You are on page 1of 12

Assessing the Economic and Ecosystem Services Contribution of Forests: Issues

in Modelling, and an Illustration


Author(s): K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta
Source: International Forestry Review, 10(2):376-386. 2008.
Published By: Commonwealth Forestry Association
URL: http://www.bioone.org/doi/full/10.1505/ifor.10.2.376

BioOne (www.bioone.org) is a nonprofit, online aggregation of core research in the biological, ecological,
and environmental sciences. BioOne provides a sustainable online platform for over 170 journals and books
published by nonprofit societies, associations, museums, institutions, and presses.
Your use of this PDF, the BioOne Web site, and all posted and associated content indicates your acceptance of
BioOne’s Terms of Use, available at www.bioone.org/page/terms_of_use.
Usage of BioOne content is strictly limited to personal, educational, and non-commercial use. Commercial
inquiries or rights and permissions requests should be directed to the individual publisher as copyright holder.

BioOne sees sustainable scholarly publishing as an inherently collaborative enterprise connecting authors, nonprofit publishers, academic institutions,
research libraries, and research funders in the common goal of maximizing access to critical research.
376 International Forestry Review Vol.10(2), 2008

Assessing the economic and ecosystem services


contribution of forests: issues in modelling, and an
illustration
K. CHOPRA1 and P. DASGUPTA2
1
Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi 110007, India and Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations,
New Delhi 110003, India
2
Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relation, New Delhi 110003, India

Email: kanchan@iegindia.org; purnamita@yahoo.com

SUMMARY

This paper develops methodology for valuing forest ecosystem services. It reviews alternative approaches to modelling the forestry sector’s
contribution to well-being. It subsequently extends existing techniques of cost–benefit analysis to the forestry sector and illustrates the
application of the methodology through a case study of the state of Himachal Pradesh in India. The extended methodology captures variations
that occur because of ecological aspects of forests, sustainability concerns regarding extraction from forests and aggregation issues in valuing
ecosystem services. It also incorporates concerns about biodiversity valuation, particularly in protected areas. The paper highlights the
importance of recognising local variations in forest values, adopting a multi-disciplinary approach to valuation and the relevance of using
more than one policy instrument for managing forest ecosystems.

Keywords: economic valuation, methodology, cost–benefit analysis (CBA), sustainability, forest ecosystem services.

Evaluer la contribution des services écomiques et d’écosystèmes des forêts: problèmes de


modélisation et une illustration

K. CHOPRA ET P.DASGUPTA

Cet article développe une méthodologie pour évaluer les services d’écosystèmes des forêts. Il passe en revue des approches alternatives
pour créer un modèle de la contribution du secteur de la foresterie au bien-être. Il étend ensuite les techniques existantes de l’analyse du
coût-bénéfice du secteur de la foresterie, et illustre l’application de la méthodologie par une étude-cas de l’état de Himachal Pradesh en
Inde. La méthodologie étendue observe les variations prenant place du fait des aspects écologiques des forêts, les défis à la durabilité liés à
l’extraction dans les forêts et les problèmes d’agrégat dans l’évaluation des services d’écosystème. Il incorpore également les soucis quant à
l’évaluation de la biodiversité, en particulier dans les zones protégées. Cet article souligne l’importance de reconnaître les variations locales
dans les valeurs des forêts, l’adoption d’une approche pluridisciplinaire del’évaluation, ainsi que l’importance d’utiliser plus d’un instrument
politique pour gérer les écosystèmes forestiers.

Evaluación del aporte de servicios económicos y de ecosistema en los bosques: asuntos de


modelación y un caso real
K. CHOPRA Y P. DASGUPTA

Este estudio desarrolla una metodología para la evaluación de los servicios de ecosistema forestal. Examina enfoques alternativos para
la modelación del aporte del sector forestal al bienestar humano, y luego extiende las técnicas actuales de análisis de costos y beneficios
al sector forestal y demuestra la aplicación de la metodología mediante el estudio de un caso real en el estado de Himachal Pradesh en la
India. La metodología capta variaciones que ocurren como resultado de aspectos ecológicos de los bosques, de cuestiones de sostenibilidad
relacionadas con la extracción de madera de los bosques, y del tema de la agregación en la valoración de servicios de ecosistema. Analiza
además la valoración de la biodiversidad, sobre todo en áreas protegidas. El estudio demuestra la importancia de reconocer variaciones
locales en los valores forestales, de adoptar una metodología multidisciplinaria para la evaluación, y de utilizar varios instrumentos de
politica para el manejo de ecosistemas forestales.
Economic and ecosystem services contribution of forests 377

INTRODUCTION United Nations System of National Accounts [SNA]). These


systems develop consolidated accounts for nations and a set
The valuation of the services contributed by a forest of four/five accounts are set up to examine national income,
ecosystem to economic activity and to human well-being is a product and its generation from different viewpoints. These
complex exercise, encompassing a range of social, economic consolidated accounts, in India, as in other countries are:
and cultural issues. Beginning with the identification of • Gross domestic product and expenditure account;
the bio-physical aspects, to building an understanding of • National disposable income and its appropriation;
the ecosystem resources, functions and attributes, to the • External transactions account; and
economic valuation of forest functions, the exercise calls for • Capital finance account.
multi-disciplinary skills. Thus, positive and negative impacts, Sector-specific production and income data help to
on-site and off-site impacts, physical, socio-economic and provide aggregate estimates that fit into the double-entry
psychological impacts, near-term and long-term impacts system of accounting and result in the following accounting
are all to be considered (Bann 1998). Valuation of forest identity:
goods and services is identified as an important agenda of
the ongoing negotiations of the Intergovernmental Forum on Aggregate demand = aggregate supply in an economy.
Forests (IFF) of the United Nations.
This paper attempts to review alternative approaches It follows, therefore, that with respect to flows of
to modelling the forestry sector and valuing the services production specific to a year from the production side:
accruing from forest ecosystems. It argues for a step-
by-step approach to integration with national income Gross Domestic Product = Gross Domestic Production
accounts, using satellite accounting as the in-between – Intermediate Use
step. The framework of satellite accounting can be used to
integrate new techniques for economic valuation and better Also, from the expenditure side:
ecological understanding into national income accounting.
This will also enhance the empirical understanding Gross Domestic Product = Private Consumption
and quantitative estimation of the links between forest Expenditure + Public Consumption Expenditure + Gross
ecosystem services and human well-being. An illustration Investment + Exports – Imports (1)
from the northern Himalayan state of Himachal Pradesh uses
an extended net present value approach to valuation. The For the forestry sector, as indeed for other sectors, the
extended methodology brings into its gamut an evaluation of contribution towards gross domestic production is:
the sustainability of benefits over time and an understanding
of aggregation problems arising out of the non-additivity Current Production (of goods and services) = Intermediate
of ecological services. It succeeds in illustrating that local Use + Final Consumption Use (domestically and in the rest
variations in value are of the essence and that these variations of the world net of any imports) + Use as Investment (2)
provide interesting pointers for policy.
With respect to capital stocks, measured at the beginning
and end of the year, usually only human-made capital stocks
APPROACHES TO MODELLING OF FOREST were considered:
ECOSYSTEMS
Closing Capital Stock = Stock at the Beginning +
Forests have been modelled within three alternative Investments during the Year – Capital Depreciation (3)
conceptual frameworks with regard to their contribution
to economic activity. First, as a sector in national income As stocks, whatever the asset boundary that defines them,
accounts in terms of their contribution to GDP; second, as are additive, the above equation shall hold for each sector,
a component of natural capital, the stock of which needs unless the stock in one sector accumulates at the cost of a
to be kept constant while a flow of goods and services is reduction in stock in another sector in the same time period.
obtained from it and, third, as an ecosystem providing goods An assumption underlying the notion of income as
and services, supporting life on Earth and contributing to a measure of welfare is that all activity contributing to
economic activity and enhancement of human well-being. economic welfare is measured by income as it is expressed
The approaches reflect progressive changes in the state in exchange. A number of economists have expounded at
of knowledge and attempts to take them into account in length on how this assumption is limiting, and a large part
addressing policy needs. These developments in the literature of economic activity lies outside the purview of the market,
are briefly reviewed in the rest of this section. nevertheless contributing to human well-being. Such analysis
has resulted in an extension of the production boundary to
Forests as a sector in national income accounts include production for self-consumption, in particular, in the
As a sector in national income accounts, forestry, generally context of developing-country agriculture. These extensions,
referred to as the forestry and logging sector, provides following from conventions, have now become standard in
inputs into the systems of national income accounting (the national income accounting practice. It follows that what is
378 K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta

or is not included within the production and asset boundaries forestry sector production and asset estimates are based on
is largely a matter of convention and keeps getting revised a number of ad hoc assumptions. Moreover, measuring and
from time to time. In estimating the contribution of a quantifying everything may be neither possible nor desirable.
particular sector, such as the forestry sector, to SNA then, To quote Vincent (1999): “A pragmatic recommendation is
one would concentrate on equations (2) and (3) above, with to orient the accounting effort towards those values of forests
a view to alternative production and asset boundaries. that are of obvious economic significance now and are likely
In India, as in other countries, the forest sector, referred to remain so in the future and to prepare adjusted national
to as forestry and logging is a part of the system of national accounts as a special product every few years.”
accounts (SNA). Just as for other sectors contributing Nevertheless, it is important for an economy to estimate
towards gross domestic production, the current production from time to time whether or not its forest capital is being
(of goods and services) from the forestry sector and the eroded. Methodologies for satellite accounting have been
stock of closing capital (natural) is the focus here. What is developed to enable this to be done. A schematic description
or is not included within the production and asset boundaries of satellite accounts attempted by other studies (Kadekodi
in the SNA is largely a matter of convention and is revised 2001) is reproduced in Figure 1.
from time to time.
The total impact of policy changes in the forestry sector FIGURE 1 Core and satellite systems and their inter-linkages
since the late 1980s finds only a partial and distorted place
in the statistics on national income. The present system of Core systems Satellite: forest sector
income accounting in the forestry sector in India takes note System of National Accounts (SNA) Selection of forestry-related sectors from SNA
and their contribution to GDP: alternative
of contributions by, for example, industrial wood, fuelwood, methodology
and minor forest products. As recorded in several studies,
Extension of production boundary contribution
there is under-estimation in this too. The contribution of Description of economic sectors of forestry-based production of goods and
services to GDP
forests to GDP has varied from 1 to 1.6 percent over the nine
year period from 1993–1994 to 2002–2003. It also depicts Capital account: national capital and additions Extending the asset boundary
or depletions from it
a declining trend in some years. Part of the reason for this
Depreciation estimates to give NDP Forest stock as natural capital
declining trend is policy measures, which aim at increasing
the stock of forests while reducing extraction from it.
Chopra et al. (2002) estimate that, if a few extensions to
include some intangible services from forests are included, The separate and additional compilation of the satellite
the forestry sector contributed 2.21 percent to GDP in 1996– accounts provides two types of opportunity. It provides a kind
1997 (at 1993–1994 prices). of periodic check (every five years or so) on how the existing
production, consumption and capital accumulation activity
Forests as a component of national capital in the country has impacted the stock of natural capital
The conceptualisation of capital in the SNA captures only a embodied in the forests of the country. At the same time, the
part of the capital accumulation that may have taken place drawing up of such a system of satellite accounting implies
in the forestry sector. In short, stocks and flows need to be taking a closer look at the services provided by forests in
looked at together. Such notions have been intrinsic to the different parts of the country and evaluating methodologies
measurement of national income. Hicks (1940 and 1946) to value them using state-of-the-art knowledge and the latest
provide the necessary condition under which income could data. It should also aim to move towards a more complete
be regarded as an index of welfare. Hicks maintains that all picture of the contribution of forest ecosystems to human
income that did not impoverish future consumption could be well-being.
considered welfare-improving. For this to be ensured, the
stock of capital had to be maintained intact. The significance Forest ecosystems services
of this precondition was extended to natural and human Even if all the above improvements and extensions were
capital by analysts such as Hamilton and Clemens (1999), made, the contribution of forests to economic activity
Dasgupta and Maler (2000) and Dasgupta (2001). as reflected in national income accounts would capture
Some extensions of the asset boundary of 1968 were human well-being only partially, as national income
made in India in SNA 1993. It was said therein that only accounts themselves only partially capture the extensive
those natural assets over which ownership rights have services which forest and other ecosystems render for
been established and are effectively enforced can qualify as human well-being.
economic assets. It follows that wherever forest resources Examining the linkages between ecosystem services
bring economic benefit to their owners, they are to be included and human well-being, the MEA (2005) groups the
in produced assets. Thus, when the forests are growing services yielded into four categories. In this comprehensive
in regions that are inaccessible and no institutional units approach, the contribution of forests to human well-being
are able to exercise effective ownership rights over them, is best expressed by examining the provisioning, regulating,
they fall outside the asset boundary. However, establishing cultural and life-supporting services they provide.
empirical estimates for such extensions is difficult. In India, As indicated in Figure 2, human well-being depends
we have a long way to go to enable this to be done. The critically on the supporting, regulating and cultural
Economic and ecosystem services contribution of forests 379

FIGURE 2 Services provided by forest ecosystems Economic valuation techniques can help in measuring
direct and indirect use values of the forest. However, it is
Provisioning Regulating Cultural neither feasible nor desirable to evaluate all the benefits and
Goods produced or provided Benefits obtained from Non-material benefits costs through such techniques; rather one concentrates on
by ecosystems regulation of ecosystem obtained from ecosystems those which are significant in a given context and at the same
x Food processes x Spiritual
x Fresh water x Climate regulation x Recreational time are appropriate for such an economic valuation. For
x Fuelwood x Disease control x Aesthetic instance, the measurement of option values and existence
x Fibre x Flood control x Inspirational
x Biochemicals x Detoxification x Educational values is very complicated and fraught with uncertainties.
x Genetic resources x Communal Uncertainties about benefit flows and costs also increase
x Symbolic
with longer planning horizons. Where there are fears of
Supporting irreversibility, the precautionary principle becomes relevant
Services necessary for the production of all other ecosystem services and approaches such as setting safe minimum standards are
x Biodiversity
x Soil formation more appropriate. Similarly, protected areas such as national
x Nutrient cycling parks, wildlife sanctuaries and other biodiversity hotspots,
x Primary production
should be maintained as such, and should not be subject to
any economic valuation exercise. Such services, including
the preservation of endangered species, are in principle
services provided by any ecosystem. This paper adopts priceless. It is also difficult to capture cultural values
this comprehensive classification for mapping the services through economic tools, other than those directly related
provided by a forest ecosystem. As methodologies for to eco-tourism/recreation. By an extension of the logic for
valuation of each of these services are developed and protected areas, one may therefore recommend that services
improved, the satellite set of accounts is expected to provide such as those of sacred groves or areas having similar cultural
a more comprehensive picture of the sectoral contribution values should not be part of a valuation exercise. Rather one
of forests. would turn to legal instruments and command- and-control
It is important to state, additionally, that such a sharpening approaches to implement these legal instruments to provide
of sectoral contributions would need to proceed side by side adequate protection for such services, including protected
with developments in macro-economic theory which ensure areas and sacred groves.
consistency in aggregation across sectors and addition of In recent years, several scholars have contributed to the
new concepts to accepted macro-economic indicators1. literature on techniques for valuing non-market benefits
(Freeman 1993; Bishop 1999). The basic economic principle
is to estimate the consumer’s marginal willingness to pay
VALUATION OF FOREST LAND AND ITS SERVICES: (WTP) (compensated demand) for the benefit in question
SOME COMMENTS AND CAVEATS (alternatively. the marginal willingness to accept (WTA)
monetary compensation for losing the benefit in question).
It is widely accepted that forests provide many kinds of The development of these methods has had particular
benefits, which have been classified as either tangible or significance in terms of informing decision makers regarding
intangible. However, market imperfections and, in many land use options. The monetary values arrived at for the non-
cases, market failures arise from various characteristics of marketed benefits serve as inputs into exercises for evaluating
forest benefits such that only a few of these values are reflected alternative land-use based projects in, for instance, cost–
in market prices. Economic theory holds that efficient benefit analysis (CBA).
allocation of resources is achieved by markets when prices The international focus on non-marketed values of
accurately reflect marginal costs of production and marginal forests such as carbon sequestration has served to bring these
consumption benefits. Public good–type characteristics, into greater prominence in local, national and international
externalities, information asymmetries, inappropriate or decision making with respect to land use changes and for
insecure property rights structures are among the commonly trade-offs between conservation and other development
discussed reasons for markets prices failing to reflect the objectives. Correspondingly, methods of appraisal are being
complete range of values of forest ecosystems. increasingly developed, ranging from physical approaches,
A more complete valuation of forests is, however, crucial such as the landscape approach and environmental impact
so that critical decision makers can make more informed assessments, to economic models. The debate across
choices, particularly in the context of debates on conservation disciplines has been brought closer by the growing concerns
of forests. It is in this spirit that this section briefly reviews about irreversibilities in the ecosystem and a concern about
valuation methods, before providing an illustration of a the adverse consequences of land use changes that may occur
more complete valuation of forest land in Himachal Pradesh, if decision making is unable adequately to take into account
a state in northern India. the non-marketed benefits.

1
There have been several attempts to identify ecological and economic benefits from forests. An early attempt, for instance, was by Singh and
Nilsson (1974).
380 K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta

As argued by Bishop (1999), the estimation of non- rate of return (IRR) and the benefit–cost ratio (BCR). The
market values in monetary terms contributes rational debate net present value criteria follow the general CBA rule as
about the relative advantages and disadvantages of alternative mentioned above, and compute present value by discounting
courses of action, and serves to make trade-offs comparable the benefits and costs that occur through time back to the
and intelligible, by expressing different costs and benefits base year (t = 0). Any project for which the NPV is negative
in terms of a single numeraire (i.e. monetary value). Thus, is not worthwhile. Maximising NPV is a criterion that is
for instance, if the argument is that economic valuation particularly useful if one has to rank alternatives or choose
methods fail to take account of distributional considerations, between alternatives. In such a case, the project with the
one way out is to enrich the analysis by incorporating social highest NPV should be selected. It is important to keep in
weights to favour the poor or disadvantaged groups within a mind that NPV can be expressed in terms of per unit of land
framework of CBA. Other methods of land use assessment area or in terms of a whole project involving conversion of a
have also been advocated in the literature. Thus, cost- certain plot to another land use.
effectiveness analysis (CEA) has been used to determine the However, several important methodological issues arise
most economical or cost-effective way to achieve a specified in applying NPV. Choosing the appropriate rate of discount
objective, and similarly, multi-criteria analysis (MCA) has and the choice of planning horizon often requires value
been used where multiple objectives are to be targeted. judgments. Issue of risk and uncertainty, distributional
Risk–benefit analysis and decision analysis have been other concerns, and the sustainability of the resource in question
quantitative methods that have been discussed. are important considerations to which there are no easy
However, having said that, the authors acknowledge answers.
that there may be situations in which altogether different
criteria for land use decisions may become important and Ensuring sustainability of resource flows over time
economic efficiency needs to be considered alongside The most critical assumption in valuing an asset over time
factors such as social and cultural value, historical claims, relates to the sustainability of resource flows. Physical
distributional impacts and other factors in order to arrive at a indicators, defining ecological sustainability of the forest
comprehensive assessment. In the following sections the net land in question, become crucial before any meaningful NPV
present value (NPV) approach is developed and applied to exercise can be conducted. For instance, if the prevailing rates
estimating the benefits from forest eco-systems in Himachal of extraction are unsustainable, then ecologically, the flow of
Pradesh, a state in northern India. benefits needs to be adjusted accordingly. There is a need
therefore to allow for such degradation, taking into account
both past trends and possibilities for potential degradation in
A POSSIBLE METHODOLOGY EXTENDING COST– the longer-run time horizon.
BENEFIT ANALYSIS AND NET PRESENT VALUE In many cases, however, the sustainable or economically
efficient harvest rate is not known and cannot be estimated
Cost–benefit analysis is a tool that has been advocated in directly. In that case one would need to rely on sensitivity
the specific context of incorporating a range of benefits and analysis to illustrate differences in net benefits under
costs associated with forest land use decisions. A benefit (B) different assumptions about physical output or impact. The
is something that increases human well-being while a cost compensatory project approach may also be helpful in this
(C) is something that reduces human well-being. With this situation, as a way of accounting for the loss of benefits due
definition, a cost–benefit analysis (CBA) typically compares to excessive levels of resource exploitation (Bishop 1999).
all the costs of a project with all its benefits, and if the project This compensatory project approach is an application of the
shows a net benefit it would meet with approval. principle that the the value of a capital asset must be kept
In the case of conversion of forest land to non-forestry constant while attributing a sustainable flow of income to
uses, one would include not only direct costs such as those it. Another way of taking this into account is by adding the
for clearing and burning the forest, but also benefits foregone user cost of the capital asset to the NPV to estimate the per
(opportunity costs) of the conversion of the forest, such hectare value.
as loss of important environmental functions (watershed
services, micro-climate regulation) and resources (fuelwood, Valuing irreversible change and non-substitutable
timber, etc). Once the stream of benefits and costs has been resources: understanding the limits to the use of NPV
determined, these need to be discounted, as, typically, the Another issue which deserves separate mention is the
costs and benefits occur over long periods of time. Using a valuation of life supporting non-substitutable resources
discount rate r and a planning horizon t, the CBA rule thus such as biodiversity and the justification for the use of
can be expressed simply as: a precautionary principle for preserving such values.
Biodiversity provides life-supporting services for human
Ȉt (Bt – Ct) (1 + r)–t > 0 beings and other species on earth. A relatively minor part
of this contribution can be captured through economic
In operationalising the CBA rule, various decision criteria valuation, as demonstrated later in this paper. However,
have been developed in order to judge between alternative a large part is not. It is neither feasible nor desirable that
options. These include the net present value (NPV), internal economic valuation be applied to all services accruing from
Economic and ecosystem services contribution of forests 381

forests. Once this is understood, policy instruments such as taken together provide a fair approximation of the value of
well-implemented legal provisions and social norms can be products and services flowing from non-protected areas.
used to ensure conservation. Legally protected areas and Table 1 summarises the techniques that have been
other biodiversity rich areas in particular are best kept in used for estimating the annual value of benefit and costs
this category (IIED 2000). In the present study methodology associated with various identified forest values for purposes
and estimation, there has been no attempt to find economic of the present study.
values of biodiversity in protected areas. In the case of It is also to be noted that expenditure is also incurred by
non-protected areas, biodiversity values are estimated for the forest department on costs that cannot be apportioned
different land use types. across different goods and services such as costs incurred
While a few attempts have been made in India to estimate in construction and maintenance activities and expenditure
the economic value of the tangible and intangible benefits on wages and salaries. These have to be deducted from the
of forests, in most cases the methodologies used have total benefit to arrive at net benefit from a particular patch
been constrained by the lack of an eco-systems approach of forest. A social rate of discount of 5 percent (Murty and
or data limitations. The most recent attempt at calculating Goldar 2006) and a time period of 20 years is used to arrive
NPV per hectare of forest land for Himachal Pradesh at the NPV of the stream of net benefits accruing for the state
(Expert Committee 2006) attempted to integrate findings of Himachal Pradesh in this illustrative exercise.
from methods that have been used in valuing India’s forest NPV is estimated at forest circle level for different kinds
benefits. In this paper the methodology adopted is based on of land use within the category of forests. The landform
the theory of cost–benefit analysis. The methods adopted or land uses within forests for which NPV is estimated
for calculating the contributions from forest ecosystems is are: dense natural forests, lopped natural forests, open tree
illustrated through a case study of Himachal Pradesh in the savannah and timber plantations. It is found that such an
following section. estimation at circle level is possible, given the present data
availability. Biodiversity in protected areas is treated as not
to be tampered with and it is recommended that the law be
NPV AS AN APPROXIMATION OF FOREST VALUE used for its protection. An approximate value for biodiversity
FOR HIMACHAL PRADESH—AN ILLUSTRATION in non-protected areas is obtained, based on inputs from
ecological studies.
Himachal Pradesh, a state in northern India, lies in the hill A few distinct features of this valuation need to be
region of the Himalayas. It has a substantial part of its area pointed out. The NPV of forest land is found after ensuring
designated as forest land (25.78 percent). In terms of volume that the stock of forests should not deplete. Past patterns of
per hectare (density of growing stock) Himachal Pradesh use and available estimates of area and biomass are studied
(203.5 m3 per ha) is amongst the leading states in India. to enquire as to whether or not this is a feasible assumption
The distribution of various species follows fairly regular for a particular state/circle. If extraction is found to be non-
altitudinal stratification. The vegetation varies from dry sustainable, an additional cost named user cost, approximated
scrub forests at lower altitudes to alpine pastures at higher by preservation value would need to be added to NPV as
altitudes. The richness and diversity of flora can be gauged a social cost of ensuring accrual of services. Ecological
from the fact that out of total 45 000 species found in the evidence on the incorrectness of simple additivity across
country as many as 3 295 species (7.32 percent) are reported values of services is also taken into account in estimating
in the state. NPV of different kinds of landforms or land uses within
According to the latest forest department statistics of forests.
Himachal Pradesh (2004) the forests of HP can be classified It is to be noted that for such an exercise, it is the NPV
into the following legally defined categories. Majority of per hectare of land with forest cover that is considered to
forest area, around 58 percent, falls under the legal category be relevant rather than the total land owned by the forest
of undemarcated protected forests. This is followed by department. The definition provided by the Food and
demarcated protected forests, which comprise around Agriculture Organization (FAO) is used to identify such
31 percent of forest area in HP. The other categories like, forest area (i.e., as that having tree canopy cover of more
reserved forests, unclassed forests and others have a small than 10 percent over an area of more than 0.5 hectares with
percentage. forestry as the principal land use).
NPV refers to the discounted sum of INR values of eco- The extent of protected areas in HP varies from 9
system goods and services that would flow from a forest over percent in Nahan to 52 percent in Dharamshala. The average
a period of time net of costs incurred. NPV will then mean the protected area for the circles is quite high at 26 percent of
loss of value of the forest resources (as viewed above) to the the total. It should be highlighted that calculations of NPV
stakeholders or the users. Seven products and services have per hectare in this exercise are based on these non-protected
been valued in this exercise: timber, carbon sequestration, areas, referred to hereafter as net forest area (NFA). Finally,
eco-tourism, non-timber forest products (NTFP), fuelwood, certain costs (forest departmental costs) that could not be
fodder, and watershed services. apportioned across different benefits within each circle,
In addition, biodiversity has also been valued partially including forest department costs, expenditure incurred in
for non-protected areas. It is considered that these services construction and maintenance activities, and expenditure on
382 K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta

TABLE 1 Methods for the estimation of benefits and costs

Good/service Annual value Annual costs


• Long-run stumpage-value approach Costs of production (departmental), extraction and
Timber
• Stumpage price of mature timber transport
Value of carbon stock = carbon content x market
rate of carbon
Carbon value Carbon content = biomass x IPCC-GPG default No direct costs.
value***
Biomass = growing stock × conversion factor
Total value of fuelwood collected in a normal
year = number of rural households collecting Cost of collecting fuelwood = (number of rural
Fuelwood and fuelwood from forest in last 365 days × average households) × (total annual time cost of collection
fodder* value of collection per collecting household. per household valued at 15% of average agricultural
(The value to be used is the relevant price in the wage rate)
nearest local market)
Per ha value of NTFP collected in each circle =
value of NTFP in each circle /net forest area in
Cost of collecting NTFP = (number of rural
Non-timber forest each circle
households) × (total annual time cost of collection
products (including Value of NTFP in each circle = value of NTFP
per household valued at 15% of average agricultural
grass) collected in a normal year per household ×circle-
wage rate)
wise rural households (the value to be used is the
relevant price in the nearest local market)
Per hectare value of eco-tourism in each circle
= total value of eco-tourism in each circle/net
Costs incurred by the forest department in the
forest area in each circle.
maintenance, preservation and development of
Eco-tourism Value of eco-tourism dependent on forest
national parks and wildlife sanctuaries. The per ha
ecosystems = number of people visiting different
costs were calculated to arrive at costs for each circle.
circles per year mainly because of natural beauty
× average expenditure incurred per person
Value per ha for soil conservation and
As per site-specific secondary studies (Kumar 2004,
Watershed services hydrological services from secondary site-
Chaturvedi 1992)
specific studies**

*Note: The value for fodder would be calculated in the same manner as for fuelwood
**For watershed benefits it may be noted that the conclusions from case studies can vary because of the complexities involved in accurately
quantifying underlying ecological relationships
***Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (2003)

forest officials (wages and salaries) have been deducted from Sustainability of flow of these services can be ensured only
the total benefit to arrive at net benefits for the circle. if the stock of capital remains constant. This can be looked
It is also important to take note of the type of forest by at in different ways, two among them being (a) forest cover
land use category, whether it is a dense natural forest, lopped by density classes and (b) growing stock of different species.
dense forest, open tree savannah, monoculture plantation, In the present context, an estimate of changes in the forest
mangrove or coastal forest or snow-bound forest. Within each capital of Himachal Pradesh is derived from two kinds of
forest circle, a categorisation of land use category enables indicative evidence based on secondary sources. First, a
one to determine which of the seven products and services study of the trend in land with forest cover (treated as an
accrue in what combinations from different land uses. This index of change) reveals that it has been non-declining since
avoids any double counting and overestimation of value of 1987, with a marginal increase in the recent past (Figure
the forest land being managed in a particular manner. The 3). Second, a study of the asset accounts of some major
time horizon for NPV calculations is recommended to be species compiled recently (Haripriya 2000) also reveals that
20 years, considering the plausible mix of species and their closing stocks are higher than the opening stocks for these
different maturity periods. species (Table 2). It is therefore assumed that the trend will
continue and that the flow of products and services will be
Verifying assumptions on sustainable accrual of forest non-declining for the two decades to come. There is, in this
services and products case, no need to assume an additional user cost of capital to
In arriving at the NPV estimates it is assumed that current be charged to potential users of the forest land.
levels of extraction are sustainable for the next 20 years.
Economic and ecosystem services contribution of forests 383

FIGURE 3 Land with forest cover and linear trend in forest hectare for each circle (Table 5) varying from US$11 750 per
cover for HP hectare to US$23 650 per hectare, given the assumptions of
the methodology. It may be reiterated that these calculations
are based on only seven services for non-protected areas.
15000
14500
14000 Reckoning with problems of aggregation and valuing
13500 biodiversity partially
13000 In a situation where the benefits are being determined by
km2

12500
12000
complicated ecological processes, it is incorrect to simply add
11500 up the value of services from forest ecosystems. As different
11000 kinds of land cover in forests yield different combinations
1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 and levels of services, the values for the different services
Year cannot be simultaneously realised either partially or fully in
almost all situations. In other words, a simple aggregation
forest cover linear (forest cover)
may amount to double counting. Table 6 presents one

TABLE 2 Assets accounts of different categories of forest in Himachal Pradesh, 2001–2002 (volume in ‘000 m3)

Activity/forest type Pine Deodar Fir/spruce Other species Total


(1) Opening stocks (standing volume) 89 232.40 54 225.70 137 889.10 58 073.80 339 421.00
(2) Net changes due to economic
activity (–) (net of deletion and 467.59 286.76 733.50 304.34 1 792.19
afforestation)
(3) Net other volume changes (net of
1 367.77 665.49 1 408.89 890.17 4 331.70
additions and reductions)
(4) Other accumulations
(encroachment & transfer of land to 7.32 4.448 11.309.00 4.765.00 27.841.00
other activities) (–)
(5) Net volume change
892.86 374.28 664.08 581.07 2 551.66
(5=2+3+4)
(6) Closing stocks (6=1+5) 90 125.26 54 599.98 138 553.18 58 654.87 341 932.60

Note: Framework adapted from Haripriya (2000)

TABLE 3 Per hectare annual net benefits of forest services in Himachal Pradesh (INR*)

Circle Timber Carbon NTFP Eco-tourism Fuelwood Fodder WS


INR* INR* INR* INR* INR* INR* INR*
Bilaspur 2 074 18 945 9 789 14 542 4 150 4 145 22 207
Chamba 1 499 30 718 1 023 1 658 322 319 22 207
Dharamshala 3 034 13 245 7 555 7 765 2 028 2 025 22 207
Mandi 922 32 915 3 426 339 836 835 22 207
Nahan 765 11 208 1 697 821 515 515 22 207
Shimla 1 535 25 132 1 084 12 791 304 304 26 952

Note: WS: Watershed services


* 40 INR = ~US$1

Circle-wise NPV estimates possible classification that could be followed to account for
Table 3 presents the annual per hectare net benefits for each the fact that different land use forms yield varying mixes of
circle in HP based on the methodology as discussed above. these service flows. Ecological studies distinguish between
The NPV is subsequently estimated for the different forest the mix of services obtained from different kinds of land use
circles, using a discount rate of 5 percent for a time period of within forests. Dense natural forests would yield a higher-
20 years. Table 4 presents the NPV estimates obtained. level of hydrological services, non-timber forest products
To sum up, a simple addition would yield an NPV per and soil conservation services. Monoculture plantations on
384 K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta

TABLE 4 NPV+ per hectare of forest services at 5 percent rate of discount for 20 years (INR*)

Circle Timber Carbon NTFP Eco-tourism Fuelwood Fodder WS


Bilaspur 25 843 236 097 121 998 181 220 51 720 51 659 276 748
Chamba 18 687 382 818 12 746 20 664 4 010 3 981 276 748
Dharamshala 37 812 165 062 94 148 96 771 25 270 25 241 276 748
Mandi 11 488 410 194 42 692 4 223 10 420 10 408 276 748
Nahan 9 529 139 681 21 149 10 228 6 423 6 415 276 748
Shimla 19 134 313 196 13 508 159 408 3 793 3 789 335 881

Note: WS: Watershed services


*40 INR = ~ US$1
+
Net present value

TABLE 5 NPV+ per hectare (simple aggregation-based the other hand yield more of timber and carbon sequestration
method) (INR)* services.
Based on Table 6, the distribution of the percentage of
Circle NPV values from different services is combined with data on the
Bilaspur 945 285 type of forest cover for each of the circles in HP to obtain
more precise NPV estimates in Table 7.
Chamba 719 654
A further gain from such ecological information is
Dharamshala 721 052 that it becomes possible to attempt to incorporate a value
Mandi 766 173 of biodiversity at least for non-critical protected areas for
Nahan 470 173 each circle. This is done by using the weighting between
Shimla 848 709 biodiversity and other goods and services implicit in
Table 6 2.
*40 INR = ~US$1 From this exercise, as presented in Table 7, it can
+
Net present value be concluded that the value of a hectare of forest land in

TABLE 6 Land use and ecosystem services

Product, service or benefit


Land use type Hydro- Carbon
Fuel- Leafy “Minor” Soil con- Biodi-
Timber Fodder logical seques-
wood matter produce servation versity
benefit tered
Dense, natural forest 0 +++ ++ 0 +++ +++? +++ +++ +++
Dense, lopped forest ++ +++ +++ + ++ +++ +++ + ++
Open lopped forest + ++ ++ +++ + ++ ++ + +
“Pure” grassland 0 0 0 +++ 0 ++ ++ + +
Monoculture planta-
+++ + + + 0 ++ + 0 +++
tion
Paddy cultivation 0 0 0 ++ 0 ++? ++? ? 0
Barren land 0 0 0 0 0 – 0 0 0
Local
Regional
Global

Extent of benefit: +++ = high; ++ = medium; + = low; 0 = none; – = negative


Source: Lele (2004)

2
Biodiversity in non-protected areas is given a weightage of 3/19 for dense natural forest, 1/14 for lopped natural forest and 1/19 for open
tree savannah.
Economic and ecosystem services contribution of forests 385

TABLE 7 NPV+ per hectare as per land use classification (INR*)

Circle Dense natural forest Lopped natural forest Open tree savannah Timber plantation
Bilaspur 923 582 782 483 681 946 398 611
Chamba 660 277 606 118 477 829 465 129
Dharamshala 675 759 591 927 496 625 306 508
Mandi 707 540 655 356 511 244 490 582
Nahan 434 252 399 482 314 341 213 407
Shimla 756 765 636 036 554 981 423 773

*40 INR = ~US$1


+
Net present value

Himachal Pradesh can vary from US$23 000 for dense it reflects the need for better management of available data
natural forest in Bilaspur circle to US$5 300 for timber scattered in different governmental agencies and departments.
plantations in Nahan circle. Some of this coordination has been attempted by the Indian
With the above assumption and methodology there is a Council of Forestry Research and Education (ICFRE), but a
large variation in the per hectare value of forest land under great deal more needs to be done.
different kinds of uses. The lowest value of dense natural This study introduces some ecological aspects of forests
forest, which is US$20 500 per hectare, is in the Nahan circle into a valuation exercise to make it more policy-relevant and
and the highest is in the Bilaspur circle, which is US$23 000 to illustrate the limits of a single disciplinary approach or of
per hectare. The range of values in the case of lopped natural one instrument in the framing of policy. Such understanding
forest is from US$9 500 per hectare in Nahan circle to has existed in the policy domain, though it does not often
US$19 500 in Bilaspur circle. Similarly, the range of open get reflected in the dependence on quick and easily obtained
tree savannah varies from INR 3.14 lakhs3 per hectare in numbers. The larger understandings, which emerge from the
Nahan to US$17 000 per hectare in Bilaspur. Finally, timber study, are as follows are:
plantation has the lowest per hectare value ranging from • Although valuation, if carried out at the relevant scale
US$ 5300 per hectare in Nahan to USD 11 500 per hectare in and using the appropriate techniques, is important,
the Chamba circle. It is clear that there exists great variation aggregation and averages can at times be incomplete;
both across scale and land use in the value of forest land. • Before being put to use for policy purposes, valuation
methodology needs to be supplemented with an
examination of distribution of the value between
CONCLUSIONS stakeholders at local regional and national levels so that
appropriate fiscal mechanisms can be set up to ensure the
The extended NPV methodology used in this paper captures correct distribution of the value of the capital asset in the
variations even within the relatively small state of Himachal event of its conversion to another use.
Pradesh because it: • Distributional justice issues also require that a study of
(a) Takes into account spatial differences in forest stock rights, privileges and concessions accompany valuation
and density cover and inter-temporal differences in exercises.
anthropogenic use resulting in either sustainable or else
non-sustainable extraction;
(b) Accounts for biodiversity value outside natural parks. REFERENCES
Needless to say, there are constraints imposed by data
and information availability, which need to be improved over BANN, C. 1998. The economic valuation of tropical forest
time. Even though the methodology arrives at approximate land use: a manual for researchers. EEPSEA Research
figures, these are estimated with a higher level of confidence Report Series.
than averages based on states which make little sense in BISHOP, J.T. 1999. (ed.). Valuing forests: a review of
particular in the context of policy. methods and applications in developing countries.
Another significant finding is the sensitivity of results International Institute for Environment and Development
to the estimates of growing stock. This is particularly true (IIED) London, UK.
for carbon sequestration and timber values. As Himachal CHATURVEDI, A.N. 1992. Environmental value of forest
Pradesh has better estimates of growing stock, the degree in Almora in Anil Agarwal. Prices of forests, Centre for
of confidence in those estimates is high. As a matter of fact, Science and Environment, New Delhi, India.

3
1 lakh = 100 000
386 K. Chopra and P. Dasgupta

CHOPRA, K. B., BHATTACHARYA, B. and KUMAR, P. VINCENT R. J. 1999. A framework for forest accounting.
2002. Contribution of forestry sector to gross domestic Forest Science 45(4), 552–561. Data and Information
product (GDP) in India. Institute of Economic Growth, Sources for Empirical Exercise
New Delhi, India.
DASGUPTA, P. 2001. Human well-being and the natural
environment. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK
DASGUPTA, P. and MALER, K.G. 2000. Net national
product, wealth and social well-being. Environment and
Development Economics 5, 69–93.
EXPERT COMMITTEE 2006. Report of the Expert
Committee on NPV, submitted to the Supreme Court of
India, April, 2006.
FREEMAN III, A. M. 1993. The measurement of
environmental and resource values: Theory and methods.
Resources for the Future. Washington, DC, USA.
HAMILTON, K. and CLEMENS, M. 1999. Genuine savings
rates in developing countries. World Bank Economic
Review 13(2), 333–356.
HARIPRIYA, G.S. 2000 Accounting for carbon in the
national accounting framework of India. In J.R. HICKS
(ed.) 1946. Value and capital (second edition). Clarendon
Press, Oxford, UK. See http://hpforest.nic.in/wsanct2.
htm.
HICKS, J.R. 1940. The valuation of social income.
Economica 7, 105–124.
HICKS, J.R. 1946. Value and capital (second edition).
Clarendon Press, Oxford, UK.
IIED 2000. Himachal Pradesh forest sector review. Main
Report, International Institute for Environment and
Development, June.
INTERGOVERNMENTAL PANEL ON CLIMATE
CHANGE 2003. Good practice guidance for land use,
land use change and forestry. 2nd workshop on GHG
inventories in the Asian Region (WGIA), held 7–8
February, Shanghai, China.
KADEKODI, G. K. 2004 (ed.). Environmental economics
in practice: case studies from India. Oxford University
Press, New Delhi, India.
LELE, S. and VENKATACHALAM, L. 2003. Assessing
the socio-economic impact of changes in forest cover on
watershed services, Centre for Interdisciplinary Studies
in Environment and Development, ISEC, Bangalore,
India.
MEA 2005. Ecosystems and human well-being: our human
planet. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, Summary
for Decision-Makers, Island Press, Washington, DC,
USA.
MURTY, M. N. and GOLDAR, B.N. 2006. Economic
evaluation of investment projects in India. Institute of
Economic Growth, Delhi, India
NSSO 1999. Common property resources in India. NSS 54th
Round Report, National Sample Survey Organisation,
India.
SINGH, K. D. and NILSSON, N. E. 1974. On the problem of
identification and evaluation of environmental functions
of forests. Report of the FAO/ECE ad hoc meeting of
forest inventory experts, Geneva, Switzerland.

You might also like