You are on page 1of 8

RECENT ADVANCES IN MCNETARY-POUCY RULES'"

•Y/' Interest Rates and Inflation

By FERNANDO ALVAREZ, ROBERT E . LUCAS, JR., AND WARREN E . WEBER*

A consensus has emerged among practitio- behavior of interest rates and prices. The short-
ners that the instrument of monetary policy run connections among money growth, infla-
ought to be the short-term interest rate, that tion, and interest rates are very unreliable, so
policy should be focused on the control of there is much room for improvement. These
inflation, and that inflation can be reduced by possibilities are surely worth exploring, but do-
increasing short-term interest rates. At the ing so requires new theory. The analysis needed
center of this consensus is a rejection of to reconcile interest-rate policies with the evi-
the quantity theory. Such a rejection is a dence on which the quantity theory of money
difficult step to take, given the mass of evi- is grounded cannot be found in old textbook
dence linking money growth, inflation, and diagrams.
interest rates: increases in average rates of
money growth are associated with equal in- I. An Economy with Segmented Markets
creases in average inflation rates and interest
rates. Much recent discussion of monetary policy
These observations need not rule out a con- is centered on a class of policies known as
structive role for the use of short-term interest "Taylor rules," rules that specify the interest
rates as a monetary instrument. One possibility rate set by the central bank as an increasing
is that increasing short-term rates in the face of function of the inflation rate (or perhaps of a
increases in inflation is just an indirect way of forecast of the inflation rate) (see John Tay-
reducing money growth: sell bonds and take lor, 1993). The properties of Taylor rules can
money out of the system. Another possibility is be studied within a Keynesian framework.'
that, while control of monetary aggregates is the Here we examine the properties of Taylor
key to low long-run average inflation rates, an rules using a neoclassical framework that is
interest-rate policy can improve the short-run also consistent with the quantity theory of
money and the body of evidence that confirms
this theory. An essential assumption in this
* Discussants: Lars Svensson, Institute for International
inquiry is that markets are incomplete, or
Economic Studies, Sweden; James Stock, Harvard Univer- segmented, in a way that is consistent with the
sity; John Williams, Federal Reserve Board. existence of a liquidity effect: a downward-
• Alvarez: Department of Economics, University of Chi-
sloping demand for nominal bonds. The
cago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, Univer- segmented-market model we use is adapted
sidad Torcuato di Telia (Argentina), and NBER; Lucas: from Alvarez et al. (2001), where references
Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 to earlier work on these models can be
East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, and Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis; Weber: Research Department, Fed-
found.
eral Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, P.O. Box 291, Minne- The model we develop is an exchange econ-
apolis, MN 55480-0291. We thank Lars Svensson for his omy: There is no Phillips curve and no effect of
discussion, Nurlan Turdaliev for his assistance, and seminar monetary-policy changes on production.^
participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis for
their comments and suggestions. Alvarez thanks the Na-
tional Science Foundation and the Alfred P. Sloan Founda-
tion for support. The views expressed herein are those of the ' See Richard Clarida et al. (1999) for a helpful review.
authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve ^ Segmented market models that have such effects in-
Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. clude contributions by Lawrence Christiano and Martin

219
220 kEk PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2001

Think, then, of an exchange economy with the sum of cash brought into goods trading by
many agents, all with the preferences the household and a variable fraction v, of
current-period sales receipts. Think of the
shopper as visiting the seller's store at some
1
U(c,) time during the trading day, emptying the
cash register, and returning to shop some
more.
Thus, every non-trader carries his unspent re-
where
ceipts fromperiod-(f - 1) sales, (1 - v,_ |)P,_ j ,
into period-? trading. He adds to these balances
v,P,y from period-? sales, giving him a total of
(1 - v,_i)P,_^y + v,P,y to spend on goods
in period t. In order to keep the determination of
over sequences {c,} of a single, non-storable the price level as simple as possible, we assume
consumption good. All of these agents attend a that every household spends all of its cash,
goods market every period, A fraction A of every period,^ Then every non-trader spends
agents also attend a bond market. We call these
agents "traders," The remaining 1 - A agents
(we call them "non-traders") never attend the (2)
bond market. We assume that no one ever
changes status between being a trader and a
non-trader. in period t.
Agents of both types have the same con- Traders, who attend both bond and goods
stant endowment of y units of the consump- markets, have more options. Like the non-
tion good. The economy's resource constraint traders, each trader has available the amount on
is thus the right of (2) to spend on goods in period t,
but each trader also absorbs his share of the
increase in the per capita money supply that
(1)
occurs in the open-market operation in f, If the
per capita increase in money is M, - M,_ , =
where cJ and cf* are the consumptions of the jLt,M, _ I, then each trader leaves the date-f bond
two agent types. We ensure that money is market with an additional /LI,M,_|/A dollars,''
held in equilibrium by assuming that no one
consumes his own endowment. Each house-
hold consists of a shopper-seller pair, where
the seller sells the household's endowment ' After solving for equilibrium prices and quantities un-
for cash in the goods market, while the shop- der the assumption that cash constraints always bind, one
per uses cash to buy the consumption good can go back to individual maximum problems to find the set
from others in the same market. Prior to the of parameter values under which this provisional assump-
tion will hold (see Alvarez et al,, 2001 appendix A),
opening of this goods market, money and '' If B, is the value of bonds maturing at date t and if 7",
one-period government bonds are traded in is the value of lump-sum tax receipts at (, the market-
another market, attended only by traders. clearing condition for this bond market becomes
Purchases are subject to a cash-in-advance
1
constraint, modified to incorporate shocks to
1 +r,
velocity. Assume, to be specific, that goods
purchases P,c, are constrained to be less than We assume that all taxes are paid by the traders, so
Ricardian equivalence will apply, and the timing of taxes
will be immaterial. These taxes play no role in our discus-
sion, except to give us a second way to change the money
Eichenbaum (1992) and Charles T, Carlstrom and Timothy supply besides open-market operations. With this flexibility,
S, Fuerst (1995), Our simpler model permits a discussion of any monetary policy can be made consistent with the real
inflation, but not of all of inflation's possible consequences. debt remaining bounded. The arithmetic that follows will be
VOL 91 NO, 2 RECENT ADVANCES IN MONETARY-POUCY RULES 221

Consumption spending per trader is thus given essentials of the model, but at the cost of
by complicating the solution method. In the ver-
sion we study here, the two cash-flow equa-
tions (2) and (3) describe the way the fixed
(3) endowment is distributed to the two consumer
types. The three equations (l)-(3) thus com-
pletely determine the equilibrium resource al-
location and the behavior of the price level.
Now, using the cash flow equations (2) and No maximum problem has been studied, and no
(3) and the market-clearing condition (1) we derivatives have been taken!
obtain To study the related behavior of interest
rates, however, we need to examine bond-
market equilibrium, and there the real interest
P,y= (1 - w,_,)/',_,}'
rate will depend on the current and expected
future consumption of the traders only. Solv-
ing (1), (2), and (4), we derive the formula
for cJ:

since M , _ , = (1 - v,_^)P,_^y is total


dollars carried forward from t — \. Thus, a cl = y = c{v,,
version

1 where the second equality defines the relative


(4) M, = P,y consumption function c(v,, fx,). Then the equi-
1 -
librium nominal interest rate must satisfy the
familiar marginal condition.
of the equation of exchange must hold in equi-
librium, and the fraction v, can be interpreted
(approximately) as the log of velocity.
(5)
Introducing shocks to velocity captures the 1 + r, \ 1+ p
short-run instability in the empirical relation-
ship between money and prices. In addition, it
allows us to study the way interest rates react
X E,
to news about inflation for different specifi-
cations of monetary policy. In the formulation
of the segmented-markets model that we use
here, there are no possibilities for substituting
X
against cash, so the interest rate does not 1 -
appear in the money demand function [in (4)],
and velocity is simply given. Given the be-
havior of the money supply, then prices are where £,(•) means an expectation conditional
entirely determined by (4), This is the quan- on events dated t and earlier.
tity theory of money in its very simplest We use two approximations to simplify equa-
form. tion (5), The first involves expanding the func-
The exogeneity of velocity in the model is, tion log[c(w,, /J,,)] around the point {v, 0) to
of course, easily relaxed without altering the obtain the first-order approximation

1 - A
both monetarist and pleasant in the sense of Thomas J,
Sargent and Neil Wallace (1985),
222 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2001

(Note that the first-order effect of velocity ior of money growth, inflation, and interest
changes on consumption is zero.) With the rates, with a potential role for interest rates as
constant-relative-risk-aversion (CRRA) prefer- an instrument of inflation control in the short
ences we have assumed, the marginal utility of run. We explore this potential in the next
traders is then approximated by section.

U'{c{v,, ii,)y) =
n. Inflation Control with Segmented Markets
where
In this section, we work through a series of
1- A thought experiments based on the equilibrium
condition (6) that illuminate various aspects of
monetary policy. These examples all draw on
the fact, obtained by differencing the equation
Taking logs of both sides of (5), we have of exchange (4), that the inflation rate is the sum
of the money growth rate and the rate of change
in velocity:
r,= p- log E,\ exp{-4)(/i,,.,, - fi,)
(7)
X
Example 1 (Constant Velocity and Money
Growth): Let v, be constant at v, and let /x, be
We apply a second approximation to the right- constant at /x. Then (6) becomes
hand side to obtain

(6)

- V,
We can view this equation interchangeably as
fixing money growth, given the interest rate, or
as fixing the interest rate given money growth
where p - p > 0 is a risk correction factor.^ and inflation. This Fisher equation must always
From equation (6) one can see that the characterize long-run average money growth,
immediate effect of an open-market-operation inflation, and interest rates.
bond purchase, /x, > 0, is to reduce interest
rates by e^ju,,. This is the liquidity effect that
the segmented-market models are designed to Example 2 (Constant Money Growth and i.i.d.
capture. If we drop the segmentation and let Shocks): Let the velocity shocks be indepen-
everyone trade in bonds, then A = 1, <|) = 0, dently and identically distributed (i.i.d.) random
and the liquidity effect vanishes. In this case, variables, with mean v and variance o^. Let ju,,
open-market operations can only affect inter- be constant at ^l. Under these conditions, (6)
est rates through information effects on the implies
inflation premium. Interest-rate increases can
only reflect expected inflation: monetary ease. r, = p + ju, - (w, - v).
With <^ > 0, the model combines quantity-
theoretic predictions for the long-run behav-
A transient increase in velocity raises the cur-
rent price level, reducing expected inflation.
' The risk correction p - p depends on conditional vari- This induces a transient decrease in interest
ances, which are constant in the following applications. rates. In this example, r, is i.i.d., with mean p +
VOL 91 NO. 2 RECENT ADVANCES IN MONETARY-POUCY RULES 223

jju and variance cr^; the inflation rate has mean somewhere, either in interest rates, money-
and variance 2(7?,. growth rates, or inflation rates. The way it
is distributed over these three variables
can, in the presence of a liquidity effect, be
Example 3 (Exact Inflation-Targeting): It is al- determined by policy. However this is done,
ways possible to attain a target inflation rate 77 the long-run connections between money
exactly. Just set the money growth rate accord- growth, inflation, and interest rates are en-
ing to tirely quantity-theoretic.
Our next two examples consider versions of
/Ll, = T7 - W, -I- W,_i. Taylor rules. Suppose, to be specific, that inter-
est rates are set according to the formula
Then interest rates will be given by
(8) r, = p + 7T + 0(T7, - TT)
r, = p+ (t,(-E,[v,^,] + 2v,- v,.^) + n.

If the velocity shocks are i.i.d., as in Example 2, where d> 0 means that if the current inflation
then Var(ju,,) = 2o-^, and r, has mean p + TT rate IT, is to exceed the target rate 77, we raise
and variance 5(/)^a^. this period's interest rate above its target
level, p + ir. To study the dynamics implied
by the rule (8), we eliminate r, and TT, be-
Example 4 (An Interest-Rate Peg): Assume tween (6), (7), and (8) to obtain the difference
i.i.d. V,, with mean v and variance a^. Let /x, equation
satisfy
/x, — /x = B(w, ~ u)
(9)
where the constant B is chosen to make r,
constant at p + /x. Then (6) implies
- V,

p -t- /x = p - B(l){v, - v ) + iJL-iv,- v).

If this equality holds for all realizations of v,, it


follows that B = -\/<f).ln this case, Var(jix,) = We can solve this difference equation "forward"
(crJ4>f'- Using (7), the variance of the inflation to get
rate is,

ai = Var(/x,.^, + w,^.i - w,)


(10)
, 21

= 1+
where
Comparing this case to Example 2, one sees that
pegging the interest rate is inflation-stabilizing,
relative to constant money growth, if and only if
M
(\> > V2.
In Examples 2, 3, and 4, the economy is
subjected to unavoidable velocity shocks. The
variability of these shocks must show up provided that the series on the right-hand side of
224 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2001

(10) converges.^ We now use (10) to study two Example 6 (A Taylor Rule with Random-Walk
more examples. Velocity): Assume that the changes, v, —
v,_^, in velocity are i.i.d. random variables
with mean 0 and variance o^. Then, for any t,
Example 5 (A Taylor Rule with i.i.d. Velocity): calculating the terms E,[s, + iJ and substituting
Let V, be i.i.d., with mean v and variance cr^. (10) yields
Inserting the corresponding values of E,[s,+j]
into (10) gives
- 77 =
e (u, - r;,_,
-\-

(11) -v)
(0
Again, the interest-rate consequences can be
calculated from the Taylor rule, (8):
,_I - v).

(13) r, = p+
The interest-rate consequences of these open- 6 +
market operations can then be calculated from
the Taylor rule, (8): As in the case of i.i.d. shocks in Example 5, (13)
implies that open-market bond sales in response
to a velocity increase will increase interest rates
(12) only if (f) > 0.

X {26-^ (j) - l)iv, - v)


Example 7 (A Change in the Infiation Target):
Holding the distribution of velocity shocks
iv,-i - v). fixed, suppose that the inflation target is
6 +
moved permanently from TT to rr. This re-
targeting changes nothing on the right-hand
The money-supply response to a temporary in- side of (10), so (10) implies simply an imme-
crease in velocity, described in (11), is to reduce diate, permanent change in the money-growth
money growth initially, increase it in the next rate from TT to TT. Of course, this implies an
period, and return to the target growth rate immediate, permanent change in the interest
thereafter. This will smooth the inflationary im- rate of TT - TT. Neither the size (j) of the
pact of the velocity increase, whether or not liquidity effect nor the responsiveness 6 of
there is a positive liquidity effect (f). If <f) > 0 the Taylor rule has any bearing on these
and 20 + </) > 1, (12) implies that these open- changes.
market operations will raise the interest rate
initially in response to a velocity increase, then
reduce it below the target, and then return it to III. Conclusions
p -\- TT.
Using a model of segmented markets, we
have shown that a policy of increasing short-
term interest rates to reduce inflation can
be rationalized with essentially quantity-
*• If 9 > 1, the right-hand side of (10) is the only solution theoretic models of monetary equilibrium. In
to (9) with bounded expected values. This case is referred to the model we used to generate all of our
as an "active" Taylor rule. If 0 < 1 (a "passive" Taylor rule)
and the series in (10) converges, (10) gives one solution to specific examples, production is a given con-
(9), but there will be others (which we do not examine here) stant, velocity is an exogenous random shock,
as well. and the equation of exchange determines the
VOL. 91 NO. 2 RECENT ADVANCES IN MONETARY-POUCY RULES 225

equilibrium price level, given the money sup- To rationalize the use of any of the interest-
ply. In this theory of inflation, consistent with rate rules we have examined, it would be
much of the evidence, interest rates play no necessary to use an objective function that
role whatsoever. assigns weight to some other objective be-
To this simple model we have added seg- sides the attainment of an inflation target. We
mented markets. With this added feature, we have in fact considered variations on the
can describe a monetary policy action inter- model presented here in which relative en-
changeably as a change in the money supply dowments of agents fluctuate, giving rise to
or as a change in interest rates. In this context, gains from pooling endowment risk. In the
we considered a series of examples under absence of a monetary-policy design to offset
different assumptions on the behavior of ve- these shocks, they will increase interest-rate
locity shocks and on the specification of a variability. In a model with segmented mar-
policy rule. kets where such pooling cannot take place,
In the first two stochastic examples. Exam- there can be real gains from policies that
ples 2 and 3, a policy at any date is set in smooth real interest rates. We leave the anal-
advance of the realization of the velocity ysis of this question, the issue of what the
shock in that period: One can commit to a founders of the Federal Reserve System
given rate of money growth, leaving interest called an "elastic currency," to another paper.
rates free to vary with the velocity shock
(Example 2), or one can commit to an interest REFERENCES
rate, leaving money growth to be adjusted
later to maintain this rate (Example 3). Nei- Alvarez, Fernando; Atkeson, Andrew, and Kehoe,
ther policy can reduce the variance of infla- Patrick. "Money, Interest Rates, and Ex-
tion to zero. The larger is the liquidity effect, change Rates with Endogenously Segmented
the higher is the relative effectiveness of the Asset Markets." Journal of Political Econ-
interest-rate rule in stabilizing inflation rates omy, 2001 (forthcoming).
about a target rate. Carlstrom, Charles T. and Fuerst, Timothy S.
In the remaining examples we consider, pol- "Interest Rate Rules vs. Money Growth
icy (however specified) is permitted to respond Rules: A Welfare Comparison in a Cash-in-
to contemporaneous velocity shocks. In Exam- Advance Economy." Journal of Monetary
ple 4, we show that under this assumption an Economics, November 1995, 36(2), pp. 246-
inflation target can be hit exactly by a money- 67.
supply rule that is conditioned on the shock, and Christiano, Lawrence J. and Eichenbaum, Mar-
that this is true whatever is the shock process. In tin. "Liquidity Effects and the Monetary
our context, inflation-targeting cannot be done Transmission Mechanism." American Eco-
any better than this. nomic Review, May 1992 (Papers and Pro-
The remaining examples in the paper con- ceedings), 82(2), pp. 346-53.
sider Taylor rules: policies in which the in- Clarida, Richard; Gall, Jordi and Gertler, Mark.
terest rate is set so as to deviate from its "The Science of Monetary Policy: A New
long-run (Fisherian) target in proportion to Keynesian Perspective." Journal of Eco-
the deviation of the inflation rate from its nomic Literature, December 1999, 37(4), pp.
target. Such rules use the same information as 1661-1707.
the rule in Example 4 that attains the inflation Sargent, Thomas J. and Wallace, Neil. "Some
target perfectly. From the viewpoint of Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic." Fed-
inflation-targeting, then, committing to a Tay- eral Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quar-
lor rule amounts to tying the hands of the terly Review, Winter 1985, 9(1), pp.
monetary authority in a way that can only 15-31.
limit its effectiveness. As our examples illus- Taylor, John B. "Discretion versus Policy Rules
trate, the importance of this limitation varies in Practice." Carnegie-Rochester Conference
with assumptions on the time-series character Series on Public Policy, December 1993,
of the velocity shocks. 39(0), pp. 195-214.

You might also like