You are on page 1of 21

INTRO

Throughout many common law and civil law nations, the notion of a corporation as a distinct institution
from its stockholders is generally understood. It is generally viewed as a foundational feature of
company law, and courts are hesitant to break from it. The notion of distinct personality, however, is not
universal, and courts in either common law or civil law nations have the authority to diverge from it.
When this happens, the courts are said to "pierce" or "lift" the corporate veil. This will almost always,
but not always, result in the imposition of culpability on another individual, maybe in adding to the
corporate body.

Removing the corporate veil entails ignoring the corporate image and seeing in behind curtain at the
real people in charge of the firm. In those other terms, when the legal company is used fraudulently and
dishonestly, the persons involved will not be able to hide behind the corporate identity. The case will be
pierced by the judge in this case. Per the Black Law Dictionary 's concept," the piercing the corporate veil
is the judicial act of imposing liability on otherwise immune corporate officers, Directors and
shareholders for the corporation's wrongful acts. “Aristotle said when one thinks of removing the
corporate veil of a form, one thinks of a procedure in which the company entity is ignored and the
incorporation bestowed by legislation is overcome by an act of the entity.

When the idea is at stake, it is allowed to prove that the person who stands behind the corporation is
obliged to fulfill its duties notwithstanding the business's status as a legal person. The Supreme Court
discussed the notion of removing the corporate veil in DDA v. Skipper Construction Co. Pvt. Ltd.,
Corporate entities were created to stimulate and develop commercial activity, not to do criminal acts or
deceive people. When the trade mark is proved to be hostile to fairness, ease, and pleasure of the
collector or worker, or just for national good, the corporate veil can unquestionably be broken.

The purpose is to compare and evaluate scenarios in which the curtain is breached with integration
aims. The common law countries of the United Kingdom and the United States are now being analyzed.
The main purpose of this research is to present a comprehensive and in-depth examination of how the
notion of lifting the veil, which has been legalized, works. Courts in several countries employ biblical
authority, either through court rulings or through law. There will be many similarities between the
countries being compared, regardless of whether they are under common law or civil law, in part
because the ancient and modern variables that led to the resurgence of corporation bodies were very
similar, and in component because the major company restrictions in the other areas listed in this study
are legal transplants.

The conceptual grounds of veil piercing, it is suggested, are found in the aspect of business form misuse.
Because corporate character arose in reaction to the social necessities, courts determine its boundaries
by looking at what courts interpret as the statutory language behind company laws, which is to achieve
positive socioeconomic and financial results through with an organizations context that enables
enterprise dealings. Because of the significance of corporations in the business world, the concept of
abuse is understood strictly in this situation, as there will requirement to be clarity in economic
concerns.
Other concerns, according to the research, justify a restricted approach to lifting the veil. For one thing,
looking outside the firm is typically only essential after the company has become insolvent. Creditor
lawsuits towards shareholders or administration, as a result, risk jeopardizing the collective bankruptcy
structure under which creditors’ rights is to be resolved. Additional issue is the possibility for veil
piercing to conflict with other legal principles, notably in tort law. Because tort legislation is primarily
concerned with identifying when civil wrongdoing occurs, it is frequently a better foundation for
deciding whether investors or administration may be held personally liable for a claimed creditor wrong.
Veil piercing has the potential to produce messy and amoral results.

It has been discovered that, in recent years, UK courts have taken a more restricted stance to veil
piercing, owing to the grounds described above. Other judges, in particular, perceive tort legislation as a
more suitable manner of addressing difficulties that are viewed through prism of corporation law in
other countries. Furthermore, although courts have yet to voice an opinion, they tend to be inclined to
more limited UK strategy. Courts in the United States, on either side, appear to take a broader view of
piercing. In the United States, this is due to the importance placed on shareholder ownership and
domination, as well as the use of piercing the corporate veil in circumstances where other judicial
factors would have decided the outcome. Other courts seem to have participated in veil piercing further
than any of the other four countries studied in this research for this reasons. Intermingling instances, for
example, account for the greatest number of piercings. However, some of the instances in issue involve
misuse of corporate property rather than intermixing. In those conditions, it is unsurprising that the
guilty shareholders should have been found liable and could have been brought liable within tort law;
disregarding corporate personhood was essential.

HISTORY

Apart from its American equivalent, which has received consistent court approval throughout time, the
English corporation veil theory has had a rocky road. The theory has elicited a range of reactions in
English courts, from excitement to downright hatred. The English doctrine's history may be loosely split
into three periods. The first phase spanned the years 1897, when the case of Salomon v. Salomon was
decided, through roughly World War II. This period is known as the early experimenting period, since
English courts explored with multiple alternatives to the theory throughout this time. Following the
wartime, the second era started and lasted until 1978, when Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council
was determined. This might be considered the apogee of the theory. Lord Denning, a passionate
champion and proponent of piercing the corporate veil and one of the most important English judges of
the latter part of the twentieth century, is responsible for much of the doctrine's vigor during this time.
Woolfson signaled the start of the third phase, which has seen the ideology fall out of popularity and has
persisted to this day.

Considering Salomon's renowned place in English law—the 1897 House of Lords ruling deeply rooted
the supremacy of distinct corporate identity and limited liability—easy it's to abandon that liability was a
contentious issue when it was first introduced. Salomon's limited liability policy was not formed. The
Limited Responsibility Act of 1855, on the other hand, gave limited liability to English firms. Salomon
simply stated that it is available to as such one-man businesses. When limited liability was initially
advocated in the mid-nineteenth century, it was met with fierce hostility. In an editorial from 1824,
Hardly anything can be more inequitable than for a few wealthy individuals to give a fraction of their
riches for the proposed company, to perform with that overabundance give the relevance of their entire
title and kudos to the culture, and then, should the monies of the incorporated body demonstrate
inadequate to meet all requirements, to withdraw into the safety of their unrisked fortune, and end up
leaving the lures to be swallowed up by the impoverished conned fist. Limited liability, at least as
applicable to "one-man firms," continued divisive after the Act's enactment.

This is obvious from the appellate ruling in Salomon v. Salomon, when the English Appellate court placed
individual accountability on Mr. Salomon for his business obligations. Despite the fact that the House of
Lords confirmed the independent legal existence of one-man firms in Salomon, the problem was not
finally resolved. Soon after Salomon, Courts started to breach the curtain. Apthorpe v. Peter
Schoenhofen Brewing and St. Louis Breweries v. Apthorpe, both taxation cases with substantially
identical circumstances, were among the first. Veil piercing was not limited to corporations with a single
ownership. The veil of corporations with several stockholders was frequently broken by the courts.

Following then, there was a period of great excitement for the corporate veil theory. Gilford Motor v.
Horne, In re Darby, Brougham, Trebanog Working Men's Club and Institute, Ltd v. MacDonald, and
Rainham Chemical Works, Ltd. v. Belvedere Fish Guano Co. were all victorious veil piercing judgments in
the early part of the twentieth century. Because there was no well-defined solution to the theory,
English courts had to rely on existing common law ideas like agency, guardianship, and tort rules to
settle corporate identity difficulties. These attempts attempted to produce a foundation that could be
used by everyone. However, the absence of a standard structure did not stop courts from penetrating
the curtain when the situation demanded it. This isn't to argue that litigants have always prevailed. In
other cases, the courts have declined to pierce the veil. Despite this, the corporate veil theory was
strong during this time. Professor Kahn-renowned Freund's 1944 paper, in which he described Salomon
as a "calamitous" judgment and argued for measures that would substantially curtail the extent of
limited liability, accurately represented the mood of the moment. He even considered legislating
Salomon's abolition.

Smith, Stone, and Knight v. Birmingham, the first effort by an English court to put forth thorough
standards for veil piercing, is the aberration to the paucity of a systems process during this era. Judge
Atkinson pointed out that if a branch may be deemed to be conducting trade on account of its parent,
which would allow veil piercing, is a fact-specific question. Judge Atkinson then continued to formulate
six important considerations for each case: (1) was the holding firm the top and brains of the marketing
endeavour? (2) Were the gains considered as the founder company’s revenues? (3) Was the parent firm
the top and brain of the trade endeavour? (4) Did the parent firm determine what must be
accomplished and how much money should be invested in the business? (5) Did the parent company
profit from its expertise and orientation? (6) Was the parent corporation in continual and effective
regulation? These answers are nearly identical to those used by US courts.

In reality, these requirements and the eleven situations described by Frederick Powell as suggesting that
a business is a simple instrumentality has a lot in common. Notwithstanding their broad breadth, these
standards have been widely ignored in future instances in the United Kingdom. One reason for this is
because English courts have tended to use conventional common law notions when implementing the
corporate veil theory. In the perspective of English courts, this effort at a complete list of veil piercing
requirements arguably represented judicial activism. One factor might be the case's peculiar facts, which
entailed the parent firm arguing for its curtain to be penetrated in attempt to get money from the
government. Following Smith, Stone, and Knight, future courts were able to separate their cases from
Smith, Stone, and Knight's, and decline to adopt their method. After World War II, the English corporate
veil concept reached its pinnacle. In re FG (Films), Jones v. Lipman, Firestone Tyre and Rubber v.
Lewellin, and Merchandise Transport v. British Transport Commission were all significant veil
penetrating cases during this time frame.

Lord Denning was responsible for a large part of the doctrine's vitality, as previously stated. Between the
1950s and 1970s, he was involved in a slew of business veil instances, including Scottish Cooperative
Wholesale Society v. Meyer, Littlewoods Mail Order Stores v. Inland Revenue Commissioners,
Wallersteiner v. Moir, and, finally, D.H.N. Food Distributors Ltd. v. Tower Hamlets London Borough
Council, the greatest well of all of them and. His excitement for the concept was best summed up in his
decision in Littlewoods, when he cautioned against blindly following Salomon: "The doctrine given forth
in Salomon v. Salomon & Co. [1897] A.C. 22 needs to be studied very carefully." It has long been
assumed that it creates a shroud over a limited company's character that the judges cannot see past.
That, however, is not the case. The curtain can be drawn apart by the courts, and it is frequently done.
They may, and frequently do, remove the face. They're looking behind them to see what's actually going
on. With financial deepening and other things, the senate has led the way. The courts must do the same.
Lord Denning's demand for more judicial discretion when it comes to character of the company is
admirable. Nevertheless, there is a distinction to be made between forcing group firms to disclose their
finances on an aggregated footing and dissolving group corporations for legal reasons (thus disregarding
their independent legal identities).

Economic statements are primarily for informative objectives, and accounts aggregation may have been
mandated by the legislation for causes unknown to restricted liability. However, Lord Denning's appeal
for judicial discretion in dealing with corporations would lead to his widely panned ruling in D.H.N. In
1956, the Supreme Court of the United States decided Lee v. Sheard, which was not a business curtain
piercing case. Lord Denning anticipated his thinking in D.H.N. by comparing a shareholder's connection
with his firm to partnerships. In D.H.N, a majority English Court of Appeal permitted a parent firm to sue
underneath the Land Compensation Act for business disruption. Despite the fact that the company and
the property it resided on were held by separate separate organizations "This case may be named the
'Three in One,'" Lord Denning said in his renowned verdict. Three businesses in one, instead, there's the
'One in three' theory. Three firms in one group." "[t]his group is substantially the equivalent as a
partnership whereby all 3 enterprises are partners," Lord Denning continued to outline the particular
financial unit idea. They must not be regarded differently in order to destroy them on a technicality."

"Modern English law has rejected the inflated view of Salomon's case... English law is now willing to
permit qualifiers of, and exemptions to, this rule, by removing the curtain of corporations," a notable
critic remarked that year. The corporation veil theory was at its pinnacle in that year. Following this, the
English court became more hostile to the concept, proving that the confidence was misguided. The
House of Lords publicly challenged the logic in D.H.N. two years later. Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional
Council, Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council, Woolfson v. Strathclyde Regional Council, Woolf "If
the Court of Appeal correctly used the concept that it is acceptable to pierce the corporate veil only if
unique conditions arise showing that it is a mere façade masking the underlying facts," Lord Keith of
Kinkel questioned. Woolfson marked the beginnings of the doctrine's demise. Despite Lord Keith's
refusal to overrule D.H.N., later cases showed that the same industrial unit concept and the corporation
veil concept were losing popularity.
The English Court of Appeal clearly dismissed the particular financial entity reasoning in Bank of Tokyo v.
Karoon, emphasizing that "we are concerned not with economy but with law." The difference between
the two is crucial in law and can be obfuscated here." In Adams v. Cape Industries plc, the English Court
of Appeal decided that the employment of company form to restrict future obligations is an intrinsic
component of corporate law, thereby ruling out veil penetrating in tort suits. It hasn't all been gloomy
and despair for litigants seeking to pierce the curtain since Adams. Two years later, in Creasey v.
Breachwood Motors Ltd., the court broke the veil separating two firms after their shared owners moved
the first corporate resources to the other to escape an approaching judgment. After expressly approving
the rationale in Creasey, the Admiralty Court disallowed the sale of a ship by one part of a business body
to another five years later, in a case containing very identical facts. However, in Ord & Anor v. Belhaven
Pubs, Creasey was overturned.

The present position of the English corporation curtain theory is aptly summarized by a notable analyst,
who stated: "Once one travels outside the sphere of specific treaties or legislation, the concept of
piercing the curtain has a minor role in British company law." Even if the evidence for applying the
principle appears strong, such as in the situation of a small, undercapitalized business which might or
might not be member of a bigger corporation, the courts are reluctant to do so. The opinion is that veil
breaching has become a rare under English law, after elevated decisions in the 1990s that came out
strongly against by the idea. Nonetheless, two recent examples imply that attitudes against veil piercing
may be changing. The English Court of Appeal broke the curtain between the parent firm and its
subsidiaries in Beckett Investment Management Group v. Hall to give effect to a promise not to interfere
in an employer. A series of expressions in Lord Justice Kay's opinion, which will be explored below,
highlight the importance of this issue for the corporation curtain concept. Similarly, in Stone & Rolls v.
Moore Stephens, a company's single owner and chairman put up a deceptive plan that its evaluation of
financial firms failed to detect,, and fleeced large amounts of money from various institutions.

After the business fell into insolvency, the liquidator filed medical malpractice charges against the
accountants. The question was whether the corporation's objectives should be imputed to the
responsible shareholder, preventing the firm from continuing its complaints against the auditors. The
majority of congress of Lords disregarded the company's independent legal existence and blamed it for
the shareholder's dishonest intents. As a result, the company's allegations against the auditors were
dismissed. The English corporation veil doctrine's fate is uncertain. Beckett and Moore Stephens may
herald a change in the doctrine's fortunes. While Adams cast question on the doctrine's application to
tort claims, Beckett confirmed the doctrine's validity in economic issues. Moore Stephens may also
suggest an English court readiness to break the corporate veil in cases involving deceptive solitary
businesses. A more rigorous conceptual model than that which now exists in legal precedent is required
for the doctrine's revival. This Essay will first make a comparison examination of the corporation veil
theory on the both sides of the Ocean before presenting such a structure.

SALOMON PRINCIPLE

The Limited Liability Act of 1855 is credited with establishing legal capacity. However, there were other
flaws, such as the fact that businesses could only be founded by royal charter or Acts of Parliament.
Corporations might be founded over time by the membership of members and the recording of details
in a central register. These amendments made it simpler for individuals to form firms, but numerous
courts rejected cases, claiming that people were just establishing their enterprises to escape future
debts. It wasn't till the seminal case of Salomon v. A. that it became clear. A.C. Salomon and Company
[1897] that the notion of limited by guarantee became a foundational principle in corporate law.

Salomon conducted a sole proprietorship boot producing firm, according to the evidence stated in the
given case. His firm began to struggle as a consequence of the weak economic, so he formed Salomon
Ltd; a corporation made up about himself and his family, and surrendered his single proprietorship to
the corporation for £39,000. The firm kept £20,000 of the £39,000 and instead awarded Mr. Salomon
20,001 shares in the firm out of a total of 20,007 (nominal value of £1 per share). Salomon's family
relatives controlled the other 6 shares. Mr. Salomon was also given a ten thousand pound movable
unsecured debenture.

Mr. Salomon's company, which he led as managing director, struggled to stay afloat and eventually went
bankrupt. As a result, Mr. Salomon sought to preserve the company by trading his debentures to a Mr.
Edmund for £5,000 and then loaned the money to the company at a ten percent interest rate. Despite
Salomon's attempts, the firm was forced to liquidate. The firm was worth £6,000 at the time. Mr.
Edmund (£5,000) was a secured creditor, and this sum was sufficient to repay him off. Mr. Salomon, on
the other hand, planned to use his equity stake in the debt securities to collect the remaining £1,000,
arguing that he'd be recognized as a creditor and repaid before of the company's debt holders.
Unsecured creditors claimed that Mr. Salomon and the corporation were one and same man, and that
as a consequence, Salomon must not be given precedence over them. As a result, the question emerged
as to if Mr. Salomon, who was Salomon Ltd's largest shareholder, would be individually accountable for
the company's debts to unsecured creditors.

The business was ruled a fiction by both the High Court and the Court of Appeal, because Salmon had
formed it against the provisions of the Companies Act 1862. Moreover, the court determined that Mr.
Salomon's firm, Salomon Ltd, was an agent of Mr. Salomon, and that Mr. Salomon should be held
accountable for the debt accumulated by the business throughout its employment. The judgments of
the High Court and the Court of Appeal were reversed on appealing to the House of Lords. The House of
Lords ruled that a business should be treated as an independent individual in the gaze of law if it was
officially and legally constituted. As a result of this judgment, Mr. Salomon was not directly accountable
for the firm's obligations, and the "corporate veil" between the corporation and its owners/shareholders
was formed. The formation or development of so "corporate veil" is what makes this situation so
important. When the House of Lords established the corporation entity, it constructed a barrier
between the company's (distinct legal identity, as noted above) and the owners'/shareholders'
identities.

The result in the Salomon v has been confirmed in a number of high-profile cases in the past, including
Macaura v Northern Assurance Co Ltd [1925] AC 619. When judges see the firm and its corporation
(owners, directors, and shareholders) as a single entity, exemptions to the notion of limited liability
occur. "Piercing the corporate veil" or "lifting the corporate veil" are terms used to describe this.

When the case is "lifted" or "pierced," the Company's officials are held accountable for the company's
obligations. This implies that the officer's own assets may be put at danger in order to pay off the
company's obligations.

In the below circumstances, the corporate structure can be removed or breached. Wrongful trading -
wrongful trading occurs when a director knows and should have fairly understood that the firm is
bankrupt or on the verge of bankruptcy and fails to take all necessary steps to limit creditor damages;
Standard Chartered Bank v Pakistan National Shipping Corporation [2002] UKHL 43 exemplifies the how
judges evaluate fraud in terms of the veil of incorporation and restricted responsibility. The courts ruled
in this instance that no one can pretend to have perpetrated a felony on account of others (in this
example, a firm with independent legal personality) in order to evade personal liability for the dishonest
activities; Avoidance of legal responsibility - This concept states that the business curtain will not shield
directors/shareholders who have lawful claims against them which are distinct from the business and
seek to evade individual culpability by relying on the firm's different legal identity. In the matter of
Petrodel Resources Ltd v Prest, the top court made this decision (2013); A corporation can serve as an
administrator if its membership, i.e. directors/shareholders, provide their permission. Individual
members are obligated by the company's (agent) activities in such instances, as long as those actions are
within the extent of power. As a result, the director/shareholders may be held personally accountable
for the agent company's actions.

After identifying what limited culpability and veil trying to lift are, their chronological fundamentals, how
they are formed, i.e. the veil of inclusion and distinct legal character, and their exclusions, we will look at
the benefits and drawbacks of limited liability that would start providing rationale for English courts
trying to balance the benefits and drawbacks.

There are certain reasoning for the aforementioned principles as follows:

1. Personal liability is reduced – this is the most prevalent and evident benefit of having a separate
legal identity and restricted liability. It's possible that it's the primary motivation for people to form
businesses. When a body corporate is formed, as previously said. This implies that if the firm falls into
economic difficulties, the directors' and shareholders' bank balance will not be utilised to wipe off the
firm's obligations, limiting their culpability.

2. Directors/shareholders can be limited by share or guarantee. When a shareholder is limited by


shares, their liability is limited to the amount they paid or are due to pay for the shares that they own.
When a company is limited by guarantee, there are members instead of shareholders. These members
are normally liable to pay an amount they have previously guaranteed to pay in case the company runs
into financial difficulty and has to pay of its debts. In most cases, the amount guaranteed by members in
£1.

Improved taxation strategy and efficiency- limited companies pay less in corporation tax than sole
traders paying basic or higher rate income tax. Currently, limited companies pay a fixed 19% corporation
tax. Additionally, when it comes to income policy, a restricted corporation provides far more freedom.
Limited company owners can reinvest excess money into the firm to cover future fees and expenses.
This implies that shareholders will take out less payments and spend less personal income tax, while also
ensuring that the company is fluid enough to weather any potential economic troubles.

3. Good security for your corporation - while forming a business, the proprietors must pick a name.
This identity must be unique and can be the the same identical to that of another current firm, which is
a restriction, but it also cannot be used or filed by another company. Sole merchants do not have access
to this type of security.
4. Provides a more good identity for your company - registration will give your company a more
official picture, which automatically contributes more honesty and respect. Moreover, because some
organisations, particularly those in the IT and financial industries, will only do work with company law,
this greater honesty may open multiple doors and boost revenue.

While there are certain benefits for incorporation of the doctrine, there are also detrimental impacts as
follows:

1. provides a more good identity for your company - registration will give your company a more
official picture, which automatically contributes more honesty and respect. Moreover, because some
organizations, particularly those in the IT and financial industries, will only do work with company law,
this greater honesty may open multiple doors and boost revenue.

2. Limited businesses are less discreet since they must be listed with Companies House and must
spend an establishment charge, which is an additional drawback. When a business is formed, all of its
private and business information becomes when extracting cash, submitting tax returns, yearly
accounts, and preserving records such as minutes of all meeting and documenting the conclusions
reached by directors and shareholders, an established firm must follow tight requirements.

IN SUMMARY: LIMITED LIABILITY IS A PRODUCT OF SEPARATE LEGAL PERSONNEL LIMITED LIABILITY IS A


PRODUCT OF SEPARATE Individual PER A firm's independent legal identity is developed and
distinguished from the personalities of its individual officials. Long before the decision of Salomon v
Salomon, the historical roots of limited liability exist publicly data.

While the Salomon decision strengthens the notion of limited liability, it, like every legal construct, is
vulnerable to anomalies. The term "lifting" or "piercing" the veil of incorporation refers to certain
instances.

The benefits of restricted liability are obvious, but there are also drawbacks, as previously stated. As a
result, it is up to each person to determine to choose if or not incorporated their company depending on
their own needs.

Current law
In Salomon's instance, the concept is subject to a number of limitations. Most importantly, legislation
may mandate that the corporation not be considered as an independent legal entity, either explicitly
or implicitly. Section 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 mandates that companies directors make a
contribution to the payments of financial liability in the event of a liquidation process if they allowed
the firm to continue accumulating debt when they should have known there was no reasonable
possibility of escaping bankruptcy.

Under a recent ruling, the Supreme Court confirmed that UK regulations allows a claimant to disregard a
corporation's distinct legal personality and "pierce the corporate veil" in certain situations. This is,
nevertheless, a one-of-a-kind cure. This is the first time the country's top court has recognized the
existence of an English law concept that allows courts to pierce the corporate veil. This concept applies
only in extremely specific circumstances, such as "where a person is liable to an established legal duty or
responsibility, or to an established regulatory limitation, which he intentionally avoids or whose
enforcement he actively delays by interposing a corporation under his control." The law can then raise
the veil in denying the corporation or its director the benefit that would have accrued if the firm had its
own legal personality. The majority of the legislatures put forward the view that this was as far as it is
willing to proceed in drifting apart from the set precedence of a corporation being treated as an
independent legal entity.

In Prest, Lord Sumption provided a clarification for the notion following:

1. In Saloman v. Saloman, the expression "piercing the corporate veil" refers to the dismissal of a
corporation's distinct identity, which happens when the court applies an exception to the norm.

2. The idea differs from a scenario in which the legislation imputes a company's decision to the persons
who manage it, while ignoring the company's separate legal personality.

3. Lord Sumption suggested two circumstances in which a person in charge of a firm may be held
accountable for some type of malfeasance:

a. The first is Lord Sumption's "concealment principle," which he believed didn't involve penetrating the
corporate veil. When a corporation or corporations are involved in a business, the real principals of the
contract are hidden. To put it another way, the parties are attempting to hide their operations behind a
"façade." In such circumstances, the Judge does not ignore a corporation's independent legal entity, but
rather exposes the real facts that the structure of a company was created to hide.

b. The "evasion principle" is the second. If there is a lawful entitlement against the individual in control
of the company and the company is deliberately interposed in order for the distinct legal corporate
personality to subdue the regulation of that right against the controlling person, the Judge may dismiss
the company's legal personality. The Judiciary may then breach the corporate entity, but only for the
aim of denying the corporation or its controller of the benefit that the business's independent legal
personality would have provided.

Lord Sumption's and Lord Neuberger's ideas were not universally embraced by the other five members
of the Court, thus this finding confirms a minority position. The most of the Court representatives were
hesitant to specify the doctrine's reach at all, with Lord Mance remarking that it is "frequently perilous
to strive to preclude all potential future scenarios which may emerge," and that he "would not like to do
so." Nevertheless, the foregoing principles represent the most recent pronouncement from England and
Wales' highest court about when a court can pierce the corporation veil, and they are likely to be
extremely convincing in future instances.

Given the restricted reach of the theory after Prest, it's hardly unexpected that there have been few
instances using the idea of penetrating the corporate veil. Given the severe requirements provided
down in Prest, courts are now extremely reluctant of attempting to breach the veil, according to the
authors' personal experience. They are more willing to employ alternative legal frameworks, such as
agency law and trusteeship principles, since they know these weapons do not constitute an invasion on
the corporation facade. For civil litigators the landmark precedence is set by Mrs Justice Rose in the case
of Pennyfeathers Limited v Pennyfeathers Property Company Limited [2013] EWHC 3530, which
included the development of land. Rose J, in ruling in favor of the plaintiffs, used both the concealment
and evasion rules to preclude D2 and D3 from hiding behind D1. In terms of the initial acquisition, it
should be shown that D2 and D3 breached their fiduciary responsibility by attempting to steer the farm
development potential to another firm. The law would not enable D2 and D3 to disguise their acts
behind D1's actions because of the concealing concept.
After defining the applicable standard, the Supreme Court unanimously concluded with the High Court
Judge that piercing the corporate veil on the facts of this case was not admissible. Mr Prest had not
been found guilty of any relevant misconduct by the judge in the first hearing. Mr Prest was not hiding
or dodging any legal responsibility due to his wife, despite the fact that he had acted wrongly in
numerous respects. It was especially significant because the legal ownership to the houses had been
transferred to the Corporations before the marriage ended. It could not be alleged that Mr Prest was
using the Companies to avoid paying his wife the divorce settlement. The judiciary yet decided that even
though legally the company owned the properties, the husband beneficially owned them hence
incurring the possibility of being transferred to the wife.

The Supreme Court collectively reversed the ruling of the Court of Appeal. Lord Sumption delivered the
main opinion, observing that the legislation pertaining to when authorities might pierce the corporate
veil was marked by "insufficient rationale."   Despite this ambiguity in the law, Lord Sumption stated that
the approach indicated in Adams v Cape Industries is that veil piercing needed some deception on the
part of the business member and was not merely a mechanism that could be used to guarantee fairness
in a specific situation. His house of lords further concluded that this concept had been reinforced in
Trustor AB v Smallbone (No 2), in which it was further determined that the dishonesty must entail the
incorporation of company law as a charade or sham to conceal genuine property ownership.

The Judicial Committee of the Privy Council, in its recent ruling in La Générale des Carrières et des Mines
v F G Hemisphere Associates LLC [2012] UKPC 27, was likely to undertake that the complainant was
correct in asserting that a judiciary in this authority could pierce the corporate veil, but it should be
mentioned that this was not contested by the respondent.

Prest respects the concept expressed in Saloman v. Saloman, which states that assets maintained under
business entities are not regarded to be the ownership of the corporation's manager unless the evasive
concept may be used. The Prest ruling, on the other hand, demonstrates that a judiciary has additional
instruments at its disposal when it wants to guarantee that a violator is unable to conceal behind a
company's independent legal identity. The Corporations concluded that the UK assets are on trust for
Mr Prest, according to the Court in Prest. Lord Sumption came to this judgment after seeing that most of
the Corporations were not continuously dealing, that the Corporations could not have supported the
acquisition of the properties they possessed, and that ownership was not related to oil trading activity.

Although it is impossible to predict when a justice may try to examine beyond a corporation's
independent legal personality, Prest shows that it is most likely to happen when a judge believes the
concept is being abused. Mr Prest was running his private business and utilizing the firms under his
authority as his own money vault. The lawful use of corporate entities for asset structuring and risk and
liability allocation, on the other hand, should be unaffected by the judgment.

Lord Clarke agreed with me. He believed that Munby J was correct in Ben Hashem v Al Shayif, that the
veil could only be breached when all other options had been explored. Furthermore, as he stated in VTB
Capital plc v Nutritek International Corp, it is incorrect to rule out all prospective piercing opportunities.
Insofar as VTB invokes the concept of piercing the corporate veil, its case includes what, at most, might
be described as an expansion of the conditions in which the corporate veil has historically been
penetrated. It is an extension because it would make the individual responsible of the firm accountable
as if he had been a co-contracting person with the business in question to an agreement to which he
was not a party. to summarize, apart from almost every other particular instance in which the judge has
pierced the veil of incorporation, VTB claims that Mr Malofeev should be respected as if he were, or had
been, a co-contracting person with RAP under the two agreements, despite the fact that neither Mr
Malofeev nor any of the contracting parties intended Mr Malofeev to be a party.

The idea that the doctrine can be applied in such a particular circumstance is unsupported by any
authority, with the exception of Burton J's court judgment in Antonio Gramsci Shipping Corporation v
Stepanovs [2011], Lloyd's Rep 647 (which he preceded in his later decision in Alliance Bank JSC v
Aquanta Corporation [2011], Lloyd's Rep 181, which was regarded by the Court of Appeal in 2012. None
of the other cases depended on by VTB in this instance are, on closer examination, helpful to its case.

The case does, nevertheless, demonstrate that if people wish to safeguard their assets against claims,
they must be cautious regarding the arrangement of their businesses and exert control over firms.
In preparation to comply with an unlawful attempt to conceal behind a corporate entity, the courts
might be creative in establishing a basis to overlook the independent legal personality of the business.

DENNING VIEW

The much-maligned single financial entity idea, which was first presented by Lord Denning, is making a
comeback. This ground-breaking viewpoint will enable a more logical concept of corporate veil piercing
cases. Regrettably, the judiciary's has not been majorly favorable to this view. Until the late 1970s,
judicial systems were known for being willing to pierce the veil when justice necessitated it. Lord
Denning is most credited with inventing the single economic unit hypothesis, which allows a court to
consider a company's parent and completely funded subsidiaries as a single entity, a concept that would
be considered expansive. The English corporate veil hypothesis has been plagued by the lack of a
comprehensive conceptual framework, which has contributed to the judiciary’s lukewarm indications.
The apparent haphazardness of legal precedent may account for some of the legislative opposition to
breaking the veil. One well-known English company law specialist termed the notion "palm-tree justice."
Instead of depending on old precedent to resolve corporate veil issues, English courts still seek the
adoption of an organized strategy to the conflicts.

Regardless of the relevance of this distinction, the judicial system has always been preoccupied with the
protection provided by limited liability, which must be restricted in order to ensure that business
operations are carried out evenly. An unrestricted market is based not only on the operation of limited
liability firms (enabling people to concur further monetary risks that otherwise they would not have
taken), but also on a necessary standard of justice in transactions. Denning LJ noted this in his remarks
at page 712 of Lazarus Estates Ltd v Beasley [1956] 1 QB 702: “No court in this land will allow a person to
keep an advantage which he had obtained by fraud. No judgment of a court, no order of a Minister, can
be allowed to stand it if has been obtained by fraud. Fraud unravels everything. The court is careful not
to find fraud unless it is distinctly pleaded and proved; but once it is proved, it vitiates judgments,
contracts and all transactions whatsoever...”

Where authorities are unwilling to completely ignore the curtain, a practice known as red lifting, they
use the method of creating an agency link. Lord Denning's decision in Wallersteiner is a good example:
after conceding that Dr. Wallersteiner's financial accounts were represented by numerous legal entities,
he added, "Even so, I am very convinced that they were essentially Dr. Wallersteiner's puppets." He had
perfect control over their every move. Each performed pertaining to his or her desires. He wielded the
greatest amount of control. No one else could come near to them. They were his operators, to use legal
lingo, who carried out his directives. He was the genius behind all of them.

It's interesting observing how Lord Denning shifts from remarking that the companies "were just the
puppets," i.e., had no separate entity, to later admitting that "they were his agents." Furthermore, the
veil is pulled back to disclose the true relationship shared by the majority owner and the businesses, and
the veil is breached in the sense of an agency agreement, making the majority owner accountable for
the activities of the company. A further method for seeing behind the curtain is to have a business
mirror a partnership and evaluate the close bond between partners and shareholders. Lord Halsbury
famously stated in the Daimler case, "...what is this thing which is described as a "corporation"?" In
actuality, it is a cooperation in all aspects save the names and, in certain ways, the position of those who
will be referred to as the managing partners.

The case of DHN Food Distributors Ltd. v. London Borough of Tower Hamlets exemplifies the notion. In
this authority, a business claimed compensation for the inconvenience caused by property
expropriation. The property, on the other hand, belonged to a third company, whose owners were
comparable to those of the other two. Lord Denning agreed with Gower's aphorism on the tendency to
disregard the corporate structures of individual enterprises within a group in favor of the broader
economic composition of the group. He emphasized that this is especially true when a parent company
owns all of the subsidiary's stock. These subsidiaries are accountable to the parent firm and are required
to carry out the parent company's commands. For the present, the three companies should be regarded
as a single entity.

Lord Denning's call for lot of consideration in flexibility in organizational personality cases is excellent. It
is critical to distinguish between requiring group enterprises to publish their records on a complete
structure and dissolving group organizations for liability concerns (thereby ignoring their separate legal
personality). Financial data is displayed solely for educational purposes, as required by law. Account
consolidation for non-restricted legal purposes. Nevertheless, Lord Denning's plea for courts freedom in
handling with corporations would result in his widely derided decision in D.H.N.

Lord Denning foreshadowed his reasoning in D.H.N. by equating a shareholder's relationship with his
corporation to a cooperation. While the corporation and the premises on which it located were owned
by separate corporate organizations, a unanimous British Court of Appeal in D.H.N. allowed a parent
corporation to seek reparation for inconvenience under the Land Compensation Act. Lord Denning
remarked in his landmark judgment, "This case may be termed the 'Three in One.'" Three companies in
one. There's also the 'one in three' hypothesis. They should not be interpreted differently in order to
defeat them on a technicality." "Modern corporate law has rejected the exaggerated interpretation of
Salomon's case... "By dropping the veil of corporations, English law is now ready to admit qualifiers and
exceptions to this concept," a famous expert commented the same year. In that year, the corporate veil
idea reached its apex. Following this, the English judiciary grew progressively hostile to the notion,
demonstrating that the optimism was misplaced.

In perspective of our four categories, it's intriguing to evaluate the legislation's stance in this
disagreement. It proceeded by peeping behind the veil to study the three firms at issue's shareholdings.
It was determined that the stockholders of all three firms were the same (and directors). This is a true
piercing of the curtain since each entity's direct role in the company's resources is acknowledged.
Ultimately, it broke through the curtain with the partnership strategic approach: "the group is effectively
the same as a partnership in which all three firms are partners." The last phase is to pull back the curtain
on the individuals of the group, permitting to be viewed as single, coherent entity: 'These corporations
as a group are entitled to compensation not just for the value of the property, but also for disruption.'

'They should not be treated separately so as to be defeated on a technical point,' Lord Denning MR says
emphatically. They should not be refused the payment they are owed for the difficulty they have
incurred. 'If each member of the group is recognized as a separate entity, nobody could have claimed
compensation in a situation that clearly calls for it,' Shaw adds. L.J. As previously noted, Lord Denning
was responsible for a significant element of the notion's life. In the years of 1950s and 1970s, he was
associated with several organization veil cases, including Scottish Cooperative Wholesale Society v.
Meyer, Littlewoods Mail Order Stores v. Inland Revenue Commissioners, Wallersteiner v. Moir, and,
finally, the landmark authority of D.H.N. Food Distributors Ltd. v. Tower Hamlets London Borough
Council. His enthusiasm for the notion was best shown in his judgment in Littlewoods, when he advised
against mindlessly adopting Salomon: "The principle set held in Salomon v. Salomon & Co. [1897] A.C. 22
must be further examined thoroughly." It has long been thought that it forms a cloud over the
personality of a limited corporation that the authorities cannot see through. Nevertheless, such is not
the case because judicial legislatures may and frequently do remove the curtain in order to uncover the
complete truth behind it. Lord Denning's flexible viewpoint, while advantageous, does not mesh well
with English courts, as has been often noted.

UNCERTAINTY OF LAW

The Supreme Court of Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd [2013] 2 AC 415 considers whether, and if so, how,
the judiciary is empowered to lift the corporate veil in the absence of clear legislative authorization. Lord
Sumption gives more insight on the notion of misuse of corporate identity under English law in this case.
First and primarily, he distinguishes between evasive and hidden scenarios. The first covers a
circumstance in which the individual establishes the firm in order to evade the earlier duty imposed on
whomsoever it may concern. The latter happens when the identities of the important "actual players" is
concealed by the corporate veil. Only avoidance, according to Lord Sumption, may justify the use of the
penetrating the corporate veil concept. In order to   seeks to discover the justification for the inclusion
of the avoidance and concealment criterion, which appears to be a limitation of the breaching the
corporation concept to the extent where it will have no implication in future instances.

Lord Sumption, on the other hand, claimed that the phrases "sham" and "facade" should be substituted
with "evasion" and "concealment." Where accountability has been concealed, he said, there would be
no mandatory requirement to breach the corporate veil since, as Lord Neuberger acknowledged, all that
is necessary is to examine behind the veil to determine the genuine players. Lord Sumption claimed that
Lord Neuberger took this stance in VTB, but held that because the court in the circumstance did not
need to lift the corporate veil, it could not be used as precedent in Prest. The Prest decision explained
that breaching the veil would only be allowed when legal regulations of a company was incorporated to
evade liability, while this is not sufficient, and that even where certain evidence of wrongdoing had
originated, it would typically be viable to award a relief by applying a further aspect of the legislation, in
this scenario trust fundamentals were applied to secure Mrs Prest was authorized to a beneficial
interest in the properties. Prest thus demonstrated that, while the corporate veil may be penetrated in
some cases, it is unclear what those situations are outside the notion that the relief is only a final option,
and as such, it appears that the judgment refused to address benefit of the chance to clarify the
legislation.

The contrast between avoidance and concealment is much more difficult to grasp and defend. The
questionable character of it can already be apparent in Lord Neuberger's judgement, which contested
the assumption that both the Jones and Gilford verdicts were evasion situations, despite the fact that he
identified the difference as it is. Furthermore, Schall correctly notes that in both the Trustor and Gencor
instances, which Lord Sumption cites as exemplifications of the concealing issue, there is de facto
avoidance of the earlier fiduciary responsibilities, specifically "the responsibility not to accomplish the
illicit transactions."

The biggest criticism levelled at this difference is the absence of any established basis for establishing it.
Lord Sumption, in his judgment, based the evasion side of the difference primarily on the presence of a
duty or constraint that an individual wishes to avoid by using a business structure. Concealment differs
from evading in that the latter only addresses the right scenario for penetrating the veil. Nevertheless,
supposing the reasonableness of an individual (natural or juridical) who means to disguise some details
by utilizing a business structure, it would be meaningless for her to do so but for the presence of some
responsibilities or limits, the breach of which inevitably leads to his or her culpability. As a result, the
difference between concealment and obfuscation is de facto a distinction between evasion and other
situations in which more traditional remedies allowing the judge to recognize the shareholder with the
corporation are accessible.

Some observers have stated that the Prest ruling should be "welcomed" because, while it confirms that
the Salomon doctrine is a fundamental of UK company law, it also acknowledges that there will be
occasions in which the curtain can be broken in order to offer a redress. This author, on the other hand,
finds such a viewpoint difficult to comprehend. While the scenario makes it clear that veil incision will
only be acceptable where there has been avoidance of debts and no other legal relief will provide an
effective solution, as shown above, the judgment provides no evidence of precisely the situations in
which the veil may still be pierced, hence the ruling should be viewed only as adding to the uncertainties
surrounding this aspect of the law. Indeed, one cynical observer has suggested that Lord Sumption
"almost looked happy" that the veil could not be penetrated in Prest because it ensured he would not
require to define the "definitive" grounds under which the veil may be pierced in the prospective.
Leaving aside cynicism, this author believes that, while Prest has restricted the doctrine by clarifying that
it is only to be employed as a last resort, a future decision will be necessary to confirm specifically when
the notion may be applied.

Lord Sumption strives in Prest to limit merely the façade concept to a firmer and more constrained
criterion. Nonetheless, it is difficult to argue that the notion of abusing the company's unique identity is
not a clear improvement over the façade/sham-test in terms of clarity and certainty. All of Lord
Sumption's constraints render the theory of breaching the veil essentially impotent. Presumably, there is
still the opportunity to dismiss the distinct legal entity concept in cases when concealment occurs, but it
is difficult to provide a concrete example of evasion. In actuality, the evasion principle serves primarily
to prevent shareholders from using the piercing notion to make them accountable for what is a
corporation responsibility (i.e., the idea has an inherent hurdle to 'forward piercing'). It also, at least
implicitly, excludes the piercing the veil theory from the legal setting since establishing new exceptions
to the Salomon principle will be more problematic (if at all).
Simultaneously, there is the concealing principle, which is concerned with alternative remedies that may
be presented when the corporation is used to obstruct third parties from exercising their rights. Lord
Sumption said nothing further at this moment. Lord Sumption did not further elaborate at this moment.
The ambiguity in Lord Sumption's ruling may inspire judges to rely more on traditional instruments, such
as those found in agency, trust, and tort law, and implement them in the framework of company law.

This is inclined to consider that there is a threat of undue interference in the manner the business
structure may be used in the corporate world. It's important to note that the corporation's liability for
investors' duties should be limited in the same way that shareholders' liability for the corporation's
defects is. The Prest case has sparked debate among many writers, demonstrating that practically all
incidents of legal personality abuse may be resolved via more traditional procedures. As a result, Lord
Walker was correct when he said that "through the corporate veil" is "only a name [...] to capture the
various instances on which a legal system provides evident exceptions to the concept of a body
corporate's independent juristic identity". Lord Sumption's goal, it appears, was to urge authorities to
center their conclusions on more traditional remedies instead of appeal to some hazy ideas by creating
the evasion and concealment difference. The issue is that he did it under the guise of avoidance and
secrecy, which was needless.

US LAW comparison

Notwithstanding these significant distinctions, the Article illustrates that many English corporation veil
decisions follow a comparable objective method to the utilitarian theory under US law. As a result, it is
conceivable to establish an English utilitarian concept that will provide the English corporate curtain
theory coherence and consistency. The article finishes with a reintroduction of Lord Denning's much-
maligned one macroeconomic unit thesis. This new concept will allow for a more methodical response
to corporate veil breaching instances.

At first look, it appears that the corporate veil principles on both sides of the Ocean are incompatible.
While judges in both nations have claimed the court's responsibility in avoiding corporate organization
abuses—and discussions of limited liability and the corporation veil concept in both countries frequently
begin with Salomon v. Salomon —the English court is notably more cautious. US courts, on the other
hand, have shown a stronger readiness to act when the circumstance calls for it. Nevertheless, the
discrepancies between these two countries are more than just variances in plaintiff victory rates. The
English and American courts have fundamentally different views on court ruling, judiciary rights and
powers to manufacture current regulatory theories, the importance accorded to political concerns, and
the function of fairness and its possible clash with theoretical principles.

1. General Deference to the Separate Corporate Personality Principle

In General there are many different types of corporate veil instances. The classic corporate veil case is
when the business identity is ignored and the investors are held to account for the company's liabilities.
For both concept of distinct company identity and the principle of limited liability—which states that a
shareholder's culpability for a company's obligations is restricted to the amount of his stock investor
overruled in this situation. Since veil breaching exposes shareholders to company debts, such cases are
known as stakeholder responsibility cases. 101 Different sorts of business veil instances exist, in which
the single company persona is ignored without imposing shareholder accountability. A subsidiary, for
instance, may well be treated as if it were not a different legal organization in order for a judge to have
power over the holding company or to force the submission of documentation from a corporation.

A independent corporate identity could be established in order to reclaim profits from theft that have
been placed into a firm. For the goal of assessing the extent of a controlling director's obligations, the
parent and affiliate major corporations may be compacted. These examples have been dubbed
"identification" cases by some observers, whereas others have adopted the more vivid analogy of
"peeping behind the curtain" by others. Although investor responsibility has been established in the
majority of corporation veil instances in the United States, shareholder responsibility is seldom enforced
in English proceedings.

This conversation has two major ramifications. First, unlike its American equivalent, the English
corporate veil concept never focused on imposing investor culpability. Instead, it has taken a far wider
approach, with identifying actions accounting for the majority of English corporate veil proceedings. 118
The effort to establish apart independent company personalities is what puts an English case within the
corporation veil theory, not the imposition of investor accountability.

Second, efforts to breach the veil of a legitimate firm are exceedingly difficult to succeed under English
law. The Adams court 's judgment to fail to breach the veil was based on the implicit assumption that
the U.S. branch was a legitimate business organization with a full-fledged mesothelioma enterprise.
Even, the House of Lords did breach the veil in the case of Rainham Chemical Works; the Law Lords'
argument was primarily based on common law ideas like employment privileges.

Rainham has also garnered little notice from the courts and pundits since then. However, if certain
components of the theory are fulfilled, US courts have been ready to breach the curtain of a legitimate
business. 122 In terms of jurisprudence, the English application to the corporate veil concept indicates a
far more deferential stance towards restricted responsibility than the American approach.

2. Reliance on Traditional Common Law Concepts

Aside from their overall attitudes toward the corporate veil theory, the English and American courts'
interpretations to the theory vary in a few key respects. While US court system have been willing to
create new teachings such as the utilitarian theory and the change ego ideology to analyse corporate
veil cases, their English equivalents have frequently limited themselves to trying to apply common law
principals such as agency and trust. In In re (FG) Films, the court determined that the British corporation
incorporated by its U.S. parent acted as the latter's representative for film record reasons.

3. The English Court of Appeal described Mr. Salomon as the beneficiary in Broderip v. Salomon,
and his business as "something illegally called into life by him to allow him to do what the laws bans."
126 In both cases, the court overturned the corporations' independent legal personalities due to the
unlawful objective of formation. Although some US courts have used agency principles to corporate veil
issues, the number of such instances is still minimal. 129 In corporate veil situations, other legal system
ideas are infrequently used. 130 In D.H.N.1, the English courts made a remarkable endeavour to develop
a new theory.

4. Absence of Overarching Theory


With exception of corporate veil instances in the United States, the English concept does not have an
overarching theory or analytical methodology. Frederick J. Powell initially proposed the utilitarian thesis
in the United States in 1931. 136 Since then, a number of state courts have embraced some form of this
approach. 137 In English cases, on the other hand, no broad analytical framework can be recognised,
and the English courts have not defined important criteria or factors. English courts typically divide
cases into one of many groups depending on a combination of the legal ideas utilised and the practical
conditions in which the issue arises.

The classifications of agency and trusts are based on the legal ideas used. But at the contrary side,
fraudulent, taxes, and Companies Act proceedings are founded on the nature or constitutional
foundation of the main allegations. The group company class includes situations in which the defendant
is a company and the plaintiff is trying to establish organization liability on a corporate unit.

The preceding reasoning might lead you to believe that the American and English methods to veil
piercing are inherently incompatible. This isn't the case at all. Unexpectedly, a number of the categories
in the current English approach have similar problems and characteristics with Powell's U.S.
instrumentality concept.

5. The Role of Policy Considerations

The willingness of the latter to accept and examine the political factors behind the law or legal rule at
question is a third distinction between the US and English judicial orientations to the corporate veil
theory. 153 In matters involving the construction of a legislation, US courts have frequently
acknowledged the statute's policy justification. The Sixth Circuit Court of Appeals, while evaluating
whether to breach the corporate veil in National Labor Relations Board v. Fullerton Transfer & Storage,
regularly referenced to federal labour rules and concentrated on if there is “a specific attempt to thwart
labor law obligations.”

In Walkovszky v. Carlton, the court discussed the legislative grounds underlying the New York Vehicle
and Traffic Law's minimal responsibility rules, as well as the necessity for the court to avoid from
second-guessing or overturning it. The courts have also recognised the unique policy problems that
underpin federal income tax and insolvency rules. Even where there were no explicit legislation at issue,
US courts considered basic policy making. In Swearngin v. Sears Roebuck & Co., for example, the court
upheld the trial court's decision to pierce the veil of a two-tier corporate architecture designed to thwart
liability cases against the producer.

The English courts, on the other hand, do not give policy concerns the same weight.The question in
Commissioner of Inland Revenue v. Sanson, a taxation issue, was whether the company in question
related to the corporation or the majority investor, which would affect the participant's tax bill. 160 The
English Court of Appeal determined the issue by using agency notions and emphasising the reality that
the shareholder had given a loan to the corporation, rather than depending on appropriate taxation
regulations.

The English corporate veil principle has a number of jurisprudential aspects that are linked. There is
minimal must to recognise the impact conceptions of fairness and policy issues because of the
structuralist attitude to court judgement and the strong commitment to distinct corporate identity
inherent in Salomon. This contra of justice and policy eliminates the use of a new conceptual approach,
enabling English courts to depend on conventional common law ideas that were not designed with
corporate veil piercing in view and are inadequately to judging corporate veil matters.

The evolution of the corporate veil theory in the United States differs from that of its English equivalent
and represents the various legal ideology that prevails in the United States. Common law principles were
used to investigate corporate veil difficulties in the United States at first, but they were swiftly shown to
be inadequate.

Unlike its English equivalent, tradition has permitted courts to concentrate on the most significant
aspects of corporate veil cases. 194 The employment of agency notions by US courts exemplifies this
distinction. In corporate veil cases, American courts have used these notions in the same way that their
English equivalents have. Nonetheless, US courts were quick to recognize the limits of agency notions.
While agency notions may be helpful in negotiated agency connections explicitly outsourced for by the
stakeholders.

The insufficiency of agency principles for addressing corporate veil allegations was also emphasized by
early US writers. Instead of in the classic common law meaning, some US judges use the word "agent"
synonymous with "instrumentality." Classical agency notions have essentially gone into the background
in U.S. corporate veil doctrine, unlike their English counterparts.

Whilst English judges' resistance to creating new legal theories is compatible with their overall judicial
ethos, it's important recalling that common law conceptions were created by jurists in the first place.
They are based on antecedents that are hundreds of years old in certain circumstances. For example,
negligence, which is the most common ground for tort liability, was a judicial process developed theory
that was only widely acknowledged in the 19th century. When the necessity came, English judges did
not refuse to develop this new theory in order to address the urgent issues of the day.

Reformulation of the concept

1. Involuntary Piercing

The single economic entity hypothesis has been discussed hence much under the assumption that it
merely pertains between a corporate parent and its subsidiary companies. Such groupings were
depicted in both a D.H.N. and Beckett. One issue with this limited area of application is that it makes the
theory vulnerable to exploitation. Because they both required consensual piercing, there was no worry
about subversion in those 2 situations. Nevertheless, in the case of involuntary piercing, a corporate
parent seeking to avoid shareholder accountability may do so by merely introducing a nominal
shareholder to the subsidiary. To prevent this, the theory must be changed such that it still applies in
circumstances when the new owners are essentially nominal. To outrun the scope of the principle, non-
corporate parent shareholders must demonstrate meaningful autonomy from the holding company.

For activating the concept, entire or almost total share ownership is just a required not sufficient—
condition. Only when the corporate parent has direct control over the subsidiary can it be held
accountable for its actions and obligations. Control is a necessity that is in line with monetary
evaluation. Inferences about the corporate parent's lower data expenditures and rich potential
risk abilities, as well as the debate that shareholder liability will not dissuade a corporate parent from
making an investment in its subsidiary, are both based on its direct authority over the subsidiary.
Without ultimate control, a corporate parent could no longer be the least-cost analyzer or efficient risk-
bearing capacity.

The financial grounds for implementing the notion of the single economic unit will be weakened.
Greater than only the ability to nominate directors is required for control. Only if a corporate parent can
direct a subsidiary's daily activities is it considered to have control over it.   The capacity to elect
directors alone may not be enough for the parent to reduce its expenses and effectively manage its
potential losses to the subsidiary. Furthermore, any corporate parent with 100% or almost 100%
ownership of its subsidiaries has the authority to nominate directors. If simply having the capacity to
nominate directors satisfies as control, the control criterion would be effectively nullified.

Nonetheless, it is still unclear who should have the responsibility of showing or disproving control. From
an evidential standpoint, the corporate parent should bear the burden of proof since it will have easier
access to the material needed to disprove its influence over the subsidiary. This can be accomplished by
demonstrating that the board of directors uses independent judgment in the subsidiary's everyday
activities or that the company has previously been conducted in contradiction to the parent's wishes To
use the one economic unit argument in an involuntary piercing action, the plaintiff must first show that
the subsidiary has no independent owners, which produces a presumption of real control by the
corporate parent. The parent then bears the onus of proof in rebutting the inference of control.

The parts of the theory that have been explored so far concern the subsidiary's territorial integrity, or, to
use the phrase of the instrumentality concept, the subsidiary's monetary value. The single economic unit
hypothesis, as a modification of the corporate veil concept, should necessitate inappropriate action or
intention, at least in the case of involuntary piercing. This is similar to the instrumentality notion's
appropriateness criterion.

Having considerable justification for this approach in Rainham Chemical Works, where shareholder
responsibility was enforced in the absence of propriety for a corporate tort, the weight of English legal
precedent plainly shows that irregularity must be evident before shareholder liability may be inflicted.
As a result, once the corporate parent's control is recognized, the plaintiff's burden of evidence changes
to proving the presence of wrongdoing. Finally, the plaintiff should be required to create that the
parent's wrongful behaviour adds to its loss, in keeping with a previous recommendation of including a
proximate causation criterion in an English instrumentality theory. Once all of these conditions are
satisfied, the single economic unit theory is used to hold the corporate parent liable.

Both backward and lateral piercing should be allowed only under specific conditions. They should be
permitted only if there is proof of asset stripping to avoid responsibility. The case of Yukong Line of
Korea v. Rendsburg Investments demonstrates the importance of lateral piercing in avoiding
responsibility avoidance Rendsburg had reneged on a charter-party agreement with Yukong after
economic conditions had worsened in that instance. Rendsburg's shareholder moved its assets to
another firm managed by him on the same day. Although the shareholder in question was an individual,
the identical chain of events could easily occur with a corporate parent. A corporate parent might do
exactly what Yukong did to avoid responsibility without lateral piercing. One could wonder why the
lateral piercing method provided for involuntary piercing is plainly unsuitable for voluntary piercing.
Jurisdiction, impropriety, and causality issues associated with deciding whether voluntary piercing
should be limited to asset stripping scenarios and not applied to all integrated subsidiaries
Although macroeconomic research shows that lateral piercing against connected subsidiaries should be
possible, assessing the level of financial interconnectedness of related firms is challenging. It
necessitates a high level of commercial knowledge on the side of the courts. Furthermore, given British
courts' legalistic stance to judicial ruling and antipathy to nondoctrinal concerns, such an investigation is
exceedingly implausible. As a result, lateral piercing is restricted to asset stripping circumstances.

2. Voluntary Piercing

Another question is whether the single financial entity idea should be open to voluntary piercing at all.
Given the broad grounds against voluntary piercing, the approach should presumably not be applicable
in voluntary piercing instances. Beckett, on the other hand, demonstrated the British courts' continued
commitment to hear voluntary piercing assertions. If the concept is made accessible for voluntary
piercing, it should be done only in extraordinary situations. Few mitigating situations should be accepted
in order to keep voluntary piercing under the single economic unit theory to a minimum level. Following
the determination of a mitigating event, it is up to the judiciary to examine the equity and policy factors
of the circumstances in order to determine whether voluntary piercing may be permitted.

For a variety of purposes, such a wide method is best suited for voluntary piercing. To begin, the huge
strain approach provided for involuntary piercing is manifestly unsuitable for consensual piercing. The
problem of control, impropriety, and causation in relation to plaintiff loss has bare minimum to do
with whether or not voluntary piercing should be authorised. Second, while many involuntary piercing
matters have the same fundamental problem of limited responsibility, voluntary piercing cases involve
such a broad range of circumstances that a comprehensive framework for judging them is likely
unattainable.

Third, in every voluntary piercing matter, the court will have to decide whether the corporate parent
should be permitted to lay apart its own subsidiary's independent personality following reaping the
advantages of incorporation. As a result, a totality of factors approach is most likely the best answer.
Even though this means that there will be minimal consistency in voluntary piercing instances, the
essence of voluntary piercing appears to make an absence of legal certainty unavoidable.

Conclusion

In this aspect, legal revision is required to bring the British stance nearer to that of other regimes that
have built a more consistent framework. Presently, the notion of penetrating the corporate veil
continues to be a significant issue since the constitutional underpinnings of it have yet to be adequately
established by the English Courts. Certainly total reformation of the theory is too extreme, but the idea
of restoring its underpinnings is not too far-fetched. Meanwhile, the Judiciary try to retain from properly
accommodating breaching the corporate veil, preferring adhering to the concept of last resort.
Grantham has criticized the Prest test as 'legalistic, formalist, and technical,' adding that it 'expressly
avoids looking at the content and economic impacts.'

There are no hard and fast rules governing the notion of penetrating the corporate veil. For years,
authorities have labored to establish and enhance their examination of these allegations. Each
successive action, nevertheless, introduces a fresh set of relevant facts into the picture, and a distinct
assessment must always be rendered as to whether the plaintiff has substantiated adequate proof of
power and influence, inappropriate purpose or use, and ensuing injury.
The choice to breach the corporate veil may be aided, at least partially, by the advice of experienced
specialists. Advisory opinion, particularly, would assist the trier of fact in deciding whether the business
has been sufficiently funded for its original purpose. On the other hand, the decision to overlook the
corporate organization will finally rely on weighing of numerous considerations, all or some of which are
required but may not be adequate to penetrate the veil. The Court of Appeal's decision in the Adams
case can be stated to be the current policy, which is nothing more than a reaffirmation of the House of
Lords' decision in Solomon's case. The basic line is that only the judiciary will raise the curtain in the face
of egregious misuse of the corporate structure. Furthermore, the tendency of a rise or reduction in
judicial pronouncements addressing the uplifting of the veil of a corporate body cannot be determined
because each court's position on the lifting of the corporate veil is dependent on the facts of each case.

There is no debate about the significance of corporate identity and restricted liability. There is no other
notion that can replace the concept. In a nutshell, without the notion of limited liability, it is hard to
imagine the smooth operation of a business in the present day. Conversely, when someone abuses the
benefit of limited culpability, it causes serious injury to the general public. Talented and genuine
businessmen lose interest in commercial transactions, creditors lose interest in investing, and ordinary
shareholders live their days in fear and uncertainty. Exploitation of the Privilege, in the end, becomes a
hindrance to the advancement of the commercial transaction. The goal of the idea of independent
corporate personality, as mentioned previously, is to stimulate and expedite industrialization or
economic transactions, not to block them.

The corporate veil concept, as a criteria exception to the general principle of restricted liability, entails
the basic decision confronting every domain of law and every judicial framework: the decision between
legal certainty and the accomplishment of justice in specific instances. Limited liability fosters legal
certainty and stimulates corporate investment. However, as many courts have realized, stubborn
defense of it will result in injustices on specific instances. It is the corporate veil doctrine's job to
guarantee that injustices do not occur. Given the United Kingdom's more liberal image, it may come as a
surprise that US courts have adopted a more active stance to piercing the corporate veil. What causes
this apparent disparity would most likely need a thorough examination of the judiciaries in these two
countries.

As a result, it is plainly evident that integration does not eliminate personal accountability at all times
and under all conditions. "Honest enterprise through firms is permitted; but, the public is safeguarded
against kitting and humbug." The integrity of a distinct entity is maintained only to the extent that the
entity is consistent with the foundational policies that give it existence.

As a result, those who profit from the formation process must ensure a corporate structure appropriate
to the scale of the firm. They are not permitted to remove company assets or mix their personal
accounts with those of the company. The Judiciary have used these circumstances as evidence to
warrant imposing culpability on the stockholders in the past.

The process of breaching the corporate veil is still one of the foremost contentious topics in company
law. There are several classifications, such as fraud, agent, charade or façade, injustice, and cooperative
operations that are seen to be the most unusual grounds for the Judicial Systems to pierce the corporate
veil. However, these divisions are only recommendations and are far from exhaustive.

You might also like