You are on page 1of 27

Multinational Enterprises

and the Global Economy,


Second Edition

John H. Dunning
Emeritus Esmee Fairbairn Professor of International lnvestment and
Business Studies, University of Reading, UK and Emeritus State of New
Jersey Professor of International Business, Rutgers, The State University
of New Jersey, Newark, USA

Sarianna M. Lundan
Associate Professor of International Business Strategy, Maastricht
University, The Netherlands and Associate Research Fellow, ETLA, the
Research Institute of the Finnish Economy, Helsinki, Finland

Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
62 Facts, theory and history

At the same time, the past 20 years has also seen the emergence of significan! numbers
of MNEs from developing countries in which, generally speaking, the state tends to play
a more dominan! role. This is the case with China, where even after sorne efforts at pri-
vatisation, the state is thought to exercise considerable influence, either directly of indi-
rectly, over the majority of large enterprises. It is also the case with a number of countries
such as Singapore, Brazil, India and Argentina, for example, where the state has taken on
3. The motives for foreign production
an active developmental role.
Finally, following a recen! wave of re-nationalisations reminiscent of the l 970s, state 3.1 INTRODUCTION
ownership of MNEs in the petroleum and mining sectors continues to be substantial. This ···
is particularly notable in the petroleum sector, where 15 of the top 25 companies in 2003 The following three chapters consider the motivations for, and the determinants of, the
ranked by reserves and production, were SOEs from developing countries and Russia, foreign value-added activities by MNEs. The present chapter describes sorne of the reasons
while three others had minority state ownership (UNCTAD, 2007). prompting firms to undertake FDI, and distinguishes between four main types of produc-
tíon 76 financed by such investment. Chapter 4 describes and evaluates sorne of the theories
and paradigms that have been put forward over the past 40 years to explain the existence
and growth of MNEs, and of their foreign activities. Chapter 5 discusses the evolution of
the eclectic or OLI paradigm, and presents an extension of this framework that incorpo-
rates the role of formal and informal institutions in the analysis of MNE activity.

3.2 WHY DO FIRMS WISH TO ENGAGE IN FOREIGN


PRODUCTION?
Chapter 2 has shown that the great majority of MNE activity is undertaken by private
business enterprises from market economies. This suggests that, like their domestic coun-
terparts, MNEs are motivated primarily by what they perceive to be in the interests of
their direct stakeholders, rathe.r than that of the wider community of which they are part.
These stakeholders include employees, managers and shareholders, 77 all of whom must
be recompensed for their contributions to the production process by an amount at least
equal to the opportunity cost of the resources and capabilities they provide (that is, the
highest return they could earn for their resources and capabilities if they were deployed
differently). Most of the literature in the tradition of neoclassical economics asserts that
any residual of income earned by a firm over and above the opportunity cost of the stake-
holders will accrue to the owners of the business in the form of profits, and that it is the
maximisation of these profits (net of tax and depreciation) in relation to the capital
invested, which is the driving force of the modern business enterprise. This may be
expressed in the following equation. Maximise:

II
TR-TC (3.1)
K

where II is the rate of return, TR is the total sales revenue, TC is the total cost of pro-
duction and K is the owner's capital invested.
A modification of the above formula, which takes account of the fact that the value of
a firm's earnings will vary according to when they are earned, is set out below. Assuming
that overa three-year period a firm will aim to maximise its total income, including that

63
64 Facts, the(ny and history T/1e motive:1·for,foreign production 65

which is derived from reinvesting the profits earned in the first two years, 78 the appropri- stakeholders can earn above the opportunity cost of their capital, they have the freedom
ate formula then becomes as follows. Maximise: to pursue other objectives. These range from maxiinising the sales of the company or
increasing its market share, to driving competitors out of business, undertaking risky
(3.2) investments which otherwise would not have been made and advancing the welfare of the
other stakeholders. Alternatively, behaviourists snch as Simon (1959) and Cyert and
where r is the maximum income a firm can earn through reinvesting profits earned in years March (1963) argued that because of the difficulty of identifying the appropriate condi-
1 and 2. Each of these two formulae assume that the value of the owner's investment stake tions for profit maxitnisation and to avoid attracting new competition or unwelcome gov-
does not change independently of the profits earned. However, once one allows for this ernroent attention, firms will be content to earn 'satisfactory', rather than 'maximum'
possibility (perhaps as a result of an appreciation or depreciation of property values, or · profits. Evolutionary economists (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Nelson, 2005) take a similar
changes in future earning capacity of the firm), it may be more appropriate to think of · stance, arguing that bounded rationality and constan! change in the range of options
the goal of the owners of afirmas maximising the value of their equity stake overa given open to firms makes it difficult to identify a .theoretical optima! performance. More
period of time. Equation (3.2) would then need to be modified as follows. Maximise: recently, increasing attention has been focused on the extent to which the various stake-
holders of the firmare able to, and in fact do, influence its objectives, and the means by
(3.3) which these may be achieved. Inter alia, the emergence of ethical investment, environ-
mental sensitivity and security-related issues are requiring firms to modify their incentive
where structures and enforcement mechanisms.
Each of the above theories suggests that, if they should so desire, the owners of a firm
may trade off part or ali of surplus profits against other goals. At the same time, depend-
ing on their bargaining power, the other stakeholders (for example, the employees and
Alternatively, it is possible to conceive of the firm as a collection of assets, the value of consumers) might be able to appropriate par! of these profits for themselves (Dunning
which its owners wish to increase as much as possible over a given period of time. The and Stilwell, 1978). lncreasingly the performance of firms - including MNEs - is being
formula to achieve the objectives of the wealth-maximising firms, as set out in most micro- judged by multiple criteria. so
economic textbooks, assuming a three-year time period, is as follows. Maximise: At a national leve!, and in corporate governance terms, economies can be broadly
classified in to 'coordinated' and 'liberal market' economies (Hall and Soskice, 2001 ).
Germany and Ja pan are primáry among the coordinated economies, although the group also
(3.4)
includes the Scandinavian countries, the Netherlands, Belgium, Austria and Switzerland.
Coordinated economies typically feature firms with high debt/equity ratios, cross-ownership
where NPVis the net present value of the expected income of a firm at time t 3, Yis the of banks and industrial enterprises and interlocking directorates, and are generally sympa-
net expected income of the firm in time 1, 2 and 3, and r is the opportunity cost of K thetic to the goals of stakeholder capitalism. By contras!, liberal market economies are
invested to earn that income. typified by the US, but also include Canada, the UK, Ireland, Australia and New Zealand.
The fact that an enterprise produces outside its national boundaries is not generally These countries feature widespread share ownership, an active market far corporate control,
thought to affect the objectives of the owners of equity capital, except perhaps in the case flexible labour markets with the right to hire and fire, and education systems geared towards
of publicly owned or state-controlled companies. However, as with any multi-activity or mobility. While it is not clear whether, in the long run, these differences result in differences
multi-plant company, it may open up the possibility of a conflict of interests not only in corporate performance, in the short run it is clear that corporate behaviour is affected by
between the various groups of stakeholders, but also between the same group of stake- who owns the company, and who influences its institutions and behaviour. 81
holders (for example, shareholders, management, labour, consumers) in one country and Publicly owned firms may operate under additional requirements, particularly in the
that in another. As Chapter 8 will suggest, the interests of the management and employ- domestic market. Similarly, private firms whose ownership is diverse, may nonetheless be
ees of an affiliate of an MNE will not necessarily coincide with those of the paren! infiuenced by large institutional investors such as pension funds, investing on behalf
company. Conflicts may arise not only about the distribution of surplus profits, but also of their members. By contras!, closely held private firms, where large parts of equity are
on decisions about the capital and institutional structure of the affiliate, the sharing of held by family members, may be able to pursue more independent strategies than more
risks and responsibilities, the pricing of intra-firm transactions, the sourcing of inputs, diversely held private firms. Indeed, in a study of 27 countries, La Porta et al. (1999a)
the kind of markets served, the timing of income flows and the amount of production found that the widely held firm was the exception rather than the rule. In a number of
undertaken by the affiliate. countries, governments and wealthy individuals hold substantial blocks of shares in large
Post neoclassical theories of the firm assert that where output is supplied in other than firms, leaving considerable seo pe for differences in corporate objectives. 82
perfectly competitive market conditions, the owners of enterprises need not necessarily The introduction of risk and uncertainty into factor or product markets adds a further
be constrained to maximising the rate of return on their capital. Wherever the equity 79 complication in evaluating the motivation of firms. Is a capital project with a 75% chance
66 Facts, theory and history Tf?e motives jOr foreign production 67

of a 15% return being earned anda 25% chance of 12% being earned likely to interest a (In Parts III and IV we shall consider other goals more explicitly.) However, it is impor-
firm more or less than an investment with a 100% chance of a return of 13.5%? tan! to note that long-term profitability is likely to be served by a combination of asset-
Economists can give no hard and fast answers without knowing the preference functions exploiting and asset-seeking investment. Furthermore, it is made up of two components.
of the owners of the firm. In the above example, much will depend on the decision maker's First, there is the profitability of the foreign affiliate itself. Secoud, the effect that foreign
attitude to risk taking. Such an attitude is likely to vary between owners, and the goals production has on the profitability of the rest of the investing organisation. This latter
and influence of the other stakeholders. This makes it difficult to give it an objective value, effect might be positive, where, for example, FDI leads toan increase in the competitive-
except in so far as it may be associated with certain (measurable) attributes of decision ness, or lowering of the costs of, the global activities of the MNE. Alternatively, it might
makers. Moreover, when it is impossible to calculate the risk, then one's judgement of the be negative where, for example, it replaces the production of another foreign affiliate.
nature of that risk may itself vary. Equation (3.1) may then be reinterpreted as follows. Maximise:
Later chapters will describe the various ways in which MNEs can and do evaluate risk
and uncertainty, influence or react to the demands and pressures of their stackehold<'rs (TR1 + !:>.TR,) - (TC1 + !:>.TC,.)
(3.5)
and to those of the wider community. We shall see that much depends on the kinds of K1 +t>.K,.
risk and uncertainty under consideration. While an increase in sorne risks, such as the
possibility of expropriation of a firm's foreign assets, is likely to reduce FDI, an increase where fp are the profits as a result of MNE activity,f indicates the foreign affiliate and r
in others, for example, acts of terrorism, or undue pressure from NGOs, the unreliabil- is the other producing units of MNE. Equations (3.2)-(3.5) may be similarly reinter-
ity of foreign-owned suppliers or the inefficiency of independent foreign sales agents, preted. Thus maximising the NPV of the MNE by engaging in FDI makes it necessary to
may increase it. consider the effect of FDI on both the NPV of the foreign affiliate and the rest of the
Formal models, such as real option models which assign a value to flexibility under MNE's operations.
uncertainty, can be used to analyse certain kinds of sequential investment, where the In practice, MNEs operate in an environment in which both intermediate and final
investor makes a small initial investment but acquires rights to expand the investment product markets are imperfect, where institutions are often second (or third) best, where
project as further information becomes available. The real options framework has been cross-border learning is an integral part of a firm's dynamic competitiveness, and where
found useful to explain many FDT-related decisions, such as those to do with the acquisi- the outcome of business decisions is uncertain. This being so, it is even more difficult to
tion of drilling or mining rights (Damodaran, 2000), the setting up of joint ventures generalise about the strategic behaviour of such firms than about that of their domestic
(Kogut, 1991), and the optima! investment in core capabilities (Kogut and Kulatilaka, equivalents. This is partly because of the greater range of options open to MNEs; partly
2001 ). However, if no usable proxy for the activity exists in the market, estimating the risk because of the differences in perception of decision makers in the MNEs towards these
(volatility) of the investment, and consequently calculating the real option value, becomes options; and partly because of differences in altitudes towards incentive structures and
difficult. A further complication of real option models is that, since the option value is risk taking. Thus, sorne firms may place a higher value on the risk-spreading opportun-
always positive, this line of reasoning has a bias towards decisions that favour waiting ities or the cultural sensitivities of FDI than others; while MNEs that compete in oligop-
instead of investment now, since it is always possible that with new information, a better olistic markets may gauge the value of their foreign activities as much by their anticipated
decision can be reached. This logic of wait-and-see <loes not always fil well with the oli- repercussions on their competitors' market position as on any profits that the affiliate may
gopolistic competition prevailing in the markets in which the larger and more powerful earn. This suggests that sorne firms may produce outside their national boundaries as part
MNEs operate. of a coherent and coordinated global asset-exploiting and-seeking competitive strategy,
It is further worth observing tl1at 1nost economic and behavioural explanations of inter- rather than to earn profits on a specific FDI. This is, however, more likely to be the case
national (or foreign) 83 production do not explicitly specify the motivation of firms engag- with experienced and globally integrated MNEs rather than with smaller firms under-
ing in that production, but only the variables likely to determine their behaviour. Moreover, taking their first foreign venture.
most explanations are concerned with explaining what firms actually do rather than what With these introductory points in mind, we now turn to examine the main kinds of
they should do. In other words, rather than hypothesising that a fall in real wages in foreign production that firms undertake.
Thailand will increase FDI in Thailand because it will increase profits, most theories
FDI first attempt to establish whether labour costs are an importan! factor in influencing
profits, and hence investment, and if they are, what is the nature of the relationship. A few 3.3 THE MAIN TYPES OF FOREIGN PRODUCTION
analysts 84 have used a composite variable, for example, sorne measure of profitability,
growth of sales or market share, to explain the industrial or geographical distribution of Broadly speaking, we might identify four types of MNE activity. Borrowing and extend-
FDI, but most have chosen to identify the variables that may be expected to influence these ing from an earlier taxonomy used by Jack Behrman (1972) they are:
objectives. 85
In this volume, we shall assume that, for the most par!, the principal objective of private 1. natural resource seekers;
enterprises in undertaking foreign production is to advance their long-term profitability. 2. market seekers;
68 Facts, theory and history Tlfe n7otives.forj'oreign production 69

3. efficiency seekers; and Mexico, Taiwan and Malaysia. Within Europe there has been sorne labour-seeking invest-
4. strategic asset or capability seekers. roent in Southern, Central and Eastern European couhtries. However, as labour costs have
isen, investment has shifted to other countries, such as China, Vietnam, Turkey, Morocco
The characteristics of each are set out in the following subsections. It is, however, worth :nd Mauritius. Frequently, in order to attract such production, host countries have set up
noting that in the early 2000s many of the larger MNEs are pursuing multiple objectives, and · · free trade or export processing zones (EPZs). The most recen! example of the export of
most engage in FDI that combines the characteristics of two or more of the above categories: • labour-intensive services which is directly the result of advances in communications tech-
Moreover, each type of MNE activity may be aggressive in the sense that the investing . nology is the widespread establishment of call .centres in India and other developing coun-
company is seeking to take proactive action to advance its strategic ohjectives, or defensive tries. 86 Home countries have sometimes allowed their own MNEs tariff concessions on
in the sense that its behaviour is in reaction to actions taken (or perceived likely to be taken): products imported from their foreign subsidiaries. The economic implications of this kind
by its competitors or by foreign govemments, which require it to protect its market position. •· of MNE activity are explored in sorne detail in Chapters 13 and 17.
The motives for foreign production may also change as, for example, when a firm .. The third type of resource-seeking FDI is pr.ompted by the need of firms to acquire
becomes an established and experienced foreign investor. Initially, most enterprises invest technological capability, management or marketing expertise and organisational skills.
outside their home countries to acquire natural resources or gain (or retain) access to new :, Examples include collaborative alliances concluded by Korean, Taiwanese and Indian
markets. As they increase their degree of multinationality, however, they may use their companies with EU or US firms in high-technology sectors; executive search subsidiaries
foreign activities as a means by which they can improve their global market position by set up by US firms in the UK; and R&D listening posts established by UK chemical com-
raising their efficiency or accessing new sources of competitive advantage. panies in Japan and French pharmaceutical companies in the US. Each of these value-
added activities parallels the investment made, for example, by Belgian MNEs in Africa
3.3.1 The Natural Resource Seekers or Japanese MNEs in Australia and South-East Asia in the natural resources in which
their home countries are deficient.
These enterprises are prompted to invest abroad to acquire particular and specific resources As Chapter 6 will show, much of the FDI by European, US and Japanese firms in the
of a higher quality at a lower real cost than could be obtained in their home country (if, J9th century was prompted by the need to secure an economic and reliable source of min-
indeed, they are obtainable at all). The motivation for the FDI is to make the investing erals, primary products for the (then) investing industrialising nations of Europe and
enterprise more profitable and competitive in the markets it serves (or intends to serve) than North Arnerica. Indeed, up to the eve of the Second World War, about three-fifths of the
it would otherwise be. Most, or all, of the output of the affiliates of resource seekers tends accumulated foreign direct capital stake was of this kind. By 1990, the prirnary sector
to be exported, mainly, although not exclusively, to developed industrialised countries. accounted for only a tenth of the inward FDI stock, about 15% of which was in devel-
There are three rnain types of resource seekers. First, there are those seeking physical oping countries. However, by 2004, the share of developing countries as host to this type
resources of one kind or another. They include primary producers and manufacturing of FDI had again increased dramatically, to a third of the total capital stake in the
enterprises, from both developed and developing countries, who are driven to engage in primary sector, boosted in part by resource-seeking investment from emerging economies
FDI by the motives of cost minimisation and security of supply sources. The resources such as China and India (UNCTAD, 2006:161, 266).
they seek include mineral fuels, industrial minerals, metals and agricultura! products, but The rising importance of other kinds of investment coupled with the voluntary or
especially those whose production requires the kind of complementary capabilities and involuntary indigenisation of many primary sectors (for exarnple, oil, rubber, tin, copper
markets that MNEs are especially well equipped to provide. Chapter 2 has suggested that and so on) previously dorninated by MNEs, is largely responsible for this development.
these include fossil fuels such as oil, coa! and gas, metals such as copper, tin, zinc and Furthermore, the declining role of unskilled or semi-skilled labour in the value-added
diamonds; and agricultura! products, such as rubber, tobacco, sugar, bananas, pineapples, process of severa] rnanufacturing activities has reduced the incentives for MNEs to seek
palm oil, coffee and tea. In recent years, resource-seeking investment of this type by Chinese out cheap supplies of labour. On the other hand, there is an increasing tendency of both
and Indian investors has been particularly notable in Africa. Sorne FDI in service activi- service and manufacturing MNEs to decentralise sorne of their routine service activities
ties is also intended to exploit location-bound resources. Examples include tourism, car to low labour cost locations, while FDI to gain access to technology, information and spe-
rentals, oil drilling, construction, medica! and educational services. One feature of this·-:~ cialised management skills is more importan! than it used to be. N ot only are MNEs from
first kind of resource-intensive MNE activity is that it usually involves significan! capital emerging economies investing in the industrial nations to gain access to knowledge, there
expenditure. Moreover, once the investment has been made, it is relatively location is increasing evidence of foreign investors in industrialised countries diversifying their
The second group of resource-seeking MNEs comprise those seeking plentiful supplies R&D activities (UNCTAD, 2005c, 2006).
of cheap and well-motivated unskilled or serni-skilled labour. This kind of FDI is usually
undertaken by manufacturing and service MNEs from countries with high real labour 3.3.2 The Market Seekers
costs, which set up or acquire subsidiaries in countries with lower real labour costs, to
supply labour-intensive intermediate or final products for export. Most of this type of These are enterprises that invest in a particular country or region to supply goods or ser-
MNE activity has been in the more advanced industrialising developing countries such as vices to markets in these or in adjacent countries. In most cases, part or all of these
70 Facts~ theory and history The motivesfiJr foreign production 71

markets will have been serviced previously by exports from the investing company which, The fourth, and increasingly importan!, reason for market-seeking investment is
either because of tariff or other cost-raising barriers imposed by host countries, or that an MNE may consider it necessary, as part of its global production and marketing
because the size of the markets now justifies local production, are no longer best supplied trategy, to have a physical presence in the leading markets served by its competitors.
by this route. Sometimes, however, an enterprise may seek to replace its exports to a ~hus, most of the larger MNEs in sectors dominated by .international oligopolists
foreign market by investing in a third country and exporting to that market from there.87 (for example, oil, rubber tyres, autos,,pharmaceul!cals, sennconductors, accountancy
One scholar (Nicholas, 1986) found that no less than 94% of the UK MNEs with foreign and advertising) not only have operatmg umts m each of the Tnad areas, but also are
manufacturing investments in 1939, first supplied the countries in which they then pro- increasingly engaging in R&D. 88 Such strategic market-seeking investment might be
duced by exports. nndertaken for defensive or aggressive reasons. Much of the 'follow the leader' or
Market-seeking investment 1nay be undertaken to sustain or protect existing markets, 'bándwagon' type of investments (which are analysed more fully in the following
or to exploit or promete new markets. Apart from market size and the prospects for chapter) are of the former kind. For example, the sheer size of the potential market in
market growth, there are four main reasons which might prompt firms to engage in either China has attracted unprecedented inf!ows of foreign investment, sorne of which has
sorts of market-seeking investment. The first is that their main suppliers or customers . followed the investments made by key customers, while sorne of it has followed the
have set up foreign-producing facilities, and that to retain their business they need to industry leaders.
follow them overseas. A classic example of this kind of FDI is that by sorne 500 Japanese Aggressive investments are those designed to advance the global interests of a firm by
auto-componen! suppliers which have set up manufacturing subsidiaries in the US, or investing in an expanding market. The response of MNEs to the completion of Europe's
concludedjoint ventures with US firms, to supply US plants of the leading Japanese auto interna! market in 1992, and to the opening up of Central and Eastern Europe to FDI
assemblers. In the services sector, cross-border M&As among accounting, anditing, law was essentially of this kind, although the belief that the European interna! market might
and advertising firms in the l 980s and 1990s were considerably stimnlated both to improve be restrictive in its policies towards imports from non-EU countries also led to sorne
their global competitive positions and by the need to offer their clients a presence in defensive strategic investment by non-EU MNEs. Subsequent analysis on the impact of
the leading markets of the world (Dunning, 1990), and this trend accelerated through the the European interna! market programme on patterns of FDI and trade within and into
1990s. Far example, between 1990 and 2000 the number of cross-border M&As in the the EU confirmed that much of the observed increase in FDI had come in the form of
business services sector rose from 11,831to137,416 (UNCTAD, 2004:420). This growth M&As, which were likely to have been strategic asset seeking in nature (Dunning, 1997b,
was three times greater than that of such purchases in manufacturing industry. 1997c).
The second reason for market-orientated FDI is that, quite frequently, products need to However, undoubtedly the single most importan! reason for market-seeking invest-
be adapted to local lastes or needs, to cultural mores and to indigenous resources and cap- ment remains the action of host governments encouraging such investment. The trad-
abilities. In addition, without familiarising themselves with local language, business itional instrument chosen by governments has been to impose tariffs or other import
customs, legal reqnirements and marketing procedures, foreign producers might find them- controls. History suggests that the majority of first-time manufacturing and service
selves al a disadvantage vis-á-vis local firms in selling consumer goods such as washing investments were undertaken to circumvent such trade barriers. Governments have also
machines, audio/video equipment, sorne drugs and cosmetics, anda wide variety of food attempted to attract inward investment by offering a gamut of investment incentives
and drink products, as well as !hose supplying intermediate products such as construction ranging from tax concessions to subsidised labour and capital costs and favourable
machinery, petrochemicals and forestry products, financia! and professional services. import quotas. More recently there has been an explosive growth of bilateral invesl!nent
The third reason for serving a local market from an adjacent facility is that the pro- agreements (BITs) concluded by both developed and developing country governments
duction and transaction costs of so doing are less than supplying it from a distance. and potential foreign investors. 89 We shall discuss these measures in more detail in
Obviously, this decision will be highly activity and country specific. The production of Chapter 20.
goods that are relatively costly to transport and can be produced economically in small Unlike those engaging in other kinds of FDI, market-seeking MNEs tend to treat
quantities is more likely to be located near the main centres of consumption than are those their foreign affiliates as self-contained production units rather than as par! of an inte-
that cost relatively little to transport and yield substantial economies of scale in their pro- grated network of cross-border activities. In consequence, they tend to be the most
duction. Firms from countries that are geographically removed from importan! markets responsive to local needs and cultural sensitivities. 90 The affiliates of market-seeking
are more likely to engage in market-seeking FDI than those that adjoin those markets firms will normally produce similar products to those supplied by their paren! compa-
(compare French or Dutch investment with US investment in Germany). In sorne cases, nies, though usually a truncated range. Usually, too, the output will be sold in the
government regulations, import controls or strategic trade policy may prompt firms to country in which it is produced, although there may be sorne exports to adjacent
relocate their production facilities. For example, the Canadian telecommunications markets. In regionally integrated markets such as the EU and NAFTA, however,
MNE, N orthern Telecom, moved man y of its production facilities to the US in the late production in one ora few countries might service ali the countries in the region. At the
1980s so that it could win Japanese contracts. At the time, Japan favoured the US as a end of the 1990s, market-seeking MNEs probably accountcd for about 40% of all
source of telecommunications equipment because of the politically sensitive US-Japan global direct investment and about 60% in the developing countries and transition
trade gap. econornies. 91
72 Facts, theory and history Tl?e motivesjOr jOreign production 73

3.3.3 The Efficiency Seekers although these may sometimes be importan!) and more to augment the acquiring firm's
(loba! portfolio of physical assets aud human wn\petences, wh1ch they perce1ve w1U
The motivation of efficiency-seeking FDI is to rationalise the structure of established !ither sustain or strengthen thelf ownersh1p-spe.c1fic advantages or weaken tho.se of thelf
resource-based or market-seeking investment in such a way that the investing company mpetitors. Increasingly, too, strateg1c and rat10nahsed FDI are gomg hand m hand as
can gain from the common governance of geographically dispersed activities. Such bene- ~~ms restructure their assets to meet their objectives. Importantly, asset-seeking invest-
fits are essentially those of the economies of scale and scope and of risk diversification. ment is also increasingly undertaken by MNEs from emergmg econom1es, as was the case,
They stem from cross-border product or process specialisation, the Iearning experiences for example, with the acquisition of IBM's PC business by the Chinese firm Lenovo in
that result from producing in different cultures, and the opportunities far arbitraging cost 2oo5, and the Indian firm Tata's purchase of the UK steel giant Corus in 2007.
and price differentials across the exchanges. The intention of the efficiency-seeking MNE Like the efficiency-seeking MNE, the strategic asset acquirer aims to capitalise on the
is to take advantage of different factor endowments, cultures, institutional arrangements benefits of the common ownership of diversified activities and capabilities, or of similar
demand patterns, economic policies and market structures, by concentrating productio~ ., activities and capabilities in diverse economic an.d potential environments. Chapter 4 will
in a limited number of Iocations to supply multiple markets. analyse the nature of these benefits in more detail. They ali arise from the imperfections
Usually, the efficiency seekers will be experienced, large and diversified MNEs produc- of the intermediate product markets in which MNEs operate and the opportunities open
ing fairly standardised products and engaging in internationally accepted production to these companies to exploit, or indeed add to, these imperfections. In sorne cases, the
processes. In the past, such FDI has usually occurred once resource-based or market- strategic asset seeker is a conglomerate primarily concerned with the management of
seeking investments have become su:fficiently numerous and important to warrant sorne financia! assets denominated in different currencies. Companies such as Hanson Capital
degree of rationalisation. Increasingly, however, investment by new entrants, such as by Ltd, far example, are primarily institutional portfolio investors, even if they own a major-
Japanese MNEs in the EU and NAFTA, by Korean firms in Central and Eastern Europe, ity of equity shares in the companies they invest. At the same time snch MNEs may, and
and by Indian firms in severa! sub-Saharan African countries, have been undertaken on often do, inject their own organisational systems and management styles into the compa-
a product-by-product basis as part of a carefully orchestrated regional or global market- nies they acquire, even if they do not involve themselves in the day-to-day management
ing strategy. In arder far efficiency-seeking foreign production to take place, cross-border functions. Investment by private equity funds, 92 which has grown considerably over the
markets must be both well developed and open. This is why foreign production flourishes past decade, is a case in point, as such investment generally involves not just the purchase
in regionally integrated markets. of a controlling share of equity, but also the provision of advice and guidance to man-
Efficiency-seeking FDI is of two main kinds. The first is that designed to take advan- agement (UNCTAD, 2006:18). Indeed, in the case of the great majority of strategic
tage of differences in the availability and relative cost of traditional factor endowments investments (including !hose of sorne quite small MNEs) the expectation is that the acqui-
in different countries. This explains much of the division of Iabour within MNEs pro- sition, merger or joint venture will bring sorne benefits to the rest of the organisation of
ducing in both developed and developing countries, with capital-, technology- and infor- which it is part. This it might do, for example, by opening up new markets, creating R&D
mation-intensive value-added activities being concentrated in the former, and labour- and synergies or production economies, buying market power, lowering transaction costs,
natural resource-intensive activities in the latter. The second kind of efficiency-seeking accessing new organisational skills, spreading administrative overheads, advancing strate-
investment is that which takes place in countries with broadly similar economic structnres gic fiexibility and enabling risks to be better spread. 93
and income levels and is designed to take advantage of the economies of scale and scope, While sorne specialist multinational conglomerates tend to be service rather than
and of differences in consumer !astes and supply capabilities. Here, traditional factor goods-producing companies, and often their foreign investments are free-standing, most
endowments play a less importan! role in influencing FDI, while 'created' competences foreign M&As are currently undertaken by MNEs that fall into one of the other three cat-
and capabilities, incentive structures and the availability and quality of supporting insti- egories just described. Strategic and economic good sense usually go hand in hand.
tutions, the characteristics of the local competition, the nature of consumer demand and However, on certain occasions and for certain purposes, strategic considerations may be
the macro and micro policies of governments play a more importan! role. the dominan! motive far FDI. One company may acquire or engage in a collaborative
alliance with another to thwart a competitor from so doing. Another might merge with
3.3.4 The Strategic Asset Seekers one of its foreign rivals to strengthen their joint capabilities vis-<l-vis a more powerful rival.
A third might acquire a group of suppliers to comer the market far a particular raw mate-
The fourth group of MNEs comprise !hose which engage in FDI, usually by acquiring rial. A fourth might seek to gain access over distribution outlets to better promote its own
the assets of foreign corporations, to promote their long-term strategic objectives - espe- brand of products. A fifth might buy out a firm producing a complementary range of
cially that of sustaining or advancing their global competitiveness. The investing firms goods or services so that it can offer its customers a more diversified range of products.
involved include both established MNEs pursuing an integrated global or regional strat- A sixth might join forces with a local firm in the belief that it is in a better position to
egy, and first-time foreign direct investors seeking to access or to buy sorne kind of secure contracts from the host government that are denied to its exporting competitors.
competitive strength in an unfamiliar market. The motive far strategic asset-seeking Ali these are examples of strategic FDI to protect or advance the investing firm's long-
investment is Iess to exploit specific cost or marketing advantages over their competitors term competitive position.
74 Fact,<¡~ theory and history Tlfe moti\les j'or jOreign production 75

There are no statistical data on the significance of efficiency-seeking or strategic activities incur costs but the major benefits accrue to the rest of the MNE. Foremost
asset-acquiring FDI94 by MNEs, particularly as they cannot easily be separated from among support investments are trade- and finance-related investments of MNEs, which
the other two kinds of value-adding activity. What does seem certain, howeve1; is that are essentially designed to promete and facilitate the exports of goods and services from
most of the cross-border intra-Triad M&As which have been concluded since the early the investing (or other) companies, and/or to assist in the purchasing of foreign-produced
1990s have been geared towards protecting or advancing the acquiring firm's global goods and services from the investing (or other) companies. . . .
competitive position. While around one-fifth of these M&As have been directed to the The kinds of value-added actlVlty undertaken by MNE tradmg affihates mclude not
growth-orientated knowledge- and information-intensive sectors, notably telecommu- only wholesale and retail distribution and marketing, but also a range of import facili-
nications, electronics and business services, the main objective of a fair number, for tating which they undertake on behalf of the investing company. The Japanese soga
example, in the food, beverages and tobacco, public utility, retail trade and financia! ser- shosha and the Korean chaebol companies are trading MNEs par exce/lence. 97 There are
vices sectors, has been to exploit rationalising and cost-cutting advantages, and/or to many others. Examples are the leading clothing wholesale and retail outlets in Europe and
defend or gain market share in an increasingly competitive market (UNCTAD, 2000b, the US, such as Sears Roebuck, Kmart, Wal-Mart, and Hennes and Mauritz, which pur-
2006). 95 chase substantial quantities of clothing and footwear from Asian suppliers, and often del-
egate the subcontracting arrangements (including the monitoring of quality control) to
3.3.5 Other Motives for MNE Activity their buying subsidiaries. Similarly, the sale of sophisticated intermediate products and
those which need regular after-sales maintenance and servicing may need the presence of
There are other reasons for MNE activity which do not easily fit in to the four categories trained personnel and of warehousing facilities for spare parts. Often trade-related sub-
just described. We shall classify these into three groups, namely, escape investments, sidiaries also provide other marketing and public relations services far their parent com-
support investments and passive investments. Let us consider each of these in turn. panies. Finally, as Chapter 7 will show, such activities are frequently the first step to the
setting up of market- or resource-seeking production facilities.
Escape investments There are other kinds of support services which might be provided by the foreign
Sorne FDI is made to escape restrictive legislation or macro-organisational policies by affiliates of MNEs. These are usually undertaken by regional or branch offices. Regional
home governments. We are not here concerned with 'flight' capital which may he associ- offices actas an intermediate centre of control and administration between the head office
ated with war, civil strife or dire economic circumstances, for example, as has occurred and the foreign operating units. Various studies98 have shown that the functions per-
at one time or another in Argentina, Zimbabwe, Uganda, Liheria, South Africa, formed by these offices vary a great deal. Typically they involve both the coordination of
Malaysia and the Philippines over the last two decades. 96 Examples of the kind of the activities of the operating units and the provision of financia! and marketing infor-
'escape' investments we have in mind include the 'round-tripping' of investment between mation for the parent company. They may also undertake such services as personnel
China and Hong Kong to exploit incentives granted only to foreign investors, investment recruitment, the search for additional investment opportunities in the region in which they
hy American biotechnology firms to undertake stem cell research in Europe, or cases are situated, site selection, public relations and liaison with host governments and/or
where Swedish MNEs have relocated their headquarters elsewhere in Europe to escape regional authorities.
high levels of taxation and/or a perceived lack of dynamism in the domestic economy Branch offices which are independent of trade and operating units are less common.
(Birkinshaw et al., 2006). We might also include in this category the relocation of the However, the idea of setting up a listening and monitoring arm of the parent company
environmentally sensitive European leather tanning sector to Eastern Europe and devel- has gained credence in recent years, particularly, for example, in the case of US firms con-
oping countries, although this has occurred largely through increased outsourcing rather templating investments in the EU, and of Japanese finance-based MNEs seeking a pres-
than through new investment (Jenkins et al., 2002). ence in the City of London.
Escape investments, such as those just described, are clearly most likely to originate
from countries whose governments adhere to ideologies and economic strategies unac- Passive investments
ceptable to the business community: and they tend to be concentrated in those sectors - Chapter 1 indicated that a foreign investment is treated as direct if the investing entity has
especially service sectors - which are most highly regulated. With the renaissance of a financia! equity interest in a foreign company sufficient to give it sorne control or
pro-market-orientated policies and the liberalisation of many markets, there is probably influence over the latter's decision making. In practice, as we have seen, data collecting
less 'escape' MNE activity in the early 2000s than a decade ago. In ali of the cases out- agencies assume this to be somewhere between 1O and 25%, although 10% is becoming
lined above, the escape motivation is likely to be one of the determining factors, but the standard criterion. We have also suggested that direct investment is motivated
seldom the only one, in the decision to relocate specific activities. differently from portfolio investment.99 The latter kind of investment is an expression of
faith in the existing organisation and management of the company, and is undertaken to
Support investments earn profits or to gain capital appreciation. By contrast, direct investment is designed
The purpose of these investments is to support the activities of the rest of the enterprise to inject new resources, management skills and institutional forms into the company, or
of which they are part. Such affiliates are rarely self-contained profit centres. Their to acquire new assets to protect or increase the investor's own profits or competitiveness.
76 Facts, theory and history The.motives for foreign production 77

Portfolio investment is presumed to involve passive management whereas direct invest;:_ . orne kind of ancillary investments. Although there is not much that the academic
ment is presumed to involve active management.
In practice, most direct investments vary in the degree of active management pursued
111
:olar can do about separating the portfolio componen! of any direct investment, helshe
s~0 uld be aware of its ~elevance. At leas! for sorne kinds of investment, he or she should
by their owners, ranging from 'complete' to 'non-existen!'. Those which veer to the passive : 10 incorporate the kind of variables that influence such investment into his explana-
end of the spectrum are of two kinds. The first are !hose of large institutional conglom, . t~Y models (Dunning and Dilyard, 1999).
erales that specialise in the buying and selling of companies. Well-known examples are · Finally, we might mention the emergence-of so-called 'born global' firms. These are typ-
T. Boone Pickens (US) and Lonrho (UK); the latter, after the departure of business . ally technology-intensive start-up firms that serve niche markets, and are able to reach
tycoon Tiny Rowland, was dernerged into a mining group anda diversified group of hold- :~ppliers and customers around the world from their inception (Madsen and Servais,
ings in Africa. However, although the investrnents are rnotivated by income potential or 1997). To the extent that they normally supply a narrow range of products or serv1ces,
capital gain, sorne direct managerial input is usually involved, as is now being increasingly have Jow Jevels of resources committed outside their domestic borders, and engage in
dernonstrated by the cross-border investrnent by private equity companies (UNCTAD, exports as their primary cross-border activity, we would consider these 'global' firms to
2006). Rarely is an acquired company left to its own devices. Such investments are under-· . be relatively conventional market-seekingfirms. However, the fact that 'born global' firms
táken to irnprove technological, marketing, financia! or organisational capabilities; others may also source various knowledge-intensive inputs globally, suggests that they may have
may involve asset stripping. efficiency and asset-seeking motivations as well. We shall return to 'born global' firms in
Most real estate involvement (in land, hotels and so on) is based on sorne expectation . Chapter 7.
of future Jand and property values, and if the motivation of such investment is primarily
financia], the 'foreignness' irnpact on the use of the assets acquired may be very limited.
This was particularly apparent in the investments made by Gulf investors into London · 3.4 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF OUTWARD FDI
hotel properties in the l 970s, and the acquisition of prestigious real estate in the US by
Japanese MNEs in th.e late l 980s. However, since the early 2000s, the oil exporting coun- The previous sections have dealt with sorne of the economic and strategic motives for
tries with growing current account surpluses, such as Kuwait, Saudi Arabia and the - FD!. However, in so far as the govermnents of the investing countries are also interested
United Arab Emirates (Dubai), whicb have traditionally been active in portfolio invest- in the outcome of the activities of MNEs, then, by inftuencing the conduct of such firms
rnent and more passive forms of FDI, have been increasingly allocating their petrodollars · or their affiliates, they may affect the amount and pattern of FDI. Cbapter 6 will, indeed,
to more active forms of investment. In addition to expanding the range of their FDis to show that, throughout history, much MNE activity has been undertaken either directly
include a variety of manufacturing and service operations in Asia and Africa, tbe state- · by nation states, or with their support and encouragement. But normally, such encour-
owned investment firrns have undertaken sorne notable M&As, including the purchase of agement has only been forthcoming if the investment was perceived to advance the Jong-
the UK shipping company P&O by Dubai Ports World, whicb led to a conflict concern- term economic and political goals of the home country.
ing their ownership of sorne US ports (UNCTAD, 2006). 1 ºº Most early British investments in North Arnerica and 19th-century investments by
The second kind of passive investment is that made by small firms and individual European colonial powers in the developing countries were of this kind (Svedberg, 1982).
investors in real estate. Often tbis is simply to foster the foreign owuership of holiday or History is replete with examples of private MNEs being used as instruments of the eco-
second homes. However, sometimes it is undertaken purely in anticipation of an appreci- nomic policy of metropolitan governments. Indeed, until the outbreak of the First World
ation in land and property prices. The boom in real estate both in the leading cities of the War, the UK and French colonies were sometimes forbidden to accept inward investment
world, and in the tourist areas of ernerging economies in the early 2000s are examples of from other than the mother country, which at the same time might give incentives to its
such investment. Here, the mainstream theories of FDI described in the next cbapter are own firms. In the second half of the 20th century there were severa! cases of uneasy
left wanting. This is because, although classified as direct, these purchases have more the alliances being concluded between MNEs and their home governments; while in the first
attributes of portfolio investment. decade of the 21st there is increasing evidence of home governments supporting FDI, and
There is sorne suggestion that the passive element in the foreign operations by MNEs the interests of their own MNEs, in the belief that it may further their own political, eco-
may be increasing. Certainly, this is more likely to be a feature of cross-border M&As than ·· nomic or strategic objectives. These issues will be explored in more detail in Chapters 6
of greenfield investments; as shown in Chapter 2, the former escalated considerably in º
and 19. 1 2 Chapter 2 observed that although the numbers of state-owned MNEs have
the l 990s. Moreover, the rate at which firms have changed ownership, particularly in declined in the past decade due to policies favouring privatisation, there are still rnany
real estate-, trade- and finance-related activities increased in that decade dramatically large MNEs that are at leas! partly state owned. 103 Indeed there is sorne evidence that
(UNCTAD, 2000b). The problem of identifying the passive or portfolio componen! of a SO Es - particularly those from Brazil and Russia - are becoming more active as foreign
direct investment is, of course, not unique to FDI. Indeed, one school of thought has investors (Sauvant, 2005). The question of the tactics pursued by state-owned MNEs, and
vie\ved the growth of the firm as belng motivated by the pursuance of profitable and the extcnt to which home govcrnmcnts may affcct thc bchaviour of private MNEs
wealth appreciation activities. 101 While most firms would be reluctant to accept this per- operating outside their home territories is an altogether different matter which is taken up
ception, and prefer to follow an 'every cobbler sticks to his las!' philosophy, most engage in Chapters 19 and 20.
78 Fact,1~ theory and history

3.5 CONCLUSIONS
The above sections have demonstrated that the types of foreign value-added activities
undertaken by MNEs may be very differently motivated. Because of this, it is difficult to
perceive an all-embracing theory of the determinants of these activities in the sense of 4. Theories of foreign direct investrnent
encompassing, within a single explanatory model, a set of variables that can fully explain · ·
each at the same time. The most, we believe, that the economist or business analyst can
reasonably do is to farmulate paradigms to provide an analytical framework which can 4.1 INTRODUCTION
incorporate theories designed to explain particular kinds of FDI and the determinants o(
the various types of MNE activity. This chapter seeks to review sorne of the leading economic and behavioural explanations
The consensus of scholarly research and business case histories over the past 30 years .. of the existence and growth of MNEs and of the foreign value-added activities they own
support this contention. Thus, the factors that explain Ria Tinto's investment in copper or control. Chapter 1 identified MNEs as multi-activity firms that engage in FDI. At the
mines in New Guinea or Geest's investment in a banana plantation in the Windward same time, it acknowledged that many MNEs also participate in a variety of cross-border
Islands are totally different from those that explain Coca-Cola's investment in a bottling non-equity alliances and/or clusters of value-adding activities over which they may exert
plant in Arusha, Tanzania, Bata's investment in a shoe factory in Belgium, the purchase considerable influence. Chapter 1 further suggested that MNEs have two near relatives.
of the Rockefeller Center in New York by the Mitsubishi Estate Corporation of Japan, First, Jike international trading companies, they undertake cross-border transactions
oran investment by the Indonesian company Summa in the first foreign-owned bank in outside their home countries, but unlike them, they own and/or control foreign produc-
Vietnam. Likewise, each of these investments is motivated by a different set of consider- tion facilities. Second, like multiplant domestic firms, MNEs operate two or more pro-
ations from those driving IBM's, Royal Dutch Shell's or ABB's strategies towards the duction units and internalise the transactions between these units. Unlike them, however,
globalisation of their R&D facilities, or Nokia's attempts to build up an international at Jeast one of these production units is located in a foreign country, and the markets inter-
network of communication facilities, or Cemex's strategy to become one of the leading nalised are transnational rather than domestic.
global players in the cement industry, or Club Méditerranée's objective to own or fran- The theory of the determinants of MNE activity must then seek to explain both the
chise hotels in each of the world's majar tourist regions. /ocation of value-adding activities, and the ownership and organisation of these activ-
However, it is one thing to argue that different explanatory variables are required to ities. As such, it needs to draw upon and integrate two strands of economic thought.
explain different kinds of fareign production, but quite another to assert that it is not pos- The first is the theory of international resource allocation based upan the spatial distri-
sible to farmulate a general paradigm or, as Kuhn (1962) puts it, 'a disciplinary matrix' bution of factor endowments and capabilities. This theory chiefly addresses itself to the
which seeks to set out a common analytical approach to explaining all kinds of MNE location of production. The second is the theory of economic organisation, which is
activity. A reading of the literature suggests that there is sorne division of opinion as to essentially concerned with the ownership of that production and the ways in which the
the nature of the distinction between a theory and a paradigm. As we see ita theory is a transactions relating to it (including those which may impinge on its location) are
set of propositions about the nature and form of the behavioural relationships between a managed and organised.
set of phenomena, the validity of which can be empirically tested. In sorne cases there may In traditional (classical or neoclassical) models of trade, which were the dominan! par-
be alternative theories to explain the same phenomena; these may be called 'competing' adigms in international economics until the 1950s, only the first issue, namely, the 'where'
theories. In others, different phenomena may (and usually do) require different explana- of production, was addressed. Questions relating to the ownership and organisation
tions, in which case the theories would be 'non-competing'. Most partial theories of the of economic activity were ignored. This was because the market for the cross-border
MNE or FDI fa]] into one or other of these categories. exchange of goods and services was assumed to be a costless mechanism. Resources were
A paradigm, on the other hand, seeks to present a general framework far analysing the assumed to be immobile across national boundaries but mobile within national bound-
relationship between phenomena from which it is possible to formulate a variety of com- aries. Firms were assumed to possess unbounded rationality and engage in only a single
peting or non-competing theories. Perceived in this way, a theory is a derivative of a par- activity. Entrepreneurs were assumed to be profit maximisers. Institutional differences
adigm, but one paradigm may be able to accommodate severa] theories.104 were assumed not to matter. Managerial strategy was assumed to be confined to identify-
The following two chapters will take up these points in more detail with respect to sorne ing the optimum leve] of output, and minimising the costs of súpplying and marketing
of the theories and paradigms that have been put forward to explain the determinants of that output.
the existence and growth of MNEs and of their global value-added activities. However, once one allows for imperfections in goods or factor markets, the possibility of
alternative patterns of ownership of firms and/or organising transactions arises. For
cxample, in place of one firm selling its product through the market to another :firn1 which
then adds value to it, the same firm may coordinate both sets of activity and, in so doing,
replace the market as a mechanism for allocating resources between the two firms, or far any

79
200 Inside the multinational enterprise

Chapter 9 considers sorne of the alternative modes of cross-border activity undertaké


by MNEs to that of the fully owned foreign affiliate. Again it argues that much of tll
theory set out in Chapters 4 and 5 can be usefully extended to explain the propensity
firms to conclude both joint and non-equity ventures (for example, strategic alliances
and also to engage in networks and related activities. This is because most economists a 1. Entry and expansion strategies of MNEs
business analysts have been as much interested in explaining the extension of the contr
exercised by firms outside their national boundaries as in their structure of ownershirf.
Chapter 9 shows that control may be acquired from various sources and exercised i 7.1 INTRODUCTION
various ways. Indeed, Part II concludes by suggesting that, in the past two decades, the
MNE has become the nexus of a plurality of cross-border control and incentive mechi In Part I we sought to identify the motives for, and determinants of, international pro-
anisms, and that the way in which it manages these to achieve its global objectives wi! . duction, and to explain the historical evolution_oLMNE actlV!ty. In th1s chapter we con-
substantially determine the extent to which it can sustain or advance its long-ter ·cter FDI as part of the institntional and orgamsat10nal strategy of firms. In domg so: we
competitive ( or 0-specific) advantages. :~ke a more micro-orientated and behavioural perspective of our subject, and cons1der
Finally we would urge the reader to consider Part II as a bridge between Parts I and the reasons why, and the situations in which, particular enterpnses become fore1gn
It does not claim to be a comprehensive analysis of the interna! workings of MNEs. ducers and/or increase, or change the content and pattern of, thelf global econom1c
prO · · h. h h
attention, for example, is given to critica! financia! or marketing issues, or to hnrno~· involvement. We also seek to identify the main determmants of the ways 111 w 1c suc
resource management in multinational firms. Its purpose is a different one. Together international production may be owned and organised. .
Part I, its aim is to prepare the reader for the analysis which follows in Parts III and In Chapter ¡ we defined an MNE as a firm that owned and controlled value-addmg
In our examination of the impact of MNEs on the economies in which they operate, activities in more than one country. In Chapter 3 we suggested that MNEs engaged m
shall repeatedly argue that this will critically depend on two main variables. The first is foreign production to increase the value of the income-generating assets of theff owners.
content and quality of the institutions of the countries (or regions) in which the MNE Chapter 5 argued that this goal was achieved by effic1ently coordmatmg thelf ex1st111g
activity takes place; and the macroeconomic and micro-management policies pursued by assets (together with those which they might acquire or lease)- thelf so-called O advan-
their governments. The second is the way in which MNEs, themselves, organise the cross- tages- with the L configurations of countries. Chapter 5 further suggested that the value-
border governance of these activities, and the reasons for this. Part II will have mcce:eded...~i~.. added activities of MNEs incurred two kinds of costs - namely, productwn, that is,
in its objective if it identifies the main changes in the global economic and politicalenvir: value-added and transaction, that is, exchange and institutional costs- wh1ch were hkely
onment determinants of this !alter variable; and how these have responded over time¡() to vary according to the nature and extent of these activities,_ the way in wh1ch they were
technological and institutional advances, and changes in the global economic and pum·······'·"•!··· coordinated and their Iocation. Thus, for example, dependmg on whether product1on
ical environment. (the process by which Iess valuable inpnts are organised to produce more valuable
outputs) is undertaken by severa! firms or by JUS! one, the costs of that producuon may
be higher or ]ower. Similarly, where the production of goods or serv1ce mvolves the use
of intermediate products at different stages of the value-added cham - a_s Jt_usually does
-the transaction costs (that is, the costs of organising these separate act1v1t1es) are hkely
to vary according to whether this function is undertaken b_y the market, by a smgle
administrative hierarchy, by sorne kind of a coopera!Jve a!hance, or by a network of
firms. MNEs are Iikely to flourish wherever the production of two or more value~added
activities are best coordinated under the same, rather than separate, ownersh1p and
control and where the entreprenenrs and managers of the organising enterprises per-
ceive it'to be in their bes! interests to !acate at leas! sorne of these activities in a foreign
country. . .
Chapter 6 further suggested that the historical growth of the MNE reflected the mter-
action between three sets of forces. The first was the extent to wh1ch the resources, cap-
abilities markets and institutions necessary for the efficient production and distribution
of gootls and services are - in sorne sense or other - the privileged assets or üghts of par-
ticular firms. As Chapter 5 argued, it is the possession of such assets or nghts that fre-
quently gives a firm a competitive edge over its rivals. The second was the extent to wh1ch
firms found it profitable to organise the transactions relating to the acqms1t10n and use of

201
202 Inside the multinational enterprise Entry and e::;pansion strategies oj.,MNEs . 203

these rights themselves, orto employ sorne other modality for this purpose; and also why, and the intra- and extra-firm incentive structures likely to affect the way in which the deci-
along with these transactions, the organisation of production, within and between firms síons necessary to achieve these objectives are taken.
was becoming increasingly concentrated in the hands of a relatively few MNEs, rathe; Neoclassical economics initially analysed market imperfections by reference to their
than being shared among many. The third factor infiuencing the growth of foreign pro- effect on the behaviour of participants in the market. In doing so, it limited its interest
duction was that, for a variety of reasons, firms were finding it increasingly to their advan- in institutions to those endogenous to markets. In particular, three kinds of structural
tage to augment their existing assets, orto produce goods and services from these assets market distortions were identified. The first was the power of the participants in the
outside rather than inside their national boundaries. ' market to infiuence price by adding or withdrawing output from the total amount being
Chapter 6 also highlighted the interaction between the growth of the human and phys- sold (or purchased). The second were those arising from the ability of firms to differ-
ical assets, and the macro organisation of value-added activity. It emphasised that the entiate, for example, by branding their products differently from those of their com-
expansion of MNE activity must be seen as part and parce! of the growth and spread of petitors. The third were those arising from the presence (or creation) of barriers to
international capitalism, technological and organisational change, the discovery of new competition. Except in the case of oligopolistic market situations, the neoclassical econ-
lands and materials, the emergence of new political and economic systems, the creation omists took these imperfections as exogenous, and continued to assume that firms acted
of strong and effective institutional frameworks, and of robust capital markets, and a as profit maximisers.
substantial lowering of the costs of the cross-border movement of goods, assets and However, as we have seen, the introduction of market imperfections broadens not only
people. Each of these events has dramatically affected not only the availability and the choices of firms in their product and production portfolios, but also the range of both
quality of goods and services together with their associated costs of production and intra- and extra-firm institutions which might infiuence these choices. First, once it is
transactions, but the ways in which that production and those transactions are owned accepted that a firm does not have to maximise profits to stay in business, then the possi-
and organised. bility of alternative objectives and strategies to achieve these objectives arise. Initially
This chapter - indeed, this part of the book - looks at these and related issues from the economists and organisational scholars tended to focus on the output and pricing deci-
viewpoint of the owners and managers of individual firms. It focuses, rather more than sions of firms pursuing a range of non-profit-maximising objectives, for example, sales or
did the previous chapters, on the institutions underpinning the resources and compe- wealth maximisation, or of sorne form of utility or constrained profit maximisation. 277
tences, owned or acquired by individual business enterprises; and on the strategic man- Eventually they carne to recognise that a more fundamental reappraisal of the incentive
agement of these, wherever and whenever this involves the enterprises in value-added structures of firms was required, as any movement away from perfect competition was
activities outside their national boundaries. This chapter, in particular, looks at the deter- liable to affect the costs and benefits of using this particular exchange mechanism. Both
minants of the nature, timing and form of the internationalisation process. transaction cost economics and that choice in strategic behaviour arise out of market
imperfections. At the same time, both are also likely to be infiuenced by a widening of the
institutions which may affect this behaviour and its underlying motivation.
7.2 THE CONCEPT OF BUSINESS STRATEGY Second, firms may themselves attempt to create new structural imperfections in antici-
pation of gaining larger profits. The traditional economics of tbe firm skirts this particu-
By strategy, we mean a deliberate choice taken by the entrepreneurs or managers of firms lar issue - mainly because it is not interested in organisational issues. Indeed, for the most
to organise the resources and capabilities within their control (that is, their O advantages) part, it assumes either that the transaction costs of using markets are zero or that they are
to achieve an objective or set of objectives, overa specified time period, that extends beyond always less than that of any other organisational firm. However, the theory of market
the day-to-day operations of the firm. In the economist's world of perfect competition, failure and of relational contracting (Williamson, 1979, 2000) suggests that this need not
strategy, management or entrepreneurship do not play a significant role. Resources and necessarily be the case. As Teece has elegantly put it: 'By neglecting the institutional foun-
capabilities are generally assumed to be immobile, fungible and homogeneous. The firm dations of market structure, the conventional tools of economic analysis are rendered
is presumed to be a rational, but passive, economic agent with little or no freedom for impotent befare many strategic management problems' (Teece, 1984:91 ).
strategic manoeuvre. Its institutions are required to be consistent with the demands of the When orthodox economists have tried to grapple with these issues, they have been pri-
marketplace. In arder for it both to cover its opportunity costs and to maximise the value · marily concerned with identifying the possible outcome of alternative behavioural strat-
of its assets, the output and price of whatever it supplies are predetermined. Moreover, in egies. As a result, the whole of the literature on oligopoly assumes a game-theoretic
equilibrium, each of the stakeholders in the firm, including the main decision takers, earn perspective which yields an indeterminate solution simply because of cognitive market
only the opportunity cost of their resources and capabilities. failure. For example, one particular oligopolist may not only be uncertain as to how its
Once market imperfections are introduced into the picture, the firm's behavioural behaviour (with respect to such decisions as price, output, range and type of products sup-
options are widened, and the owners and managers have positive and strategic roles to plied, innovatory activities, types of markets served and so on) will affect its competitors,
play. Their roles will vary according to the nature and extent of the market imperfections, but also how they, in turn, will react to this behaviour. Most economic models then seek
the coincidence of interest between the various stakeholders in the business, their judge- to identify the consequences of certain types of behaviour without explicitly examining
ment of the probability and time profile of the outcome of alternative courses of action, the institutions or strategies that might determine that behaviour.
Entry and expansion strate9ieiv of MNEs 205
204 Inside the multinational enterprise

A similar approach is taken to analysing infarmation asymmetries, uncertainty and of the same. Although the emphasis is on specific are~s of decision making, there is an
time. Most economics (as opposed to finance) textbooks pay Iittle attention to the first • . reasing recognitioh that successful strategists are those who are Willmg and able to ta.ke
while the second and third tend to be treated as a cost that needs to be recovered through :~ystemic and integrated approach towards the organisation of their value-added ac\Iv-
higher earnings (though the term 'transaction cost' is not usually used).278 Thus net . · including those that are undertaken outside thelr na!Ional boundanes. The fallow-
Ille 8' f . d ºth
income earned in five years' time has a cost of not being earned today, which is equal to ing sections seek to apply sorne of these. concepts to a number o Issues concerne wI
the interest that would have been earned today if reinvested over four years. Similarly, a he organisation, ownership and operat10ns of MNEs. First, however, we consider the
project with a 50% chance of earning f5 million and a 50% chance of earning f4 million · ~ery nature of a firm's economic activities from a business perspective.
might be treated as of equal val u e to a project with a 100% chance of earning f4.5 million.
Over the last decade or so, another method far valuing the effects of uncertainty
investment decisions has been proposed by the real options literature (Dixit and Pindyck 7.3 THE VALUE-ADDED CHAIN
1994; Amram and Kulatilaka, 1999; Damodaran, 2000). The idea behind this '
is that when faced with considerable uncertainty, the firm would prefer to retain maximum 7,3.1 Sorne General Principies
flexibility regarding its resource commitments, and if the competitive situation allows, to
wait as long as possible to obtain better information befare making the investment. In The rnain task of a business enterprise- and it is unique to this organisatio.n-is to engage
essence, any investment under uncertainty can contain real options, if the investment is in production. Production is defined as any value-creating or -addmg actlVlty. Such added
not viewed as a one-time deal, but rather as a sequence of smaller investments, where the value is achieved by converting inputs of lesser economic worth to outputs of greater
continuation of the project can be reassessed after each step. Such 'options to wait' are economic worth. Pul another way, the firm owns or hires the services of a set of human,
valuable if the investor is essentially protected from downside risk, while enjoying the pos- physical or financia! assets, for which it must pay at Ieast their opportumty cost. In a
sibility of waiting for a favourable turn in the market to proceed with the investment. profit-maximising model, the strategy of the ownernof the firm IS to coordmate andallo-
While, in theory, an option will never have a negative value, in reality the value of an cate these assets in such a way as to produce the maximum surplus (that IS, economic rent)
'option to wait' is tempered by the actions, or anticipated options, of competitors, if for over and above their opportunity cost, all of which is assumed to accrue to the owners as
instance a competitor can gain market share while another firm has chosen to wait. profits. . . . .
By using a modified options pricing formula, it is possible to assess the value of the These profits may be distributed to shareholders or remvested m the busmess m the
flexibility embodied in sequential investments, and to contras! this with a one-time expectation of earning future profits or increasing the net value of the firm. Alternatively,
investment decision evaluated on the basis of its NPV. While there are clear limitations in imperfectly competitive conditions, the owners of the firm may pursue other obiectives.
to this approach - for example those arising from the idiosyncratic character of many Surplus profits may be absorbed as managerial inefficiency, or they may be wholly or
corporate investment projects (such as investment in R&D), and the resulting difficulty partly distributed to or appropriated by other stakeholders (for example, consumers an.d
in estimating risk (volatility) - there have been severa! attempts to model the MNE as the owners of Iabour services) according to the goals they are seekmg to achieve, and their
a collection of real options (Buckley and Casson, 1998; Casson, 2000; Kogut and respective bargaining powers. . .
Kulatilaka, 2001). The real options approach has also been employed to explain joint In order to achieve its objectives, a firm must also engage m transactwns. E ven the füm
venturing (Kogut, 1991; Fo Ita and Miller, 2002) and sequentia! market entry (Kogut and that undertakes a single economic activity has to participate in two sets of transact10ns.
Ch ang, 1996). The first is with the owners of the resources and capabilities it uses to produce the value
These, of course, are simple illustrations of the inadeq uacy of the market as a deter- added· the second is with the purchasers of the goods or services which are the output of
ministic resource-allocative institution, the replacement or enlargement of which by the ac;ivity. These transactions are externa! to the firm, that is, between it and indepen-
extra-market institutions opens a new range of strategic options to decision takers. In dent economic agents (far example, other firms and households), and they are usually
fact, not only do most decisions set in train a whole set of interrelated outcomes each of organised by the market. Although these transactions involve costs, such as those Iden-
which is uncertain, but almos! every decision, whether it is concerned with the best way tified in Chapter 5, they have to be incurred if the firm is to produce at ali. Furthermore,
to organise innovatory activities, or the introduction of a wage incentive scheme, impinges the costs may not be independent of the benefits. The cost of coordmatmg labour mputs
on the leve! of, and balance between, receipts and costs in a way that is difficult to esti- and monitoring employee performance may be directly related to the productlVlty of that
mate with any certainty. The alternatives chosen, then, will depend on the strategist's esti- Iabour. Higher transaction costs associated with the search for possible buyers may be
mation of the likely alternative outcomes - and/or those to whom decision rnaking has partially or wholly offset by the additional sales generated by that search. In recen! years,
been delegated; and the incentive structures affecting his or her decision making. analysts have been giving increasing attention to such issues as corporate soc:a~ respons1-
The approach of the business strategist is less formal and, understandably, more bility, environmental sustainability, ethical investment, and consumer bargammg power,
prag1natic than that of the economist. Instead of seeking generalised explanations to a with respect to the conditions un<ler which certain products are produccd and transacted.
particular problem, he/she is concerned with identifying particular solutions for an indi- Each of these is suggesting that simplistic profit-maximising models may not always
vidual firm, or group of firms that possess similar characteristics, and the determinants reflect the de facto multiple goals of managers.
206 Inside the n1ultinational enterprise Entry and expansion strategies ,aj" ]l.fNEs 207

. In a simple profit-maximising model, then, the primary objective of the firm is to bu ¡985), prefer to cal! it, the 'value chain') which identifies the various stages of econornic
1ts mputs and sel! its output in a way that maximises the revenue far any given level of pn;'. activity that rnake upa production sequence of a specific productor service frorn start
duct10n less that of the (net) transaction costs incurred in earning this revenue. In add' to finish. At each stage, up to the point at which the product or service is sold to the
lllon, ü w1ll continue to increase its. output until the marginal production and (net) final consurner, an interrnediate product is produced, which then becornes an input into
transa~tion ~osts are equal .to 1ts marginal revenue. There are various pro blems associated the next stage of the process. 279 The value-added chain of a cotton shirt, far exarnple,
even.w1th th1s apparently simple accounting.exercise. One is that because it is not always would include the design of the shirt, the growing of the raw cotton, the spinning of the
poss1ble to measure transact10n costs - part1cularly those associated with risk and inter" yarn, the weaving or knitting of the yarn into cloth, the manufacture of the garrnent
personal relationships - it is difficult to judge whether or not costs are being minimised 0 (far exarnple, cutting, sewing and packaging) and finally the marketing of the final
revenue. being maximised at a given leve! of output, or, indeed, whether the right leve! r product and its distribution to wholesalers and retailers. The value-added chain of a
output ." bemg produced. Another is that sorne transaction costs are not easily allocable particular firrn, by contras!, rnay cover only one of the steps outlined above, or indeed
to. p.arl!cular mputs, far example, the costs of monitoring labour performance so as to all of thern.
mm1m1se shlfkmg or opportunism by workers, or those of ensuring that subcontractors At each stage of the chain, value is added to that created previously such that the gross
adhere to the terms of their contrae!. value (of output) of the end product is equal to the value added (or net output) of each
As won as a firm chooses to engage in more than one value-added activity, not only are of the separate stages. Thus if RA is the gross receipts frorn the sales of the final product
both 1ts. transact10n costs and benefits likely to increase, but also it begins to assume a role A and N Ai' .. ., N Av are the value added at stages i, ii, ... , v of the chain then:
wh1ch: m füeory at leas!, may be accomplished by other organisational modalities. By
engagmg m upstream or downstream value activities, in addition to the one which it is RA =(NAi+ NAii + NAiii + NAiv + NAv). (7.1)
already undertaking, a firm internalises the market far what is being bought or sold. In so
domg, 1t bnngs, under a single ownership, activities which were previously (or, in the case However, the concept of a chain is not entirely appropriate far describing the produc-
of a new acl!v1ty, might have been) produced by two (or more) separate producers. A firm tion process. Indeed, as we shall see later, this is becorning less so over time because sorne
that divers1fies 1ts output, far example, from being a producer of refrigerators to being a interrnediate products are not used by firrns sequentially but jointly at various stages of
producer of refrigerators and washing machines, also incurs additional transaction costs the production process. These include common institutions and incentive structures,
through the common governance of both activities. Presumably it believes that these costs administrative, financia! and advisory services, transport services and public utilities, and
are either less than those which would be incurred by using the market, or that there are sorne professional (far exarnple, auditing, advertising and legal) services. Although, in
compensatory gains to be reaped, such as economies of scope, and the sharing of common theory, it rnay also be possible to assign such cornplernentary value-adding activities to
overheads, from internalising the market far the two products. Diversifying the location of particular stages of production, in practice it rnight be exceedingly difficult to do.
product10n most certainly adds to a firm's transaction costs, far example, those to do with Nevertheless, they are par! of the value-added network of activities.
reconc1hng formal or informal institutional differences, hierarchical control and intra-firm The choice of the particular value-added chain (or chains) and the stage of the chain
communications. However, again, these may be more than outweighed by the revenue in which a firm rnay be involved, will be deterrnined by its perceived institutional,
gamed from new markets, a reduction in the unit cost of transactions common to foreign resource-based and marketing advantages, and the strategy it adopts to exploit these
and domest1c product10n, the benefits of output specialisation, the cross-border arbitrag- advantages (Tallrnan, 1991). As we have suggested elsewhere, such a strategy is likely to
mg of factor pnces and the spreading of risk and environmental volatility (Kogut, 1985). affect the firm's future competitive position (Dunning, 1993a, 2000a). The geographical
The above analysis, then, provides the setting far understanding the decision of a firm configuration of these activities will also depend on the firrn's perception of the relative
to produce outside its national boundaries. This will occur when the firm perceives that attractions of alternative production locations. As Porter (1994, 1996) and Enright
the net benefits of supplying any given market, or set of markets, is best achieved by (2000b) have ernphasised, a firrn's response to these attractions rnay be a critica! determ-
engagmg m foreign production relative to sorne other modality of supplying that (or inan! of its strategy.
those) market(s). It could be, far example, that the firm considers that the costs of engag- So far, we have not discussed the organisation ar ownership of the value-added chain
mg m any actlV!ty, plus the (net) cross-border transaction costs of internalising the market or network, that is, how the various stages are coordinated with each other. The options
far the mtermediate product used in that activity, are higher than those either of engag- open to a particular firrn are numerous. They vary frorn each activity being perforrned by
mg m the same activity in the home country and exporting its output from there, or of a separately owned producing entity, or in cooperation with another entity, to the entire
concludmg the transaction with an independent firm in the foreign country. network being under the cornmon ownership of a single hierarchy. But, however they are
organised, the activities in the network are linked by a series of vertical and horizontal
7.3.2 Value-added Networks and MNE Activity transactional relationships. The precise forrn of these relationships will depend on legal
rcquircmcnts, business customs, and other institutional norms, and the perceived strategic
Let us now look at the process of the internationalisation of a firrn. Here we introduce and econornic benefits offered by thern. These are likely to vary considerably between
the concept of the value-added chain (or, as sorne writers, far exarnple, Porter (1980, countries, and in the same country over time.
Entry and expansion strategies oj' MlVEs 209
208 Jnside the multinational ente1prise

The more it is believed that a hierarchical control of successive stages of economjc are undertaken in the home country. A pharmaceuti~al company undertaking the final
actlVlty w1ll benefit the firm rather than using the market or forming coalitions with other d ge preparation' and packing processes as well as the marketmg and drstnbut1on of
firms, the more vertical integration will be the preferred organisational mode. The lower t~:~n~l product in the country of sale might be an example of this kind of firrn. In both
the transaction costs of the contractual relations and the less the production economies mw,S the presumption is that the firm finds 1t less costly to engage m Stages m.and . IVhtof
of internalising transactions, the more the organisation of exchange along a value chaitr duction in a foreign country than in its homé country. Another presumpt10n is t a
is likely to be market orientated. While general conditions of production and distribution p~o firm finds it profitable to engage in the·value-added activity itself rather than license
may favour sorne configurations over others, between industries, there are also notable :h: right to a foreign producer. (If the latter ro u te were chosen, the broken line between
differences within industries, such as in the longstanding preference of General Motors Stages iii and iv would be a continuous line.). . .
to rely on independent suppliers while Ford has at times attempted to integrate the entire product Bis destined far sale in the domest1c market, but 1t 1s assumed that part of the
value chain. Such differences illustrate that the costs of contracting and the costs of inter- value-adding process is imported from a foreign country. The broken transact10n lme md1-
nalisation are dependen! on the institutional assets (Oi) of the firm, and that firms with cates that the market for that intermediate product is internalised. We also assume that
better relational capabilities are likely to experience lower costs over either mode of trans- the entire output of the foreign affiliate is exported to the paren! company, and that the
acting, and in consequence, more flexibility in the design of their value-added activities. latter relies exclusively on its foreign affiliate for the first stage offüe product10n process.
Figure 7.1 illustrates four different kinds of value-added chain of growing complexity. In Case 2, the fact that the first part of the value-added process 1s assumed to be under-
Case 1 assumes that the firm is producing a product (Product A) which has four taken abroad suggests that the MNE is a resource see/cer (see Chapter 3), for example, an
identifiable stages of production (i-iv). Each of these stages may also involve the purchase aluminium company investing in a bauxite mine in the Caribbean, ora rubber company
of support or complementary assets which may be either provided by the firm itself, or seeking to own plantations in Liberia. However, an MNE might no less invest abroad to
purchased from other firms. The output of each stage consists of the value of the inter- take advantage of relatively cheap labour in the later stages of the product10n process (for
mediate goods or services which are either produced by the firm itself or bought from example, investment by a German MNE in the Malaysian semiconductor industry or by
other firms, plus the value added by that firm. Such value added includes the payment for a Japanese firm in the Thai textile industry, which might both 1mport mtermedrnte prod-
both production- and transaction-related activities; it also contains a residue of profit ucts from and export final products to the parent company or home country).
(which might be negative) which accrues to the owners of the firm. For the sake of expos- A final situation is illustrated by Cases 3 and 4. Here, an MNE is assumed to produce
1t10n, we shall assume that all transaction costs are included in the costs of complemen- two products (A and B) in four stages of production which are intended for sale m two
tary assets. No attempt is made to break down the various components of value added foreign countries (1 and 2). Consider the possible dynamics of fore1gn producuon. In Case
(wages, interest, rent and so on). However, these and the prices of intermediate products 3 we assume that the firm undertakes the first stage of production, for example, the R&D
may vary, inter alia according to the quantity of the products bought and sold, and the and design work for each of the products in the home country. Thus it is a multidomestic
efficiency with which they are used to create value-added activities. market-seeking MNE. The next stage of production of both products is concentrated in
A broken line between the boxes indicates that the two activities are under common (foreign) Country !; the final two stages of Product A are produced in. Country.l, and
ownership and that the transactions are internalised. A continuous line indicates that they those of Product B in Country 2. Both products are then sold to thelf domestrc con-
are undertaken by independently owned firms, and that exchange takes place through sumers. In Case 4, we assume that, as a result of (say) the removal of all trade barners
mtermediate product markets. The firm is assumed to be a multi-activity firm (even between the two foreign countries, the firm concentrates its output of Product A m
though it sells only one final product) in that it engages in four stages of the production Country I and of Product B in Country 2 although, for each product, it undertakes part
process. In Stages i and ii, a firm produces only in its home country, although part of this of the first stage of production in the home country and part of the final (for example,
output may be exported. In Stages iii and iv, it produces part of its value added in a foreign sales and distribution) stage in both the home and foreign countries. Case 4 represents a
country and part in the home country. The firm is also assnmed to buy its factor inputs change in the status of the MNE from a market-seeking toan efficiency-seeking investor,
from, and to sel! its final product to, the other market participants. and from a multidomestic to a globally (or regionally) integrated company.
Case 2 in Figure 7.1 takes the analysis a step fnrther. It now assumes that the firm pro- The simple concepts introduced in the previous paragraphs and illustrated in Figure 7.1
duces two end products (A and B) and that, in each case, it engages in four stages of may be extended and refined to cover much more complex value-added networks.
production. In other words, it is a horizontally diversified and a vertically integrated Chapters 8 and 9 will analyse sorne of the organisational strategies of MNEs and the kmd
multi-activity firm. Second, it assumes that at leas! two of the value-adding stages in the of cross-border transactional relationships that they may form w1th thelf affihates andlor
product1on of both products are located in a foreign country. Third, as well as buying with other firms supplying intermediate products, as well as with their other stakeholders
inputs from the factor services market, the firm is assumed to engage in two externa! trans- (for example, suppliers of factor services). In most large MNEs, these relat10nsh1ps range
actions between the appropriate boxes. from spot-market transactions, through a large range of collaborat1ve arrangements wrth
Figure 7'.1 also illustrates the location uf the various stages of value-added activity. other firms, to joint ventures and lOOo/o-owntxl affiliates. . .
Product A 1s mtended for sale in a foreign market. The firm is assumed to produce the As MNEs have become more globally orientated, and as they ongmate from a greater
final two stages of the production process in a foreign country, while the first three stages number of countries, we are observing that even the terms and conditions of non-eqmty
Case J: One product - two countries

Home country Foreign country

Product A
~:~-~''''''''''''.."'''~,,~:''¡''~~~
(iii) (iv) For sa.le in
fore1gn
For sale in
rlornestic market Stages of production market
Stages of production

"'e
~ Case 2: 'J\vo products - two countries

:---------~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::~----------

ProductA
mtm:~-~ 1 1 wtw-~ For sale in
For sale in domestic market foreign
market
·--------------~---~------------~

Product B

,----i--,
(i)
L__J- ~
~ (n)
(iii) (iv) · mMket
Fornloiodom"tw
1
(ii)
1 1
(iii)
J 1
(iv)
1

Case 3: Multidomestic MNE Foreign country (2)


Foreign country (1)

ProductA
R&D
--~:~"'''"'""'"ES'~:-.,
----------------,------~
------------------- ____
¡ R&D 1
supplied

b:o~~:;: - ~: ~:
: : For sale in

conntry(l)
supplied

b;;,~~;;'.;' D :

~-~rnnntry(2)
For sale in

Product B - - -
(ii) (iii) (iv)
(iv) (í)
(i) (ii) (iii)

N
~ Case 4: Regionally integrated MNE
~

PrndnctA~---:~ D D D ~ For sale in Por sale in

~·D D D ~'"~jjfi:~"~T'
(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (i) {ii) (iii) (iv)

Figure 7.1 The value chain: four possible cases


212 Entry and expansión strategifs ·aj· MNEs 213
lnside the n1ultinational enterprise

transactional relationships are increasingly refiecting a myriad of different legal cultu ¡ explaining other motives far FDI. These include much. of resource-seeking investment,
and other insütutional norms of the countries in or between which they are c;nduct;~ asset-seeking (rather than assét-exploiting) investment, and the emergence.of the so-
Thrs, m turn, rs affecting the transaction and production costs of altemative organisationai called 'born global' firms discussed later in this chapter. Nonetheless, we beheve that m
arrangements. Cross-hcensmg agreements - a kind of barter or counter-trade in techno]- drawing attention to the importance of learning in the strategies of firms, the model does
ogy ~ have been commonly practised for many years, as has tire sharing of human capa- usefully emphasise an aspee! of the intemalisation process that continues to be of central
b1ht1es or.physrcal. resource capacrtres between firms. What is noticeable, however, is the importance, although experiential learning is increasingly complemented by other forms
dramatrc mcrease m the nmnber of such collaborative arrangements and the complexity of Iearning in the MNE network.
and mgenmty of them. We. shall take up these rssues m more detail in Chapter 9. The point !ndeed, Iearning through imitation, or as a result of deliberate searching and scanning
we w1sh to emphasrse here 1s that vanous collaborative arrangements not only have affected for new information, is an increasingly importan! part of the knowledge-generating
the content an·d· ownersh1p of the value-added network of particular products and/or of activities of MNEs (Forsgren, 2002). Furthermore, as Delios and Henisz (2003) have
the total actlV!!Ies of firms, but also have heen affected by the incentive structures and shown, institutional factors in the host country, such as the uncertainty over the policy
enforcement mechanisms underpinning the network of activities. It is for this reason if fo environment, or the government's credibility in committing to its policies, also affect the
no other, that we believe this demands a more holistic approach to evaluating th~ OL~ sequencing of investment and the type of learning undertaken by firms. In their study of
configuratron of firms, and the strategic response of managers to these variables. 665 Japanese manufacturing firms in 49 countries, learning from an initial entry concen-
The following section considers sorne of the possible phases in the evolution of an trating on marketing and distribution activities was preferred m low pohcy .uncertamty
MNE from the one prior to the initial act of FDI through to a globally integrated network environments. In high uncertainty environments, MNEs preferred to engage m JOmt ven-
of. cross-border value-added activities. In so doing, it also looks at the alternative strat- tures with local firms. The authors also found that in uncertain political environments,
eg1es open to a firm at each phase of its internationalisation process. MNEs that had made their initial entry usingjoint ventures, were more likely to increase
their resource commitment by investing in a wholly owned affiliate.
To the extent that multinationals are in the process of becoming transnational (Bartlett
7.4 ANALYSIS OF THE INTERNATIONALISATION PROCESS and Ghoshal, 1989), or metanational (Doz et al., 2001 ), so that the firm coordinates an
interdependent network of intra- and inter-firm relationships, the objective of which is
7.4.l Introduction knowledge and institutional integration within the firm, the absence of indirect forms of
Ieaming in the process model is indeed a major deficiency. However, these criticisms and
There can be no doubt of the growing plurality of the routes towards the globalisation of qualifications notwithstanding, we believe that the stages model of gradually mcreasmg
product10n and markets. Nor can it be disputed that changes in the externa! economic and resource commitment still serves as a useful starting-point, particularly in the earher
technological environment over the last decade have fostered a sharp increase in the geo- stages of the internationalisation process, and in the case of less experienced, often
graph1cal. drvers1ficat10n of the origin of MNEs, and the countries in which they Iocate smaller firms. Further insight into the factors facilitating the internationalisation process
the!f affihates (see Chapter 2). Consequently, a schematic representation of the inter- is offered by a network approach to understanding the evolvement of MNE activity,
nat10nahsat10n process is likely to be useful in so far as it describes the possible alterna- which we examine in the following subsection.
trve.s,. rather than as a depiction of the actual process of internationalisation of any
md1v1dual firm. 7.4.3 A Network Approach to the Multinational Firm
We shaU begin om discussion by briefiy reviewing sorne critica! aspects of the process
theory of mternatronahsat10n d1scussed in Chapter 4. This theory relates experiential A complementary approach to the dynamics of the OLI configuration of firms was ini-
learmng by firms to a pattern of gradually increasing international resource commitment tially taken by organisational scholars who stressed the firm-spec1fic advantages wh1ch
coupled with a widening geographical pattern of MNE activity. This discussion is ro1'. arise from being part of a network of complementary activities, and who viewed the inter-
lowed by a brief introduction to the modern MNE as a network, which is necessary to nationalisation process as one which is dependen! on the advantages of cooperative cross-
apprecmte the variety of configurations of organisational coordination and control that border relationships - especially between buyers and sellers. The thesis of the early
multmallonal firms adopt when they engage in cross-border activities. Chapters 8 and 9 network scholars (far example, Johanson and Mattson, 1987a, 1987b) was that, since
wrll d1scuss these organisational features of the MNE in more detail. firms are dependen! on each other in the networks in which they operate, their activities
need to be coordinated. However, rather than this coordination being determined by the
7.4.2 Learning in the Internationalisation Process market or individual hierarchies, it is fashioned by the web of transactions, forged by firms
engaging in a series of bilateral exchange relationships. Since these relationships are likely
In Chapter 4, we argued that while the process theory of internationalisation developed to take time and effort to establish and develop, Lheir precise form w11l dcpend not JUSI on
by the U ppsala school was useful m understanding the initial expansion process of many the immediate interests of the firm, but on how it affects the efficiency of the network as
market-seekmg MNEs, part1cularly from small home countries, it was Iess relevan! to a whole (and hence, in the long run, its own efficiency).
214 lnside the multinational enterprise Entry and expans"ion strategies aj· MNEs 215

With the expanding geographical reach of many contemporary MNEs, substantial The following subsections take an incremental appr~ach to the process of internation-
changes have occurred in the systemic organisation of firms, sorne of which can best be alisation of value-added activities by firms, but it should be stated_ at the outset that the
characterised in terms of networks. As we have discussed, in addition to the changing sequen ce of events to be described, and illustrated m Figure 7.2, is not necessanly that
configuration of their administrative structures, the boundaries of the MNE have which a given firm will follow. Resource-seekmg MNEs are, for example, hkely to pursue
become more porous, and have incorporated many forms of equity and non-equity rela- different path of internationalisation from market- or asset-seekmg MNEs. The steps
tionships, such as joint ventures and strategic alliances. While sorne firms have long since a have set out should be taken asan illustration of increasing foreign resource commit-
had cooperative relationships with certain suppliers or customers, or indeed with par- w:nts and complexities of cross-border coordination. While sorne firms may well _go
ticular governments, we believe that, in addition to the growth in inter-firm collabora- :rough the five phases identified, others, depending inter alia on thelf motives for foreign
tive activity, the inf!uence of the activities of national regulators, NGOs and other economic involvement, may leapfrog over one or more p~ases; There is als~ no ~nd1cat1on
non-market actors on the firm has increased significantly along with global reach. In of how long it might take afirm to proceed through any given phase. Later m this chapter,
Chapter 5, we suggested that the relational capabilities derived from the firm's institu-. for example, we shall give sorne attention to both 'born _g_Iobal' firms; and also to those
tional assets (Oi) are used in part to manage these demands. We shall return to this issue which venture abroad primarily to access new cornpetitive (or 0-specific) advantages
in Part IV. ther than to better exploit existing advantages. Moreover, as the final sect10n of_ this
ra . ·1dt
The adoption of the terminology of networks is one way for scholars to try to come to chapter will show, established and globally orientated_MNEs are mcreasmg Y a op mg a
terms with the complexity that presents itself in the organisation and operations of Iuralistic and integrated approach to their modahlles of entenng new markets, or
p . . t
MNEs. At their most general, such networks are similar to the network models of linear responding to changes in the global economic environmen . .
programming, where series of nodes are connected by different carrying capacities, and While the phases depicted here are more dlfectly apphcable to market-seebng manu-
one is looking for the optima! way to push resources through the network. Sorne nodes facturing firms, we shall also attempt to incorporate the different pha_ses of mternat10n-
are usually better connected than others, and if such nodes represen! affiliates or business alisation of service firrns, which as Chapter 2 has revealed, are becommg_ an mcreasmgly
divisions of the firm, these are of greater strategic significance within the MNE network. importan! kind of MNE activity. To the extent possible, we shall also indicate the kmd of
On the other hand, if parts of the network are not connected, there are said to be struc- entry mode (greenfield, acquisition, joint venture), that might be prevalen! m each phase,
tural holes in the configuration. depending on the motivation for the investment (see Chapter 3). We shall a_Iso note when,
Increasingly, what is being transferred between the different members of the network, instead of FDI, alliances or Iicensing might be a preferred way to service the foreign
in addition to intermediate goods and finished products, is ali kinds of knowledge. market.
Indeed, we might say we live in an age of alliance or knowledge capitalism (Dunning,
1997a; Dunning and Boyd, 2003). However, the kind of knowledge that is likely to be both 7.4.4 Phase 1: Exports and Foreign Sourcing
valuable and rare is tacit knowledge, that is, that embodied in people and organisations,
and in the learning relationships and shared experiences which people and organisations Firms initially engage in transactions across national boundaries for one of :wo reasons.
have with each other (Cantwell, 199lb; Spender, 1996). Since valuable knowledge is fre- The first is to acquire income-generating assets, or inputs into their value cham, ata lower
quently tied to skilled employees and to local institutional mores, a great deal of it tends real cost than they can from domestic sources. The second is to protect existmg, or seek
to be location specific. The challenge for the MNE then becomes to absorb the locally gen- out new, markets for the output of their domestic value-adding activities. In both cases,
erated knowledge held by its foreign affiliates, and to leverage it with the financia! and however the decision to become international is normally just one of severa! strategic
other resources available within the firm (Birkinshaw, 1996; Birkinshaw and Hood, 1998; options ~ firrn may pursue. For example, the resources and capabilities which a firm uses
Holm and Pedersen, 2000). From a structural perspective, the multinational has to find a in seeking and servicing foreign markets might be better spent on diversifymg mto new
way to coordinate its disparate parts in a way that allows it to pursue current market lines of activity in the home market, upgrading its supply capabihties, irnprovmg product-
opportunities, while at the same time, being able to reach and 'tap into' various Iocation- ivity in its domestic factories, or acquiring other indigenous compames. Alternal!vely, a
specific resources abroad. These changes in the structure and management of MNE firm seeking to acquire new assets by way of an M&A may choose to do so by engagmg
affiliates will be discussed further in Chapter 8. in a non-equity a!liance with a foreign firrn. There is always sorne uncertamty about the
In addition to describing the systemic structure of an MNE, a network approach also costs involved in entering into a cross-border business relationship, and while sorne firms
allows us to emphasise the issues of control and coordination, and their institutional may opt to engage in such a relationship as a strategic choice, otliers may be pushed by
underpinnings, which lie somewhere between the arm's-length transactions of the market, changes in the market for intermediate goods, or, indeed, that for the final product.
and administrative fiat within the firm. This is particularly pertinent when one extends the Although Phase I does not involve any FDI, there are, nonetheless, a number of pos-
analysis from within the firm to encompass a number of different actors outside of the sible ways a firm can becorne linked to cross-border activity. Consider just four cases. The
firm, whether they be suppliers, customers or competitors. The economics of these coop- first is where a firm wishes to outsource the production of int~rrnetl1ate 111puts, or the final
erative inter-firm relationships, such as joint ventures and strategic alliances, will be dis- product itself, to a firm in a foreign country that enjoys a cost advantage as compared to
cussed in more detail in Chapter 9. domestic production. Indeed, the growth of contractual outsourcmg is a hallmark of the
Entry an,d expansion strategies. of MN Es 217

contemporary form of globalisation, and it is likely to encompass ¡¡ot just the outsourc-
ing of intermediate manufacturing inputs, such as components or subassemblies, but also
that of services, such as call centres. 280 Interestingly, even before the curren! expansion of
outsourcing operations, Korhonen et al. (1996) discovered that more than half of the
Finnish SMEs that internationalised in the l 970s and. l 980s, entered Phase 1 through
imports of machinery, raw materials, componen ts and final goods to be resold, rather
than through exporting.
The second case is where a firm wishes to export its goods to a new foreign market .
.3 M
o However, because of its relative ignorance or the uncertainties about the local demand
iEo ·o
o il ~ conditions, a new entran! - particularly if it is a small firm - might wish to avoid the risks
.g •
ii
·~ -~
"'
o
o
o "o.o~ in making an investment in a foreign sales or purchasing outlet. Instead, it may prefer to
8 buy the services of a local sales agent, that is, make use of the externa! market. On the
í?o iEo o N

o
o
"'•
1l z
E
g
g ü
.g other hand, where a market has to be created for a product, where the product needs to
ü
o M "
o
·o & ~ be adapted to the requirements of the local huyers, where multiple products are being
·§
o ~
o
·.g .'!

E
,,"
o·- .8
Cl
marketed and there are net benefits to coordinating the sales of these products, or where
an efficient after-sales usage, repair and maintenance service is a key ingredient of the
º'
_,
""
lL
8 § o o'
5, "o
·- '
o
g
~'
f'
o
·¡g product's appeal, a firm may decide that the risk that a foreign sales agent will not ade-
'8" .go º' '
~
quately meet its needs is likely to outweigh any setting up costs of marketing and distri-
"
o "-' 'E
B.E
'O ·¡:
o .;'.:
-
""'
o
'""'' ~-
bution facilities from the start (a Phase 2 entry). Chapter 6, for example, gave sorne
t:: " '' bistorical illustrations. of this form of entry by British MNEs into foreign markets.
.
"
o~

"'~
" o
'" o
'" ' The third kind of value-added activity consists of the production of goods ora service,
~ ·ª
~ i':;
the buying or selling of which requires a regular and continuing association betweeu the
<(,\? parties to the exchange. This is the case where the product is idiosyncratic, is sold in smal!
""o
o quantities, or is irregularly traded. Here, an initial market entry might take place directly
·HE with a supplier or a customer, even though the firm may use the services of a foreign
~ ·~ broker to help it search for, or negotiate with, such suppliers or customers. Thus firrns
» ¿ '6
"
o
o
oo o
·o
o transacting non-standardised interrnediate products (including proprietary rights and
o
o managerial services) will tend to sell these products (for example, license the rights to their

E "~ '
' use) to other firrns which they perceive will best advance their own interests. By contras!,
o ''
o: ~
firrns buying 'custorn rnade' products frorn foreign suppliers will tend to develop ongoing
to
~
~
o
"2 8 -~ contractual relationships with their suppliers. The OEM producers involved as suppliers
o. "'~
Cl
~ in an outsourcing relationship are likely to fall into this category; and in due course, sorne
'' - - - - i§
""'
of thern rnay evolve into global producers in their own right, as for exarnple was the case

E "" .9"2'"
00
2:
with Acer (Leung and Yip, 2003).
The fourth type of Phase 1 entry is one where the firrn generares an output which is
. N

~ -·
1,;
7 ~
o
"[ "' _¡;,.
00
~
~

difficult or irnpossible to trade across space. Since sorne products and services cannot be
"
~
o. ~
o. li
o.
~
¡f ]~
o. -
~

•o "'
"
transported over space, a foreign entry rnust take the forrn either of an FDI (Phase 3-5
entry) or, if the interrnediate products are tradable, of a contractual agreernent with a pro-
E ~
"'o '9 ducing firrn in that country. Such contractual agreernents include turnkey construction
¡;¡
E
o "'"'-< projects - such as the construction of a highway or a power station in Africa by Chinese
""'" ~"
construction co1npanies - or licensing agreements for hotel chains or franchising agree-
ments for food and/or beverage service chains such as McDonald's or Starbncks. In
"o
" "'
<'.
"'
Phase 1 entry the construction cornpany has no perrnanent presence in the foreign loca-
tion, while thc liccnce or franchise owner has little orno involvement in the day-to-day
~
"
~
~ ~"'
management of its licensees or franchisees, but instead earns income due to the exchange
of an interrnediate product (for exarnple, codifiable knowledge).
216
218 Inside the niultinational enterprise Entry and expansion strategies aj· J\fNEs 219

However, if the construction company in the previous example set upa marketing office trade-related activities. The most familiar hazards are those commonly associated_ with
for the purposes of obtaining new contracts, this would constitute a Phase 2 entry, and if rincipal/agent problems, especially where a particular agent serves many prmcipals.
it set up an office that coordinated al leas! sorne aspects of project management for a ~hese include the costs of ensuring that the distributor or import merchant operates m
variety of different projects, this would constitute a Phase 3, 4 or 5 entry, depending on the best interests of the exporting or importing company (which may mclude not advanc-
the complexity and range of tasks handled by the local African affiliate. Similarly, when- ing the interests of the latter's competitors). · .
ever McDonald's or Starbucks actually own and operate their affiliates abroad, this rep- Again, it is not difficult to identify the interna! and externa! factors affectmg the strat-
resents a Phase 3-5 entry. A special case are services where the buyer has to travel to the egy of firms which might cause them to switch from usmg foreign sales_ or purchasmg
country in which the service is produced, as in the case of an Australian tourist seeking agents to setting up or acqmnng marketmg or purchasmg facil!ties of the!I own. Clearly,
to purchase the services of a hotel in Fiji. In this case, the Fijian hotel owner earns invisi- if a firm did not choose the !alter route m the first place, its post-entry country-specific
ble exports as the service is paid for in foreign currency, and if the hotel is part of a fran- learning experiences and its growth in sales might cause the balance of advantages
chised chain, the franchise owner will have earned its contractual share as well. between using an interna! and externa! market to shift in favour of the former. While there
In terms of resources transferred abroad, Phase l invo!ves a minimal commitment and is nothing inevitable about this process, it is likely that the more familiar and experienced
relies heavily on contractual modes. While a firm selling its output to intermediaries ~ay, a firm is, and the larger the buying or selling stake it has in a particular country (for
m due course, wish to expand its activities by investing in foreign marketing and distri- example, with respect to the volume and type of products traded), the more it will prefer
bution, or by expanding the stages of value added performed abroad, a firm sourcing to own its marketing and distribution networks. At the same time, trade-related FDI may
mputs from abroad may be content with long-term contractual agreements with suppli- be undertaken by specialist trading companies, the larger of which may also perform a
ers, ~r it may wish to exert more control and to invest in its own facilities for foreign pro- wide range of business services germane to both imports and exports. 282
duct10n either via an acquisition or a greenfield investment. Much will depend on the For example, in their study of 276 Danish firms, Pedersen et al. (2002) found that
characteristics of the targeted market, the kinds of goods and services being produced between 1992 and 1997, 17% had switched from using an independent export mtermedi-
and traded, the market structures in which firms compete, and the nature of the cross- ary to an own sales organisation to serve foreign markets. As the firm gained more experi-
border transactional mechanisms. The literature suggests that the value and significance ence of the foreign market, it was more likely to invest in its own sales orgamsat10n, but
of these variables will be strongly influenced by country-specific economic, political, insti- this was tempered by the presence of switching costs, in the form of contractual restric-
tutional and cultural considerations. Firm-specific factors, such as the technical and tions and possible loss of customers ('take-down' costs), as well as the cost of setting up
managerial capabilities of the investing firm, its potential stake in the new market, its an own marketing and distribution affiliate.
knowledge about competitors or potential competitors and the quality of the institutions However, for companies of all nationalities, FDI in trade-related activities is importan!,
of host countries, will also be relevan!. Indeed, as it influences the determinants of trade although the share of wholesaling and retailing in the outward FDI stock in services has
and production, so the configuration of OLI advantages facing firms will affect their declined from 17% in 1990 to 10% in 2004, dueto the explosive growth of FDI m other
initial entry strategies in to foreign markets.281 service sectors (UNCTAD, 2006). Often these affiliates are parts of primary or secondary
producing firms. In 1982, for example, as muchas 52% of all US-owned trade-relat_ed
7.4.5 Phase 2: Investment in Marketing and Distribution foreign investments were owned by non-service (mainly manufacturmg) compames
(UNCTC, 1989). In J 999, non-service MNEs accounted for 41 % of US outward FDI m
Apart from firms for whom the purchasing or selling of their products can only be accom- services, and in 2000, for 10% in Germany (UNCTAD, 2004:105). Such services consist
plished through sorne kind of physical presence in a foreign market, those seeking to of the trading, marketing and financia! services attached to exports from the home
acquire an existing foreign company, or !hose who are selling or buying in specialised or country or those supporting the sales of a foreign affiliate in the local market.
unfamiliar markets where local expertise is especially valuable, most firms regard the use Trade-, and marketing-related FDI, of course, covers a wide . spectrum offunct10ns,
. 283
of foreign agents and distributors as a first step towards both market- and resource- and a firm may choose different entry routes for organising different functions.
seeking (but not usually efficiency- or asset-seeking) FDI. The reasons why firms might Advertising responsibilities, for example, might be subcontracted to a specialist foreign
wish to internalise the market for selling the output of their va!ue-added activities reduce firm while after-sa!es servicing activities might be internalised. The maior mterna\lonal
to a trade off between the advantages of securing control over the form, the quality and airline companies own their own maintenance and repair facilities at sorne airports) while
terms of those activities, and the risks associated with the commitment of the resources at others they buy these services from independent local firms. Japan's soga shosha
involved.
(general trading companies) offer a synergistic and tightly controlled package of tradmg
To the neoclassical economist, the choice is primarily a matter of the efficiency of alter- activities, in contras\ to the marketing of Hong Kong and Taiwanese products, which
natJve organisational n1odes in maximising revenues and minin1ising costs, which include tends to be dispersed among a large number of independent trading firms (Bilis, 2001 ). In
both production and transaction costs. The two obvious advantages of using forcign rccent years, howcver) the trade facilitating role of the sogo shosha has declined, particu-
brokers are first, their familiarity with and experience of local institutions and demand or lar!y in relation to exports, as Japanese MNEs are undertaking more of the marketing and
supply conditions, and second, their ability to exploit economies of scale and scope of distribution function themselves (UNCTAD, 2004:133). As in the goods-producing
220 Inside the n1ultinational enterprise Entry and expansion strategies of )\1NEs 221

sector, the form of organisation chosen will depend on its perceived impact on the international ventures, affects the process of intemationalisation (Gabrielsson and
revenue-earning capacity of the MNE and the relevan! production and transactional Kirpalani, 2004; Knight and Cavusgil, 2004; Kuemn'lerle, 2005). 286
costs involved. Broadly speaking, the greater the presence or likelihood of market failure Judging the fu]] impact of such firms is complicated by the fact that there is no agreed-
in the various trading functions, the more likely these will be internalised within MNEs. upon definition of what length of time 'born' refersto, and exactly how the global nature
Another case of a Phase 2 entry is that of a firm which, in order to efficiently exploit of these firms is to be interpreted. To the extent that they normally supply a narrow
any competitive advantage it may possess, must combine these advantages with others range of products or services, have low levels of resources committed outside their
possessed by a firm or groups of firms in a foreign country. Thus, for example, a US firm domes tic borders, and engage in exports as their primary cross-border activity, we would
looking to export to the Chinese market may need to engage in a collaborative venture consider these 'global' firms to be more like those identified in Phases 1-3 of our scheme.
with a local firm to access the appropriate distribution channels. In such cases, while the Indeed, while 'born globals' typically eam a significan\ proportion of their revenue from
firm might desire to gain the full control obtained through internalising the marketing and abroad in the first few years, evidence on lsraeli 'born globals' suggests that, in many
distribution function, opaque business practices and exclusive local networks might make other ways, these firms are following a relatively conventional process of gradually
it impossible to serve the market without having a local partner. increasing resource commitment to foreign markets, where the establishment of mar-
It should also be recalled that investment in trade-related activities might sometimes be keting affiliates abroad is an essential step in their internationalisation process (Hashai
a first step to the foreign production of goods and services. Indeed, the firm may already and Almor, 2004).
be engaged in such activities in other countries. Warehousing is an example. lt is only a
small step from the storage of finished goods to the holding of intermediate products or 7.4.6 Phase 3: Foreign Production of Intermediate Goods and Services
kits of parts, which require sorne inspection, assembling and packaging before being sold
to the domestic or export market. Moreover, a trade-related presence may provide a firm While Phase 2 is a critica! step in the evolution of an MNE, both in its own right and
with a better idea of its own capacity for foreign production, or that of local firms to because it can lead to further FDI, the amount of resources and capabilities committed
supply its intermediate inputs. It might also offer the firman insight into foreign technol- is usually quite small. This is likely to change quite dramatically as and when a firm starts
ogy, institutions and organisational structures, and also in to the kind of product adapt- to engage in the foreign production of goods or services, as opposed to facilitating the sale
ations that need to be made to meet the demands of foreign customers. In short, a or purchase of goods and services already produced. For many (but not ali) manufac-
trade-related or marketing affiliate may provide a potential foreign investor with a useful turing firms, initial greenfield (but not acquired) market-seeking activity tends to be in
insight into the prospects and opportunities for foreign production and, in so doing, comparatively low value-adding activities, which are usually at the final assembling or
reduce the set-up and transaction costs associated with that production. For example, in initial processing stage of the value-adding chain. As and when local or regional markets
a detailed case study of a medium-sized Norwegian firm, Welch et al. (2002) found that enlarge, the economic viability of setting up or acquiring a foreign production facility is
purchasing connections made by it in Russia sorne years earlier were instrumental at a likely to increase.
later stage in providing the firm with the connections and credibility that were required to The extent to which this actually leads to FDI largely depends on the types of inter-
obtain market access in that country. mediate ar final products supplied, the nature of production processes utilised, and the
At the same time, it is also possible that instead of the exporter expanding from the pro- quality of the local supply capabilities. If the domestic production process is capital inten-
vision of goods to related services such as warehousing, this can better be undertaken by sive, or demands a lot of specialised equipment and highly trained labour, and if it cannot
other specialist firms in the exporting country. Far example, firms such as ATL Logistics be easily scaled down, then it may be a long time before local production is started. If the
in Hong Kong are increasingly undertaking the sorting and labelling of goods for cloth- optimum scale of plant is small and local inputs are readily and cheaply available, then
ing retailers before they leave China, so that these can be shipped directly to stores in the foreign production may not only replace exports atan early stage; it may also be the initial
importing country. Alternatively, a company such as NYK Logistics in Shanghai may modality of entry into the foreign market. lt should be observed that the optimmn leve!
shrink-wrap goods intended for individual supermarkets, so that they can be processed and locational requirements of production are likely to vary between the different stages
more efficiently at the importing company's warehouse. 284 of value-added activity, as, indeed, may the cross-border transport and transaction costs
Finally, we need to consider a type of global firm whose internationalisation process associated with these and other value-added activities.
has been accelerated, the so-called 'born global' firms. 285 These are often technology- Figure 7.2 depicts Phase 3 investment where a particular part of the manufacturing or
intensive start-up firms serving niche markets that have adopted flexible structures that service process is transferred from the home country to a foreign country. Thus foreign
can reach suppliers and customers around the world from their very inception (Madsen value-added activity might take the place of exports, or of its domestic equivalen! where
and Servais, 1997). Beginning with Oviatt and McDougal's (1994) study of international the FDI is intended to supply products to the domestic market, in place of either domes-
new ventures, research on international entrepreneurship has explored small firm inter- tic production or production which might be undertaken by local firms in the foreign
nationalisation, particularly in high-technology fields. These studies have sought to country. On the other hand, foreign production might supplement, orbe quite independ-
evaluate which channels are available for 'born globals' to reach international markets, ent of, its domestic counterpart. ln any, or ali, of these cases, either a completely new (that
and how their limited and often highly specialised resources, and the structuring of the is, greenfield) value-added facility may be set up or an existing facility acquired.
222 Inside the multinalional enterprise Entry ,and expansion strateg¡es of MNEs 223

. With. the advent of the interne! and improved telecommunications' it is becomI·ng In the older models, trade and licensing were assumed to prm;de foreign production,
1ncre~s1ngly economic to source many services, such as customer call centres, back-office rather than being perceived as a learning experience of the input and output markets in
funct10ns and computer programming, from abroad. In such cases, the production of the foreign countries, or, in the case of trade in intermediate products (for example, licensing
service rn located m places with a suitably trained and cost-competitive workforce, while or subcontracting), of foreign production as well. However, this experience value of non-
the service Ilself can be transferred asan intermediate input back to the originating firm equity forms of cross-border transactions has been noted in various empirical studies, and
or extended directly to customers around the world. BT's decision in 2003 to locate it' lies at the core of the Uppsala school theory of internationalisation discussed earlier.
directory_ enquiries service to a cal! centre in India is an example of the latter, while th:. Since learning does play a role, a firm's knowledge of foreign markets and production con-
outsourcmg of Philips', financia! services centre to Poland in 2004 is an intermediate input ditions is often a function of time, and the extent and form of prior foreign involvement.
of the Phase 3 vanety. In both cases, the outsourcing of intermediate services was made But other variables, such as the size of the firm and its interaction with local trading and
by greenfield investment in a foreign location. In other instances, where the MNE no other enterprises, may be no less importan t. As we have already discussed, a Phase 2 mar-
longer feels it necessary or beneficia! to maintain hierarchical control over such activities keting affiliate may provide a potential foreign_ investor with a useful insight into the
outscoring may be contractual and hence of a Phase 1 kind. In that case, a cal! centre in' prospects and opportunities for foreign production and, in so doing, reduces the set-up
say, India may be operated either by a local firm, or by a large contrae! service provide; and transaction costs associated with that production.
such as the US firm Convergys, which has set up affiliates in a number of developing coun-
tries (UNCTAD, 2004:158). 7.4.7 Phase 4: Deepening and Widening of the Value-added Network
Where do_es licensing the property rights of the internationalising firm to a foreign pro-
ducer enter mto the picture? In our analysis of initial entry in Phase 1, we have treated the While firms in Phase 3 perform intermediate processing, such as assembly abroad, firms
export of property rights in the same way as the export of final goods. However, if a in Phase 4 perform all the tasks related to producing a final good, and engage in the mar-
company previously exporting final goods to its own marketing affiliates now finds, for one keting and distribution of the final product, whether in the host market or for export.
reason or another, that it is strategically or economically desirable to produce part or al! Using local technology and creative inputs to develop new products, the affiliate can gain
of thes_e_goods in a foreign counüy, but that it is best to do so by concluding a licensing or what is known as a 'product mandate', giving ita more importan! role in the multinational
franchismg agreement With a foreign firm, then the firm will replace the export of the final network as compared to a simple assembly operation. In Phase 4, foreign affiliates control
good by an export of an intermediate product or service, for example, codifiable know- most stages of the value chain, engage in their own sourcing, and can begin to develop
ledge. The final product will then be produced in the foreign location by an unaffiliated the kinds of contractual and cooperative connections that make them insiders in the host
firm, and subsequently sold to the firm's own marketing affiliate (combined Phase ¡ and 2 market. In general, while Phase 4 internationalisation is more focused on the capabilities
entry). However, if the firm decides to establish its own foreign assembling affiliate (either of the affiliates themselves, in Phase 5, more attention is paid to the integration of the
ª. greenfíeld venture oran acquisition), we have a Phase 3 entry, with the output being sold affi!iates into the MNE network. One factor that generally separates Phase 4 affiliates
either through the firm's own marketing and distribution affiliate, or by an independent from those in Phase 5 is the role of innovatory activities. Affiliates in Phase 4 would nor-
agent. It IS also possible that the assembling affiliate is the result of a joint venture with a mally rely on R&D carried out in the home country of the MNE, orinan affiliate centre
foreign partner, as is the case of much of manufacturing investment in China, as a result of excellence in another host country. Consequently, in Figure 7.2, Phase 4 is denoted by
of ownership restrictions imposed by the host government (Buckley et al., 2004). a transfer of all but the R&D stage of production to the host country.
The literature on the choice between producing a particular good or service in a domes- Entry into Phase 4 often represents a continuation of the process of maturing of the
tic production facility and exporting it from there, or producing it in the country in which foreign affiliate which was previously engaged in intermediate processing in Phase 3. Such
Il IS sold (or m a third country) is extensive, and reference was made to it in Chapter 4. activities usually require the least investment in human competences, physical capital and
Most of these studies emphasise the role of comparative manufacturing, organisational institutional infrastructure, and hence tend to involve the least risk. If successful, and if
and marketmg costs of exporting and local production, as well as expectations about and when markets expand, local supply capabilities improve, or host governments offer
future market size and growth, transport costs, government-related trade barriers and more incentives, then more of the upstream higher value-added activities set out in Figure
incentives and/or disincentives offered to foreign direct investors. In a seminal ~aper, 7.2 may be transferred from the home to the host country. The more value-added activ-
Buckley and Casson (1981) suggested that the point of switching would be negatively cor- ities can be adapted to the particular supply capabilities and market needs of the foreign
related With the relative importance of set-up and recurren! fixed costs to the total pro- country, and can benefit from a congenia! innovatory environment, the more foreign pro-
duct10n costs of the mvestmg firms, as well as the ways in which increasing familiarity with duction is likely to start earlier than it otherwise would. Moreover, over time, many
a foreign market may mftuence the choice of how best to service that market. In addition of these capabilities can be elevated by improved training and education, upgrading the
they argued that licensing was likely to be the preferred servicing mode whenever cross'. quality of resources, devolving more entrepreneurial responsibilities to local managers,
border transport and tariff costs and the intra-firm governance costs of FDJ, wcrc high. networking with indigenous firms, as well as by the provision of appropriate support facil-
As and when these latter costs fell, they argued, firms might be tempted to switch their ities (for example, roads, utilities, telecommunications) and the development of more-
foreign involvement from licensing to FDI. efficient production methods and organisational techniques.
224 lnside the multinational enterprise Entry rind expansion strategfes aj· MNEs 225

Sometimes these improvements may be undertaken by the firms themselves, and case, such sequen tia! investment will normally take place through an acquisition, merger
sometimes they are provided by national or regional governments financed by regional ar strategic alliance:
or international agencies, such as the World Bank or the Asian Development Bank. Another form of sequential invólvement is for an MNE, which has successfully pene-
Chapter 1Owill show that as countries move through various stages of the development trated one foreign market, to move into another (usually adjacent) market, which is con-
process, their capacity to attract inward investment changes, as is most recently illus- sisten! with the learning argument advanced by the Uppsala school. In her historical
trated by the rising share of inbound MNE activity now being attracted to Central and analysis, Wilkins (1970, 1974) tells of how in the 19th and early 20th centuries the markets
Eastern Europe and China (UNCTAD, 2006). Furthermore, both positive incentive in successive Latin American countries were penetrated by American MNEs. Investment
structures (for example, tax concessions, investment allowances, regional subsidies, by leading European MNEs in sub-Saharan Africa at the time followed a similar pattern
bilateral investment agreements) and negative incentives (for example, threat of loss of (Franko, 1976; Archer, 1986). Both the geographical and industrial structure of Asian
markets as a result of government procurement schemes designed to favour local pro- MNE activity in Europe has considerably widened since the first foray by Japanese firms
ducers, import controls, and the ad verse actions of competitors) could encourage into the UK in the early 1970s. Most recently of all, the ripple effect of the learning
impel firms to find ways of producing locally, and of incurring the relevan! adjustment process involved in FDI is being demonstrated by the increasing number of European
costs. 287 countries in which Central and Eastern European MNEs have a presence (UNCTAD,
In the case of resource-seeking FDI, which is primarily prompted by the presence of 2006).
L-bound endowments, the initial entry is intended less to replace existing import markets Furthermore, the kinds of adjustments undertaken by firms can be country or indus-
and more to internalise them. While the locational options for the secondary processing try specific. An example of the latter is the case of Japanese automotive firms, whose
of the natural resources are often wider, these downstream operations frequently require keiretsu-type advantages have been successfully transplanted to the automol!ve mdustry
more sophisticated human and physical assets than are initially possessed by many of the in the US, while Japanese electronics manufacturers have adapted much more to the pre-
countries that own the resources. Again, as economic development proceeds and the vailing standards in the US market (Kenney and Florida, 1995; Kotabe et al., 2003).
experience of the foreign affiliates engaged in primary prodnction increases, the parent Overall, as the kind of investment undertaken by Japanese MNEs in the US and Europe
companies may be willing to invest more in secondary processing operations, particularly has evolved towards more knowledge-seeking investment, the traditional buyer-supplier
if prompted by host governments. Examples include forward vertical integration by US relationships have become less importan! than other cooperative relationships for the
crude oil producers in Canada into refining and petrochemical operations, MNEs success of the investment (Mason and Encarnation, 1994; Morgan et al., 2002).
engaged in mining in South Africa expanding in to the processing of aluminium, steel, and Increasingly, it would seem that foreign investors have become 'insiders', either by
titanium, and Korean-owned fishing companies in Canada and the US going into fish undertaking an increasing proportion of their sales themselves or, depending on the rela-
processing operations (UNCTAD, 2007). tive production and transaction costs, by buying them from local firms in the local market.
The sequential growth of MNE activity in this phase may take severa! forms. These The completion of the interna! market in Europe and the setting up of NAFTA in North
include increased FDI in different value-added stages or expanding the number of prod- America has stimulated this transition. The maturing of foreign production is also coin-
ucts produced in one location, or expansion into multiple host countries, ora combina- ciding with the increasing autonomy of MNE affiliates, and their expanded role as 'learn-
tion of one or more of these elements. 288 Such growth may take the form of an acquisition ing' affiliates within the multinational firm (Birkinshaw, 1996; Birkinshaw et al., 1998;
or merger, oran extension of the firm's existing facilities. An example is a widening of the Holm and Pedersen, 2000). Such affiliates may not only actas disseminating channels of
range of products produced by foreign affiliates. In this case, the number of value-added the technology and organisational practices of their paren!, but also con tribute to the gen-
chains in which there is a componen! of foreign production is increased. A t first, the value- eration of new knowledge both from their own R&D facilities and by accessing that of
added activities of a greenfield facility are likely to be a truncated version of those under- other firms.
taken in the home country. In such cases, the output of the foreign affiliatc is confined to Furthermore, sequential investment by the MNE in existing operations, which is often
supplying the products that offer the best (and most secure) rates of return, while other at leas! partly financed by reinvested earnings, is also likely to increase as MNE invest-
products supplied by the MNE may continue to be imported from the parent company or ment becomes more mature. In spite of its ernpirical significance, the issue of reinvestment
another foreign affiliate. This could (though not necessarily) lead to other products being has not received a great deal of attention in the literature. 289 One exception is a study on
produced. For example, when Japanese electronics firms entered the US market in the late 70 MNE affiliates in the UK by Mudambi (1998), which showed that those which had
1970s and 1980s, they did so by first entering in their core business areas, and subseq uently been established the longest were more likely to invest again in the same host location as
expanding into non-core areas, using prior investment as a platform for future investment compared to more recent entran!& Another study of 194 Japanese electronics affiliates
(Chang, 1995; Kogut and Chang, 1996). in Korea, Taiwan and Singapore by Song (2002) found that such affiliates continued to
More generally, such a widening of the product base (that is, horizontal diversification operate, and evento invest, in the face of adverse developments in production conditions,
of the affiliate) is likely to occur either where there are opportunities of economies of particularly in respect of wage increases between 1988 to 1994. His study suggests that it
scope to the affiliate as well as to the paren! company, or where, for offensive or defensive is not just local experience in terms of duration that contributes to upgrading, but that
strategic reasons, an MNE perceives a need to diversify its foreign asset base. In this latter investment in firm-specific capabilities and local sourcing also plays a role. Interestingly,
226 Inside the n1ultinational enterprise Entry and expansion strar.e~ies oj' MNEs 227

in his sample, the Japanese electronics firms were more likely to upgrade their operations ration and water and sewage systems sorne FDI has been involved, in addition to
gene . ' .
m Smgapore than m Taiwan and Korea, which may have been due to policies pursuect b : build-operate-and-transfer contracts and manag_ement contracts. .
the Smgaporean government to induce MNEs to upgrade their local capabilities. y· Finally, we might ma.ke note of an rnrne that is the wunterpart to our focus on mter-
It is also often the case that both resource- and market-seeking foreign investment by national expansion. This is the issue of d1vestment, wh1ch may take place e1ther_as a result
one group of firms m1ght encourage mvestment by others (the 'gold rush' to invest in of the poor performance of a foreign affiliate, or due to a strateg1c reorgamsatwn w1thm
Chma in the 1990s is a case in point). In Chapter 4 we discussed the 'follow the leader'. the MNE. 2" A study by Benito (1997) on a_sample of 153 FDls made by Norwegianfirms
and 'e_xchange of threats' international strategies of firms competing in international oli/:' between 1982 and 1992 confirmed the empmcal s1gmficance of d1vestments, as more than
gopohstic markets. We suggested that the securing of incremental markets might not only · half of the sample investments were d1vested w!lhm a decade: Bemto also found that
help to lower the average fixed costs of the mvestmg firm (for example, by spreading R&J)':. reenfield affiliates were less likely to be d1vested than !hose acqmred via M&As, although
and marketing outlays over larger volumes of output), but that it might also prevent a ~e motivations for the divestments were not known. Another study by Mata and Portugal
competitor from taking advantage of these economies of scale or scope. In such a sitfü (2000) using a comprehensive sample of fareign .(fully or partially owned) affihates m
ation, it follows that once foreign production becomes worthwhile, a group of MNils ': Portugal, distinguished between a sale (capital d1vestment) anda closure _(hqmdat10n) of
might set up production units even though it might not be profitable far sorne or ali the foreign affiliate. This study found that greenfield affihates wern less hkely to be sold
them, since it would be even less profitable if they stayed out of the market altogethei. than acquisitions, although they had a greater hazard of bemg hqmdated.
Naturally, this bunching of FDI will not always occur; in sorne instances the size of !he In summary, if successful, an initial act of foreign production creates its own momen-
local or regional market may just not be large enough to accommodate more than one or tum, and is likely to lead to sequential investment in the form of either (or both) vertical
two producers. Moreover, even if and when it does take place, it need not do so in the same integration or (and) horizontal diversification, as well as to the encouragement of related
countries, particularly where the investment is designed to supply products for the export and supportive activities. A possible exception to this general statement is where one firm
market. 290 , acquires another to gain certain strategic assets, but shed_s others wh1ch add httle to
Not only might competitors want to match the moves made by another firm, but other its existing competitive advantages. As we have seen, th1s kmd of FDI - along w1th the
firms in related industries might be prompted to invest as well. For example, the substan- conclusion of cross-border strategic alliances - is becoming a more importan! compo-
tial investments made in the UK by Ford and General Motors in the inter-war years; and nen! of MNE activity, particularly within the Triad, and by sorne developing countries
by Nissan and Toyota since the 1980s, leda large number of US and Japanese componen! (UNCTAD, 2006). The recen! growth of ali farms of efficiency- and strategic asset-
suppliers to fallow them. Similarly, the presence of local resource-producing com>ian1ies seeking FDI by well-established MNEs wishing to complement the1r assets or governance
(far example, oil exploration companies) has frequently led to investment by foreign advantages with those of other (foreign) firms, suggests that sorne of the earher explan-
downstream specialists, such as petrochemical or synthetic fibre companies. In the past, ations of the ways in which firms internalise the markets far their intermediate products
FDI by primary or manufacturing companies has prompted supporting or facilitating may be less relevan! than they once were. In addition to intra-Triad J\1.&As, examples of
investment by service companies, including construction companies, banks, insurance asset-augmenting FDI in this phase include joint ventures or acqms1t10ns by firms from
companies, advertising agencies, hotels, car rentals and restaurants (UNCTAD, 2004). countries such as Taiwan and South Korea, and most recently from China and India, to
Such investment is rarely trade replacing; the majar question is whether the potential gain existing brand names and access to distribution channels in Europe and the US (van
investors choose to undertake the value-adding activities, based on their 0-specific advan- Hoesel, 1999; Makino et al., 2002). Indeed, much of the asset-seeking investment has been
tages, themselves, or sell the right to do so (far example, via licensing, franchising, man- orientated towards acquiring knowledge-intensive or institutional assets or new markets,
agement contracts) to independent foreign producers. and such investment will be considered as part of Phase 5 internationalisation in the fol-
A special case of initial entry into Phase 4 occurs in instances where the seller of the lowing subsection.
products has to produce them in the country of consumption. Examples include goods
which are costly to handle or transport, far example because they are perishable or have 7.4.8 Phase 5: The Integrated Network Multinational
a low value to weight ratio, and services which need the instantaneous andjoint presence
of producers and consumers, such as sorne forros of medical consultancy,2 91 \Vholesale In their foreign market entry and expansion strategies, most MNEs coordinate, at least to
retail distribution or import merchanting. Indeed, a recen! report by UNCTAD (2004) on sorne extent, their foreign and domestic operations. If they did not, there would be no
the (substantial) role of services in foreign investment and trade highlights the variety of point in their making the FDI in the first place. Chapters 8 and 9·will examine in more
different modalities adopted by service MNEs in their internationalisation process. These detail sorne of the cross-border institutional and organisational mechanisms which an
have varied from predorninantly non-equity alliances in the case of airlines, to M&As and MNE might adopt. For the moment, we would observe that it is possible to conceive of
joint ventures in postal services, telecommunications, retailing and financia! services. In a continuum of control over foreign production which ranges from zero to complete; that
legal and accounting services, the mode of entry has generally been governed by the this control may be cxcrcised for a variety of reasons; and that the degree of contr~l and
local regulatory environment; while expansion has often been based on partnerships or coordination exercised will vary over time (far example, with learning and expenence)
alliances. In the case of privatisation investments in pub!ic utilities, such as electricity according to industry-, firm- and country-specific factors.
228 Entry and expansion strategies of MNEs 229
Inside the multinational enterprise

In its discussion of efficiency-seeking or rationalised investment, Chapter 3 was mainl petitiveness (Dunning, 1996; Dunning and Lundan, 1998; Dunning and McKaig-Berliner,
concerned with the kinds of value-added activities in which MNEs engage. But well befo: 2002). Such investment is often prompted by the fact that many knowledge assets are geo-
such foreign production takes place, there are certain decisions which affect the prosper~ graphically confined, and can only be accessed by having a presence m the area. Th1s 1s cer-
lly of resource- or market-seeking affiliates, which are likely to be centrally controlled and tainly the case in industries such as sem1conductors, clustered around Sihcon Valley, and
coordmated by the paren! company. Examples include !hose related to R&D activities biotechnology, clustered around major public research C<'ntres in Boston, New York (New
and capital expenditure, accounting procedures, institution development and market ser- Jersey), San Diego and Cambridge, UK. Research has revealed, far example, that US
vicing. The rationalisation of international production is but one step in the process biotechnology firms with higher innovative output are more likely to receive fareign equity
towards the regional or global integration of intra-firm production and transactions. participation, while in the US semiconductor industry, fareign firms are more likely to cite
Phase 5 in the evolution of an MNE investment envisages a distribution of value- local patents than are domestic firms. This fact would seem to suggest that the reason_ far
added activities between the home and foreign countries rather similar to that described the fareign firms' presence is to learn about (and to con tribute to) the local cluster (Alme1da,
between two foreign countries in Figure 7.1 (Case 4). In this phase, the paren! and the ]996" Shan and Song, 1997; Kuemmerle, 1999a). .
foreign affiliate produce different products, each of which is sold in world or regional If knowledge-seeking investment occurs via acquisitions, acquiring firms have to achieve
markets, and, in practice, frequently traded within the MNE. Part of the R&D for each integration within the firm, while in the case of joint ventures and strategi_c alliances: inte-
product is also undertaken at the location of the subsequent stages of production. This gration is accomplished largely at an inter-firm leve!. Apart from the differences m the
phase is then different from the preceding four, each of which was concerned with the financing of the capital expenditure between the eqmty and non-eqmty forms of ventures,
geographical allocation of the stages of production of a particular product along the the relative efficiency of the incentive structures within the firm, as compared to those
value chain. 293 between contractual firms, is likely to be the critica! determinan! of the long-term perfor-
Clearly, if and when this fifth phase in the evolution of an MNE (illustrated in Figure mance of these ventures. The general impression is that M&As seldom increase share-
7.2) is reached, will depend on a variety of factors. These include the range and types of holder value in the long run, and often contribute to ongoing managerial problems within
products produced, the extent to which product or process specialisation may Iead to the firm. Indeed, evidence from recen! meta studies on post-acquisition performance sug-
economies of sca1e or scope, the opportunities for such economies offered by countries in gests that while the target firm's shareholders typically experience gains in the short run,
which the investment is currently being made, or contemplated, the ease with which inter- the acquirer firm's shareholders end up no better or worse off than before the merger
mediate or final products can be traded across national boundaries, the intra-firm trans- (Agrawal and Jaffe, 2000; Bruner, 2002; King et al., 2004). While there is no reason to
action costs involved, and the attitude and strategy of the MNE towards the management expect that one form of coordination is inherently better than another, non-eqmty modes
of its foreign value-added activities. Such intra-firm product specialisation and integra- can be an alternative means for the MNE to reach its objectives, provided that the mter-
l!on of markets is likely to be accompanied by a sharp increase in the trade between the firm incentives can be set correctly. We shall return to this issue in Chapter 9.
various production units of the MNE. Chapter 14 will show that the kinds of activities There are comparatively few MNEs that practise a globally integrated product and/or
associated with intra-firm trade have a number of contextually related characteristics. process strategy of a Phase 5 kind (Rugman and Verbeke, 2004b); and hardly any of them
Among the activity-specific characteristics are the opportunities to exploit plant eco- have developed a genuine reciproca! resource and organisational relationship between
nomies of scale, and the importance of cross-border incentive structures and communi- their various production units (Hedlund, 1986; Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Doz et al.,
cation facilities. The most importan! country characteristic is that there are few or no 2001; Birkinshaw et al., 2003). The handful that have evolved to this phase have included
barriers to trade. Only MNEs that take a global or regional view of their foreign activ- sorne of the Jargest motor vehicle, consumer electronics, computer and hotel companies.
ities, and which believe that they have to integrate their domestic and foreign operations, Yet even these have not been prepared to allow the management of ali their affiliates to
are likely to practise a strategy of cross-border specialisation. participate in decisions about the configuration of ali their value-added activities, notably
As indicated earlier, an importan! componen! of Phase 5 activity is strateaic asset- R&D. Indeed, in recen! years there has been sorne reversa! away from the globally mte-
seeking investment, which may take the form of both joint ventures and M&A~. We can grated matrix form by such firms as ABB and Procter & Gamble, due, so it would appear,
identify two majar strands of this type of FDI. The first is apparent in the figures on to its inherent complexity (Westney, 2003).
global M&A activity, particularly in sorne of the mega mergers of recen! years such as Furthennore, product strategies are likely to be based on an intra- rather than interre-
Time Warner-AOL, Daimler-Chrysler and HP-Compaq (see Chapter 2 for sorne evidence gional allocation of resources. For example, according to the data provided by Rugman
of recen! trends). In such cases, which often combine efficiency- and strategic asset- and Verbeke (2004b), only nine out of the 365 firms with sufficient data from the Fortune
seeking motivations, the acquiring firm desires to acquire control of an intact package of Global 500 are global in the sense of having20% or more of sales in each part of the Triad,
knowledge, capabilities and productive assets that the target firm has to offer. while not having more than 50% in any one region, and as many as 320 firms have more
The second strand of asset-seeking investment is specifically related to the sourcing than half of their sales in the home region. 294 There may be sorne specialisation of activ-
of knowledge assets abroad. Research a propos both the leading n1anufacturing and ity bettveen countrics in the Triad, but there may also be such specialisation between
business services firms reveals that the access to foreign-based technological and managerial countries within the Triad, far example, within the EU. The question of whether the
competences is becoming an increasingly importan! determinan! of a firm's global com- regionalisation of production by MNEs is a step towards globalisation, or is a substitute
230 Inside the multinational enterprise J;,Jitry and expansivn strateg~es·of MNEs 231

for it in the presence, or likelihood, of intra-regional trade and investment barriers, is a identifying, accessing and combining resources and capabilities globally and leveraging
subject still under investigation. them within their operational ambits. What is distinctive about the dragon multmat10n-
However, as the following chapter will show, the organisation of MNE activity is als is their accelerated r:üe of internationalisation, and although they are generally qmte
currently undergoing considerable change as firms seek to gain the benefits of global large, in. this sense they are also akin to the <born globals' discussed earlier. These are firms
integration, while meeting the demands of their local customers, suppliers and host that are very global and have gr0 wn to a substantial size in spite of a limited home market,
government. Moreover, it is not just the activities of the fully owned affiliates of MNEs and severely restricted domestic resources and capabilities. They have accomphshed th1s
that are being restructured, but ali cross-border transactional relationships, including · growth by maximising the utility of their network relationships, and by not expandmg the
exporting and ali forms of cooperative alliances. International joint ventures and non- core of the firm uncontrollably.
equity alliances are an integral part of the strategy of efficiency- and strategic asset- Finally, we might mention the case of Bharti Enterprises, which is notable far having
seeking MNEs. These changes are affecting both the route towards, and the form taken grown to a large business empire by outsourcing ali of its core _operations to foreign
by, the process of internationalisation. Contemporary thinking suggests that MNEs are MNEs. Such relationships include, for example, a 10% eqmty partlc1pat10n by Vodafone
best regarded as the nerve centres of systems of intra- and inter-firm relationships, bound in the mobile communications market, contracts with Ericsson and IBM to operate the
together by a common entrepreneurial vision, and able to draw upan a fund of organisa- network infrastructure, and ajoint venture with Wal-Mart to enter the fragmented retail
tional and technological expertise in each of the markets in which they operate. 295 sector.296 However, the case of the Bharti group is notan example of internationalisation
However, the network relationships of the modern MNE are more multifaceted and as such, since it is primarily concentrated on the Indian market. Rather, it is an example
varied than in the past. Partly this is because recent economic and political events have of 'reverse' outsourcing, which effectively exploits the competences of integrated fore1gn
demanded a reappraisal of the institutions of cross-border governance, and partly MNEs looking to expand their activities in the Indian market.
because the costs and benefits of inter- and intra-firm relationships differ so much accord-
ing to the activities and the parties involved in the exchange.
In Phase 4, we asserted that sorne foreign affiliates had acquired a special status within 7.5 CONCLUSIONS
the MNE of which they were part by receiving a 'product mandate', and by virtue of
having become insiders in the host market. In Phase 5 we believe that such affiliates are After discussing the concept of the value-added chain and its relevance for our under-
more likely to achieve strategic importance as specialised 'centres of excellence'. This standing of the foreign activities of MNEs, this chapter has traced sorne of the main entr_y
means that the affiliate has global responsibility for developing and advancing excellence strategies into foreign value-added activities which might be pursued by firms that prev1-
in one area of competence within the firm (Holm and Pedersen, 2000). However, trans- ously engaged only in domestic production. It has also attempted to describe the phases
ferring and utilising the localised knowledge and institutions accessed or created by the of internationalisation through which a firm may progress, and how these are dependen!
affiliate to the rest of the firm is strongly dependen! on the ability of the MNE to set on the initial motivations for FDI, as well as the range of feasible entry strategies avail-
appropriate incentives to achieve integration. able to the firm.
A novel solution to the question of knowledge integration is offered by the meta- We would emphasise, once again, that there is nothing automatic or inevitable about
national firm (Doz et al., 2001). MNEs, such as Nokia (Finland), Shiseido (Japan) and the movement of a firm's value-added activities through the phases described. Nor are
Acer (Taiwan), are said to benefit from being born in the wrong place, and needing to these the only foreign entry and growth strategies which a firm may pursue. The growing
break free of geography. While established competitors might try to redesign their exist- complexity of MNE operations and new organisational forms, for example 'born global'
ing organisations by cultivating centres of excellence, and by investing heavily in better firms, asset-seeking M&As, and most recenti y of all private equity managed MNEs, 297 has
information systems and in knowledge management, metanational firms are more likely resulted in notable 'phase jumping' between Phases 1 and 4. Indeed, we have suggested
to focus on identifying and accessing new technologies, turning them into innovative that much of the received literature on the internationalisation process is less relevan! to
products, and finally scaling up the innovations globally. Their key advantage is an uncon- much of the contemporary foreign production by intra-Triad MNEs than it is to explain-
ventional process of prospecting for knowledge from everywhere in the firm's operating ing the first-time market- and resource-seeking FDI in developing countries an_d in
environment. Far example, Doz et al. describe how Acer modelled its organisational Central and Eastern Europe; or that undertaken by the burgeonmg small and medmm-
structure after McDonald's, by dividing itself into 40 independent local companies that sized MNEs.
assemble computers according to local needs. By labelling sorne subsystems as perishable, Clearly, too, the modality of a firm's global involvement will be related to its organisa-
Acer cut in half its inventory of these rapidly changing items. tional structure, information systems and governance procedures. To understan~ the
An idea similar to that of the metanational is .that of the so-called 'dragan multi- pattern of incremental and sequen tia! investment by firms, as well as that of the mult1tude
nationals', which use their network connections for leverage (Mathews, 2002b). These of cooperative alliances being forged by them, new models or conceptual frameworks
are large MNEs mostly from F.ast Asia including, again, Acer (Taiwan) and Li & Fung are required - perhaps on the lines of a network cu1n institutional ~pproach ear~1er
(Hong Kong), but also Ispat (India) and Cemex (Mexico ). These latecomer firms have described. It should also be emphasised that the form of entry by firms mto new fore1gn
managed to overcome their peripheral locations and lack of specific capabilities by deftly markets, ar that of the expansion or restructuring of existing FDI, will be determined by

L
232 lnside the n1ultinational enterprise

the industry- and conntry-specific characteristics, and by the strategic response of firms
to the OLI configurations with which they are faced.
Sorne of the changes in the internationalisation processes of firms are likelv to reflect
exoge~ous events. Most noticeably, over the past two decades, entry and expan~ion choice
has. w1dened as a result of falling communication and transportation costs, the Jibera]-
1satwn of severa! cross-border markets, and the reconfiguration and/or upgrading of 8. The organisation of MNE activity: the
nat10nal and supranational institutions. These have opened up new opportunities for ·
MNE activity, particularly in Central and Eastern Europe, and in China and India.
interna! network
Furthermore, growing regional integration within each par! of the Triad has created
new opportunities for established integrated MNE& By contras!, sorne of the change 8.1 INTRODUCTION
is endogenous to the firms themselves. The growing appreciation of the importance of
knowledge, capabilities and institutional efficiency as the core competences of firms has It has long been recognised that the way in which a firm organises and coordinates its
led to more strategic asset-seeking investment, which up to now has Jargely taken the form value-added activities will not only influence the efficiency with which its competitive or
of M&A& At the same time, the focus on knowledge and learning has greatly widened 0-specific advantages are utilised, but may also constitute a valued competence in its own
corporate networks by increasing the number and variety of cooperative relationships. right. It was Alfred Chandler (1962, 1977, 1990) who first emphasised the importance of
We have also sought to demonstrate in this chapter that with a wide range of inter- organisational innovation as a factor influencing the emergence and growth of the large
national activities and possible modes of coordination, the importance of the institutions US enterprise in the !alter par! of the 19th century; and particularly in those cases where
of governance within the firm (Oi), and the relational capabilities derived from them, has firms were led to shift their transactions of intermediate producís (al dependen! stages of
become paramount. Such capabilities underpin the ability of integrated MNEs to coor- the value-added chain) from externa! markets to managed hierarchies. 298
dinate their activities in Phases 4 and 5, but they are also needed to facilitate the growth Chandler further suggested that such organisational change, which, he accepted, was
of firms m Phase 1 that rely on extensive contractual outsourcing to gain a competitive initially triggered by a series of technological innovations and the emergence of manage-
advantage. At the leve] of home and host countries, governments also play an important rial capitalism earlier in the 19th century, would necessitate a fundamental restructuring
role in affecting the relative costs and benefits of the different modalities of servicing a of the locus and geography of decision making. As the size of firms and the round-
market. In particular, we have highlighted the role of infrastructure and institutional aboutness of production increased, so <lid the number and complexity of intra-firm trans-
development in encouraging firms to move from purely marketing and distribution aciiv- actions. In consequence, it became importan! to more clearly delineate and define the
ities to foreign production, and also to expanding their foreign production by increasing boundaries of managerial responsibility and governance, and the lines of communication
local sourcmg, and gaining an insider status in the local market. There is sorne evidence between the headquarters of a company, its regional and branch offices, and its operating
to suggest that such fully fledged affiliates contribute more to the host economy, as well mlits. Likewise, a rep!acement of externa] markets by administrative fiat mean! that it was
as representmg a umque resource and listening post for the paren! firm. The following two necessary to construct more forrnalised incentive structures, control and enforcement
chapters will explore in more detail the changes in the interna] organisation of MNEs, mechanisms, communication channels and administrative procedures to guide interna!.
and the growth of cooperative relationships. decision takers.
In examining the implications of these changes for the interna! governance of
firms, Chandler argued that the unitary (U-form) or functional structure of organisa-
tion - in which decision-taking responsibility was linked to stages in the value-added
chain or the transactions associated with these stages - became less snitable as a firm
became more diversified along its value-added chains or in its inpnt or ontput markets.
He suggested that its interests were likely to be better served by a multidivisional (M-
form) structure, which consisted of a hierarchical division of labour based on the prod-
ucts produced or the geographical areas served, rather than on the functions performed
by a firm.
We have already asserted in Chapter 1 that the distinctive feature of an MNE is that it
is a geographically diversified multi-activity firm. We have further suggested - and will
elaborate on this point in this chapter - that the entry of a firm into a foreign arena is
likely to impose additional, and often quite different, demands on its organisational
structure and the distribution of its decision-making responsibilities. These consequences
are likely to be most marked in the case of glohally integrated MNEs where traditional

233

You might also like