether, or to diminish
that a faster increase in the supply of its costs, by substituting the industry of
skills can lead to an acceleration in the women and children for that of men; of that
of ordinary labourers, for trained artisans.
demand for skills (Acemoglu 1998). So (quoted in Habakkuk 1962, p . 154)
the timing of the increases in supply
and demand is not a coincidence- These iilcentives for skill-replacing tech-
instead, it reflects technology respond- nologies, I argue, were shaped by the
ing to the supply of skills. Furthermore, large increase in the supply of unskilled
rapid skill-biased technical change is workers. So, it may be precisely the dif-
not necessarily associated with rapid ferential changes in the relative supply
overall technical progress. In fact, an of skilled and unskilled workers that ex-
plain both the presence of skill-replacing
technical change in the nineteenth cen-
but simply because the effect of supply o n tech-
nology is more important in understanding the tury and skill-biased technical change
questions posed above. I discuss below 1 during the twentieth century.
may respond to changes in skill premia,' low s u low
and ~ply A major shortcoming of the "pure
this response may account for the joint behavior of
the supply of, and demand for, skills over the past technological" approaches-of both ex-
century. ogenous and endogenous varieties-is
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 13

that they do not provide a natural expla- zational change, labor-market institu-
nation for the fall in the wages of tions, and international trade have in-
low-skill workers. Although a number of teracted with technical change in a fun-
papers, including Caselli (1999), Green- damental way, amplifying the direct
wood and Yorukoglu (1997), and Galor effect of technical change on inequality,
and Moav (2000), show that technologi- and likely causing the decline in the
cal revolutions may be associated with a wages of less-skilled workers.
fall in the wages of low-skill workers, it Therefore, the overall picture that
is difficult to see how sustained techno- emerges is not necessarily one in which
logical change can be associated with technology is the only factor affecting
an extended period of falling wages of the distribution of income. On the con-
low-skill workers and stagnant average trary, the underlying thesis of this essay
wages. This leads to the next question is that technology itself is no more than
for this essay. an endogenous actor. To explain the
Why did the real wages of low-skill changes in the distribution of income,
workers fall over the past several de- and to forecast what other changes may
cades? There are a number of possible happen in the future, we need to under-
answers. First, labor-market institu- stand the forces that shape technologi-
tions, for example labor unions, under- cal progress, and how technology inter-
went important changes over the past acts with the overall organization of the
thirty years, and these changes may labor market.
have reduced the wages of many manu- There is considerable uncertainty on
facturing workers, causing an increase many issues, and both more theoretical
in inequality and a decline in the real and more empirical work are needed.
wages of low-skill workers (e.g., Rich- Two areas deserve special attention.
ard Freeman 1991; John DiNardo, Ni- The first is the differential behavior of
cole Fortin, and Lemieux 1995; David residual inequality and returns to
Lee 1999). Second, international trade schooling during the 1970s. Most
between skill-scarce less-developed coun- economists view changes in residual in-
tries and skill-abundant rich economies equality as related to changes in labor-
increased over this period, and this may market prices. It is therefore puzzling
have put downward pressure on the that during the 1970s, while returns to
wages of low-skill workers in the United schooling fell, residual and overall in-
States (e.g., Adrian Wood 1994; Edward equality increased. I argue below that
Leamer 1995). Third, there has been a models based on a single skill index
transformation of the way in which (one type of skill or many types of skills
firms are organized, or perhaps in the that are perfect substitutes) are unable
way that firms and workers match (see, to explain this pattern. Instead, we need
for example, Acemoglu 1999a; Michael models with multidimensional skills.
Kremer and Eric Maskin 1999; Timothy Moreover, for this type of model to ex-
Bresnahan 1997; Bresnahan, Erik Bryn- plain the behavior of residual inequality
jolfsson, and Lorin Hitt 1999; and during the 1970s and the 1980s, techno-
Autor, Frank Levy, and Richard Mur- logical progress needs to have changed
nane 2000). Although each of these fac- the demand for different types of skills
tors could have been the cause of the differentially. The endogenous technol-
recent changes in the wage structure, I ogy models discussed above provide a
argue that their direct effect has been possible explanation for why different
limited. Instead, I suggest that organi- dimensions of skills may have been
14 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2002)

affected differentially by technical rizes many of the salient trends I want


change. Nevertheless, the reasons for this to emphasize. In particular,
type of behavior require much more re- 1. There has been a remarkable in-
search. More generally, we know rela- crease in the supply of skills in the U.S.
tively little about the determinants of economy over the past sixty years. In
residual inequality, and this topic is a 1939, just over 6 percent of American
major research area for the future. The workers were college graduates. By
second area is cross-country differences 1996 this number had increased to over
in the behavior of wage inequality. 28 percent. In 1939, almost 68 percent
While inequality increased sharply in of all workers did not have a high
the United States, the United Kingdom, school degree. In 1996, this number
and Canada, it increased much less had fallen to less than 10 percent (see,
in Germany and many Scandinavian for example, Autor, Katz, and Krueger
economies. Although there are a num- 1998, table 1). The relative supply of
ber of recent papers addressing these skills plotted in figure 1 provides a
questions, much uncertainty still re- summary of these changes.
mains. I conjecture that cross-country 2. There has been no tendency for
differences in wage inequality may the returns to college to fall in the face
reflect, in part, technological choices of this large increase in supply-on the
made by these countries in response contrary, there is an increase in the col-
to the different incentives created by lege premium over this time period. An
their labor-market institutions, but important issue is whether changes in
much more research on this topic is the returns to college (or more gener-
required. ally other measures of wage inequality)
correspond to true changes in the re-
2. Emvirical
I
Trends turns to skills. As is well-known in the
labor literature, observed schooling pre-
The objective of this section is to il-
mia may reflect returns to ability. This
lustrate a number of major inequality
raises the possibility that changes in the
trends from the past several decades.
returns to schooling may be driven by
My aim is not to offer a comprehensive
composition effects (changes in the
survey of the empirical literature, but
composition of ability across schooling
simply to highlight the most salient
groups). In the appendix, I elaborate
trends to anchor the theoretical discus-
how changes in the distribution of un-
sion (see, e.g., Peter Gottschalk 1997;
observed skills across groups can create
George Johnson 1997; Katz and Autor
composition effects, and show that
2000, for recent surveys).
these composition effects cannot be re-
Figure 1 plots a measure of the sup-
sponsible for the changes in the wage
ply of college skills between 1949 and
structure. Therefore, here I interpret
1995, constructed along the lines of
these changes in the observed returns
Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998), as the
to schooling as changes in the true
ratio of college equivalents (those with
price of skills.
at least college + 0.5 x those with some
3. Following an acceleration in the
college) to noncollege equivalents
supply of skills, returns to college fell
(those with high school or less + 0.5 x
sharply during the 1970s, leading
those with some college).8 I t also plots
Richard Freeman to conclude that
returns to college. This picture summa-
"Americans are over-educated" (Free-
8 See the appendix for data details. man 1976). Returns to college then rose
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 15

1 I I I I 1 I

39 49 59 69 79 89 96
year
Relative Supply of College Skills and College Premium
Figure 1.The Behavior of the (log) College Premium and Relative Supply of College Skills (weeks worked by
college equivalents divided by weeks worked of noncollege equivalents) between 1939 and 1996. Data from
March CPSs and 1940, 1950, and 1960 censuses.

very sharply during the 1980s. This in- illustrates two more important patterns:
crease in the returns to schooling has 1. Overall wage inequality started to
been one of the major motivating facts increase sharply in the early 1970s after
for the empirical inequality literature a period of relative stability-prior to
(e.g., Bound and Johnson 1992; Katz the 1970s, the 90th, SOth, and 10th per-
and Murphy 1992). centiles of the wage distribution fol-
There have also been important lowed each other closely, but came
changes in the overall distribution of apart sharply in the 1970s.
wages. Figure 2 plots the 90th, 50th 2. Median wages stagnated from 1975
and 10th percentiles of the overall onwards, while workers at the 10th
wage (weekly earnings) distribution percentile of the wage distribution (i.e.,
for white male workers between 1963
and 1997 (with the 1963 values for this would likely contribute to the composition ef-
all series indexed to lOO).9 This figure fects. Moreover, male-female wage difference nar-
rowed substantially over the same time period as
"ample constructed as described in the appen- well. School quality for black men also under-
dix. I focus here on wage inequality for white men went significant transformation (e.g., Welch 1973;
since labor market partici ation of women in- Card and Krueger 1992), and this could create
!'
creased substantially over t l e sample period, and significant composition effects.
16 Jozcrnal of Economic Literature, V ol. XL ( M a r c h 2002)

0 index 10th pctile wages A index 50th pctile wages


index 90th pctile wages

150 1

year
Indexed Wages for White Males 1963-97
Figure 2. Changes in the Indexed Value of the 90th, 50th, and 10th Percentiles of the Wage Distribution for
White Males (1963 values normalized to 100).Data from March CPSs.

"low-skill workers") saw their earnings


" Figure 3 turns to another measure: re-
fall in real terms to levels even below sidual (within-group) inequality, which
those in 1963.10 shows inequality among observationally
equivalent workers. This figure displays
1°Average wages, like median wages, have stag-
nated. For example, white men aged 30-49 earned
three measures of residual inequality
409 a week in 1999 dollars in 1949, and 793 in among white male workers between
1969, which corresponds approximately to a 3.4 1963 and 1997: 50-10, 90-50 and 0.5
percent a year increase in real wages between
1949 and 1969. In contrast, the same age group
tirnes 90-10 log wage residual differen-
earned 909 in 1989, or experienced only a 0.6 per- tials ( I plot 0.5 tirnes 90-10 wage differ-
cent a year increase between 1969 and 1989 (all entials in order to fit this on the same
numbers author's calculation from census data).
The behavior of the median and average wage
scale as the other measures).
growth depends on the consumption deflator. I
have followed the literature in using the ersonal the increase in benefits, the share of labor in na-
consumption expenditure deflator I t has %een ar- tional income has not fallen over this period (see,
gued that this deflator overstates inflation because e.g., Krueger 1999). So whether average wages
of difficulties in measuring quality change (e.g., have stagnated or continued to increase in line
Michael Boskin e t al. 1995). Even in the presence with output growth depends on 11o\v benefits are
of such measurement problems, a large gap re- valued relative to earnings. I t is also important to
mains between the rate of increase of real wages note that if these non-wage benefits are taken into
before and after the 1970s, unless there is an "ac- account, inequality ap ears to have increased even
celeration" in this bias exactly around the 1970s. more than the nnrnfers here indicate (Brooks
Part of this gap is due to the increased importance Pierce 2000). This is because high-wage workers
of nonwage income and benefits. I n fact, thanks to are the primary recipients of such benefits.
Acemoglu: Teclznicak Change, Ineqzcakity, and tlze Labor Market 17

0 90-50 residual differences A 50-10 residual differences


0.5 times 90-10 residual diffs

I I I I I I I

65 70 75 80 85 90 95
year
Residual Inequality Measures for White Males 1963-97
Figure 3. 90-50, 50-10 and 0.5 x 90-10 Differentials from Log \lJeekly Wage Regressions for White Males
Aged 18-65.

To calculate these measures, I look at much in tandem with overall inequality-


the residuals from a standard Mincerian it shows a sharp increase starting in the
wage regression of the form early 1970s.11 Remarkably, all three mea-
In w,t = X',tPt + vlt, (1) sures of residual inequality behave very
similarly, suggesting that forces affecting
where wit is weekly earnings for individ- the top of the male wage distribution
ual i observed in year t , and Xit is a set of (90-50) are also affecting the bottom of
controls which include nine education the wage distribution (50-10). Finally, note
dummies, a quartic in experience, and an important contrast between figure 1
region controls (constructed from the and figures 2 and 3. While returns to
March CPSs; see the appendix for details schooling fell during the 1970s, overall
of the sample). The fact that pt is in-
dexed by t Cndicates that returns to these
11 DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux (1995) provide
observed are to evidence from the May Current Po ulation Surve
vary from year to year. The measures of K
( C P s ) data that residual and overa wage inequal
ity started to increase in the 1980s. Katz and Autor
residual inequality are calculated as the
(2000), on the other hand, find that residual wage
difference between 90th and inequality started to increase in the 1970s from
10th (or the 50th and the l o t h , etc.) March and Ma CPS data, and from census data.
percentile values of the residual distri- See the appenc6x. Recent work by Thomas Piketty
and Emanuel Saez (2001) also finds an increase in
bution froln this regression, V t t . Residual inequality during the 1970s using data from the
inequality appears to have increased very Internal Revenue Service tax returns.
18 Jozcrnal of Economic Literature, V o l . XL ( M a r c h 2 0 0 2 )
and residual inequality increased. I the returns to skills will also lead to an
return to this issue later in the essay. increase in within-group inequality.
Suppose that there are L ( t ) unskilled
3. Introduction t o the Theory (low-education) workers and H ( t ) skilled
of Skill Prelnia (high-education) workers, supplying la-
bor inelastically at time t . All workers
While, undoubtedly, many factors af- are risk neutral, and maximize (the pres-
fect the distribution of wages, a natural ent value of) labor incorne. Also sup-
starting point for an econornic analysis pose that labor markets are competitive
is that of supply and demand. In the in- ( I return below to the role played by
troduction to his pioneering study of noncornpetitive elements, especially in
incorne distribution, Tinbergen (1975, the European context).
p. 15) wrote The production function for the ag-
. . . what matters is t h e difference between gregate economy takes the constant
qualities available and qualities required by elasticity of substitution ( C E S ) form
the demand side, that is by t h e organization
of production. (italics in original)

This is where I begin as well. I intro- where p 5 1, and Al(t) and Ar,(t) are factor-
duce a simple framework that links augmenting technology terms. Although
wages to supply of skills and to demand all the results of interest hold for a general
generated by the technology possibili- constant returns to scale F ( . ) function, I
ties frontier of the economy. There are focus on the CES production function to
two types of workers, skilled and un- simplify the discussion. I drop the time
skilled (high and low-education work- argument when this causes no confusion.
ers), who are imperfect substitutes. Im- T h e elasticity of substitution between
perfect substitution between the two skilled and unskilled workers in this
types of workers is important in under- production function is o = 1/(1- p). I
standing how changes in relative sup- refer to skilled and unskilled workers as
plies affect skill premia. For now I gross substitutes when the elasticity of
think of the unskilled workers as those substitution o > 1 (or p > O), and gross
with a high school diploma, and the complements when o < 1 (or p < 0).
skilled workers as those with a college Three noteworthy special cases are: (i)
degree.l"o the focus in this section is o + 0 (or p + -DO) when skilled and un-
on returns to schooling (or between- skilled workers will be Leontieff, and
group inequality), and I use the terms output can be produced only by using
"skill" and education interchangeably. skilled and unskilled workers in fixed
In practice, education and skills are proportions; (ii) o + when skilled and
only iinperfectly correlated, so it is use- unskilled workers are perfect substi-
ful to bear in mind that since tliere are tutes, and (iii) o + 1, when the pro-
skilled and unskilled workers within the duction function tends to the Cobb
same education group, an increase in Douglas case. The value of the elasticity
of substitution will play a crucial role in
12This classification of workers into skilled and the interpretation of the results that fol-
unskilled groups is obviously appropriate only for
the twentieth-century United States. In many low. I n particular, in this framework,
other countries or eriods, hi h school graduates teclinologies either increase the pro-
could b e considere%to be "skiyled" workers. More ductivity of skilled or unskilled workers,
generally, the two-skill model is a convenient
simplification, less realistic than a world wit11 a that is, tliere are no explicitly skill-
continuum of imperfectly substitutable skills. replacing or unskilled-labor-replacing
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 19

technologies.13 But, as we will see be- This equation implies au;~/aH/L > 0: as
low, depending on tlie value of the elas- the fraction of skilled workers in the
ticity of substitution, an increase in A17 labor force increases, the unskilled wage
can act either to complement or to should increase. Similarly, the skilled
"replace" skilled workers. wage is
Tlie production function (2) admits
three different interpretations:
1. There is only one good, and
skilled and unskilled workers are iinper- which yields a t u ~ / a H / L< 0; everything
fect substitutes in tlie production of tliis else equal, as skilled workers become
good. more abundant, their wages should fall.
2. The production function (2) is also Combining these two equations, the skill
equivalent to an economy where con- premium-the wage of skilled work-
sumers have utility function [Ye + Y;]~/P ers divided by the wage of unskilled
defined over two goods. Good YI, is pro- workers-is14
duced using only skilled workers, and Y1
is produced using only unskilled work-
ers, with production functions YI, = AhH,
and Yl =AlL. In tliis interpretation, it is
important that the economy is closed.
We will see in section 6.3 that different
results obtain when international trade Equation (4) can be rewritten in a more
in tliese two goods is allowed. convenient form by taking logs,
3. A mixture of the above two
whereby different sectors produce
goods that are imperfect substitutes,
and liigh- and low-education workers are
employed in both sectors. Naturally, the skill premium in-
Although the third interpretation is creases wlien skilled workers become
more realistic, I generally use one of the more scarce, i.e.,
first two, as they are easier to discuss.
Since labor markets are competitive,
the unskilled wage is
This is the usual substitution effect, and
shows tliat for given skill bias of technol-
ogy, as captured by Ah/&, the relative
demand curve for skill is downward slop-
ing with elasticity l/o = (1- p). Intui-
13A more general formulation would replace
equation (2) with the production function tively, an increase in HIL creates two
different types of substitution. First, if
14For some parameter values, skilled workers
nlay have lower wages than the unskilled, i.e.,
where B , and Bi, would b e directly unskilled-labor- o 5 1. One may want to impose
replacing and skill-replacing technologies, and an H
increase in b, would correspond to some of the
tasks previously performed by the unskilled being
taken over by the skilled (see, e.g., Johnson and
Stafford 1999 on this). For most of the analysis
here, there is little to b e gained from this more
r
to avoid this. Alternative1 , one could assume that
skilled workers can use t l e technologies nornlally
used by the unskilled, A,, and be more (or equally)
general production function (but see section 5.3). productive at this than the unskilled.
. . . .
20

.
f
Skill premium
. \ Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. X L (March 2002)

..........................
Relative demand
for skills
college graduate workers (relative to
high school graduates) tliat were as high
as 40 percent quickly fell to less tlian 20
percent. The extent of substitution was
also clear. First, many college graduate
workers could not find employment in
skilled jobs: Angrist (1995) shows a
I I
sharp increase in the unemployment
rn' ........................... .......------
I rate of college graduates, and Ze'ev
I A l l - b i a s e d tech. Schiff and E h u d Ya'ari (1989) report
I
change
I
that only one in eiglit Palestinian gradu-
H/L Hf/L'
ates could find work in liis profession,
Figure 4. The Relative Demand for Skills witli the rest working as unskilled labor-
ers, mainly in the construction industry.
Second, preinia for tasks usually per-
skilled and unskilled workers are produc- formed by more educated workers fell
ing the same good, but performing dif- sharply. Between 1984 and 1987, the
ferent functions, an increase in the num- preiniuin for administrative and inana-
ber of skilled workers will necessitate a gerial jobs (relative to manual laborers)
substitution of skilled workers for tasks fell from .32 to .12, while the preiniuin
previously performed by tlie unskilled. for clerical workers fell from .02 to -.08
Second, if skilled and unskilled work- (see Angrist 1995 for details).
ers are ~ r o d u c i n gdifferent goods, tlie As equation (6) sliows, the elasticity
greater number of skilled workers will of substitution, o, is important for the
lead to a substitution of the consumption behavior of tlie skill premium when
of tlie unskilled good by the skilled good. supply changes. The elasticity of substi-
In botli cases, this substitution hurts the tution is also crucial for the response of
relative earnings of skilled workers. the skill premium to changes in tech-
Figure 4 draws tlie relative demand nology. Unfortunately, this parameter is
for skills, equation (5), against the rela- rather difficult to estimate, since it re-
tive supply of skills, H I L , which is taken fers to an elasticity of substitution that
to b e given for the purposes of this ex- combines substitution both within and
ercise. An increase in the relative sup- across industries. Nevertlieless, there
ply, from H I L to H'IL', moves tlie equi- are a number of estimates using aggre-
librium point along the downward gate data that give a range of plausible
sloping relative demand curve, and values. The majority of these estimates
reduces tlie skill premium from OI to of. are between o = 1 and 2 (see for exain-
An interesting case study of the re- ple Freeman 1986). The response of
sponse of the returns to schooling to an college preiniuin for Palestinian labor
increase in the supply of skills is pro- reported in Angrist (1995), for example,
vided by the experience in the West implies an elasticity of substitution be-
Bank and Gaza Strip during the 1980s. tween workers with sixteen years of
As Josliua Angrist (1995) illustrates, scliooling and tliose witli less than
there was a very large increase in tlie twelve years of schooling of approxi-
supply of skilled Palestinian labor as mately o = 2.
Palestinian institutions of liigher educa- Given the focus of tliis essay, it is also
tion, totally absent before 1972, began important to know how the skill premium
to open. Angrist shows that premia to responds to technology. Differentiation
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 21

of (5) shows that tlie result depends on elasticity of substitution between skilled
tlie elasticity of substitution: and unskilled workers greater than 1.
I t is also useful to compute the aver-
age wage in tliis economy. Without con-
trolling for changes in tlie educational
composition of the labor force, tlie
Therefore, if o > 1 (i.e., p E (0, I]), then average wage is
improvements in the skill-complementary
technology increase the skill premium.
This can be seen in figure 4 as a sliift out
of the relative demand curve, moving the
wliich is also increasing in H I L as long as
skill premium from o to o". The con-
the skill premium is positive (i.e., o > 1
verse is obtained when o < 1: tliat is,
or A;(H/L)P - A: > 0). Intuitively, as the
wlien o < 1, an improvement in the pro-
skill composition of the labor force
ductivity of skilled workers, Ah, relative
improves, wages will increase.
to tlie productivity of unskilled workers,
Therefore, tlie results so far imply
Al, sliifts the relative demand curve in
that in response to an increase in H I L :
and reduces tlie skill premium. This case
appears paradoxical at first, but is, in 1. The relative wages of skilled workers,
fact, quite intuitive. Consider, for ex- the skill premium o = Z U ~ / Z decreases.
O~,
ample, a Leontieff (fixed proportions) 2. Wages of unskilled workers increase.
production function. In this case, wlien 3. Wages of skilled workers decrease.
A!, increases and skilled workers become 4. The average wage (without control-
more productive, the deinand for un- ling for education) rises.
skilled workers increases by more than
the deinand for skilled workers. In some It is also useful to liighlight tlie iinpli-
sense, in this case, the increase in Ah is cations of an increase in Ah on wage
creating an "excess supply" of skilled levels. First, an increase in A!,, with A1
workers given the number of unskilled constant, corresponds to an increase in
workers. This excess supply increases the Ah/Al; tlie implications of this change
unskilled wage relative to the skilled on the skill premium were discussed
wage. Tliis observation raises an iinpor- above. Moreover if Ah increases, every-
tant caveat. I t is tempting to interpret tliing else being equal, we expect both
improvements in teclinologies used by tlie wages of unskilled and skilled work-
skilled workers, A!,, as "skill-biased." ers (and therefore the average wage) to
However, when the elasticity of substitu- increase: in tliis framework, technological
tion is less tlian 1, it will be advances in improvements always increase all wages.
technologies used with unskilled work- T h e most central result for our pur-
ers, Al, that increase the relative produc- poses is tliat as H I L increases, the skill
tivity and wages of skilled workers, and premium, a, should fall. In terms of
an increase in Ah relative to Al will be figure 4, tlie increase in supply cor-
"skill-replacing." responds to a rightward shift in tlie ver-
Nevertlieless, the conventional wis- tical line from H I L to H'/L', which
dom is that the skill premium increases would move the econoiny along tlie
wlien skilled workers become relatively downward sloping demand curve for
more-not relatively less-productive, skills. But this tendency of tlie skill pre-
which is consistent with o > 1. I n fact, mium to fall could be counteracted by
as noted above, most estimates sliow an changes in technology, as captured by
22 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

ln (Al,/Al). Therefore, this simple for- of wages and employment. Autor, Katz,
i$ulation encapsulates the essence of and Krueger (1998) report employment
tlie two forces that Tinbergen (1975) and wage-bill shares for different
emphasized: groups of workers in their appendix ta-
The two preponderant forces at work are ble A l . If we assume a specific value for
technological development, which made for o , we can translate tliese numbers into
a relative increase in demand and hence in clianges in Al,/Al. In particular, notice
the income ratio . . . and inci-eased access that the relative wage bill of skilled
to schooling, \vhich made for a relative workers is given by
decrease. ( p . 35, italics in original)

As discussed in the empirical trends


section, the past sixty years, and par-
ticularly the past thirty years, have wit- Hence, we have
nessed a rapid increase in the supply of
skills, H I L , but no corresponding fall in
the skill premium. This implies that the
demand for skills must have increased- In table 1, I calculate the implied
as a result of Tinbergen's "teclinological A{,/Az values for 0 = 1.4 and for o = 2
developmentm-to prevent tlie relative using workers witli some college, col-
wages of skilled workers from declining. lege graduates, and college equivalents
Althougli in riclier models tliere could definitions of Autor, Katz, and Krueger
be otlier factors leading to such a steady (1998)-see their paper for a more de-
increase in the demand for skills, the tailed analysis that controls for potential
cause highlighted by this simple fraine- composition effects. In all cases, there
work, skill-biased technical change, is a is a large implied increase in A{,/Al and
natural candidate. More explicitly, the (Al,/Al)(O- l)/O. For example, the num-
relative productivity of skilled workers, bers indicate that, assuming an elastic-
(A{,/Al)(O- 1)/0, must liave increased. ity of substitution of 1.4, the relative
The increase in (Ah/Al)(O-l)/o can be productivity of college graduates, Ah/&,
interpreted in a number of different which was approximately 0.030 in 1960,
ways. In a two-good economy, such skill- increased to 0.069 in 1970, and to 0.157
biased teclinical change corresponds to in 1980. Between 1980 and 1990, it in-
an increase in Al,/Al and p > O ( o > 1) creased by a factor of almost three to
-i.e., skilled workers becoming more reacli 0.470. As equation (5) sliows,
productive. Skill-biased technical change changes in the demand index
could also take the form of a decrease D = (A{,/A~)? may be more informative
in Al,/Al and p < O ( o < 1). In this case than clianges in A{,/Al, so table 1 also
tlie "pliysical" productivity of unslzilled gives the evolution of D.
workers would increase, but their rela- T h e view that the post-war period is
tive wages would fall d u e to relative characterized by skill-biased technical
price effects. Alternatively, with tlie change also receives support from the
one-good interpretation, skill-biased within-industry changes in employment
technical change simply corresponds to patterns. With constant teclinology, an
a change in the production function increase in the relative price of a factor
that increases (Ah/Al)(o- I)/". should depress its usage in all sectors.
Some back-of-tlie-envelope calcula- Since the college premium increased
tions provide a sense of the rise in Ah/& after 1979, with constant technology,
implied by the clianges in tlie structure there should be fewer college graduates
Acemoglu: Technical C h a n g e , I n e q u a l i t y , a n d t h e L a b o r M a r k e t 23

TABLE 1
EMPLOYMENT
SHARES
AND SKILL-BIASED
TECHNICAL 1940-1990
CHANGE,

Elnployment Share Wage Bill Share


Some College College Some College College
college graduate equivalent college graduate equivalent
1940 6.4 6.1 9.3 8.9 12.3 16.7
1950 9.5 7.7 12.4 11.0 11.9 17.4
1960 12.5 10.1 16.4 14.1 16.4 23.4
1970 16.4 13.4 21.5 16.5 21.5 29.7
1980 23.6 19.2 31.0 22.4 28.1 39.3
1990 30.8 24.0 39.3 28.5 36.7 51.0
0 = 1.4 0=2

Some College College Some College College


college graduate equivalent college graduate equivalent
-
Ah -
"1' -
"1' -
A" "1' "1'
- D
AI AI A1 4I "I AI

1940 0.004 0.21 0.016 0.31 0.035 0.38 0.140 0.37 0.303 ,055 0.392 0.63
1950 0.006 0.24 0.011 0.28 0.030 0.37 0.146 0.38 0.219 0.47 0.313 0.56
1960 0.013 0.29 0.030 0.37 0.080 0.48 0.189 0.43 0.343 0.59 0.476 0.69
1970 0.017 0.32 0.069 0.47 0.179 0.61 0.199 0.45 0.485 0.70 0.652 0.81
1980 0.042 0.40 0.157 0.59 0.486 0.81 0.270 0.52 0.643 0.80 0.933 0.97
1990 0.090 0.50 0.470 0.81 1.777 1.18 0.357 0.60 1.064 1.03 1.673 1.29

Note: The first panel gives the ratio of the employment of skilled relative to unskilled workers, and the wage bill of
skilled to unskilled workers for the corresponding skill categories. These data are taken from Autor, Katz, and
Krueger (1998). Some college refers to those with more than high school (hence the measure is those with more
than high school divided by those with high school or less). College graduate refers to all those with a college
degree, and college equivalent is defined, as in Autor et al., as those with a college degree + 0.5 x those with some
college (correspondingly, the unskilled are defined as those with high school and less + 0.5 x those wit11 some
college). The bottom panel gives the implied technology shifts usi;glequation (9) above for different values of the
elasticity of substitution. The demand index D is defined as ( A j r / A l ) ~

employed in all sectors-and the sec- complementarity during tlie 1910s and
toral composition should adjust in order 1920s. In light of this evidence, one
to clear the market. The evidence is very might consider the bulk of tlie twenti-
much the opposite. Berman, Bound, eth century to have been characterized
and Griliches (1994) and Murphy and by skill-biased technical change, though
Welch (1993) show a steady increase in whether technical cliange during the
the share of college labor in all sectors. early twentieth century was or was not
This discussion leads to my first con- skill-biased is not central for tlie focus
clusion, which I highlight for future of this paper.
reference.
4. Steady- Demand and Acceleration
Conclusion 1. The past sixty years must Hypotheses
have been characterized by skill-biased
technical change. The previous section liighlighted the
importance of skill-biased technical
Furthermore, Goldin and Katz (1998) cliange over the past several decades. A
provide evidence of teclinology-skill first liypothesis is that skill-biased
24 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. X L ( M a r c h 2002)

teclinical change takes place steadily- to equation ( l l ) ,"technological devel-


at a constant pace-over time. Alfred Mar- opments" take place at a constant rate,
shall begins The Principles of Econom- but the supply of skilled workers could
ics by reiterating tlie eighteenth-century grow at different rates. Therefore,
taxonomist Carl Linneaus' motto that changes in the returns to skills are
"Nature does not inake leaps." I t is also caused by uneven growth in tlie sup-
natural in this context to begin with a ply of skills. When HIL grows faster
hypothesis in which skill-biased techni- than the rate of skill-biased technical
cal change does not inake jumps, but change, (o - l)yl, the skill premium will
progresses steadily. The alternative fall. And when the supply growth falls
would be a process tliat is at times more short of this rate, the skill premium will
skill-biased tlian otliers-or even unskill- increase. T h e story has obvious appeal
biased during some episodes. In this because the 1970s, when returns to
section, I contrast tlie steady-demand scliooling fell sharply, were a period of
hypothesis, which maintains that skill- faster than usual increase in the supply
biased technical change has progressed of college graduate workers as figure 1
at a constant pace over the post-war pe- and table 1 show. I n contrast, the 1980s
riod, against the acceleration hypothe- were a period of slow increase in the
sis, which sees a break with past trends supply of skills relative to the 1970s.
in recent decades. Katz and Murpliy (1992) estimate a ver-
sion of equation (11) above using ag-
4.1 Steady- Denzand Hypothesis gregate data between 1963-87.1" Tliey
find
According to this hypothesis, there
has been no major change in the struc-
ture of demand for skills. Versions of
this story have been suggested by Free-
man (1976), and it has been proposed This approach does fairly well in captur-
as an explanation for tlie changes in tlie ing the broad features of the changes in
wage structure during the 1970s and the college premium between 1963 and
the 1980s by Katz and Murphy (1992), 1987. Tlie predicted values from the
and more recently by Murpliy, Riddell, above equation are quite close to tlie ob-
and Roiner (1998) and Card and served movements in the college pre-
Lemieux (2000). mium, suggesting tliat the U.S. labor
In a simple form, this hypothesis can market since 1963 can be characterized
be captured by writing by an elasticity of substitution between
college graduate workers and noncollege
workers of about o = 1/0.71= 1.4, and an
annual increase in the demand for skills
where t is calendar time. Substituting at tlie rate of about 3.3 percent (or
this equation into ( 5 ) ,we obtain yl = 2 . 0.033 = 0.115). The increase
in the college premium during the 1980s
is then explained by tlie slowdown in the
15They use the relative supply of college
equivalent workers. This is defined as college
I t is useful to link this equation to the graduates + 0.29 x sonle college - 0.05 x high
school dropouts divided by high school gradu-
two forces discussed above, and emplia- ates + 0.69 x some college + 0.93 x high school
sized by Tinbergen (1975). According dropouts.
Acemoglu: Technical C h a n g e , Inequality, a n d t h e L a b o r iMarlcet 25

growth rate of the supply of college biased technical change. I t is hard to


graduate workers. know whether the computer wage pre-
Nevertlieless, there are a number of mium is for computer skills, or wlietlier
reasons for preferring a cautious inter- it is even related to the widespread
pretation of this regression evidence. use of computers in the labor market.
The regression uses only 25 aggregate For example, DiNardo and Jorn-Steffen
observations, and tliere is significant se- Pisclike (1997), Horst Enthorf and
rial correlation in the college premium Francis Kramartz (1998) and Lex Bor-
(as also noted by Katz and Murphy). If ghans and Bas T e r Wee1 (2000) show
the true data were generated by an ac- that the computer wage premium is
celeration in skill bias and a larger likely to be a preiniuin for unobserved
value of the elasticity of substitution, skills.16
this regression could estimate a smaller Tlie second set of evidence comes
elasticity of substitution and no accel- from tlie cross-industry studies of,
eration in the demand for skills (see be- among others, Berman, Bound, and
low on tliis). For example, Katz and Griliches (1994), Autor, Katz and
Murphy sliow tliat if the true elasticity Krueger (1998), and Stephen Machin
of substitution is o = 4, a significant ac- and Jolin Van Reenan (1998). These pa-
celeration in the skill bias of technical pers document tliat almost all industries
change is required to explain the data. began employing more educated work-
Moreover, from the wage-bill sliare ers during tlie 1970s and tlie 1980s.
data reported above, Autor, Katz, and They also show that more computerized
Krueger (1998) conclude that even for industries experienced more rapid skill
the range of the values for the elasticity upgrading, i . e . , they increased their de-
of substitution between o = 1 and 2, mand for college-educated workers more
slzill-biased technical change is likely to rapidly. For example, Autor, Katz, and
have been more rapid during the 1980s Krueger run regressions of changes in
than tlie 1970s. This can also be seen in the college wage-bill share in three-
table 1 above, where, for most mea- digit industries on computer use
sures, the increase in (A~/A~)Y appears between 1984 and 1993. They find:
much larger between 1980 and 1990
tlian in otlier decades. W e therefore
need to discuss more detailed evidence
on this issue.
4.2 Evidence o n Steady-Denzand versus where ASc denotes the annual change in
Acceleration the wage-bill share of college graduates
The first piece of evidence often put in that industry (between tlie indicated
forth in support of an acceleration re- dates), and A C Z L ~ is
J - tlie
~ ~ increase in
lates to tlie role of computers in the the fraction of workers using computers
labor market. Krueger (1993) argued in that industry between 1984 and 1993.
that computers changed the structure of Tliese regressions are informative since
wages, and showed that workers using 16 Equally, however, it would be wron to inter-
computers are paid more, and this com- pret the findings of DiNardo and Pisclze (1997)
puter wage preiniuin has increased over and Enthorf and Krainartz (1998) as evidence
time. Altliough tliis pattern is striking, against an acceleration in skill-biased technical
change, since, as argued below, such technical
it is not particularly informative about change would increase the market prices for a
the presence or acceleration of skill- variety of skills, including unobserved skills.
26 Journal of Economic Literature, V ol . X L ( M a r c h 2002)

the college wage-bill share is related to the demand for skills, since industries
the demand for skills as shown by equa- that are highly computerized may de-
tion (9). The results indicate that in an mand more skilled workers for other
industry where computer use increased reasons as we11.18 In fact, when Autor,
by 10 percent, the college wage-bill Katz, and Krueger (1998) run the above
share grew by about 0.15 percent a year regressions for the 1960-70 college
faster between 1980 and 1990, and 0.3 wage-bill shares, they obtain
percent faster a year between 1990 and
1996.
Although this evidence is suggestive,
it does not establish that there has been Therefore, industries investing more in
a change in the trend growth of skill- computers during the 1980s were al-
biased technology. As pointed out in ready experiencing more skill upgrading
conclusion 1 above, the only way to during the 1960s, before the spread of
make sense of the post-war trends is to computers (though perhaps slower than
incorporate skill-biased technical change after the 1980s, since the coefficient
over the whole period. Moreover, here is about half of that between 1980
Goldin, and Katz (1998) present evi- and 1990). This suggests that at least
dence suggesting that capital-skill com- part of the increase in the demand for
plementarity may have been as high skills coming from highly computerized
during the 1910s as during the recent industries may not be the direct effect of
period because of increased demand for computers, but reflect a secular long-run
skills coming from the introduction of shift toward more skilled workers. So
electricity in most manufacturing pro- faster skill upgrading by highly comput-
cesses. Similarly, even though there erized industries is not inconsistent with
were few computers in workplaces the steady-demand hypothesis.
before the 1970s, other technological The third, and probably most power-
developments may have increased the ful, piece of evidence in favor of an ac-
demand for skills as rapidly as-or more celeration in skill bias also comes from
rapidly than-computers. Therefore, the Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998). They
question is whether computers and the document that the supply of skills grew
associated information technology ad- faster between 1970 and 1995 than be-
vances increased the demand for skills tween 1940 and 1970-by 3.06 percent
more than other technologies did dur- a year during the latter period com-
ing the 1950s and the 1960s, or even pared to 2.36 percent a year during the
earlier. This question cannot be an- earlier thirty years. In contrast, the col-
swered by documenting that computer- lege premium increased between 1970
ized industries demand more skilled and 1995 by about 0.39 percent a year,
workers.17 while it fell by about 0.11 percent a
Cross-industry studies also may not year during the earlier period. If de-
reveal the true impact of computers on mand for skills had increased at a steady
pace, the college premium should have
17This argument is related to a point first raised
by Lawrence Mishel and Jared Bernstein (1994). 18 Mark Dorns, Timothy Dunne, and Kenneth
They ointed out that rnuch of the evidence pre- Troske (1997) show that new technolo ies (but
s e n t e l i n favor of the impact of technolo on in-
equality shows that there has been skZK-biased
1
not con~puters)are adopted by plants t at have
rnore skilled and inore highly aid workers, and
technical change during the 1980s, not that skill- ants do not increase tgeir wages or de-
biased technical change has accelerated relative to
earlier periods.
btP
:id ~ d skills
r
technologies.
after the ilnplenlentation of these
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 27

also fallen since 1970.1Qoreover, more flexible time trends show an accel-
Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) docu- eration in the relative demand for skills
ment greater within-industry skill up- during the 1970s or the 1980s (the cubic
grading in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s and quartic time trends are almost iden-
than in t h e 1960s, which is also con- tical, hence practically indistinguishable
sistent with more rapid skill-biased in the figure).
technical change during these later A fourth piece of evidence comes
decades. from Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997)
A simple regression analysis also con- and Per Krusell e t al. (2000). These
firms this point. I combined t h e data authors argue, based on t h e work of
from the March CPSs and decennial Griliches (1969), that equipment capital
censuses used in figure 1 above. Using is more complementary to skilled work-
these data, a regression similar to that ers than unskilled workers. This prem-
of Katz and Murphy for t h e period ise may b e reasonable since advances in
1939-96 yields similar results: equipment often appear to substitute
machines for tasks previously per-
formed by unskilled workers. Following
t h e work by Robert Gordon (1990) and
with an R h f 0.63 and an implied elastic-
ree en wood, Zvi Hercowitz, and Krusell
(1997), these papers document that t h e
ity of substitution of 1.8, which is some-
post-war period has witnessed a secular
what larger than the estimate of Katz
decline in the relative price of equip-
and Murphy. However, adding higher
ment capital, and argue that t h e associ-
order terms in time (i.e., time squared,
ated increase in the stock of equipment
time cubed, etc.) improves the fit of the
capital led to skill-biased technical
model considerably, and these higher-
change. Moreover, they argue that this
order terms are significant. I n figure 5, I
relative decline accelerated in t h e early
plot the implied time trends from regres-
1970s, and the associated acceleration
sions with higher-order terms as well as the
in t h e stock of equipment capital
linear trend (all numbers were rescaled
increased the demand for skills.
to fit in one graph). All three of these
Krusell e t al. (2000) formalize their
1Qhe college premium fell between 1940 and approach by assuming the following
1970 in part because it is estimated to be very high production function:
in the 1940 census. There may b e reasons to be
suspicious of data quality from this census, be-
cause (i) the education variable was different, (ii)
r = K : [ ~ ~ L+P( 1 - bl)(bz~,h
there may have been an overstatement of years of
+ ( 1 - bz)Hh)b/h](l- a)/P
schooling, possibly by as much as a factor of 1.5 or where K, is structures capital (such as
2 for sorne cohorts, and (iii) there was no self-
employment income in this census. But it is not buildings), and K, is equipment capital
clear whether any of these rneasurernent problems (such as machines). The parameter
will cause an upward bias in the college premiurn. ol = 1 / ( 1 - A) is the elasticity of substitu-
a
In any case, the level of the colle e premiurn from
this census is not out of line wit other historical
evidence (see, e.g., Goldin and Katz 2000; and
tion between equipment and skilled
workers, and o z = 1 / ( 1 - y ) is the elastic-
Piketty and Saez 2001). Moreover Autor, Katz, and ity of substitution between unskilled
Krueger show that even ignoring data from the
1940 census, there is evidence for an acceleration workers and the equipment-skilled
in the skill bias of technical change. For example, worker aggregate. If o l > o z (i.e., y > A),
for the range of the values for the elasticity of sub- equipment capital is more complemen-
stitution between o = 1 and 2, skill-biased techni-
cal change appears more rapid during the 1980s tary to skilled workers than unskilled
than in the 1970s and the 1960s. workers, and an increase in K, will
28 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
o linear time trend o quadratic time trend
+ cubic time trend A quartic time trend

I I I I I - ----- 7I
39 49 59 69 79 89 96
year
Alternative Time Trends for the Relative Demand for Skills
Figure 5. Estimates of Time Trends froin Regressions of In on In (HIL),year, yea+, year3 and year4
between 1939 and 1996 (with observations in 1939, 1949, 1959 froin the decennial censuses and
observations for 1963-96 froin the March CPSs)

increase the wages of skilled workers equipment goods, t h e r e will b e an asso-


more than the wages of unskilled work- ciated increase in t h e quantity of equip-
ers. More formally, the skill premium in ment capital, K,, increasing t h e demand
this model is for skills steadily.
Figure 6, which plots t h e log of this
relative price series, shows the faster
proportional decline after t h e 1970s.
T h e behavior of t h e relative price series
then suggests that t h e r e may have been
Differentiation of (12) shows that as an acceleration in t h e substitution of
long as y > A, which corresponds to equipment capital for labor, causing
equipment capital being more comple- more rapid skill-biased technical change.
mentary to skilled workers than un- Nevertheless, because t h e r e are seri-
skilled workers, we have do/d& > 0. So ous difficulties in adjusting capital
provided that equipment capital is more prices for quality, we may want to b e
complementary to skilled workers than cautious in interpreting this evidence.
unskilled workers, an increase in the Another problem comes from t h e fact
quantity of equipment capital will in- that, as I discuss in more detail below, a
crease t h e demand for skills. Since t h e variety of other evidence does not sup-
post-war period has been characterized port the notion of faster technological
by a decline in the relative price of progress since 1974, which is a basic
Acenzogku: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 29

o Log rel. price of equip. capital Pre-1974 trend


Post-1974 trend

lo

year
Figure 6. Behavior. of the Log Relative Price of Equipment Capital, 1963-92

tenet of this approach. Finally, one column 1. T h e remainder of t h e table


would presume that if, in fact, t h e de- shows that once these terms are entered
cline in t h e relative price of equipment simultaneously with the time trend, the
capital is related to the increase in the time t r e n d is significant, while there is
demand for skills, then in a regression no evidence that t h e relative price of
of equation ( l l ) ,it should proxy for t h e equipment capital matters for the de-
demand for skills and perform better mand for skills. While this evidence
than a linear time t r e n d . Table 2 re- may simply reflect t h e fact that the rela-
ports a series of regressions which show tive price of equipment is measured
that, on the contrary, the level o r the with error, it casts some doubt on the
log of the relative price of equipment view that t h e relative price of equip-
capital is not significant in such regres- ment capital is directly linked t o the
sions. Column 1 shows the equivalent of demand for skills and that its faster
the regression by Katz and Murphy decline since t h e 1970s indicates an
(1992) with only a time trend and the acceleration in skill bias.
relative supply of skills. Columns 2 and A final piece of evidence for accelera-
3 show regressions that replace t h e time tion comes from t h e behavior of overall
trend with the level and log of the rela- and residual inequality over the past
tive price of equipment capital. These several decades. T h e sharp rise in both
terms are significant, but the fit of the overall and residual wage inequality
regression is worse than t h e one in since the early 1970s, documented in
30 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2 0 0 2 )

TABLE 2
THE EFFECTOF THE RELATIVE
PRICE OF EQUIPMENT
ON SKILLED
PREMIA

Dependent variable is log college premium


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Relative supply -0.742 -0.388 -0.610 -0.691 -0.740
(0.053) (0.037) (0.068) (0.100) (0.054)
Time 0.026 0.022 0.024
(0.002) (0.007) (0.005)
Log relative price

Relative price

Adjusted R2 0.900 0.864 0.795 0.898 0.897

Note: This table reports the regression of the log college prerniuin on a linear time trend,
the log relative supply of skilled workers and various measures of the relative price of
equipment capital. For comparability, all data taken from Krusell et al. (2000).

section 2, weighs in favor of a marked Pierce view, instead, suggests that the
change in labor market prices and de- increase in residual inequality and t h e
mand for skills during recent decades. bulk of t h e rise in overall inequality
This argument is based on the view that are related to changes in labor market
changes in residual inequality reflect prices, and therefore to t h e supply and
changes in labor market prices, a thesis demand for skills. Second, according to
put forth by Chinhui Juhn, Murphy, this view, the rise in residual inequality
and Brooks Pierce (1993)." This view is is an important piece of evidence in the
important for an interpretation for the debate on acceleration: residual in-
recent changes in wage structure for equality, which was stable during the
two reasons. First, as the evidence in 1960s, began to increase rapidly during
section 2 indicates, much of the recent the early 1970s (figures 2 and 3), indi-
increase in overall inequality is d u e to cating a discontinuity in labor market
the rise in residual inequality. If resid- prices and, most likely, in the rate of
ual inequality were unrelated to the de- increase of the demand for skills.
mand and supply of skills, the frame- A concrete example is useful for clari-
work here could only account for a fying why residual inequality is linked
relatively small fraction of the increase to labor market prices. Suppose that
in overall inequality. T h e Juhn-Murphy- two otherwise identical individuals dif-
fer in terms of their unobserved skills
" Of course, an alternative-and inore cynical-
(for example, in terms of interpersonal
view would b e to interpret residual inequality as
"a measure of our ignorance" (as Moses Abraino- skills, motivation, specific skills for their
vitz 1957 did for T F P ) . When a standard wa e
regression such as (1) provides a good fit, t e a
residuals will be less disperse. Nevertheless, given
job, o r IQ)." Denote t h e unobserved

the variety of skills that we are unable to measure fl By unobserved skills, I inean skills that are
in standard data sets, much of the residual will not observed by the econometrician. These skills
plausibly reflect rewards to some unobserved could be-and are likely to be-observed by em-
skills. ~ l o y e r sT
. hese types of skills are often referred to
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, a n d the L a b o r Market 31
skill of individual 1 by a1 and that of behavior of overall and residual in-
individual 2 by a2 > al, and assume that equality since the 1970s suggest a
wages are given by marked shift in the demand for skills
In w,t = 28ta, + yth,, (13) over the past several decades. I therefore
tentatively conclude:23
where yt is the price of h skills at time t,
while 8t is the price of a skills. Since
these individuals are identical in all re- Conclusion 2. T h e behavior of returns
to schooling and residual inequality
spects other than their unobserved skills,
a , we have the variance of log wages over the past three decades suggests an
acceleration in the demand for skills
(or of residual wages) among these two
individuals as: beginning in the 1970s or 1980s.
Var(1n to) = - a1)2.
5. Acceleration in Skill Bias
Now if at a later date, t', this variance
What explains the more rapid in-
increases to Var(1n w)', and we know that
these two individuals are still identical crease in the demand for skills over
t h e past several decades? T h e first pos-
in all other respects and that a2 - a1 has
sibility is a change in labor market insti-
not changed, we can interpret the in-
tutions. T h e second is t h e role of in-
crease in Var(1nto) as reflecting an in-
creased international trade. T h e third is
crease in the price of unobserved skills,
more rapid skill-biased technical change.
8t. T h e discussion in the appendix
shows that t h e bulk of t h e increase in
I argue in section 6 that changes in
labor market institutions and t h e in-
overall and residual inequality cannot
creased importance of international
b e explained by composition effects,
trade cannot explain the change in labor
i.e., by changes in a z - a l , so this in-
crease is most likely d u e to a rise in t h e market prices by themselves. Moreover,
price of and demand for unobserved the evidence discussed in section 4 is
consistent with new technologies play-
skills during the 1 9 7 0 ~ . 2 V h e r e f o r e ,
ing an important role in changing t h e
with this interpretation, t h e rapid rise
wage structure. So h e r e I begin with
in t h e residual inequality during the
changes in technologies, and in particu-
1970s and t h e 1980s indicates a more
lar, I discuss "pure technological" ap-
rapid increase in demand for skills
proaches where technology is t h e only
during these decades than earlier.
factor determining t h e demand for
Overall, there is a variety of evidence
skills.
suggesting an acceleration in skill bias
over the past 25-30 years. Although not 5.1 "Techtzological Re2jolutiotzs" atzd
all evidence is equally convincing, the Acceleratiotz in Skill Bias
rise in the returns to schooling over t h e
T h e first group of technological theo-
past thirty years, despite the very rapid
ries links the acceleration in skill bias to
increase in the supply of skills, and the
exogenous technological developments,
and argues that a "technological revolu-
as "unobserved ability." This does not iinply that
these unobserved skills are necessarily synony- tion" led to more rapid skill-biased
mous with IQ or other single dirneilsional skill technical change beginning in t h e 1970s
indices.
'"ut differently, the absence of large coin osi "The most important caveat is that the avail-
tion effects indicates that the rise in r e s i d u 3 in: able data suggest relatively slow skill-biased tech-
equality likely reflects changes in the demand nical change during the second half of the 1990s
for unobserved skills rather than changes in the (see Mishel, Bernstein, and John Schinitt 1998;
"supply of unobserved skills." and Murphy and Welch 2000).
32 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

or the 1980s. I n terms of the model de- acceleration is that new technologies
veloped above, this corresponds to a are more complementary to skilled
more rapid increase in Ah/Az during this workers than to unskilled workers-for
period, translating into greater skill pre- example, there are more rapid advances
mia. Many of the proponents of this in the technologies used by skilled
view argue that the acceleration in skill workers, as captured by Ai, above. Rapid
bias is, at least in part, related to infor- technological progress then corre-
mation technology and computers (for sponds to an acceleration in slcill bias.
example, Krueger 1993; Berman, Bound, An alternative perspective, building on
and Griliches 1994; Autor, Katz, and an idea originally suggested by Nelson
Krueger 1998; Berman, Bound, and and Phelps (1966), also focuses on the
Machin 1998). effect of rapid technical change on in-
An interesting version of this story is equality, but puts the emphasis on the
the one developed by Krusell e t al. ability of skilled workers to deal with
(2000) discussed above. They argue that the introduction of new technologies.
the demand for skills accelerated as a According to this view, demand for
result of the more rapid decline in skills will automatically increase during
the relative price of capital equipment periods of rapid technological change.
beginning in the early 1 9 7 0 ~ The .~~ Welch (1970) gave an early succinct
Krusell e t al. theorv is attractive since it
i
summary of these two views. T h e first
provides a unified framework in which view, which we may call the accelera-
we can identify both the cause of the tion hypothesis, sees human capital as a
steady increase in the demand for skills, factor of production, and the more rapid
and the source of the more r aL ~ i dskill- increase in the demand for skills results
biased technical change, though the evi- from an acceleration in technical change
dence provided in the previous section that favors this factor of production. In
casts some doubt on the link between other words:
the relative price of equipment and the
demand for skills. [Tlechnical change may not be neutral
between skill classes. It may b e that incre-
T h e main idea of all these theories of
ments in technology result in increments in
the relative productivity of labor that are
241 classify this approach as one of exogenous positively related to skill level. (Welch 1970,
technology, since the driving force, the decline in p . 38)
the relative price of equipment capital, is assumed
exogenous.
An alternative interpretation of the approach by In contrast, the second vie\v-the
Krusell e t al. (2000) is that the main determinant Nelson-Phelps hypothesis-argues that25
of the demand for skills is not technology-skill
corn lementarit but capital skill complementarity. 25A recent paper by Samuel Bowles, Herbert
, . . -
I berieve that t e dist~nctionbetween technology- Gintis, and Melissa Osborne (2001) has a similar
skill versus capital-skill is not very useful. Capital- classification of different approaches. They call
skill complementarity could play an im ortant role the first view Walrasian, and the second Schumpe-
only in a model as in Greenwood e t a? (1997) or terian. I n the first, skills that enable workers to
Krusell e t al. (2000), where new capital embeds produce more are valued, while in the second, it is
superior technologies. In this sense, it is a combi- skills that enable workers to deal with changes in
nation of new capital and new technologies that is economic and social environments. They also pro-
increasing the demand for skills. Moreover, Autor, pose an alternative, Coasian, view, where "skills"
Katz, and Krueger (1998) show that demand for are workers' ca acity to work within organizations
more educated workers across industries is af- and follow autIority From the point of view of
fected by high-tech capital (e.g., computers), but the analysis here, this view is not fundamentally
not by equi rnent capital, suggesting further that different from the Walrasian view, since workers
it is new tec\nologies, not simply capital intensity, are paid more for skills that increase their marginal
that matters for inequality. contribution to the profits of their employers.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and t h e Labor Market 33
ITlhe ~
L i I
r o d u c t i v i t vof education would be approaches, it is useful to consider a
positively related to the rate of change in use- simple model based on Galor and Moav
ful technology (the ability to change) and to
the size of the tecl~nological gap (room for (2000). Suppose that
innovation). In this case, if the rate of utiliza-
tion of technology is accelerating, or if the A1 = $l(g)a and All = $lla (14)
technology gap i s growing, t h e return to
education will rise relative to other inputs. where a is a measure of aggregate tech-
(p. 38) nology, and g is the growth rate of a , i.e.,
g = b / n . The presumption that skilled
Studies building on the Nelson- workers are better equipped to deal with
Phelps hypothesis include Galor and technological progress can be captured
Tsiddon (1997), Greenwood and Yoru- by assuming that @'I < 0. Galor and Moav
koglu (1997), Caselli (1999), Aghion (2000) refer to this assumption as the
and Howitt (1998, ch. 9 ) , Galor and "erosion effect," since it implies that
Moav (2000), Violante (2000), Rubin- technical change erodes some of the es-
stein and Tsiddon (1999), Aghion, tablished expertise of unskilled workers,
Howitt and Violante (2000), and Gould, and causes them to benefit less from
Moav and Weinberg (2000).2'3These pa- technological advances than skilled work-
pers argue that there has been a tech- ers do. Substituting from (14) into (4),
nological revolution in the U.S. econ- the skill premium is
omy starting in the 1970s and relate the
rise in inequality to the increased
demand for skills resulting from the
technological revolution. For example,
Greenwood and Yorulzoglu (1997) draw
a parallel between the First and the
Second Industrial Revolutions and what
has been happening in the U.S. econ-
Therefore, as long as 4'1 < 0, more rapid
omy since 1974. Caselli (1999) develops
technological progress, as captured by a
a similar theory where a technological
higher level of g, will increase the skill
revolution increases the demand for
premium.
workers who can switch to the sectors
Theories that explain the increase in
that benefit from the introduction of
inequality as a result of rapid tech-
new technologies.27
nological progress have a number of
To get a basic understanding of these
attractive features.28 First, many econo-
" See Aghion (2001) for an approach that com- mists and commentators view the ad-
bines the Nelson-Phelps insi hts with the Schum- vances in computer and information
%;
peterian notion of creative- e struction to discuss
technology a
the impact of the diffusion of computers on -, as break with the tech-
inequality. nologies of the past, and so are open to
27The explanation offered by Rubinstein and
Tsiddon (1999), and Aghion, Howitt, and Violante 28These theories also predict that inequality
(2000) is somewhat different. They argue that should increase when new technologies are being
there is increased uncertainty at times of rapid introduced, but should decline when these new
technological change, and more skilled workers technologies are standardized and being used rou-
are better able to cope with uncertainty. This idea tinely by many firms (see, for example, Galor and
is also related to a thesis first put forth by Michael Tsiddon 1997, or Aghion, Howitt, and Violante
Piore and Charles Sabel (1984) that the oil price 2000). So far, there seems to be no evidence of a
shocks increased the uncertainty faced by produc- decline in inequality in the United States, but per-
ers, and induced them to change the organization haps the years to come will see a return to the
of production toward organizational forms that levels of inequality experienced during the 1960s,
require adaptable workers. vindicating this approach.
34 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

the idea that we might be in the midst I t is difficult to imagine how a new
of a technological revolution. Second, a and radically more profitable technol-
variety of evidence supports the notion ogy will first lead to 25 years of substan-
that skilled workers have a comparative tially slower growth. Although, in an
advantage in coping with rapid tech- influential paper, Paul David (1990)
nical change. Ann Bartel and Frank argues that the spread of electricity to
Lichtenberg (1987) show that firms in- American manufacturing was also slow
troducing new technologies hire more and productivity gains from electrifica-
skilled workers. Bartel and Nachum tion were limited until the 1920s, the
Sicherman (1998) document that re- parallel with the recent productivity
turns to unobserved ability appear to be slowdown should not be overstated.
higher in industries with more rapid First, though productivity growth from
technical change. Andrew Foster and electrification was sluggish during the
Mark Rosenzweig (1996) provide evi- early 1900s, the U. S, economy overall
dence from developing countries that had a much higher level of output
more educated workers are better growth than the growth levels experi-
placed to take advantage of advances in enced over the past three decades. Data
agricultural technology. from table A-XVIII of John Kendriclz
T h e main difficulty with both the (1961) imply that output growth be-
theories based on the acceleration and tween 1899 and 1909 in the U.S. econ-
the Nelson-Phelps hypotheses is that omy was 4.2 percent a year, while be-
they rely explicitly on rapid technical tween 1909 and 1919, it was 3 percent,
change in recent decades." There is and between 1920 and 1929, output
little direct evidence that the decades grew by 3.6 percent a year. Second, as
between 1970 and 1995 have been a pe- noted by Stephen Oliner and Daniel
riod of rapid technical change, how- Sichel (1994), computers and other ad-
ever. First, this period has experienced vanced office equipment have only been
sluggish T F P and output growth rela- a trivial part of the aggregate capital
tive to earlier periods. Greenwood and stock of the U.S. economy until the mid-
YorulzogIu (1997) and Hornstein and 1990s. I t is therefore unlikely that the
Krusell (1996) argue that the slow T F P whole of the U.S. economy has been
growth itself may be an outcome of the adapting to the changes in this rela-
more rapid technical change. According tively small part of the capital stock. Fi-
to this argument, new revolutionary nally, as shown by Ernie Brendt, Cath-
technologies first reduce productivity erine Morrison, and Larry Rosenblum
growth as firms and workers spend time (1994), more computerized sectors did
learning to use these technologies. not perform any better in terms of labor
productivity growth over this period;
this pattern is also difficult to recon-
29Another argument that applies only against cile with a computer-led technological
approaches based on the Nelson-Phelps hypothe-
sis is that historical evidence is not necessarily in revolution.
line with a view that demand for skills always in- I t is also useful to note that although
creases during times of rapid technical change. As computers have no doubt increased our
discussed in the introduction, the major techno-
logical changes of the early nineteenth century a standards of living and quality of life
ear to have been large1 skill-replacing (unski!: over the past thirty years, they may be
[iased), even though t i e g seem as radical as much less radical innovations than cer-
computer technolo y This suggests that it is
the skill bias of tec%*ology, not merely its ra id tain previous new technologies (see
arrival, that is important for the demand for skilys. Gordon 1998). To gain perspective,
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and t h e Labor Market 35
consider the difference that the tele- increase in the supply of skills. There is
graph made to a world in which the no a priori reason to expect the accel-
fastest medium of communication was eration in skill bias to coincide with the
pigeons. Mokyr (1990, p. 124) describes rapid increase in the supply of skills.
this as follows: Those who want to subscribe to the
exogenous technological progress view
The telegraph had an enormous impact o n
19th-century society-possibly as great as
have to explain this as a chance event.31
that of the railroad. Its community and politi- 5.2 Endogenous Skill-Biased Technical
cal value was vast, as was its effect in coordi-
nating international financial and commodity
Change
markets. Unlike the railroad, it had no close T h e theories discussed so far a r e -
substitutes, the closest being homing pigeons
and semaphore.
sume technical change to be skill-
biased b y nature (or, at the very least,
O r consider the difference that the auto- recent technologies to have increased
mobile and air conditioning made to the the demand for ;kills d u e to exogenous
"
quality of life, and electricity and in- reasons). A different perspective is to link
terchangeable parts made to the manu- the types of technologies that are devel-
facturing sector. As also pointed out by oped and adopted to (profit) incentives,
Gordon (1998), compared to these improve- or to demand pull as emphasized by
ments, the switch from mainframes to Schmookler (1966).s2
PCs, or from telephone to e-mail, or from Historical evidence is consistent with
the typewriter to the word processor may the notion that profit incentives and op-
be modest.30 aortunities are imnortant
L L
for the de-
A final problem for all of the ap- velopment and introduction of new
proaches based on exogenous techno- 3 l O n e could argue that the supply of skilled
logical developments is the coincidence workers increased because, during the 1960s,
in the timing of this change, and the workers anticipated that there was going to be a
technological discontinuity in the decades to
rapid increase in the supply of skilled come, and responded to this by increasing their
\vorlzers. Recall that there was a very education. This story appears quite unreasonable,
large increase in the supply of college however. There is no evidence that anyone, let
alone teenagers, foresaw the technological devel-
graduate \vorlzers during the late 1960s opments of the 1970s and the 1980s as early as the
and the early 1970s (figure 1 and table 1960s. Moreover, the increase in the supply of
1 show the large increase in the em- skills can be largely explained by two factors.
First, the Vietnam era draft laws encouraged
ployment share of college workers be- young males to stay in college lon e r (and indi-
tween 1970 and 1980). So the accelera- rectly also influenced female enroflments) Sec-
tion in skill bias is either concurrent ond, college enrollments were on an upward trend
since the early 1950s, and much of the increase in
with, or immediately follows, this large the suppl of college graduate workers is ac-
counted &r by the interaction of this upward
30Another ar ument is that our ability to mea- trend with the very large relative size of the baby
sure T F P grow$ may have deteriorated following boom cohorts.
a change in technological regime, However, as 32This is also the approach taken by the endog-
Martin Bailey and Gordon (1988) document, pro- enous rowth theory, which determines the overall
ductivity slowdown has been concurrent in many rate o f technical change-but not the degree of
sectors, some of them with little problems in skill bias-from profit incentives (e.g., Romer
measuring output or output uality. It is interest- 1990; Gene Grossrnan and Elhanan Helpman
ing to note, however, that evi3ence in favor of this
hypothesis may yet emerge, especial1 since pro-
ductivity growth has been quite rapidduring the
2
1991; A hion and Howitt 1992). An advantage of
the e n ogenous-technolog perspective in this
context is that it provides cLar reasons for the de-
past three years (but see Gordon 1998, and more gree of skill bias to increase even without a change
recently, Dale Jorgensen and Kevin Stiroh 2000, in the overall pace of technological improvement
on this). -see below.
36 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2002)

technologies. Fernand Braudel (1984, cotton gin on the South was nothing
p. 566) took a strong position on this: short of spectacular. In the court case
[Tlhe efficient application of technology over the patent rights, Judge Johnson
lags, by definition, behind the general move- wrote:
ment of the economy; it has to be called on,
sometimes several times, to meet a precise "[. . . as a result of the cotton gin] . . .
and persistent demand. individuals who were depressed with poverty,
and sunk with idleness, have suddenly risen to
An interesting example of the timing wealth and respectability. Our debts have been
of technological development respond- paid off, our capital increased; and our lands
are treble in value." (Quoted in Constance
ing to profit incentives is given by the Green 1956, p . 92)
introduction of the electric street car in
U.S. cities during the late nineteenth Within a short time, Eli Whitney's gin
century. In his history of electricity in turned the United States from a cotton
the United States, David Nye (1990) importer into the largest cotton exporter
describes this as follows: in the world.
Cities grew larger, better transportation Schmookler (1966) provides a famous
was needed, so t h e [electric] trolley was in- argument for the importance of demand
vented, called into being by the crowded late pull in the development of many tech-
nineteenth century cities . . . . By the 1870s nologies. H e documents rapid innova-
large cities had ceased to b e accessible by
foot, or built to the scale of pedestrians, and
tions in railroads follo\ving increased
traffic congestion was terrible. ( p . 85) purchases of railroad equipments, and
more generally argues that industries
This created the profit opportunities to with greater investments experience
develop and introduce the electric trol- faster technological progress because
ley. The technological requirements had the returns to such progress are greater.
been met long before, and awaited these A natural next step is then to argue that
profit opportunities. Nye writes, "How- the degree of skill bias in technical change
ever great the need for the electric trol- is also determined by profit opportuni-
ley after 1870, it was hardly a new idea; ties and by the demand for different
it had been the object of experiment types of technologies. Here, by endoge-
during four decades" (p. 86). nous (skill bias) technology approach I
Another example of the type of inno- mean the view that the degree of skill
vation responding to profit incentives is bias in technical change is influenced
provided by the cotton gin. In the late by profit incentive^.^^
eighteenth and early nineteenth centu- A key determinant of profitability is
ries, only green seed cotton, which was market size. As Schmookler (1966)
difficult to clean, could be grown in stated in the title of two of his chapters:
most of the American South, and Brit- "The amount of invention is gooerned by
ain imported most of its cotton from the t h e extent of t h e market." T h e most suc-
West Indies, Brazil, and India. A ma- cessful businessmen have always been
chine to remove the seeds was essential aware of this. For example, Matthew
for the success of American cotton. In
contrast to almost all other textile inno- 33An alternative explanation for the increase in
wage inequality based on endogenous technical
vations that were taking place in Eng- change is offered by Huw Lloyd-Ellis (1999). In
land and Europe, such a machine, the his model, it is the interaction between endoge-
cotton gin, was developed in the United nous technical change and the slowdown in the
growth of labor quality that leads to increased in-
States in 1793 by Eli Whitney in re- e uality. Skill bias is not endogenous in Lloyd-
sponse to this need. T h e impact of the Eylis' model.
Acemogku: Technical Clzange, Inequality, a n d t h e L a b o r Market

Boulton wrote to his business partner, his pioneering study of t h e supply-


James Watt, "It is not worth my while demand framework, in fact, foresaw this
to manufacture your engine for three possibility, and wrote (1975, p. 61): ". . .
countries only, but I find it very well an inequality-furthering phenomenon is
worth my while to make it for all technological development. But need it
t h e world" (quoted in Michael Scherer b e ? Increasingly we get t h e feeling that
1984, p . 1 3 ) . Schmookler (1966) simi- technological development is not simply
larly provided many examples where something given, but that it may b e
market size was crucial in determining guided, within limits."
the directions of technical change. T h e At some level, the idea that there will
horseshoe is perhaps the most interest- b e more technologies developed, cre-
ing one. Schmookler documented that ated and adopted for slzilled workers-
there was a very high rate of innovation "within limitsn-when t h e r e are more
throughout the late nineteenth and early skilled worlzers to use them is quite ap-
twentieth centuries in this very ancient pealing. An extreme form of this view is
technology, invented in the second cen- captured by my model in Acemoglu
tury B.C., and no tendency for inven- (1998), where forward-looking profit-
tors to run out of additional improve- maximizing firms create new technolo-
ments. O n the contrary, inventions and gies anticipating the profitability of
patents increased because demand for these different investments. According
horseshoes was high. Innovations came to this view, it would b e the Vietnam
to an e n d only when "the steam traction War draft laws and the high college e n -
engine and, later, internal combustion rollment rates of t h e baby boom cohorts
engine began to displace the horse . . ." that induced the development of com-
(p9 3 ) . puters. Such an interpretation is not lit-
According to this reasoning, t h e de- eral. A more plausible interpretation may
velopment of skill-biased technologies b e that new technological platforms-
will be more profitable when they have macroinoentions to use Joel Mokyr's
a larger market size-i.e., when t h e r e term, or General Purpose Technologies
are more skilled workers. Therefore, to use Bresnahan and Trajtenberg's term-
t h e equilibrium degree of skill bias stem from advances in basic science or
could b e an increasing function of the from labs with little profit-maximizing
relative supply of skilled workers. An incentive. T h e development of t h e mi-
increase in t h e supply of skills will t h e n crochip would b e such a macroinven-
lead to skill-biased technical change. tion. But what matters for most worlzers
Furthermore, an acceleration in the in t h e labor force is how this new tech-
supply of skills can lead to an accelera- nological platform is developed, i.e.,
tion in t h e demand for slzills. I t is useful t h e microinoentions that follow t h e
to link this approach to technological macroinvention. At t h e expense of over-
development with t h e above framework. simplifying, we can say that t h e micro-
While the above supply-demand frame- chip could have been used to develop
work explains the prices of skills by sup- advanced scanners to increase the pro-
ply and technology, t h e perspective of ductivity of unskilled workers, or ad-
endogenous skill bias relates technology vanced computer-assisted machines to
to the supply of skills.34 Tinbergen, in b e used by slzilled workers to replace
unskilled workers. T h e theory of endog-
34 Naturally, it is also possible to link the supply enous skill bias requires that the extent of
of skills to skill prernia. See below for a discussion. the advances in these two technologies
38 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

is affected by profit opportunities. When profit-maximizing monopolists. Creat-


there are more college graduates, com- ing a new machine costs B units of the
puters become relatively more profit- final good Y, and the marginal cost of
able to develop than scanners, and this producing these machines, once cre-
explains the acceleration in skill bias.35 ated, is zero. T h e marginal willingness
T h e endogenous response of firms to to pay for an additional machine in the
the increase in supply will raise the de- two sectors is given by the derivatives
mand for slzills. I n fact, supply may not of phYjl and plYl with respect to Nh and
simply create its own demand, but the Nz, i.e.,
response of firms could be so pro- pr,H and pzL. (17)
nounced that demand could ooershoot I assume that the creator of each new
the supply. I n this theory, therefore, machine obtains this "market" marginal
the increased supply may be the cause \villingness to pay (see Acemoglu 1998,
of the increase in the skill premium for a more rigorous and detailed discus-
(see Acemoglu 1998, and also Michael sion). Equation (17) therefore highlights
Kiley 1999). Here I outline a simplified two effects that encourage the creation
version of this theory based on the above of new technologies.
framework.
Suppose that consumers have a utility 1. The price effect: technologies produc-
function defined over Y = [YIP
+Y;]~/P, ing more expensive goods will be im-
and that Yh = NhH and Y L =N1L where Nh proved faster. Since goods using the
and N1 can be interpreted as the num- scarce factor will command a higher
ber of specialized machines used with price (see equation 16), this effect
slzilled and unskilled workers, respec- implies that there will be more inno-
tively. This is equivalent to the above vation directed at the scarce factor-
setup with Ah = N I , and Az=Nz. An in- i.e., directed at unskilled workers
crease in N1, relative to N1 will corre- during the 1970s and the 1980s.
spond to skill-biased technical change 2. The market size effect: a larger clien-
as long as o = 1/(1- p) > 1. From con- tele for a technology leads to more
sumer maximization, the relative price innovation. Since the clientele for a
of skill-intensive goods is technology is the number of workers
who use it, the market size effect en-
courages innovation for the more
abundant factor, and encourages
where once again ph denotes the price of more technologies for skilled and
good Yh and pl is the price of Y1 . highly educated workers during the
Suppose now that these specialized 1970s and the 1980s.
machines are created and sold by T h e creation of new machines will
35 There is some evidence that the composition
stop when the marginal increase in
of R&D shifted toward more skill-biased tech- profits is equal to the marginal cost of
nologies during the period of the rapid increase in innovation in both sectors. This implies
the supply of college-educated workers. From the
R&D expenditure data reported by the NSF, in
that in equilibrium
1960 company funded R&D for office computing
was 3 percent of the total company funded R&D
expenditure. This ratio had increased to 13 percent
b y 1987, suggesting that during this pe;iod of i.e., the price and market size effects
raoid increase in the suaalv of skills. there was
siinificantly more ~ & ~ ' h i ; e c t e dto 'one of the
have to be balanced in equilibrium. How
technologies most complementary to skills. can equation (18) be satisfied? Since H I L
Acenzogku: Technical C h a n g e , Inequality, a n d tlze L a b o r Market 39
is fixed, equation (18) can only hold if T h e r e are a number of implications
the relative price of skill-intensive goods, that follow from this approach. First, as
p = ph/pl, adjusts. From equation (16), this t h e relative supply of skilled workers
can only happen if Nh/Nz changes. There- has been growing througliout the past
fore, in this economy, the skill bias of tech- sixty years, we expect technology to e n -
nology has to adjust in order to "clear the dogenously respond by becoming more
technology market." Combining (16) and skill-biased over time. If t h e elasticity
(18), we obtain equilibrium skill bias as of substitution between skilled and un-
skilled workers is greater than 2, i . e . ,
p > 1/2, t h e increase in t h e demand for
- ,
skilled workers would b e more than
This equation shows that when p > 0, i.e., enough to offset t h e increase in the
when skilled and unskilled good are gross supply of skilled workers, and t h e econ-
substitutes, the market size effect will omy would b e moving steadily along an
dominate the price effect, and a greater upward-sloping relative demand curve
relative supply of skilled workers will lead for skills. This would explain why re-
to more skill-biased technologies-higher turns to college have been increasing
ATh/N1. over t h e past half century.
Finally, by substituting from equation A new theory for t h e acceleration in
( 1 9 ) , the skill premium in this economy slzill bias also emerges from this simple
is model. According to this theory, t h e
rapid increase in t h e supply of college
educated worlzers during t h e 1970s cre-
ated a more pronounced shift toward
where the final expression is obtained by skill-biased technologies, further in-
combining (16) and (19). creased t h e demand for skill, and raised
T h e most important result is that if t h e college premium. This story be-
p > 1/2, i.e., if the elasticity of substitu- comes more interesting once we recog-
tion G is greater than 2, t h e skill pre- nize that the equilibrium slzill bias of
mium will b e an increasing function of technologies, Nh/Nz, is a sluggish vari-
the relative supply of skills.36 This is be- able determined by t h e slow buildup
cause an increase in H I L encourages so and development of new technologies.
much skill-biased technical change that I n this case, a rapid increase in the sup-
the demand for slzilIs increases more than ply of skills first reduces the skill pre-
enough to offset t h e increase in t h e mium as t h e economy moves along a
supply of skills. As a result, t h e (long- constant technology (constant Nh/N1)
run) relative demand for slzills is an up- curve as drawn in figure 7. After a while
ward-sloping curve as drawn in figure 7, t h e technology starts adjusting, and t h e
and an increase in t h e supply of skilled economy moves back to t h e upward-
workers increases t h e skill premium. sloping relative demand curve, with a
very sharp increase in t h e college pre-
36The result that the elasticity of substitution mium. This theory therefore gives an
needs to be greater than 2 for the long-run rela- interpretation for both t h e decline in
tive demand to slope upwards is a feature of the
simple model here, and does not generalize to t h e college premium during t h e 1970s
richer environments. In any case, there are a nurn- and its subsequent surge, and relates
ber of estimates above 2, and a somewhat upward both to t h e large increase in the supply
sloping relative demand curve for skills, even with
this model's parameterization, is an empirical of skilled worlzers.
possibility. F o r the key insights of this theory,
40 Journal of Econonzic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Relative Wage

1 Long-run Relative
uemand for Slalls
Long-run Rel. Wage

Initial Rel. Wage

Short-run Response

I I I
r
Exogenous Shift in Relative Supply
Figure 7. The Dynamics of the Relative Wage of Skilled Workers in Response to an Increase in the Supply of
Skills with Elldogellous Skill-Biased Technical Change

that increases in the relative supply of Additional exogenous skill-biased tech-


skills induce skill-biased technical nical change is then necessary for the
change, we do not need the long-run skill premium to increase above its
relative demand curve to be upward- initial level.
sloping. When p < 1/2, increases in the There are also other historical epi-
supply of skills still induce skill-biased sodes in which a large increase in the
change, but this technical change is not supply of skills appears to have affected
enough to prevent the skill premiurn the direction of technical change. High
from falling. Further "exogenous" skill- school enrollment and graduation rates
biased technical change is also neces- doubled in the 1910s. Goldin and Katz
sary to explain why returns to schooling (1995) argue that increased enrollments
have risen over the past sixty years. were mostly driven by supply side fac-
With a downward-sloping long-run de- tors; changes in the location and curric-
mand curve, the story for the 1970s and ula of schools and improvements in
the 1980s is also different. The large in- transportation technology. The skill
crease in the supply of skills again premiurn fell sharply in the 1910s. But,
moves the economy along a steeply despite the even faster increase in the
downward-sloping constant technology supply of high school skills during the
demand curve. The response of technol- 1920s, the skill prerniurn levelled off
ogy then moves the econorny to a less and started a mild increase. Goldin and
steep long-run demand curve as drawn Katz (1995) conclude that the demand
in figure 8, raising the skill premium. for high school graduates must have
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Marlcet 41

Relative Wage
I I
I I
I I
I I
I
I
I
I
I

Initial Rel. Wage ..............

Long-run Rel. Wage


Long-run Rel, Wage ..............

Long-run Relative
Demand for Skills

Short-run Response
Short-run Response ..............
I
I
I
I I

Exogenous Shift in Relative Supply


Figure 8. The Dynamics of the Relative Wage of Skilled Workers in Response to an Increase in the Supply of
Skills -6th Limited Endogenous Skill-Biased Technical Change

expanded sharply starting in the 1920s, creased the Israeli population by 1 2


presumably d u e to changes in office percent in the first half of the 1990s. A
technology and higher demand from theory with exogenous technology
new industries, such as electrical ma- would predict a large decline in the
chinery, transport and chemicals (see relative wages of educated workers,
also Goldin and Katz 1998).37 very much as in the case of Palestinian
Another interesting case study comes labor discussed above.38 I n practice, the
from the resDonse
L
of the Israeli labor education premium did not fall (e.g.,
market to the influx of large numbers of Rachel Friedberg 1997). This seems to
highly educated immigrants from the be mainly because most industries in-
former Soviet Union. T h e size of this creased their employment of more
influx was enormous: migration in- skilled workers during this large influx
(Neil Gandal, Gordon Hanson, and
37As Goldin and Katz (2000) show using data Matthew Slaughter 2000; and Sarit
from Iowa Prairies, returns to education were
most likely higher in 1915 than in 1950. Although
this evidence suggests that the long-run relative 38The key difference between the two episodes
demand curve for skills was downward sloping is that Palestinian labor is a relatively small frac-
over this period, it is consistent with the notion of tion of the Israeli work force, so we expect much
skill-biased technical chan e induced by an in- less of a technology response to changes in the
crease in the s ~ l p p skilleb
l~ workers Specifically, educational composition of Palestinian labor. Fur-
during this period, demand for skills expanded thermore, Palestinian college graduates are not a
very rapidly to accommodate the very large in- close substitute for Israeli college graduates, and
crease in the supply of high school graduates (see only a limited range of occupations are open to
Goldin and Katz 1995, 2000). them.
42 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Cohen and Chang-Tai Hsieh 2000). of rural industry came to the cities.
This response suggests a change in Fourth, "there was a large influx of
the production structure toward more labor from Ireland" (p. 137). Finally,
skilled workers, consistent with the "technical changes in agriculture in-
theories outlined in this section.39 creased the supply of labor available to
Despite this evidence showing simul- industry" (p. 137).
taneous increases in the supply of, and According to the endogenous tech-
demand for, skills in a number of episodes, nology hypothesis, this increase in the
it is difficult to distinguish exogenous supply of unskilled labor should encour-
and endogenous technical change. The age unskill-biased technical change. And
exogenous technical change theory as predicted by this approach, there
maintains that technical change is often were inajor skill-replacing (unskill-
slzill-biased. Endogenous technical change biased) technologies introduced during
theory instead suggests that new tech- this period, most notably the factory
nologies should be skill-biased when system replacing tasks previously per-
the supply of skills increases. Since the formed by slzilled artisans. Moreover, in
supply of skills has increased most of his classic study, Habakkuk argues that
the time over the past one hundred or the increase in the supply of labor was
so years, the implications of the two an important inducement to the devel-
theories are quite similar. The increase opment of factory methods. He also
in the supply of unskilled labor in the quotes an American historian, Handlin,
English cities during the early nine- to explain why the adoption of factory
teenth century provides an interesting methods in the United States was
contrasting event for the two ap- solnewhat delayed. Handlin wrote:
proaches. Bairoch (1988, p. 245) de-
[N]o matter what degree of standard-
scribes this rapid expansion as follows: ization technical process of manufacturing
". . . between 1740 and 1840 the popu- reached, the absence of a cheap labor supply
lation of England . . . went up froin 6 precluded conversion to factory methods.
inillion to 15.7 million. . . . while the (p. 146)
agricultural labor force represented 60-
Habakkuk placed much more impor-
70% of the total work force in 1740, by
tance on the role of wages in determin-
1840 it represented only 22%." Habak-
ing innovation decisions, a view that
kuk (pp. 136-37) also emphasizes the
later became known as the "Habakkuk
increase in the supply of unskilled labor
hypothesis." But he also emphasized the
in English cities, and attributes it to
different availabilities of skilled labor in
five sources. First, enclosures released
Britain and the United States. He wrote:
substantial labor from agriculture.
- Sec-
ond, "population was increasing very [ I ] n both countries this provided manufac-
rapidly" (p. 136). Third, labor reserves turers with an incentive to adopt and devise
methods which replaced skilled by non-
skilled . . . [but ] . . . the English had a
39 Since Israel can be approximated by a small stronger incentive than the Americans to
open economy, another possibility is a change in replace skilled by unskilled labor. ( p . 152)
the output mix and trade patterns. Gandal, Han-
son, and Slaughter (2000) and Cohen and Hsieh
(2000) find no evidence for this, and show that With a similar reasoning to Habalzlzuk
demand for skills increased in all Israeli sectors. and Schmookler, the endogenous tech-
Cohen and Hsieh (2000) also argue that because nology view suggests that nineteenth-
many Russian immigrants initially worked in low-
skill occupations, the supply of skills to the Israeli century businessmen took advantage of
economy may not have increased by much. the rapid increase in the supply of labor
Acemoglzc: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Marlcet
in the cities by developing the factory As discussed above, a major problem
system. According to this view, there is for the "technological revolution" mod-
a close link between the skill-replacing els is the slowdown in TFP. Since the
technologies of the nineteenth century endogenous technology approach places
and the change in the factor supplies the emphasis on which type of tech-
faced by employers-"the reserve army nologies are developed, it is not incon-
of unskilled labor." Although these his- sistent with the slow growth in TFP
torical examples are informative, they during the past thirty years: an accel-
do not reveal whether endogenous tech- eration in the skill bias of new technolo-
nology choices are iinportant in under- gies does not require faster technical
standing more recent skill-biased tech- progress. The evidence presented in
nical change. A systematic study of how Richard Newell, Adain Jaffee, and
technologies respond to large changes Robert Stavins (1999) is consistent with
in the relative supply of skills is clearly the notion that changes in the direction
a worthwhile future research project.40 of technical change can happen without
An iinportant aspect of the endoge- an increase in the overall rate of pro-
nous technology theory is that it inakes ductivity growth. They show that inno-
relatively tight predictions regarding vation in air conditioners responded to
the future path of technical change. changes in energy prices by becoming
While, with exogenous skill bias theo- inore energy-efficient, but find no in-
ries, there is no clear reason to expect a crease in the rate of productivity
further acceleration or deceleration in growth. In fact, Aceinoglu (1998) and
the skill bias of new technologies, ac- Kiley (1999) show that the increased
cording to this endogenous skill bias effort of firms to develop more skill-
theory, the future path of technical biased technologies could run into de-
progress should be closely tied to the creasing returns, and hence inay cause a
path of the supply of skills. If the relative slowdown in TFP growth. Intuitively,
supply of skills continues to increase, the overall productivity growth in the
we should expect further skill-biased economy is maximized with a balanced
technical change.41 distribution of resources toward devel-
oping skill-biased and unskill-biased
40It is also useful to note that the skill bias of technologies (due to decreasing returns
technology most likely res onds not only to to each activity). During periods of
changes in the relative soppfy of skills, but to a rapid skill-biased technical change, all
variety of other factors. Recent work b Marcus
Mobius (2000) and David Thesmar a n J Mathias resources go into developing skill-
Thoenig (2000) shows how the size of the product biased machines, and cause a decline in
market, the degree of competitive pressure and advances in unskill-biased technologies.
instability facing firms may affect the way firms
choose to organize, and therefore the demand for Because of the decreasing returns to
skills. Moreover, Mobius suggests that these
changes reduced the demand for skills during the
nineteenth century as there was greater stan- the 1980s has come to an end. I t also has to be
dardization of products, but increased this de- noted that the increase in the relative supply of
mand during the past several decades as the need college educated workers in the 1990s may have
for flexibility increased. How the organization of been less than the revious trend (see figure I ) ,
and this may have aPfected the technolo y choices
roduct markets and the extent of competition af-
fect technology choices and the demand for skills
is a very promising area for future research.
B
of firms. In particular, with the increased abor force
participation of less skilled workers, there may
41Although evidence from the 1990s suggests now be a sufficient number of unskilled workers
that skill-biased technical change is now slower, supplying labor at low wages to make the further
there is not yet sufficient evidence to decide development of unskilled-labor-cornpleinentary
whether the rapid skill-biased technical change of technologies quite profitable.
44 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
scale, improveinents in the other sector ers.43 In the basic framework of section
will not fully offset this decline, and 3, average wages always increase when
overall TFP growth will fall.42 the supply of educated workers in-
Finally, it is useful to discuss briefly creases, and all wages should rise in re-
the response of skills to technology. sponse to an increase in the productiv-
The analysis so far treated the supply of ity of skilled workers, Ah. Yet, over the
skills as exogenous, and investigated the past thirty years the wages of low-slzill
implications of the supply on the de- workers have fallen in real value, which
mand for skills. Naturally, the supply contrasts with their steady increase in
of skills will also respond to econornic the previous thirty years.
incentives: more workers are likely to Models of faster technological prog-
acquire skills when skill premia are ress would naturally predict that un-
higher. Such supply choices can be eas- skilled workers should benefit froin this
ily incorporated into this framework. faster progress. The endogenous tech-
Suppose, for example, that the relative nology approach discussed in the pre-
supply of skills, HIL, is an increasing vious subsection, on the other hand,
function of the skill prerniurn, a.In this predicts that there inay be no improve-
case, if the long-run deinand curve for ments in the technologies for unskilled
skills is upward-sloping, we can have workers for an extended period of time
an equilibrium path in which both the because skill-biased innovations are
relative supply of skills and the skill more profitable than unslzill-biased in-
premium increase together over tiine novations. Yet in that case, their wages
(see Acemoglu 1998). This equilibrium should be stagnant or increase slowly,
configuration gives us an attractive in- but not fall.
terpretation for the joint behavior of Some of the studies mentioned above
college skills and the college pre- have suggested explanations for the fall
mium in the U.S. economy over the past in the wages of low-skill workers. For
sixty years (see figure 1): high returns example, recall that Galor and Moav
to schooling encourage education, (2000) argue that faster technological
which in turn induce inore skill-biased change creates an "erosion effect," re-
technical change, increasing returns to ducing the productivity of unskilled work-
schooling again. ers. Using equation (3) from above, in
the simplified version of their model
discussed in section 5.1, the unslzilled
5.3 A Puzzle: The Decline in Wages
wage is ZUL = $z(g)a[l + $;(H/L)P](~ - P)/P,
of Low- Skill Workers
where the $1 function captures the ero-
A coinmon shortcoming of all the sion effect. The rate of growth of un-
pure technology approaches discussed skilled wages will be ~ ~ L / Z U=Lg(1 + E$),
in this section is that they do not natu- where E$ is the elasticity of the $1 func-
rally predict stagnant average wages tion which is negative by the assump-
and/or falling wages for unskilled work- tion that $'I < 0. If this elasticity is less
than -1, an acceleration in econoinic
42The view that too much effort toward inl- growth can reduce the wages of
roving the skill-biased technologies may be re-
fated to the T F P slowdown is consistent with the
pattern of sectoral T F P growth observed recently. 43 However, recall that if the increase in non-
As Gordon (1998) and orgensen and Stiroh (2000) wage benefits is taken into account, avera e wa es
I,
document, there has e e n rapid T F P growth in % fp
increased over this period. So the more ro ust act
computer-producing sectors, but mediocre, or might be the fall in the real wages of low-skill
even disappointing, T F P growth in other sectors. workers.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 45

low-skill workers due to a powerful and Green show that an increase in H I L


erosion effect. can raise inequality, and depress the
Aceinoglu (1999a) and Caselli (1999) wages of low-skill workers. Although
derive a fall in the wages of less-skilled this is related to the effects of the in-
workers because the capital-labor ratio crease in the relative supply of skills on
for low-education/low-skill workers falls the path of technological progress dis-
as firms respond to technological devel- cussed in the last subsection, the mech-
opments. In Caselli's model this hap- anism in Beaudry and Green's paper is
pens because the equilibrium rate of quite different. The increase in H I L in-
return to capital increases, and in my creases the demand for capital, and
paper, this happens because firms de- pushes the interest rate up. This in-
vote more of their resources to opening crease in the interest rate hurts un-
specialized jobs for skilled worlzers. skilled workers inore than skilled work-
Consider the following simple exam- ers because of the assumption that
ple to illustrate this point. There is a q <a.
scarce supply of an input K , which A potential problem with both the
could be capital, entrepreneurial talent Beaudry and Green and Caselli stories
or another factor of production. Skilled is that they explicitly rely on an increase
worlzers work with the production in the price of capital. Although the in-
function terest rates were higher during the
Y,, = A;K; - "H", 1980s in the U.S. economy, this seems
(20)
mostly due to contractionary monetary
while unslzilled workers work with the policy, and related only tangentially to
production function inequality. Perhaps future research will
Y , = A ~ K -; "L", (21) show a major role for the increase in
where Kz and Kh sum to the total supply the interest rates in causing the decline
of K , which is assumed fixed. For siin- in the wages of low-education workers,
plicity, assume that Y1 and Yh are perfect but as yet, there is no strong evidence
substitutes. In equilibrium, the marginal in favor of this effect.44
product of capital in the two sectors has Overall, a potential problem for mod-
to be equalized, hence els based on technical change is to ac-
count for the decline in the wages of
Kz K - Kl low-skill workers.45 I argue in the next
A L L - A/,H '
section that the effect of technical
Therefore, an increase in Ah relative to change on the organization of the labor
Az will reduce Kz, as this scarce factor
44 Acemoglu (1999a), which is more in the spirit
gets reallocated from unskilled to skilled
of the organizational theories discussed below, ob-
worlzers. The wages of unslzilled workers, tains the decline in the wages of unskilled workers
wL = (1- ~ ) A ? K-; "L" - 1, will fall as a through a change in the organization of produc-
result. tion, which also entails a reallocation of capital
away from them, but no increase in the rate of
An innovative version of this story is return to capital.
developed by Paul Beaudry and David 45 Another possibility is that some of the techno-
Green (2000). Suppose that equation logical de\~elopinentsof the past two decades have
been "truly labor-replacing," for example, corre-
(21) above is replaced by Y I = A)K: -qLq, s onding to an increase in Bi(t) or h, in terms of
with 7 < a , and K is interpreted as t t e production function in footnote 1 3 Autor.
physical capital. This implies that un- Levy, and Murnane (2000), for exam le, suggest
that computers have replaced unskiied routine
skilled workers are more "dependent" tasks. This possibility has not been extensively
on capital than skilled workers. Beaudry researched yet.
46 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2002)

market both amplifies the effect of cause of the increase in inequality. In-
technology on wage inequality, and stead they have become powerful actors
provides a possible explanation for this only by interacting with technical
decline. change, amplified the direct effect of
technical change on inequality, and
6. Ramifications of Tech7zical Change contributed to the fall in the wages of
low-skill workers.
This section discusses how technical 6.1 Organizatio7zal Change a7zcl
change can affect labor market prices I7zequality
by transforming the organization of the
labor market. T h e idea that technology A variety of evidence suggests that
affects the organization of production, important changes in the structure of
and the institutions around it, is an old firms have been taking place in the U.S.
one. Marx put it in a dramatic fashion: economy over the past 25 years. More-
"The hand-mill gives you society with over, it seems clear that a major driving
the feudal lords; the steam-mill, society force for this transformation is changes
with the industrial capitalist." T h e argu- in technologies (hence the view that
ment here is not as extreme, but re- technical change is essential for the
lated: recent technological developments changes in the organization of firms).
may have led to important changes in F o r example, team production and
the organization of production. other high-performance production
My focus here is on three sets of methods are now widespread in the
changes that could account for the fall U.S. economy (e.g., Casey Ichniowski,
in the wages of low-skill workers: the Giovanna Prennushi, and Kathryn
transformation of the organization of Shaw 1997, or Eileen Applebaum and
firms; change in labor market "insti- Rosemary Batt 1994). Similarly, Peter
tutions,"46 particularly the decline in Cappelli and Steffanie Wilk (1997) show
unionization; and the interaction between that there has been an increase in the
international trade and technical change. screening of production workers, espe-
Organizational change often destroys cially from establishments that use
the types of jobs that pay high wages to computer technology and pay high
low-skill workers. Deunionization re- wages.
duces the bargaining power of low-skill Murnane and Levy (1996) report case
workers. And international trade with study evidence consistent with this
less developed countries (LDCs) in- view. From their interviews with human
creases the effective supply of unskilled resource personnel at a number of com-
labor and depresses the marginal value panies, they describe the change in the
product of less skilled workers in the hiring practices of U.S. companies. A
U.S. economy. Therefore, a11 three nlanager at Ford Motor colnpany in
changes could be responsible for the 1967 describes their hiring strategy as
changes in the U.S. wage structure and follows: "If we had a vacancy, we would
for the decline in the wages of low-skill look outside in the plant waiting room
worlzers. Nevertheless, I argue that these to see if there were any warm bodies
factors by theinselves are not the major standing there. If someone was there
and they looked physically OK and
4 6 1 am using the term institutions loosely here,
to capture the rules of the game in the labor mar-
weren't an obvious alcoholic, they were
ket, patterns of bargaining, as well as government hired" ( p . 19). In contrast, comparable
labor lnarlcet policy. companies in the late 1980s use a very
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Marlcet 47

0.35 1 I I I I I
1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993
Year
Figure 9. The Evolution of the Percentage of Employment in the Top and Bottom 25 Percentile Industry-
Occupation Cells (weight-at-the-tails of the job quality distribution)

different recruitment strategy. Murnane tively high or relatively low wages. In


and Levy discuss the cases of Honda of 1983, 35 percent of employment was in
America, Diamond Star Motors, and the top and bottom 25-percent job
Northwestern Mutual Life. All three categories. By 1993, this number had
companies spend substantial resources risen to just under 38 percent. So, ap-
on recruitment and hire only a fraction proximately 2.5 percent more workers
of those who apply. Kremer and Maskin now have either higher or lower quality
(1999) provide evidence of more segre- jobs rather than medium quality jobs.
gation of workers across establishments. T h e actual changes in the distribution
I t seems that high-wage workers are of jobs may b e much larger than this,
now much more concentrated in certain since substantial changes in the types
establishments. Similarly, in Aceinoglu of jobs often take place within given
(1999a) I documented a change in the occupations.
composition of jobs over the past T h e view that changes in the organi-
twenty years. Figure 9 here replicates a zation of firms have had a fundamental
pattern found in that paper, and plots effect on the labor market is often ex-
the total percentage of workers ern- pressed in the popular press, and in the
ployed in the top 25-percent and bot- organizational literature (e.g., Shohana
tom 25-percent industry-occupation Zuboff 1988). This organizational ap-
cells (what I called weight-at-the-tails proach is formalized by Kremer and
of the job quality distribution). These Maskin (1999), Aceinoglu (1999a), Mobius
are the cells (job types) that pay rela- (2000), Thesmar and Thoenig (2000),
48 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

and Gilles Duranton (2001). Kremer mulation implies that if the productivity
and Maskin consider a production func- (ability) of unslzilled workers, A/, is very
tion which distinguishes between man- low relative to A/,, they pull down the
agers and workers. They show that a productivity of skilled workers. In
change in technology or an increase in contrast, when they work in separate
the dispersion of skills may encourage firms, slulled workers are unaffected by the
high-skill workers to match with other productivity of unskilled workers. More-
high-skill workers, rather than work as over, p > l, which implies that improve-
managers in establishments employing ments in the productivity of skilled work-
low-skill workers. ers has more effect on the productivity
Here I outline a simple model, syn- of new-style organizations. The parame-
thesizing Kremer and Maskin (1999) ters Bp and B, capture the relative effi-
and Acemoglu (1999a), that captures ciency of old and new-style production
the effect of the technical change on functions.
the organization of production, and via T h e labor market is competitive, so
this channel, on wage inequality. T h e the equilibrium organization of produc-
basic idea is simple. As the productivity tion will maximize total output, given
of skilled workers increases, it becomes by Bp[(A/L)P+ (A~,lao)p]l/p + B,A!(H - ho),
more profitable for them to work by where 1x0 E [0,HI is the number of
themselves in separate organizations skilled workers employed in the old-style
rather than in the same workplace as organizations. For all cases in which
the unskilled workers. This is because ho > 0, the solution to this problem will
when the skilled and the unskilled work involve
together, their productivities interact,
and unskilled workers may put downward +
W H = BpAEh$- ' [ A ~ L PAEla$](l-P ) / P
(22)
pressure on the productivity of skilled P
= BsA,,
workers (for example, because unskilled i.e., skilled workers need to be paid B,A!
workers have to implement part of the to be convinced to work in the same
production process designed by skilled firms as the unskilled workers. The
workers). unskilled wage is
Specifically, suppose that firms have
access to the following production
functions
the old-style production function: Now consider an increase in Ah. Dif-
Y = Bp[(A/L)P+(Ahlzo)~]~/~, ferentiating (22) yields alao/aA/, < 0, that
the new-organization production function: is, there will be fewer skilled workers
Y =BB!~N, working with the unskilled. Moreover,
differentiation also gives a(Ahho)/dAh< 0,
where ho is the number of skilled work- so the efficiency units of skilled workers
ers employed in the old-style firms, and that the unskilled work with declines.
1 % is~ the number of skilled workers em- From (23), this implies that clw~/dAl,< 0.
ployed in new organizations separately Therefore, skill-biased technical change
from unskilled workers. The fact that encourages skilled workers to work by
when they are employed in the same themselves, and as a result, unskilled
firm these two types of workers affect wages fall. Intuitively, because, in the
each other's productivity is captured by old-style organizations, the productiv-
the CES production function. This for- ity of skilled workers depends on the
Acewzoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and t h e Labor Market 49

ability of unskilled workers, when the this evidence does not yet enable an as-
skilled become even more productive, sessment of whether changes in organi-
the downward pull exerted on their pro- zational forms have been an important
ductivity by the unskilled workers be- contributor to the changes in labor
comes more costly, and they prefer to market prices, and future research is
work in separate organizations. This re- required to determine the role of
duces the ratio A/,ho/L and depresses organizational change in the rise in
unskilled wages. As a result, improve- inequality.
ments in technology, which normally 6.2 Institutional Change
benefit unskilled workers as in section
3, may hurt unskilled workers because Labor market "institutions," includ-
they transform the organization of ing minimum wage laws, the impor-
production. tance of collective bargaining in wage
An increase in B , / B p , which raises the determination, and perhaps social
relative profitability of the new organi- norms, undoubtedly have an important
zational form, also leads to further seg- effect on the distribution of wages. T h e
regation of skilled and unskilled work- Great Compression in the wage distri-
ers in different organizations. This last bution after the Second World War is
comparative static result is useful since difficult to explain without invoking
Bresnahan (1999) and Autor, Levy and changes institutions and social norms
Murnane (2000) argue that by replacing (see, e.g., Goldin and Robert Margo
workers in the performance of routine 1992). Could changes in labor market
tasks, computers enabled a radical change institutions also account for the in-
in the organization of production.47 crease in wage inequality and the dis-
This is reminiscent of a technological continuity in that demand for skills
change that makes the new-organization during the past decades?
production function more profitable. Two major changes in labor market
These organizational stories are at- institutions over the past 25 years are
tractive since they provide a unified ex- the decline in the real value of state and
planation for the changes in the wage federal minimum wages and the reduced
structure and the apparent changes in importance of trade unions in wage de-
the organization of firms. An interesting termination. Although many economists
recent paper by Eve Caroli and Van suspect that these institutional changes
Reenan (1999) provides evidence sug- may be responsible for the changes in
gesting that changes in wages have been the structure of the U.S. labor market
accompanied by changes in organi- (see Freeman 1991; DiNardo, Fortin,
zational forms. Acemoglu (1999a) and and Lemieux 1995; Lee 1999), I will
Kremer and Maskin (1999) also provide argue that these changes are unlikely
evidence suggesting a number of orga- to be the major cause of the recent
nizational changes in the U.S. economy increase in U.S. wage inequality.
during the past 25 years. Nevertheless, The real value of the minimum wage
was eroded throughout the 1980s as the
"A related perspective is offered by Aghion nominal minimum wage remained con-
(2001), who also argues that computers replace
unskilled tasks. He suggests that colnputers are a stant for much of this period. Since the
"general-purpose technology," so their diffusion minimum wage is likely to increase the
follows an inverted S shaped pattern. H e sug- wages of low-paid workers, this decline
gests that as inore and inore firms adopted com-
puters over the past decades, demand for unslzilled may b e responsible for increased wage
worlcers fell rapidly. dispersion. DiNardo et al. (1995) and
50 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
Lee (1999) provide evidence in support increase in wage inequality. Unions
of this hypothesis. Although the contri- often coinpress the structure of wages
bution of the decline in the ininirnu~n and reduce skill premia (see for example
wage to increased wage dispersion can- Lloyd Reynolds 1951; or Freeman and
not be denied, most economists believe James Medoff 1984). Throughout the
that this is unlikely to have been a ma- postwar period in the U.S. economy,
jor factor in the changes in the U.S. unions negotiated the wages for many
wage structure. First, only a small frac- occupations, even indirectly influenced
tion of male workers are directly af- managerial salaries (see DiNardo,
fected by the rniniinu~nwage (even in Kevin Hallock, and Pischlze 2000).
1992, after the minimum wage hike of Unions also explicitly tried to compress
1990-91, only 8 percent of all workers wage differentials. This suggests that the
between the ages of 18 and 6 5 were decline of unions may have been a major
paid at or below the minimum wage). cause of the changes in the structure of
Although the minimum wage may in- wages.
crease the earnings of some workers Although deunionization could in
who are not directly affected, it is un- principle be an important factor in the
likely to affect the wages above the me- structure of wages, the extent and tim-
dian of the wage distribution. But as ing of deunionization suggests that it is
figure 3 shows, the difference between not the major driving force of the in-
the 90th percentile and the median crease in inequality. First, wage in-
behaves very similarly to the difference equality increased in many occupations
between the median and the 10th per- in which prices were never affected by
centile." This implies that whatever unions (such as lawyers and doctors).
factors were causing increased wage Moreover, in the United States, de-
dispersion at the top of the distribution unionization started in the 1950s, a period
are likely to have been the major cause of stable wage inequality. During the
of the increase in wage dispersion 1970s, though unionization fell in the
throughout the distribution. Second, the private sector, overall unionization rates
erosion in the real value of the mini- did not decline rnuch because of in-
mum wage started in the 1980s, creased unionization in the public sec-
whereas, as shown above, the explosion tor. Overall union density was approxi-
in overall wage inequality began in the mately constant, around 30 percent of
early 1970s (subject to the caveat raised the work force, between 1960 and 1975.
in footnote 11). I t was the anti-union atmosphere of the
The declining importance of unions 1980s and perhaps the defeat of the air-
may be another important factor in the traffic controllers' strike that led to the
largest declines in unionization, dating
4Qxcept during the early 1980s when there is a much of deunionization after the rapid
Inore rapid increase in inequality at the bottonl of increase in inequality during the early
the \va e distribution, most likely due to the fall-
q,
inf sea value of the minimum wage. There are 1970s.49 Evidence from other countries
su stantlally larger increases in inequality at the also paints a similar picture. For exam-
bottonl of' the distribution aillong female worlzers ple, in the United Kingdom, wage in-
or in a sanlple that combines Inale and fernale
worlzers. This reflects the larger effect of mini- equality started its sharp increase in the
lnuin wage laws on female earnings. Fi uie 3
sliows that there are factors, other than J l e ' d e - 49 An interesting recent paper by Henry Farber
cline in the real value of the minimum wage, hav- and Bruce Western (2000) dates the nlajor decline
ing a major effect on the top and the bottonl of in union activity to the early 1980s, a few months
the male wage distribution. before the air-traffic controllers' strike.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 51

mid-1970s, while union density in- pressed. Alternatively, collective deci-


creased until 1980 and started a rapid sion making within a union may reflect
decline only during the 1980s (Amanda the preferences of its median voter, and
Gosling 1998). In Canada, while union- if this median voter is an unskilled
ization rates increased from around 30 worker, h e will try to increase unslzilled
percent in the 1960s to over 36 percent wages at the expense of skilled wages. I t
in the late 1980s (Riddell 1993, table is also possible that union members
4.1), wage inequality also increased choose to compress wages because of
(see for example Freeman and Karen ideological reasons or for social cohe-
Needels 1993, figure 2 . 4 ) . sion purposes. T h e empirical literature
Although the timing of deunioniza- supports the notion that unions com-
tion does not appear to be consistent press wages, though it does not distin-
with this institutional change being the guish among the various reasons (see
~ n a j o rcause of the changes in wage in- Freeman and James Medoff 1984). I
equality, deunionization could clearly capture wage compression in a reduced
affect the wages of unskilled workers. form way with the equation
One possibility is that deunionization is
a contributing factor. But in this case,
why did the unions decline while tech-
nology was rapidly becoming more skill- where ty < 1. Unions could never attract
biased? Acemoglu, Aghion, and Violante skilled workers unless they provided
(2001) suggest that deunionization may some benefits to them to compensate for
have been caused by the technological the wage compression. Here I simply as-
developments of the past decades. Ac- sume that they provide a benefit p to all
cording to this perspective, technical workers, for example, because unions in-
change is the driving force of the crease productivity (e.g., Freeman and
changes in the wage structure, but it Medoff 1984; and Freeman and Edward
also leads to deunionization, and the re- Lazear 1995), or because they encourage
sulting deunionization can have a sig- training. Alternatively, P could be part of
nificant indirect effect on wage inequal- the rents captured by the union. The
ity, causing the wages of less-skilled zero-profit constraint for firms would be:
workers to fall. (wH- P)H + (wL - P)L I AhH + A1L (in the
To see the basic argument, suppose that case where p stands for rents, the zero-
production can be carried out either in profit condition ensures that the firm
unionized or nonunionized firms. I n does not wish to open a non-union
nonunionized firms, workers receive plant). Combining this equation with
their marginal products, which I denote (24), and assuming that both hold as
by Ah and A1 for skilled and unskilled equality, we obtain
workers. Assume that unions always
compress the structure of wages-i.e.,
they reduce wage differentials between
skilled and unskilled workers. This Skilled workers will be happy to be part
wage compression could be driven by a of a union as long as W H given by (25) is
variety of factors. Acemoglu and Pischke greater than Ah. As Ai7/Az increases-i.e.,
(1999), for example, argue that unions as skill-biased technical change raises
encourage productive training, and such the productivity of skilled workers rela-
training is incentive compatible for firms tive to the unskilled-WH will fall relative
only when the wage structure is com- to Ah. Therefore, skill-biased technical
52 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . XL ( M a r c h 2002)

change inakes wage compression more 6.3 Trade, Technical Change,


costly for skilled workers, eventually de- and Inequality
stroying the coalition between skilled
Finally, I discuss another inajor
and unskilled workers that maintains
change affecting the U. S. economy: the
unions.
increased volume of international trade.
The important point is that deunion-
I argue that increased international
ization causes a decline in the wages of un-
trade by itself is not the cause of the
skilled workers from W L = '*l'b::~(.~,~jp'L
WAl
changes in the U.S. wage structure, but
to Al. Unskilled workers, who were pre-
trade may have been an important fac-
viously benefiting from wage compres-
tor in the rise of wage inequality by
sion imposed by unions, now experi-
affecting the degree of skill bias of
ence a fall in real earnings. Therefore,
technical change. This subsection is
technical change not only affects wage
somewhat different from the previous two,
inequality directly, but also induces a
since it is not about the effect of tech-
change in labor market institutions. T h e
nology on the organization of the labor
effect of this change in institutions on
market, but on the effect of a major
inequality can be potentially larger than
change in regulations on technological
the direct effect of technical change,
developments.
and explain the decline in the real
Standard trade theory predicts that
wages of less-skilled workers.
increased international trade with less-
Although Acemoglu, Aghion, and Vio-
developed countries ( L D C s ) , which are
lante (2001) provide some evidence
inore abundant in unskilled workers,
consistent with these patterns, whether
should increase the demand for skills in
deunionization was important in the de-
the U.S. labor market. So the increase
cline of the wages of low-skill workers and
in international trade may have been an
whether technical change is responsible
underlying cause of the changes in U.S.
for deunionization are open questions.
wage inequality.
I t inight also be interesting to investi-
T o discuss these issues, consider the
gate whether changes in technology
two-good interpretation of the model in
may have also affected the coalition
section 3. Consumer utility is defined
supporting the minimum wage, and
hence played a role in the decline in
over [YIP
+ Y;]~/P, with the production
functions for two goods being YI, = A h H
the minimum wage during the 1980s.
and Yz = A1L. Both goods are now tradable.
For example if unions, which have tra-
For simplicity, let me just compare the
ditionally supported minimum wages,
U.S. labor market equilibrium without
were weakened by the technological de-
any trade (as characterized in section 3)
velopn~entsof that decade as argued in
to the equilibrium with full international
this subsection, technical change may
trade without any trading costs.
have indirectly contributed to the weak-
Before trade, the U.S. relative price
ening of the coalition in support of the
of skill-intensive goods, p~,/pz,is given by
minimum wage.50
SOFinally, both the decline in the role that
unions pla and in the value of the minimum wage
may have 8 e e n caused by changes in certain social
norms, for exam le, the norm of "equal work
equal pay.', The &cline o i the same norms could 1996). Unfortunately, there is currently little re-
also b e responsible for the increase in inequality search on the effect of social norms on inequality
(e.g., the emergence of the winner-take-all society and on why inequality norms may have changed
as claimed by Robert Frank and Philip Cook over the past thirty years.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 53
where H and L denote the supplies of since the producers face the same rela-
skilled and unskilled labor in the United tive price of skill-intensive goods, and
States. The skill premium is then simply have access to the same technologies.
equal to the ratio of the marginal value Before trade, however, the skill pre-
products of the two types of workers, mium in theA LDACs was h = B A ~ / A ~ ,
that is, o U S = pUSAh/Az. Next, suppose where @ =(AI,H/AIL)P - 1 is the relative

that the United States starts trading with price of skill-intensive goods in the
a set of LDCs that have access to the LDCs before trade. The saine argument
saine technology as given by Ah and Al, as above implies that fl > p w , i.e., trade
but are relatively scarce in skills. Denote with the skill-abundant United States re-
the total supplies of skilleq and upskilled duces the relative price of skill-intensive
yo5kers in the LDCs by H and L where goods in the LDCs. This implies that
H / L < H / L , which siinply reiterates that a " < & ; after trade wage inequality
the United States is more abundant in should fall in the LDCs.
skilled workers than the LDCs. Although in theory increased trade
After full trade opening, the product with the LDCs can be the cause of the
markets in the United States and the rapid increase in the deinand for skills,
LDCs are joined, so there will b e a most evidence suggests that the direct
unique world relative price. Since the effect of increased international trade
supplies of skill- and unskill-iniensive on the U.S. labor market has been rela-
goods are Ah(H + H) and Al(L + L ) , the tively minor. First, as equation (27)
relative price of the skill-intensive good shows, the effect of international trade
will be works through a unique interzjening
mechanism: inore trade with the LDCs
increases the relative price of skill-
intensive goods, p, and affects the skill
premium via this channel. In fact, in
The fact t h a ~R ~ V > pus follows irninedi-
this simple framework, the percentage
ately from H / L < H / L . Intuitively, once
increase in the skill premium is propor-
the United States starts trading with
tional to the percentage increase in the
skill-scarce LDCs, deinand for skill-
relative price of skill-intensive goods.
intensive goods increases and pushes the
Perhaps the most damaging piece of
prices of these goods up.
evidence for the trade hypothesis is that
Labor demand in this econoiny is de-
most studies suggest the relative price
rived from product demands. The skill
of skill-intensive goods did not increase
premium therefore follows the relative
over the period of increasing inequality.
price of skill-intensive goods. After
Robert Lawrence and Slaughter (1993)
trade opening, the U.S. skill preiniuin
found that during the 1980s the relative
increases to
price of skill-intensive goods actually
fell. Jeffrey Sachs and Howard Shatz
(1994) found no major change or a
where the fact that coIV > w U S is an iinme- slight decline. A more recent paper by
diate consequence of pw > pus. There- Krueger (1997) criticized the methods
fore, trade with less developed countries and data used by these studies, and
increases wage inequality in the United found an increase in the relative price
States. of skill-intensive goods. Nevertheless,
The skill premium in the LDCs will the increase in these prices is relatively
also be equal to wlV after trade opening small, so would not be able to account for
54 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L (Ma,rch 2002)

the large increase in the skill premium the same point by showing that the con-
experienced in the U.S. economy. tent of unskilled labor embedded in the
Second, with trade as the driving U.S. iinports is sinall relative to the
force, increased production of skill- changes in the supply of skills taking
intensive goods should be drawing place during this period.51
workers away froin other sectors. In Although the above arguments sug-
contrast, as documented by Murphy gest that increased international trade
and Welch (1993), Berman, Bound, and with the LDCs is not the major cause of
Griliches (1994) and Autor, Katz, and the changes in the wage structure by it-
Krueger (1998), all sectors, even those self, they d o not rule out a powerful ef-
producing less-skilled goods, increased fect of international trade when it inter-
their demands for more-educated work- acts with technical change. In a world
ers. This pattern is not consistent with with endogenous technical change, in-
trade being the main driving force of creased international trade could affect
the increase in the demand for skilled the types of technologies developed and
workers (though one has to bear in adopted by firms, and have a large ef-
mind the increase in outsourcing in fect through this channel. This possibil-
interpreting this fact; see Robert ity was first raised by Wood (1994), who
Feenstra and Hanson 1999). argued that trade with the LDCs will
Third, a direct implication of the lead to defensive skill-biased innova-
trade view is that, as shown above, tions. Wood, however, did not develop
while demand for skills and inequality the mechanism through which such de-
increased in the United States, the con- fensive innovations could occur. I now
verse should have happened in the illustrate liow trade causes skill-biased
LDCs that have started trading with technical change using the endogenous
the inore skill-abundant U. S, economy. The technology lllodel developed in section
evidence, however, suggests that inore 5.2 (this analysis draws on Aceinoglu
of the LDCs experienced rising in- 1999b).
equality after opening to international Suppose that the United States starts
trade (see Hanson and Ann Harrison trading with the LDCs as discussed
1994; or Donald Robbins 1995). Al- above, and assume that the LDCs al-
though the increase in inequality in a ways use U.S. technologies. Therefore,
nuinber of cases inay have been due to the supply of skilled and un%killed
concurrent political and econoinic re- goodsAin the LDCs is Yh FAJH and
forms, the preponderance of evidence Yl =AlL where as before H / L < H / L .
is not favorable to this basic iinplication T h e immediate effect will be an
of the trade hypothesis. increase in the relative price of
Finally, a nuinber of econon~istshave skill-intensive goods as illustrated by
pointed out that U.S. trade with the
LDCs is not iinportant enough to have a 51 This is probably the wealzest criticisnl against
the trade view, and many studies have pointed out
inajor impact on the U.S. product mar- how international trade could have a larger effect
ket prices and consequently on wages. on U.S. labor market prices in the presence of la-
Paul Kruglnan (1995) illustrates this bor market rents. For example, George Borjas and
Valerie Rainey (1995), Dani Rodrik (1997), and
point by undertaking a calibration of a Dube and Reddy (1999) have argued that the
siinple North-South model. Katz and threat of international trade may reduce wages,
Murphy (1992), Berman, Bound, and especially in sectors with substantial rents, and
this change in bargaining ower may affect the
Griliches (1994) and George Borjas, earnings of unslzilled wor&rs more, increasing
Freeinan, and Katz (1997) emphasize inequality.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 55
equation (27). Now, recall from the librium price of skill-intensive goods
analysis in section 5.2 that there is a cannot change either. Combining equa-
relative price effect on the direction of tions (18) and (27) gives the post-trade
technical change (because developing skill bias of technology as
technologies to produce the inore ex-
pensive good is more profitable). There-
fore, trade, by making the skill-intensive
goods more expensive, encourages more
skill-biased technical change.
To determine exactly how the direc-
tion of technical change will be affected
by trade, we need to know the market where AfS/AfS is the pre-trade skill bias
sizes for new technologies after trade of technology in the United States.
opening. I t is plausible to assume that The implication is that when the di-
trade opening with the LDCs will not rection of technical change is endoge-
have a major effect on the enforcement nous, trade between the United States
of intellectual property rights in the and the LDCs will induce skill-biased
South. In that case, trade opening will technical progress. T h e result is not
induce skill-biased technical change in only that trade leads to an increase in
the United States. Specifically, as long skill premia, but that this can happen
as after trade opening the United States without the counterfactual iinplications
does not start producing technologies of the standard trade models discussed
for unskilled workers in the LDCs, the above.
relative market sizes for the two types T h e first implication of this induced
of technologies remain at HIL. This im- skill bias is that the impact of trade on
plies that the technology inarket clear- labor markets may b e much larger than
ing condition, equation ( I S ) , no longer predicted by the standard trade models,
holds. In particular, since p j y > ~p j T J ~ which helps against the criticism that
froin equation (27), there will now only the amount of trade the United States
be incentives for skill-biased technical undertakes with the LDCs is not large
change. This process continues until enough. Second, because trade causes
plTJ = p ~ / p j v
= (H/L)-1, so that incentives skill-biased technical change, the fact
to develop the two different types of that all sectors have increased the em-
technologies are balanced. This implies ployinent of skilled workers is consis-
that the skill bias of technical change is tent with trade being the underlying
still determined by equation (18) from cause of the increase in inequality.
section 5.2, i.e., by U.S. domestic rela- Third, for the same reason, there is a
tive supplies alone. Intuitively, the rela- force counteracting the decline in in-
tive price of skill-intensive goods plays equality in the LDCs implied by trade:
two roles in this model. T h e first is to these economies use U. S. technologies,
clear the market for goods (i.e., equa- which are becoming more skill-biased.
tion 27), and the second is to ensure Finally, and quite strikingly, trade
equilibrium in the technology market leaves the relative price of skill-intensive
(cfr. equation 18). Since the technology goods in the United States unchanged
inarket clearing condition relates the in the long-run. Recall that changes in
relative price of skill-intensive goods to relative prices are the usual intervening
the relative supplies in the U.S. market, mechanism in trade models, so a nuin-
which do not change, the long-run equi- ber of studies have concluded that trade
56 Journal o f Econonzic Literature, V ol. X L ( M a r c h 2002)
has not been an important factor in the 7. Changes i n Resiclual Inequality
increase in inequality because the rela-
tive price of skill-intensive goods has T h e previous sections highlighted
not increased much (e.g., Lawrence and that there are major unanswered ques-
Slaughter 1994; Sachs and Shatz 1995). tions regarding the causes of the in-
In this model, the long-run relative crease in inequality, the reasons for the
price of skill-intensive goods in the faster skill-biased technical change in
United States is unaffected by trade. the past few decades, and the determi-
More generally, induced skill-biased nants of the fall in the wages of low-
technical change in the United States skill workers. These questions awaiting
implies that trade will increase the further research notwithstanding, we
price of slzill-intensive goods by only have a reasonably simple and useful
a limited amount, while still having framework, and the beginnings of con-
a major effect on the U.S. labor sistent answers. In contrast, in this and
inarlzet . the next section, I discuss areas where
Notice finally that the interaction be- answers are much inore tentative, and
tween international trade and technical there is a greater need for future re-
change inay help to explain the decline search. I begin with residual inequality.
in the wages of low-skill workers. In- A major issue that most models dis-
creased international trade acts as an cussed so far failed to address is the dif-
increase in the supply of unskilled ferential behavior of returns to school-
workers, and as shown in our basic ing and residual inequality during the
framework in section 3, this would put 1970s. I argue in this section that an
downward pressure on unskilled wages. explanation for this pattern requires
Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1987), for models with multi-dimensional slzills.
example, provide evidence that in- 7.1 A Single Inclex Model
creased international trade during the of Residual Ineqz~ality
1980s reduced the wages of high
school graduate worlzers (though they The simplest model of residual in-
also suggest that the effect of the immi- equality is a single index model, in
gration of less-skilled workers was which there is only one type of skill,
greater). though this skill is only imperfectly ap-
Overall, international trade could still proximated by education (or experi-
be a major driving force of the changes ence). Expressed alternatively, in a sin-
in the wage structure. However, for gle index model observed and
increased trade to have such a large unobserved skills are perfect substi-
effect on the structure of wages-and to tutes. Consider, for example, the model
avoid the aforementioned counterfac- developed above, but suppose that in-
tual implications-it must cause a stead of skills, we observe education,
change in the path of technological e.g., whether the individual is a college
progress. So the combination of trade graduate, which is imperfectly corre-
opening and endogenous technical lated with true slzills. A fraction 4, of
change gives an alternative theory for college graduates are highly skilled,
acceleration: skill-biased technical change while a fraction $,, < $, of noncollege
accelerates, neither exogenously nor in graduates are highly skilled. Denote
response to the changes in the supply the skill premium by o = w H / w L .The
of skilled workers, but due to trade college premium, i.e., the ratio of
opening. average college to noncollege wages, is
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 57
zero disturbance term. Here yt is the price
of observed skills, while 8t is the price
of unobserved skills. T h e education
-
-
@cw+ ( 1 - 0,) premium can be written as
+ (1 - $n)'
$n(J)
while within-group inequality, i.e., the In at E E(ln w,t I hlt = 1) - E(ln zolt / hZt= 0 )
= yt + @t(A~t - Aot)
ratio of the wage of high-wage college
graduates (or noncollege graduates) to where Ait = E(ln zolt 1 hlt = 1) and Aot is
that of low-wage college graduates (or defined similarly. Residual inequality
noncollege graduates), is ~owzthln= (J) (since can be measured by Vnr(A,t 11%= 0 ) and
high-wage workers in both groups earn Var(AztI h = 1) .
Z U H , while low-wage workers earn W L ) . T o simplify the discussion, assume
As long as @, and @,, remain constant, we that there is perfect sorting into educa-
and w1ulthln will always move together. tion, in the sense that there exists a
Therefore, an increase in the returns to threshold z such that all individuals
observed skills-such as education-will with unobserved ability above n obtain
also be associated with an increase in the education. Then within-group inequal-
returns to unobserved skills. ity among high and low-education work-
This framework provides a natural ers will move in opposite directions as
starting point, linking between- and long as the price of observed skills, 8, is
within-group inequality. I t predicts that constant: as n declines (and average
within- and between-group inequality education increases), Var(Azt1 h = 1) will
should move together. But during the increase, but Vnr(A,t I h = 0 ) will fall. In-
1970s, returns to schooling fell while tuitively, there are more and more
residual (within-group) inequality in- "marginal" workers added to the high-
creased sharply. W e can only account education group, creating more unob-
for this fact by positing a decline in 4, served heterogeneity in that group and
relative to @,, of a large enough magni- increasing within-group inequality. But
tude to offset the increase in a; this in contrast, the low-education group be-
would ensure that during the 1970s the comes more homogeneous. Therefore,
college premium could fall despite the without a change in the prices for unob-
increase in within-group inequality. A served skills, this approach cannot ac-
large decline in 4, relative to @,, would count for the silnultaneous increase
predict a very different behavior of the in inequality among both low- and
college premium within different co- high-education groups.5"
horts. Yet the appendix shows little evi- 7.3 Churning and Residual Inequality
dence in favor of this. I therefore con-
Another approach emphasizes that
clude that the single index model cannot
workers of all levels of education may
explain the changes in residual inequality
face difficulty adapting to changes. This
during the 1970s and the 1980s.
7.2 Sorting ancl Residual Inequality S 2 A natural variation on this theme would be a
situation in which y and 8 move to ether How-
Another approach would conlbine ever, this x,ill run into the same pro%lems as the
educational sorting with an increase in
the demand for skills. Suppose that
a
sin le index model: if y and 8 always move to-
get er, then such a model would predict that
within-group ine uality should have fallen during
wages are given by In w,t = 8tn, + yth, + ~ , t the 197'0s Thcre're, models based on sorting also
require a mechanism for the prices of observed
where h, is a dummy for high education, and unobserved sltills to move differently during
a, is unobserved ability, and elt is a mean the 1970s.
58 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

has been argued by Piore and Sabel 1970s. Therefore, a mechanism that
(1984), and more recently by Aghion, could lead to differential behavior in
Howitt, and Violante (2000) and Gould, the prices to observed and unobserved
Moav, and Weinberg (2000). Violante skills is still necessary.54
(2000) offers an alternative, but related
theory, where increased churning is 7.4 A Two-Irzdex Model
driven by the greater productivity gap of Residual Inequality
between different firms (because of
Since models based on a single index
faster embodied technical change) and
of skill (or models where different types
increased skill dynamics of ex ante
of skills are perfect substitutes) are in-
identical workers (which he contrasts
consistent with the differential behavior
with the argument that it is innate abil-
of returns to schooling and within-group
ity differences that matter). According
inequality during the 1970s, an obvious
to all these approaches, an increase in
next step is to consider a two-index
inequality results from more rapid tech-
model where observed and unobserved
nical change, not because of skill bias
skills are imperfect substitutes. There
but because of increased "churning" in
are good reasons to expect that in the
the labor market. Aghion, Howitt, and
real world skills are multidimensional.
Violante (2000), for example, suggest
For example, the social psychologist
that only some workers will be able to
Howard Gardner (1988) makes a strong
adapt to the introduction of new tech-
case that we should always think of
nology, and this will increase wage
skills as multidimensional, and that the
inequality.
standard IQ measures fail to capture
An advantage of this approach is that
this multidimensionality. There is a
it is in line with the increased earnings
long tradition in economics building on
instability pointed out by Gottschalk
the Roy model which uses models with
and Robert Moffit (1994). However,
multidimensional skills to analyze wages
there is relatively little evidence, other
and returns to schooling (e.g., Robert
than this increase in earnings instabil-
Willis and Sherwin Rosen 1975). In the
ity, supporting the notion that there is
context of the determinants of earnings,
more churning in the labor market. The
a recent paper by Bowles, Gintis, and
data on job creation and job destruction
reported by Steven ~ a v i s John
, Halti- 54An interestin theory similar to the churning
wanger, and Scott Schuh (1996) shows models that coulf lead to such a differential be-
havior is advanced by Galor and Tsiddon (1997).
no increase in job reallocation during They draw a distinction between abiljty and edu-
the 1980s or the early 1990s, and most cation, and argue that returns to abilit increase
evidence does not indicate much of a faster during periods o f rapid tecXnological
change. I f we view the 1970s as a period o f ra id
decline in job stability over this period technolo ical change, as suggested above, this t i e -
(e.g. Francis Diebold, David Neumark, ory woul% imp1 an increase in the returns to abil-
and Daniel Polsky 1997; or Henry ity (unobserve8 skills) durin this period Never-
theless, this explanation is st81 not consistent with
Farber 1995).53 Also theories based on the facts because high-ability individuals are more
churning do not naturally predict a di- likely to be high education, so rapid technolo ical
vergence between returns to education pro ress should also increase returns to schoofing.
Pergaps a combination o f this mechanism with dif-
and residual inequality during the ferential sorting into education, or with imperfect
substitution between high- and low-education
53More recent evidence indicates that there workers, might be able to account for the diver-
may have been a decrease in job tenure during the gence between returns to schooling and residual
later parts o f the 1990s (see Neumark, Polsky, and ine uality during the 197Os, but such a model has
Daniel Hansen 1999). n o t i e e n developed yet.
60 Journal of Econojmic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

Overall, single index models are not substantially in the United States and
capable of explaining the changes in re- the United Kingdom, but remained
sidual inequality over the past thirty fairly stable in many continental Euro-
years, and we do not yet know how im- pean econon~ies(see for example Davis
portant various factors are. Analysis of 1995; Gottschalk and Timothy Smeeding
the determinants of residual inequality 1999).
and the reasons why there was an explo- T h e standard explanation for this
sion in overall inequality beginning in divergent behavior, succinctly summa-
the 1970s remains a inajor research rized by Kruginan (1994) and O E C D
area. (1994), and sometimes referred to as
the Krugman hypothesis, maintains that
8 . Cross-Country Patterns inequality did not increase as much (or
not at all) in Europe because labor mar-
So far, I have focused on U.S. wage ket institutions there encourage wage
inequality patterns and on the incen- compression, limiting the extent of in-
tives to develop new technologies coin- equality. This can be captured in the
ing from the U.S. supply of skills. The competitive framework of section 3,
cross-country dimension presents a where firms are always along their rela-
number of challenges, in particular be- tive deinand curve, by assuming that
cause it is difficult to explain why in- labor inarket institutions iinpose an ex-
equality increased much inore in soine ogenous skill premium G = W H / W L . This
countries than others. In addition, for implies:
the endogenous technology view, it is
important to know whether it is the
relative supply of skills in each country
or in the world as a whole that deter-
mines the direction of technical change. where the level of enlployinent of un-
I now briefly discuss these issues. skilled workers, 1, will generally be less
than their labor supply L because of
8.1 Dzjrferences in Inequality Patterns
wage compression. A inore conlpressed
Although the tendency toward wage structure-i.e., a lower 6-will in-
greater inequality has been a feature in crease the unemployment of unskilled
Inany developed and less developed workers, given by L - 1.
countries (see Freeman and Katz 1995; T h e view that wages are more com-
and Berinan and Machin 2000), there pressed in Europe clearly has soine
are also inarked differences in the be- merit. Francine Blau and Lawrence
havior of within- and between-group in- Kahn (1995) show that the inajor differ-
equality across these countries. Katz, ence in overall inequality between the
David Blanchflower, and Gary Loveman United States and Inany continental
(1995), Murphy, Riddell, and Roiner European econonlies is not in the 90-
(1998), and Card and Lemieux (2000) SO differential, but in the 50-10 differ-
show that the differential behavior of ential. This suggests that the lninimuin
the supply of skills can go a long way wage, strong unions, and generous
toward explaining the differences in transfer progranls in Europe are in
the returns to schooling, especially be- part responsible for the relative wage
tween the United States, Canada, and coinpression in Europe.
the United Kingdom. Nevertheless, it is Nevertheless, the Krugman hypothe-
puzzling that wage inequality increased sis runs into two difficulties. First, unless
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market 61

there are extrelnely rigid institutions a possibility, we have no direct evi-


that fix the skill premium exogenously, dence to assess how far off the relative
skill-biased technical change should demand curve European economies
increase wage inequality irrespective may be, and how they would respond to
of the degree of exogenously imposed skill-biased technical change when they
wage compression. I n contrast, in many are away from the relative demand
continental European economies, most curve for skills.56
notably in Germany, wage inequality My preferred approach to explaining
was very stable (see, e.g., Freeman and cross-country differences is to consider
Katz 1995). the effect of labor market institutions
Second, the Kruglnan hypothesis on technology choices. In particular,
makes an explicit prediction: profit- the European labor market institutions,
maximizing employment decisions of which coinpress the structure of wages,
firms should lead to a decline in the will give greater incentives to adopting
employinent of unskilled workers rela- labor-complementary technologies, and
tive to that of skilled workers. In fact, will reinforce wage compression. I give
skill-biased technical change inight a silnple example to illustrate the point
even reduce the unemploylnent rates of here. Suppose the productivity of a
skilled workers. Yet, in Europe, the un- skilled worker is Ah =all, whereas the
employinent of skilled and unskilled productivity of an unskilled worker is
workers increased together (e.g. Stephen & = a , where a is a measure of aggre-
Nickel1 and Brian Bell 1996; Krueger gate technology in use, and q > 1. Sup-
and Pischke 1.997), and unskilled em- pose that wages are determined by rent
ployment did not grow faster in the sharing, unless they fall below a legally
United States than in European econo- mandated minimum wage, in which
mies (Card, Kramartz, and Lelnieux case the minilnuin wage binds. Hence,
1996; Krueger and Pischke 1997). zoj = ~ n i n{PAj,zc;],w here j = I or h, and P
I t is possible that bargaining arrange- is worker's share in rent sharing. Note
ments in Europe between firms and that the cost of technology upgrading
unions, imply not only wage compres- does not feature in this wage equation,
sion, but also deviations from the rela- because rent sharing happens after
tive demand curve for "skills" given by technology costs are sunk. T o capture
(30). This may b e because European in- wage compression, suppose the mini-
stitutions force firms to pay uniform mum wage is binding for unskilled
wages to all educated workers irrespec- workers in Europe. Now consider tech-
tive of their exact skills (marginal prod- nology adoption decisions. In particular,
uct), making the employment of skilled
5GAn alternative view suggested by Nickell and
workers less profitable as well. Alterna-
tively, if unions represent both skilled
Bell (1996) explains the differences in the wa e
k
structure across countries by differences in t l e
skill distribution. According to this view, because
and unskilled workers, and are commit-
of the relative weakness of the U.S. high school
ted to wage compression, they may not system, American noncollege workers are less
want to suffer a large decrease in the skilled than their European counterparts. How-
employlnent of unskilled workers, and ever, recent work by Dan Devroye and Freeman
(2001) shows that differences in skill distribution
prefer to make certain concessions in have little to do with cross-country differences in
wage levels in order to induce firms to wage dispersion. They doculllent that dispersion
employ more unskilled workers at a of internationally comparable test scores anlong
native-born Americans are similar to those in
colnpressed wage structure. Although Europe, but wage inequality among native-born
such deviations froin equation (30) are Americans is much higher.
62 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2002)

firms can either produce with some productivity of unskilled workers (see
existing technology, a , or upgrade to a Acemoglu and Pischke 1999 for this
superior technology, a' = u + a , at cost y. argument in the context of training).
The profit to upgrading the technology As long as the cost of upgrading to
used by a skilled worker is (1 - P)aq - y, the new technology, y,is small, i.e., less
both in the United States and Europe. than yu, firms will upgrade both with
The new technology will therefore be skilled and unskilled workers in the
adopted when United States and Europe. I n this case,
cross-country inequality levels will be
stable. This corresponds to the situation
Note that there is a holdup problem, dis- in the 1950s and the 1960s. In contrast,
couraging upgrading: a fraction P of the if y is high, for example, because the
productivity increase accrues to the technological improvements of the 1980s
worker due to rent sharing (Paul Grout are more expensive to implement, there
1984; Aceinoglu 1996). may be a divergence in inequality be-
The incentives to upgrade the tech- tween the two economies. For instance,
nology used by unskilled workers, on if y E (yU,a), then new technology will not
the other hand, differ between the be adopted with unskilled workers in
United States and Europe. In the the United States, but it will be used
United States, this profit is given by with unskilled workers in Europe. As a
(1- p)a - y. So, the new technology will result, while wage inequality increases
be adopted with unskilled workers if in the United States, it will remain
stable in Europe. Therefore, a simple
story for cross-country differences in
inequality trends emerges from this
Clearly, yu < ys, so adopting new tech- model: wage compression encourages
nologies with skilled workers is more the use of more advanced technologies
profitable. The returns to introducing with unskilled workers, and acts to rein-
the new technology are different in force itself in Europe. In contrast, tech-
Europe because the minimum wage is nological developments can harm the
binding for unskilled worlzers. To sim- earnings of low-skill U.S. workers who
plify the discussion, suppose that even are not protected by this type of wage
after the introduction of new technology, compression. Whether the interaction
the i~linimum wage binds, i.e., between wage compression and tech-
g > P(A + a ) . Then, the return to intro- nology choice could be important in ex-
ducing the new technology in Europe plaining European inequality and un-
with unskilled workers is a - y, and firms employment patterns is an area for
will do so as long as y < a. Since a > yU, future study.
firins in Europe have greater incentives
to introduce advanced technologies with 8.2 International Determinants
unskilled workers than in the United
of Teclznology
States. This is because the binding mini- The endogenous technology frame-
mum wage in Europe makes the firm the work developed above links the skill
Jill1 residual claimant of the increase in bias of technology to the relative supply
the productivity of unskilled workers. of skills. There are a number of inter-
This highlights that in an economy with a esting and difficult issues that arise
compressed wage structure, firms inay when we consider the international di-
have a greater incentive to increase the mension. Here I simply mention some
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and t h e Labor Market 63

preliminary approaches, but clearly be unable to pay for these technologies


much theoretical and empirical work because of credit problems.
remains to be done. It is also worth noting that even when
A first extension of the endogenous a country is using U.S. technologies, its
technology idea to an international con- effective skill bias may be influenced by
text might be to suppose that skill bias its domestic skill supply. This is be-
in each country is determined by the cause U.S. technologies need to be
country's relative supply of skills. Yet it adapted to local conditions, and firms
may be more plausible to imagine a will have a greater incentive to do this
situation where new technologies spread when there is a larger supply of workers
across countries. In this case, it may be to use these technologies. So it may be
the incentives in the technologically not only tecl~nological change that is
most advanced country (the technologi- endogenous to relative supplies, but
cal leader) that determine the skill bias also teclanology adoption.
of world technologies. This description Finally, another interesting cross-
may be adequate for understanding the country dimension comes from looking
skill bias of technologies used by less at wage inequality trends in LDCs. As
developed countries (see for example discussed in section 6.3, the first-order
Acemoglu 1999b). But it is also possible predictions of the standard trade theory
for other technologically advanced econo- are not borne out: instead of a decline
mies to pursue a different pat11 of tech- in inequality, which would have been
nological development than the leader, expected due to the greater integration
in which case domestic incentives may of these economies into world trade,
be important in shaping skill bias. inequality increased in most LDCs. A
What determines the skill bias of recent paper by Berman and Machin
technologies developed by the techno- (2000) shows an interesting pattern:
logical leader? This depends on the while there has been rapid skill upgrad-
market sizes for different types of tech- ing in many middle income countries,
nologies, hence on the international there is much less evidence for rapid
enforcement of intellectual property skill upgrading in the poorest econo-
rights. For example, in the discussion mies. A possible explanation for these
on the effect of trade on technology, I patterns is that middle income countries
supposed that there were no intellec- are adopting advanced technologies
tual property rights for United States much more rapidly than the poorest
companies enforced in less developed countries, and since these technologies
economies. In this case, incentives to are more skill-biased, these economies
develop new technologies are shaped by are undergoing rapid skill upgrading
the United States (or O E C D ) supplies. and increases in inequality. Further-
This may be a good starting point, since more, if, as claimed by Acemoglu and
even when property rights are enforced, Zillibotti (2001), new technologies de-
there will be a number of difficulties veloped in the rich economies are typi-
facing U.S. companies marketing their cally "too skill-biased" for LDCs, the
technologies in other countries, espe- recent acceleration in skill bias could
cially in the case of technologies that have negative implications for the
will be used with relatively low-skill LDCs. More generally, the impact of
workers. For example, technologies may technologies developed in the advanced
need to be adapted to conditions in lo- economies on L D C labor markets is an
cal markets, or producers in LDCs may area that requires further research.
64 Journal of Economic Literature, V o l . X L ( M a r c h 2 0 0 2 )

9 . Conclusion ers has induced the development of


skill-complementary technologies.
This essay discussed the link between
The acceleration in skill-biased tech-
technical change and the labor market,
nical change is then likely to have
with special emphasis on the recent
been a response to the rapid increase
changes in the U.S. wage structure. I n
in the supply of skills during the past
this process, I surveyed part of the
several decades, though this perspec-
large literature on the determinants of
tive does not suggest that we are nec-
the rise in inequality, and put forth a
essarily in the midst of a "Technologi-
different 'interpretation of the changes
cal Revolution"; what has changed
in technologies and their impact on the
is not necessarily the overall rate of
labor market than the most widely ac-
progress, but the types of technologies
cepted view. I t is difficult to summarize
that are being developed.
this large literature, and therefore, even
The recent technological develop-
more difficult to summarize this es-
ments are also likely to have affected
say. Nevertheless, it may b e useful to
the organization of the labor mar-
reiterate some of the main points:
ket-including the way firms organize
1. The behavior of wages and returns to production, labor market policies, and
schooling in the United States indi- the form of labor market "institu-
cates that technical change has been tions"-and may have had a large
skill-biased during the past sixty effect on the structure of wages
years, and probably for most of the through this channel.
twentieth century.
Many of these conclusions are tenta-
2. Though more controversial, the evi-
tive. There is much research to be done
dence also points to an acceleration
to understand the process of technical
in skill bias during the past few
change and how it impacts the labor
decades.
market. I n particular, what determines
3. In contrast, much of what we know sug-
wage differences among observationally
gests that technical change was not skill-
similar workers, why the trajectories of
biased during the nineteenth century,
the Anglo-Saxon and continental Euro-
and most likely, it was skill-replacing.
pean economies have diverged, and how
4. We can understand the behavior of
technical change and institutional
technical change by recognizing that
change interact are important areas for
the development and use of technol-
future research.
ogy respond to profit incentives. When
developing skill-biased techniques is
more profitable, new technology will Appendix
tend to be skill-biased. According to this A l . Data Sources
perspective, the early nineteenth cen- The samples are constructed as in Katz and
tury was characterized by skill-replacing Autor (2000). I thank David Autor for providing
me with data from this study. Data from 1939,
developments because the increased 1949, and 1959 come from 1940, 1950, and 1960
supply of unskilled workers in the censuses. The rest of the data come from 1964-97
English cities made the introduction of March CPSs. The college premium is the coeffi-
cient on workers with a college degree or more
these technologies profitable. relative to high school graduates in a log weekly
5. In contrast, the twentieth century has wage regression. The regression also includes
been characterized by skill-biased dummies for other education categories, a quartic
in experience, three region dummies, a nonwhite
technical change because the rapid dummy, a female dummy, and interactions be-
increase in the supply of skilled work- tween the female dummy and the nonwhite dummy
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Marlcet 65

TABLE A1
CITANGES
ANNUALIZED IN OVERALL
AND RESIDUALWAGEINEQUALITY
((FROM KATZAND AUTOR)

Census March CPSs May CPSs (ORGs)


90-10 50-10 90-10 50-10 90-10 50-10
Changes in overall inequality
1960s 0.10
1970s 0.10
1980s 0.17
1990s -
Changes in residual inequality
1960s 0.03
1970s 0.09
1980s 0.07
1990s -

Note: The numbers give 10 x annualized changes from Table 4 of Katz and Autor (2000). 90-10 is the difference
between the 90th and 10th percent of the log wage or residual distlibution, and 50-10 is the difference between the
median and 10th percent of the corresponding distribution. The residuals are estimated from log earnings regres-
sions with nine education dummies, a quartic in experience and their interactions. See notes to Tables 3 and 4 in
Katz and Autor (2000).

and the experience controls. T h e sample includes sources: decennial censuses, and March CPSs and
all full-time full-year workers between the ages of May CPSs (and later Outgoing Rotation Group
18 and 65, and except those with the lowest 1 per- files-ORGs). These numbers show no significant
cent earnings. Earnings for top coded observatiolls change in residual or overall inequality during the
are calculated as the value of the to code times 1960s, and consistent increases in inequality from all
1.5. The relative supply of skills is c a t u l a t e d from sources during the 1970s and the 1980s. For example,
a sample that includes all workers between the the data from the Census and the March CPSs indi-
ages of 18 and 65. It is defined as the ratio of cate that the 90-10 differential increased about 0.10 a
college equivalents to non-college equivalents, cal- year between 1970 and 1979, while the 50-10 dif-
culated as in Autor, Katz, and Krueger (1998) ferential increased by about 0.11 a year during the
using weeks worked as weights. I n particular, col- same period. The May CPS data show a smaller
lege e uivalents = college graduates + 0.5 x work- increase in the 90-10 differentials during this
\
ers wit some college, and noncollege equivalents =
high school dropouts + high school graduates + 0.5 x
riod, but a corn arable increase in the 50-10
ferelltial OveraK although there is less uniformity
iz:
workers with some college. among data sources regarding the behavior of re-
Samples used for overall and residual wage in- sidual inequality than returns to schoolin (see
equality include ollly white male full-time full year Katz and Autor 2000), there is considerabfe evi-
workers between the ages of 18 and 65, and ex- dence that residual and overall inequality started
clude those earning less than half the real value to increase during the 1970s.
of the 1982 minimum wage converted from nomi-
A3. Can Cornposition Effects Explain
nal dollars using the personal consumption expen-
diture deflator (see Katz and Autor 2000). Earn- Inequality Changes?
ings for top coded observations are calculated as A possible explanation for the patterns we ob-
the value of the top code times 1.5. serve could be changes in the distribution of un-
observed skills- or more concretely, composition
A2. The Belanolor of Ooerall Inequality
effects. For example, the average ability of workers
During the 1970s with high education may have increased relative to
I n an important paper on the effect of labor that of workers with low education over time.
market institutions on inequality, DiNardo, Here, I document that the increase in the returns
Fortin, and Lemieux (1995) provide evidence sug- to education and residual inequality are not smply
gesting that in the May CPSs, there is no increase due to composition effects. Note first that compo-
in inequality during the 1970s. I n table A l , I dis- sition effects cannot by themselves explain the re-
lay numbers from the survey by Katz and Autor cent changes in inequality: as noted in subsection
b 0 ), who report changes in residual inequality 7.2, compositioll effects suggest that ine uality
for the past four decades from three different among educated and uneducated workers s ould %
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)

TABLE A2
COMPOSITION
EFFECTS

Bornin19- 06-10 11-15 16-20 21-25 26-30 31-35 3640 4145 46-5 51-55
Year J +
Panel A
1950 1.448 1.370 1.175 1.093
1960 1.551 1.564 1.525 1.421 1.303 1.132
1970 1.680 1.656 1.613 1.539 1.392 1.153
1980 1.567 1.560 1.538 1.402 1.222 1.063
1990 1.798 1.761 1.723 1.674
Panel B

Panel C

Note: The top panel gives the college premium from the census indicated at the beginning of the row for cohoits
born in the five-year intervals indicated at the head of the column. For example, the first number is for individuals
born between 1906-10 from the census of 1950. The college premium is defined as the wages of workers from that
cohort with a college degree or more hvided by the wages of workers from that cohoit with twelve years of
schooling. The bottom panel gives the change in the college premium for a given cohort between the two indicated
dates and the difference between the wage growth of two neighboring cohorts as indicated by equations (34) and
(35).All data are from the decennial censuses for white males born in the United States.

move in opposite directions. This suggests that Consider changes in cohort quality first. If, as
changes in the true returns to skills have played at many claim, the U.S. high school system has be-
least some role in the changes in inequality. come worse, we might expect a decline in Ao, with-
More generally, to get a sense of how important out a corresponding decline in Al,. As a result,
composition effects may be, consider a variant of AIt -Aot may increase. Alternatively, as a larger
equation (13) above with two education levels, high fraction of the U.S. population obtains higher edu-
h = 1 and low 1%= 0, and suppose wages are given by cation, it is natural that selection into education
(i.e., the abilities of those obtaining education)
will change. I t is in fact possible that those who
are left without education could have very low un-
where 12, is a dumm for high education, a, is un- observed ability, which would translate into a low level
observed ability, a n X q t is a mean zero disturbance of Aot, and therefore into an increase in Alt -Aot.
term. Define the (log) education premium-the Although these scenarios are plausible, theoret-
difference between the average wages of high and ically the opposite can happen as well. For exam-
low education workers-can be written as ple, many academics who have been involved in
the U.S. education system for a long time com-
In ot = E(ln tu1t1 lxl = 1)- E(ln wit 1 h , = 0) plain about the decline in the quality of universi-
= yt + Alt - Aot ties, while the view that American high schools
where A1, = E(a, 1 lzi = 1) and Aot is defined simi- have become much worse is not shared universally
larly. The increase in the education premium can (e.g., Krueger 1998). The selection argument is
be caused by an increase in yt (a true increase in also more complicated than it first appears. I t is
the returns to skills) or an increase in Alt-Aot. true that, as long as those with high unobserved
There are basically two reasons for an increase in abilities are more likely to obtain higher educa-
A1,-Aot: (1) changes in cohort quality, or (2) tion, an increase in education will depress Aot. But
changes in the pattern of selection into education. it will also depress Alt. T o see why, assume that
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market
there is perfect sorting-i.e., if an individual with
ability n obtains education, all individuals with TABLE A3
ability a' > a will do so as well. I11 this case, there CHANGESI N INEQUALITY
BY COIIORT
will exist a threshold level of ability, n, such that (FHOM JUHNET AL. 1993)
only those with a > a obtain education. Next con-
sider a uniform distribution of a , between bo and
bo + b,. Then, Panel A: 90-10 Differentials for Log Weekly Wages
Year of
inarket entry 1964 1970 1976 1982 1988
and

So both A. and Al will decline when ii decreases to


a'. Moreover, Al - A o = b1/2, so it is unaffected by
the decline in n. Intuitively, with a uniforln distri-
bution of a i , when n increases, both A. and Al fall
by exactly the same amount, so the composition
effects have no influence on the education pre-
miurn. Clearly, with other distributions of ability,
this extreme result will no longer hold, but it re- Panel B: 90-10 Differentials for Log Itage Residuals
inains true that both A. and Al will fall, and
whether this effect will increase or decrease the Year of
education premium is unclear. Overall, therefore, inarket entry 1964 1970 1976 1982 1988
the effects of changes in colnposition on education
premia is an empirical question. 1983-88 1.09
Empirically, the importance of composition ef- 1977-82 1.06 1.16
fects can b e uncovered by looking at inequality 1971-76 .96 1.09 1.18
chan es by cohort (see McKinley Blackburn, 1965-70 .86 .96 1.12 1.23
Davi% Bloom, and Freeman 1992; Juhn, Murphy, 1959-64 .92 .86 .98 1.12 1.21
and Pierce 1993). To see this, rewrite equation
(31) as 1953-58 .88 .91 .99 1.15 1.26
1947-52 .89 .94 .99 1.14
194146 .94 .94 1.05
193540 .95 .98
where c denotes a cohort-i.e., a group of indi-
viduals who are born in the same year. I have im- 1929-34 .99
posed an important assumption in writing equa-
tion (32): returns to skills are assumed to be t h e Note: This table replicates Table 3 of Juhn, Murphy,
same for all cohorts and ages; y,-though clearly and Pierce (1993). The top panel reports the 90-10
they vary over time. W e can now define cohort differential for log weekly wages of the cohorts that
specific education prelnia as
have entered the labor market in the corresponding
six-year interval. Panel B gives the 90-10 differential
for the residuals from a regression of log weekly wages
on education controls.
where Alct 5 E(ai, I 12, = 1) and Ao,, is defined simi-
larly. Under the additional assumption that there
is no further schooling for any of the cohorts year t , and that yst = y, + yt (this assumption is
over the periods under study, we have also not necessary, but simplifies the discussion).
In w,, = yt + A ~ -
, Aoc, which implies ,
Then A In o,,,, - = y,, - y, + yt, - yt, where obviously
s f - s = t'- t. Now consider a different cohort, c"
that is age s' in the year t and age s in the year t".
Then A ln o,,,,,- ,,, = y,, - y, + yt - ytr,. So, the true
i.e., chan es in the returns to education within a change in the returns to skills between the dates t"
collort wikl reveal the true change in the returns, and t' is
Yet, the assum tion that returns to skills are con-
stant over the ffetime of an individual may be too
restrictive. Murphy and Welch (1992), for exam-
ple, show quite different age-earning profiles by Using data from the 1950-90 censuses, table A2
education. Nevertheless, a similar argument can gives some of the single and double differences of
b e applied in this case too. For exam le, sup- cohort inequality for white men aged 26-55. The
F
pose In ocst= yTt+ A,, - Ao, for cohort c o age s in single differences show increases in the returns to
68 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
college within most cohorts, with the exception of tion and Ine uality," MIT miineo, forthcoming
the years between 1970 and 1980. Therefore, r i e i e - e s t e r Conf S e r Public Pol.
these increases are likely to reflect differential age Acemoglu, Daron and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1999.
effects by education. In contrast, the nuinbers in "The Structure of Wages and Investlnent in
panel C for tlie 1950-70 eriod show no increases, General Training," J . Polit. Econ. 107:3, pp.
suggesting that the doubfe ditference does a good 539-72.
job of controlling for coinposition effects. The Acemoglu, Daron and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2001.
'nuinbers for tlle 1960-80 period are negative, "Productivity Differences," Quc~rt. J . Ecoiz.
which likely reflect the decline in the college pre- 116:2, p p 563-606.
lnium between 1960 and 1980. The final row gives Aghion, Philippe. 2000. "Technical Change, Insti-
the most important results of this table. The 1970- tutions, and the Dynainics of Inequality," Har-
90 double differences are large and positive, sug- vard miineo; forthcoming Econometricn.
gesting that the true returns to education in- Aghion, Philip e and Peter Howitt. 1998. Endoge-
creased over this time Interestingly, nous Grolot% Tlieory. MA: MIT Press.
despite tlle well-known eui~e~i:~~hatthe college Aghion, Philippe; Peter Howitt and Gianluca Vio-
~ r e m i u i n increased faster for ounger workers lante. 2000. "Technology, Knowledge, and In-
over the 1980s, tlie results in tagle A2 show that equality," mirneo, Harvard U.
tlie true increase in returns to skills between 1970 Ahinad, Syed. 1966. "011 the Theory of ~ n d u c e d
and 1990 are coinparable for cohorts born be- Invention," Ecoiz. J . 56, pp. 344-57.
tween 1936 and 1955. These results therefore in- Angrist, oshua. 1995. "The Econolnic Returns to
dicate that tlie inajor cornpoilent of the increase in Schoolng in the West Bank and Gaza Strip,"
tliat college premium during the 1980s and 1990s Amer. Econ. Rev. 85:5, pp. 1065-87.
was changes in true skill prices, not cornposition Appelbaum, Eileen and Rosemary Batt. 1994. The
effects. N e ~ uAmerican \Vorkplace. NY: ILR Press.
Table A3, which replicates table 3 from Juhn, Autor, David; Alan Krueger and Lawrence Katz.
biurphy, and Pierce (1993), shows that tlie in- 1998. "Computing Inequality: Have Computers
crease in overall and residual inequality cannot be Changed the Labor Market?" Quart. J . Econ.
explained by coinposition effects either. Panel A 113:4, p p 1169-213.
shows tliat the 90-10 differential for cohorts en- Autor, David; Frank Levy and Richard Murnane.
tering the market between 1935 and 1964 is ap- 2001. "The Slzill Content of Recent Technologi-
proximately constant between 1964 and 1970, but cal Change: A11 Empirical Exploration," MIT
increases sharply for each cohort between 1970 miineo.
and 1976, and then increases further between Bailey, Martin and Robert Gordon. 1988. "The
1982 and 1988. Panel B shows a similar picture for Productivity Slowdown: Measurement Issues
log wage residuals. These results suggest that the and Explosion of Computer Power," Broolcings
changes in the structure of wages observed over Pap. Ecoiz. Act., Macroecon. 2, pp. 379-431.
the past thirty years cannot be explained b pure Bairoch, Paul. 1988. Cities nncl Economic Deuelop-
coin,osition effects, and reflect rnainly c&nges ment: Fronz tlze Daton of Histort to the Present.
in t i e true returns to observed and unobserved Christopher Braider, t r a n s Cdicago: U . Clii-
skills. cago Press.
Bartel, Ail11 P. and Frank Lichtenberg. 1987. "The
Comparative Advantage of Educated Workers
in Implementing New Technology," ", Rel;. Ecoiz.
Abramovitz, Moses. 1956. "Resource and Output statis;. 69:1, pp-1-11.
Trends in the United States since 1870," Ainer. Bartel. Ail11 and Nacliuin Sicherinan. 1998. "Tech-
Econ. Rev. 46, pp. 5-23. nological Change and the Skill Acquisition of
Acenioglu, Daron. 1996. "A biicrofoundation for Young Workers," J . Labor Econ. 16:4, pp. 718-55.
Social Iiicreasi~lgReturns in Human Capital Ac- Beaudry, Paul and David Green. 1999. "What Is
curnulation," Quart. J . Econ. 111:3, pp. 779- Driving U.S. and Canadian Wages: Exogenous
804. Technical Change or Endogenous Choice of
-. 1998. "Why Do New Technolo ies Conl- Technique?" NBER work. aper 6853.
~ l e i n e n tSkills? Directed Technical Cfange and Berman, Eli; John Bound anQZvi Griliclies 1994.
?T'age Inequality," Quart. J . Econ. 1 1 3 2 , pp. "Changes in the Demand for Sltilled Labor
1055-89
- within U.S. Manufacturing Industries: Evidence
-. 1999a. "Changes in Unemployment and from the Annual Survey of Manufactures,"
Wage Inequality: A11 Alternative Theory and Quart. J . Econ. 109, pp. 365-67.
~ o G e~vicfence:" Amer. Econ, Reu. 89:5, pp. Berman, Eli; John Bound and Stephen Machin.
1259-78. 1998. "Implications of Skill-Biased Technologi-
, 1999b "Patterns of Skill Plaernia," NBER cal Change: International Evidence," Quai-t. 1.
work. paper 7018. Econ. 11,: pp. 1245-80.
--. 2000 "Labor- and Capital-Augmenting Berinan. Eli and Stenhen Machin. 2000. "SBTC
Technical Change," NBER work. paper 7544. Happens! ~ v i d e n c e ' o nthe Factor Bias of Tech-
Acemoglu, Daron, Phillipe Aghion and Gianluca nological Change in Developing and Developed
Vlolante. 2001. "Technical Change, Deunioniza- Countries," Boston U. iniineo.
Acemoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market
Blackburn, McKinley; David Bloom and Richard ture of Wages and Employment: A Colnparison
Freeinan. 1992. "Changes in Earnings Differen- of the United States, Canada and France," Can.
tials in the 1980s: Concordance, Conver ence, J. Econ.
Causes, and Conseqoences," NBER irorfz pa- Caroli, Eve and John van Reenen. 1999. "Wage
per 3901. Inequality and Organizational Change," UCL
Blau, Francine D . and Lawrence M. Kahn. 1996. mirneo.
"International Differences in Male Wage In- Caselli, Francesco. 1999. "Technological Revolu-
equality: Institutions versus Market Forces," J. tions," Amer. Econ. Rev. 89:1, pp. 78-102.
Polit. Econ. 104:4, pp. 791-836. Cohen, Sarit and Chang-Tai Hsieh. 2000. "Macro-
Borghans, Lex and Bas Ter Weel. 2000. "Do We economic and Labor Market Impact of Russian
Need Computer Skills to Use a Computer: Evi- Irnrnigration in Israel," Princeton U. inirneo.
dence from the United Kingdom," Maastricht David, Paul. 1975. Teclznical Clzoice, Iiznovation
mimeo. ancl Econoinic Growth: Essays o n Ainerican and
Borjas, George J.; Richard B. Freeman and Britislz Experience i n tlze Nineteenth Century.
Lawrence F . Katz. 1997. "How Much Do Immi- London: Cambridge U. Press.
gration and Trade Affect Labor Market Out- David, Paul. 1990. "The Dynamo and the Com-
comes?" Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 0:1, pp. 1- puter: A11 Ilistorical Perspective on the Modern
67. Productivity Paradox," Aiizer. Econ. Rev. 80:2,
Borjas, George J. and Valerie Rarney. 1995. "For- pp. 355-61.
eign Competition, Market Power and Wage 111- Davis, Steven J . 1992. "Cross-Country Patterns of
equality," Quart. J. Econ. 110.4, pp. 1075-110. Changes in Relative Wages," in N B E R Macro-
Boskin Michael; Ellen Dulberger, Robert Gordon, econolnics Annual 1992. Olivier Jean Blanchard
Zvi Griliches and Dale Jorgenson. 1998. "Con- and Stanley Fischer, eds. Cambridge and Lon-
sumer Prices, the Consumer Price Index, and don: MIT Press, pp. 239-92.
the Cost of Living,"]. Econ. Per.spect. 12:1, pp. Davis, Steven J.; John Haltiwanger and Scott
3-26. Schuh. 1996. Job Creation and Destruction.
Bound, John and George Johnson. 1992. "Changes MA: MIT Press.
in the Structure of Wages in the 1980s: An Devroye, Dan and Richard Freeman. 2000. "Does
Evaluation of Alternative Explanations," A ~ n e r . Inequality in Skills Explain Inequality of Earn-
ECOII.Reo. 82:3, pp. 371-92. ings across Countries?" Harvard U. inimeo.
Bowles, Samuel; Herbert Gintis and Melissa Os- Diebold, Francis; David Neuinark and Daniel
borne. 2001. "The Determinants of Earnines: A Polsky. 1997. "Job Stability in the United
Behavioral Approach," J. ECOII.Lit. 39:4: pp. States," J. Labor Econ. 15:2, pp. 206-33.
1137-76. DiNardo, John; Nicole Fortin and Thoinas
Braverman, Harry. 1974. Labor and Monopoly Leinieux. 1995. "Labor Market Institutions and
Capital: The Degradation of Work i n the Twen- the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semi-
tieth Century. NY: Monthly Review Press. parametric Approach," Econolnetrica 64:5, pp.
Brendt, Ernie; Catherine Morrison and Larry 1001-44.
Rosenblum. 1994. "High-tech Capital Forma- DiNardo, John; Kevin Hallock and Jorn-Steffen
tion and Labor Composition in U.S. Manufac- Pischke. 2000. "Unions and Managerial Pay,"
turing Industries: A11 Exploratory Analysis," J . London School Econ. miineo.
Econonzetrics 65, pp. 9-43. DiNardo, John and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1997.
Bresnahan, Timothy F. 1999. "Computerization "The Returns to Computer Use Revisited: Have
and Wage Dispersion: A11 Analytical Reinter- Pencils Changed the Wage Structure Too?"
pretation," Stanford U. mimeo. Quart. J . Econ. 112:1, pp. 291-303.
Bresnahan, Timothy F.; Erik Brynjolfsson and Doms, Mark; Timothy Dunne and Kenneth
Lorin M. Hitt. 1999. "Information Technolo y Torske. 1997. "Workers, Wages and Technol-
Workplace Organization and the Demand fo; ogy," Quart. J. Econ. 112, pp. 217-52.
Skilled Labor: Firm-level Evidence," NBER Duranton, Gilles. 2001. "The Economics of Pro-
work. paper 7136. duction Systems: Segmentation and Skill-Biased
Cappelli, Peter and Steffanie Wilk. 1997. "Under- Change," mimeo, London School of Econoinics.
standing Selection Processes: Organization De- Entorf, Horst and Francis Kramartz. 1998. "Does
terininants and Perforlnance Outcomes," Unmeasured Ability Explain the Higher Wages
mimeo, Wharton School, U. Pennsylvania. of New Technology Workers?" Europ. Econ.
Card, David E . and Alan Krueger. 2000. "School Rev. 41, pp. 1489-509.
Quality and Black-White Relative Earnings: A Farber, Henry. 1995. "Are Lifetime Jobs Disap-
Direct Assessment," Quart. J. Econ. 107, pp. pearing? Job Duration in the United States,"
151-200. NBER work. paper 5014.
Card, David and Thomas Lemieux. 2001. "Can Farber, Henry and Bruce Western. 2000. "Round
Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to Up the Usual Suspects: The Decline of Unions
College for Younger Men?" Quart. J. Econ. in the Private Sector," Princeton U. Ind. Rel.
116:2, pp. 705-46. work. paper 437.
Card, David; Francis Kramartz and Thomas Feenstra, Robert and Gordon Hanson. 1999. "The
Lemieux. 1996. "Changes in the Relative Struc- Impact of Outsourcing and High-Technology
70 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
Capital on Wages: Estimates for the United States, Gordon, Robert. 1990. Meast~reinentof Durable
1979-1990," Quart. 1.Econ. 114:3, pp. 907-40. Goods Prices. IL: U. Chicago Press.
Foster, Andrew and Mark Rosenzwei 1996. . 1998. "Current Productivity Puzzles from
"Technical Change in Human Capitaf'Return a Long-term Perspective," Northwestern U.
and Investments: Evidence from the Green miineo.
Revolution," Ainer. Econ. Rev. 86, pp. 931-53. Gosling, Amanda. 1998. "The Determination of
Frank, Robert H . and Phillip J . Cook. 1995. The Union Status and Wages in British Estab-
Winner-Talce-All Society. NY: Free Press. lishments," U Essex. discuss pafer 491.
Freeman, Richard. 1976. The Ozjeredzccated Gottschalk, Peter. 1997. "Inequa ity in Income,
Anzerican. NY: Academic Press. Growth and Mobility: The Basic Facts," 1.Econ.
, 1986, "Demand for Education," in Hand- Perspect. 11, pp. 21-40.
book of Labor Econoinics, Vol. I. Orley Ashen- Gottschalk, Peter and Robert Moffitt. 1994. "The
felter and Richard Lapard, eds. North-Holland: Growth of Earnings Instability in the U.S.
Elsevier. Labor Market," Broolcings Pap. Econ. Act. 2,
. 1991. "How Much Has De-unionization p p 217-72.
Contributed to the Rise of Male Earnings In- Gottschalk, Peter and Timothy M. Smeeding.
equality?" NBER working paper 3826. 1997. "Cross-National Comparisons of Earnings
Freeman, Richard and Lawrence F . Katz. 1995. and Income Inequality," 1. Econ. Lit. 35:2, pp.
"Introduction and Summary," in difference.^ 633-87.
and Changes in Wage 5'tructure.s. R. Freeman Gould, Eric D . ; Omer Moav and Bruce A. Wein-
and L. Katz, eds. Chicago: U. Chicago Press. berg. 2000. "Precautionary Demand for Educa-
Freeman, Richard and Edward Lazear. 1995. "An tion, Inequality, and Technological Progress,"
Economic Analysis of Works Councils," in miineo, MIT.
W0rk.s Counci1.s: Con.sultation, Representation, Green, Constance M. 1956. Eli Whitney and the
and Cooperation in Industrial Re1ation.s. Joel Birth of American Technology. MA: Little,
Rogers and Wolfgang Streeck, eds. NBER Brown.
Compar. Labor Markets Series, Chicago: U. Greenwood, Jeremy; Zvi Hercowtiz and Per
Chicago Press. Krusell. 1997. "Long-Run Implicatiolls of
Freeman, Richard and James Medoff. 1984. W h a t Investment-Specific Techological Change,"
Unions Do. NY: Basic Books. Amer. ECOII.Rezj. 87:3, p 342-62.
Freeman, Richard and Karen Needles. 1993. "Skill Greenwood, Jeremy an$ h l e h m e t Yorukoglu.
Differences in Canada in an Era of Rising La- 1997. "1974," Carneeie-Rochester C o n f Ser.
bor Market Inequality," in Small Differences Public Pol. 46, pp. 49-35.
That Matter. D . Card and R. Freeman, eds. Griliches. Zvi. 1957. "Hvbrid Corn: An Exvlora-
Chicago: U. Chicago Press and NBER. tion in the ~ c o n d i n i c s of ~ e c h n o ~ g i c a l
Friedberg, Rachel. 1997. "The Impact of Mass Mi- Change," Econonzetrica 25, pp. 501-22.
gration on the Israeli Labor Market," RI: Brown , 1969. "Capital-Skill Complementarity,"
U. Population Studies and Training Center Rev. Econ. Stati.st. 51, pp. 465-68.
work. paper 97-11. Grossman, Gene and Elhanan Helpman. 1991. In-
Galor, Oded and Daniel Tsiddon. 1998. "Techno- novation and Growth in the Global Economy.
logical Progress, Mobility and Economic MA: MIT Press.
Growth," Amer. Econ. Rezj. 87, pp. 363-82. Grout, Paul. 1984. "Investment and Wages in the
Galor, Oded and Omer Maov. 2000. "Ability Bi- Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargain-
ased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality ing Ap roach ' Econoinetrica 5 2 , i p 449-60.
and Economic Growth," Quart. J. Econ. 115, Habakkug H J. 1 9 6 2 Anzerican an Britrsh Tech-
pp. 469-98. nology in the Nineteenth Century. London:
Gandal, Neil; Gordon H . Hanson and Matthew J. Cambridge U. Press.
Slaughter. 2000. "Technology, Trade, and Ad- Hanson, Gordon H . and Alln Harrison. 1995.
justment to Immigration in Israel," mimeo, "Trade Technology, and Wage Inequality: Evi-
Dartmouth College. dence from Mexico," NBER work. paper 5110.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence F . Katz. 1995. "The Hayami, Yujiro and Vernon Ruttan. 1970. "Factor
Decline of Non-Competing Groups: Changes in Prices and Technical Change in Agricultural
the Premium to Education, 1890 to 1940," Development: the U.S. and Japan, 1880-1960,"
NBER work. paper 5202. J. Polit. Econ. 77, pp. 1115-41.
. 1998. "The Origins of Technology-Skill Hornstein, Andres and Per Krusel. 1996. "Can
Complementarity," Quart. 1. Econ. 113:3, pp. Technology Iinproveinents Cause Productivity
693-732. Slowdowns?" NBER Macroeconoinic.s Annual,
, 2000. "Education and Income in the Early p p 209-59.
20th-century: Evidence from the Prairies," Ichniowski, Casey; Kathryn Shaw and Giovanna
forthcoming,]. Econ. Hi.st. Prennushi. 1997. "The Effects of Human Re-
Goldin, Claudia and Robert A. Margo. 1992. "The source Management Practices on Productivity:
Great Compression: The Wage Structure in the A Study of Steel Finishing Lines," Anzer. ECOII.
United States at Mid-Century," Quart. I. ECOII. Rev. 87:3, pp. 291-313.
107:1, pp. 1-34. James, John A. and Jonathan S. Skinner. 1985.
Acenaoglu: Technical Change, Inequality, and t h e Labor Market 71
"The Resolution of the Labor-Scarcity Para- mentary and Inequality," U. Rochester mimeo;
dox," J . ECOII.Hist. 45, p 513-50. forthcomin Econometrics.
Terome, Harry. 1934. Mec%aniratlon in Historv. Lawrence, Rok,ert and Matthew Slaughter 1993.
" NY: NBER: "Trade and U.S. Wages: Giant Sucking Sound
Tohnson. George. 1997. "Changes in Earnings In-
''
or Small Hiccup?" Brookines
u
Pav.
,
Econ. Act. 2,
equality: TI; Role of ~ e m G dShifts," /. %con. p p 161-226.
~ e r s ~ e c11,
t . pp. 41-54. Leamer, Edward E . 1995. "Trade, Wages and
Jorgensen, Dale W. and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2000. Revolving-Door Ideas," NBER work, paper
"Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic 4716.
Growth in the Information Age," Broolcings Lee, David S. 1999. "Wage Inequality in the U.S.
Pap. ECOII.Act. 1, pp. 125-236. During the 1980s: Rising Dispersion or Falling
Julln, Chinhui; Kevin M. Murphy and Brooks Minimum Wage?" Quart. J . ECOII.114, pp. 941-
Pierce. 1993. "Wage Inequality and the Rise in 1024
Returns to Skill," J . Polit. Econ. 101, pp. 410- Llovd-Ellis. Huw. 1999. "Endogenous Tecllnologi-
42. &1 Change and Wage 1neq;lity," Amer. Ec&.
Katz, Lawrence and David Autor. 2000. "Changes Reu. 89:1, p 47-77.
in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequal- Machin. S t e n f i n and Tohn Van Reenen. 1998.
ity," in Handbook of Labor Econonzics vol. 111. "TechnolGy and Cl;anges in Skill Structure:
Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds. Amster- Evidence from Seven OECD Countries,"
dam: Elsevier. Quart. J. Econ. 113:4, pp. 1215-44.
Katz, Lawrence and Kevin Murphy. 1992. Marglin, Stephen A. 1974. "What Do Bosses Do?
"Changes in Relative Wages: Supply and De- The Origins and Functions of Hierarchy in
mand Factors," Quart. J . ECOII.107, pp. 35-78. Capitalist Production," Reu. Radical Polit. Econ.
Katz, Lawrence; Gary W. Lovemail and David G. 3, p 33 60
Blanchflower. "A Comparison of Changes in the
Structure of Wages in Four OECD Countries"
in Dqferences and change.^ in Wage Structures.
!!
Mishef'LGrehce and ared Bernstein. 1994. "Is
the Technology Blac Box Empty? A11 Empiri-
cal Examillation of the Impact of Technology on
R. Freeman and L. Katz, eds. IL: U. Chicago Wage Inequality and the Employment Struc-
Press. ture," mimeo, Econ. Policy Institute.
Kendrick, John W. 1961. Productioity Trends i n , 1998. "Technology and the Wage Struc-
the United States. NJ: Princeton U. Press. ture: Has Technology's Impact Accelerated
Kennedy, Charles. 1964. "Induced Bias in Innova- since the 1970s?" Res. Lab. Econ. 17, pp. 305-
tion and the Theory of Distribution," Econ. J . 55.
74, p p 541-47. Mishel, Lawrence; Jared Bernstein and John
Kilep, Michael. 1999. "The Sup lp of Skilled La- Schmitt. 1998. "Wage Inequality in the 1990s:
bor and Skill-Biased Technokgical Progress,. Measurement and Trends," mimeo, Econ. Pol-
Econ. J. 109, pp. 708-24. icy Institute.
Kremer, Michael and Eric Maskin. 1999. "Segre- Mobius, Marcus. 2000. "The Evolution of Work,"
gation by Skill and the Rise in Inequality," Har- mimeo, MIT.
vard mimeo. , Toel. 1990 The Leoers o f Riche.~:Techno-
Mokvr., J

Krueger, Alan. 1993. "How Computers Have logical Creatioity and Economic Pr0gre.s~.NY:
Changed the Wage Structure: Evidence from Oxford U. Press.
Microdata, 1984-1989," Quart. J . Econ. 110, , ed. 1993. The Briti.sh Industrial Reuo1z~-
pp. 33-60. tion: AII Econoinic Perspectioe. CA: Westview
. 1997. "Labor Market Shifts and the Price Press.
Puzzle Revisited," Princeton U. Ind. Rel. work. Murnane, Richard J. and Frank Levy. 1996.
paper 375. Teaching the Ba.sic Neeo Skills. NY: Free Press.
. 1998. "Reassessing the View That Amer. Murphy, Kevin M.; W. Craig Riddell and Paul M.
Schools Are Broken," Princeton U. Ind. Rel. Romer. 1998. "Wages, Skills and Technology in
work. paper 395. the United States and Canada," in General Pur-
. 1999. "Measuring Labor's Share," Ainer. pose Technologies. E . Helpman, ed. MA: MIT
Econ. Reu. 89, pp. 45-51. Press.
Krueger, Alan B. and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 1997. Murphy, Kevin M. and Finis Welch. 1992. "The
"Observations and Conjectures on the U.S. Em- Structure of Wages," Quart. J . Econ. 107, pp.
ployment Miracle," NBER work. paper 6146. 255-85.
Krugman, Paul. 1994. "Part and Prospective , 1993. "Industrial Change and the Rising
Causes of High Unemployment," in Reducing Ilnportallce of Skill," in Uneuei~ Tide.s. S.
Unenzployment: Current Issues and Policy Op- Danziger and P. Gottschalk, eds. NY: Russell
tions. MO: Fed. Reserve Bank Kansas City. Sage.
, 1995. "Growing World Trade: Causes and , 2000. "Wage Differentials in the 1990s: Is
Conseauences." Broolcines u
Pav. Econ. Act. 1,
8
the Glass Half Full or Half Empty?" unpub. pa-
pp. 327'-77. per.
Krusell, Per; Lee Ohanian, Victor Rios-Rull and Nelson, Richard and Edmund Phelps. 1966. "In-
Giovaillli Violante. 2000. "Capital Skill Comple- vestment in Humans, Technological Diffusion
Journal of Econonaic Literature, Vol. XL (March 2002)
and Economic Growth," A E A Papers Proceed- Sachs, Jeffrey and Howard Shatz. 1994. "Trade
ings 56, pp. 69-75. and Jobs in U.S. Manufacturing," Broolcings
Newell, Richard; Adain Jaffee and Robert Stavins. Pap. Econ. Act. 0:1, pp. 1-69.
1999. "The Induce Innovation Hypothesis and Samuelson, Paul. 1965. "A Theory of Induced In-
Energy-Saving Technological Change," Quart. novations Along Kennedy-Weisacker Lines,"
J . Econ. 114, pp. 907-40. Reu. Econ. Statist. 47, pp. 444-64.
Nickell, Stephen and Brian Bell. 1996. "The Col- Scherer, Michael. 1984. Innountion and Growth.
lapse in Demand for the Unskilled and Unem- MA: MIT Press.
ployment across the OECD," Oxford Reu. Econ. Schiff, Ze'ev and Ehud Ya'ari. 1989. Intifada, The
Pol. 11, pp. 40-62. Palestinian Uprising-ism el'.^ Third Front. NY:
Neumark, David; Daniel Polsky and Daniel Han- Simon and Schuster.
sen. 1999. "Has Job Stability Declined Yet? Evi- Schmookler, Jacob. 1966. Invention and Econoinic
dence for the 1990s," J. Lab. Econ. 17:4, S29- Growth. MA: Harvard U. Press.
64. Schultz, Theodore. 1975. "The Value of the Ability
Nye, David E . 1990. Electrifying America: Social to Deal with Disequalibria," J. Econ. Lit. 13,
Meanings of a Neeo Technology, 1880-1940. p p 827-46.
MA: MIT Press. Thesmar, David and Mathias Thoenig. 2000. "Crea-
OECD. 1994. Jobs Study. Vols. 1 and 2. Paris and tive Destruction and Firm Organization Choice:
Washington, DC: OECD. A New Look into the Growth-Inequality Rela-
Oliner, Stephen and Daniel Sichel. 1994. "Com- tionship," Quart. J . ECOII.115:4, pp. 1209-38.
puters and Output Growth Revisited: How Big Tinbergen, Jan. 1975. Income Difference: Recent
Is the Puzzle?" Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 0 3 , Research. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
p p 273-317. Violante, Giovanni L. 2000. "Technological Accel-
Pierce, Brooks. 2001. "Compensation Inequality," eration, Skill Transferability and the Rise in Re-
forthcoming, Quart. J . Econ. sidual Inequality," Ulliversitp College London
Piketty, Thomas and Emannuel Saez. 2001. "In- mimeo.
come Inequality in the United States, 1913- Welch, Finis. 1970. "Education in Production," J .
1998," MIT and Harvard mimeo. Polit. Econ. 78, pp. 312-27.
Piore, Michael and Charles Sabel. 1984. The Sec- , 1973. "Black-\Vhite Differences in Re-
ond 1ndu.strial Divide. NY: Basic Books. turns to Schooling," Anzer. Econ. Reu. 63:5, pp.
Reynolds, Lloyd G. 1951. The Structure of Labor 893-907.
Markets; Wages and Labor Atobility in Theory Williamson, Jeffrey. 1990. Coping with City
and Practice. NY: Harper. Groeoth Dzcrin the British Indzcstrial Reuolz~-
Riddell, Craig. 1993. "Unionization in Canada and t i o n MA: Camfridge U Press.
the United States: A Tale of Two Countries," in Williamson, Jeffrey G. and Peter H . Lindert. 1980.
Sinall Differences That Matter. David Card Anzerican Ineqz~ality: A Atacroeconomic His-
and Richard Freeman, eds. IL: U. Chicago tory. NY: Academic Press.
Press. Willis, Robert and Sherwin Rosen. 1975. "Educa-
Robbins, Donald J. 1995. "Trade and Inequality in tion and Self-Selection," J . Polit. Econ. 87, pp.
Seven Developing Countries: Summary and 817-36.
Synthesis of Country Studies," Harvard, HIID Wood, Adrian. 1994. North-South Trade, Employ-
mimeo. nzent and Inequality: Changing Fortunes i i ~a
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Slcill Drioen World. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Far? Washington DC: Institute Int. Econ. Woolf, Arthur G. 1984. "Electricity, Productivity,
Romer, Paul M. 1990. "Endogenous Technological and Labor Saving: American Manufacturing
Change," J . Polit. Econ. 98:5, S71-S102. 1900-1929," Explor. Econ. Hist. 2 1 2 , pp. 176-
Rubinstein, Yonna and Dani Tsiddon. 1999. "Cop- 91.
ing with Technological Progress: The Role of Zuboff, Shohana. 1988. In the Age of the Sinart
Ability i i ~Atalcing Inequality So Per.sistent," Tel Machine, The Future of Work and Power. NY:
Aviv U. work. paper. Basic Books.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 10 -

You have printed the following article:


Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market
Daron Acemoglu
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 40, No. 1. (Mar., 2002), pp. 7-72.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28200203%2940%3A1%3C7%3ATCIATL%3E2.0.CO%3B2-P

This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an
off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please
visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.

[Footnotes]

3
Endogenous Technological Change
Paul M. Romer
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2: The Problem of Development: A
Conference of the Institute for the Study of Free Enterprise Systems. (Oct., 1990), pp. S71-S102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3CS71%3AETC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

3
Induced Bias in Innovation and the Theory of Distribution
Charles Kennedy
The Economic Journal, Vol. 74, No. 295. (Sep., 1964), pp. 541-547.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28196409%2974%3A295%3C541%3AIBIIAT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

3
Factor Prices and Technical Change in Agricultural Development: The United States and
Japan, 1880-1960
Yujiro Hayami; V. W. Ruttan
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 5. (Sep. - Oct., 1970), pp. 1115-1141.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28197009%2F10%2978%3A5%3C1115%3AFPATCI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 2 of 10 -

3
The Supply of Skilled Labour and Skill-Biased Technological Progress
Michael T. Kiley
The Economic Journal, Vol. 109, No. 458. (Oct., 1999), pp. 708-724.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28199910%29109%3A458%3C708%3ATSOSLA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-5

4
Education in Production
F. Welch
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 1. (Jan. - Feb., 1970), pp. 35-59.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28197001%2F02%2978%3A1%3C35%3AEIP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

6
Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis
Per Krusell; Lee E. Ohanian; José-Víctor Ríos-Rull; Giovanni L. Violante
Econometrica, Vol. 68, No. 5. (Sep., 2000), pp. 1029-1053.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28200009%2968%3A5%3C1029%3ACCAIAM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

6
Technological Revolutions
Francesco Caselli
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 1. (Mar., 1999), pp. 78-102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199903%2989%3A1%3C78%3ATR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

9
Black-White Differences in Returns to Schooling
Finis Welch
The American Economic Review, Vol. 63, No. 5. (Dec., 1973), pp. 893-907.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28197312%2963%3A5%3C893%3ABDIRTS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

10
Measuring Labor's Share
Alan B. Krueger
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the One Hundred
Eleventh Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1999), pp. 45-51.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199905%2989%3A2%3C45%3AMLS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Z

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 3 of 10 -

11
Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric
Approach
John DiNardo; Nicole M. Fortin; Thomas Lemieux
Econometrica, Vol. 64, No. 5. (Sep., 1996), pp. 1001-1044.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28199609%2964%3A5%3C1001%3ALMIATD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-K

24
Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis
Per Krusell; Lee E. Ohanian; José-Víctor Ríos-Rull; Giovanni L. Violante
Econometrica, Vol. 68, No. 5. (Sep., 2000), pp. 1029-1053.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28200009%2968%3A5%3C1029%3ACCAIAM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

24
Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change
Jeremy Greenwood; Zvi Hercowitz; Per Krusell
The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3. (Jun., 1997), pp. 342-362.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199706%2987%3A3%3C342%3ALIOITC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

24
Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis
Per Krusell; Lee E. Ohanian; José-Víctor Ríos-Rull; Giovanni L. Violante
Econometrica, Vol. 68, No. 5. (Sep., 2000), pp. 1029-1053.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28200009%2968%3A5%3C1029%3ACCAIAM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

25
The Determinants of Earnings: A Behavioral Approach
Samuel Bowles; Herbert Gintis; Melissa Osborne
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No. 4. (Dec., 2001), pp. 1137-1176.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28200112%2939%3A4%3C1137%3ATDOEAB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

32
Endogenous Technological Change
Paul M. Romer
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2: The Problem of Development: A
Conference of the Institute for the Study of Free Enterprise Systems. (Oct., 1990), pp. S71-S102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3CS71%3AETC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 4 of 10 -

33
Endogenous Technological Change and Wage Inequality
Huw Lloyd-Ellis
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 1. (Mar., 1999), pp. 47-77.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199903%2989%3A1%3C47%3AETCAWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-U

44
Changes in Unemployment and Wage Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Some Evidence
Daron Acemoglu
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 5. (Dec., 1999), pp. 1259-1278.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199912%2989%3A5%3C1259%3ACIUAWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N

References

Resource and Output Trends in the United States Since 1870


Moses Abramovitz
The American Economic Review, Vol. 46, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-eighth Annual
Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1956), pp. 5-23.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28195605%2946%3A2%3C5%3ARAOTIT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E

Changes in Unemployment and Wage Inequality: An Alternative Theory and Some Evidence
Daron Acemoglu
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 5. (Dec., 1999), pp. 1259-1278.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199912%2989%3A5%3C1259%3ACIUAWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N

The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training


Daron Acemoglu; Jörn-Steffen Pischke
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 3. (Jun., 1999), pp. 539-572.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199906%29107%3A3%3C539%3ATSOWAI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 5 of 10 -

On the Theory of Induced Invention


Syed Ahmad
The Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 302. (Jun., 1966), pp. 344-357.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28196606%2976%3A302%3C344%3AOTTOII%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

The Economic Returns to Schooling in the West Bank and Gaza Strip
Joshua D. Angrist
The American Economic Review, Vol. 85, No. 5. (Dec., 1995), pp. 1065-1087.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199512%2985%3A5%3C1065%3ATERTSI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-O

Technological Change and the Skill Acquisition of Young Workers


Ann P. Bartel; Nachum Sicherman
Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 16, No. 4. (Oct., 1998), pp. 718-755.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0734-306X%28199810%2916%3A4%3C718%3ATCATSA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-R

International Differences in Male Wage Inequality: Institutions versus Market Forces


Francine D. Blau; Lawrence M. Kahn
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 104, No. 4. (Aug., 1996), pp. 791-837.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199608%29104%3A4%3C791%3AIDIMWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I

Changes in the Structure of Wages in the 1980's: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations


John Bound; George Johnson
The American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 3. (Jun., 1992), pp. 371-392.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199206%2982%3A3%3C371%3ACITSOW%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

The Determinants of Earnings: A Behavioral Approach


Samuel Bowles; Herbert Gintis; Melissa Osborne
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No. 4. (Dec., 2001), pp. 1137-1176.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28200112%2939%3A4%3C1137%3ATDOEAB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 6 of 10 -

Technological Revolutions
Francesco Caselli
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 1. (Mar., 1999), pp. 78-102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199903%2989%3A1%3C78%3ATR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern Productivity
Paradox
Paul A. David
The American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and
Second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1990), pp. 355-361.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199005%2980%3A2%3C355%3ATDATCA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

Job Stability in the United States


Francis X. Diebold; David Neumark; Daniel Polsky
Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15, No. 2. (Apr., 1997), pp. 206-233.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0734-306X%28199704%2915%3A2%3C206%3AJSITUS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-4

Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973-1992: A Semiparametric


Approach
John DiNardo; Nicole M. Fortin; Thomas Lemieux
Econometrica, Vol. 64, No. 5. (Sep., 1996), pp. 1001-1044.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28199609%2964%3A5%3C1001%3ALMIATD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-K

Technical Change and Human-Capital Returns and Investments: Evidence from the Green
Revolution
Andrew D. Foster; Mark R. Rosenzweig
The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 4. (Sep., 1996), pp. 931-953.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199609%2986%3A4%3C931%3ATCAHRA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 7 of 10 -

Technological Progress, Mobility, and Economic Growth


Oded Galor; Daniel Tsiddon
The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3. (Jun., 1997), pp. 363-382.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199706%2987%3A3%3C363%3ATPMAEG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q

Inequality, Income Growth, and Mobility: The Basic Facts


Peter Gottschalk
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 2. (Spring, 1997), pp. 21-40.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0895-3309%28199721%2911%3A2%3C21%3AIIGAMT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L

Cross-National Comparisons of Earnings and Income Inequality


Peter Gottschalk; Timothy M. Smeeding
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 2. (Jun., 1997), pp. 633-687.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28199706%2935%3A2%3C633%3ACCOEAI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-G

Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change


Jeremy Greenwood; Zvi Hercowitz; Per Krusell
The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3. (Jun., 1997), pp. 342-362.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199706%2987%3A3%3C342%3ALIOITC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of Technological Change


Zvi Griliches
Econometrica, Vol. 25, No. 4. (Oct., 1957), pp. 501-522.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28195710%2925%3A4%3C501%3AHCAEIT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-A

Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach
Paul A. Grout
Econometrica, Vol. 52, No. 2. (Mar., 1984), pp. 449-460.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28198403%2952%3A2%3C449%3AIAWITA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-2

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 8 of 10 -

Factor Prices and Technical Change in Agricultural Development: The United States and
Japan, 1880-1960
Yujiro Hayami; V. W. Ruttan
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 5. (Sep. - Oct., 1970), pp. 1115-1141.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28197009%2F10%2978%3A5%3C1115%3AFPATCI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q

The Effects of Human Resource Management Practices on Productivity: A Study of Steel


Finishing Lines
Casey Ichniowski; Kathryn Shaw; Giovanna Prennushi
The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3. (Jun., 1997), pp. 291-313.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199706%2987%3A3%3C291%3ATEOHRM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

Changes in Earnings Inequality: The Role of Demand Shifts


George E. Johnson
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 2. (Spring, 1997), pp. 41-54.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0895-3309%28199721%2911%3A2%3C41%3ACIEITR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Z

Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill


Chinhui Juhn; Kevin M. Murphy; Brooks Pierce
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, No. 3. (Jun., 1993), pp. 410-442.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199306%29101%3A3%3C410%3AWIATRI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I

Induced Bias in Innovation and the Theory of Distribution


Charles Kennedy
The Economic Journal, Vol. 74, No. 295. (Sep., 1964), pp. 541-547.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28196409%2974%3A295%3C541%3AIBIIAT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

The Supply of Skilled Labour and Skill-Biased Technological Progress


Michael T. Kiley
The Economic Journal, Vol. 109, No. 458. (Oct., 1999), pp. 708-724.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28199910%29109%3A458%3C708%3ATSOSLA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-5

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 9 of 10 -

Measuring Labor's Share


Alan B. Krueger
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the One Hundred
Eleventh Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1999), pp. 45-51.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199905%2989%3A2%3C45%3AMLS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Z

Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis


Per Krusell; Lee E. Ohanian; José-Víctor Ríos-Rull; Giovanni L. Violante
Econometrica, Vol. 68, No. 5. (Sep., 2000), pp. 1029-1053.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28200009%2968%3A5%3C1029%3ACCAIAM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

Endogenous Technological Change and Wage Inequality


Huw Lloyd-Ellis
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 1. (Mar., 1999), pp. 47-77.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199903%2989%3A1%3C47%3AETCAWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-U

Endogenous Technological Change


Paul M. Romer
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2: The Problem of Development: A
Conference of the Institute for the Study of Free Enterprise Systems. (Oct., 1990), pp. S71-S102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3CS71%3AETC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequilibria


Theodore W. Schultz
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 13, No. 3. (Sep., 1975), pp. 827-846.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28197509%2913%3A3%3C827%3ATVOTAT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-F

Education in Production
F. Welch
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 1. (Jan. - Feb., 1970), pp. 35-59.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28197001%2F02%2978%3A1%3C35%3AEIP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 10 of 10 -

Black-White Differences in Returns to Schooling


Finis Welch
The American Economic Review, Vol. 63, No. 5. (Dec., 1973), pp. 893-907.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28197312%2963%3A5%3C893%3ABDIRTS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

Education and Self-Selection


Robert J. Willis; Sherwin Rosen
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87, No. 5, Part 2: Education and Income Distribution. (Oct.,
1979), pp. S7-S36.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28197910%2987%3A5%3CS7%3AEAS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.

You might also like