You are on page 1of 10

Farm Sector Performance and Reform Agenda

Author(s): Rip Landes and Ashok Gulati


Source: Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 39, No. 32 (Aug. 7-13, 2004), pp. 3611-3619
Published by: Economic and Political Weekly
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4415385 .
Accessed: 09/04/2014 07:03

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Economic and Political Weekly is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Economic and Political Weekly.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Bpecial articles

Farm Sector Performance


and Reform Agenda
Recent political changes in India have brought back agriculture to the centre stage of policy
discussions. How long it stays there is yet to be seen. But it would be worth analysing the
structural and policy-induced changes in agriculture since the reformsstarted in 1991, and try
to build a political consensus on the reform agenda that can put agriculture on a higher
growth trajectory, makes it globally competitive and enables the masses to share in its gains,
and is also sustainable in the long run. This paper is an attempt in that direction.
RIP LANDES, ASHOK GULATI

achievementof consensusonreformcouldhavepositiveimpacts
Introduction on the performanceof agriculture.

D uring 1991-93, India introduced major reforms to indus- II


trial, trade, and exchange rate policy that helped spark
India's emergence as one of the fastest growing deve-
Impactof Non-Agricultural
Reforms
on Agriculture
loping countries. Since 1990, annual GDP growth has averaged
5.6 per cent and consumer price inflation has averaged just The macroeconomicreformsof 1991-93havehadat leasttwo
8 per cent, with performance on growth and price stability even importantimpactson the agriculturalsector.First,deregulation
stronger in more recent years. External accounts, previously a of industry,moreopen trade,anddevaluationarewidelyagreed
chronic weakness of the Indian economy, have turned robust, to have stimulateda significant improvementin the rate of
with rising exports and current account surpluses pushing economic growth, thus strengtheningand diversifying food
foreign reserves to more than $100 billion. Most importantly, demand.Second,althoughdomesticandborderpoliciesdirectly
the share of the population in poverty has dropped from 39 per affectingagriculturewere not includedin the reforms,reduced
cent in 1987-88 to 26 per cent in 1999-2000 [Government of levels of industrialprotectionhave improvedincentives for
India 2003a]. investmentin agriculturethroughimprovementsin the sector's
The 1991-93 reforms, and the growth they have spawned, have domestictermsof trade.
created pressures for change in agriculturalpolicy. Food demand Anadditionalimpactof thereformsmaystemfromthestrength-
is growing and diversifying, in turn placing new demands on ening of the balanceof paymentsand its influenceon policy
marketinfrastructureand institutions. Long-standing production, priorities.Comfortablereservelevels anda muchmoreresilient
procurement,and distributionprogrammesfocused on foodgrains balanceof paymentshaveprobablyallowedpolicy-makersto be
are increasingly expensive and out of step with market demand. less focusedon agriculturalself-sufficiencyandmoreamenable
Burgeoning subsidy outlays are constraining public investment to the modest,mostlyunilateral,openingof tradein agricultural
in transforming institutions and market infrastructure, while a goods that came later in the 1990s.
thicket of regulation appears to be restricting private agribusiness
investment. And, despite improved growth in the overall
Rising Incomes and Agriculture
economy, growth in farm output and, particularly,ruralemploy-
ment is slowing. The most importantimpactof the 1991-93reformson Indian
There have been some important changes in agricultural agriculture hasbeenthestrengthening anddiversificationof food
policy since the early 1990s, including removal of quanti- demandresultingfromfastergrowthin percapitaincomes.The
tative trade restrictions required by the Uruguay Round Indianeconomyhas now expandedat an annualrateof 5.8 per
Agreement on Agriculture (URAA), and initial steps to pare cent(4 percentpercapita)sincetheearly1990s,rankingit among
down regulation of domestic input and output markets. The the fastestgrowingdevelopingeconomiesduringthe period.As
recent elections have sharpened the focus on the performance important,fastergrowthwas achievedwhile maintainingprice
of agriculture, but political consensus for fundamental reform stability.Percapitaincomeis nowabout$2,530atpurchasing power
in agriculture has, in the past, been elusive. The goals of this parity[WorldBank2003] and middle-andhigh-incomehouse-
paperare to survey the performance of agricultureand agricultural holdsincludingmorethan200 millionconsumersnow comprise
policy since the 1991-93 reforms, and identify key areas where thefastestgrowingcomponents of thepopulation 2003].
[Bijapurkar

Economic and Political Weekly August 7, 2004 3611

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure 1: Growth of Food Consumption in India productsare now showing relatively high, even accelerating
12% - - - - -- - - -. -.- - - -
01970s 01 980s * 1990s growth.
--- - .-
10%-- ---.-------
Strongerandmorediversefood demandis placingnew pres-
8% - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - sureson agriculturalpolicy, rangingfromresearchprioritiesto
6% -
the developmentof public and privatemarketinstitutionsand
facilities to efficiently meet these demands.Shifting demand
patterns,when combinedwith official price and inputpolicies
and institutionalinertiafavouringcereals,providethe context
for the costly build-upof wheat and rice surplusesbeginning
in 1997-98.Incontrastto theextensivepublicsectorintervention
4% . . . . . . . .
associatedwiththeachievementof self-reliancein staplecereals,
4-A - - - - - - - - - --
efficientlyservingIndia'sincreasinglydiversefood marketsis
Note: Foodconsumptionbased on nationalproduction,supplyanddistribution likely to involve a primaryrole for privatemarkets,processing
estimates. and investment.
Source: Food and AgricultureOrganisationof the UN, FAOSTATdatabase.

Figure 2: Relative Agricultural Prices and GFCF in India


Improved Relative Prices for Agriculture
35,000 - 1.4
An improvementin the relativeprices facing agricultureas-
30,000 1.3 sociatedwiththe 1991-93reformshasalsohadimportant impacts,
0
25,000 + 1.2 evenwithoutmajoragricultural reforms.Throughthemid-1980s,
i/^ --1.1
Z 20.000
- rj-q policies that protectedindustryand taxed agriculturemeant
:.~ 1.0 relativepriceswerebiasedagainstagriculture.After1990,however,
15,000 1
0.9 S relativepricesturnedin favourof agriculture. Althoughfarm
'i 10,000
0 0.8 policy changeslaterin the 1990s, primarilyhigherwheat and
0
5,000
rice supportprices,likely playeda role in this reversal,reduced
0.7 <
industrialprotectionwas the key factor.
0 0.6
Improvedrelativeprice incentivesin agriculturehave corre-
spondedwith an increasingrole for privateinvestmentin the
sector(Figure2). Thisappearsto havehadsomeimpacton several
Public\ Private-a- Rel Ag Prices sub-sectors,suchas poultryandhorticulture, wheredemandand
GFCF= Gross fixedcapitalformationin and foragriculture. investmentincentiveshavebeenparticularly strong.Totalinvest-
Source: EconomicSurvey,Gol; Ministryof Agriculture,Gol. mentin agriculture,however,remainslow and has shownlittle
dynamism.Comparedwith the averageeconomywidelevel of
Rising incomes, particularly in lower- and middle-income gross fixed capitalformation(GFCF)of about26 per cent of
households where the marginal propensity to spend on food is GDP in 2000-02, agriculturalGFCF was only 16 per cent of
high, are having important impacts on food demand in India. agriculturalGDP. Withinthis total, on-farmGFCFwas about
Middle- and upper-income consumers, as well as urbanconsum- 6 per cent of agriculturalGDP, while estimatedGFCFin agri-
ers, are upgrading and diversifying their diets, and changing culture-relatedactivitieswas about10 percent [Governmentof
the pattern of growth in food consumption. Growth in demand India2003b]. Burgeoningsubsidyoutlaysappearto be curbing
for staple foods, particularly wheat and rice, which have been publicinvestmentin agriculture.And,despiterisinganddiversi-
the focus of agricultural development policy, institutions, fyingfood productdemand,privateagribusinessinvestmentthat
and spending is now slowing (Figure 1). By contrast, demand could strengthenruralemploymentremainslargelyunattractive
for other foods, including fruits, vegetables, fats and livestock comparedwith other sectors.
Table 1: Agricultural Supply and Demand Indicators for India
Period Real GDP DemandIndicators Supply/InvestmentIndicators Real Prices (WPI)
in Real GDP/ Real Yield Relative GFCGin/forAgriculture Total Agriculture Food-
Agriculture Capita Agriculture Index1 Prices2 In For Total GFCF grains
Exports 1981-82=100
GrowthRate3
1982-92 (percent) 3.2 3.1 5.2 2.5 1.3 1.2 2.0 1.6 6.0 1.1 0.3
1992-2001 (percent) 2.9 4.0 7.3 1.2 1.6 2.3 3.0 2.7 6.9 0.5 1.7
1992-97 (percent) 3.4 4.2 14.7 1.4 1.2 2.0 3.2 2.8 7.8 0.7 1.4
1997-01 (percent) 2.3 3.9 -1.3 1.0 2.0 2.6 2.7 2.6 5.9 0.3 2.0
Share of Period Share of Period Period Share of Share of Share of Share of Period Period
GDP Average Ag GDP Average Average Ag GDP Ag GDP Ag GDP GDP Average Average
(Per Cent) (Per Cent) (Per Cent) (Per Cent) (Per Cent) (Per Cent)
1981-83 (average) 39.0 5,987 3.9 104.2 0.99 8.3 10.7 19.0 22.8 99.9 1000
1991-93 (average) 31.7 8,136 4.2 134.0 1.13 6.8 9.5 16.3 24.2 111.4 102.6
1996-98 (average) 27.6 9,972 6.6 143.7 1.20 6.4 9.4 15.8 26.0 115.5 110.1
2000-02 (average) 24.2 11,614 5.4 149.4 1.30 6.4 9.6 16.0 26.1 116.7 119.2
(1) 1981-82 = 100. (2)Agriculture/Manufacturing,
base 1981-82 = 100. (3) Growthrates between 3-yearaverages centered on years indicated(1982 = 1981-83
average, etc)
Source: EconomicSurvey, Gol, variousissues; Ministryof Agriculture,Gol; Handbookof Statistics,Reserve Bankof India, 2002.

3612 Economic and Political Weekly August 7, 2004

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
as wheat, rice, corn, oilseeds, and cotton have all declined 4-6 per
Agricultural Performance cent annually during 1982-2001. Global domestic support,export
Althougheconomic performancehas strengthenedsince the subsidy, and market access policies have contributed to the
early1990s,andlargefoodgrainsurplusesaccumulatedformuch declines in world prices, and some hikes in India's cereal support
of the period,growthin the farmsectorhas weakened(Table1). and marketprices may have been justified by India's earlier bias
In the yearsimmediatelyfollowing reforms(1992-97), agricul- against agriculture. But, broad global price trends are funda-
turalGDP grew about 3.4 per cent annually,but then slowed mentally driven by productivity and marketing efficiency gains
to about2.3 per cent (1997-01). The exact cause of this slump in other parts of the world that are not being matched in India.
remainsa matterof debate and research,and it is difficult to These sector indicators suggest that, despite the strengthening
separatetheimpactsof monsoonperformance fromotherfactors. of demandand improvementsin the sector's termsof trade,growth
But,sluggishfarmsectorgrowthandthesharpslowdownin rural in agricultural productivity has slowed and investment remains
employmentgains in the latterhalf of the 1990s is a constraint weak. A potential explanation for these apparentlycontradictory
to sustaininghigh rates of overall economic growth, and to trends lies in the performance of India's agricultural policies.
achievingrural-urban and regionalbalancein economicgains.
Well-endowedregions,includingthosewithbetterinfrastructure Ill
andgovernance,havetendedto registerrelativelystronggrowth MajorAgricultural Policies
comparedwith some others,includingheavilypopulatedstates
suchas UttarPradeshandBihar.Thesedisparitiesmaystemless India's majordomestic agriculturalpolicy instrumentsinclude
fromreformsthathave been undertaken,ratherthanthose that a system of minimum support prices for major crops, input
have not, but regional imbalancesare a concern in India's subsidies on fertiliser, power, and irrigation water, and public
democraticpolitythat,perhapsparadoxically,becomesan argu- investments in surface, and to a lesser extent, groundwater ir-
ment to slow furtherreform. rigation. Historically, these interventions have been accompa-
Factorson boththe supplyanddemandsides havecontributed nied by border measures, including quantitative restrictions on
to sluggishfarmsectorgrowth.Lookingfirstat thedemandside, imports and exports, import tariffs, and state trading. The border
we have seen thatdomesticdemandhas certainlybeen thereto measures were applied in various combinations to different
supportstrongerperformanceby thesector.Agricultural exports, commodities but, except for traditionalexport crops such as tea,
whichnowaccountfor6-7 percentof farmoutput,also strength- coffee, cashews, and spices, traditionallyisolated Indian markets
ened duringthe 1990scomparedwith the 1980s, drivenlargely from world markets. In addition, until the 1991 devaluation, an
bygainsin nontraditional items,suchas cereals,oil cakes,cotton, overvalued rupee imposed roughly a 20 per cent tax on domestic
andmarineproducts(Table2). Theseexports,however,weakened production.
substantiallyduring1997-98-2001-02,reflectinginternalsupply The impacts of these policies on Indian agriculture have been
anddemandconditions,as wellas competitionanddecliningprices documented in a number of studies [Gulati and Narayanan2003;
in worldmarkets.But,even if decliningworldprices- resulting Gulati and Kelley 1999; US Department of Agriculture 1999]
partlyfrompolicies in othercountries- have had a dampening which indicate that, when all commodities are treatedas imports,
influence on Indian exports, the domestic marketdominates aggregate farmoutputhas been taxed by this policy regime during
demandand has provideda strong impetusfor expansion. 1986-2002 (Figure 3).2 Outlays on price supports and input
On the supplyside, sluggishgrowthin farmoutputhas been
associatedwithconflictingtrendsin productivityandinvestment. Table 2: Trends in India's AgriculturalExports
Ontheone hand,growthin productivity(yields)has slowedand, Period Real Agricultural
Exports(Per Cent)
on the other,relativeprice incentivesfor agriculturehave im- Total Comp1 Other
provedand there has been somewhatfaster growthin private Growthrates
agricultural investment.But,despitethesomewhathigherinvest- 1982-92 5.2 5.9 4.7
mentgrowth,perhapsthe key pointsto be takenfromthesedata 1992-91 7.3 7.3 7.2
are that privateinvestmentin agricultureremainsnoticeably 1992-97 1997-01
14.7
-1.3
19.1
-5.8
11.0
2.7
lower thanin the rest of the economy and growingmuchmore
slowly.Anotherimportantissue, of course,is thegenerallyweak Note: tobacco,
(1) Exportscompetitivewith developed countries (cereals, cotton,
meats and preps, oilmeal, animaland vegetable oils, and
performancein public agriculturalinvestmentin the 1990s, otherfood and live animals).
implyingadeclineinhistoricallyproductiveinvestmentin surface Source: EconomicSurvey,Gol, variousissues.
irrigationsystems.Privateinvestment,whilegrowingfasterthan
public investmentand now accountingfor the largershareof Table 3: Trends in Public and Private GFCF
in and for Agriculture
capitalformationin the sector,also slowed comparedwith the (Per cent)
1980s (Table 3).
Pricetrendsin the domesticmarketsuggest thatprice policy Period Public Private Total
has also played a role in sector performance.In concertwith Growthrate*
highersupportprices,Indianfoodgrainpricesrose in realterms 1982-92 -2.5 5.2 1.6
the from the 1992-99 0.8 3.5 2.3
during 1990s, shifting historical
pattern of constant 1992-97 1.5 4.2 2.8
or declining real prices and holding resources in foodgrain 1997-99 -1.1 1.8 1.1
production.In contrast,growthin real prices for the sector as Shares of agriculturalGDP
a wholeactuallyslowedin the 1990s,suggestingthat,apartfrom 1981-83 average 10.3 8.6 19.0
1991-93 average 5.9 10.4 16.3
foodgrains,thesectormaybe doinga reasonablejob of adjusting 1996-98 average 5.4 10.4 15.8
todiversifyingdemand.But,India's risingrealcommodityprices, 1998-2000 average 5.0 10.3 15.3
whetherfor foodgrainsor otherfoods, are sharplyat odds with *Growthrates between 3-year averages centredon
years indicated.
long termglobaltrends.Real worldpricesforcommoditiessuch Source:Ministryof Agriculture,Gol.

Economicand PoliticalWeekly August 7, 2004 3613

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure 3: Aggregate Producer Support Estimates for India weakening the environment for private investment that could
boost efficiency and employment.

20 IV
PolicyPerformance
Agricultural
-40 - -
None of India's domestic support policies faced discipline as
-.60
a result of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture. As
notified to the WTO, India's Aggregate Measure of Support
0 L
(AMS) shows negative aggregate support through the 1990s.
Input subsidies are notified by India as support to small, resource
- -100 poor farmers that is exempt under the URAA. Similarly, expen-
ditures under the "foodgrain subsidy" are notified as domestic
food aid and not counted as producer support.
-120.............I The market access disciplines of the URAA that required
coD - 0 C o0 Cj c T LO I(D r-t O c 0
Co 0Co ) O O 0' c) co
c cc c0
cc c)
cc cc ac0c
c c0c co o o o cc o o o0 "tariffication"of agricultural imports, together with India's loss
of its WTO balance of payments waiver in 1997, did lead to
Source:Gulatiand Narayanan2003.
changes in India's border policies for agricultural products.
Changes, completed in April 2001, included the removal of
subsidies are large, but the impacts of these measures have quantitative import restrictions and establishment of tariffs for
typically been more than offset by relatively low domestic farm- all agriculturalimports. For major commodities, however, tariff
gate prices that prevail due to quantitative import and export bindings are sufficiently high to prevent imports, although some
restrictionsand high marketing costs. Although some commodi- imports of high-value and processed items (fruits, nuts, canned
ties, particularlyoilseeds, have been fairly consistently protected goods, etc) are now occurring at bound rates. In most cases where
(subsidised), and others have been protected in occasional market significant imports have occurred, such as edible oils, pulses,
conditions, the sector as a whole has been taxed, even following and cotton, it is because of a unilateral GoI decision to set applied
the 1991 devaluation. More recent protection estimates show that, rates below bound rates. For a few commodities, including
through a combination of rising budgetary subsidies and smaller oilseeds (phyto-sanitary regulation) and corn (tariff rate-quota
gaps between domestic and world prices, the taxation of Indian administration), non-tariff barriers likely prevent trade at bound
agriculturehas declined significantly. When the majorcommodi- rates even when market price conditions are favourable.
ties are treated as exportables - and relative prices are compared There are several importantareas of agriculturalpolicy during
at the border rather than the farm gate - protection even turns the 1990s that are instructive to analyse in terms of performance
positive for 2001 and 2002. and alternatives for reform.
An additional set of domestic policies affecting agriculture is, - Grain producer price policy
however, not directly accounted for in the above protection - Removal of export restraints
measures but are, perhaps, increasingly importantin their impact - Protection of oilseeds and oils
on the sector's adjustment to expanding demand. A partial list. - Market and regulatory reform
-The Essential Commodities Act (ECA), enacted afterthe Bengal
Famine but still in force in the 1990s, empowers central and state
Grain Producer Price Policy
governments to impose restrictions on the storage and movement
of commodities, such as foodgrains, pulses, and edible oils, thus The most observable recent development in Indian agriculture
limiting the scope for private investment in these markets. was the accumulation of large government surpluses of wheat
- Until recently, all food-processing industries were limited to and rice, including the emergence of significant - and subsidised
small-scale capacities and, despite deregulation, small-scale, low - exports of these commodities. The stockpiles and exports
technology firms established under the old laws still dominate occurred alongside rising real domestic wheat and rice prices and
the industry. Some products are still restricted to small-scale actual declines in per capita consumption, even as roughly 260
firms, and food-processing units still require approval from eight million Indianscontinue to live in poverty.Addressingthis perverse
central government ministries. set of outcomes is a major challenge to Indian policy-makers.
- Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee (APMC) regula- The surpluses emerged in the context of secular changes in con-
tions requireagriculturalsales to occur only in regulated markets, sumerdemand, together with changes in producerprice and public
limiting private investment in market activities, as well as in- distributionpolicies. Thereis good evidence thataggregatedemand
tegration of producers with the marketing chain. is shifting away from wheat and rice. Although there is contro-
- Weak laws providing insufficient protection for lessors and versy on this issue, analyses of consumer demand based on
lessees limit use of land leasing to assemble larger, more efficient NationalSampleSurveydata[Kumar2001 a] suggestthat,while low
operational units, and limit private investment to improve agri- income groups still show positive income elasticities of demand
cultural land. for cereals, but those for the population as a whole are near zero.
Although most of these issues have been the targetof discussion Nationalminimumsupportprices(MSPs) forfoodgrainsand other
and some action by the central government, there has been little major commodities are recommended by the Commission for
actual implementationof reform. State governments, which must Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP), but are actually set by a
accept and implement any changes, have been reluctant to act committee chairedby the primeminister.CACP recommendations
on central government reform recommendations. These regula- are based on several factors, but assessments of costs of pro-
tions impose costs on the agricultural marketing and processing duction (COP) and domestic and global marketconditions appear
industries and additional taxes on farm output, as well as key. Historically, the MSPs for wheat and rice were generally

3614 Economic and Political Weekly August 7, 2004

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure 4: Indian Wheat Support Price, Production Costs An important factoraffectingMSPpolicyin the 1990sconcerns
and World Price
the changing political dimensions of the policy when India
250 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - enteredan era of coalition governmentsand the farm lobby
225 ... . becamemoreinfluential.During1995-96- 2001-02,just before
, 200- - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - - - - and duringthe accumulationof surpluses,the governmentset
\~
MSPs above the CACP recommendationin four out of seven
1 5. . . . .... . . .. , . . . . .
yearsfor rice andfive out of seven yearsfor wheat[Parikh2002
et al]. Anotherkey dimensionis thatthe MSPmechanismis one
of the few leversavailableto Indianpolicy-makersand thereis
a tendencyto try to use it to achieve multiplepolicy goals,
175.I -- - MSP (official) - - World(US) includingboth price stabilisationand income support.
The failureof price policy to successfullyadaptto the new
50 -., .-.,-,---".-, , . l . _.".-.'.' .' environmenthas had a numberof impacts.First,breakingwith
thehistoricalpattern,domesticwheatandricepriceshavetended
to strengthenrelativeto bothworldanddomesticprices,andto
move above domesticmarketclearinglevels (Figure5). While
-0 I- COP(Punjab) MSP(shadow) benefitingthe relativelyfew producersreceivingwheatandrice
Note: MSP(official)based on officialexchange rate,whichwas 20-30 per MSPs, higherconsumerprices have undoubtedlyhad negative
cent overvaluedduring1980-81-1990-91. MSP(shadow)based on impacts.Per capita wheat and rice consumptionhas actually
shadow exchange rates. declined in recent years, as higher procurementand prices
Sources: Ministryof Agriculture,
Gol;US Departmentof Agriculture,
Economic contributedto declinesin consumptionof open marketsupplies
Research Service.
that have not been offset by subsidiseddistribution.A recent
Figure 5 Trends in Wholesale Prices in India
studyof the economywideimpactsof increasingthe wheatand
Allcommodities -
riceMSPswhentheyareabovemarketclearinglevels foundthat
.
reducedconsumptionand investmentassociated with higher
All food - .
pricesactuallyreducedincomes,bothin aggregateandfor most
Meat,fish and eggs ruraland urbanincome groups [Parikhet al 2002].3
Vegetables Second,bymaintaining highprices,thegovernmenthasbecome
Fruits - _ I '
responsibleforthestorageandtransportof mostof the marketed
Milk _
[ 81-91 surplusof FAQ-gradewheatandrice in thecountry-what some
, ,
.91-00 observershavetermeda "defactonationalisation"
Edibleoil of graintrade.
Pulses
In additionto raisingbudgetarycosts, the policy provideslittle
incentivefor privateinvestmentin grain storage,handling,or
Rice --- ,,,,i' distribution,with the exceptionof the fees traderscan earn in
Wheat l__ -- the exportof subsidisedgrain allocatedby the government.
2.00.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 10.0 Third,by focusing on supportingrelativelyhigh pricesonly
GrowthRate (Per Cent) for wheatand rice in a few regions,MSP policy has not been
Source:Ministryof Commerce,Gol. made an effective tool for stabilisingproducerpricesfor other
crops and supportingthe diversificationof agriculture.
increased at ratesbelow inflation, and remained well underimport Fourth,the budgetarycost of FCI operationsundercurrent
parityprices.Althoughintendedto be a nationalprogrammecovering policies has now reached about $5.5 billion. When policies
all majorcrops,the MSPs aregenerally defended by GoI purchases
supportdomestic prices above marketclearing, much of this
only for wheat and rice in the major surplus areas of Punjab, subsidyaccruesto producersratherthanconsumers.Combined
Haryana,western UttarPradesh, and Andhra Pradesh (rice only). withthecostof subsidiesonfertiliserandotherinputs,thesubsidy
Beginning in the late-1990s, the MSPs set for wheat and rice bill has burgeonedto about$15 billion annually,far exceeding
became increasingly out of step with domestic marketconditions. bothpublic($1 billionin 2001-02)andprivate($2.8billion)capital
One key factor was (and still is) that the COP concept used in formationin agriculture.Subsidyoutlaysarecrowdingout new
setting the price became a "full cost" measure that, in addition investmentneededto boostproductivity andmarketing
to variable input costs, included the rental value of land, the efficiency.
Finally,the policy of maintaininghigh wheatand rice prices
imputed value of family labour, and a return to management. hascontributed toemergentenvironmental problems,particularly
Another was pressure to compensate farmers for the price swings associated with the intensive wheat-ricecropping system in
associated with changes in India's rice and wheat export policy northernIndia.Whencombinedwith the low cost of irrigation
during 1995 and 1996. For rice, higher market prices resulting water- muchof which is eitherfree, stolen,or subsidised- the
from the initial removal of export restraintslater created pressure
strongpriceincentivesfor wheatandrice arecontributingto the
for higher MSPs when world prices fell. Similarly for wheat,
rapiddeterioration of groundwater resources,andrisingconcern
lower marketprices following the re-imposition export restraints with deterioratingsoil fertilityin some areas.
led the government to compensate farmers with higher MSPs.
With these developments, the MSPs became disconnected from
domestic market conditions and - when world prices fell from Removal of Export Restraints
a temporary spike in 1996-97 - from competitive world market
Throughthe 1980s and early 1990s, Indianagriculturewas
prices (Figure 4). The tendency for MSPs to be increased has burdenedwith export restrictionsand overvalued exchange
likely been compounded as MSP benefits boost land rental, ratesthatresultedin net taxationof the sector.Exportsof agri-
labour,and managementcosts, thus leading to higherCOP. culturalgoodswererestrictedthroughmyriadcontrols,including

Economic and Political Weekly August 7, 20043615

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure 6: Rice Trade and Protection in India beginning to stimulate market integration or coordination
1.6 - - .- .- .- .- .- .- .- .- .- -.- - - - -
- -.. - - - - - - - 5.0 between exporters,millers, and contractproducersin orderto
4.9 5.0 ensurequality [Bhatt2004; Roy 2002].
-4.0
With these potentiallypositive impacts on investmentand
competitiveness,theremovalof exportrestraintsopensupa new
setof policyissuesconcerningtheimpactsof globalpricechanges
0
o0 0.9 0.9
7 09.
on thedomesticmarket.First,theremovalof riceexportrestraints
0.5 1.0 2:
- 70.5
initiallybenefitedproducersandtraderswhenit pulleddomestic
C Net Exports -Importable -0.4 05E - e pricesabovetheMSP.But,whenworldpricesretreated,theMSPs
'0.84I c becamedisconnectedfrommarketrealities,leadingto increases
c~~~~~~~~~a" in domesticand exportsubsidycosts. Thus, with the removal
x~~~~~~-.
-C 0.6 -2.0.. of exportrestraints,it becomesimportantto haveanMSPsetting
mechanism(and discipline)that keeps MSPs connectedwith
0.2 ' ~ ~ ~.4 domesticand world prices.
Second,sinceanimportant rationaleforrestraining
exportswas
0,2 - -5.0 to ensurestabledomesticconsumerprices,theremovalof export
o
oo o') C) oa) o' restraintsmay increaseperiodicdemandson domesticdistribu-
tionprogrammes to stabilisesuppliesfor lower-incomeconsum-
C- NetExports -s- Importable -9? Exportable ers. The recenthigherdomesticpricesanddeclinesin percapita
(in million tonnes) Hypothesis Hypothesis
exportprices, for the sake of domestic food security. For a number rice consumption suggestthatat leastsomeconsumershavebeen
Source:Gulati
Source: Gulatiand and Mullen 2003.
Mullen 2003. adverselyaffected.However,since globalrice priceshavebeen
declining since the mid-1990s, these impactsare more likely
prohibitions,licenses, quotas, marketing controls and minimum drivenby highMSPsanddeclinesin distribution associatedwith
export prices, for the sake of domestic food security. For a number implementation of theTargetedPublicDistributionSystem,than
of products, the quantitative controls on exports were admin- by the removalof exportrestraints.
istered through trading enterprises in the public and cooperative
sectors.
Import Protection: Case of Oilseeds and Oils
Agricultural export policies began to change in 1994 and,
barringthe occasional reversal,have been progressively liberalised. Althoughthe1991-93economicreformssubstantially liberalised
The ministryof commerce, throughthe directorgeneral of foreign India'sexternaltraderegimefor manynon-agricultural goods,
trade, imposes or removes export restrictions in order to promote progressin phasingout quantitativerestrictionson agricultural
exports while also ensuring 'adequate' domestic supplies of productsremainedslow. Exceptfor the liberalisationof import
essential commodities at 'reasonable' prices. Reforms have licensingon sugarandcottonin 1994,mostagricultural products
included reductions in products subject to state trading,relaxation remainedsubjectto importcontrols.In 1997, followingthe loss
of export quotas, the abolition of minimum export prices, and of thebalance-of-payments waiver,Indiaphasedoutquantitative
increased credit availability for exports. In 2000, India also began importrestrictionsand QRs were finally lifted in April 2001.
to provide significant budgetary subsidies to support exports of Despitethe fearsof Indianpolicy-makers,the largeanticipated
surplus cereals when the combination of declining world prices surgein farmimportsdid not materialise.Importsincreasedin
and higher domestic prices make Indian wheat and rice some categories,includinghigh-valueandprocesseditemswith
uncompetitive in world markets. tariffsof 50-100 percent,butnot to levels thatposedsignificant
Developments in the Indian rice market since the removal of threatsto domestic producers.
export restraints may be indicative of the impacts of this type Oilseedsandproductsarea majorsectorof domesticproduc-
of reform (Figure 6). Private traders were permitted to export tion andconsumptionthathas, perhaps,been the most affected
common rice beginning in 1994-95 and, although exports remain by importliberalisation policyduringthe 1990s(Figure7). Trade
small relative to production, India immediately became a major policy changesin the sectorhave, however,been mostlyunilat-
player, selling primarily into the lower end of the international eral,ratherthanmandatedby URAA disciplines.Until 1993-94,
market.Since 2000-01, however, the combination of lower world all edible oil imports were controlledby the State Trading
prices and firm domestic prices has made Indian rice exports less Corporation, whichbasedimportdecisionson domesticmarket
price-competitive, leading to GoI subsidies for rice exports. conditionsandotherpolicy goals. Importswerereducedsharply
Rice exports have helped moderate the growth of surplus rice during1987-93,asthegovernmentattemptedto boostproduction
stocks and, together with higher MSPs and lower domestic incentivesand adoptionof moderntechnology.
distribution of subsidised rice, contributed to a strengthening of In 1993-94, the governmentabandonedthis approachand
domestic prices. The growth in exports, along with relaxation openedimportsto privatetraders,subjectonly to tariffswhich
of earlier policies limiting rice milling to small-scale enterprises, were set well below boundrates.Importspicked up
slowly at
are stimulating investment in moder rice milling and grading first,but surgedin the late 1990s, eventuallymakingIndiathe
equipment. The opening up of exports exposed the inefficiency world's largestimporter.Tariffsfor most oils have now been
of domestic rice marketing and processing infrastructure,and the raisedto 65-85 percent, butare still well below the boundrates
absence of quality and grading standards, needed to compete in of 300 percent.Hikesin thetariffon palmoil, themajor
imported
world markets. Although the bulk of India's rice continues to oil, as well as rapeseedand sunfloweroils, are constrained
by
be processed in inefficient, small-scale mills with no formal the relativelylow 45 per cent bound rate for soybeanoil, the
grading standards,the basmati rice export business, in particular, secondlargestimportedoil. Despitethe tariffs,oil importshave
has sparkedinvestmentin bettertechnologyfor processingand continuedto expand, now accountingfor 45-50 per cent of
grading.In some cases, the basmatiexport business is also domesticoil consumption.

3616 Economic and Political Weekly August 7, 2004

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure 7: Edible Oil Imports and Tariffs in India remunerativeand stable prices directly to growers. There is
8.0 150 evidencethatthecurrentapproachof taxingoil importsprimarily
7.0 benefitsoilseed processorsand traders,with only a portionof
i6"
=
.
^
*e t
125 the protectionactuallybenefitingoilseed growers [Gulatiand
c C 6.0-%
S

r- C:
?%' ^
C
Kelley1999;Figure8]. Evenin a veryefficientandfullyintegrated
'"' 5.0 "- . ,'
marketthebenefitto oilseedgrowersof a tariffon oils is limited
.2 ) . . " 75 0.
C to the rateof oil extractionfrom the seed, rangingfrom about
4.0 QR 75
o
00'8 ftll___ ..e',517 18 per cent in the case of soyabeanto about45 per cent for
sunflowerseed.With the domestic processing industryoper-
CO O0 .( 30 3 atingforonly three-fourmonthsof theyear,oilseedprocurement
operationswouldentailonly short-termgovernment stockholding.
i.0 Anotheroptionis to ease restrictionson oilseed importsand
0.0 1 0O on the scale of domestic processing facilities to foster the
to
co co 0
aco co o o-
co . , D 'n 0 o ax CO) 0 developmentof a moreefficient,verticallyintegrateddomestic
-) 0) a) 0 0 a ) 0) ) 0) 0
processingandmarketingindustry.Inadequatescale, poortech-
I Imports- TariffRate - - - International Price (Palm Oil) nology, and low potentialto boost capacity utilisationfrom
Source:Gulatiand Mullen2003. domesticraw materialsnow make most of India's processing
capacityfragmented,inefficientby world standards,and inca-
Figure 8: Competitiveness of Oilseed Production pable of producingqualityoil and feed protein.An alternate
and Oil Processing in India
scenario,requiringcoordinationof oilseed and oil tariffsand a
solutionto currentnon-tariffbarriersto oilseed imports,might
Rapeseed-
mustard allow processorsto importoilseedsandboostcapacityuse, thus
making investmentsin more efficient, integratedunits more
economicallyviable. A more efficient and dynamic industry
Sunflower wouldyield benefitsfor bothproducersandconsumers,as well
oil
IEdible as anenvironmentmoreconduciveto privateinvestmentto boost
'*|~ :~-^* ~' ~Oilseeds
?~ ~ local oilseed production.
Groundnut
Market and Regulatory Reform

Soyabean
India'sdomesticagriculturalmarketsandprocessingindustry
have,historically,beensubjectto a virtualthicketof regulation,
initially intendedto protect consumersand promote labour-
0.0
0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 intensive industry,but also severely limiting the viability of
NominalProtectionCoefficients,1990-95 Average
employment-generating private investment.Several of these
Source:Gulatiand Kelley1999. regulatory issuesarelistedin theabovediscussionof agricultural
policy.Recently,however,initialstepshavebeentakentoliberalise
The swings in edible oil importpolicy have clearly had an domesticagriculturalmarkets.Among these changesare:
impact on domestic production,consumption,and prices of - The temporaryremovalof licensing requirements,stocking
oilseedsandoils. Importrestraintsduring1987-93led to higher limits,and movementrestrictionsfor wheat,paddy/rice,coarse
domesticoil and oilseed prices,leadingto increasesin planted grains,edible oilseeds and edible oils underthe ECA by some,
area and yields. Since 1994, with reducedprotectionfor oils, but not all, state governments.
and the lack of a procurementmechanismto defendMSPs for - GoI removalof plantscale restrictionsand licensingrequire-
oilseeds,oilseed areahas tendedto decline and yield growthto ments for most food processingactivities.
stagnate[Kumar2001b; Gulatiand Kelley]. Also, chronically - GoI removal of the restrictionson futures tradingon 54
low capacityutilisationratesin the oilseed processingindustry commodities,includingwheat, rice, oilseeds and pulses.
have fallen even lower. On the consumptionside, however, - Gol reformof the milk and milk productsorderto no longer
consumershave benefitedfrom lower real domesticoil prices restrictlarge-scaleinvestmentsin new processingcapacity.
and significantgains in per capita consumptionsince 1993. In addition,the GoI has proposed,for the considerationof the
The overallwelfareimplicationsof the changesin oil import states,revisionsto the APMCAct thatwouldpermitthe devel-
policy have not been analysed.Farmersand oilseed processors opmentof privatemarketsand is, reportedly,workingon legal
regularlylobbyfor restrictionson oil imports,andsome policy- changesto facilitatelandleasingandcontractfarming.Another
makershavebeenlookingfornon-tariff restrictions
togetaroundthe important reformunderconsiderationis to streamlinefoodsafety
low 45-percentboundratefor soyabeanoil so thattheycanhave laws,includingconsolidationof responsibilitiesandjurisdiction,
moreflexibilityto raisetheratesforpalmandotheroils [Chandra- as well as closer alignmentwith internationalstandards.
shekhar2002]. Oilseed processorsalso lobby periodicallyfor These proposedreformsare likely to help improvethe envi-
freerimportsof oilseeds and lower duties on crudevs refined ronmentforprivateinvestment,structural change,andefficiency
oils, inorderto boostcapacityutilisationin crushingandrefining. gainsin agribusinessthatcouldyieldsubstantialbenefitsstreams
Largelyunanalysedare variouspolicy optionsfor improving to Indianproducersandconsumers,andboostruralemployment.
the competitivenessof the domestic oilseed and productsin- Estimatesof currentmarketingcosts in the agriculturalsector
dustry.One optionis to shift fromrelianceon oil importtariffs indicatethe potentialfor efficiency gains:
as the tool for intervention,to an MSP programmethatdefends - Inthecaseof vegetables,mostof whicharemarketedwithlittle
oilseed pricesthroughgovernmentpurchasesand,thus,assures grading,packaging,processingor otherformof valueaddition,

Economicand PoliticalWeekly August 7, 2004 3617

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Figure9: PoultryProducerPrices and RetailMarginsin India cent of the population,there is a deep-rootedbelief that the
80 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . welfareof the poor is linked closely to the protectionof agri-
culture. In India's era of coalition governments,it has been
70 - -- - - - - - - increasinglydifficult for policy-makersto take risks on agri-
culturalpolicy reformthat would entail short-runadjustment
costs- eithereconomicorpolitical.Althoughthereis a significant
50 L- and growingreform-mindedconstituency,there is little doubt
thatthe largelydefensivepositionstakenby Indiain the recent
540 -- Cancunministerialhave been popularin India.
30 -- 'T - - Tomoveforward,it wouldappearimportant toforgerecognition
andagreementon severalbroaddirectionsforthereformagenda:
20 - - - - Pricepolicy: As long as producerpricepolicy attemptsto meet
both incomeand price stabilisationgoals, it will be difficultto
10 - - - -
containitscosts,orto servetheefficientallocationof resourcesin
thesector.Inthecontextof market-orientedreformandamoreopen
North West , C th traderegime,it will be importantfor price policy to take more
Source:Landes and Persaud. B Producerpriceo Producer-retail
margin explicit accountof domesticand worldprice conditions,rather
thanameasureof production costs.Extensionof effectiveproducer
farmersreceive about 25 per cent of the consumerprice, and pricestabilisationto cropsotherthanwheatand rice could help
losses in the supplychain are roughly40 per cent (McKinsey). promoteboth sector diversificationand income stability.For
- For wheat,most of which is sold to consumerswithoutvalue incomesupport,otherpolicyinstruments, includingtargetedfood
addition,producer-to-retail marketingcosts also appearhigh, distributionandactuariallysoundcropinsuranceproducts,may
particularly if the costs of governmentoperationsare included. providesupportwith lower cost and less marketdistortion.
Estimatesbasedon GoI,FCI,andWorldBankdataindicatetotal Exportrestraints:The removalof restraintson exports is an
producer-to-consumer marginfor wheatof aboutRs 4,850 per importantstepin reducingthe traditionalimplicittaxationof the
tonne, or 80 per cent of the producerprice (USDA). agriculturalsector.The removalof suchconstraintscanpromote
- In southernand western India, vertically integratedbroiler beneficialprivateinvestmentandemploymentin thesupplychain
operations are reducing production costs among contract for internationallycompetitivecommodities.To be sustained,
growers, andefficiencygains in the formof reducedproducer- however, free exports will require consumer and business
consumermarginsappearsignificant.Producersare benefiting acceptanceof the influenceof world price fluctuationsin the
fromreducedmarketingriskandassuredreturns,whileconsum- domesticmarket,and in adjustingpolicy prices.In the case of
ers gain from lower prices (USDA; Figure9). food staples,low-incomeconsumersmay need continuedpro-
- Sincethe removalof quantitativeimportrestrictions,imported tectionfromany upswingsin worldanddomesticpricesthrough
processedfoodsarenowseen in manyurbanstores,despitetariffs currentor enhancedfood distributionprogrammes.
of50-60percent.Typically,however,thebulkof themarginbetween Import liberalisation/protection: Concerns with the market
the portandthe consumeris not due to the tariff,butto the high distortingpolicies of othercountriesshouldnot preventimple-
marginstakenby importers,wholesalersand retailers(USDA). mentation of economically beneficial import liberalisation
Followingthroughon marketingandregulatoryreformappears measures.The removalof quantitativeimportrestrictionshas
to be criticalto the emergenceof a moredynamicand efficient generallyhad negligibleimpacton producers,while providing
agribusinesssector drivenby privateinvestment.Anotherpo- benefits to consumers. In some sectors, such as oilseeds,
tentiallysignificantchangenow occurringin some urbanareas liberalisationcould lead to additionalgains for consumers,
is the emergenceof largescale, chainwholesalingandretailing producers,and processors- not to mentionemploymentgains
enterpriseswithinvestmentfromeitherdomesticorforeignfirms. - by facilitatingdevelopmentof moreefficient processingand
Inothercountries,theemergenceof largescaleandchainretailing marketing.Importliberalisationanddomesticderegulationhave
has been a key to the developmentof moreefficient, vertically benefitedmanynon-agricultural industriesandconsumerssince
integratedsupplychains.This phenomenonhas the potentialto 1991-93, why not agriculture?
be an importantdevelopmentin India,as well, althoughcurrent Public investment:The inability to reform price policy and
rules againstFDI in retailingis likely to slow its growth.It is containinputsubsidieshasled to a declinein publicinvestmentin
unclearwhetherthe recent and proposedreformswill be suf- agricultureata timewheninvestmentin newtechnology,infrast-
ficient to sparkincreasedprivatedomesticand foreign invest- ructure,andinstitutionsis needed.EventhoughIndia'ssubsidies
ment,orif additionalreformsand/orpublicinfrastructure invest- havenotbeenchallengedundercurrentWTOrules,their with-
ments will be needed to improvethe investmentclimate. draw would provide a large pool of resources with which to
compensateproducersfor pricepolicy reformthroughhigher-
V returninvestmentsin technology, markets,andinfrastructure.
ShapingReformAgenda Privateinvestment:Publicinvestmentcannotbe expectedto fill
theinvestmentgapinagriculture. Improvingtheclimatefor private
Consensus-building for changein agriculturalpolicy has been investmentand employmentin marketsfor agriculturalinputs
very difficultin India.Thereis a greatdeal of inertiain current and outputs is, therefore, essential for boosting the growth
policies and institutions,in partbecauseof the belief thatthese and competitiveness of an increasingly diverse agricultural
policies have served India well in achieving foodgrainself- sector. Stimulatingprivatedomestic and foreign agribusiness
sufficiency,butalso becausethey have createdpowerfulvested investmentwill requirepublicinvestmentsin marketinfrastruc-
interests.Perhapsmore importantly,with the farm sector the ture,supportiveimportand exportpolicies, andcomprehensive
sourceof 25 per cent of GDP, and of income for about65 per 'behindtheborder'reformsof marketregulationsandinstitutions.

3618 Economicand Political Weekly August 7, 2004

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VI The Hindu Business Line (Online). http:www.blonnet.com/2004/02/03/
stories/2004020301521100.htm, February 3, 2004.
AnalyticalNeeds Bijapurkar,R (2003): 'The New ImprovedIndianConsumer'Business World
(Online). Available at http//:www.businessworldindia.co/Dec0803/
To help push forward a consensus on reform, there appear to coverstoryOl.asp,December 8, 2003.
be several important analytical gaps to be filled. First, while Chandrashekhar,G (2002): 'TradePerturbedover ProposedCurbson Soya
Oil Inflow', The Hundu Business Line, (Online) Available at
policies largely maintained low and stable cereal prices through www.blonnet.com/2002/03/28/stories/2002032800461.htm March 28,
the 1970s and 1980s, current farm policy has relied on the 2004.
proposition that higher administered producer prices will have Diao, Xinshen, E Diaz-Bonilla, and S Robinson (2003): How Much Does
it Hurt?: The Impact of Agricultural Trade Policies on Developing
positive long runbenefits for employment and income generation Countries.InternationalFood Policy Research Institute,August, p 8.
among the poor. Even in a country where the average consumer Dohlman, E, S Persaud and R Landes (2003): India's Edible Oil Sector:
spends about 55 per cent of their income on food, and the poor Imports Fill Rising Demand, Market and Trade Economics Division,
EconomicResearchService,US Departmentof Agriculture,OCS-0903-01,
spend upwards of 70 per cent, it is rare to find an advocate of
November, p 20.
the potential long run benefit of lower food prices. In a further Government of India(2001): EconomicReforms:AMedium-Term Perspective.
departurefrom historical practice, recent policies have embodied Prime Minister's Economic Advisory Council, New Delhi, January.
the proposition that larger current subsidies on inputs have a - (2002a): Agricultural Statistics at a of
Glance, Department Agriculture
and Cooperation, New Delhi, June.
higher economic return than public investments in agriculture. - (2002b): High Level Committee Report on Long-Term Grain Policy,
More research and analysis within economywide frameworks Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food and Public Distribution, New
may be effective in evaluating the growth and equity impacts Delhi, Online. Available at http://fcamin.nic.in/hlc_contents.htm
of these alternative policy options, and in provoking debate and May 9, 2003.
- (2002c): Reportof Inter-MinisterialTaskForce on AgriculturalMarketing
consensus on development strategy.
Reforms,Departmentof AgricultureandCooperation,New Delhi, May 27.
Second, much of Indian agriculturalpolicy, and fear of market- - (2003a): Economic Survey 2002-03, Ministry of Finance, New Delhi,
oriented reform, is based on the perception that reducing import (Online). Available at http://indiabudget.nic.in/May 12, 2003.
barrierswill increasedomestic price volatility andthreatenproducer - (2003b): Report of the Committeeon Capital Formation in Agriculture,
livelihood and consumer welfare. Thus, Indian WTO positions Department of Agriculture and Cooperation, New Delhi, (Online).
Available at http://agricoop.nic.in/ statistics2003/FinalReport.doc
typicallystriveto maintainboundratesatlevels thatwill preventtrade, March 2003.
and to also have the right to introduce QRs through safeguard Gulati, A and S Bathla (2002): Capital Formation in Indian Agriculture:
or other mechanisms. Research should be able to play a role by Trends, Composition, and Implications for Growth, Occasional Paper
24, National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development, Mumbai.
providing objective analysis of the extent to which concerns with Gulati,A andT Kelley (1999): TradeLiberalisationand IndianAgriculture.
volatility may be true, and by examining options for providing Oxford University Press, New Delhi.
and consumer with less market distortion Gulati, A and K Mullen (2093): Responding to Policy Reform: Indian
producer price stability
and more scope for beneficial import and export competition. AgricultureDuring the 1990s and After, paper preparedfor the Four;h
Annual Conference on India Economic Policy Reform, The Centre for
Finally, border reforms that have occurred have tended to Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanfor!
expose inefficiency in India's domestic agricultural markets University, Palo Alto, June.
Gulati,A and S Narayanan(2003): SubsidySyndromein IndianAgriculture.
stemming from heavy regulation, poor technology, and substan- Oxford Press, New Delhi.
tial underinvestment - both public and private. While some initial Gulati,A, GUniversity Purselland K Mullen (2003): IndianAgricultureSince Reforms:
steps have been taken to reduce the web of regulation that has Performance,Policy Environment,and Incentives(Mimeo, International
deterredprivateinvestment, and private investment has increased, Food Policy Research Institute).
P K and A Gulati (2003): 'From Plate to Plough: Agricultural
much more is needed. Research should be able to play a role Joshi, Diversification in India', paper presented at the 'The Dragon and the
in examining the climate for private investment and identifying Elephant:A ComparativeStudy of Economic and AgriculturalReforms
additional reforms, beyond those already identified, which may in China and India', In New Delhi, India, March 25-26.
be needed to help stimulate domestic and foreign investment in Kapila, R and U Kapila (eds) (2002): Indian Agriculturein the Changing
Environment,Vols 1 and 2, Academic House, Ghaziabad, India.
the sector. m3 Kumar, P (2001a): 'Food Demand Projections for India', Agricultural
Economics Policy Paper 98-01, IARI, New Delhi.
Addressfor correspondence: - (2001b): 'AgriculturalProductivityand Performance'in S S Acharyaand
D P Chaudhri(eds), IndianAgriculturalPolicy at the Crossroads,Rawat
AGulati@cgiar.org
Publications, Jaipur and New Delhi, India, pp 353-475.
Landes,M R (2002): 'India:PotentialBenefits of WheatMarketingReform',
Notes InternationalSeminaron Wheatand Wheat Products,Hyderabad,India,
September 27-28.
[The views expressed are those of the authors.] Landes,M R andS Persaud(2004): India's PoultrySector:Developmentand
1 The terms-of-tradefor agriculture,that is the ratio of prices received Prospects, Marketand Trade Economics Division, Economic Research
to prices paid in the sector, also improved during the period. Relative Service, U S Departmentof Agriculture. ATR WRS-04-03, January.
K A Ganesh Kumarand G Darbha(2002): 'Growthand Welfare
prices for agricultureand manufacturingare used here because the data Parikh, S,
are more current. Consequences of Rise in MSP', Economic and Political Weekly,
2 When commodities are treated as exports, aggregate support becomes Vol XXXVIII, No 9, March 1-7, pp 891-95.
marginally positive in 2001 and 2002. Pursell,G (1996): 'India:TradePolicy, the ExchangeRate and the Domestic
3 Given this evidence, one could hypothesise that more poverty reduction Termsof Tradefor Agriculture',Mimeo, WorldBank, Washington,DC.
have occurred in the 1990s had Roy, A S (2002): 'Induss Food in Talks to Upgrade Rice Mills, The Hindu
might foodgrainprice policy maintained Business Line, (Online), http:www.blonnet.com/2002-05/10/stories/
its historical balance of producer and consumer interests, ratherthan
2002051000131.htm [May 10, 2002].
tilting towards a small subset of producers. U S Departmentof Agriculture(1994): 'Estimatesof ProducerandConsumer
SubsidyEquivalents:GovernmentInterventionin Agriculture,1982-92',
References Economic Research Service, Statistical Bulletin No 913, December,
p452.
Ahluwalia,M (2002): 'EconomicReformsin Indiasince 1991:HasGradualism - (2001): The Road Ahead: Agricultural Policy Reform in the WTO -
Worked?' Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol 16, no 3 (Summer): Summary Report, Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic
pp 67-88. Research Service, AER No 797, January2001, p 26.
Bhatt, D (2004): 'KRBL Acquires IntegratedRice Milling Plant in Punjab', WorldBank (2003): WorldDevelopmentReport.IBRD, Washington,p 250.

Economicand PoliticalWeekly August 7, 2004 3619

This content downloaded from 14.139.45.243 on Wed, 9 Apr 2014 07:03:53 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like